2005 - hettne b - beyond new regionalism

Upload: sofia-medina

Post on 03-Jun-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    1/319

    Beyond the New Regionalism

    BJORN HETTNE

    Over the last decade regionalism, or what has become known as new regionalism,has become a prominent issue in a number of social science specialisations:European studies, comparative politics, international economics, internationalrelations (IR) and international political economy (IPE). The approach of thesedifferent academic specialisations varies considerably, which means that regional-ism means different things to different people. 1 In fact, we are facing an intriguingontological problem. There has been little agreement about what we study whenwe study regionalism. This implies that there also is a lack of agreement abouthow we should study it; in other words, we are facing an epistemologicalproblem as well. The great divide, albeit an exaggerated one, is between whathas been termed old and new regionalism. Whatever the merits of this distinc-tion, I shall use it in this article as a pedagogical device to underline the shiftingterrain and the instruments to explore it. Yet I shall also propose its dissolution,and a move beyond new regionalism, in looking more generally for the role of

    New Political Economy, Vol. 10, No. 4, December 2005

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    2/319

    Generations of regionalisms: continuities and discontinuitiesAs suggested, regionalism is one of those contested concepts that has continued tobafe social scientists for years. I have therefore to start with the problem of de-nition, even if this often has proved to be somewhat of a dead end, due to the factthat region, regional cooperation, regional integration, regionalism, regionalisa-tion and region building are moving targets. The overproduction of conceptssignals a certain disarray. Thus we have to come back to the problem of denition

    when dealing with different approaches to the elusive phenomenon of regionalism.

    Conceptualisation

    The concept of region is used differently in different disciplines: in the eld of geography, regions are usually seen as subnational entities, either historical pro-vinces (which could have become nation-states) or more recently created units.In IR, regions are often treated as supranational subsystems of the internationalsystem. It is of some importance whether regions are seen as subsystems of theinternational system or as emerging regional formations with their own dynamics.Even so, such macroregions can be dened in different ways: as continents or assupranational formations of countries sharing a common political and economicproject and having a certain degree of common identity. The minimum deni-tion of a world region is typically a limited number of states linked together bya geographical relationship and a degree of mutual interdependence. 4 According

    to a more comprehensive view, a region consists of states which have somecommon ethnic, linguistic, cultural, social, and historical bonds. 5 Even more

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    3/319

    economy), social integration (the formation of a transnational society) and politi-cal integration (the formation of a transnational political system). 9 Regionalcooperation is somewhat less complex and normally refers to joint efforts bystates to solve specic problems. Ernst B. Haas dened the concept as follows:regional cooperation is a vague term covering any interstate activity with lessthan universal participation designed to meet commonly experienced need. 10

    Andrew Axline asserted that regional cooperation can only be understood fromthe perspective of the national interests of the individual member states, andthat the politics of regional negotiations will involve accommodating these inter-ests for all partners. 11 Regional integration is, in contrast, normally taken to implysome change in terms of sovereignty. According to Haas, the study of regionalintegration is concerned with explaining how and why states cease to be whollysovereign. 12

    Regionalism and regionalisation are two more recent concepts, and much efforthas been devoted to the distinction between them. Regionalism refers to a ten-dency and a political commitment to organise the world in terms of regions;more narrowly, the concept refers to a specic regional project. In some denitionsthe actors behind this political commitment are states; in other denitions theactors are not conned to states. According to Anthony Payne and AndrewGamble, regionalism is a state-led or states-led project designed to reorganizea particular regional space along dened economic and political lines. 13 Theygo on in their pioneering book to say that regionalism is seen as something

    that is being constructed, and constantly reconstructed, by collective humanaction, 14 which sounds like a more comprehensive view as far as agency is con-15

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    4/319

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    5/319

    Europe was the centre of the debate about old regionalism. In the 1960s the tbetween the neofunctional description (and prescription) and the empirical world,now dominated by de Gaulles nationalism, disappeared. Stanley Hoffmanasserted that integration could not spread from low politics (economics) to thesphere of high politics (security). 25 Integration happened only as long as itcoincided with the national interest. The image of the EC began to diverge.According to Alan Milward, the EC should be seen as a rescue of the nation-state. 26 The EC could furthermore be understood as a confederation rather thana federation, according to the intergovernmentalist turn in the study of Europeanintegration. The ontological shift thus implied an epistemological shift towards amore state-centric, realist analysis.

    Haas responded to his critics by calling the study of integration pre-theory(since there was no clear idea about dependent and independent variables), thenspoke about the eld in terms of obsolescence, and ended up suggesting thatthe study of regional integration should cease to be a subject in its own right.Rather, it should be seen as an aspect of the study of interdependence(a concept then popularised by Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye). 27 This wasagain a new turn. The global context was not really considered by old regionalismtheory, concerned as it was with regional integration as a planned merger of national economies through cooperation among a group of nation-states. Com-parative studies were for obvious reasons rare. Haas listed a number of backgroundfactors for successful integration and Philippe Schmitter focused particularly

    on Latin America.28

    Axline criticised neofunctionalism for being Eurocentric:The goal of integration and the dependent variable of the theory used to under-

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    6/319

    Regionalisation and globalisation represent related but different aspects of thecontemporary transformation of world order; globalist and regionalist politicalprojects may have different impacts at different points in time. Contemporaryglobalisation can, in accordance with the classical theory of Karl Polanyi, beseen as a second great transformation, a double movement, where an expansionand deepening of the market is followed by a political intervention in defence of societal cohesionthe expansion of market constituting the rst movement andthe societal response the second. 31 The second movement contains counter-movements caused by the dislocations associated with market penetration intonew areas. Regionalism is thus part of both the rst and second movement, witha neoliberal face in the rst, and a more interventionist orientation in thesecond. There is thus a transnational struggle over the political content of regio-nalisation, as well as over that of globalisation.

    However, regions must at the same time be understood as endogenous pro-cesses, emerging from within the geographical area in question. They are not

    simply geographical or administrative objects, but subjects in the making (orun-making); their boundaries are shifting, and so are their capacities as actors,which can be referred to as their level of regionness. 32 Regionness denes theposition of a particular region in terms of regional cohesion, which can be seenas a long-term historical process, changing over time from coercion, the buildingof empires and nations, to voluntary cooperation. In general terms one can speak of ve levels of regionness: a regional space, a translocal social system, an inter-

    national society, a regional community and a regionally institutionalised polity.The regional space is a geographic area, delimited by more or less natural physical

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    7/319

    of regionalism coincided, resulting in great confusion. Let us try to clarify someof them.

    With regard to old and new regionalism, the former was a Cold War pheno-menon. It was specic with regard to its objectives (some organisations beingprimarily security-motivated, others more economically oriented), whereas thelatter resulted from a more comprehensive, multidimensional societal process.The new regionalism took shape in a multipolar world order and in a context of globalisation. It formed part of a global structural transformation. In this trans-formation a variety of non-state actors were to be found operating at severallevels of the global system.

    The new regionalism as studied in IPE can also be contrasted both to what isbetter termed the new protectionism, which was basically an early interpretationof the new wave of regionalism by neoliberal economists who feared that thesudden interest in regionalism heralded a new protectionism. 34 The differencelay very much in the ontological and epistemological perspectives. Neoliberals

    conceived the new regionalism as a trade promotion policy, building on regionalarrangements rather than a multilateral framework; by contrast, for IPE, regiona-lism was a comprehensive multidimensional programme, including economic,security, environmental and many other issues. To neoliberals, regionalismcould only be a second-best contribution to the task of increasing the amount of world trade and global welfare, and at worst a threat against the multilateralorder. The IPE perspective, on the other hand, held that free trade was not the

    main issue and that regionalism could contribute to solving many problems,from security to environment, that were not efciently tackled on the national

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    8/319

    zones which the regions enter or leave depending on their economic position andpolitical stability, as well as their level of regionness. This means that the regionsmay be differently situated and dened at different occasions, or at different timesin world history. The level of regionness can purposively be changed. Forinstance, security cooperation within a region would lead to improved stability,making the region more attractive for international investment and trade, anddevelopment cooperation would mean a more efcient use of available resources.

    The blind man metaphor is relevant also for the recent debate. It contains anumber of different theoretical approaches, from a revival of neofunctionalismto social constructivism, and with neorealism, neoliberal institutionalism andliberal intergovernmentalism in between. There are quite a few interesting theore-tical explanations of specied aspects of regionalism. The problem with rigidtheorising is that it must delimit the object for study, even while the objectrefuses too much reductionism. 38 An empirical case can (and perhaps should)be approached from different theoretical angles. Different theories illuminate

    different dimensions of a multidimensional phenomenon. Therefore I will notpropose any preferred theory in this overview.

