79e41507dc8a586239

Upload: angelgmv9492

Post on 03-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    1/18Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1321061

    Toward a model of strategic outsourcing

    Tim R. Holcomb *, Michael A. Hitt 1

    Texas A&M University, Mays Business School, Department of Management,

    College Station, TX 77843-4221, United States

    Available online 16 June 2006

    Abstract

    Acknowledging efficiency motives, firms have increasingly turned to outsourcing in an effort to capture cost savings.Transaction cost theory (TCT) has been the dominant means of explaining outsourcing as an economizing approach whereby

    cost efficiencies are achieved by assigning transactions to different governance mechanisms. Recent research has used the resource-

    based view (RBV) to examine the role of specialized capabilities as a potential source of value creation in relationships between

    firms. Although research in supply chain management has expanded substantially, only limited applications of TCTand the RBVare

    available, especially in the field of operations management. We extend both perspectives to explain conditions leading to strategic

    outsourcing.

    # 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Strategic outsourcing; Operations strategy; Resource-based view; Transaction cost theory; Resource management; Value creation;

    Operations management; Supply chain management; Capabilities; Vertical disintegration; Intermediate markets

    1. Introduction

    Understanding how firms establish firm scope has

    interested management scholars for some time, and a

    body of research has explored the boundary conditions

    firms consider when choosing to source activity from

    the marketplace (e.g. Fine and Whitney, 1999; Gilley

    and Rasheed, 2000; Quinn, 1999). In particular, this

    research highlights the complex choices firms make

    when deciding whether to internalize or outsource

    production. On the one hand, internalization requires

    firms to commit resources to a course of action, which

    may limit strategic flexibility and be difficult to reverse

    (Leiblein et al., 2002). On the other hand, internaliza-

    tion may be required by firms to more effectively carry

    out production. The complexity of these boundary

    decisions has intensified in recent years stimulated by

    increased competitive pressures, the rapidity of tech-

    nological change, and the dispersion of knowledge

    across different organizations and geographic markets

    (Hoetker, 2005; Teece, 1992). Accordingly, a variety of

    outsourcing arrangements has emerged. We rely on both

    transaction-based and resource-based logics to explain

    the emergence of one such arrangement strategic

    outsourcing in which firms rely on intermediate markets

    to provide specialized capabilities that supplement

    existing capabilities used in production.

    What determines firm scope? A well-developed

    approach for boundary decisions associated with firm

    scope is transaction cost theory (TCT). According to

    this perspective, firms integrate production to minimize

    costs from opportunism and bounded rationality of

    www.elsevier.com/locate/jomJournal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

    * Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 979 845 4852;

    fax: +1 979 845 9641.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (T.R. Holcomb),

    [email protected] (M.A. Hitt).1 Tel.: +1 979 458 3393; fax: +1 979 845 9641.

    0272-6963/$ see front matter # 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.jom.2006.05.003

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jom.2006.05.003http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jom.2006.05.003mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    2/18Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1321061

    firms and their suppliers, the uncertainty and frequency

    of market exchange, and asset specificity that arises

    from supplier-firm or firm-customer relationships

    (Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1985). This theory holds

    that certain types of governance mechanisms manage

    exchanges with particular characteristics more effi-

    ciently than others; cost economizing therefore reflectsa firms efforts to minimize costs arising from the

    governance of market exchanges.2 Accordingly, the

    decision to outsource often rests on economizing

    motives related to the fit between firms governance

    choices and specific attributes about an economic

    exchange (Grover and Malhotra, 2003; Silverman et al.,

    1997).

    Recently, however, scholars have presented

    resource-based perspectives of integration that augment

    transaction-based views and sharpen the focus on firms

    relative advantages (Combs and Ketchen, 1999;Leiblein and Miller, 2003; Poppo and Zenger, 1998).

    This growing body of work, which is based on the

    original work of Penrose (1959) and uses Barneys

    (1991) more recent translation of the resource-based

    view (RBV) of the firm, emphasizes the importance of

    resources in guiding firm activity and the management

    of a firms portfolio of capabilities as central to

    competitive advantage.3 More specifically, this research

    contends that the reasons for internalization extend

    beyond the cost of transacting through the market to the

    conditions that enable firms to establish, maintain, anduse capabilities more efficiently than markets can do

    (Conner, 1991; Ghoshal and Moran, 1996; Teece et al.,

    1997).

    The resulting convergence between these two

    theories has stimulated a number of empirical studies,

    which has created a more effective understanding of

    what drives strategic outsourcing. For example, in

    recent years, transaction cost scholars have accepted

    that transaction-based and resource-based perspectives

    deal with partly overlapping phenomena, often incomplementary ways and that capability endowments

    matter to boundary decisions (Williamson, 1999, p.

    1098). Combs and Ketchen (1999) found evidence that

    firms often place resource-based concerns ahead of

    exchange economies when deciding on potential

    interfirm cooperation. Complementary to this view,

    Madhok (2002) pursued the question of how firms

    should organize production given certain resource-

    based conditions (e.g. pre-existing strengths and

    weaknesses). He suggested that boundary decisions

    depend not only on the conditions surrounding thetransaction, but also on capability attributes, and the

    governance context that it creates. Thus, substantial

    empirical support exists for the proposition that

    capability considerations trade-off with economizing

    constraints in the decision to outsource (e.g. Hoetker,

    2005; Jacobides and Winter, 2005; Poppo and Zenger,

    1998).

    Our work contributes to this stream by extending

    earlier conceptualizations of outsourcing based on

    economizing conditions, such as asset specificity, small

    numbers bargaining, and technological uncertainty, toinclude factors that influence the selection and

    integration of capabilities from intermediate markets

    (Argyres and Liebeskind, 1999; Jacobides and Winter,

    2005). In particular, we consider the complementarity

    of capabilities, strategic relatedness, relational cap-

    ability-building mechanisms, and cooperative experi-

    ence as four important conditions that establish a

    resource-based context for strategic outsourcing.

    According to this perspective, in the decision regarding

    the strategic outsourcing of production, firms evaluate

    internally accessed capabilities and those capabilities

    available externally from intermediate markets, andconsider how they might best be integrated to produce

    the greatest value.

    Therefore, this work goes beyond the question of

    governance mechanisms to enrich our understanding of

    capability selection and use, providing a more mean-

    ingful understanding of strategic outsourcing. Whereas

    transaction-based perspectives typically confine out-

    sourcing to more specialized, repetitive activities such

    as manufacturing, logistics, and facilities management,

    resource-based theory provides a context to explain

    strategic outsourcing arrangements for more visible and

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 465

    2 There are multiple sources and aspects of transaction costs. Coase

    (1937), for example, emphasized the frictional costs, such as those

    costs that arise from negotiating, drafting, and monitoring contracts.

    Williamson (1975, 1985) expanded this perspective by focusing

    attention on the costs of transactional hazards (e.g. difficulties) and

    governance mechanisms to limit such hazards. Whereas Williamson

    focuses on the tendency of transaction difficulties to emerge as a

    function of the exchange, Coases frictional costs are a feature of

    economic conditions that occur independent of deliberate calculation

    or motives (see also Jacobides and Winter, 2005).3 Resources, broadly defined, have often been used in the literature

    in a generic sense to include capabilities (e.g. Barney, 1991). Other

    scholars have claimed that capabilities represent how firms manage

    resources (e.g. Dutta et al., 2005; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003) or that

    capabilities represent a unique combination of resources that enable

    firms to pursue specific actions that create value (Sirmon et al. in

    press). For purposes of this paper, we use resources to represent

    tangible or intangible assets owned or controlled by firms (Barney,

    1991; Grant, 1996) and capabilities to represent organizational

    routines that allow firms to effectively integrate and use resources

    to implement their strategies (Lavie, 2006; Winter, 2003).

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    3/18

    potentially sensitive functions such as research and

    development (R&D), engineering design, and customer

    support. This trend is evident in the personal computer

    (PC) and communications equipment sectors, where

    growing demand for new product offerings has driven

    the market for third-party R&D and design. As a result,

    the volume of outsourced R&D, design, and manu-facturing services in these two sectors is expected to

    grow almost two-fold between 2004 and 2009, from

    $179 billion to $345.5 billion (Carbone, 2005).

    Despite the dramatic increase in strategic out-

    sourcing in recent years, few systematic studies of

    strategic outsourcing have been completed (Gilley and

    Rasheed, 2000). In fact, this topic has received only

    limited exposure in the fields of healthcare management

    (e.g. Billi et al., 2004; Roberts, 2001), economics (e.g.

