a class of heath-jarrow-morton

Upload: ben-salah-mouna

Post on 03-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    1/22

    A CLASS OF HEATH-JARROW-MORTON TERM STRUCTURE MODELS

    WITH STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY

    CARL CHIARELLA AND OH KANG KWON

    School of Finance and EconomicsUniversity of Technology Sydney

    PO Box 123

    Broadway NSW 2007

    Australia

    [email protected]

    [email protected]

    ABSTRACT. This paper considers a class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton term structure mod-

    els with stochastic volatility. These models admit transformations to Markovian sys-

    tems, and consequently lend themselves to well-established solution techniques for the

    bond and bond option prices. Solutions for certain special cases are obtained, and com-

    pared against their non-stochastic counterparts.KEY WORDS: stochastic volatility, interest rate modeling, Heath-Jarrow-Morton,

    bond option

    1. INTRODUCTION

    The majority of the term structure models prior to Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992)

    were finite dimensional Markovian systems in which the interest rate economy was de-

    termined by the spot rate and perhaps one or two additional state variables. This enabled

    the use of standard arbitrage arguments, along the lines of Black and Scholes (1973)and Merton (1973), to derive the PDE for the bond and bond option prices which, in

    turn, enabled the application of well-developed techniques from the theory of PDEs to

    obtain analytic solutions, and numerical solutions in cases where this was not possible.

    The progenitors of this approach could be regarded as Vasicek (1977) and Brennan and

    Schwartz (1979).

    Although these early models were useful from the viewpoint that analytic solutions were

    often available, the calibration of model parameters to observed market data was a highly

    non-trivial task. In particular, many models could not be calibrated consistently to the

    initial yield curve, and the relationship between the model parameters and the market

    observed variables were not always clear. Furthermore, it was not always possible to

    incorporate observed market features, such as the humped volatility curve, into thesemodels.

    By contrast, the Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) approach provides a very general

    interest rate framework, capable of incorporating most, if not all, of the market observed

    features. The HJM models are automatically calibrated to the initial yield curve, and the

    Date: First version April 10, 1998. Current version November 1, 1999.

    1

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    2/22

    connection between the model parameters and the market variables often emerge from

    the theory.

    The main drawback of the HJM framework is that it results in models that are non-

    Markovian in general, and consequently the techniques from the theory of PDEs no

    longer apply. For the general HJM model, Monte Carlo simulation, which can often be

    time consuming, is the only method of solution. To overcome these problems, many

    authors, including Carverhill (1994), Ritchken and Sankarasubramanian (1995), Bhar

    and Chiarella (1997), Chiarella and Kwon (1998a), Chiarella and Kwon (1998b), andBhar, Chiarella, El-Hassan and Zheng (1999), have considered ways of transforming

    the HJM models to Markovian systems. In these transformed systems, the desirable

    properties of the earlier Markovian models and the HJM framework coexist, and provide

    useful settings under which to study interest rate derivatives.

    In the standard HJM framework, the uncertainty in the interest rate market is represented

    by Wiener processes that drive the forward rate process. All other processes in the in-

    terest rate market, including the forward rate volatilities, are thus also driven by the

    same Wiener processes. Consequently, the standard HJM model does not incorporate

    additional independent sources of stochastic volatility, as considered in Hull and White

    (1987), Heston (1993), and Scott (1997).

    The main contribution of this paper is the specification of volatility processes that are

    driven by additional Wiener processes that are independent of those that drive the for-

    ward rate process in the standard HJM framework. Such models will be referred to as

    stochastic volatility HJM models. The stochastic HJM models considered in this paper

    transform to Markovian systems, and hence enjoy the benefits enjoyed by such mod-

    els. For certain special cases, explicit bond price formulae, in the spirit of Ritchken and

    Sankarasubramanian (1995), Inui and Kijima (1998), and Chiarella and Kwon (1998a)

    are given, along with numerical examples highlighting the effect of the additional Wiener

    processes. The class of models constructed in this paper can, in some sense, be consid-

    ered as analogues of the Hull and White (1987) and Heston (1993) stochastic volatility

    models within the HJM framework, and provides one way of incorporating stochasticvolatility into the HJM framework, as alluded to in Jarrow (1997).

    The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. In

    2 the HJM framework is briefly

    outlined. The stochastic volatility model is then introduced in a simplified -dimensional

    setting in 3, and the general stochastic model is described in 4. Numerical examples

    illustrating the effect of stochastic volatility are given in

    5, and the paper concludes with

    6.