    Dimensions, actors and levels

    In contrast with the time in which Haas was writing there are today many region-alisms and thus a very different base for comparative studies. 39 Different kinds of

    regions in interaction have appeared on different levels of the global system. Oldregional organisations continued but with new functions, while new regional

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    9/319

    free trade. Monetary issues are of course inseparable from trade. However, otherdimensions were soon added to the regional complexity. There was, rst of all,the problem of development, which, albeit often related to trade, is quite distinctand has generally been discussed in terms of developmental regionalism. Securityalso emerged as a regional issue, thus creating an interest in so-called securityregionalism. 40

    Trade blocs . Regional trading arrangements are often seen as a second-bestand therefore judged according to whether they contribute to a more closed ormore open multilateral trading system, embodied in the so-called stumblingblock vs. stepping stone dichotomy. Many of the regional trading arrangementsthat existed during the era of the old regionalism in the 1950s and 1960s wereinward-looking and protectionist, and were often regarded by contemporaryeconomists as failures. At the time, however, they were widely considered to beinstruments for enhancing industrial production, as in the strand of development

    thinking associated with the United Nations Economic Commission for LatinAmerica and the even more ambitious strategy of the United Nations Conferenceon Trade and Development, both led by Rau l Prebisch. The culmination of thisprocess was the demand for a new international economic order (NIEO). Region-alism developed into a form of global mobilisation against an unequal world order,but lost some of its strength in the process. As suggested by Percy Mistry, theWorld Trade Organization (WTO) has been hijacked by governments of

    Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries toprotect their interests in a world where power is challenged by developing41

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    10/319

    The Asian Financial Crisis (AFC) of 1997 underlined the degree of inter-dependence within the larger region of Southeast and East Asia and exposedthe weakness of existing regional institutional economic arrangements, causingcrises for both the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) and AsiaPacic Economic Cooperation (APEC), the two competing regional organi-sations. 45 The affected countries were frustrated over the lack of remediesoffered on the global level. In the West the opportunity was taken to imposeneoliberal policies in a region known (and criticised) for its interventionism.

    Before the AFC there was little discussion about regional approaches to themanagement of nancial stability outside Europe. Monetary regionalism inEurope is itself not a complete success story, but it shows the importance of insti-tutional backing as well as of political commitment and a common approach toeconomic policy. This discovery was later made in East Asia. A regional approachin the form of an Asian Monetary Fund was proposed by Japan, but received littlesupport and was resisted by the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the United

    States and the European Union (EU). This underscored the need for deeper insti-tutionalisation and stronger commitments from the countries in the region. In May2002 there was a meeting of the ASEAN Plus Three (APT) countries in ChiangMai about the ways that regional cooperation could combat nancial crises onthe regional level. This meeting may prove to have been a breakthrough for mon-etary regionalism, but it is too early to tell what the result will be. Looking at thedynamics of the crisis, it is obvious that ASEAN (which is a sophisticated regional

    organisation) is too small, whereas APEC (being transregional) is too big andcontains too many contradictory interests. An appropriate organisation, the

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    11/319

    in Africa). The strategy is only manageable within multidimensional and compre-hensive regional organisations, such as those mentioned, since these can exploitspillover effects and linkages between trade and non-trade and economic and poli-tical sectors / benets. By contrast, the North American Free Trade Agreement(NAFTA) is mainly a trade agreement and will nd it more difcult to exploitsuch linkages. What this highlights is the general trend towards more multidimen-sional forms of regional cooperation and towards regional organisations with ahigher degree of actorness a concept to which we will return shortly.

    Security regionalism . We have already noted that the rst generation of regionalintegration was concerned initially with economics but ultimately with peace andsecurity. In more recent theorising, security concerns are seen as causal factorsthat force countries to cooperate because of the risk of the regionalisation of con-ict. By this I mean both the outward spread or spillover of a local conict intoneighbouring countries, and the inward impact from the region in the form of dip-

    lomatic interference, military intervention and, preferably, conict resolutioncarried out by some kind of regional body. Security regionalism has nowbecome a genre in its own right. 48

    Regionalism and conict can be related in many different ways. One has to dowith the choice of unit for investigation, such as a regional security complex,dened by Barry Buzan as a group of states whose primary security concernslink together sufciently closely that their national security cannot realistically

    be considered apart from one another.49

    Buzan goes on to note that the task of identifying a security complex involves making judgements about the relative50

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    12/319

    several stages. The concept also includes more acute interventions in crises, butthe long-term implications should always be kept in mind. The region can because (the regional complex), means (regional intervention) and solution (regionaldevelopment). Indeed, in discussing regional crisis management in the longerperspective beyond intervention, it is important to link security regionalism anddevelopment regionalism. Ultimately, these two dimensions are complementaryand mutually supportive. This is implied in the concept of security communities,which Karl W. Deutsch famously dened as the attainment of institutionsand practices strong enough and widespread enough to assure, for a long time,dependable expectations of peaceful change among its population. 54

    Actors

    Much of current mainstream regionalism theory continues to be dominated bystate-centric perspectives. In summing up the body of research on regionalism

    produced by the United Nations University / World Institute for DevelopmentEconomics Research (UNU / WIDER), the editors admitted that our project,in spite of good intentions to the contrary, has been too state-centric and toofocused on formal organisations rather than pinpointing the processes of moreinformal regionalisation that take place on the ground. 55 This is by no meansequivalent to rejecting the state. States and intergovernmental organisations areoften crucial actors and objects of analysis in the process of regionalisation.

    The state, as well as the forces of state making and state destruction, are all atthe core of understanding todays political economy of regionalism. However,

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    13/319

    status of their authoritarian regimes. Often, the state is not much more than a(neopatrimonial) interest group. Furthermore, although the rhetoric and ritual of regional diplomacy serves the goal of the reproduction and legitimisation of thestate, it can also be a means to create a facade that enables certain regimeactors to engage in other more informal modes of regionalism, such as trans-state regionalism or networks of plunder. 60 This has also been referred to asshadow regionalism.

    Business interests are often supposed to be globalist in their orientation.However, this seems to be a myth. Globalisation strategies tend actually to endup creating more regionalised patterns of economic activity. 61 According toRobert Wade, one should talk about the regionalisation rather than the globalisa-tion of business. 62 For example, the larger European business interests were verymuch behind the EUs 1992 project, led by Jacques Delors. 63 For their part, civilsocieties are still generally neglected in the description and explanation of newregionalism. This is an important gap. Similarly, even if the external environment

    and globalisation are often readily called into account, extra-regional actors them-selves are also generally weakly described and conceptualised within the study of regionalism. This is somewhat surprising, given the considerable attentionwhich external actors such as foreign powers, donors, international nancialinstitutions, non-governmental organisations, transnational corporations and soon receive in the study of national and local transformation processes, especiallyin the South. In the nal analysis, it is not really a question of state-led regionalism

    versus non-state-led regionalism. On the contrary, state, market, civil society andexternal actors often come together in a variety of mixed-actor collectivities,64

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    14/319

    Actorness is a phenomenon closely related to regionness, the latter implying anendogenous process of increasing cohesiveness, the former a growing capacity toact that follows from the strengthened presence of the regional unit in differentcontexts, as well as the actions that follow from the interaction between the actorand its external environment. Actorness with reference to the outside world is thusnot only a simple function of regionness, but also an outcome of a dialecticalprocess between endogenous and exogenous forces. The unique feature of regional(as compared to national great power) actorness is that this has to be createdby voluntary processes and therefore depends more on dialogue and consensusbuilding than coercion. This way of operating is the model that Europe holdsout as a preferred world order, since this is the way the new Europe (organisedby the EU) has developed in its recent peaceful evolution.

    Actorness denes the capability to inuence the external environment.Regionness denes the position of a particular region in terms of its cohesion.The political ambition of establishing regional cohesion, a sense of community

    and identity has been of primary importance in the ideology of the regionalistproject. A convergence of values may take place even if this is not the explicitpurpose of the project. The approach of seeing region as process implies an evol-ution of deepening regionalism, not necessarily following the idealised stagistmodel presented here, for that mainly serves a heuristic purpose. Since regiona-lism is always a political project, created by human actors, it may, assumingthat it gets off the ground in the rst place, not only move in different directions,

    but also, just like a nation-state project, fail. In this perspective, decline wouldmean decreasing regionness. Enlargement, or widening, also implies decreasing

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    15/319

    relations between continents, have more actor capacity, and their mutual relationstherefore gain a certain signicance for the organisation of world order. In whatfollows I will focus on lower and higher levels of regionalism as being thusfar undertheorised in the literature. As higher levels (interregionalism and multi-regionalism) link up to the discussion on world order in the next part of the article,I will start with the former.

