a demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

54
A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries * Ramiro de Elejalde Eugenio Giolito December 3, 2020 Abstract We study the demand-smoothing incentives for private hospitals to per- form c-sections. First, we show that a policy change in Chile that increased delivery at private hospitals by reducing the out-of-pocket cost for women with public insurance increased the probability of a c-section by 8.6 percent- age points despite private hospitals receiving the same price for a vaginal or cesarean delivery. Second, to understand hospitals’ incentives to perform c-sections, we present a model of hospital decisions about the mode of de- livery without price incentives. The model predicts that, because c-sections can be scheduled, a higher c-section rate increases total deliveries, compen- sating the forgone higher margin of vaginal deliveries. Finally, we provide evidence consistent with the demand-smoothing mechanism: hospitals with higher c-section rates are more likely to reschedule deliveries when they ex- pect a high-demand week. Keywords: health care, provider incentives, labor and delivery JEL classification: I11, I13, I18 * We thank Matías Busso, María Lombardi, Olga Namen, Julio Cáceres-Delpiano, María Nieves Valdés and participants at several seminars and conferences for their valuable comments. Errors are ours. Departamento de Economía, Universidad Alberto Hurtado, Chile; [email protected]. Departamento de Economía, Universidad Alberto Hurtado, Chile and IZA egi- [email protected]. 1

Upload: others

Post on 17-Jul-2022

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean

deliveries ∗

Ramiro de Elejalde† Eugenio Giolito‡

December 3, 2020

Abstract

We study the demand-smoothing incentives for private hospitals to per-form c-sections. First, we show that a policy change in Chile that increaseddelivery at private hospitals by reducing the out-of-pocket cost for womenwith public insurance increased the probability of a c-section by 8.6 percent-age points despite private hospitals receiving the same price for a vaginalor cesarean delivery. Second, to understand hospitals’ incentives to performc-sections, we present a model of hospital decisions about the mode of de-livery without price incentives. The model predicts that, because c-sectionscan be scheduled, a higher c-section rate increases total deliveries, compen-sating the forgone higher margin of vaginal deliveries. Finally, we provideevidence consistent with the demand-smoothing mechanism: hospitals withhigher c-section rates are more likely to reschedule deliveries when they ex-pect a high-demand week.

Keywords: health care, provider incentives, labor and deliveryJEL classification: I11, I13, I18

∗We thank Matías Busso, María Lombardi, Olga Namen, Julio Cáceres-Delpiano, María NievesValdés and participants at several seminars and conferences for their valuable comments. Errorsare ours.

†Departamento de Economía, Universidad Alberto Hurtado, Chile; [email protected].‡Departamento de Economía, Universidad Alberto Hurtado, Chile and IZA egi-

[email protected].

1

Page 2: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

1 Introduction

The rate of c-sections has increased worldwide in recent years. According to Betrán

et al. (2016), the largest increase in c-section rates has occurred in Latin America

and the Caribbean (LAC), where it went from 27% in 2000 to 42% in 2014. Recent

studies in several countries suggest a correlation between delivery at for-profit private

hospitals and c-sections (for example, see Hoxha et al., 2017). Figure 1 shows

that both deliveries at private hospitals and c-section rates have increased in recent

decades in Chile. 1

If the correlation between deliveries at private hospitals and c-sections is causal,

then the increase in c-section rates may be due to physician or hospital incentives

rather than any change in medical conditions presented in pregnancy. This deserves

attention given the extensive evidence that non-medically indicated c-sections are

detrimental to the health of mothers and newborns (see Card et al., 2018, Costa-

Ramón et al., 2018 or Borra et al., 2019, for recent examples). 2

The literature on physician and hospital incentives has focused on the price

mechanism to perform more c-sections, i.e. the physician or hospital receiving higher

fees for a c-section than a vaginal delivery. A seminal paper in this literature is

Gruber et al. (1999) and more recent examples are Allin et al. (2015) or Foo et al.1This relationship was first documented qualitatively by Murray (2000), who found that women

treated by private obstetricians are more likely to have c-sections than women treated by midwivesor doctors in public hospitals. More recently, Borrescio-Higa and Valdés (2019) found an associationbetween high c-section rates and women with health insurance giving birth at private hospitals.