    2. HEATH-JARROW-M ORTON FRAMEWORK

    In this section, an overview of the general Heath-Jarrow-Morton framework is given.

    For further details, the reader is referred to Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992), Brace and

    Musiela (1994), or Musiela and Rutkowski (1997).

    2.1. The Risk-Neutral Framework. Let , and assume given a filtered prob-

    ability space

    satisfying the usual conditions, with filtration

    generated by an -dimensional standard -Wiener process

    .

    2

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    3/22

    In the standard HJM interest rate framework, the time

    instantaneous rate of return on

    an investment contracted at time , denoted , is assumed to satisfy the stochastic

    integral equation

    (2.1)

    where

    ,

    , and

    represents thedependence of the forward rate process on the Wiener path . For finite dimen-

    sional Markovian specialisations of the HJM model, the path (

    ) dependence simplifies

    to dependence on a finite number of state variables such as the spot rate

    . Rel-

    atively mild regularity assumptions are imposed on

    so that the integrals are

    well defined, and required manipulations are valid.

    The spot rate process, , is obtained by setting in (2.1), so that

    (2.2)

    The money market account

    , representing the time

    value of unit investmentmade at time , is given by the equation

    (2.3)

    Finally, the time price of a maturity zero coupon bond, denoted , is defined

    as

    (2.4)

    The differential forms of (2.1) and (2.2) are easily obtained and have the form

    (2.5)

    (2.6)

    By using the stochastic Fubinis theorem and Itos lemma, HJM showed that

    satisfies

    (2.7)

    where

    .

    3

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    4/22

    2.2. Derivative Prices as Conditional Expectations. It follows from Itos lemma and

    (2.7) that the discounted bond price process satisfies

    (2.8)

    and is consequently an

    -martingale under the equivalent martingale measure

    .

    Thus

    (2.9)

    Substituting for

    and

    , and imposing the condition

    ,

    yields the important identity

    (2.10)

    which gives the bond price as the expected value of the discounted payoff. More gener-

    ally, if

    is a price process for a

    -expiry option on ,

    , with

    payoff

    , then

    (2.11)

    2.3. Feynman-Kac Theorem and Partial Differential Equations. If the interest rate

    economy is Markovian, then an application of the Feynman-Kac Thoerem to (2.10) re-

    sults in the partial differential equation

    (2.12)

    for the bond price, where is the infinitesimal generator associated with the Markovian

    system resulting from (2.5) and (2.6). There are well-developed theoretical and numer-

    ical techniques for solving such equations, and consequently many authors, including

    Ritchken and Sankarasubramanian (1995), Inui and Kijima (1998), Chiarella and Kwon(1998a), Chiarella and Kwon (1998b), and Bhar, Chiarella, El-Hassan and Zheng (1999),

    have studied conditions under which the HJM model transforms to Markovian systems.

    3. ONE DIMENSIONAL HJM MODELS WITH STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY

    Being path dependent, the volatility processes in the standard HJM framework are tech-

    nically stochastic. However, in the literature (see Hull and White (1987), Heston (1993),

    and Scott (1997)), the term stochastic volatility appears to be reserved only for those

    volatility processes which are driven by Wiener processes linearly independent of the

    Wiener processes that drive the underlying asset price process, or, as in this case, the for-ward rate process. It is in this sense that the standard HJM models fail to be stochastic

    volatility models. A good discussion of stochastic volatility models in a non-stochastic

    interest rate environment is Heston (1993) and Scott (1997) in a generalised setting.

    In order to give a transparent exposition of the main ideas of this paper, the special case

    of

    -dimensional stochastic volatility HJM models are considered in this section. The

    -dimensional generalisation is considered in 4.

    4

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    5/22

    3.1. Embedding Stochastic Volatility in the HJM Framework. In the case of the

    -dimensional HJM model, recall from (2.5) that the forward rate process evolves ac-

    cording to the stochastic differential equation

    (3.1)

    Separable volatility processes of the form

    (3.2)where is a deterministic function, have been considered by numerous authors (Ritchken

    and Sankarasubramanian (1995), Inui and Kijima (1998), Bhar, Chiarella, El-Hassan and

    Zheng (1999)), and have been shown to generate a useful class of Markovian interest

    models in which a closed form formula for the bond price is available. It must be noted

    that an additional assumption such as must be made in order to

    obtain a Markovian model, although the bond price formula remains valid in the absence

    of such assumptions. For example, in the Vasicek type model the additional assumption

    , where

    is a constant, is made, while for the CIR type model, the

    assumption made is

    .