    Lower level regionalisms . As indicated, in the terminology employed here sub-regions are smaller parts of macroregions. Glenn Hook and Ian Kearns denedsubregionalism as a regionalist project promoted by weaker states in contradistinc-tion to the Triad or the Core. 69 This corresponds to what I referred to earlier asintermediate and peripheral regions. In my understanding, regions can be weak orstrong, but, as long as they display internally some degree of regionness, cohesionand actorness, they are to be seen as distinct regional formations. The EconomicCommunity of West Africa (ECOWAS) is in this view a region, but it is doubtful

    whether APEC is a region. Rather, it is a transregional organisation.Microregions exist between the national and the local level, because theyconsist of subnational territories rather than whole countries. 70 Historically,microregions have been seen as subnational regions within the territorial boun-daries of particular nation-states (or before that empires). Microregions may ormay not fall within the borders of a particular nation-state. Increasingly, theyare constituted by a network of transactions and collaboration across national

    boundaries, which may very well emerge as an alternative or in opposition to thechallenged state, and sometimes also in competition with states-led regionalism. 71

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    16/319

    Still, it is evident that micro-level forms of regionalism may sometimes be lessformal and inter-state than formal macroregions; they may ultimately be morereective of private sector interests than those of either states or civil societies.However, at the same time there is increasing evidence also that macroregionsand subregions are themselves increasingly inuenced by non-state actors. So,if regions are made up by actors other than states alone, and if state boundariesare becoming more uid, then it also becomes more difcult to uphold old distinc-tions between microregionalism and macroregionalism.

    Higher level regionalisms . Regionalisation has structural consequences beyondand above the particular region. Transregionalism refers to actors and structuresmediating between regions. To the extent that this takes place in a formal waybetween the regions as legal personalities one can use the word interregionalism.If the pattern of interregional relations becomes more predominant, constituting anew regionalised form of multilateral world order, we speak of multiregionalism.

    This is of course a very distant and highly uncertain prospect (to the extent indeedthat it is seen as a prospect at all). Like new regionalisms operating on the regionallevel, all transregional arrangements are voluntary and cooperative, but canbecome more or less institutionalised and formalised, thus forming the structureof a multiregional world order.

    Interregionalism is the latest step in the theorising of regionalism. The pheno-menon is very much a consequence of the EU policy of creating and relating to

    regions as preferred counterparts in the international system. From this perspec-tive, interregionalism simply constitutes a part of the foreign policy of the EU,

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    17/319

    Westphalian world of nation-states, it is more rooted in territory; and, in contrast totraditional multilateralism, it is a more exclusive relationship, since access toregional formations is limited by the principle of geographical proximity. Never-theless, interregionalism, not to speak of multiregionalism, is a long-term,non-linear and uncertain trend which certainly will include setbacks, the naloutcome of which we cannot yet expect to know.

    In sum, looking at the existing patchwork of transregional and interregionalagreements there is, in terms of structural outcome, presently no clear pictureon the horizon. Transregional arrangements are voluntary and cooperative.They are also very diverse and difcult to categorise. Few are interregional inthe proper sense of the word; some relations are transregional, some bilateral(for example, hybrid relations between a regional organisation and a greatpower). The fact that the EU constitutes the hub of these arrangements is in fullaccordance with its regionalist ideology, which, as is well known, encompassesnot only trade and foreign investment but also political dialogue and cultural

    relations between regions. We shall come back to this in the third part below.

    Regionalism and world order

    To go beyond the new regionalism, which was the expressed purpose of this over-view, implies to my mind looking at the context in which regionalisation occurs, aswell as the interrelationships between regions and the larger context, not least other

    regions. It is signicant that the pioneering works in exploring the new regionalismreferred even in their titles to world order (Gamble and Payne) or international75

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    18/319

    but not necessarily an orderly one). However, this order is seen as an outcome of underlying factors social forces and political units which then gain moreanalytical importance for understanding world order. 77 The concept is, further-more, commonly used normatively in a more political sense, which is to say itdescribes not primarily the actually existing order (or historical orders) butmodels and / or utopian projects. It has even been used as a political slogan. 78

    In order to be able to compare alternative models, I propose a non-normativeand mainly political denition of world order as constituted by three dimensions:structure, mode of governance and form of legitimisation. Structure is the way theunits of the system are related, that is, different forms of polarity determined bythe distribution of power and resources; mode of governance refers to avenuesof inuence on decision making and policy making; legitimisation is the basison which the system is made acceptable to the constituent units. On the structuraldimension, I make a further distinction between the unipolar, the bipolar and themultipolar. Polarity can dene relations between regions as well as great powers

    and these relations are not necessarily hostile (as postulated in realist theory). Inthe area of governance, the distinction I draw is between the unilateral, the pluri-lateral and the multilateral. The difference between plurilateral and multilateral isespecially important. A plurilateral grouping of actors is exclusive, whereas multi-lateral by denition implies inclusion, provided the rules of the game are acceptedby all parties. Multilateralism is therefore often seen as preferable, but, for manypurposes, regionalism, as a form of plurilateralism dened by geographical proxi-

    mity, is just as useful. By contrast, unilateralism undermines collective arrange-ments and may even be a path towards imperialism. By relying on unilateral

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    19/319

    World order of course implies a system including all of the world and all humanbeings. The degree of order within a region or in the international system canvary; thus different security theories speak of regional security complexes, anar-chies, anarchic societies, regional security communities and so on. The securityagenda is broadened, which makes regional approaches to security more relevant.

    Identifying world orders

    Theoretically, there are various options of world order. After the First World War,Europe believed in the power of collective security through the League of Nations.After its collapse, the United Nations (UN) constituted mankinds new hope fora stable and just world order based on multilateralism and international law(and the ction of a international community of equal states). As we saw, theearly theorising on regional integration was, above all, concerned with inter-national order. Later, in the 1970s, there was discussion of a New International

    Economic Order and thus the issue of order and justice was raised on a globalplane. More recently, after the rst Gulf war in 1991, President George H. W.Bush coined the concept a new world order, based on multilateralism and inter-national law and upheld via US hegemony. Signicantly, George Bush Senior didnot seek to change the regime in Baghdad after this war. This gives an indicationof his enduring respect for the multilateral world order, since then demolished bythe neoconservative movement and its inuence on the present US administration.In short, the old multilateral world order, based on US hegemony, is being trans-formed. The question is: in what direction?

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    20/319

    the ladder to the transnational level by means of the voluntary pooling of statesovereignties. The state can be replaced or complemented by a regionalisedorder, or by a strengthened global civil society supported by a new normativearchitecture of world order values. 79 Global cosmopolitanism thus emphasisesthe role of community at the global level, as well as the formation of global norms.The most likely candidate for such a role, although it does not appear to beimminent, is the interregional network pursued by the EU, facilitating multi-regional governance as the major alternative to unilateralism. There is also the

    possibility of moving down the ladder, which implies a decentralised, neomediae-val world, whether constituted by self-reliant communities (stable chaos)suggested by green political theory 80 or something more Hobbesian (durabledisorder), which at present seems more likely. 81 Transnational forms of govern-ment on the regional and global level are meant to prevent such a decline of worldorder and pathological anarchy. 82

    After 11 September 2001 there existed initially, to a greater degree even than in

    connection with the rst Gulf war, the possibility of forging an institutionalisedmultilateralism, an international regime based on the premises of an extendedscope for international law and extensive participation by states and other transna-tional actors. Of course, there was never such a thing as fully-edged multilater-alism. By false multilateralism is meant political and military actions that takeplace in the guise of multilateralism, but which in reality are expressions of more limited interests: plurilateralism, if it is a matter of a group of majorpowers; regionalism, if it is a geographically united bloc; or unilateralism, if asuperpower or regional major power is, to all intents and purposes, acting alone.

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    21/319

    Regionalism would, however, put its mark on a future post-Westphaliangovernance pattern. In such a world order, the locus of power would move irrever-sibly to the transnational level. The states system would be replaced or com-plemented by a regionalised world order and a strengthened global civilsociety, supported by a normative architecture of world order values, such as mul-ticulturalism and multilateralism. The EUs recent emphasis on interregionalismmay in the longer run prove to be important in the reconstruction of a multilateralworld order in a regionalised form, here called multiregionalism, meaning a hori-

    zontalised, institutionalised structure formed by organised regions, linked to eachother through multidimensional partnership agreements. The EUs ambition is toformalise these as relations between regional bodies rather than as bilateral contactsbetween countries; but, for the moment for pragmatic reasons, the forms of agree-ment show a bewildering variety. The EUs relations with the various geographicalareas are furthermore inuenced by the pillared approach in its own internaldecision making, creating articial divisions between, for instance, foreign and

    development policy.84

    The development of the pattern has also been inuencedover time by shifting bilateral concerns among additional members: for example,the United Kingdom and South Asia, Iberia and Latin America.