2Several papers in medical journals also document that c-sections with cephalic presentationare associated with adverse maternal and newborn outcomes. These papers show a higher risk ofmorbidity and postpartum infections in the case of the mother (Villar et al., 2007), a higher risk ofcomplications in future pregnancies (Ananth et al., 1997), a higher risk of injury for the newborn(Alexander et al., 2006), and a higher risk of a stay of 7 days or more in neonatal intensive careunit (Villar et al., 2007). For a review of the association between c-sections and health outcomessee Hyde et al. (2012).

2

Page 3: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 1: Share of deliveries at private hospitals and c-section rates in Chile

Source: Departamento de Estadísticas e Información de Salud (DEIS), Ministerio de Salud, Chile.

(2017). In this paper, we analyze a demand-smoothing mechanism: the scope to

schedule of c-section deliveries, which is absent for vaginal deliveries. This flexibility

may allow hospitals to schedule more deliveries and increase aggregate profits via

a quantity effect even without price incentives. Therefore, we study whether this

demand-smoothing mechanism can explain, at least in part, the high c-section rates

of private hospitals when direct price incentives are not present.

To answer this question, in Section 2 we exploit a 2003 policy change in Chile

that decreased the cost of delivery at private hospitals for women with public health

insurance. Crucially, under this program, insurance pays private hospitals the same

fee per delivery regardless of whether it is a vaginal delivery or a c-section. Using a

difference-in-differences (DID) strategy exploiting the eligibility conditions for the

program, related to insurance affiliation, we find that the policy increased the prob-

3

Page 4: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

ability of delivery at a private hospital by 14.5 percentage points and the probability

of a c-section by 8.6 percentage points.

After we show evidence that private hospitals perform more c-sections than pub-

lic hospitals even without price incentives, in Section 3 we introduce a model of hos-

pital decisions about the mode of delivery to understand the logic of the demand-

smoothing mechanism. We model a profit-maximizing hospital receiving the same

price for vaginal and cesarean deliveries, with the latter having a higher cost. How-

ever, while the hospital can schedule a c-section for a given period, a vaginal delivery

arrives randomly either in the present or future period.

The model predicts that, at the margin, when the hospital increases the share of

deliveries allocated to c-sections, the total number of deliveries increases (a positive

quantity effect). This effect in equilibrium compensates for the higher margins of

vaginal deliveries (a negative price effect). We conclude that, if vaginal deliveries

have sufficient variation over time, a higher c-section rate may allow the hospital to

more than compensate for the cost difference and to increase profits.

To quantify the importance of the demand-smoothing mechanism, we calibrate

an extended version of the model with data and perform counterfactual experiments.

The experiments suggest that constraining private hospitals to the c-section rate of

public hospitals would decrease the capacity utilization of the former by 24% and

reduce their profits by 12%. We then use the calibrated model, together with data

on capacity utilization before and after the policy, to study if the demand-smoothing

mechanism can explain, at least in part, the observed behavior in the c-section rates

of PAD hospitals. The model replicates the positive correlation between changes

in utilization and changes in c-section rates, providing further evidence that our

4

Page 5: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

proposed mechanism may be behind some of the effects of the policy

Consistent with the demand-smoothing mechanism, in Section 4 we provide ev-

idence that hospitals with higher c-section rates are more likely to reschedule a

delivery when its due date (at a gestational age of 40 weeks) is expected to be a

high-demand week. In particular, we find that the probability of an early-term birth

(on week 37 or 38) is an increasing function of the expected demand at term (calcu-

lated as the number of deliveries that would have reached week 40 at the same time).

This relationship holds only for private hospitals participating in the program, or

hospitals with c-section rates above 40%.

Finally, in Section 5 we discuss our results and other possible mechanisms that

may relate c-sections with physician/hospital incentives.

Our paper fits within the literature that have linked c-sections with price in-

centives (Gruber et al., 1999), fear of liability risk (Dubay et al., 1999; Currie and

MacLeod, 2008; Frakes and Gruber, 2020) or procedural skill (Currie and MacLeod,

2016). Our work is also related to research on the effects of the type of hospital

on c-section rates. For example, Johnson and Rehavi (2016) compared c-section

rates for HMO-owned hospitals and non-HMO-owned hospitals for physician and

non-physician patients, using data for California from 1996-2005. They found that

c-section rates for non-physicians are lower in HMO-owned hospitals than in non-

HMO-owned hospitals, while c-section rates for physician patients do not depend

on hospital ownership.3

This paper makes two main contributions. First, it demonstrates that a policy

that increased access to private hospitals for women with public insurance had the3Other examples are Shen (2002) and Lien et al. (2008).

