2. powers presidency

28
INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES IDE Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical comments IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 233 Interaction of Powers in the Philippine Presidential System Takeshi KAWANAKA* APRIL 2010 Abstract The executive – legislative relations in the Philippines have been described in two contrasting stories, namely the “strong president” story, and the “strong congress” story. This paper tries to consolidate the existing arguments and propose a new perspective focusing on the “compromise exchange” between the president and the congress across the different policy areas. It considers that the policy outcome is not brought by unilateral power of the president or the congress, but formed as the product of such an exchange. Interaction of powers and their complementary function are addressed. Furthermore, aside from the constitutional power, the weak party discipline is pointed out as a key factor in making the exchange possible. Keywords: executive – legislative relations, presidency, policy process, democracy * Senior Research Fellow, Area Studies Center ([email protected])

Upload: trishia-garcia

Post on 20-Jul-2016

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: 2. Powers Presidency

INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES

IDE Discussion Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussions and critical comments

IDE DISCUSSION PAPER No. 233

Interaction of Powers in the Philippine

Presidential System Takeshi KAWANAKA* APRIL 2010

Abstract The executive – legislative relations in the Philippines have been described in two contrasting stories, namely the “strong president” story, and the “strong congress” story. This paper tries to consolidate the existing arguments and propose a new perspective focusing on the “compromise exchange” between the president and the congress across the different policy areas. It considers that the policy outcome is not brought by unilateral power of the president or the congress, but formed as the product of such an exchange. Interaction of powers and their complementary function are addressed. Furthermore, aside from the constitutional power, the weak party discipline is pointed out as a key factor in making the exchange possible.

Keywords: executive – legislative relations, presidency, policy process, democracy * Senior Research Fellow, Area Studies Center ([email protected])

Page 2: 2. Powers Presidency

The Institute of Developing Economies (IDE) is a semigovernmental,

nonpartisan, nonprofit research institute, founded in 1958. The Institute

merged with the Japan External Trade Organization (JETRO) on July 1, 1998.

The Institute conducts basic and comprehensive studies on economic and

related affairs in all developing countries and regions, including Asia, the

Middle East, Africa, Latin America, Oceania, and Eastern Europe. The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s). Publication does not imply endorsement by the Institute of Developing Economies of any of the views expressed within.

INSTITUTE OF DEVELOPING ECONOMIES (IDE), JETRO 3-2-2, WAKABA, MIHAMA-KU, CHIBA-SHI CHIBA 261-8545, JAPAN ©2010 by Institute of Developing Economies, JETRO No part of this publication may be reproduced without the prior permission of the IDE-JETRO.

Page 3: 2. Powers Presidency

INTRODUCTION From a comparative perspective, the presidential legislative power in the Philippines is at the middle level, in both constitutional and partisan powers (Shugart and Carey 1992, Haggard and McCubbins eds. 2001). This middle level strength raises some problems for researchers. Generally, it is more difficult to explain why it is neither weak nor strong than why it is weak or strong. It is also difficult to examine empirically. In conventional arguments in the studies on Philippine politics, however, there have been two contrasting views on the presidential power. One claims that the Philippine president is strong. This group focuses on the constitutional powers, and the administrative control over the bureaucracy (de Dios 1999, 2002). Another emphasizes the influence of dominant social class in the congress. This group claims that presidential legislative initiatives that undermine the social interests usually fail, due to the resistance of the congress (e.g. Abueva 2002). Both of them seem to describe the actual characteristics of the Philippine presidency, but not comprehensively. Instead of assuming that the policy outcome is a result of unilateral influence of the president or the congress, this paper proposes an alternative hypothesis that the policy outcome in the Philippines is a product of the “compromise exchange” between the president and the congress over the unconnected policy areas. Such an exchange is made possible when the superior player switches depending on the policy areas. In the Philippines, the president has the superior power in the budget process and policy implementation, while the congress dominates the legislative process of ordinary policies. Through offering compromises in the policy area where one is dominant, each player seeks concessions from the opponent in other areas where the opponent is dominant. This “compromise exchange”, deriving from the switch of dominant players in different areas, is made possible by the constitutional framework and weak party discipline. In the following section, we will deal with the theory of “compromise exchange”. Then, we will examine the theory in actual policy outcomes. PRESIDENT AND CONGRESS Form of Government and Party System in the Philippines The Philippines adopts a presidential system. The president monopolizes the executive

1

Page 4: 2. Powers Presidency

power and has the power to appoint secretaries of departments, who are not allowed to hold a seat in the legislature1. The power is strictly divided by the executive and the legislative branches. The legislature is bicameral, composed of the Senate and the House of Representatives. The Senate has 24 members elected from the national constituency, while the House has more than 200 members elected from single member districts and the limited proportional representation (the party list system). Table 1 President and Congress under the 1987 Constitution The President The Senate The House of Representatives

Members 1 24 216 (SMD) + max 50 (PR)* Term six years six years three years Term Limit No reelection No three consecutive terms No four consecutive terms District National

constituency National constituency Single member district (SMD)

+ national constituency Method of

Election Plural Plural by bloc voting (12

names), change half of the

members every three years

Plural + Limited proportional

representation (max three seats

for each party)

* As of November, 2008. Actual number of the PR representatives is 22. Source: Author. Regarding the local governance, the Philippines has a unilateral system, instead of a federal system. Aside from local governments which are headed by elected local chief executives and local councils, the central government maintains local offices for respective departments. As for the party system, the Philippines had the two-party system of the Nacionalista Party and the Liberal Party, after its independence in 1946 until the declaration of martial law in 1972. After the democratization in 1986, the number of parties increased drastically, and there is no stable dominant party (Kasuya 2008). Actually, a party is formed by an individual presidential candidate every election time. In the first place, there are some leading presidential candidates. They are usually senators, cabinet secretaries or vice presidents. They decide whether they will use the existing parties for

1 But, the consent of the Committee on Appointment composed of the members of the Senate and the House of Representatives is required to finalize the appointments.