    Even so, a multipolar system in which the EU constitutes the hub and drivingactor does already exist in an embryonic form. The core of the global interregionalcomplex contains triangular relations within the Triad. East Asia is dominated bythe two great powers, China and Japan, with which both the US and the EU havebilateral relations as well. Transregional links within the Triad are constituted byAPEC and by the Asia-Europe Meeting (ASEM), as well as various transatlantic

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    22/319

    as set by US security interests. This is wholly in line with traditional realist secur-ity doctrine and therefore not new. Yet the current policy of the US goes beyondclassical realism ( a la Kissinger or Brzezinski) towards reinforcing what the neo-conservative think tank, the Project for the New American Century, describes as apolicy of military strength and moral clarity. This formulation captures theessence of neoconservatism: military strength and an obligation to use it in amoral mission to change the world in accordance with American values, rstamongst which is liberty. The opportunity, the unipolar moment, came after

    the end of the Cold War, which means that this thinking is thus older than9/ 11. 86 To my mind, it is wrong to call the present world order unipolar,since the remaining superpower has to ll the power vacuum created by thecollapse of the other. As shown in Iraq, there is no automaticity involved.

    To dub this ideological structure neoconservatism is hardly an appropriatedescription of what seems rather to be a militant revolutionary doctrine, rejectingthe multilateral world order model and the role of the UN as the protector of this

    order. Neoconservatism, or militant libertarianism, and isolationism, howeverdifferent these typically American doctrines may seem, are both sceptical aboutsubsuming national interests to international cooperation and collective securityand constitute different expressions of the specicity (the exceptionalism) of the US as the home of a chosen people.

    The current US policy (but to a lesser extent also that of the administration of Bill Clinton) is increasingly discussed in terms of imperialism, a concept that isused academically, pejoratively and positively by different people. 87 A minimumacademic denition of imperialism should surely contain a unilateralist, exploita-

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    23/319

    with a complicated ontological problem. We are not quite sure about or agreedupon the object of study. The very concept of region remains extremely vagueand evasive, and makes sense only when associated with the Westphalian logicof bounded, politically controlled territories and the question of what happensto this logic in the context of globalisation and regionalisation. The early theoristslooked for post-Westphalian trends, but the global dynamics were then stied bythe bipolar structure.

    One discontinuity that emerges in retrospect is thus the stronger normative and

    prescriptive nature of the early debate, whether the point of departure was feder-alism, functionalism or neofunctionalism. The idea was to achieve peace bymoving beyond the Westphalian logic to nd institutionalised forms of permanentinternational cooperation. The more recent debate is generated much more by theerosion of national borders and the urgent question of how to nd an alternativeorder beyond Westphalia. Neofunctionalism, the only one of the three earlyapproaches with theoretical ambitions, was dismissed before regionalism (or

    regional integration which was the preferred concept) had shown its real face.There was a lively debate without much happening on the ground, or perhaps itis more correct to say that whatever happened in the eld of regional integrationwas distorted and nally stied by the Cold War and the bipolar world order.Based on this poor showing in the real, empirical world, the critics, mostly realists,had a fairly easy task in questioning the viability of and the case for regional inte-gration. The new wave of interest in regionalism should thus be seen in the contextof the ending of the Cold War and the beginning of globalisation. The challengenow, in other words, is to theorise a fast emerging empirical phenomenon without

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    24/319

    Continental regions can certainly coincide with civilisations; they are oftenunderstood in a simple geographic sense. However, there are continental organisa-tions such as the AU and the OAS which may move from paper existence to realregions to the extent that this level becomes functional and operational. It is never-theless misleading to see more operational regions on a particular continent, forinstance Africa, as subregions. Thus ECOWAS and SADC are regions, notsubregions, but depending on the strength of the AU they may become subregionsin the future.

    In the second part of the article an attempt was made to show the complexity of more recent regionalisation initiatives and processes in terms of dimensions,actors and levels of action. Regionalism was rst interpreted mainly as atrading arrangement, but it soon became clear that this new trend went beyondtrade and into monetary policy, development strategy, security and environmentalprotection, to mention just the most important elds of cooperation or provision of regional public goods. The region thereby became an arena for many actors apart

    from governments, and, through the increasing cohesion of the region (regionness)as well as through its increasing capacity to act (actorness), the region itself is becoming an important actor, ultimately with the potential of shaping worldorder. In particular, the phenomenon of interregionalism has to be furthertheorised. We need to know if it is a general trend in world society or only aprojection of the EU view of the world.

    Even in the absence of a thoroughly regionalised world (multiregionalism), theprocess of regionalisation is, in one way or the other, bound to have an impact onthe future world order. The current ideology of globalism argues in favour of a par-

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    25/319

    differences do not express varieties of national mentality Europe versusAmerica but constitute contrasting world order principles held by politicalgroupings in both areas. It is therefore reasonable to expect coexistence,whether uneasy or not, and the emergence of hybrids formed somewherebetween these competing world order models. Even so, changes in the US aremuch the more important. Notwithstanding the election of the second GeorgeW. Bush administration, there exists in the US now a call for a return to multi-lateralism: the US and its main regional partners must begin to prepare for life

    after Pax Americana.93

    Such a shift would bring Europe and the US closer, butit will not eliminate the difference between the models of multiregionalismand a global concert of regional powers; between a post-Westphalian and aneo-Westphalian world order.

    Notes

    Much of my recent work in this eld has been carried out jointly with Fredrik So derbaum, and his help in writingthis article has also been invaluable. Tony Paynes generous support and enthusiasm was also of great importance,now as earlier.

    1. Donald Puchala once compared this predicament with the blind mans unsuccessful attempts to dene anelephant. See the discussion in Ben Rosamond, Theories of European Integration (Palgrave, 2000), p. 12.

    2. For introductions to the earlier debate focusing on Europe, see R. J. Harrison, Europe in Question (Allen &Unwin, 1974); Rosamond, Theories of European Integration ; and Dimitris N. Cryssochoou, TheorizingEuropean Integration (Sage, 2001).

    3. Previous overviews of the recent debate include Bjo rn Hettne, Andras Inotai & Osvaldo Sunkel (eds), Studiesin the New Regionalism Vols I V (Macmillan 1999 / 2001); Mario Telo ` (ed ) European Union and New

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    26/319

    16. Helge Hveem, The regional project in global governance, in: So derbaum & Shaw, Theories of New Region-

    alism , p. 83.17. Hurrell, Regionalism in theoretical perspective, p. 39.18. Sophie Boisseau du Rocher & Bertrand Fort, Paths to Regionalisation: Comparing Experiences in East Asia

    and Europe (Marshall Cavendish, 2005), p. xi.19. Iver. B. Neumann, A region-building approach, in: So derbaum & Shaw, Theories of New Regionalism ,

    pp. 16078.20. Sometimes the economic nationalism in the interwar period is referred to as the rst wave or generation. Luk

    Van Langenhove and Ana-Cristina Costea speak of three generations of regionalism, referring to: a rst gen-eration of economic integration, a second generation of internal political integration and a third emerging

    generation of external political integration. Speaking in terms of generations also allows the authors toavoid the dichotomy between old and new regionalism. They believe that a neo new regionalism isshaping up, with greater ambitions in global governance in general and the United Nations institutionsin particular. See Luk Van Langenhove & Ana-Cristina Costea, Third generation regional integration:the transmutation of multilateralism into multiregionalism?, unpublished manuscript, United NationsUniversity / Comparative Regional Integration Studies (UNU / CRIS), 2005.

    21. This section draws on Rosamond, Theories of European Integration .22. David Mitrany, The Prospect of Integration: Federal of Functional, Journal of Common Market Studies ,

    Vol. 4, No. 1 (1965), pp. 11949; and David Mitrany, A Working Peace System (Quadrangle Books,1943, 1966).

    23. Rosamond, Theories of European Integration , p. 60.24. Bela Balassa, The Theory of Economic Integration (Allen & Unwin, 1961).25. Stanley Hoffman, Obstinate or Obsolete? The Fate of the Nation State and the Case of Western Europe,

    Daedalus , No. 95 (1966), pp. 86585.26. Alan S. Milward, The European Rescue of the Nation State (Routledge, 1992).27. Robert O. Keohane & Joseph S. Nye (eds), Transnational Relations and World Politics (Harvard University

    Press, 1972); also Power and Interdependence (Little, Brown & Co., 1977).