    Chen et al., 2004a; Shy and Stenbacka, 2003), and

    strategic management (e.g. Fine and Whitney, 1999;Quinn, 1999; Quinn and Hilmer, 1994). Accordingly,

    this work represents an early attempt to frame and

    provide a theoretical understanding to the strategic

    outsourcing concept in operations and supply chain

    management research using both transaction-based and

    resource-based logics.

    This work follows Grover and Malhotras (2003)

    call for more research by operations management

    scholars that integrate strategic management and

    organizational theory into the study of interfirm

    relationships. In particular, our work contributes tothe stream of research synthesizing TCT and the RBV

    by integrating them to extend earlier conceptualiza-

    tions of outsourcing. We also make three important

    contributions to the outsourcing literature. First, we

    offer a more concise definition of strategic outsourcing

    that extends transaction-based logics and considers

    value created when firms more effectively leverage the

    specialized capabilities these relationships provide.

    Second, we explain how developing a capabilities

    view better informs the discourse about the out-

    sourcing choices that firms make. Prior work has

    established a relationship between outsourcing andcost economies from the selection of more efficient

    governance mechanisms (e.g. Cachon and Harker,

    2002; Walker and Weber, 1984). However, to date,

    there has been little understanding provided of the role

    that internal and external capabilities play in strategic

    outsourcing decisions. Herein, we shift the focus on

    value creation from different exchange conditions to

    value chain structures and to theprocess by which firms

    produce goods and services. Thus, we provide

    managers with a richer framework to understand the

    trade-offs between internalization, past relationships

    and experience, and capabilities that guide their

    decision to internalize or outsource. Third, we high-

    light the expanded role that boundaries serve in the

    formation of strategic outsourcing relationships.

    Establishing firm boundaries requires understanding

    more than how internally- and externally-sourced

    production activities affect performance (Araujo et al.,2003). It also requires a better understanding of the

    bridging function that boundaries perform in linking

    firms production activity with intermediate markets

    (McEvily and Zaheer, 1999). Accordingly, we argue

    that a more complete understanding of the organization

    of economic activity requires a greater sensitivity to the

    interdependence of capabilities, production activity,

    and interfirm relations that emerge from boundary

    decisions, as suggested by Coase (1988).

    Fig. 1 summarizes our model for strategic out-

    sourcing. This model depicts conditions for valuecreation integrated with economizing arguments for

    strategic outsourcing. These theoretical arguments are

    examined in the following sections. We begin with a

    concise review of the literature and derive a more

    complete definition of strategic outsourcing. Next,

    transaction-based and resource-based arguments for

    outsourcing are reviewed. Building on these two

    perspectives, we present a model of strategic out-

    sourcing that uses transaction- and capability-based

    factors to examine a firms decision to outsource.

    Finally, we discuss opportunities for future research.

    2. Theoretical foundation

    Whereas transaction-based perspectives explain

    different governance mechanisms, resource-based

    theory considers the relative capabilities of focal

    firms and exchange partners as important in vertical

    integration decisions (e.g. Afuah, 2001; Argyres,

    1996). According to this view, firms are largely

    heterogeneous in terms of their resources and

    capabilities (e.g. Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1984),

    and thus often carry out the same activity withdifferent production efficiencies and costs. As a result,

    separate firms that display different ways of accom-

    plishing the same task achieve different cost effi-

    ciencies and performance outcomes.

    2.1. Strategic outsourcing defined

    We define strategic outsourcing as the organizing

    arrangement that emerges when firms rely on inter-

    mediate markets to provide specialized capabilities that

    supplement existing capabilities deployed along a

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481466

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    4/18

    firms value chain.4

    Further, we suggest that strategicoutsourcing creates value within firms supply chains

    beyond those achieved through cost economies. As

    explained later, intermediate markets that provide

    specialized capabilities emerge as different industry

    conditions intensify the partitioning of production. As a

    result of greater information standardization and

    simplified coordination, clear administrative demarca-

    tions emerge along a value chain (Jacobides, 2005).

    Partitioning of intermediate markets occurs as the

    coordination of production across a value chain is

    simplified and as information becomes standardized,making it easier to transfer activities across boundaries

    (Richardson, 1972). Accordingly, an orientation toward

    strategic outsourcing evolves, as specialized capabil-

    ities emerge, resulting in a greater dependence on

    intermediate markets for production (Fine and Whitney,

    1999; Quinn, 1999).

    The decision to outsource existing production

    represents the simplest form of strategic outsourcing.

    Gilley and Rasheed (2000) refer to this organizing formas substitution-based outsourcing. With substitution,

    firms discontinue internal production (e.g. the produc-

    tion of goods or services) and replace existing activities

    and/or factors of production (e.g. resources) with

    capabilities provided by intermediate markets. Accord-

    ingly, applying a capabilities perspective, we suggest

    that firm scope is partly determined by considering the

    performance differential between existing internal

    capabilities and those available in intermediate markets

    for substitution. By contrast, firms can also decide to

    outsource production a priori. Gilley and Rasheed referto this form as abstention-based outsourcing, which

    occurs when firms acquire capabilities from inter-

    mediate markets, rather than incur the necessary

    investments to internalize production. Thus, firm scope

    is also determined by examining the differential

    between the costs of internally developing new

    capabilities against accessing these capabilities in

    intermediate markets (Argyres, 1996; Langlois and

    Robertson, 1995).

    Research indicates that economizing firms often

    consider the value of their capabilities in decisions

    about internalizing an activity or conducting itthrough intermediate markets (e.g. Argyres, 1996;

    Combs and Ketchen, 1999; Hoetker, 2005). Specifi-

    cally, in deciding whether or not to internalize, firms

    often compare their capabilities with those of other

    firmsas signaled by the price and quality terms that

    exchange partners are prepared to provide (Jacobides

    and Winter, 2005). However, due in part to ambiguity

    that emerges based on imperfections in the market,

    boundedly rational agents are often unable to foresee

    potential synergies from the integration of distinctive

    capability combinations.

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 467

    Fig. 1. A theoretical model for strategic outsourcing.

    4 Avaluechain, as definedherein, consists ofthe set of value-adding

    activities within a supply chain that may be undertaken for a product

    to be made or a service to be rendered. The concept of the value chain

    was originally used to conceptualize the set of productive activities

    that occur within the boundaries of any given firm, such as research

    and development, engineering design, inbound/outbound logistics,

    marketing, etc. (see Porter, 1985). Our definition of the term is

    consistent with the general use (e.g. Porter, 1985) to mean a structured

    set of activities associated with a firms productive output, regardless

    of whether they take place within the boundaries of a single integrated

    firm or occur externally using intermediate markets. Focusing on

    distinct activities that firms perform provides an efficient way of

    examining how boundaries change and how specialized capabilities

    from intermediate markets can be leveraged to accommodate some or

    all of the activities within a value chain.

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    5/18

    An important distinction introduced herein is how

    resource-based logics influence the decision to strate-

    gically outsource more effective specialized capabilities

    along a value chain, beyond that which we know by

    examining different governance mechanisms. More

    effective capabilities can enable firms to increase

    inventory turns, shorten product development cycles,and reduce the time-to-market for new products (Clark

    and Fujimoto, 1992; Petersen et al., 2005). Stated

    differently, we contend that strategic outsourcing not

    only creates cost economies by shifting production

    activity from a focal firm to intermediate markets, but

    also creates economic value, especially when produc-

    tion involves the use of potentially more valuable

    specialized capabilities (Fine and Whitney, 1999;

    Mowery et al., 1996). Argyres (1996) was one of the

    first to provide qualitative evidence on the role of

    capabilities in internalization decisions, observing thatcapabilities are a significant driver of firm scope in the

    cable connector industry. When comparing transaction-

    and firm-level influences on firm scope, Leiblein and

    Miller (2003, p. 854) found that firm-level capabilities

    independently and significantly influence firms

    boundary decisions. Jacobides and Hitt (2005, p.

    1222) examined how capability differences shape the

    make-versus-buy decision concluding that, productive

    capabilities can and do play a major role in the

    determination of vertical scope, and account for mixed

    governance modes.

    2.2. Specialized capabilities and the emergence of

    intermediate markets

    A stream of research originally characterized as

    vertical disintegration (Stigler, 1951) helps explain

    strategic outsourcing by developing a capabilities

    view (e.g. Langlois and Robertson, 1995; Leiblein and

    Miller, 2003). According to this perspective, the

    emergence of new intermediate markets is driven

    largely by the desire of firms to pursue gains from the

    trade of specialized production. Richardson (1972) wasone of the first to suggest that boundaries were

    contingent on the different activities in which firms

    engage, the capabilities such activities require, and the

    selection and use of those capabilities along a value

    chain. Jacobides (2005) examined conditions leading to

    increased specialization. He explained the emergence of

    new intermediate markets on the basis of gains from

    intrafirm specialization that condition a market, divid-

    ing previously integrated value chains among different

    sets of specialized firms and shifting the focus on value

    creation from the final market for goods or services to

    the value chain structure and the process by which the

    good or service is produced (2005, p. 490).