2

Page 5: 2. Powers Presidency

their campaign or establish new ones. That is the party formation at the initial stage. When the winner is decided, the party system goes through reorganization. Reorganization is driven as party switching to or coalition formation with the president’s party. Politicians change their affiliations, and some parties disappear. Since the parties are short term groupings of politicians, they are not cohesive. In recent years, left leaning parties supported by labor unions and peasant groups have gained some seats in the lower house through the proportional representation (the party list system), and this opens up opportunities for cohesive parties to appear. Such cohesive parties, however, have little chance to become dominant in the congress, since each party is allowed to hold a maximum three seats under the current law. Political parties are not expected to play key roles in policy making as they are very fluid. The key players in policy making in the Philippines are institutional players defined by the constitution, namely, the president, the senate and the House of Representatives2. Preferences of the Players Assuming that political players seek to hold and maintain the power, three institutional players have different incentives defined by the respective method of election. 2 Eaton (2002) explained the policy process in the Philippines through the election system and preferences of these institutional players. MacIntyre (2001) also discuses policy outcomes based on these three institutional players.

3

Page 6: 2. Powers Presidency

Table 2 Institutional Players and Expected Behavior Player Method of Election Expected Behavior

President Plural in national constituency.

No reelection. The presidency is the final point of a political

career in the Philippines. But the president

may be apprehensive about being ousted in

the midst of his term. The president is also

concerned with policy performance at the

national level, like fiscal discipline and

stability of the macro economy. The

president tends to consider the problem in the

short term as he can stay in the position for

six years only. Senate Plural by bloc voting (12

names) in national

constituency. No three consecutive terms.

Senators can still further their careers to

cabinet posts, the vice presidency and the

presidency. They can also continue their

careers by keeping their current positions.

Senators pay much attention to their images

in the media for nationwide popularity. Each

senator acts independently. Formation of the

majority is fluid. House of

Representatives

(SMD)

Plural in single member

districts. No four consecutive terms.

Representatives seek to establish and

strengthen their power base at their local

bailiwicks. They try to maximize the pork

barrel distributions in order to secure

personal votes. Representatives, supported by

their own local political machine, have little

incentive to rely on political parties for

elections.

Source: Author. For the president, the current post is the final point of his political career. The next election, therefore, generally does not affect the behavior in the current term3. The

3 President Gloria Macapagal-Arroyo was able to run for the presidential election in 2004, because she assumed the presidency as vice president after President Joseph

4

Page 7: 2. Powers Presidency

president may give an “anointment” to a certain candidate as his successor. It is possible for the president to support the “anointed” candidate during an election campaign, expecting the candidate will play the role of the incumbent’s alter ego. This “anointment” is expected to bring reelection incentive. Such an “anointment”, however, does not work to bind the successor for the predecessor’s interest protection, because there is no means to secure the commitment of the successor. In this situation, an “anointment” usually does not prepare the reelection incentive for the president. The president is forced to be free from reelection incentive and seeks policy stability during his term to stabilize his current power. For this purpose, the president gives much attention to legislations for fiscal discipline and macroeconomic stability. Additionally, the president calculates his payoffs in a relatively short time frame, as his term is limited to six years. The president, therefore, is expected to prefer ad hoc solutions for policy problems or just to put off the necessary actions, instead of adopting long term strategies for fundamental solutions. On the other hand, the senators have the reelection incentive. Although the constitution prohibits three consecutive terms for the senators, they can shift to the executive posts, the House of Representatives, or other elective offices. The term limit has little influence on the senators’ behavior. Against its rival institutional players, the senate usually tries to contain the House of Representatives that seek maximization of pork barrel, and to resist legislations that expand the presidential discretions. Another important feature is that the senators have the incentive to promote their own personal political career against their colleagues. The senators are actually each others’ competitors, because they are elected in the national constituency with 12 names in bloc voting. Candidates need to get in the top 12 to win the election. In this setting, the senators have less incentive to pursue collective interests. The members of the House of Representatives also face a constitutional limit on their term (no four consecutive terms), but they can shift to provincial governors or can position members of own families to take care of the posts in their absence. The representatives keep the incentive to secure personal votes in such a situation (Cain et al., 1987). The term limits, therefore, do not influence their behavior. Based on the reelection incentive and the different methods of election, the representatives have

Estrada stepped down in the midst of his term. This case is exceptional under the 1987 constitution.

5

Page 8: 2. Powers Presidency

different preferences from those of the president and the senate. The single member district is generally considered to be more conducive to strong party discipline than the multi-member district. The case of the Philippines, however, does not seem to fit the pattern. The main reason is that nomination of a political party does not influence the result of elections. It is true that the affiliation with a party contributes to a candidate’s campaign because a party helps a candidate in voting, counting monitoring and finance. But, it is not crucial in deciding the fate of a candidate. A candidate depends on each local political machine which is developed not by parties but through the personal or family capacity (Kawanaka 2002). The representatives do not need to compete with their colleagues in the House unlike the senators, because most of them are elected from the single member districts. The representatives, rather, share the incentive to maximize the collective interest of the House, which is the increase of pork barrel distribution. For the collective action, they, of course, face the collective action problem (Olson 1965). In addition, even if they do not need to compete in the elections, the representatives are expected to compete for the lucrative posts in the House. The House of Representatives formed a system to mitigate these problems, by means of giving relatively strong power to the Speaker of the House, not through political parties4. Explaining Policy Outcome The policy process in the Philippines is characterized by the interaction of these three institutional players who have different preferences. To simplify the logic, we do not 4 The Speaker of the House holds the following powers for mitigating the collective action problem and intra-House competitions. First, the Speaker appoints the chairs of committees. Second, the Speaker appoints the members of the bicameral conference committee, which negotiate with the senate counterpart on the conflicting issues in legislations. Third, the Speaker has the rights to speak and vote at all committees. Fourth, the Speaker holds the power to supervise and intervene in the management of committees through regular meetings with chairs and vice chairs. Fifth, the Speaker can influence the allotment of bills to committees through the Committee on Rules. Finally, the Speaker decides the schedule of session and priority issues. In addition, pork barrel distribution rarely creates competition among the House members, because the amount of the pork barrel allocation to each legislator is decided uniformly, and the actual release is negotiated between the president and the House leaders, or between the Department of Budget and Management and individual representatives, but not among the representatives.

