14.461: technological change, lecture 3 competition

54
14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition, Policy and Technological Progress Daron Acemoglu MIT September 11, 2014. Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 1 / 54

Upload: others

Post on 16-Oct-2021

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3Competition, Policy and Technological Progress

Daron Acemoglu

MIT

September 11, 2014.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 1 / 54

Page 2: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Competition, Policy and Innovation Introduction

Introduction: Competition

What is the effect of competition on innovation and technologicalprogress?

The baseline models of endogenous technology suggest that it isnegative because greater competition reduces profits from monopolythat innovator will acquire.

This is both unintuitive and inconsistent with several studies, which,if anything, find a negative relationship (e.g., Nickell, 1996, orBlundell, Griffi th and Van Reenen, 1999).

One reason for this may be that benchmark models have too stylizedrepresentations of competition.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 2 / 54

Page 3: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Competition, Policy and Innovation Introduction

Introduction: Patent Policy

Related question: what’s the effect of patent enforcement oninnovation?Baseline models: more patent protection always better.Opposite view: Boldrin and Levine and some practitioners: patentsare always bad and innovation does not require patent protection.Middle view: of course patents are used for rent seeking and naturallythere is a trade-off because of the ex post monopoly power grantedthe patent holders and the potential ex ante incentive benefits.

This might lead to a situation in which intermediate levels ofprotection are preferred.Also, perhaps greater patent protection is not always good forinnovation even in the presence of ex-ante incentive effects.

This lecture: introducing some richer models of competition andinnovation policy for theoretical and empirical analysis of the impactof competition on innovation.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 3 / 54

Page 4: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Preferences

Main Model: Preferences

Infinite-horizon economy in continuous time.

Continuum 1 of individuals with preferences over the unique finalgood: ∫ ∞

texp (−ρ (s − t)) logC (s) ds

Supply 1 unit of labor inelastically.

Closed economy, no investment; Euler equation:

g (t) ≡ C (t)C (t)

=Y (t)Y (t)

= r (t)− ρ

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 4 / 54

Page 5: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Technology

Final Good Technology

Unique final goods produced from continuum 1 of intermediates withCobb-Douglas production function:

lnY (t) =∫ 1

0ln y (j , t) dj

We normalize the price of the final good to 1. Then the demand forintermediate good j at time t is:

y (j , t) =Y (t)p (j , t)

, ∀j ∈ [0, 1] .

In each j , 2 firms compete: perfect substitutes

y (j , t) = yi (j , t) + y−i (j , t) .

More generally, imperfect substitutes, so that y (j , t) is an aggregateof two or several imperfectly substitutable products.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 5 / 54

Page 6: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Technology

Intermediate Good Technology

Each intermediate good has productivity qi (j , t) at time t andproduced from labor:

y (j , t) = qi (j , t) li (j , t)

Marginal cost of producing intermediate j for firm i :

MCi (j , t) =w (t)qi (j , t)

where w(t) is the wage rate at time t.Let firm i be the technological leader:

qi (j , t) ≥ q−i (j , t) .

Bertrand competition

pi (j , t) =w (t)q−i (j , t)

and y (j , t) =q−i (j , t)w (t)

Y (t) .

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 6 / 54

Page 7: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Technology

Profits

Firm i’s technology: qi (j , t) = λnij (t).

Profit function for leader i :

Πi (j , t) = [pi (j , t)−MCi (j , t)] yi (j , t)

=

(w (t)q−i (j , t)

− w (t)qi (j , t)

)Y (t)pi (j , t)

=(1− λ−nj (t)

)Y (t)

where nj (t) ≡ nij (t)− n−ij (t) is the technology gap.Profits of followers and neck-and-neck firms equal to 0.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 7 / 54

Page 8: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model R&D

R&D and Innovation Process

Innovations follow a controlled Poisson Process

Flow rate of innovation for leader and follower given by

xi (j , t) = F (hi (j , t))

hi (j , t) : number of researchersF ′ (·) > 0, F ′′ (·) < 0, F ′ (0) < ∞The cost for R&D is therefore

w (t)G (xi (j , t))

where G (xi (j , t)) ≡ F−1 (xi (j , t)) .