    28. Ernst B. Haas, International Integration: The European and the Universal Process, InternationalOrganization , Vol. 15, No. 4 (1961), pp. 36692; and Ernst B. Haas & Phillipe Schmitter, Economics

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    27/319

    (Cambridge University Press, 1993); and Vincent Cable & David Henderson (eds), Trade Blocs? The Future

    of Regional Integration (Royal Institute of International Affairs, 1994).36. Cable & Henderson, Trade Blocs? , p. 8.37. Andrew Gamble & Anthony Payne, Conclusion: the new regionalism, in: Gamble & Payne (eds),

    Regionalism and World Order , p. 251.38. For surveys of theoretical approaches, see So derbaum & Shaw, Theories of New Regionalism ; and Finn

    Laursen, Comparative Regional Integration: Theoretical Perspectives (Ashgate, 2003). The formerfocuses on theoretical approaches, the latter makes a conscious selection of both theoretical approachesand empirical cases to illuminate them. Two more focused theoretical explorations are Mattli, The Logicof Regional Integration ; and Stefan A. Schirm, Globalization and the New Regionalism: Global Markets,

    Domestic Politics and Regional Cooperation (Polity, 2002).39. See the special issue of Third World Quarterly , Vol. 20, No. 5 (1999) on New Regionalisms in the

    New Millennium.40. The discussion on these issues draws on Bjo rn Hettne & Fredrik Soderbaum, Regional cooperation: a tool

    for addressing regional and global challenges, in: Ministry of Foreign Affairs, International Task Force onGlobal Public Goods , Stockholm, 2004, available at http: // www.gpgtaskforce.org / bazment.aspx

    41. Percy S. Mistry, New regionalism and economic development, in: So derbaum & Shaw (eds), Theories of New Regionalism , pp. 11739.

    42. Ibid. , p. 136.43. Diana Tussie, Regionalism: providing a substance to multilateralism?, in: So derbaum & Shaw (eds),

    Theories of New Regionalism , pp. 99116.44. Stephany Grifth-Jones, International nancial stability and market efciency as a global public good, in:

    Inge Kaul, Pedro Conceicao, Katell Le Goulven & Ronald Mendoza (eds), Providing Global Public Goods: Managing Globalization (Oxford University Press for United Nations Development Programme, 2003),pp. 43554.

    45. Richard Higgott, From Trade-Led to Monetary-Led Regionalism: Why Asia in the 21st Century will beDifferent to Europe in the 20th Century, UNU / CRIS e-Working Papers No. 1, Bruges, 2002.

    46. Peter Robson, The New Regionalism and Developing Countries, Journal of Common Market Studies ,Vol. 31, No. 3 (1993), pp. 32948.

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    28/319

    60. Morten Bas, Marianne H. Marchand & Timothy M. Shaw, The weave-world: the regional interweaving of

    economies, ideas and identities, in: So derbaum & Shaw (eds), Theories of New Regionalism , pp. 192210.61. Winfried Ruigrok & Rob van Tulder, The Logic of International Restructuring (Routledge, 1995).62. Robert Wade, The disturbing rise in poverty and inequality, in: David Held & Mathias Koenig-Archibugi

    (eds), Taming Globalization (Polity, 2003), p. 34.63. Roland Axtman, Globalization and Europe (Pinter, 1998), p 173.64. Fredrik So derbaum & Timothy M. Shaw, Conclusion: what futures for new regionalism?, in: So derbaum &

    Shaw (eds), Theories of New Regionalism , p. 222.65. Theorising actorship has so far been focused on the EU. A pioneering study is that of Gunnar Sjo stedt,

    The External Role of the European Community (Saxon House, 1977).

    66. Van Langenhove, Theorising Regionhood.67. Hettne, Neo-Mercantilism.68. Charlotte Bretherton & John Vogler, The European Union as a Global Actor (Routledge, 1999), p. 38.69. Glenn Hook & Ian Kearns (eds), Subregionalism and World Order (Macmillan, 1999), p. 1.70. Kenichi Ohmae, who observed the phenomenon at an early stage, referred to these formations as

    region states, which is somewhat misleading. He also saw them as emerging out of globalisation whichis a simplication. See Kenichi Ohmae, The Rise of the Region-State, Foreign Affairs , Vol. 72, No. 1(1993), pp. 78-87.

    71. Bob Jessop, The political economy of scale and the construction of cross-border microregionalism,in: So derbaum & Shaw, Theories of New Regionalism , pp. 17998.

    72. James H. Mittelman, The Globalization Syndrome: Transformation and Resistance (Princeton UniversityPress, 2000); and Markus Perkmann & Ngai-Ling Sum (eds), Globalization, Regionalization and the Build-ing of Cross-Border Regions (Palgrave, 2002).

    73. Joakim O jendal, South East Asia at a constant crossroads: an ambiguous new region, in: Schultz et al., Regionalization in a Globalising World , p. 160.

    74. James Parsonage, South East Asias Growth Triangle: A Subregional Response to Global Trans-formation, International Journal of Urban and Regional Studies , Vol. 16, No. 3 (1997), pp. 30717.

    75. Gamble & Payne (eds), Regionalism and World Order and the various follow-up studies from the projecthave even been referred to as the world order approach. See, for instance, Fredrik So derbaum, Introduc-

    Bjo rn Hettne

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    29/319

    Press of Kentucky, 2004); and Chalmers Johnson, The Sorrows of Empire: Militarism, Secrecy and the End of

    the Republic (Metropolitan Books, 2004).88. Paul Kennedy, The Rise and Fall of Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conict from 1500 to2000 (Random House, 1987). Eric Hobsbawm made the following observation regarding old and new imperi-alism, further underlining the problem of sustainability: The present world situation is quite unprecedented.The great global empires that we have seen before . . . bear little comparison with what we see today in theUnited States empire . . . A key novelty of the US imperial project is that all other great powers and empiresknew that they were not the only ones, and none aimed at global domination. None believed themselvesinvulnarable, even if they believed themselves to be central to the world as China did, or the RomanEmpire at its peak (cited in Burbach & Tarbell, Imperial Overstretch , p. 179).

    89. Shaun Breslin et al. (eds), New Regionalisms in the Global Political Economy (Routledge, 2002), p. 11.90. W. Andrew Axline, Comparative case studies of regional cooperation among developing countries, in:

    Axline, The Political Economy of Regional Cooperation , p. 11.91. Andrew Hurrell, The regional dimension in international relations theory in: Farrell et al. , Global Politics of

    Regionalism , pp. 3853.92. Immanuel Wallerstein makes an interesting distinction between civilisation and the empirical historical

    system, the empire. A civilization refers to a contemporary claim about the past in terms of its use in thepresent to justify heritage, separateness, rights. See Immanuel Wallerstein, Geopolitics and Geoculture:Essays on the Changing World-system (Cambridge University Press, 1991). Another materialist approachis to be found in Robert Cox, Civilisations in World Political Economy, New Political Economy , Vol. 1,No. 2 (1996), pp. 14156. In the globalised condition, civilisations are de-territorialised and constitutecommunities of thought, global projects in conict and dialogue. The interplay implies a supra-intersubjectivity and, if it takes the form of dialogue rather than conict, one can speak of a new multila-teralism. This concept is developed in Robert W. Cox, The New Realism: Perspectives on Multilateralismand World Order (Macmillan, 1997).

    93. Charles A. Kupchan, After Pax Americana: benign power, regional integration and the sources of stablemultipolarity, in: Birthe Hansen & Bertel Heurlin (eds), The New World Order: Contrasting Theories

    (Palgrave, 2000), pp. 13466.

    Beyond the New Regionalism

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    30/319

    The World Economy (2007)doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2007.01038.x

    Blackwell Publishing LtdOxford, UKTWECWorld Economy0378-5920 2007 The Author Journal compilation Blackwell Publishers Ltd.2006>XXXOriginal ArticlesREGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMYRICHARD POMFRET

    Is Regionalism an Increasing Featureof the World Economy?

    Richard Pomfret University of Adelaide and the Johns Hopkins University, Bologna, Italy

    Measuring the importance of regionalism in international trade is desirable but difcult. The number of regional trade agreements (RTAs) reported to the WTO or the proportion of world trade which is between countries in a RTA are frequently cited as evidence that regionalism is growing at an accelerating rate.This paper questions whether RTAs really are as important as the headline numbers suggest, orwhether they just occupy an excessively large part of policymakersand economic journaliststime.The main contributions are to analyse the number of RTAs and the share of world trade criteria in order to show why both are meaningless in the current world economy.The paper concludes that, although the extent of regionalism is difcult to measure and the desirability of individual RTAs is difcult to assess, thethreat to the multilateral trading system does not appear to be as large as is often reported, because the long-term dynamics of RTAs lead either to state formation, which is important but rare, or to ineffectiveness, which is the fate of the vast majority of RTAs.

    1. INTRODUCTION

    R EGIONAL Trade Agreements (RTAs) are a major and perhaps irreversiblefeature of the multilateral trading system is the opening sentence of aWorking Paper (Crawford and Fiorentino, 2005), which appears on the same WTOwebpage as a dramatic graph showing the increasing number of RTAs reportedsince the early 1990s.1 As of June 2005, 312 RTAs had been notied to theGATT/WTO, and 196 of these were in the decade after the establishment of the

    WTO in January 1995. Numbers like these are so frequently reported that it hasbecome a stylised fact of the world trading system that regionalism is growing at

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    31/319

    924 RICHARD POMFRET

    an accelerating rate.2 The aim of this paper is to question whether RTAs reallyare as important as the headline numbers suggest, or do they just occupy an excessivelylarge part of policymakers and economic journalists time?