6

Page 9: 2. Powers Presidency

distinguish between the senate and the House here. Instead, we treat the congress as one. The currently dominant arguments can be classified into the following two. One is the “strong president” story. This view thinks that the policy process is dominated by the president who holds formal and informal superior power. The president actually holds strong constitutional power and has large discretions over the implementation of policies. The bureaucracy is also fully placed under the president’s control. Such a strong presidential power is often used for explaining inconsistency of policies in the Philippines. This view claims that policies are changed every six years when the president changes. This argument further asserts that the Philippines has a barrier to further economic growth due to this policy instability (de Dios and Esfahani 2001). The other is the “strong congress” story. This view emphasizes that the policy process is dominated by the congress. It does not mean that the congress takes policy initiatives. Instead, it asserts that the status quo is generally maintained due to the veto power of the congress. The “strong congress” story fits the argument of dominant social class. They explain that the dominant social class controls the congress, and such a class prevents the reforms which bring damages to the class interests. As typical cases, the scholars point out the failures of the land reform and the tax reform. The argument on the shift from the presidential system to the parliamentary system is developed based on this perspective. That is to say, gridlock in policy making often takes place in the Philippines due to the veto power of the legislature, and this obstructs the reforms conducive to economic growth. The “strong president” and the “strong congress” stories are contradictory in their logic, but, both stories describe correctly certain aspects of the actual executive – legislative relations in the Philippines. It would be more comprehensive and precise if we suppose that there are two types of policy area. In some areas, the president is dominant, while in other areas, the congress controls the process. And actual policy outcome is made through the “compromise exchange” over the different policy areas. For this purpose, we can classify three policy areas, which are ordinary legislation, budget making and implementation, and ordinary policy implementation. The congress is dominant in general legislation, because the president has no power to

7

Page 10: 2. Powers Presidency

introduce bills or intervene in the session. Moreover, the president is only given the package veto power, but not the partial veto. The degree of presidential intervention is limited. On the other hand, the president can control the budget making and implementation. First, the president has the exclusive power to introduce the budget proposal to the congress. Second, the congress is not allowed to amend the budget proposal to exceed the total amount of the presidential proposal. Third, the president can exercise the partial veto aside from the package veto on the budget bill approved by the congress. The partial veto allows the president to amend the budget virtually at the final stage. Finally, the Presidential Decree No. 1177, which provides automatic appropriation of the expenditure for the debt service, augments the presidential power5. The congress, especially the House of Representatives, seeks to increase the allocation of pork barrel funds within the ceiling imposed by the president. The target for additional funds is always the debt service. The congress underestimates the debt repayment and attempts to take away its funds for pork barrel items. The ban on the amendment of the debt service causes difficulty for the congress in securing additional sources for fund transfers. In addition to these powers in the budget making process, the president also has the power to change the budget at the implementation phase. Actual fund release is controlled by the president through the Department of Budget and Management. The congress occasionally tries to insert the rules to provide the congress with the authority over the fund release, but these rules are deleted by the presidential veto. As for the ordinary policy implementation, the president monopolizes the power. The regulatory power is under the sole jurisdiction of the president. The president issues executive orders for this purpose under the mandate of the statutes. The president’s legislative powers are listed in Table 3.

5 The Presidential Decree No. 1177 was enacted by President Ferdinand Marcos under his authoritarian rule. The decree has statutory effects. The decree can be amended or repealed in the same procedure for ordinary statutes. To date, however, the decree has not been amended or repealed.

8

Page 11: 2. Powers Presidency

Table 3 Legislative Power of the President Power Yes or No

Package Veto (Reactive) Yes (Override by 2/3 of the congress) Partial Veto (Reactive) Yes (Only for budget and tax measures) Decree (Proactive) No (Executive orders within the mandate of

statutes) Exclusive Introduction of Bills (Proactive) No (Except for budget proposals) Budget Enactment (Proactive) Yes (Exclusive introduction and ceiling) Referendum No Dissolving the congress No (Source) Author.

Bargaining arises due to the reverse power balance between the president and the congress in the ordinary legislation, the budget making/implementation and the ordinary policy implementation. As a precondition for bargaining, the president and the congress need to have different preferences in each area. In the general legislation, the congress usually prefers the status quo, while the president prefers to leave the status quo, especially in economic issues. In contrast, for the budget process, the president prefers to restrain the expenditure, while the congress, particularly the House of Representatives, prefers to obtain more allotment for their local projects, which eventually leads to expansion of the expenditure. Since the ordinary legislation is technically independent of the budget process and policy implementation, the decision making seems to proceed as if they are not related. The compromises, nonetheless, are made and exchanged across the different areas, and such bargaining as a whole decides the final outcome.

9

Page 12: 2. Powers Presidency

Figure 1 Interaction between Two Policy Areas

Compromise

Outcome The President The Congress

Budget Process

Compromise

Outcome The President The Congress

General Legislation

(Source) Author. The president provides compromises in the budget process in order to obtain the compromise from the congress in the ordinary legislation. The congress cooperates with the president on the legislation of the president’s initiative, to gain the further allocation in the budget. Figure 1 shows this type of interaction across the different areas. If the ordinary legislation is independent of other policy areas, the congress can easily realize its preference. In the same way, if the budget process is decided without any connection to other areas, the president’s ideal point would be the final outcome. In the actual process, the final outcomes in the respective areas are brought relatively closer to the rival’s ideal point. We can say that this pattern is made possible by the interaction between the compromises across the different areas. As we have seen, the president has no power to propose a bill at the congress. But he can allow his allies in the congress to file a bill, and certify it as an administration certified bill or priority bill for fast enactment. On the other hand, the congress desires increase and fast release of pork barrel funds. In this situation, enactment of the