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 8 / 54

Page 9: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model R&D

R&D by the Leader

Technology levels: qi (j , t) = λnij (t)︸ ︷︷ ︸leader

> q−i (j , t) = λn−ij (t)︸ ︷︷ ︸follower

R&D by the leader to improve its technology, xi (j , t):

qi (j , t) = λnij (t)successful=⇒R&D

qi (j , t + ∆t) = λnij (t)+1

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 9 / 54

Page 10: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model R&D

R&D by the Follower - Quick Catch-up

R&D by the follower in quick catch-up regime:

Catch-up R&D, x−i (j , t):

q−i (j , t) = λn−ij (t)successful=⇒R&D

q−i (j , t + ∆t) = λnij (t)

Interpretation: follower is developing a related (closely substitutable)but different product.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 10 / 54

Page 11: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model R&D

R&D by the Follower - Quick Catch-up

IPR Policy:

Patent enforcement: η ≡{η1, η2, ...}, such that ηn ∈ R+ for eachn ∈N is the flow rate at which a follower that is n− step behind cancopy the leader’s technology.

Will also introduce Regulated infringement fee and Regulatedlicensing fee.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 11 / 54

Page 12: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model R&D

R&D and the Law of Motion

nj (t) ≡ nij (t)− n−ij (t): the technology gap between firms

nj (t + ∆t) =

next state︷ ︸︸ ︷nj (t) + 1

0

nj (t)

with approx. probability︷ ︸︸ ︷xi (j , t)∆t

(x−i (j , t) + ηnj (t))∆t

1− (xi (j , t) + x−i (j , t) + ηnj (t))∆t

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 12 / 54

Page 13: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model R&D

Allocations and Equilibrium

Let [ηn ]n∈Z+, t≥0 be the IPR policy sequence. Then an allocation isa sequence of price, output and R&D decisions for a leader that isn = 0, 1, ...,∞ step ahead,

[pn (t) , yn (t) , xn (t)]n∈Z+, t≥0

a sequence of R&D decisions for a follower that is n = 0, 1, ...,∞ stepbehind,

[x−n (t)]n∈Z+, t≥0

a sequence of wage rates [w(t)]t≥0 and a sequence of industrydistributions over technology gaps [µn (t)]n∈Z+, t≥0 .

Equilibrium = Markov Perfect Stationary(“Steady-State”)Equilibrium(Markov because strategies conditioned only on payoff relevant statesand stationary because we look at stationary industry distribution).

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 13 / 54

Page 14: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Value Functions

Steady State Value Functions

Defined normalized value: vn ≡ Vn/Y , where Vn is net presentdiscounted value of profits.For leaders:

ρvn = maxxn≥0

(1− λ−n

)−ω∗G (xn) + xn [vn+1 − vn ]

+x∗−n [v0 − vn ] + ηn [v0 − vn ]

For followers

ρv−n = maxx−n≥0

−ω∗G (x−n) + x−n [v0 − v−n ]

+x∗n [v−n−1 − v−n ] + ηn [v0 − v−n ]

For neck-and-neck firms

ρv0 = maxx0≥0{−ω∗G (x0) + x0 [v1 − v0] + x∗0 [v−1 − v0]}

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 14 / 54

Page 15: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Value Functions

Labor Market Clearing

Labor Supply = 1; thus

1 ≥∞

∑n=0

µ∗n

[1

ω∗λn+ G (x∗n ) + G (x

∗−n)

]

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 15 / 54

Page 16: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Major Simplification to Start With

Suppose that nij (t) is “technologically” restricted to be 0 or 1.

This might be because if the leader gets two steps ahead of thefollower, the follower automatically copies the previous step.In actuality, however, this is just a trick to get simple expressions.

IPR policy for now implies the possibility that the follower can copythe one step ahead leader.