    In the automobile sector, for example, advances in

    engineering and production technologies have led

    manufacturers to decouple supply chain capabilities

    giving up parts of the value chain to newly formed

    specialists in intermediate markets (Fine and Whitney,1999). Similar trends are evident in the PC and

    communications sectors, with the emergence of electro-

    nics manufacturing services (EMS) and original design

    manufacturing (ODM) firms, such as Flextronics, Hon

    Hai, Sanmina, and Compal Communications, and the

    corresponding growth of original equipment manufac-

    turersinthesesectorsthatonlymarket,butdonotdesignor

    manufacture their own equipment. In the banking sector,

    standardization and advances in information technology

    led to significant specialization of production activities

    such as application development and data processing,which enabled non-financialfirms such as IBM, EDS, and

    Accenture to become key participants in the intermediate

    market for information services. Accordingly, given

    advances in technology and standardization, new inter-

    mediate markets emerge, decomposing the value chain,

    allowing firms to acquire valuable yet specialized

    capabilities cost-effectively via the market. As a result,

    firm boundaries shift as activities that were carried out

    internally are transferred to newly formed intermediate

    markets.We thereforearguethat strategicoutsourcing not

    only allows firms to reducecosts, butalso to enhance theirportfolio of capabilities, and value creation potential,

    especiallywhenfirmsproduceuniquecombinationsusing

    capabilities provided by these markets.

    We suggest that three assumptions underlie resource-

    based views about strategic outsourcing. First, selection

    determines gains available to firms from capabilities

    accessed in the intermediate markets and then

    intensifies the effect of these capabilities on firm

    performance. Complementarity and relatedness creates

    uniquely valuable synergy, especially when specialized

    capabilities are effectively combined and when no other

    combination can replicate the resulting value chainactivities (Harrison et al., 1991, 2001; Prahalad and

    Bettis, 1986; Richardson, 1972; Tsai, 2000). To the

    extent that intermediate markets have superior cap-

    abilities that complement a firms existing capabilities,

    selection processes will combine the specialized

    internal and external capabilities. By contrast, if a firm

    possesses superior capabilities that are already inte-

    grated, selection will accommodate internalization.

    Second, strategic outsourcing relationships form

    within a social context. Ties, both direct and indirect,

    with firms in intermediate markets create a network

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481468

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    6/18

    (Uzzi, 1997), and become an important source of

    information about the reliability and performance of

    current and future exchange partners (Granovetter,

    1985). Such information helps a focal firm to learn

    about capabilities available in intermediate markets.

    Repeated ties improve trust in current and potential

    exchange partners and increase the likelihood of futurecooperation (Gulati, 1995). Accordingly, cooperative

    experience forges close bonds over time and increases

    confidence that exchange partners will pursue mutually

    compatible interests thereby reducing the probability of

    opportunism (Das and Teng, 1998), and facilitating the

    exchange of capabilities crucial for performance (Combs

    and Ketchen, 1999; Uzzi, 1996). Because strategic

    outsourcing involves coordinating the actions of two or

    more firms, cooperative experience is vital to its success.

    Third, firms enhance their ability to leverage

    specialized capabilities by developing and refiningmechanisms that strengthen the synergies such cap-

    abilities provide. We refer to these mechanisms as

    relational capability-building mechanisms (Dyer and

    Singh, 1998; Makadok, 2001), which allow firms to

    enhance the potential value of specialized capabilities

    deployed along a value chain. When purposefully

    developed, relational capability-building mechanisms

    allow firms to accumulate, integrate, and leverage

    experience over time; they are derived from previous

    capability-building actions, the results of those actions,

    and the future actions firms pursue (Fiol and Lyles,1985). From a transaction-based perspective, these

    mechanisms reduce coordination and integration costs

    and enable firms to exploit new opportunities in the

    market, especially when they develop the mechanisms

    to more effectively manage the portfolio of capabilities

    they acquire from intermediate markets. These mechan-

    isms also create causal ambiguity, obscuring the use of

    capabilities deployed across a value chain and making it

    difficult for competitors to determine a priori the

    sources of value within firms supply chains.

    In sum, we contend that specialized capabilities

    accessed by strategic outsourcing may allow firms toachieve greater performance gains. In the following two

    subsections, we briefly describe several economic

    incentives behind strategic outsourcing and contrast

    this organizing arrangement with two related concepts:

    strategic purchasing and strategic alliances.

    2.3. Economic motives and incentives behind

    strategic outsourcing

    Although previous empirical studies of outsourcing

    have produced equivocal results, there is increasing

    evidence that certain economic motives may prompt a

    firms decision to pursue this organizing form. We

    provide three possible economic motives behind strategic

    outsourcing. First, strategic outsourcing potentially

    reduces bureaucratic complexity. As firms grow, infor-

    mation asymmetries emerge (Hitt et al., 1996). Asym-

    metries produce information deficits. Informationdeficits add to the administrative demands of organizing

    transactions. Excessive bureaucratic costs associated

    with governance oversight reduce firm performance

    (DAveni and Ravenscraft, 1994; Rothaermel, Hitt and

    Jobe,inpress). In turn, these demands distract managerial

    attention from important sources of innovation and

    growth and add to the costs of internalization (DAveni

    and Ravenscraft, 1994). As transaction volumes increase,

    mobility and exit barriers form reducing strategic

    flexibility and often trapping firms in obsolescent tech-

    nologies (Harrigan, 1985). Thus, strategic outsourcinghelps firms align competing priorities, focus manage-

    ment attention on growth and innovation opportunities,

    and target resources to those tasks firms do best.

    Second, strategic outsourcing improves production

    economies, especially when firms fail to achieve

    sufficient production scale to overcome cost disadvan-

    tages (Teece, 1980). Because decisions about price and

    production are made before actual demand is observed,

    as transaction volumes vary, firms may find it difficult to

    make optimal use of available capacity or may ration

    production when existing production scale limitsactivity (Green, 1986). Strategic outsourcing allows

    firms to avoid or reduce rationing and meet production

    requirements by relying on intermediate markets as

    demand varies over time; it also provides a mechanism

    for firms to reduce uncertainty, transfer risk, and share

    scale economies with specialized firms from these

    markets. As a result, overhead is reduced, production

    costs decline, and investments in certain facilities and

    equipment are eliminated, which in turn reduces firms

    break-even points.

    Based on the considerations noted above, financial

    advantages evolve in three ways. First, firms pursuingstrategic outsourcing through substitution (Gilley and

    Rasheed, 2000) benefit from financial capital (cash)

    exchanged for internal factors of production (e.g.

    facilities, equipment, management and production

    personnel, etc.) when assets are transferred or sold to

    firms in intermediate markets. The nature and size of

    this financial capital-factor exchange often has sub-

    stantial effects on the total value of strategic out-

    sourcing deals. Second, with strategic outsourcing,

    firms can reduce or eliminate longer-term capital

    outlays to fund future investments related to the

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 469

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    7/18

    outsourced production. This allows firms to partly

    shift specific internal costs, including fixed charges,

    such as amortization and depreciation costs, to

    intermediate markets. Finally, strategic outsourcing

    can buffer firms by providing access to resources (Miner

    et al., 1990). Thus, firms reduce their exposure as

    capacity and costs are more directly linked to actualproduction output (e.g. the number of units produced).

    This allows firms to transfer the risk of changes in

    production as well as responsibility for future capital

    outlays to intermediate markets.

    Third, increases in bureaucratic complexity increase

    the coordination costs associated with different factors

    of production, especially when specialization reduces

    the degrees of freedom (Rothaermel et al., in press).

    Diminishing returns result when the loss of strategic

    flexibility and the increase in administrative costs

    outweigh the benefits of integration (Jones and Hill,1988). Accordingly, when increased specialization

    simplifies coordination across a value chain (Jacobides,

    2005), or when internal production is more efficient

    through intermediate markets, firms are more likely to

    integrate and use specialized capabilities.