5

Page 6: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

unforeseen consequence of increasing the c-section rate. Second, our results suggest

that hospitals/physicians have incentives to have a high c-section rate despite having

a lower unit margin. Our results imply that future health policies may consider

incentives other than price when designing contracts or payment systems.

2 Impact of easing access to private hospitals on

C-Sections

2.1 Institutional Setting

Health insurance in Chile is mandatory for employees and retirees, but optional for

the self-employed and economically inactive individuals. Health insurance buyers

can choose between public or private insurance. In 2016, 74% of the population

had public insurance, 19% had private insurance, and 7% were uninsured or had a

specific type of insurance for the police and armed forces.4

Private insurance is supplied by private firms called ISAPRES (the Spanish

acronym for Institución de Salud Previsional). Public insurance is administered by

the Fondo Nacional de Salud (FONASA) and is financed by a 7% tax on enrollees’

taxable incomes and government transfers.5 Individuals with public insurance are

assigned to one of four groups: A, B, C, or D. Group A includes only individuals

who are below the indigence line, receive government subsidies or demonstrate they

receive no income. The remaining three groups are classified by monthly income. In4Source: FONASA (2017).5The 7% tax on the enrollee’s taxable income is up to a maximum of approximately 200 dollars.

6

Page 7: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

2016, 18% of the population was in group A, 25% in B, 11% in C, and 20% in D.6

Individuals with public insurance have two options for receiving their bene-

fits: Modalidad Atención Institucional (MAI), which involves the network of public

providers, and Modalidad Libre Elección (MLE), which grants access to private hos-

pitals for individuals in groups B, C, and D.7 Under the MLE option, the government

sets the hospital fees and copayments for all medical procedures (which do not vary

by groups). Private hospitals choose whether or not to participate in the program,

and individuals with public insurance can choose from among the available hospitals.

In 1996, the government made MLE more attractive by the introduction of a

diagnosis-related group (DRG) payment system called PAD (the Spanish acronym

for Pago Asociado a Diagnóstico). Under this system, both the patient’s copayment

and the hospital price are fixed amounts defined by FONASA for the treatment as-

sociated with a diagnosis, irrespective of the actual medical procedures performed.8

The PAD system includes a code for delivery that covers both vaginal and ce-

sarean deliveries. Thus, with PAD delivery, a private hospital receives the same

payment independent of the mode of delivery. The PAD delivery covers doctor and

midwife fees, hospital stay, medical exams, medication and immunization costs, and

postnatal care for 15 days after the patient is discharged. Importantly, to be eligible

for PAD delivery, a woman with public insurance must: (i) be enrolled in group B,

C, or D, (ii) expect a single baby, (iii) have a pregnancy with a gestational age of 376Individuals with incomes of less than 360 dollars are in group B, those with incomes between

360 and 530 dollars are in group C, and those with incomes greater than 530 dollars are in groupD. These groups are important because the coinsurance rate in public hospitals (but not in privatehospitals) depends on group affiliation: it is zero for individuals in groups A and B, 10% forindividuals in group C, and 20% for individuals in group D.

7Private health insurance, on the other hand, only provides access to private hospitals, exceptin special cases like an emergency.

8For details of the evolution of the PAD program, see the Appendix.

7

Page 8: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 2: Share of deliveries by women with public insurance groups B, C or D financedwith PAD delivery

Note: The number of PAD deliveries includes deliveries in private hospitals financed by PAD.Source: FONASA, Ministerio de Salud, Chile.

weeks or more (at the time of delivery), and (iv) have a non-high-risk pregnancy.9

Our policy of interest is a 2003 policy change that decreased the copayment for

delivery from 60% to 25%. The decrease in the copayment for PAD delivery in 2003

was significant: it fell from 630 dollars in 2002 to 270 dollars in 2003.10 After this

change, the use of PAD delivery in private hospitals for women with public insurance

B, C, or D increased from 10% in the 1st quarter of 2003 to 45% in the 1st quarter

of 2008 (see Figure 2).9To satisfy these eligibility requirements, on week 37, a woman must present a medical certificate

about her pregnancy risk status in her chosen hospital. Since the high-risk status is loosely definedin the PAD requirements, the hospital can request additional tests for the patient and eventuallyreject the case. If the hospital accepts the case, the woman pays the copayment and gets PADcoverage.