Suppose also that R&D uses final good rather than labor, so that thegeneral equilibrium interaction is also shut off.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 16 / 54

Page 17: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Structure of Equilibrium in the Simplified Economy

From the analysis so far, we have that the normalized profits of theleader (who is necessarily one step ahead) is

π1 ≡Π1

Y= 1− λ.

Naturally, also,π−1 = 0.

Suppose also that when two firms are neck and neck, they can“collude”and obtain some fraction of π1, i.e.,

π0 = επ1,

where we can then think of ε as an inverse measure of competition.(What could be wrong with this reasoning? What about π1?)

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 17 / 54

Page 18: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

R&D Technology and Value Functions

Suppose also that the R&D cost function is

G (x) =x2

2.

Then value functions can be written as (with x ′ denoting the otherfirm’s R&D)

rv1 = π1 + (x−1 + η) (v0 − v1)rv0 = π0 + x0 (v1 − v0) + x ′0 (v−1 − v0)− x20/2.rv−1 = (x−1 + η) (v0 − v−1)− x2−1/2.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 18 / 54

Page 19: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Equilibrium

Characterizing this equilibrium is now trivial.

First, we have x1 = 0, because the leader cannot gain from furtherinnovation– a much simplified version of a more general lazymonopolist effect.Next, as intermediate step, we have the following equations:

x0 = v1 − v0x−1 = v0 − v−1.

Thus anything that increases the gap between neck and neck valuesand monopoly values increases R&D of neck and neck firms, andanything that increases the gap between this value and the value of afollower increases the R&D of a follower.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 19 / 54

Page 20: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Equilibrium (continued)

Now completing the algebra, we obtain:

x0 = −η +√

η2 + 2 (1− ε) (1− λ)

x−1 = −(η + x0) +√

η2 + x20 + 2 (1− λ)

This implies that a higher ε (lower competition) reduces x0 andincreases x−1, which is what we might have expected intuitively.The first is due to the escape competition effect, which was absentin the benchmark endogenous growth models. The second effect isthe standard appropriability effect, which was already present inboth input variety and Schumpeterian models.Also, higher η increases x−1 + η (it reduces x−1 but less thanone-for-one): this is the availability effect– previous advances arenow more widely available to followers to build on, so less of thewasteful R&D that is done by those that are behind.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 20 / 54

Page 21: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Equilibrium (continued)

Which effect dominates?Aghion et al. define “aggregate innovation”as

µ (x−1 + η) + 2 (1− µ) x0,

where µ is the fraction of sectors that are in the neck-and-neck state.A natural alternative would be

µx−1 + 2 (1− µ) x0,

so that we do not count transitions due to η as innovation.In fact, we will also see that the “right”measure is

2 (1− µ) x0,

so that only R&D that contributes to improvements in technologyused in production is counted.For now, which measure we look at doesn’t matter (but it will later).

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 21 / 54

Page 22: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Equilibrium (continued)

The fraction of sectors that are in the neck-and-neck state, µ, can becomputed from the steady-state accounting (inflow equals outflow)equation.In particular, inflow into the state 1 is

(1− µ)2x0

and outflow from this state is

µ(x−1 + η),

so equating inflow to outflow, we obtain

µ =2x0

η + x−1 + 2x0.

It can be shown that the effect of competition on aggregateinnovation generally has an inverted U-shape.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 22 / 54

Page 23: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Empirical Evidence

Aghion et al. provide evidence from UK firms consistent with such aninverted U-shaped relationship.They use measured price-cost ratios (the Lerner index) as a proxy forcompetition (in particular, operating profit minus financial costsdivided by sales).

Lerner index =operating profit - financial cost

sales

What might be wrong with this measure?

Using this measure, they find a robustly inverted U between citationweighted patents and the Lerner index.They also provide similar results when they instrument for the Lernerindex using “policy instruments”meaning interventions either due tosingle markets for Monopoly and Merger Commission investigations,presumably reducing monopoly power in the industry.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 23 / 54

Page 24: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Empirical Evidence (continued)

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 24 / 54

Page 25: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Empirical Evidence (continued)

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 25 / 54

Page 26: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Empirical Evidence: Regression Evidence

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 26 / 54

Page 27: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

Empirical Evidence: Further Evidence

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 27 / 54

Page 28: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Model Major Simplification

IPR and Competition

Even at this level of generality, it is clear that IPR and competitionare related. Changes in η will affect the degree of competition in theeconomy.