    2.4. Strategic outsourcing and related concepts

    We draw a distinction between strategic outsourcing

    and strategic purchasing. Strategic purchasing refers to

    the ongoing process of soliciting, negotiating, andcontracting for the delivery of goods and services from

    suppliers (Chen et al., 2004b; Murray and Kotabe,

    1999). Key activities include procurement, supplier and

    contract management, and other related supply chain

    management actions (Salvador et al., 2002) that involve

    arms-length transactions with suppliers (Chen and

    Paulraj, 2004). Firms regularly purchase products or

    services from suppliers on a frequent or recurring

    basisfrom the procurement of production inputs to

    the purchase of supplies for office and administrative

    use (Walker and Weber, 1987). Accordingly, these

    decisions tend to be more routine and rarely involve thetransfer of resources (Chen et al., 2004a). By contrast,

    strategic outsourcing is less common, and may involve

    the transfer or sale of resources to firms in intermediate

    markets. Moreover, strategic outsourcing reflects a

    primary relational view involving linkages with

    exchange partners that provide access to specialized

    capabilities. This relational view explains performance

    gains that arise when these capabilities are configured

    along the value chain to create value that cannot be

    realized through internalization (Das and Teng, 1998;

    Sirmon et al., in press). Equating strategic outsourcing

    with the purchase of goods and services fails to capture

    full nature of this organizing form.

    We also differentiate strategic outsourcing from

    strategic alliances. Strategic alliances represent colla-

    borative arrangements that firms establish to achieve

    common goals in which benefits are ultimately shared

    by alliance partners (Inkpen, 2001). As such, inalliances, individual firm performance is a function

    of both the total value generated by the alliance and the

    share of this value each firm appropriates (Alvarez and

    Barney, 2001; Hamel, 1991). Alliances also allow

    partners to share risks and resources (Ireland et al.,

    2002), to gain access to new knowledge (Dyer and

    Singh, 1998), and to obtain access to new product

    markets (Hitt et al., 2000). By contrast, strategic

    outsourcing arrangements generally involve a focal

    firms decision to deploy specialized capabilities along

    its value chain thereby linking firm performancedirectly to the productive activities it controls. While

    alliances infer joint decision-making and shared

    residuals, strategic outsourcing primarily benefits firms

    that originate the action (Insinga and Werle, 2000) by

    allowing them to appropriate directly the residual value

    such actions create. Accordingly, outsourcing decisions

    are not based on appropriation logic per se, rather on

    economic terms defined by a focal firm after consider-

    ing the different cost/performance trade-offs.

    3. Transaction-based arguments for strategicoutsourcing

    Efficiency assumptions in TCT drive the classical

    reasoning for strategic outsourcing. With this view,

    difficulties that emerge from market-based exchanges

    generate transaction costs. Such costs include negotia-

    tion, contracting, monitoring, and enforcement costs, as

    well as costs incurred when resolving disputes. Based

    on this perspective, the performance implications of

    outsourcing and thus the decision criteria firms apply

    are based on the alignment of different governance

    structures with attributes of the exchange and theunderlying contracting environment. For example, a

    firm that selects a simple governance structure lacking

    adequate safeguards and controls is exposed to moral

    hazard and hold-up risks when the contracting

    environment is complex or when it involves transac-

    tion-specific investments (Leiblein et al., 2002). By

    contrast, selecting an excessively complex governance

    structure for a simple contracting environment unne-

    cessarily intensifies bureaucratic complexity, which

    reduces decision-making speed, decreases strategic

    flexibility, and increases overall costs (Williamson,

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481470

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    8/18

    1985). Accordingly, cost economies as a consequence

    of effective governance structures represent important

    criteria in the decision to strategically outsource. We

    briefly describe three transaction-based considerations

    for strategic outsourcing: asset specificity, small

    numbers bargaining, and technological uncertainty.

    3.1. Asset specificity

    Among the exchange conditions originally identi-

    fied by Williamson (1975), asset specificity has been

    perhaps the most robust empirically. Specific assets, in

    contrast to general purpose assets, are considered an

    obstacle to market efficiency, because they are costly

    to redeploy to alternative uses (Williamson, 1991).

    Thus, asset specificity is the principal factor giving

    rise to transaction costs. Williamson (1985) defined

    asset specificity as durable investments that are made

    in support of particular exchange transactions.

    Specific assets are investments made in specific,

    non-marketable resources and reflect the degree to

    which an asset can be redeployed to alternative uses

    and by alternative users without sacrificing productive

    value (Williamson, 1991, p. 281). Highly specific

    supply chain assets, for example, might include

    investments in facilities, equipment, personnel, and

    firm- or process-specific training associated with the

    production of goods or services that have little or no

    use outside the exchange relationship (Grover and

    Malhotra, 2003).With strategic outsourcing, one of the principal

    challenges in deciding whether to make a specific

    investment concerns the possibility that exchange

    partners might act opportunistically. Asset specificity

    creates a bilateral interdependency between the firms

    (Carney, 1998; Jones, 1983). As such, conditions of

    outsourcing often lead to one or more firms being

    locked in and increasingly vulnerable. Trading

    hazards created by the structure of the market exchange,

    in turn, produce transactions costs. Diseconomies

    related to weak incentives and monitoring costs emerge.Under these conditions, asset specificity exposes

    outsourcing firms to potential opportunism, when

    exchange partners advance their own self-interest.

    Contracting in such situations is difficult, expensive,

    and often counter-productive. Consequently, where

    resource investments by focal firms are idiosyncratic to

    an exchange relationship, interfirm cooperation is likely

    to involve internalization. Thus, we propose that:

    Proposition 1a. Requirements for firm-specific invest-

    ments by a focal firm in exchange-specific assets

    between the firm and specialized firms from intermedi-

    ate markets negatively affect the likelihood a firm will

    pursue strategic outsourcing.

    Under certain conditions, however, asset specificity

    may serve as a catalyst for interfirm cooperation. When

    firms involved in outsourcing relationships are required

    to invest collectively in the development of specificassets or new capabilities, such collaboration can form a

    reciprocal interdependency that increases the level of

    cooperation and reduces the incentive to engage in

    opportunism. These conditions reduce the costs of using

    capabilities from intermediate markets (Combs and

    Ketchen, 1999; Teece, 1992). Accordingly, in contexts

    that involve mutual investments in capabilities, colla-

    boration may encourage mutual gain, even when such

    investments result in exchange-specific assets, and thus

    increase the likelihood a firm will pursue strategic

    outsourcing. Thus, we propose that:

    Proposition 1b. Requirements for collaborative invest-

    ments in exchange-specific assets between a firm and

    specialized firms from intermediate markets positively

    affect the likelihood a firm will pursue strategic out-

    sourcing.

    3.2. Small numbers bargaining

    TCT scholars also argue that small numbers

    bargaining situations create market inefficiencies that

    create higher switching costs and increase the like-lihood of opportunistic behavior (e.g. Klein et al., 1978;

    Williamson, 1975). The possibility of opportunistic

    behavior arises when the number of specialized firms in

    intermediate markets is small, resulting in small

    numbers bargaining (Williamson, 1975). Moreover,

    the likelihood of opportunistic behavior is most severe

    when focal firms are required to make significant

    exchange-based investments because such investments

    may be subject to hold-up by external partners (Klein

    et al., 1978). Small numbers bargaining affects the

    distribution of bargaining power in outsourcing

    relationships. Bargaining power is defined as the abilityto influence the outcomes of negotiated relations

    (Bacharach and Lawler, 1981; Schelling, 1956). Firms

    with more bargaining power can obtain more favorable

    outcomes. In this case, bargaining power is important

    because it can lead specialized firms to act opportu-

    nistically in order to gain an advantage in outsourcing

    relationships. Thus, small numbers bargaining reduces

    the likelihood firms will pursue outsourcing.

    Moreover, when the degree of competitiveness

    within intermediate markets is low (e.g. small number

    of specialized firms), specialized firms acting oppor-

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 471

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    9/18

    tunistically may be less willing to share costs caused by

    changes in production volume or design specifications,

    thereby increasing transaction costs for a focal firm

    (Walker and Weber, 1987). By contrast, the higher the

    degree of competitiveness in an intermediate market,

    the more likely that partners will collaborate to share

    scale economies by leveraging adjustment costs acrosscustomers (Walker and Weber, 1984). Such economies

    dampen opportunistic bargaining, reduce potential

    transaction costs, and therefore provide a stronger

    incentive for firms to outsource. Accordingly, the

    greater the density of specialized firms, the lower a focal

    firms exposure to small numbers bargaining, and the

    more likely that strategic outsourcing will emerge.

    Thus, we propose that:

    Proposition 2. The number of specialized firms from

    intermediate markets is positively related to the like-

    lihood a firm will pursue strategic outsourcing.