    Stochastic volatility may be introduced into the standard HJM model in several ways,

    but the method adopted in this paper is to assume a volatility process of the form

    -

    (3.3)

    where

    is a vector of a finite set of fixed

    tenor forward rates with

    , and are deterministic

    functions, and

    is a stochastic process satisfying

    (3.4)

    where is a constant, , , and are deterministic functions, and is a

    standard Wiener process such that

    (3.5)

    Appropriate choice of the parameter - allows the volatility or variance to be modeled as

    a stochastic process. An example of such a volatility specification is

    with

    satisfying

    (3.6)

    where

    ,

    ,

    , and

    are constants.

    To apply the techniques of Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992), it is convenient to replacethe correlated Wiener processes and with uncorrelated processes, and it is

    easily seen that

    and

    , defined by

    (3.7)

    (3.8)

    5

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    6/22

    have this property. Inversion of the pair of equations above yields

    (3.9)

    (3.10)

    and substituting (3.10) into (3.1) gives

    Now define

    (3.11)

    (3.12)

    (3.13)

    Then (3.1) can be rewritten as

    (3.14)

    which is the starting point in Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992), for a -dimensional

    model with volatility processes

    . Assuming the existence of market prices of

    risk

    , , associated with the two sources of uncertainty, and following

    the arbitrage arguments of Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992), the forward rate process is

    seen to satisfy

    (3.15)

    where

    , and

    are standard Wiener processes under the equivalent martingale measure

    . The gen-eral framework developed in Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) applies verbatim to the

    stochastic volatility model introduced in this section, and in particular, expressions such

    as (2.2), (2.6), and (2.10) remain valid for the stochastic volatility model.

    3.2. Markovian System. The volatility process of the form (3.3) satisfies the Markov-

    ian condition given in Inui and Kijima (1998) and Chiarella and Kwon (1998 a), and,

    consequently, the corresponding HJM model transforms to a Markovian system. Since

    the transformation in the case of stochastic volatility has not been considered in previous

    literature, the argument is briefly outlined below.

    Define state variables

    and

    by

    (3.16)

    (3.17)

    6

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    7/22

    and for

    define

    (3.18)

    (3.19)

    Note that and .

    Lemma 3.1. The variables and satisfy the equations

    (3.20)

    (3.21)

    where

    (3.22)

    (3.23)

    Proof. See Appendix A.

    Since the volatility process (3.3) is a function of forward rates

    ,

    ,

    the equations governing the evolution of the forward rates must also be computed. For

    this, note that, from (3.15), the stochastic integral equation for

    is

    Lemma 3.2. The stochastic differential equation for the forward rate is

    (3.24)

    where

    .

    Proof. See Appendix B.

    Proposition 3.3. Let the market price of risk

    be a function of

    ,

    ,

    ,

    and

    , where

    . Then the set

    forms an

    -dimensional Markovian system.

    Proof. From Appendix C, the state variables and satisfy the equations

    and from (3.4),

    satisfies the equation

    (3.25)

    Recall that

    .

    7

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    8/22

    Now, if

    is a function of

    ,

    ,

    , and

    , then together with (3.2),

    these equations determine a Markovian system having

    , , , and

    as the state variables.

    Note the dependence of the drift term in (3.25) on the market price of risk

    . This is

    analogous to the corresponding situation in the stochastic volatility models of Hull and

    White (1987), Heston (1993), and Scott (1997), and arises from market incompleteness,

    which is in turn a result of the absence of a traded asset related to volatility.

    3.3. State Variables and as Functions of Forward Rates. The economic

    significance of the state variables and is not at all clear from (3.16) and (3.17).

    In this subsection, it is shown that they can, in fact, be expressed as linear combinations

    of forward rates, and hence a useful interpretation of the state variables in terms of

    economically meaningful variables is established.

    Setting in (2.1), and using Lemma 3.1, the equation for the forward rate

    can be written

    (3.26)

    For notational convenience, let

    and

    (3.27)

    Then (3.26) can be written

    (3.28)

    An important feature of (3.28) is that

    and

    are deterministic functions, and

    so, for any , (3.28) gives the value of

    , and hence the value of , as

    linear combination of the state variables

    and

    .