Aghion et al. suggest that higher η (less strict IPR) should increaseaggregate innovation because it pushes more industries into neck andneck state, where R&D tends to be higher (necessarily higher whenε = 0).

But there measure of aggregate R&D directly depends on due to IPRrelaxation, which is not really innovation.

We need a more detailed analysis for understanding the effect of IPRon innovation.

For this, let us return to the general framework.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 28 / 54

Page 29: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model

R&D by the Follower - Quick Catch-up

Let us start with IPR policy, that is more general, potentially statedependent.

IPR Policy:

Patent enforcement: η ≡{η1, η2, ...}, such that ηn ∈ R+ for eachn ∈N is the flow rate at which a follower that is n− step behind cancopy the leader’s technology.

Let us also introduce Regulated infringement fee and Regulatedlicensing fee.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 29 / 54

Page 30: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model

R&D and the Law of Motion

Recall: nj (t) ≡ nij (t)− n−ij (t): the technology gap between firms

nj (t + ∆t) =

next state︷ ︸︸ ︷nj (t) + 1

0

nj (t)

with approx. probability︷ ︸︸ ︷xi (j , t)∆t

(x−i (j , t) + ηnj (t))∆t

1− (xi (j , t) + x−i (j , t) + ηnj (t))∆t

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 30 / 54

Page 31: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model

Steady State Value Functions

Recall also the normalized value: vn ≡ Vn/Y :For leaders:

ρvn = maxxn≥0

(1− λ−n

)−ω∗G (xn) + xn [vn+1 − vn ]

+x∗−n [v0 − vn ] + ηn [v0 − vn ]

For followers

ρv−n = maxx c−n≥0

−ω∗G (x−n) + x−n [v0 − v−n ]

+x∗n [v−n−1 − v−n ] + ηn [v0 − v−n ]

For neck-and-neck firms

ρv0 = maxx0≥0{−ω∗G (x0) + x0 [v1 − v0] + x∗0 [v−1 − v0]}

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 31 / 54

Page 32: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model

Optimal R&D Decisions

R&D decisions:

x∗n = max{G ′−1

([vn+1 − vn ]

ω∗

), 0}

x∗−n = max{G ′−1

([v0 − v−n ]

ω∗

), 0}

x∗0 = max{G ′−1

([v1 − v0]

ω∗

), 0},

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 32 / 54

Page 33: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model

Optimal R&D Decisions (cont’d)

Relaxation of patent enforcement will reduce vn+1 − vn, and thus x∗n :disincentive effects.

Because typically x∗0 > x∗n , relaxation of IPR also tends to shift more

industries into neck-and-neck state and increase overall R&D -composition effect.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 33 / 54

Page 34: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model

Steady-State Equilibrium

Proposition

A steady-state equilibrium exists.

Proposition

The equilibrium growth rate is:

g ∗ = lnλ

[2µ∗0x

∗0 +

∑n=1

µ∗nx∗n

].

This explains why the right equation for growth above was2(1− µ)x0.

Proposition

If IPR policy is uniform, then:

x∗n > x∗n+1, ∀n ∈ Z++.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 34 / 54

Page 35: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model General Discussion

Impact of IPR Policy

IPR policy in this more general model creates two effects:1 Composition effect: relaxation of patent protection increases fractionof industries where firms are neck-and-neck.Neck-and-neck firms perform more R&D, thus innovation and growthincreases.

2 Disincentive effect: relaxation of patent protection reduces the valueof innovation, thus discourages R&D both for leaders and followers.

Optimal level and structure of IPR determined by the interaction ofthese two forces.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 35 / 54

Page 36: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model General Discussion

A Thought Experiment

Which company should be protected more:

A company with a bigger lead, orA company with a more limited lead over its rival?

Naive intuition: less protection for technologically advanced firms toexploit the composition effect.