10Decreto 48 of the Ministry of Health promulgated on February 11th, 2003, and came into forceon April 2nd, 2003 (see http://bcn.cl/2bofl.).

8

Page 9: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

2.2 Data and Descriptive Statistics

In our analysis, we use hospital discharge data from the Health Statistics and In-

formation Department (DEIS) of the Ministry of Health, publicly available for the

period 2001–2018. This dataset includes information on the discharging hospital,

the discharge date, length of stay, the main diagnosis code (ICD-10 codes), whether

the patient had surgery, and the patient’s county of residence, age, gender, and type

of insurance. We restrict the sample to women between 15 and 47 years of age with

private or public insurance, giving birth in a hospital, with a hospital stay of fewer

than 21 days, during the period 2001–2005.11

We use the ICD-10 codes and whether the patient had surgery to construct

the variables vaginal delivery and c-section (codes 080–084).12 We also construct

variables to identify the type of hospital. We classify hospitals as public hospitals,

private hospitals working with PAD delivery (PAD private hospitals), and private

hospitals not working with PAD delivery (non-PAD private hospitals). Public hos-

pitals belong to the public healthcare system while private hospitals do not. We

consider that a private hospital is a PAD private hospital if it had at least one deliv-

ery financed by PAD delivery in 2001–2005. In 2005, there were 233 hospitals with

positive deliveries: 61 PAD private hospitals, 9 non-PAD private hospitals, and 163

public hospitals. The hospitals identified as “non-PAD” have a share of around 3%

of total deliveries through the period under analysis. Moreover, they work basically

(more than 90%) with (upper-income) women with private insurance before and11As we explain below, we restrict our sample to the period 2001–2005 to avoid contamination

from confounding policies implemented after the policy of interest.12Codes O80, O81, O83, O840, and O841, and codes O848 and O849 for women who did not

have surgery are classified as vaginal deliveries, codes O82 and O842, and codes O848 and O849for women who had surgery are classified as cesarean deliveries.

9

Page 10: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 3: Distribution of hospitals by c-section rates and maternity specialization, 2002

Sample: Hospitals with 100 or more deliveries in 2002.Note: The size of the circle is proportional to the number of deliveries in the hospital in 2002.

after the policy.13

Figure 3 characterizes hospitals in terms of their c-section rates and maternity

specialization (measured by the ratio of deliveries over total hospitalizations) in

2002, before the policy change analyzed here. PAD private hospitals (diamonds)

have high c-section rates to such extent that there is almost no overlap in terms

of c-section rates between these hospitals and public hospitals (circles) and non-

PAD-private hospitals (triangles). Moreover, the PAD private hospitals with the

highest c-section rates are highly specialized in maternity services. This evidence

suggests that PAD private hospitals pursue a business model with a specialization

in deliveries financed by public insurance.

Table 1 shows summary statistics of hospital discharge data. They show that13For more details about the characteristics of the different types of hospitals see section A of

the Appendix.

10

Page 11: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

28% of all deliveries are c-sections, but the c-section rate is 56% in PAD private

hospitals, 30% in non-PAD private hospitals, and 23% in public hospitals. Of all

deliveries, 15% occur at PAD private hospitals, 3% at non-PAD private hospitals,

and 82% at public hospitals. The distribution of deliveries by the mother’s insurance

affiliation is 48% for public insurance A, 38% for public insurance B, C, or D, and

14% for private insurance. The average mother’s age is 26.8 years.

Figures 4a and 4b show the trends in deliveries at PAD private hospitals and

c-section rates for women with different types of insurance for 2001–2005. Figure 4b

shows that the share of deliveries at PAD hospitals went from 8% in 2002 to 27%

in 2005 for women with public insurance B, C or D, while remaining stable for the

other groups. Figure 4b shows that c-section rates correlated closely with the type

of insurance: 20–25% for women with public insurance A A, 35% for women with

public insurance B, C, and D, and 50% for women with private insurance. More

relevant for our work, after the policy change, c-section rates increased for eligible

groups (public insurance B, C, or D) but remained fairly constant for non-eligible

groups (public insurance A and private insurance).