    Another useful feature of (3.28) is that it can be used to express the state variables

    and as linear combinations of a finite set of forward rates. For this, fix two tenors

    . Then setting

    in (3.28), for

    , gives rise to the system

    (3.29)

    Inverting this system of equations, the state variables and can be written as

    linear combinations of forward rates

    and

    in the form

    (3.30)

    (3.31)

    3.4. Pricing Partial Differential Equation. Since the stochastic volatility model intro-duced in this section is Markovian, the Feynman-Kac Theorem can be applied to obtain

    the pricing PDE for interest rate contingent claims. Recall that if the state variables

    ,

    , for a Markovian system satisfies

    (3.32)

    8

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    9/22

    where

    , then the associated infinitesimal generator is given by

    (3.33)

    where

    (3.34)

    For the case at hand, the state variables are given by Proposition 3.3, and the equations

    determining the drift and diffusion coefficients are given in Lemma 3.2 and Proposi-

    tion 3.3. To clarify the above discussion, the infinitesimal generator in the case where

    and

    is given below. For this case, the only forward rate contained in the

    set of state variables is the spot rate, and the relevant equations are

    (3.35)

    where

    The infinitesimal generator is then given by

    (3.36)

    and the pricing PDE for a contingent claim is given by

    (3.37)

    subject to appropriate boundary conditions.

    3.5. Bond Price as a Function of the State Variables. The bond price formula for

    HJM models driven by separable volatility processes was obtained by Ritchken and

    Sankarasubramanian (1995) for the one dimensional case, and extended to the general

    case by Inui and Kijima (1998). The formula was then further generalised by Chiarellaand Kwon (1998a) to forward rate dependent volatility processes. In this subsection, a

    brief outline of the derivation of the bond price formula is given. Note that from (2.4)

    and (3.15), the price of a

    -maturity bond is given by the equation

    (3.38)

    9

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    10/22

    From Appendix D,

    (3.39)

    where

    , and consequently

    (3.40)

    Note that the state variables and can be replaced by forward rates, as shown in

    3.3.

    3.6. Pricing of European Bond Options. To compute the price of a

    -maturity

    European option on a -maturity bond, with payoff

    , the system of stochastic

    differential equations (3.35) must be solved numerically for the values of state variables

    ,

    ,

    , and

    , and the discount factor

    , at option maturity

    . The bond price

    can then be computed using (3.40), and this, together with

    the payoff function

    , determines the option price

    . Repeating

    the simulation a suitable number of times, and taking the average, then gives the value of the European option. Results from implementing this procedure are given in 5.

    4. GENERAL HJM MODELS WITH STOCHASTIC VOLATILITY

    In this section, the introduction of stochastic volatility into the

    -dimensional HJM

    model, presented in 3, is extended to the general -dimensional HJM framework.

    4.1. Embedding Stochastic Volatility in the HJM Framework. Recall from (2.5)

    that in the

    -factor risk-neutral HJM framework, the instantaneous forward rate process

    evolves according to the equation

    (4.1)

    where

    are independent standard Wiener processes. Let be a positive integer,

    and fix a sequence

    . Define a vector of forward rates

    by

    (4.2)

    As in the -dimensional case, to introduce stochastic volatility into the HJM model, the

    are assumed to be of the form

    -

    (4.3)

    where

    and

    are deterministic functions, -

    , and

    satisfy

    (4.4)

    Note that since , the variable is redundant.

    10

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    11/22

    where

    ,

    , and

    are deterministic functions, and

    , for

    . It is

    further assumed that

    if

    if (4.5)

    where

    ,

    , and

    for all

    . Then the Wiener processes,

    ,

    defined by

    (4.6)

    (4.7)

    are independent, and inversion of the the above system yields

    (4.8)

    (4.9)

    Substituting (4.9) into (4.1) gives

    Now define

    (4.10)

    (4.11)

    (4.12)

    Then (4.1) can be written

    (4.13)

    which is the starting point in Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) with volatility processes

    . Assuming the existence of market prices of risk

    ,

    , and

    following the arguments of Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992), one obtains

    (4.14)

    where

    and

    are

    standard Wiener processes under the equivalent martingale measure

    . The results ob-

    tained in Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) remain valid for the stochastic volatility

    model introduced in this section modulo the obvious modifications, viz. replacing

    by

    and

    by

    .