10

Page 13: 2. Powers Presidency

president’s priority bills and allocation/release of pork barrel funds are expected to be interconnected. In fact, the local media often reports that the president releases the pork barrel funds to have his priority bills approved by the congress. In this sense, the “compromise exchange” is not a new finding. Nonetheless, the exchange of the budget allocation and legislation of priority bills are usually discussed in the context of the “strong president” story. The president is perceived to be able to control the congress through budget management. But, emphasis on the president’s control is one sided, because the president is also pressured to give some concessions to the congress in both the legislation and budget process. This could be interpreted as the congress exercising its influence through its veto power in legislation. Importantly, the weak party discipline is the precondition which makes the “compromise exchange” possible. Strong party discipline sometimes strengthens the president’s control over the congress, because the president is usually the leader of the dominant party. But, at the same time, the opposition also becomes cohesive. If the congress is dominated by the opposition, the divided government emerges. If the party discipline is weak, the president may have a chance to let the opposition members shift their affiliation or at least to cooperate with his policy initiatives through negotiation. For example, in the 12th congress (2001-2004), the Speaker of the House who was close to the president was supported by 91.8 percent of the total members of the House in the election of the speakership. Also in the 13th congress (2004-2007), the president’s ally was supported as the Speaker by 80.9 percent of the total members. When we look at this pattern, we can say that it is less possible to have a divided government in the Philippines after 1986. The president usually has collaborative relations with the majority of the House. Nonetheless, such an ad hoc coalition may be costly to the president, because the president needs to provide resources to the congress every time an important issue is on the agenda. To examine the theory above, we will take a look at the legislative performance and budget distribution in the next section.

11

Page 14: 2. Powers Presidency

EXAMINING POLICY OUTCOMES Legislative Performance If the “compromise exchange” enables the president to legislate his preferred policies, the enactment rate of the president’s priority bills becomes higher than without such exchanges. The ideal examination method is to compare the enactment rate of the president’s priority bill with the “compromise exchange” and that without the exchange. This is actually impossible because we cannot control the “compromise exchange.” We, therefore, compare the enactment rates of the president’s priority bills and those of ordinary bills assuming that ordinary bills are not supported by the “compromise exchange”. Table 4 indicates the enactment rates in the post-democratization congress (1987-2004). Table 4 Enactment Rates at the House of Representatives

Congress/Administration National

Application Enactment

Rate Local

Application Enactment

Rate 8th / Aquino (1987-1992) 191/5,237 3.6% 809/30,183 2.7%

9th / Ramos (1992-1995) 156/3,184 4.9% 306/11,448 2.7%

10th / Ramos (1995-1998) 147/3,785 3.9% 393/6,766 5.8%

11th / Estrada (1998-2001) 67/4,197 1.6% 348/8,738 4.9%

12th / Arroyo (2001-2004) 89/2,920 3.0% 84/3,764 2.2%

Total 650/19,323 3.4% 1,940/60,899 3.2%

(Source) The House of Representatives.

On average, the enactment rate of national application bills is 3.4 percent, while that of local application bills is 3.2 percent6. Bills hardly survive.7

6 National application bills are applied nationwide. Economic reform bills are included in this category. On the other hand, local application bills are applied limitedly to certain areas. These are, for example, bills for specific facilities. 7 In addition, the rates of presidential veto against the bills are: 3.9 percent in the 8th congress, 8.0 percent in the 9th congress, 3.1 percent in the 10th congress and 4.8 percent in the 11th congress. These figures include the partial vetoes against the general appropriation acts. We can observe the tendency that the veto is more exercised against local application bills.

12

Page 15: 2. Powers Presidency

Compared with these average rates, the president’s priority bills are enacted at higher rates. Table 5 shows the data on the president’s priority bills in the 8th and the 12th congresses. Table 5 Enactment Rates of President’s Bills at the House of Representatives

Congress /

Administration President’s Priority

Bills Enacted Bills among

President’s Priority

Bills

Enactment Rate

8th / Aquino 93 54 58.1%

12th / Arroyo 20 8 40.0%

(Source) The House of Representatives Since not all the president’s priority bills are approved by the House, it seems that the president’s influence over the congress is not perfect. But, considering the legislation results, it is possible to say that the president’s policy initiatives are relatively supported by the House. Here is a problem in measurement. The enactment rate does not completely indicate how the president’s preference is realized in legislation. If the congress imposes essential amendments to the bills, the president’s policy plan may be virtually scrapped.

13

Page 16: 2. Powers Presidency

Figure 2 Two Tax Reforms and Tax Effort

* Tax effort here means the ratio of tax revenue to nominal GDP. The left vertical axis indicates the tax effort, while the right vertical axis shows the real GDP growth rate. (Source) Department of Budget and Management, National Economic and Development Agency. Tax reforms are often discussed regarding legislative “distortion” on the president’s initiative. The Philippines had two major tax reforms after the democratization. One was introduced under the Aquino administration in 1986 just after the democratization. At that time, the congress was not yet convened, and the reform was brought by the presidential power only, through the executive order. Another reform was enacted under the Ramos administration in 1997. This second tax reform needed to go through the ordinary legislative process at the congress. Figure 2 shows the ratio of tax revenue to the nominal GDP (tax effort). This figure casts a simple picture that the tax effort increased after the first tax reform under the Aquino administration, but declined after the reform under the Ramos administration. In other words, when there was no congressional intervention, tax effort went up. But tax effort went down when there was an intervention. Although tax reform is not the sole cause for fluctuation of tax effort, it

14

Page 17: 2. Powers Presidency

is still a major factor. It is natural to assume both President Aquino and President Ramos had the same goal for the tax reforms, which is revenue expansion. Based on this assumption, it is plausible to say that the effects of tax reforms are affected by the congress that prefers a lower tax rate. The president was forced to give concession even though he could enact the tax reform. From the number of enacted bills, we find that the congress gives concession to the president. But we need to examine the content of the enacted bill to check how much the bills were modified. In this sense, we still do not know completely if the congress really made compromises to the president. Budget Control The outcome of the budget process shows a different trend as compared with ordinary legislative processes. Table 6 shows the comparison of the presidential budget proposals and the enacted budgets from 1995 to 2005.