    3.3. Technological uncertainty

    Technological uncertainty refers to unanticipated

    changes in circumstances surrounding technology, i.e.,

    new generations of technology that render existing

    technology obsolete (Folta, 1998; Robertson and

    Gatignon, 1998). Broadly defined, technology repre-

    sents theoretical and practical knowledge, skills,

    production and supply chain systems, and relatedartifacts that can be deployed along a firms value chain

    to develop goods and services (Burgelman et al., 1996).

    Changes in technology create new complexities for

    structuring value chain activities, especially when new

    knowledge is applied at a faster rate reducing the time

    between innovations (Song and Montoya-Weiss, 2001).

    In the presence of technological uncertainty, greater

    resource commitments produce more exposure to

    negative shocks. Thus, relative to arrangements that

    provide on-demand access to capabilities through

    intermediate markets, technological uncertainty may

    serve as a disincentive to internalize because it oftenrequires greater resource commitments.

    These conditions may prompt firms to pursue

    strategic outsourcing to reduce their exposure to

    unforeseen contingencies and to improve financial

    and operational stability and predictability. Schoon-

    hoven (1981, pp. 355356) found that destandardiza-

    tion and decentralization of task execution had

    positive effects on firm performance under conditions of

    technological uncertainty. Harrigan (1985, 1986)

    argued that increases in technological uncertainty

    may lead firms to use less firm-specific resources. As

    a consequence, internalization is likely to decrease in

    the long-run, because strategic outsourcing allows firms

    to partly transfer the risk of task variability to the

    intermediate markets. Specialized firms in these

    markets may be better able to achieve cost efficiencies

    that are difficult for focal firms to achieve by balancing

    task requirements across multiple customers. Astechnological uncertainty increases, internal economies

    of specialization deteriorate in relation to the external

    economies of specialized firms (Teece, 1980). As such,

    strategic outsourcing not only can provide scale

    economies during periods of technological uncertainty,

    but may also act as a coping strategy helping to deal

    with risk. From this perspective, strategic outsourcing

    provides more predictable and orderly patterns of

    exchange within and between firms.

    However, at higher levels of technological uncer-

    tainty, larger information deficits increase the likelihoodfor opportunism, making it costly to handle exchanges

    through intermediate markets. These asymmetries

    reduce the ability to foresee potential contingencies

    that may occur in the future making it costly to write,

    monitor, and enforce complete contracts (Grossman and

    Hart, 1986). As a result, parties to such exchanges are

    more likely to regularly renegotiate the terms of their

    relationship, which increases the likelihood of oppor-

    tunism. At increasingly higher levels of uncertainty,

    greater information deficits emerge, reducing cost

    economies and increasing the difficulty of interfirmcollaboration. Reductions in cost economies lead to

    diminishing returns. At higher levels of technological

    uncertainty, firms find it difficult to accurately predict a

    priori the combination of possible events and outcomes

    that are likely to emerge from production (March and

    Simon, 1958). Thus, beyond a certain level of

    technological uncertainty, we expect this relationship

    to be negative. Specifically, we propose that:

    Proposition 3. Technological uncertainty will have a

    non-linear (inverse U-shaped) effect on the likelihood a

    firm will pursue strategic outsourcing, with the slopepositive at low and moderate levels of technological

    uncertainty but negative at high levels of technological

    uncertainty.

    3.4. Critique of transaction-based arguments for

    strategic outsourcing

    While providing a number of important insights

    regarding the most efficient means to govern a

    particular economic exchange (Grover and Malhotra,

    2003), TCT generally involves a set of restrictive

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481472

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    10/18

    assumptions that ignore the potential influence of a

    firms extant governance forms, its portfolio of

    exchange transactions, and other firm-specific capabil-

    ities on value created through value chain activities.

    Thus, in equilibrium, TCT implies that all firms facing a

    similar set of exchange conditions and transactional

    attributes will reach similar conclusions regardingwhich activities to internalize and which activities to

    outsource (Leiblein and Miller, 2003). However, this

    proposition is untenable. Comparisons of internaliza-

    tion decisions across firms in the same industry suggest

    that the internalization decisions often differ dramati-

    cally. For instance, while companies such as IBM and

    Nokia have remained historically integrated, other

    companies such as Dell, HP, Ericsson, and Motorola

    outsource a variety of production functions ranging

    from R&D and engineering design to manufacturing

    and logistics. Moreover, variance in performance withinand between these two groups of firms suggests a more

    complex set of factors affect the decision to outsource.

    Thus, using economizing motives alone limits the

    quality of discourse about the decision to outsource. In

    the following section, we extend the conceptual

    orientation of strategic outsourcing to consider

    resource-based factors.

    4. Resource-based arguments for strategic

    outsourcing

    Drawing on the RBV, we extend transaction-based

    perspectives of strategic outsourcing by focusing

    attention on the role of specialized capabilities obtained

    through intermediate markets. This approach, however,

    requires a refinement in the traditional role of

    boundaries. In particular, while conventional

    approaches to boundary conditions emphasize bound-

    aries as an economizing buffer to environmental

    contingencies (Araujo et al., 2003), boundaries also

    act as a bridge to intermediate markets through

    relationship ties formed by a focal firm. In other

    words, boundaries integrate as well as separate a firmfrom its environment. In this work, we define bridging

    as the process by which firms establish linkages with

    intermediate markets, suggesting that new capabilities

    may be obtained through relationships established

    within and across a firms relationship network (e.g.

    Burt, 1992; Granovetter, 1973). Herein, our focus is on

    the specialized capabilities provided through these

    relationships.

    The ability to access new and potentially more

    valuable capabilities is a critical driver of strategic

    outsourcing because these actions can fundamentally

    alter a firms capability endowments (Morrow et al.,

    2005), making it easier to pursue new opportunities in

    the market. We maintain that different conditions affect

    the value of capabilities sourced from intermediate

    markets. In particular, we briefly describe four resource-

    based considerations for strategic outsourcing: com-

    plementarity of capabilities, strategic relatedness,relational capability-building mechanisms, and coop-

    erative experience.

    4.1. Complementarity of capabilities

    Beginning with Penrose (1959), strategy scholars

    have proposed that firms enhance value chain perfor-

    mance when they align with exchange partners in order

    to access complementary capabilities (e.g. Harrison

    et al., 1991; Rothaermel, 2001; Teece, 1986). Applied to

    strategic outsourcing, this argument suggests that firmsseek ties with specialized firms that possess capabilities

    beneficial to and needed by a focal firm. Such

    capabilities may be required to replace existing

    capabilities deployed along a value chain (e.g.

    substitution-based outsourcing) or to fulfill a specific

    need not currently available in a firm (e.g. abstention-

    based outsourcing).

    Capability complementarity reflects a situation in

    which specialized capabilities enhance the value

    creation potential of a focal firms own capability

    endowments. Complementary capabilities are differ-ent, yet mutually supportive (Luo, 2002a; Hitt et al.,

    2001). Richardson (1972) suggests that capabilities

    are complementary when they represent different

    phases of production and require in some way or

    another to be coordinated in order to create

    maximum value (Richardson, 1972, p. 889). Where

    complementarities exist, the integration of internal

    and external capabilities enhances the potential

    performance gains firms realize, especially when

    economies of scope in production increase their

    market power (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992). When

    complementary capabilities are idiosyncratic andindivisible, and thus not otherwise available in the

    factor markets (Barney, 1986), strategic outsourcing

    can provide access to them.

    When complementary capabilities are linked

    together, they are especially difficult for competitors

    to duplicate because imitation not only requires

    obtaining the capabilities from intermediate markets,

    but also duplicating their deployment along a value

    chain (Holcomb et al., 2006). Barney (1988) suggested

    that acquiring firms gain above normal returns from

    acquisitions only when private or uniquely valuable

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 473

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    11/18

    synergies can be realized. Private and uniquely valuable

    synergy is created when information about the

    combination is obscured from rivals and when no other

    combination of firms could produce the same value.

    Research suggests that firms participating in exchange

    relationships that involve complementary capabilities

    perform better than firms with relationships that areformed to achieve cost economies (Harrison et al.,

    2001; Holcomb et al., 2006). Chung et al. (2000) also

    found the likelihood of alliance formation was

    positively related to the complementarity of investment

    banks capabilities. Similarly, other research suggests

    that firms consider the potential for complementarity an

    important partner selection criterion (Hitt et al., 2000,

    2004).