2.3 Empirical Strategy

We estimate the impact of the policy on the probability of a c-section using a DID

strategy that exploits the 2003 decrease in the copayment for PAD delivery. We

use the affiliation to public insurance groups B, C, or D as the treatment variable,

restricting our sample to singleton births only.

11

Page 12: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

(a) Delivery at a PAD private hospital

(b) C-section rates

Figure 4: Trends in delivery at PAD private hospitals and c-section rates by type ofinsurance

12

Page 13: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Our estimating equation is

Yit = β0 + β1 Public InsuranceB,C orDit × Postt

+β2 Public InsuranceB,C orDit

+β3 Public InsuranceAit + µt + δc + λa + εit

(1)

where Yit is the outcome variable (a dummy for cesarean delivery) for delivery i

in month-year t, Public InsuranceB,C orDit is a dummy for delivery by a woman

affiliated to public insurance group B, C, or D, Public InsuranceAit is a dummy for

delivery by a woman affiliated to public insurance group A, and Postt is a dummy

that equals one after April 2003.14 Moreover, µt is a month-year fixed effect, δc is

a mother’s county of residence fixed effect, λa is a mother’s age fixed effect, and εit

includes unobservables that affect the outcome variable. In our estimating equation,

β1 captures the causal effect of interest.

To justify the common trends assumption we tested the presence of parallel

trends in the pre-treatment period. With that purpose, we estimated the following

econometric model:

Yit = β0 +∑T

τ=1 β1,τ Public InsuranceB,C orDit × 1(t = τ)

+β2 Public InsuranceB,C orDit

+β3 Public InsuranceAit + µt + δc + λa + εit

(2)

where each β1,τ is the coefficient of the interaction between a quarterly dummy and14The norm that decreased the copayment for PAD delivery was approved on February 11th,

2003, but it came into force on April 2nd, 2003.

13

Page 14: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

the treatment dummy, taking the 4th quarter of 2002 as the baseline. The blue

line in Figure 5 shows the time-varying coefficients from equation (2). Although

most of the pre-treatment impacts are non-significant, we reject the null that all

pre-treatment coefficients are zero. This failure to reject the null hypothesis is likely

related to an anticipatory effect (discussed below) and some significant (but small

in magnitude) impact in the first quarters of 2001. We check the robustness of our

results to pre-existent trends by including a linear trend in the treatment group and

other robustness checks in Section 2.5.

Notice in Figure 5 that the impacts of the program start in the first quarter of

2003, which is in the quarter immediately previous to the policy. This anticipation

effect is related with a drop in the c-section rates of PAD private hospitals during

the months previous to the policy (see Figure A.3 in the Appendix), and therefore

with the drop in the rates for women with private insurance (see Figure 4b above).

One rationale for this anticipation is that the temporary drop in c-section rates is

related to increases in capacity ahead of the expansion triggered by the policy. The

relationship between hospital utilization and the c-section rates is further explored

in Section 3.15

As a robustness check for the dynamic impact of reform, we estimate an alterna-

tive specification that intends to correct for pre-existing linear trends, which takes15Recall that the policy was implemented in April 2003 but the norm was issued in February.

14

Page 15: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 5: Time-varying effects of the program on the probability of a c-section

the form:

Yit = β0 +∑T

τ≥T β1,τ Public InsuranceB,C orDit × 1(t = τ)

+β2 Public InsuranceB,C orDit + β3 Public InsuranceA

+β4 Public InsuranceB,C orDit × t+ µt + δc + λa + εit

(3)

where T corresponds to the start of the post-reform period equation (3). There-

fore, this specification keeps the period-treatment interactions only for the post-

policy period while estimating a linear trend in time interacted with the treatment

variable in the pre-period.16 The post-policy treatment coefficients, shown in a red16We do not include interactions for the pre-period to avoid multicollinearity with the linear

trend.

15

Page 16: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

dashed line, are therefore estimated relative to a counterfactual that the observed

pre-trend had continued after the policy. As it is apparent, most of the impact of

the policy remains even when we control for this linear trend.