    2. HISTORICAL BACKGROUND

    The cornerstone of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) andhence of the WTO is the non-discrimination principle embodied in unconditionalmost-favoured nation treatment. Yet, since 1947 the principle has seemedunder recurring threat, most especially in three waves of discriminatory tradepolicies.3

    In the 1950s six western European countries began a process of economicintegration that led to the establishment of a customs union in the 1960s, which

    through contagion and imitation effects led to other RTAs. Seven other Europeancountries formed the European Free Trade Association (EFTA) in 1960. The sixEU members used preferential trading agreements to encourage future membersand as a substitute for traditional foreign policy instruments.4 Developing countriesin Africa, the Caribbean and Latin America signed many RTAs, which were tovarying degrees modelled on the EU. The Generalised System of Preferences (GSP)in 1971 legitimised extension of tariff preferences for developing countries. Inthe event, however, only the EU itself had any signicant effect in terms of the

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    32/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 925

    completing the internal market) and widening (to 15 members in 1995) of the EU.There were also some new or extended RTAs in South America (Mercosur), SouthAsia (SAFTA), West Asia (ECO), Southeast Asia (AFTA) and Africa (many).

    In both of these waves, however, apart from the obvious and importantdevelopments in European economic integration and NAFTA, it turned out thatdiscriminatory trade policies posed less of a threat to the global trading systemthan observers like Patterson (1966) or Pomfret (1988) feared. Completion of theKennedy Round in the 1960s and of the Uruguay Round in 1994 was much moresignicant for the global trading system than were the contemporaneous wavesof regionalism. By 1995 with the establishment of the WTO there existed a bodyof world trade law centred on the non-discrimination principle, strengtheneddispute resolution mechanisms, and low bound tariffs in the major economies for all goods outside agriculture.

    In the early 2000s, a third wave of discriminatory trade policies can be observed.

    This time it is led by East Asia, partly stimulated by a perception that the globaleconomic institutions let the region down in the 1997 Asian Crisis and partly bythe increase of Chinas economic power.5 The collapse of the 1999 WTO meetingsin Seattle and the diminishing signicance of APEC further stimulated newapproaches to trade liberalisation in the Asia-Pacic region. Bilateral negotiationswere begun in 1999 by Japan with Singapore, and plurilateral negotiations wereinitiated between China and ASEAN. Singapore, South Korea and Thailand allembarked on bilateral agreements. In their embracing of bilateral agreements, the

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    33/319

    926 RICHARD POMFRET

    apparent strength of the WTO system.7 One difculty with assessing the extent of the threat that RTAs pose for the multilateral trading system is that the importanceof regionalism is difcult to measure.

    3. COUNTING RTAs

    Many commentators cite the large number of RTAs notied to the WTO asevidence of the growth and signicance of regionalism. From this perspective,because the number of RTAs notied to the WTO reached an all-time high in theearly 2000s, regionalism was more prevalent than ever. Crawford and Fiorentino(2005) in their survey of RTAs state that Between January 2004 and February2005 alone, 43 RTAs have been notied to the WTO, making this the most prolicRTA period in recorded history.

    These counts include notications under GATT Article XXIV, GATS Article V,and the Enabling Clause, as well as accessions to existing RTAs. They undercountthe total number of RTAs, because some RTAs under negotiation have not yet beennotied to the WTO and others are among non-WTO members. On the other hand,the cumulative WTO counts overstate the current situation because they do not excludeabrogated RTAs.8 When ten new countries joined the EU in 2004, 65 RTAs betweenthe EU and the new members and among the new member countries were subsumedinto the EU RTA. Thus in Crawford and Fiorentinos most prolic RTA period

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    34/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 927

    TABLE 1

    RTAs Notied to the WTO, January-June 2005

    Agreement Notication Date WTO Provisions Type of Agreement

    ThailandAustralia 5 January Article XXIV Free trade agreementThailandAustralia 5 January GATS Art. V Services agreementMoldovaBulgaria 28 January Article XXIV Free trade agreementMoldovaBosnia & Herzegovina 28 January Article XXIV Free trade agreement

    MoldovaSerbia & Montenegro 28 January Article XXIV Free trade agreementMoldovaCroatia 31 January Article XXIV Free trade agreementMoldovaFYROM 31 January Article XXIV Free trade agreementRomaniaBosnia & Herzegovina 14 February Article XXIV Free trade agreementRomaniaSerbia & Montenegro 14 February Article XXIV Free trade agreementRomaniaFYROM 14 February Article XXIV Free trade agreementBulgariaBosnia & Herzegovina 11 March Article XXIV Free trade agreementBulgariaSerbia & Montenegro 11 March Article XXIV Free trade agreementPanamaEl Salvador 18 March Article XXIV Free trade agreementCroatiaFYROM 1 April Article XXIV Free trade agreementPanamaEl Salvador 5 April GATS Art. V Services agreementJapanMexico 22 April Article XXIV Free trade agreementJapanMexico 22 April GATS Art. V Services agreementRomaniaIsrael 25 April Article XXIV Free trade agreementFYROMBosnia & Herzegovina 11 May Article XXIV Free trade agreementEFTATunisia 7 June Article XXIV Free trade agreement

    Source: http://www.wto.org see the Appendix for a more extensive listing of RTAs notied from 1995 to2006.

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    35/319

    928 RICHARD POMFRET

    when the RTAs involve larger economies (Thailand-Australia or Japan-Mexico),

    the restrictive terms of the agreement make it unlikely to have a big impact onthe bilateral trade.Counting RTAs is not just a poor measure of the extent of regionalism; it can

    lead to nonsensical conclusions about trends in the global economy due to thetreatment of regional disintegration and integration. The replacement of a regionalbloc by a web of bilateral or plurilateral agreements increases the number of RTAs, and by the counting criterion indicates an increase in regionalism. Conversely,the replacement of a network of minor RTAs by a single RTA can be interpretedas a decline in regionalism. This is not an abstract point; the dissolution of Yugoslavia,Czechoslovakia and the Soviet Union and the collapse of Comecon were the maindriving force behind the GATT/WTO indicator after 1989, while the accessionof ten eastern European countries to the EU in 2004 and 2007 rendered manynotied RTAs null but increased regionalism in Europe.

    The main reason for the rapid increase in the number of RTAs during the 1990swas the proliferation of bilateral and plurilateral free trade agreements amongcountries of the former Council for Mutual Economic Assistance and amongsuccessor states to Yugoslavia, the USSR and Czechoslovakia. The new EasternEuropean RTAs were a response to regional disintegration, i.e. the dissolution of a larger regional bloc (the CMEA) or of individual countries, rather than a trendtowards regionalism in Central and Eastern Europe.10 As the Kyrgyz Republic(1998), Georgia (2000), Moldova (2001) and Armenia (2003) joined the WTO,

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    36/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 929

    in EU negotiations where theacquis communautaire had to be accepted.11 A similar

    phenomenon of a reduced number of RTAs being associated with an extensionof regionalism would arise if the EU brought the Balkan non-member countriesinto a customs union similar to that between the EU and Turkey; the customs unionwould displace a tangle of RTAs of which 31 have been reported to the WTO.12

    In sum, the common practice of citing the number of RTAs notied to theWTO as a measure of the extent of regionalism in the global trading system isunfounded and misleading. It is unfounded because not all notied agreementsare of equal signicance. It is misleading because it interprets the fallout from amajor event of the 1990s (the transformation of eastern Europe and the USSR)in simplistic terms as an increase in regionalism in the global economy.

    4. THE SHARE OF WORLD TRADE COVERED BY RTAs

    An alternative measure of the extent of regionalism is the share of world tradeconducted under RTAs. All WTO members except Mongolia have signed RTAs.According to Crawford and Fiorentino (2005), for some WTO members preferentialtrade represents over 90 per cent of their total trade. Schiff and Winters, co-leadersof a major World Bank research project on RTAs, state that some 55 to 60 percentof world trade now occurs within such trade blocs (1998, p. 178). These percentagessuggest that the unconditional MFN treatment required by Article I of the WTOs

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    37/319

    930 RICHARD POMFRET

    the USA. Thus, if some Canadian exports enter the US market unimpeded by anti-

    dumping or countervailing duties which would have been imposed in CUSTAsabsence, then that trade might be ascribed to the RTA. When we do not observethe counterfactual, however, it is hard to measure the RTAs impact.13

    The inclusion of Mexico to create NAFTA was a different matter becauseMexico still had some signicant tariffs in 1993. However, even if we acceptthat NAFTA stimulated US-Mexican trade, it is still unclear whether all of thistrade should be ascribed to NAFTA and, if not all, then how much? Mexico wasengaged in substantial unilateral trade liberalisation at the same time as it wasnegotiating NAFTA, so that it is not valid to compare trade ows before and after NAFTA came into effect and ascribe any increase to NAFTA-related liberalisation.14

    The general point is that even if WTO members are parties to RTAs whicheliminate tariffs on most of their trade, in a world with low MFN tariffs suchtariff reductions are unlikely to make much difference to actual trade ows.15 The

    contrast between this conclusion and the perceived large effects of RTAs may bebecause modern RTAs go beyond trade, to cover all kinds of behind-the-borderobstacles to trade. These trade costs are important (Anderson and van Wincoop, 2004),and, as border measures such as tariffs and non-tariff barriers to trade diminish,the signicance of other trade costs becomes more apparent. The role of RTAs indiminishing them will be addressed in the next section. The extent to whichbehind-the-border trade costs are reduced by an RTA and hence increase trade is,however, not captured by the size of trade ows between the signatories of the RTA.