    Different but complementary resources can help a

    firm improve scale economies, enhance responsiveness

    and innovative potential, and increase quality. Further-more, because complementary capabilities are gener-

    ally relationship-specific (Dyer and Singh, 1998), the

    value created may be unavailable to rivals through

    alternative sources (e.g. private; Barney, 1988), which

    may create a sustainable competitive advantage. Thus,

    strategic outsourcing relationships are more important

    to value-creating activities when these relationships

    provide specialized capabilities that are complementary

    to those currently held by a firm, especially when the

    integration of those capabilities across a value chain

    create private and uniquely valuable synergy. From theresource-based perspective, firm scope then is deter-

    mined by the limits in specialization and the need to

    maximize gains from the combination of complemen-

    tary capabilities along a value chain.

    By applying this logic, we argue that strategic

    outsourcing is a likely alternative when benefits from

    specialized capabilities accessed from intermediate

    markets are based on complementarity. A complemen-

    tarity perspective for strategic outsourcing suggests that

    a firm will ally with partners in whom the greatest

    complementarity exists between the firms capability

    endowments and those held by partners in intermediatemarkets. Thus, we conclude that the complementarity of

    capability endowments between a firm and its exchange

    partners has a positive effect on the likelihood the firm

    will pursue strategic outsourcing. Specifically, we

    propose that:

    Proposition 4. The extent of complementarity that

    exists between a firms existing capability endowment

    and capabilities available from intermediate markets

    positively affects the likelihood a firm will pursue

    strategic outsourcing.

    4.2. Strategic relatedness

    Strategic relatedness characterizes the degree to

    which firms are strategically similar; it reflects the

    extent to which firms produce similar goods and

    services, serve similar markets, utilize similar produc-

    tion and supply chain systems, or rely on similartechnologies. Relatedness provides a rationale for

    capability-sharing between firms (Prahalad and Bettis,

    1986; Rumelt, 1974; Tsai, 2000). We expand this view

    of relatedness to include goal congruence and the

    commonality of knowledge-sharing routines. A high

    degree of relatedness between a firm and its exchange

    partners implies that they share common goals and are

    able to transfer knowledge between them more

    effectively. Accordingly, strategic relatedness is an

    important factor in a firms decision to pursue strategic

    outsourcing.Goal congruence is the degree to which firms

    operational, strategic, and performance objectives

    overlap and/or reinforce one another. When firms

    goals are not congruent, performance considered

    satisfactory to a focal firm may not be satisfactory to

    exchange partners and vice versa. Likewise, behavior

    promoting the interests of a focal firm may not promote

    the interests of those partners (Luo, 2002b). The

    presence of congruent goals helps to resolve these

    potential concerns. Despite the importance of goal

    congruity for success in exchange relationships (Luo,2002a), evidence suggests a lack of goal congruity in

    many such relationships. As profit-maximizing goals

    are aligned, strategic outsourcing not only reduces

    monitoring and enforcement costs associated with the

    arrangement but also increases synergies as well. When

    goals are aligned, specialized firms are more likely to

    share common interests with a focal firm and thus be

    more supportive of exploiting new opportunities, even if

    such opportunities require these firms make additional

    investments. These synergies enable firms with com-

    mon goals to more quickly exploit competitive

    imperfections observed in the market (Mahoney andPandian, 1992), and thus hold the potential to create

    value beyond cost savings alone.

    Goal congruency also reduces conflict and

    encourages cooperative behavior (Parkhe, 1993). Thus,

    firms with exchange partners that share congruent goals

    find it easier to collaborate thereby enhancing the value

    of these relationships. Moreover, congruent goals

    improve the quality of relationships with exchange

    partners, which reduce the probability of opportunism

    (Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1996). With the threat of

    opportunism reduced, exchange partners may be more

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481474

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    12/18

    willing to make additional resources available. Finally,

    congruent goals can reduce the need for formal

    contractual arrangements (Dyer and Singh, 1998).

    These informal agreements in turn promote adaptability

    and reduce the need for formal governance mechanisms

    (Uzzi, 1997). Thus, costs are reduced to the extent that

    less monitoring and enforcement is required.By contrast, incongruent goals often lead to the

    development of sub-goals, which exchange partners

    may pursue at the expense of a focal firm (Williamson,

    1975). Incongruent goals also impede cooperation, limit

    the exchange of resources between exchange partners

    (Luo, 2002a), and can lead to early termination of these

    relationships. Furthermore, in the presence of incon-

    gruent goals, the time and energy spent resolving

    disputes detract from developing and implementing

    innovative strategies and can prevent valuable strategies

    from emerging. Incongruent goals therefore make itdifficult to leverage specialized capabilities accessed by

    firms through strategic outsourcing. Thus, we argue that

    goal congruency affects the likelihood a firm will

    pursue capabilities from intermediate markets through

    strategic outsourcing. Specifically, we propose that:

    Proposition 5a. Goal congruency between a firm and

    specialized firms from intermediate markets positively

    affect the likelihood a firm will pursue strategic out-

    sourcing.

    A high degree of strategic relatedness also results

    when focal firms and specialized firms share common or

    similar knowledge-sharing routines (Dyer and Singh,

    1998). We define knowledge-sharing routines as regular

    patterns of interactions that permit the transfer,

    assimilation, and integration of new knowledge (Grant,

    1996). The advantage of such routines lies in the ability

    to economize effort, which reduces coordination costs

    and affords greater capacity for knowledge-sharing

    between firms.

    Common knowledge-sharing routines may emerge

    as new intermediate markets are formed by increasing

    specialization within an industry (Jacobides, 2005). Forexample, with the emergence of intermediate markets

    specializing in information services, firms have

    increasingly transferred in-house computing systems

    resourcesi.e., programming and data center opera-

    tions personnel, computer hardware, and enterprise

    application software as well as software design and

    programming processes and methodologiesto firms

    in these markets (e.g. EDS, IBM, and Accenture) who

    integrate and use these resources. As a result of these

    transfers, focal firms commonly share routines with

    their partners, which facilitates knowledge-sharing.

    Further, because firms within an industry often share

    common knowledge structures, the emergence of

    vertically specialized markets in an industry increases

    the likelihood they will share common knowledge-

    sharing routines. Accordingly, the emergence of

    intermediate markets increases the diffusion of knowl-

    edge and thus increases the probability of strategicoutsourcing in an industry.

    Various scholars have argued that interorganizational

    learning is also critical to competitive success, noting

    that firms partners are, in many cases, the most

    important sources of new knowledge (Powell et al.,

    1996; Von Hippel, 1988). Common knowledge-sharing

    routines between a firm and its exchange partners

    enable more efficient absorption and use of acquired

    knowledge (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Absorptive

    capacity includes relationship-specific capabilities,

    such as knowledge-sharing routines, that arise whenfirms develop mutually specialized ways of exploiting

    each others capabilities. Dyer and Singh (1998) define

    partner-specific absorptive knowledge as a function of

    (1) the extent to which firms develop overlapping

    knowledge bases, and (2) the extent to which partners

    develop routines that maximize the benefit of their

    interactions. In sum, we conclude that effective

    knowledge-sharing routines are crucial to the exploita-

    tion of intermediate markets and thus affect the

    likelihood firms will pursue strategic outsourcing.

    Thus, we propose that:Proposition 5b. Commonality of knowledge-sharing

    routines between a firm and specialized firms from

    intermediate markets positively affects the likelihood

    a firm will pursue strategic outsourcing.

    4.3. Relational capability-building mechanisms

    Evidence suggests that firm performance is affected

    by its abilities to integrate, build, and reconfigure

    resources. This process is referred to as dynamic

    capabilities (Teece et al., 1997). According to Loasby(1998, p. 139), managing capabilities is itself a

    capability; that is, firms develop capabilities over time

    that help them develop and link productive capabilities

    across a value chain. In particular, dynamic capabilities

    have been used to explain why firms in the same industry

    perform differently. For example, Helfat and Peteraf

    (2003) suggest that dynamic capabilities are embedded

    within firms and consist as a set of specific and

    identifiable strategic and organizational routines. We

    usethe work on the dynamic capabilities(e.g.Teece et al.,

    1997; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003) to define relational

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 475

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    13/18

    capability-building mechanisms as routines that allow

    firms to synthesize and leverage specialized capabilities

    (Dyer and Singh, 1998; Makadok, 2001). Our view of

    these mechanisms also complements recombinatory

    (e.g. Galunic and Rodan, 1998; Grant, 1996; Kogut and

    Zander, 1992) views of capabilities, which emphasize the

    manipulation of competences residing within the firm.Accordingly, these mechanisms improve a firms ability

    to accumulate, integrate, and leverage specialized

    capabilities across a value chain, and affect its ability

    to pursue new opportunities in the future.