15

Page 18: 2. Powers Presidency

Table 6 Presidential Proposals and Final Budgets Fiscal

Year Total Amounts of the

Presidential Budget

Proposals

Enacted

Budgets Changes(%) The Ratio of

Government

Expenditure to GDP

as of Session for

Budget(%) 1995 390.9 382.2 -2.25 +1.0

1996 404.5 394.4 -2.50 +0.6

1997 476.2 493.4 +3.61 +0.3

1998 540.8 565.3 +4.53 +0.1

1999 579.5 579.5 0.00 -1.9

2000 650.0 629.0 -3.23 -3.8

2001 725.0 Not enacted *** -4.0

2002 780.8 780.8 0.00 -4.0

2003 804.2 804.0 -0.02 -5.4

2004 864.8 Not enacted *** -4.6

2005 907.6 907.6 0.00 -3.8

* 1 billion pesos. (Source) Author, based on the Business World articles in CODEX. This table indicates that the ceiling imposed by the president is strictly maintained if the current fiscal balance worsens. But, the ceiling is broken if the budget has surplus. As mentioned above, the constitution prohibits the budget bill amendments to increase the total amount over the presidential proposal. The presidential ceiling was, nonetheless, neglected twice under the Ramos administration. This happened as a result of the combination of automatic appropriation of the debt service and the presidential partial veto. In these two years, the congress projected optimistic economic performance and estimated the reduction of debt service based on the favorable exchange rate. The congress, then, transferred funds from the debt service to local projects, and increased the funds allocation which they preferred. This move was not considered unlawful since the total amount of revised budget did not exceed the presidential proposal at this point. The president, however, exercised partial veto on the debt service after the congress passed the bill. The initial amount based on the automatic appropriation scheme was revived, and pushed up the total amount over the ceiling (Gutierrez 1998).

16

Page 19: 2. Powers Presidency

The budget surplus forms the background to this “trick” to make the budget expand. The president did not strongly intend to prevent this “trick” under the good fiscal condition. In this sense, such budget expansion was the president’s compromise to the congress. But as the budget condition worsened and the president could not tolerate the budget deficit, the ceiling was strictly imposed. Supported by the constitutional provision, control over the total amount seems to work well. The congress sabotages the session when the president controls the budget process. The budget was not enacted sometimes, or the process was terribly delayed. The president, hence, is not free to control the budget making. Especially, the president has difficulties in abolishing or slashing the pork barrel funds, because such an act causes serious damages to the members of the congress. The representatives, in particular, resist the reduction of pork barrel allocation. The failure of President Estrada’s attempt to abolish the pork barrel was a typical case of the strong resistance from the congress. President Estrada promised, during his campaigning for the 1998 presidential election, that he would totally abolish the pork barrel funds. As he promised, he did not include items for the pork barrel in the 1999 fiscal year budget proposal. But, ultimately, President Estrada was forced to compromise and approved the budget amendments to revive pork barrel. In the following year, President Estrada tried to impose constraints over the areas where pork barrel funds could be used. Moreover, the President did not allow fast release of pork barrel funds in the running appropriation. Such constraints and delay in release triggered again the protest of the House of Representatives. The President finally exercised partial vetoes on 52 items of the congress approved budget. Again, for the 2001 budget, the delayed release of pork barrel funds incurred anti president sentiment in the House of Representatives, and this eventually stopped the session. The congress, at that time, was busy with the impeachment trial against President Estrada, and could not enact the appropriation act. In sum, the president’s constitutional power over budget making basically works for fiscal discipline. But, as the deficit becomes serious, the president has less room for compromise to the congress. The president and the congress also face serious conflict in the budget making process. Gridlock in policy making may also take place, because the president loses the bargaining power in ordinary legislation.

17

Page 20: 2. Powers Presidency

Institutions for Interest Coordination and Pork Barrel Politics In order to facilitate the “compromise exchange” between the president and the congress across the different areas, they need a place for negotiation. This is the institutions for interest coordination. The Legislative Executive Development Advisory Council (LEDAC) and the Presidential Legislative Liaison Office (PLLO) function for this purpose8. The LEDAC is the place where the president, cabinet secretaries and leaders of the congress meet together and discuss the legislative agenda. The PLLO, on the other hand, is a part of the Office of the President. The PLLO has offices at the senate and the House, and lobbies the legislature on a daily basis for passage of the president’s priority bills. These institutions for interest coordination among institutional players play a crucial role where political parties are less cohesive and do not work for interest aggregation. The interest coordination is backed by the pork barrel funds. The origin of the pork barrel funds after the democratization was regional development funds under the Aquino administration. These funds are reorganized into two types under the Arroyo administration, namely the Priority Development Assistance Fund (PDAF) and the funds under the Department of Public Works and Highways (DPWH). Each member of the congress (senator and representative) is given a fixed amount of allocation. Table 7 summarizes the pork barrel funds in 2002 and 2003 budgets. Table 7 Pork Barrel Funds in 2002 and 2003 Budgets

PDAF DPWH Total 2002 Amount of Pork Barrel

(Share in Total) 4,979 13,886

(29.1%) 18,864

(2.5%)

Total 47,632 742,022

2003 Amount of Pork Barrel (Share in Total)

6,168 13,387 (25.1%)

19,555

(2.4%)

Total 53,312 825,113

(Source) Department of Budget and Management.

8 Additionally, the Bicameral Conference Committee is also important for coordination between the senate and the House of Representatives.

18

Page 21: 2. Powers Presidency

Each congressman identifies the projects that he wants to implement. After such identification, the departments concerned will work on them. For fund release, the Department of Budget and Management issues the permit for fund release considering the condition of the national coffers. Although the budget and management secretary has jurisdiction over the permit issuance, the president can influence the release through the budget and management secretary, reflecting on the issues in the legislative process. Measuring the “compromise exchange”, nonetheless, is difficult either quantitatively or qualitatively. Checking the correlation between the pork barrel fund release and legislators’ behavior (e.g. voting in the session for the president’s priority bills) seems an appropriate examination for such exchange. Unfortunately, the data on roll call vote, which is considered to indicate the legislators’ behavior, does not reflect the exchange precisely, at least, in the Philippines. Furthermore, the compromises are exchanged not only between the pork barrel and the passage of bills, but also through other issues. Considering such conditions, it seems difficult to present significant correlation9. The local media, however, often reports the bargaining between the president and the congress through pork barrel distribution, and the probability of “compromise exchange” is quite high. For example, Gutierrez (1998: 77-79) reports that the congress approved the 1994 expanded value added tax reform on the condition that the president releases the funds of the Congressional Initiative Allocation (CIA), which is also pork barrel. I also confirmed the bargaining through pork barrel in my interview with an official in the congressional secretariat10. CONCLUSION In general, the presidential legislative power in the Philippines is at the middle level. But if we take a closer look at the power, we find “compromise exchange” deriving from the structure in which the superior player changes depending on the policy areas. The “compromise exchange” forms the policy outcomes in the Philippines. This is the key in this paper. As a precondition, it is important that the political parties are less cohesive in the Philippines. It enables the president to placate the opposition in the congress, and it eventually prevents a rigid divided government.