    This restriction is imposed purely to simplify exposition. The analysis in this section remains valid

    for any correlation structure.

    11

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    12/22

    4.2. Markovian System. The volatility processes given by (4.11) and (4.12) satisfy the

    Markovian condition given in Inui and Kijima (1998) and Chiarella and Kwon (1998a),

    and the corresponding HJM model transforms a finite dimensional Markovian system.

    Since the method for transforming the model to a Markovian system closely parallels the

    method employed in

    3, the proofs are kept brief.

    For

    , define variables

    and

    by

    (4.15)

    (4.16)

    and for define

    and

    by

    (4.17)

    (4.18)

    (4.19)

    Lemma 4.1. The variables

    and

    can be expressed in the form

    (4.20)

    (4.21)

    where

    (4.22)

    (4.23)

    Proof. See Appendix A.

    Lemma 4.2. The stochastic differential equation for the forward rate is

    (4.24)

    where

    .

    Proof. See Appendix B.

    12

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    13/22

    Lemma 4.3. The state variables

    and

    satisfy the stochastic differential equa-

    tions

    (4.25)

    (4.26)

    Proof. See Appendix C.

    Proposition 4.4. Let

    be a function of

    ,

    ,

    , and

    , where

    and

    , for each

    . Then the set

    forms an

    -dimensional Markovian system.

    Proof. From (4.4), the SDE governing the evolution of

    with respect to Wiener

    processes

    is

    (4.27)

    Since

    are assumed to be functions of the state variables, the result now follows

    from Lemma 4.2 and Lemma 4.3.

    4.3. State Variables

    and

    in Terms of Forward Rates. As in the -dimensional

    case, the state variables

    and

    can be expressed in terms of a finite number of

    fixed tenor forward rates.

    Setting

    in (2.1), and using Lemma 4.1, the equation for the forward rate can

    be written

    (4.28)

    Let

    and

    (4.29)

    Then (4.28) can be written

    (4.30)

    Once again, since

    and

    are deterministic functions, (4.30) gives the value

    of

    , and hence the value of

    , as linear combination of a finite number ofstate variables

    and

    .

    Now, fix tenors

    . Then setting

    in (4.30), for

    , gives rise to the linear system

    (4.31)

    13

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    14/22

    where

    ...

    ...

    ...

    Inverting this system of equations, the state variables

    and

    can be expressed as

    linear combinations of forward rates

    ,

    .

    4.4. Bond Price as a Function of the State Variables. From Appendix D, the price of

    a -maturity bond, in the stochastic volatility HJM model introduced in this section, is

    (4.32)

    where

    . Note from

    4.3 that the state variables

    and

    can be expressed in terms of a finite number of fixed tenor forward rates, and so the

    stochastic volatility model of this paper falls under the exponential affine class of models

    in the sense of Duffie and Kan (1996).

    5. NUMERICAL EXAMPLE

    In this section, a special case of the general stochastic volatility framework introduced in

    4 is considered to illustrate the effect of stochastic volatility on the spot rate, the bond

    price, and the European call price.

    5.1. Model Specification. The model used for numerical simulation in this section is

    the

    -dimensional model of

    3, with volatility process given by

    (5.1)

    where

    and

    are constants. The dynamics of

    is restricted to be of the form

    (5.2)

    where , , and are constants.

    14

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    15/22

    5.2. System of Stochastic Differential Equations. The model specified by (5.1) and

    (5.2) is a -dimensional Markovian system with state variables , , and

    . The system of SDEs governing the dynamics are:

    (5.3)

    (5.4)

    (5.5)

    5.3. Parameters and Simulation. The set of parameters used for the simulation are as

    follows:

    (5.6)

    Antithetic variable method was used to compute

    (i) time

    distribution of the spot rate and the

    -year bond price,

    (ii) time price of an at-the-money -month call option on the -year bond,

    for various correlation coefficients

    and the volatility of volatility

    .

    5.4. Distribution of Spot Rate and Bond Price. The effect of varying the correlation

    between the Wiener process driving the forward rate process and that driving the sto-

    chastic scaling factor is illustrated in Figure 5.1 for the distribution of the spot rate, and

    Figure 5.2 for the distribution of the bond price.