    Relational capability-building mechanisms also act as

    a focal point for learning andleveragingexperiencesfrom

    past capability-building actions, the results of those

    actions, and the firms future actions (Fiol and Lyles,

    1985). They represent a more systematic and routine

    implementation of dedicated processes that support

    production activity involving the use of specializedcapabilities. For example, Kale et al. (2002) found that

    firms with a dedicated capability to manage interfirm

    relationships generated substantially higher market value

    than firms without such capability. Stated differently,

    firmsthatsystematicallyinvestindevelopingtheabilityto

    manage interfirm relationships consistently perform

    better than others that choose not to make such

    investments. Zollo and Singh (2004)found that dedicated

    processesinwhichfirmsaccumulateandexplicitlycodify

    acquisition experience significantly improved overall

    acquisition performance by counteracting the coordina-tion problems that future contingencies create. Accord-

    ingly, we expect investments in development of relational

    capability-buildingmechanisms willreduce coordination

    andintegration costs, andimprove the synergistic benefits

    available through strategic outsourcing.

    In sum, relational capability-building mechanisms

    not only enable firms to generate greater value

    (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992; Makadok, 2001), but

    also create additional ambiguity that allow firms to

    sustain certain advantages over time (Rumelt, 1984).

    Under these conditions, we expect relational capability-

    building mechanisms to directly affect the likelihoodfirms pursue strategic outsourcing. Accordingly, we

    propose that:

    Proposition 6. Relational capability-building mechan-

    isms positively affect the likelihood a firm will pursue

    strategic outsourcing.

    4.4. Cooperative experience

    Strategic outsourcing relationships are formed

    within a social context that influences selection

    decisions and the pattern of interfirm linkages that

    emerge. We represent cooperative experience as

    repeated ties, direct and indirect, formed with specia-

    lized firms from intermediate markets. Repeated ties

    with these firms create a pattern of relationships in

    which focal firms can access information about the

    reliability and performance of current and futurepartners (Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1997). These ties

    reduce information asymmetries, heighten awareness

    about specialized capabilities and firms from inter-

    mediate markets, and establish a basis for trust. In turn,

    trust enhances the potential benefits of strategic

    outsourcing by reducing the risk of adverse selection

    and improving the level of collaboration once such

    relationships are established. Herein, we define trust as

    a firms confidence in the reliability of a specialized firm

    to fulfill its obligations and act fairly when the

    possibility for opportunism is present. Zaheer et al.(1998) found that organizational trust formed by

    repeated market exchanges is an important driver of

    interfirm relationships because it enhances overall

    performance, decreases the complexity and costs of

    negotiation processes, and reduces conflict. Examining

    international joint ventures (IJVs), Luo (2002b) found

    that cooperation had a linear effect on IJV performance,

    especially at higher levels of contract term specificity

    and contingency adaptability, which represents the

    extent to which unanticipated contingencies are

    accounted for and the guidelines for handling suchcontingencies are specified in a contract. We suggest

    that a focal firms cooperative experience with

    specialized firms reduces information asymmetry and

    opportunistic behavior, and thus enhances the potential

    benefits of strategic outsourcing. Accordingly, coop-

    erative experience increases the likelihood that addi-

    tional outsourcing arrangements will be pursued with

    these firms in the future.

    Whereas, according to the transaction-based view,

    interfirm cooperation occurs only when the costs of

    governing production can be minimized, the resource-

    based perspective suggests that firms share capabilities inorder to stimulate growth (Combs and Ketchen, 1999).

    As such, cooperation represents the willingness of a

    partner firm to pursue mutually compatible interests . . .

    ratherthan act opportunistically (Das andTeng, 1998, p.

    492). Because market exchanges are embedded in a

    social context, the governance of interfirm exchanges

    involve more than contracts; they depend on the level of

    cooperation between the firm and its partners (Luo,

    2002b). For such relationally-governed exchanges, the

    enforcement of obligations, promises, and expectations

    involves social processes that promote norms of

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481476

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    14/18

    adaptation and information exchange. The significance

    of cooperative experience is reflected in the paradox that

    results: firms are expected to pursue strategies and

    programs that best serve their interests; however,

    interfirm relationships require simultaneous investment

    and restraint in order for each party to gain maximum

    value from the relationship (cf. Das and Teng, 1998).The pattern of cooperation that emerges when

    intermediate markets form around specialized capabil-

    ities (Jacobides, 2005; Richardson, 1972) encourages

    firms to engage in repeated exchanges, especially as these

    markets mature improving accessibility to specialized

    capabilities. Repeated ties with specialized firms

    improve trust and increase the likelihood of future

    cooperation (Gulati, 1995). This pattern of connections

    broadens the firms scope and also affects the nature of

    ongoing capability development processes (Araujo et al.,

    2003; Jacobides and Winter, 2005), i.e., the way in whicha firm shapes or improves its value chain over time.

    Changes in capabilities then reshape intermediate

    markets, allowing additional firms to participate. These

    changes facilitate growth in the number of potential

    suppliers but also increase the complexity of the selection

    and coordination process. Cooperative experience

    provides knowledge that helps in selecting and coordi-

    nating specialized capabilities in which relationship ties

    serve as a valuable conduit for rich information.

    Previous cooperation, defined in terms of both the

    length and quality of the exchange relationship, fostersa climate of trust, openness and confidence. Repeated

    interactions or cycles of exchange between parties

    strengthen their willingness to trust each other and to

    expand the boundaries the relationship (Rousseau et al.,

    1998). Over time, such relationships become integrated

    into the social context that develops between firms,

    which fosters knowledge-sharing, supports adaptability,

    and deters opportunism. In so doing, the synergy from

    exchange relationships is magnified. Specifically,

    exchange relationships based on trust are more likely

    to exploit market opportunities requiring access to

    resources from exchange partners. Such relationshipsare more likely to result in collaborative efforts to

    exploit emerging opportunities in the market. We

    conclude that cooperative experience affects the like-

    lihood firms will pursue strategic outsourcing. Thus, we

    propose that:

    Proposition 7. Cooperative experience between a firm

    and specialized firms from intermediate markets,

    defined by the length and the quality of previous rela-

    tionships, positively affects the likelihood a focal firm

    will pursue strategic outsourcing.

    5. Discussion and conclusion

    The dominant goal most often cited for strategic

    outsourcing is cost efficiency. According to this

    perspective, firms internalize value chain activity to

    minimize costs from opportunism and bounded

    rationality, the uncertainty of frequent marketexchanges, and specific assets that may arise from this

    organizing arrangement. This rationale, in part, holds

    that specific governance mechanisms used to manage

    certain exchanges are more efficient and reflects the

    view of firm boundaries as the point at which resource

    owners relinquish control over access and use.

    Accordingly, transaction-based perspectives develop

    logic for strategic outsourcing on the basis of

    economizing motives linking governance choices to

    attributes of an exchange.

    The restrictive assumptions offered by TCT suggestthat, in equilibrium, firms with similar exchange

    conditions will make the same decisions about strategic

    outsourcing. However, the arguments presented herein

    show this proposition to be incomplete. Strategic

    outsourcing enables firms to bridge boundaries and

    access capabilities from intermediate markets that are

    subsequently deployed along the value chain. Accord-

    ing to the RBV, resource heterogeneity leads to

    otherwise similar firms displaying significantly differ-

    ent ways of accomplishing the same set of value chain

    activities, emboldened by the use of different capabil-ities. We argued that by linking value chain activities

    with intermediate markets for the purpose of gaining

    access to valuable specialized capabilities, firms can

    accrue value beyond the cost economies available

    through more efficient governance mechanisms. Thus,

    we augmented transaction-based arguments with

    resource-based perspectives to sharpen the focus on

    conditions that might favor the use of specialized

    capabilities.

    The purpose of this work has been to extend our

    understanding of strategic outsourcing by integrating

    transaction-based and resource-based logics. First, weoffered a more concise definition of strategic out-

    sourcing and extended the focus on cost economies

    resulting from more efficient governance mechanisms

    to consider value that is created when firms more

    effectively leverage the specialized capabilities that

    outsourcing relationships provide. An important dis-

    tinction introduced herein is how firms understanding

    of their capabilities and those of specialized firms affect

    their decision to strategically outsource. We also

    showed how the emergence of new intermediate

    markets (e.g. vertical disintegration; Jacobides, 2005;

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 477

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    15/18

    Richardson, 1972) provides a theoretical framework

    explaining the logic for a capabilities view of strategic

    outsourcing. In particular, we shift the focus on value

    creation from different exchange conditions to value

    chain structures and to the process by which firms

    produce goods and services. Accordingly, intermediate

    markets that maintain specialized capabilities emerge asconditions within an industry intensify the partitioning

    of production activity. As a result, boundaries shift to

    accommodate access to specialized capabilities that are

    then deployed along a firms value chain.