9 Kawanaka (2008) tries to test the correlation, but does not find evidence to support such correlation directly. 10 In the interview, it was also mentioned that the timing of fund release was important, in addition to the amount.

19

Page 22: 2. Powers Presidency

Such a weak party system is formed through the situation that political candidates win the elections by means of their personal votes instead of the party support. Each candidate can secure his political machine because his respective bailiwick is geographically limited in the single member district. The presidential system also weakens the party as the election of the executive is separated from those of the legislature. When we consider the preference of the House of Representatives, the representatives share the same preference among their colleagues, but not with the president even if he is the party leader. On the other hand, the opposition party faces the same problem of weak discipline. The members of the opposition easily shift their position depending on the concessions which the president provides. If we suppose a counterfactual whereby the political parties were more cohesive in the Philippines, the expected result would be that the president’s party and the opposition tend to have rigid conflict and a divided government emerges more often. The president would have difficulty in appeasing the opposition and making them collaborate with his policy initiative. In short, weak political parties are one of the main causes of this “compromise exchange.” Considering the “compromise exchange,” the case of the Philippines implies that the interaction of the power of each player should be taken into account in addition to measuring the strength of the power itself. How do the presidential powers in different areas complement each other? How do the partisan powers affect the constitutional design? Is there an endogenous mechanism between the constitutional and partisan powers? These are future prospective research questions.

20

Page 23: 2. Powers Presidency

References

Abueva, Jose V. (2002) “Towards a Federal Republic of the Philippines with a Parliamentary Government by 2010”, in Jose V. Abueva, Rey Magno Teves, Gaudioso C. Sosmeña, Jr., Clarita R. Carlos, and Michael O. Mastura (eds) Towards a Federal Republic of the Philippines with a Parliamentary Government: A Reader. Marikina City. MM: Center for Social Policy and Governance Kalayaan College.

Cain, Bruce, John Ferejohn and Morris Fiorina (1987) The Personal Vote: Constituency Service and Electoral Independence, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

de Dios, Emmanuel S. (1999) “Executive-Legislative Relations in the Philippines: Continuity and Change”, in Colin Barlow (ed.) Institutions and Economic Change in Southeast Asia : the Context of Development from the 1960s to the 1990s . Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

--------------------------. (2002) “Nationalism and the Strong State in the 1935 Philippine

Constitution.” The Philippine Review of Economics. 39:1. June. de Dios, Emmanuel S. and Hadi Slehi Esfahani. (2001) “Centralization, Political

Turnover, and Investment in the Philippines”, in J. Edgardo Campos (ed.) Corruption: The Boom and Bust of East Asia. Quezon City: Ateneo de Manila University.

Eaton, Kent (2002), Politicians and Economic Reform in New Democracies: Argentina and the Philippines in 1990s. Pennsylvania: Pennsylvania State University Press

Gutierrez, Eric. (1998) “The Public Purse”, in Sheila S. Coronel (ed.) Pork and Other Perks: Corruption and Governance in the Philippines. Pasig City: Philippine Center for Investigative Journalism.

Haggard, Stephan and Mathew D. McCubbins (ed.) (2001) Presidents, Parliaments, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Kasuya, Yuko (2008) Presidential Bandwagon: Parties and Party Systems in the Philippines, Tokyo: Keio University Press.

Kawanaka, Takeshi (2002) Power in a Philippine City, Chiba: Institute of Developing Economies.

----------------------- (2008) Who Eats the Most? Quantitative Analysis of the Pork Barrel Distributions in the Philippines. IDE Discussion Paper No.126.

Maclntyre, Andrew (2001) "Institutions and Investors: The Politics of Economic Crisis in Southeast Asia” International Organization 55:1 (winter): 81-122.

21

Page 24: 2. Powers Presidency

22

Olson, Mancur (1965) The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Shugart, Matthew Soberg and John M. Carey (1992) Presidents and Assemblies: Constitutional Design and Electoral Dynamics. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Page 25: 2. Powers Presidency

No. Author(s) Title

232 Takahiro FUKUNISHI FDI and Export particiaption of Local Firms in Africa: The Case ofthe Kenyan Garment Industry 2010

231 Hitoshi SUZUKI A Critical Review of Opinion Polls relating to Iranian Voting Intentions:Problems of Research Methodology as applied to Complex Societies 2010

230 Mai Fujita The Diversity and Dynamics of Industrial Organisation: Transformation ofLocal Assemblers in the Vietnamese Motorcycle Industry 2010

229 Miki HAMADA, Masaru KONISHI Related Lending and Bank Performance: Evidence from Indonesia 2010

228 Hisao YOSHINO Strategic Trade Policy and Non-Linear Subsidy 2010

227 Masahiro KODAMA Large Fluctuations in Consumption in Least Developed Countries 2010

226 Chiharu TAMAMURACost Reduction Effects of “pseudo FTAs” in Asia -Application of a PriceModel Based on a Multilateral I/O Table- 2010

225 Koji KUBO Natural Gas Export Revenue, Fiscal Balance and Inflation in Myanmar 2010

224 Mariko WatanabeSeparation of Control and Lash-flow Rights of State Owned ListedEnterprises: Channels of Expropriation following Discriminated Share Reformi Chi