But this intuition is motivated by uniform IPR.

With state-dependent relaxation of IPR it is possible to createincentives.

positive incentive effects instead of disincentive effects

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 36 / 54

Page 37: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model General Discussion

Optimal IPR Policy

Both growth-maximizing and (steady-state) welfare-maximizing.

State-dependent IPR can create significant gains:

Low patent protection for leaders that are a few steps ahead.Full patent protection for leaders that are suffciently advanced.Opposite of the above naive intuition.Trickle-down of incentives: full protection for a leader that is n∗

steps ahead gives better incentives to all leaders n < n∗ steps ahead.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 37 / 54

Page 38: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model Reinterpreting Microsoft vs. DOJ

Microsoft R&D Relative to Sector Average

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 38 / 54

Page 39: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model Reinterpreting Microsoft vs. DOJ

Microsoft R&D Relative to Sector Average - After DOJCase

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 39 / 54

Page 40: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Back to the General Model Reinterpreting Microsoft vs. DOJ

R&D by Other Technology Leaders Relative to SectorAverage

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 40 / 54

Page 41: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation

Parameterization of IPR Policy

Uniform IPR

IPR policy→Technology gap: n→

none−0

η︷︸︸︷−1

η︷︸︸︷−2

η︷︸︸︷−3

η︷︸︸︷−4

η︷ ︸︸ ︷−5−6−7−8−9−10−11−.−.−∞

State-Dependent IPR

IPR policy→Technology gap: n→

none−0

η1︷︸︸︷−1

η2︷︸︸︷−2

η3︷︸︸︷−3

η4︷︸︸︷−4

η5︷ ︸︸ ︷−5−6−7−8−9−10−11−.−.−∞

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 41 / 54

Page 42: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation

Parameters:

List of parameters: r ,γ,λ,Bryear = 5%The empirical literature usually assumes

Innovation(t) = B0 exp(κt)(R&D_inputs)γ

where B0 : constant, exp(κt) : trend term. Thus we assume

x = Bhγ

Kortum (1993) ; Pakes and Griliches (1980) ; Hall, Hausmann andGriliches (1988) report:

γ ∈ [0.1, 0.6]

Set benchmark elasticity as γ = 0.35. Do robustness check withγ = 0.1 and γ = 0.6.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 42 / 54

Page 43: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation

Parameters (cont’d)

For step size λ, similar reasoning to Stokey (1995) :

Expected duration between consecutive innovations = 2.5 years

+

Annual growth rate = 2%

⇓λ = 1.05

Robustness checks with λ = 1.01 and λ = 1.2 ( = 10 yr)

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 43 / 54

Page 44: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Patents in Quick Catch-up

Table 1: Patent Length in Quick Catch-up...

λ = 1.05,γ = 0.35 Full IPR OptimalUniform IPR

OptimalState-dependent IPR

η1 0 0 0.71η2 0 0 0.08η3 0 0 0η4 0 0 0η5 0 0 0

x ∗−1 0.22 0.22 0.12x ∗0 0.35 0.35 0.25x ∗1 0.29 0.29 0.41µ∗0 0.24 0.24 0.46µ∗1 0.33 0.33 0.19µ∗2 0.20 0.20 0.13ω∗ 0.95 0.95 0.96

Researcher ratio 0.032 0.032 0.028

ln C (0) 33.78 33.78 34.20g ∗ 0.0186 0.0186 0.0204

Welfare 683.0 683.0 692.1

Table 1. Optimal Patent Length in Quick Catch-up Regime

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 44 / 54

Page 45: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Patents in Quick Catch-up

Figure 1: Value Function

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 45 / 54

Page 46: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Patents in Slow Catch-up

Slow Catch-up Value Functions

Slow catch-up→

q−i (j , t) = λn−ij (t)successful=⇒R&D

q−i (j , t + ∆t) = λn−ij (t)+1

For leaders:

ρvn = maxxn≥0

(1− λ−n

)−ω∗G (xn) + xn [vn+1 − vn ]

+x∗−n [vn−1 − vn ] + ηn [v0 − vn ]

For followers

ρv−n = maxx−n≥0,a−n∈[0,1]

−ω∗G (x−n) + x−n [v−n+1 − v−n ]

+x∗n [v−n−1 − v−n ] + ηn [v0 − v−n ]

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 46 / 54

Page 47: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Patents in Slow Catch-up

Table 2: Patent Length in Slow Catch-up...