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    38/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 931

    harmonisation, or service activities. Robert Lawrence (1996) popularised the term

    deep integration to capture regional agreements in these new areas. Such deepintegration can improve market efciency and, in view of the difculties associatedwith policy harmonisation, RTAs can provide a testing ground for alternativepolicy blueprints. On the other hand, the complexity of deep integration also offerspotential for welfare-decreasing RTAs.

    Deep integration has the potential to be welfare-improving by reducing non-tariff barriers to trade and by cutting behind-the-border trade costs. Non-tariff barriers hamper regional integration, and in many cases are used by producers tosegment markets in order to enjoy local monopoly power. Major steps in improvingthe operation of the EU internal market involved establishing principles of mutualrecognition and disallowing minor variations in safety, health or environmentstandards, although this has led to tedious case-by-case judgments.

    A positive building block argument for regional agreements is that they can

    be testing grounds for international policies in new areas. On the other hand,turning a policy designed by a few countries into a global institution may arousefears of it being moulded to the designers interests.16 Examples of bilateralagreements which have gone beyond WTO commitments with respect to TRIMS(trade-related investment measures) and TRIPS (intellectual property rights) arediscussed below; WTO-Plus articles in a North-South agreement, which benetthe partner from the North but preclude desirable policy options of the partner from the South, may be a poor blueprint for global agreements.

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    39/319

    932 RICHARD POMFRET

    Thus, there is a potential trade-diverting bias in RTA design, which is one justication

    for the GATT/WTO requirement that an FTA should cover virtually all trade sothat countries cannot customise RTAs to include only sectors where trade diversionis more likely.17 With deeper integration the exclusions may be less transparent.In NAFTA, the rules of origin (RoOs) have been designed, especially for textilesand apparel and for automobiles, to favour trade diversion. More broadly, the verydetailed RoOs in NAFTA serve to manage trade, often to the benet of specicUS rms, while as a tax on intermediate inputs the RoOs global impact is presumedto be negative (Krueger, 1999).18 The extension to service sectors in deep integrationarrangements almost inevitably increases the opportunity for rent-seeking, becausemost service providers are governed by regulations which may be desirable butwhich also offer the opportunity to erect discriminatory barriers to trade.19

    Third-wave RTAs take up deep integration issues or address very specic tradeissues. One reason for being concerned with a trading partners domestic policies

    or service sector structure is a sense that trade should be fair as well as free. If behind-the-border trade costs vary from country to country, then the trade playing eldis not at. Foreigners will nd greater difculty in penetrating the market of a countrywith poorly developed infrastructure, nancial institutions and other supportservices. This concept of unfairness has been most often voiced by the USA,which sees its home market as easier to supply than other countries markets,and hence US exporters and import-competing producers are at a competitivedisadvantage.20

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    40/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 933

    More controversial has been the US position of going beyond WTO commitments

    on TRIMS and TRIPS. WTO-Plus on TRIMS has included references to indirectexpropriation (i.e. requiring compensation if policy changes reduce the expectedprotability of a foreign investment) or mechanisms requiring compulsory inter-national arbitration. On TRIPS, obligations to register patents on existing drugs if new uses are found, as in the US-Morocco FTA, may extend a patents life beyondthe requirements of TRIPS a practice sometimes called evergreening of patents.In both of these areas, the WTO-Plus features benet US transnational corporationsbut reduce the partners policy exibility, and may constrain negotiating optionswithin the WTO (IISD, 2004, p. 25).

    Third-wave bilateral trade agreements are replete with examples of highlyspecic agreements. The typical scenario is announcement of free trade negotiationsaccompanied by data on the total trade between the negotiating countries andestimates of the potential welfare gains from trade expansion, and then several

    years later the governments sign a highly specic agreement, which may achievelimited goals, but also reects a desire not to lose face by abandoning the freetrade agreement. The 2004 Australia-US FTA, for example, involved two countrieswith substantial bilateral trade, but the outcome was almost trivial; Australiafailed to achieve its major goals of reducing obstacles to its farm exports to theUSA, but still signed the agreement, while the USA obtained a specic TRIPSconcession from Australia.21 In the negotiations between Thailand and Japan thekey issues for Thailand were reducing barriers to agricultural exports and to

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    41/319

    934 RICHARD POMFRET

    The specicity of these beyond trade arguments in support of second- and third-

    wave RTAs makes it difcult to generalise about their desirability and almostimpossible to measure the extent of regionalism in the global economy. One issueis that, even though regional arrangements with deep integration or the recentbilateral agreements are not concluded in global fora, their impact is often non-preferential and benecial to the global trading system. Improved operation of theEU-wide nancial system, for example, helps to make trade nance competitivelyavailable to external as well as internal suppliers to EU markets. Measures suchas improvements in customs clearance efciency should facilitate all trade.22 Asecond issue is the difculty of quantifying the effect of measures that reducetrade costs. Whereas the impact of a tariff cut or removal of a non-tariff barrier affecting a specic product can be estimated, at least as a rst approximation,with a partial equilibrium model, quantifying the impact of a measure that reducestrade costs in general requires a general equilibrium model. In principle, computable

    general equilibrium (CGE) models can estimate the impact of a deep integrationmeasure or a trade-facilitating non-tariff item in a bilateral treaty and they cancontrast regional implementation with global implementation, but in practiceCGE models are too coarse to capture the specicity of such measures.23 Beforeconcluding on the extent of regionalism, the next section reviews how patterns of regionalism differ from one part of the world to another.

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    42/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 935

    twentieth century. The only close parallel is the relationship between Australia and

    New Zealand, with much shared culture and history, and the CER is the deepestRTA apart from the EU.Between 1957 and the early 1970s the EU used trade agreements as a tool of

    foreign policy and constructed a pyramid of preferences which challenged thenon-discrimination principle upon which GATT was based. These discriminatoryarrangements have become less signicant since the 1970s, as the EU has foundsuperior foreign policy instruments, and less complex, as the intended goodwilleffect was eroded by preferred partners concerns about their relative position inthe pyramid. Preference margins were eroded by cuts in the EUs MFN tariffs inthe various rounds of multilateral trade negotiations, and the 2001 EverythingBut Arms regulation granted duty-free access to EU markets to all least devel-oped countries exports other than arms.24 The 1995 Barcelona Process to createa Euro-Mediterranean free trade area by 2010 and the 2000 Cotonou Partnership

    Agreement with African, Caribbean and Pacic countries are essentially artefactsfrom the earlier era, which now aim to create simplied reciprocal free traderegimes with the two broad groups of most preferred partners rather than to create anely delineated hierarchy of partners and clients.

    The USA was the main defender of non-discriminatory trade policies until 1980,but after that it began to use RTAs to strengthen western hemisphere ties amongmarket-based democracies and as an instrument of foreign policy. The CaribbeanBasin Initiative, which was in 198283 the rst step in this new direction, now

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    43/319

    936 RICHARD POMFRET

    Outside the western hemisphere, RTAs have limited economic signicance for

    the USA. They are largely aimed at achieving specic goals and used as an instrumentof foreign policy. The rst such RTA was the 1985 US-Israel free trade agreement,which was in response to an EU-Israel FTA and clearly a special case. The bilateraltrade agreements negotiated by the USA since 2001 (Jordan, Singapore, Australia,Bahrain, Morocco and South Africa) are intended to reward allies. Such agreementscan be expected to benet the smaller partner, although their economic contentis minor as any sensitive products are likely to be excluded.26 The USA has exertedsome trade diplomacy at a regional level, proposing a Middle East Free Trade Areaand the Enterprise for ASEAN Initiative, but with little concrete to show for it.27

    Proposals for RTAs made minimal progress in Asia before the late 1990s. InEast Asia regional integration has increased since 1985, but it has been market- rather than policy-driven.28 ASEAN was formed as a political bloc and despite manyideas for joint industrial projects or for preferential tariffs it had little economic

    content until the ASEAN free trade area (AFTA) began to be taken slightly moreseriously in the 1990s.29 Malaysias proposal for an East Asian Economic Caucusin the late 1980s was successfully opposed by the USA and Australia, and theopen regionalism (i.e. coordinated non-discriminatory trade liberalisation) of Asia-Pacic Economic Cooperation (APEC) became the model for the region;the Bogor Declaration at the 1994 APEC summit expressed consensus on themultilateral approach. Japan, South Korea, China, Hong Kong and Taiwan stoodout as economies without RTAs.