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    0.06

    0.0492 0.0494 0.0496 0.0498 0.05 0.0502 0.0504 0.0506 0.0508

    -0.75

    -0.50

    -0.25

    0.00

    0.25

    0.50

    0.75

    FIGURE 5.1 . Distribution of Spot Rate with

    and Varying

    The effect of varying the volatility of volatility,

    , on these distributions is illustrated in

    Figure 5.3 and Figure 5.4.

    It is interesting to observe from Figure 5.1 and Figure 5.2 that increasing

    from negative

    to positive values tends to skew the spot distribution to the left and the bond distribution

    to the right. Both distributions tend to peak around zero correlation between the two

    15

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    16/22

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    0.06

    0.87 0.8705 0.871 0.8715 0.872 0.8725 0.873

    -0.75

    -0.50

    -0.25

    0.00

    0.25

    0.50

    0.75

    FIGURE 5.2. Distribution of Bond Price with and Varying

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    0.06

    0.0492 0.0494 0.0496 0.0498 0.05 0.0502 0.0504 0.0506 0.0508

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    FIGURE 5.3 . Distribution of Spot Rate with and Varying

    Wiener processes. When there is positive correlation between the two Wiener processes,

    Figure 5.3 and Figure 5.4 show that an increase in volatility of volatility skews the spot

    rate distribution to the left and the bond price distribution to the right.

    5.5. Call Price as Function of

    and

    . The effect of varying the correlation

    andthe volatility of volatility on the price of a -month call option on a -year bond is

    illustrated in Figure 5.5 and Figure 5.6 respectively.

    Figure 5.5 shows that the call option value increases with increasing correlation , and

    this is to be expected given the skewing to the right of the bond price distribution in this

    situation. Similarly, Figure 5.6 shows that the call option value increases with increasing

    volatility of volatility.

    16

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    17/22

    0

    0.01

    0.02

    0.03

    0.04

    0.05

    0.06

    0.87 0.8705 0.871 0.8715 0.872 0.8725 0.873

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    FIGURE 5.4. Distribution of Bond Price with and Varying

    6e-005

    8e-005

    0.0001

    0.00012

    0.00014

    0.00016

    0.00018

    0.0002

    -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1

    FIGURE 5.5. Call Price against with

    6. CONCLUSION

    A fairly broad class of forward rate volatility processes within the HJM framework has

    been considered in this paper. These forward rates depend on a set of fixed tenor forward

    rates, time dependent quantities, and stochastic quantities driven by Wiener processesindependent from those driving the forward rate dynamics.

    It is shown how the stochastic dynamics of the resulting system can be reduced to a Mar-

    kovian form, and that many of the subsidiary state variables introduced by the Markovian

    reduction procedure can be expressed in terms of a set of fixed tenor forward rates. The

    only non-market traded quantities in the stochastic dynamics are the stochastic volatility

    quantities.

    17

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    18/22

    0.0001

    0.00012

    0.00014

    0.00016

    0.00018

    0.0002

    0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

    FIGURE 5.6. Call Price against with

    It is possible to obtain an explicit formula for the bond prices in this framework so thatMonte Carlo simulation is required only for the calculation of option prices. This fact

    makes option pricing feasible with the class of stochastic volatility models presented in

    this paper.

    Some numerical results have been given indicating how the level of the volatility of

    volatility, and the correlation between the noises driving the forward rates and the sto-

    chastic volatility, affect the spot rate, bond price, and European call option values. These

    calculations indicate the computational feasibility of the approach developed in this pa-

    per, at least as far as off-line calculations are concerned. No doubt further research

    on numerical methods tailored to these stochastic volatility models would also make

    feasible calculations in trading time.

    It has also been shown how the models developed in this paper may be viewed as a

    subclass of the exponential affine class of interest rate models considered by Duffie and

    Kan (1996).

    APPENDIX A. PROOF OF LEMMA 3.1 AN D LEMMA 4. 1

    Consider firstly Lemma 4.1. It follows easily from definition (4.3) that

    Using this identity,

    18

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    19/22

    Next, for

    , let

    (A.1)

    so that

    ,

    . Then for

    ,

    and likewise

    Addition of the previous two equations yields the required identity

    Lemma 3.1 is obtained by setting .

    APPENDIX B. PROOF OF LEMMA 3.2 AN D LEMMA 4.2

    Consider the more general case of Lemma 4.2, and, for notational convenience, write for

    each

    (B.1)

    (B.2)

    Then the integral equation for the forward rate process can be written

    (B.3)

    19

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    20/22

    Assuming volatility processes of the form (3.3), and differentiating w.r.t.