2010

223 Haruka I. MATSUMOTO The Taiwan Strait Crisis of 1954-55 and U.S.-R.O.C. Relations 2010

222 Miwa TSUDA The Experience of National Rainbow Coalition (NARC): PoliticalParties inKenya from 1991 to 2007 2010

221 Kensuke KUBO Inferring the Effects of Vertical Integration from Entry Games: AnAnalysis of the Generic Pharmaceutical Industry 2010

Ik KUROIWA Sh k T i i M h i f th E i C i i i E t A i

~Previous IDE Discussion Papers ~

220 Ikuo KUROIWAHiroshi KUWAMORI

Shock Transmission Mechanism of the Economic Crisis in East Asia:An Application of International Input-Output Analysis 2010

219 Yuri SATO, Mai FUJITA Capability Matrix: A Framework for Analyzing Capabilities in ValueChains 2009

218 Soya MORI, TatsufumiYAMAGATA

Measurements to Assess Progress in Rights and Livelihood of Personswith Disabilities: Implications Drawn from the IDE-PIDS Socio- 2009

217 Omar Everleny Pérez Villanueva The Cuban Economy: A Current Evaluation and Proposals forNecessary Policy Changes 2009

216 Takeshi INOUE, ShigeyukiHAMORI

What Explains Real and Nominal Exchange Rate Fluctuations?Evidence from SVAR Analysis for India 2009

215 Nu Nu Lwin Analysis on International Trade of CLM Countries 2009

214 Koichiro KIMURA The Technology Gap and the Growth of the Firm: A Case Study ofChina’s Mobile-phone Handset Industry 2009

213 Soshichi KINOSHITA The Effect of Product Classifications on the Formulation of ExportUnit Value Indices 2009

212 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA, Zheng JI,Ayako OBASHI

Agglomeration versus Fragmentation: A Comparison of East Asia andEurope 2009

211 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA, ToshiyukiMATSUURA

Complex Vertical FDI and Firm Heterogeneity: Evidence from EastAsia 2009

210 Hajime SATO The Iron and Steel Industry in Asia: Development and Restructuring 2009

209 Hiroko UCHIMURA, YurikaSUZUKI

Measuring Fiscal Decentralization in the Philippines 2009

208 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA Market Access and Intermediate Goods Trade 2009

207Kazunobu HAYAKAWA, DaisukeHIRATSUKA, Kohei SHIINO, SeiyaSUKEGAWA

Who Uses FTAs? 2009

206 Ikuko OKAMOTO Issues Affecting the Movement of Rural Labour in Myanmar: RakhineCase Study

2009

205 Takao TSUNEISHIBorder Trade and Economic Zones on the North-South EconomicCorridor: Focusing on the Connecting Points between the Four 2009

Page 26: 2. Powers Presidency

No. Author(s) Title

204Ando ASAOBo MENG

Trade Coefficients and the Role of Elasticity in a Spatial CGE ModelBased on the Armington Assumption 2009

203 Toshihiro KUDO Location Advantages and Disadvantages in Myanmar:The Case ofGarment Industry 2009

202 Yasushi HAZAMA Economic Voting and Electoral Volatility in Turkish Provinces 2009

201 Tatsuya SHIMIZU Structural Changes in Asparagus Production and Exports fromPeru

2009

200Takeshi INOUE,Shigeyuki HAMORI

An Empirical Analysis of the Monetary Policy ReactionFunction in India

2009

199 Yuko TSUJITA Deprivation of Education in Urban Areas: A Basic Profile ofSlum Children in Delhi, India

2009

198 Kaoru MURAKAMI Constructing Female Subject: Narratives on Family and LifeSecurity among Urban Poor in Turkey

2009

197 Akiko YANAI Normative Influences of "Special and Differential Treatment"on North-South RTAs

2009

196 Hisaya ODA Pakistani Migration to the United States:An Economic Perspective

2009

195 Yukihito SATO Perfecting the Catching-up: The Case of Taiwan’s MotorcycleIndustry

2009

194 Natsuko OKA Ethnicity and Elections under Authoritarianism: The Case ofKazakhstan

2009

193 Futaba ISHIZUKAVietnamese Local State-owned Enterprises (SOEs) at theCrossroads: Implications of SOE Restructuring at the Local 2009

192 Y hi HAZAMA Constitutional Review and Democratic Consolidation: A2009192 Yasushi HAZAMA Constitutional Review and Democratic Consolidation: A

Literature Review2009

191 Hisao YOSHINO Technology Choice in the IT Industry and Changes of the TradeStructure

2009

190 Toshikazu YAMADA In Memory of Dr. Ali Al-Gritly (1913-1982): His Views onEgypt’s Experience with Socialism

2009

189 Kanako YAMAOKA The Feasibility of Cuban Market Economy: A Comparison withVietnam

2009

188 Tomohiro MACHIKITA, YasushiUEKI

Linked versus Non-linked Firms in Innovation: The Effects ofEconomies of Network in Agglomeration in East Asia

2009

187 Hisao YOSHINO Financial Policies and Dynamic Game Simulation in Poland andHungary

2009

186 Kazushi TAKAHASHI Is South Sulawesi a Center of Growth in Eastern Indonesia?:Japanese ODA Strategy Revisited

2009

185 Bo MENG,Satoshi INOMATA

Production Networks and Spatial Economic Interdependence:An International Input-Output Analysis of the Asia-PacificRegion

2009

184Bo MENG,Nobuhiro OKAMOTO,Yoshiharu TSUKAMOTO

Input-Output Based Economic Impact Evaluation System forSmall City Development: A Case Study on Saemangeum's Flux 2009

183

Nobuhiko FUWA, Seiro ITO,Kensuke KUBO, TakashiKUROSAKI, and YasuyukiSAWADA

How Does Credit Access Affect Children's Time Allocation ina Developing Country? A Case Study from Rural India 2009

182 Moriki OHARAYuri SATO

Asian Industrial Development from the Perspective of theMotorcycle Industry 2008

181 Takeshi KAWANAKA Political Conditions for Fair Elections 2008

180 Takeshi INOUE The Causal Relationships in Mean and Variance between StockReturns and Foreign Institutional Investment in India 2008