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    44/319

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    45/319

    938 RICHARD POMFRET

    Singapores bilaterals go beyond trade, and mainly concern nancial market

    liberalisation, while Thai bilaterals seem to have been primarily to offer thePrime Minister an international stage; to the extent that they create special traderelationships, the bilateral agreements of Singapore and Thailand are anti-regionalismbecause they dilute ASEAN trade ties. Beyond East Asia, Chinese negotiationstend to be single-issue deals, e.g. in the China-Australia agreement China seeksabolition of its non-market-economy status in anti-dumping calculations.34 Insum, the spaghetti bowl of recent East Asian RTAs makes for complicated artwork(as, for example, in Feridhanusetyawan, 2005, pp. 1011), but the RTAs have littleeconomic impact.35

    In other parts of the world RTAs have had even less impact. The League of Arab States dates from 1945, but even though the Arab League was mooted asa common market in 1956 (i.e. before the EUs founding Six signed the Treatyof Rome) and a Greater Arab Free Trade Area agreement was signed in 1997

    there has been little implementation.36

    In Africa dozens of RTAs have been signedbut with little impact on trade. In South Asia, despite the existence of the SouthAsian Association of Regional Cooperation (SAARC) since 1985 and a preferentialtrade arrangement since 1995, the two largest countries, India and Pakistan, didnot even grant one another full MFN treatment; since the signing of the SouthAsia Free Trade Area (SAFTA) agreement in 2004 relations are warmer, but stillappear to be subordinate to bilateral agreements with countries outside the region.37

    In West and Central Asia, especially since the dissolution of the USSR, many

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    46/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 939

    the agreement when unpleasant consequences seem likely or political alliances

    shift.38

    None of this has much consequence for the global trading system.In sum, we observe different patterns in different parts of the world, which areamalgamated under the rubric of regionalism but are in reality quite diverse. Shouldthis be a cause for concern? The key components of the multilateral trading systemare non-discrimination and transparency. Attempts to form seriously discriminat-ing RTAs have foundered in Latin America and Africa, and failed to get off theground in Asia, largely because policymakers did not want to bear the tradediversion costs of importing from inefcient producers in partner countries. If theEU is treated as a single unit, as it is in WTO fora, then there is not muchdiscrimination due to RTAs.39 Transparency has been a greater victim due to thecomplexity of many RTAs.40

    7. CONCLUSIONS

    Claims that the world economy is experiencing a dramatic increase in regionalismare based on faulty measures and misrepresent the reality of an increasinglyintegrated global trading system based on non-discriminatory trade policies.

    Despite the increased attention being paid to regional arrangements, the holdof multilateralism is stronger than ever as practically all trading nations have nowacceded to the WTO, with lower trade barriers and stronger trade dispute settlement

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    47/319

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    48/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 941

    RTAs in terms of economic analysis and the interaction of politics and economics.

    The second-best analysis (i.e. because world trade is already distorted, reducinga distortion by preferential trade liberalisation may be welfare-improving or welfare-reducing) is traditionally framed as trade creation versus trade diversion.It most often appears in the contrast between the grand announcements of RTAsby political leaders wishing to make a foreign policy impact or to indicate their countries friendship, and the implementation record as policymakers are lobbiedby domestic producers or realise the costs of trade diversion.44 Second-best con-siderations can also be seen in debates over whether RTAs produce benecialWTO-Plus outcomes. All RTAs claim to be WTO consistent, but the imprecisionof GATT Article XXIV and GATS Article V mean that this is not always clear,and WTO-Plus may be undesirable if it precludes negotiation of broader superior outcomes.

    Politics have driven some of the major developments highlighted in the previous

    section, e.g. the EU, FTAA and the competition between China and Japan for Asian hegemony. This can have large and unstoppable economic consequencesfor the global trading system (as in the road from the Treaty of Rome to the EU)or it can have negligible economic consequences (as in the current stand-off inEast Asia). At times the outcome may be somewhere in between (does NAFTAmildly reinforce market-driven integration trends behind low external trade barriers,as in ASEAN, or does it create a trading bloc?), but the eventual outcome islikely to be one of the extremes Politically motivated regional integration leads

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    49/319

    942 RICHARD POMFRET

    RTA signatories, are clearly inadequate. The desirability of RTAs, which due to

    their second-best nature is impossible to determinea priori , is also difcult toassess. Nevertheless, the threat to the multilateral trading system does not appear to be as large as is often reported, because the long-term dynamics of RTAs leadeither to state formation, which is important but rare, or to ineffectiveness, whichis the fate of the vast majority of RTAs.

    APPENDIXRTAs Notied to the WTO from 1 January, 1995, to the End of 2006

    Agreement Notication Date WTO Provisions Entry into Force

    EC Accession (Austria,Finland, Sweden)

    20 January1995 Article XXIV 1/1/95

    EC Accession (Austria,Finland, Sweden) 20 January GATS Art. V 1/1/95NAFTA 1 March GATS Art. V 1/1/94COMESA 29 June Enabling Clause 8/12/94EC (Treaty of Rome) 10 November GATS Art. V 1/1/58CER 22 November GATS Art. V 1/1/89ECTurkey 22 December Article XXIV 1/1/96IcelandFaroe Islands 23 January1996 Article XXIV 1/7/93SwitzerlandFaroe Islands 8 March Article XXIV 1/3/95NorwayFaroe Islands 13 March Article XXIV 1/7/93

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    50/319

    REGIONALISM IN THE WORLD ECONOMY 943

    BulgariaFYROM 19 February2000 Article XXIV 1/1/00WAEMUUEMOA 3 February Enabling Clause 1/1/00EFTAMorocco 18 February Article XXIV 1/12/99ECMorocco 1 August Article XXIV 1/7/00CEMAC 29 September Enabling Clause 24/6/99EAC 11 October Enabling Clause 7/7/00ECIsrael 7 November Article XXIV 1/6/00ECMorocco 8 November Article XXIV 1/3/00ECSouth Africa 21 November Article XXIV 1/1/00Kyrgyz RepublicArmenia 4 January2001 Article XXIV 27/10/95TurkeyFYROM 22 January Article XXIV 1/9/00EFTAFYROM 31 January Article XXIV 1/1/01GeorgiaUkraine 21 February Article XXIV 4/6/96GeorgiaTurkmenistan 21 February Article XXIV 1/1/00

    GeorgiaRussia 21 February Article XXIV 10/5/94GeorgiaKazakhstan 21 February Article XXIV 16/7/99GeorgiaAzerbaijan 21 February Article XXIV 10/7/96GeorgiaArmenia 21 February Article XXIV 11/11/98MexicoIsrael 8 March Article XXIV 1/7/00ChileMexico 8 March Article XXIV 1/8/99ChileMexico 14 March GATS Art. V 1/8/99EFTAMexico 22 August GATS Art. V 1/7/01EFTAMexico 22 August Article XXIV 1/7/01New ZealandSingapore 19 September GATS Art. V 1/1/01N Z l d Si 19 S b A i l XXIV 1/1/01

    Agreement Notication Date WTO Provisions Entry into Force

    APPENDIX Continued

  • 8/12/2019 2005 - Hettne B - Beyond New Regionalism

    51/319

    944 RICHARD POMFRET

    CroatiaBosnia & Herzegovina 6 October Article XXIV 1/1/01USAChile 19 December Article XXIV 1/1/04USAChile 19 December GATS Art. V 1/1/04USASingapore 19 December Article XXIV 1/1/04USASingapore 19 December GATS Art. V 1/1/04ChinaHong Kong 12 January2004 Article XXIV 1/1/04ChinaHong Kong 12 January GATS Art. V 1/1/04ChinaMacao 12 January Article XXIV 1/1/04ChinaMacao 12 January GATS Art. V 1/1/04ECChile 18 February Article XXIV 1/2/03ChinaEl Salvador 17 March GATS Art. V 1/6/02ChinaEl Salvador 16 February Article XXIV 1/6/02CEFTA Accession (Croatia) 3 March Article XXIV 1/3/03CroatiaAlbania 31 March Article XXIV 1/6/03AlbaniaBulgaria 31 March Article XXIV 1/9/03AlbaniaKosovo 8 April Article XXIV 1/10/03KoreaChile 19 April Article XXIV 1/4/04KoreaChile 19 April GATS Art. V 1/4/04EU Enlargement 28 April GATS Art. V 1/5/04EU Enlargement 30 April Article XXIV 1/5/04ArmeniaUkraine 27 July Article XXIV 18/12/96ArmeniaKazakhstan 27 July Article XXIV 25/12/01ArmeniaMoldova 27 July Article XXIV 21/12/95ArmeniaRussia 27 July Article XXIV 25/3/93A