    Second, we extended the view of boundaries as

    providing a bridge between firms and intermediate

    markets (Araujo et al., 2003) to explain how value chain

    linkages are enabled through strategic outsourcing. On

    the one hand, boundaries provide a space for the

    development of valuable and difficult-to-imitate cap-

    abilities within the firmthe buffering function. On theother hand, boundaries provide a bridge to access

    specialized capabilities outside the control of the firm.

    While TCT generally establishes firm boundaries on the

    basis of anticipated efficiencies, our extended model of

    strategic outsourcing accommodates a view of bound-

    aries in which firms join with exchange partners to

    create synergies they cannot realize alone.

    This extended model of strategic outsourcing

    suggests several research questions worthy of further

    investigation. First, we still know very little about the

    process by which specialized capabilities are deployedand integrated along a value chain. For example, how do

    firms integrate specialized capabilities along the value

    chain? What performance measures best reflect

    synergies created by the use of specialized capabilities

    across the value chain? Although exchange transactions

    through the market can often be economized, value

    derived from strategic outsourcing lies more in the

    combinative value of specialized capabilities available

    through intermediate markets. Thus, scholars should

    closely examine the underlying processes involved with

    integration and measurement of specialized capabilities

    along a value chain.Second, our understanding of the sources of value

    creation is limited. Do focal firms pursuing outsourcing

    benefit more by selecting valuable capabilities from

    intermediate markets or by more effectively integrating

    these capabilities in difficult-to-imitate ways? Using our

    model of strategic outsourcing, for example, scholars

    can evaluate Makadoks (2001) assertions regarding

    synergies from the two main sources of rent genera-

    tionresource-picking and capability-building

    within a strategic outsourcing context. According to

    this perspective, specialized capabilities affect firm

    performance by enhancing the productivity of other

    capabilities that firms possess.

    Finally, as strategic outsourcing arrangements con-

    tinue to expand in scope and complexity, scholars

    should more closely examine specific attributes of

    outsourcing deals, especially when such deals involve

    the divestment of assets by a focal firm as part of theexchange. In some cases, these arrangements involve

    the exchange of substantial financial considerations for

    assets controlled by a focal firm. Where is value created

    (and lost) by focal firms and intermediate markets? How

    do financial considerations affect focal firms decision

    to outsource? What are the implementation challenges?

    How do investors view these arrangements? Thus,

    research that provides a more comprehensive view of

    strategic outsourcing deals and anticipates aggregate

    economic considerations is needed.

    The value-creating potential of the firm is at the heartof the theory of the firm. Adopting a model of strategic

    outsourcing can help scholars and practitioners to

    understand the strategic, operational, and financial

    motivations and incentives behind this organizing

    arrangement. If outsourcing is pursued strategically,

    firms can achieve above normal returns. Examining the

    different conditions in which value creation occurs can

    extend managements view of strategic outsourcing and

    provide a new paradigm for supply chain practitioners

    to demonstrate the practical benefits of strategic

    outsourcing.

    Acknowledgements

    We thank David Ketchen, Tomas Hult, and the two

    anonymous reviewers for their helpful suggestions. We

    also benefited from valuable comments and suggestions

    by Sharon Alvarez, Lorraine Eden, and Michael Holmes

    on earlier drafts of this article.

    References

    Afuah, A., 2001. Dynamic boundaries of the firm: are firms better off

    being vertically integrated in the face of a technological change?

    Academy of Management Journal 44 (6), 12111228.

    Alvarez, S.A., Barney, J.B., 2001. How entrepreneurial firms can

    benefit from alliances with large partners. Academy of Manage-

    ment Executive 15 (1), 139148.

    Araujo, L., Dubois, A., Gadde, L.E., 2003. The multiple boundaries of

    the firm. Journal of Management Studies 40 (5), 12551277.

    Argyres, N., 1996. Evidence on the role of firm capabilities in vertical

    integration decisions. Strategic Management Journal 17 (2), 129

    150.

    Argyres, N.S., Liebeskind, J.P., 1999. Contractual commitments,

    bargaining power, and governance inseparability: incorporating

    T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481478

  • 7/28/2019 79e41507dc8a586239

    16/18

    history into transaction cost theory. Academy of Management

    Review 24 (1), 4963.

    Bacharach, S.B., Lawler, E.J., 1981. Bargaining: Power, Tactics, and

    Outcomes. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco.

    Barney, J.B., 1986. Strategic factor markets: expectations, luck and

    business strategy. Management Science 32 (10), 12301241.

    Barney, J.B., 1988. Returns to bidding firms in mergers and acquisi-

    tions: reconsidering the relatedness hypothesis. Strategic Manage-ment Journal 9, 7178.

    Barney, J.B., 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advan-

    tage. Journal of Management 17 (1), 99120.

    Billi, J.E., Pai, C.W., Spahlinger, D.A., 2004. Strategic outsourcing of

    clinical services: a model for volume-stressed academic medical

    centers. Health Care Management Review 29 (4), 291297.

    Burgelman, R.A., Maidique, M.A., Wheelwright, S.C., 1996. Strate-

    gic Management of Technology and Innovation, 2nd ed. Irwin,

    Burr Ridge, IL.

    Burt, R.S., 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competi-

    tion. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.

    Cachon, G.P., Harker, P.T., 2002. Competition and outsourcing with

    scale economies. Management Science 48 (10), 13141333.

    Carbone, J., 2005. EMS profits get squeezed. Purchasing 134, 2933.

    Carney, H., 1998. The competitiveness of networked production: the

    role of trust and asset specificity. Journal of Management Studies

    35 (4), 457479.

    Chen, I.J., Paulraj, A., 2004. Towards a theory of supply chain

    management: the constructs and measurements. Journal of Opera-

    tions Management 22 (2), 119150.

    Chen, I.J., Paulraj, A., Lado, A.A., 2004a. Strategic purchasing,

    supply management, and firm performance. Journal of Operations

    Management 22 (5), 505523.

    Chen, Y.M., Ishikawa, J., Yu, Z.H., 2004b. Trade liberalization and

    strategic outsourcing. Journal of International Economics 63 (2),

    419436.

    Chung, S., Singh, H., Lee, K., 2000. Complementarity, status simi-larity and social capital as drivers of alliance formation. Strategic

    Management Journal 21 (1), 122.

    Clark, K.B., Fujimoto, T., 1992. Product Development Performance.

    Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA.

    Coase, R.H., 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 4 (16), 386405.

    Coase, R.H., 1988. The nature of the firm: influence. Journal of Law,

    Economics, and Organization 4 (1), 3347.

    Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new

    perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science

    Quarterly 35 (1), 128152.

    Combs, J.G., Ketchen, D.J., 1999. Explaining interfirm cooperation

    and performance: toward a reconciliation of predictions from the

    resource-based view and organizational economics. Strategic

    Management Journal 20 (9), 867888.Conner, K.R., 1991. A historical comparison of resource-based theory

    and 5 schools of thought within industrial organization economics:

    do we have a new theory of the firm. Journal of Management 17

    (1), 121154.

    DAveni, R.A., Ravenscraft, D.J., 1994. Economies of integration

    versus bureaucracy costs: does vertical integration improve per-

    formance. Academy of Management Journal 37 (5), 11671206.

    Das, T.K., Teng, B.S., 1998. Between trust and control: developing

    confidence in partner cooperation in alliances. Academy of Man-

    agement Review 23 (3), 491512.

    Dutta, S., Narasimhan, O., Rajiv, S., 2005. Conceptualizing and

    measuring capabilities: methodology and empirical application.

    Strategic Management Journal 26 (3), 277285.

    Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative strategy

    and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Acad-

    emy of Managemsent Review 23 (4), 660679.

    Fine, C.H., Whitney, D.E., 1999. Is the make-buy decision a core

    competence? In: Muffato, M., Pawar, K. (Eds.), Logistics in the

    Information Age, Servizi Grafici Editoriali. Pandova, Italy, pp.

    3163.

    Fiol, C.M., Lyles, M.A., 1985. Organizational learning. Academy ofManagement Review 10 (4), 803813.

    Folta, T.B., 1998. Governance and uncertainty: the trade-off between

    administrative control and commitment. Strategic Management

    Journal 19 (11), 10071028.

    Galunic, D.C., Rodan, S., 1998. Resource recombinations in the firm:

    knowledge structures and the potential for Schumpeterian innova-

    tion. Strategic Management Journal 19 (12), 11931201.

    Ghoshal, S., Moran, P., 1