    (B.4)

    (B.5)

    for

    . Similar computations establish

    (B.6)

    (B.7)

    These equations combine to yield the expression

    and the result follows from Appendix A. Setting

    yields Lemma 3.2 as a specialcase.

    APPENDIX C. PROOF OF LEMMA 4.3

    The key identity

    (C.1)

    follows from (4.3). Now, first consider (4.25).

    by (C.1)

    Next consider (4.26). From (B.1) and (B.2),

    (C.2)

    and from (B.4)-(B.7),

    20

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    21/22

    APPENDIX D. PROOF OF (3.39) AN D (4.32)

    Recall the definitions of

    and

    from Lemma 3.1, and define

    (D.1)

    Then

    and for ,

    Analogous computation yields

    Now, using (A.1) and Fubinis Theorem

    for

    , and similar computations yield

    Addition of the previous two equations implies

    21

  • 7/28/2019 A Class of Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    22/22

    Summation over

    results in the equation

    and hence

    REFERENCES

    Bhar, R. and Chiarella, C. (1997), Transformation of Heath-Jarrow-Morton Models to Markovian Sys-

    tems, European Journal of Finance 3, 126.

    Bhar, R., Chiarella, C., El-Hassan, N. and Zheng, X. (1999), Reduction of Forward Rate Dependent HJM

    Models to Markovian Form: Pricing European Bond Options, Working paper, School of Finance and

    Economics, University of Techonology Sydney.

    Black, F. and Scholes, M. (1973), The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal of Political

    Economy 81, 637659.

    Brace, A. and Musiela, M. (1994), A Multifactor Gauss Markov Implementation of Heath, Jarrow, and

    Morton, Mathematical Finance 4(3), 259283.

    Brennan, M. and Schwartz, E. (1979), A Continuous Time Approach to the Pricing of Interest Rates,

    Journal of Banking and Finance 3, 133155.

    Carverhill, A. (1994), When is the Short Rate Markovian?, Mathematical Finance 4(4), 305312.

    Chiarella, C. and Kwon, O. (1998a), Forward Rate Dependent Markovian Transformations of the Heath-

    Jarrow-Morton Term Structure Model, Working paper, School of Finance and Economics, University

    of Techonology Sydney.

    Chiarella, C. and Kwon, O. (1998b), Square Root Affine Transformations of the Heath-Jarrow-Morton

    Term Structure Model and Partial Differential Equations, Working paper, School of Finance and

    Economics, University of Techonology Sydney.

    Duffie, D. and Kan, R. (1996), A Yield Factor Model of Interest Rates, Mathematical Finance 6(4), 379

    406.

    Heath, D., Jarrow, R. and Morton, A. (1992), Bond Princing and the Term Structure of Interest Rates: A

    New Methodology for Contingent Claim Valuation, Econometrica 60(1), 77105.Heston, S. (1993), A closed form solution for options with stochastic volatility with application to bond

    and currency options, Review of Financial Studies 6(2), 327343.

    Hull, J. and White, A. (1987), The Pricing of Options on Assets with Stochastic Volatilities, Journal of

    Finance 42(2), 281300.

    Inui, K. and Kijima, M. (1998), A Markovian Framework in Multi-Factor Heath-Jarrow-Morton Models,

    Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 33(3), 423440.

    Jarrow, R. (1997), The HJM Model: Its Past, Present, and Future, Journal of Financial Engineering

    6(4), 269279. Keynote Address, IAFE 1997 Conference.

    Merton, R. (1973), The Theory of Rational Option Pricing, Bell Jounal of Economics and Management

    Science 4, 141183.

    Musiela, M. and Rutkowski, M. (1997), Martingale Methods in Financial Modelling, first edn, Springer-

    Verlag, New York. Applications of Mathematics 30.

    Ritchken, P. and Sankarasubramanian, L. (1995), Volatility Structures of Forward Rates and the Dynamicsof the Term Structure,Mathematical Finance 5(1), 5572.

    Scott, L. (1997), Pricing Stock Options in a Jump-Diffusion Model with Stochastic Volatility and Interest

    Interest Rates: Applications of Fourier Inversion Methods, Mathematical Finance 7(4), 413426.

    Vasicek, O. (1977), An Equilibrium Characterisation of the Term Structure, Journal of Financial Eco-

    nomics 5, 177188.

    22