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 47 / 54

Page 48: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Licensing in Slow Catch-up

Licensing with Slow Catch-up

Suppose that followers can close the gap between themselves and theleader by “reverse engineering” the current leading-edge technology,and in return, they will have to pay a license fee to leader.

IPR Policy:

Regulated licensing fee: (normalized values)ζ = (ζ1 (t) , ...., ζ∞ (t)), such that ζn (t) ∈ R+ for each n ∈N attime t is the patent fee that the follower should pay in order to useleader’s technology.Interpretation: licensing fees are bargained between leader and follower,and government policy determinants outside options in this bargaining.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 48 / 54

Page 49: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Licensing in Slow Catch-up

Licensing with Slow Catch-up: Value Functions

For leaders:

ρvn = maxxn≥0

(1− λ−n

)−ω∗G (xn) +

xn [vn+1 − vn ] + a∗−nx∗−n [v0 − vn + ζn ] +

(1− a∗−n) x∗−n [vn−1 − vn ] + ηn [v0 − vn ]

For followers - choose R&D and also licensing:

ρv−n = maxx−n≥0,a−n∈[0,1]

−ω∗G (x−n) +

a−nx−n [v0 − v−n − ζn ] + (1− a−n) x−n [v−n+1 − v−n ]

+x∗n [v−n−1 − v−n ] + ηn [v0 − v−n ]

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 49 / 54

Page 50: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Licensing in Slow Catch-up

Table 3: Licensing in Slow Catch-up...

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 50 / 54

Page 51: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Leapfrogging in Slow Catch-up

Regulated Infringement Fee in Slow Catch-up

Suppose that followers can engage in frontier R&D and “leapfrog”the technology leader, but might have to pay an infringement fee.

IPR Policy:

Regulated infringement fee: (normalized values)ϑ = (ϑ1 (t) , ...., ϑ∞ (t)), such that ϑn (t) ∈ R+ for each n ∈N attime t is the penalty that the follower should pay if the follower’sfrontier innovation turns out to be infringing the existing patent.

τ : Lanjouw and Schankerman (1998) reports that 10% of thepatents are filed for infringement

=⇒ τ = 0.1

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 51 / 54

Page 52: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Leapfrogging in Slow Catch-up

Value Functions under Infringement Fees

For leaders:

ρvn = maxxn≥0

(1− λ−n

)−ω∗G (xn) + xn [vn+1 − vn ]

+xc∗−n [vn−1 − vn ] + x f ∗−n [v−1 − vn + τϑn ]

+ηn [v0 − vn ]

For followers - choose catch-up and R&D levels:

ρv−n = maxx c−n≥0,x f−n≥0

−ω∗G (x−n) +

xc−n [v−n+1 − v−n ] + x f−n [v1 − v−n − τϑn ]

+x∗n [v−n−1 − v−n ] + ηn [v0 − v−n ]

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 52 / 54

Page 53: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Leapfrogging in Slow Catch-up

Table 4: Infringement Fee in Slow Catch-up...

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 53 / 54

Page 54: 14.461: Technological Change, Lecture 3 Competition

Quantitative Investigation Conclusion

Conclusion

The effect of competition and various types of policy will likelydepend on the nature and extent of competition in the market.

The devil is unfortunately in the details.

But also some general principles:

Appropriability effect.Lazy monopolist effect.Escape competition effect.Disincentive effect from IPR relaxations.Availability effect from IPR relaxations.Composition effects.Trickle-down of incentives.

The positive and normative implications of models of endogenoustechnological change concerning competition and policy will dependon these forces.

Daron Acemoglu (MIT) Competition, Policy and Innovation September 11, 2014. 54 / 54