179 Naoko AMAKAWA Reconstruction and Development of Rural Cambodia--FromKrom Samakki to Globalization-- 2008

Page 27: 2. Powers Presidency

No. Author(s) Title

178 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA,Toshiyuki MATSUURA

Pitfalls of Location Choice Analysis: The Finished GoodsProducer versus the Intermediate Goods Producer 2008

177 Yoko ASUYAMA The Contribution of Supply and Demand Shifts to EarningsInequality in Urban China 2008

176 Yoko ASUYAMA Changes in the Causes of Earnings Inequality in Urban Chinafrom 1988 to 2002 2008

175 Satoshi INOMATAA New Measurement for International Fragmentation of theProduction Process:An International Input-Output Approach

2008

174 Mayumi MURAYAMA,Nobuko YOKOTA

Revisiting Labour and Gender Issues in Export ProcessingZones: The Cases of South Korea, Bangladesh and India 2008

173 Masahiro KODAMA The Impact of Unstable Aids on Consumption Volatility inDeveloping Countires 2008

172 Hiroshi OIKAWAEmpirical Global Value Chain Analysis in Electronics andAutomobile Industries: An Application of Asian InternationalInput-Output Tables

2008

171 Eiichi YOSHIDATransformation of Woodworking and Furniture IndustrialDistricts in Kampala, Uganda: Dichotomous Development ofSME Cluster and Large Firm Sector

2008

170 Azusa HARASHIMA The Impact of Tobacco Production Liberalizationon Smallholders in Malawi 2008

169Zaid Bakht, Md. Salimullah,Tatsufumi Yamagata, andMohammad Yunus

Competitiveness of the Knitwear Industry in Bangladesh: AStudy of Industrial Development amid Global Competition 2008

168 Hitoshi OTA Indian IT Software Engineers in Japan: A Preliminary Analysis 2008

167 Hiroshi Oikawa TNCs in Perplexity over How to Meet Local Suppliers:The Case of Philippine Export Processing Zone 2008

166 Takeshi INOUE, ShigeyukiHAMORI An Empirical Analysis of the Money Demand Function in India 2008

165 Mayumi MURAYAMA Re-Examining ‘Difference’ and ‘Development’: A Note onBroadening the Field of Gender and Development in Japan 2008

164 Jose Luis CORDEIRO Constitutions aroumd the World: A View from Latin America 2008

163 Takahiro FUKUNISHI Clothing Export from Sub-Saharan Africa: Impact on Povertyand Potential for Growth 2008

162 Koichi USAMI Re-thinking Argentina's Labour and Social Security Reform inthe 1990s: Agreement on Competitive Corporatism 2008

161 Mai FUJITA Value Chain Dynamics and the Growth of Local Firms: TheCase of Motorcycle Industry in Vietnam 2008

160 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA,Kuo-I CHANG

Border Barriers in Agricultural Trade and the Impact of TheirElimination: Evidence from East Asia 2008

159Satoru KUMAGAI, ToshitakaGOKAN, Ikumo ISONO,Souknilanh KEOLA

The IDE Geographical Simulation Model: Predicting Long-Term Effects of Infrastructure Development Projectso 2008

158 Satoru KUMAGAI A Journey through the Secret History of the Flying GeeseModel 2008

157 Satoru KUMAGAI A Mathematical Representation of "Excitement" in Games: AContribution to the Theory of Game Systems 2008

156 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA,Fukunari KIMURA

The Effect of Exchange Rate Volatility on International Trade:The Implication for Production Networks in East Asia 2008

155 Kazunobu HAYAKAWA The Choice of Transport Mode: Evidence from JapaneseExports to East Asia 2008

154 Jose Luis CORDEIRO Monetary Systems in Developing Countries: An Unorthodox 2008154 Jose Luis CORDEIRO View 2008

Page 28: 2. Powers Presidency

No. Author(s) Title

153 Takao TSUNEISHIDevelopment of Border Economic Zones in Thailand:Expansion of Border Trade and Formation of Border EconomicZones

2008

152 Nguyen Binh Giang Improving the Foreign Direct Investment Capacity of theMountainous Provinces in Viet Nam 2008

151 Syviengxay Oraboune Infrastructure (Rural Road) Development and PovertyAlleviation in Lao PDR 2008

150 Chap Moly Infrastructure Development of Railway in Cambodia: A LongTerm Strategy 2008

149 Thandar Khine Foreign Direct Investment Relations between Myanmar andASEAN 2008

148 Aung Kyaw Financing Small and Midium Enterprises in Myanmar 2008

147 Toshihiro KUDO Myanmar Sugar SMEs: History, Technology, Location andGovernment Policy 2008

146 Momoko KAWAKAMI Exploiting the Modularity of Value Chains: Inter-firmDynamics of the Taiwanese Notebook PC Industry 2008

145 Toshikazu YAMADA Sustainable Development and Poverty Reduction underMubarak’s Program 2008

144 Miki HAMADA Bank Borrowing and Financing Medium-sized Firms inIndonesia 2008

143 Yoko IWASAKI Methodological Application of Modern Historical Science to‘Qualitative Research’ 2008

142 Masahiro KODAMA Monetary Policy Effects in Developing Countries withMinimum Wages 2008

141 Yasushi HAZAMA The Political Economy of Growth: A Review 2008

140 Kumiko MAKINO The Changing Nature of Employment and the Reform of Laborand Social Security Legislation in Post-Apartheid South Africa 2008

139 Hisao YOSHINO Technology Choice, Change of Trade Structure, and A Case ofHungarian Economy 2008

138 Shigeki HIGASHI The Policy Making Process in FTA Negotiations: A Case Studyof Japanese Bilateral EPAs 2008

137 Arup MITRA andMayumi MURAYAMA Rural to Urban Migration: A District Level Analysis for India 2008

136 Nicolaus Herman SHOMBE Causality relationship between Total Export and AgriculturalGDP and Manufacturing GDP case of Tanzania 2008

135 Ikuko OKAMOTO The Shrimp Export Boom and Small-Scale Fishermen inMyanmar 2008

134 Chibwe CHISALAUnlocking the Potential of Zambian Micro, Small and MediumEnterprises "learning from the international best practices - theSoutheast Asian Experience"

2008