2.4 Results

Table 2 presents the estimates of equation (1) for the probability of delivery at a

PAD private hospital (columns (1) to (3)) and the probability of a c-section (columns

(4) to (6)). Columns (1) and (4) report the estimates for the basic model, columns

(2) and (5) include age-year and county-year interactions, and columns (3) and (6)

add linear trends in the treatment group (public insurance B, C, and D) and in

public insurance A.

Our estimates indicate that, as a consequence of the policy, the probability of

delivery at a PAD private hospital increased between 7 (when we include linear

trends on the treatment group) and 15 percentage points, and the probability of a

c-section increased between 3.1 and 8.7 percentage points. In terms of the sample

means (for the treatment group in the pre-treatment period), this implies an increase

between 104% and 224% for the probability of delivery at a PAD private hospital

and between 13% and 35% for the probability of a c-section. The specification with

linear trends in columns (3) and (6) should be interpreted as a lower bound because

the linear trend could also capture part of the effect of the policy.

Our interpretation of the previous results is that they are driven by supply-

side incentives unrelated to direct price incentives. However, part of these effects

can be related to an interaction of supply incentives with patients’ preferences.

For example, a plausible story is that women with public health insurance have

16

Page 17: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

a marked preference for a c-section that is “satisfied” by private hospitals but not

by public hospitals. However, the available evidence does not seem to support

this claim (for example, see McCourt et al., 2007).17 Angeja et al. (2006), using

a survey of pregnant women in Santiago, Chile, find that 77.8% of respondents

preferred vaginal delivery, and only 9.4% preferred cesarean delivery. The results

are similar for women interviewed in public hospitals (c-section rate of 22%) and

private hospitals (c-section rate of 60%).

2.5 Robustness checks

In this section, we present robustness checks to our identifying assumptions. For

space reasons, we show results for the probability of c-section only. In Section B of

the Appendix, we show the same exercises for the probability of delivery at a private

hospital.

In addition to the common trends assumption, discussed above, our identifica-

tion strategy relies on the following assumptions: no contemporaneous confounding

policy changes, and no compositional changes in the treated and comparison groups.

The first identifying assumption is that there are no contemporaneous confound-

ing policy changes. We are particularly concerned with two policies: (i) a change

in the regulatory framework for private insurance companies which restricts their

discretion to change premiums, and (ii) a new policy called AUGE/GES that grants

better coverage for individuals with certain health conditions, including preterm

birth. Regarding the first policy, the change in the regulatory framework for private17McCourt et al. (2007) reviews the research literature on consumer preferences for elective

cesarean section since 2000, and find that a very small number of women request a c-section,ranging from 0.3 to 14%.

17

Page 18: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

insurance companies was approved in May of 2005 but put into effect the following

year. Regarding the second policy, AUGE/GES was approved in 2004 but put into

effect from July 2005 onwards. We restrict our sample to the period 2001-2005, so

it would not affect our results.

In addition, we run a robustness exercise that restricts the sample to a time

window around the policy. Columns (1) to (3) of Table 3 show the impact on the

probability of a c-section for a time window of 12, 6, and 3 months around the

policy. The results imply that, if we restrict the time window to 3 months around

the policy, the probability of a c-section increases 2.8 percentage points (against 8.6

with the full-sample). This result implies an increase of 10% in the probability of a

c-section following the policy change.

The second identifying assumption is no compositional changes between treated

and comparison groups. Given that the treatment condition depends on insurance

affiliation, a concern is the possibility of women switching from private to public

insurance because of the policy.

As a first robustness check for the second assumption, in column (4) of Table 3

we show the results of equation (1) if we restrict the comparison group to women

with public insurance A, and column (5) if we add women with private insurance

to the treatment group. The rationale behind this exercise is that the policy should

not affect the composition of public insurance A, so dropping women with private

insurance (column (4)) or including women with private insurance with those in

public insurance B, C, or D (column (5)) should be robust to these concerns.

The results in column (4) with only women with public insurance A as the

comparison group are similar to the main model. The result in column (5) shows

18

Page 19: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

that, if we considered women with private insurance as part of the treatment group,

the policy would increase the probability of a c-section by 4.6 percentage points,

a 16% increase in terms of the sample mean. This effect is smaller than the main

model but still significant.

A second robustness check to further address the possible endogeneity of insur-

ance affiliation is to instrument this variable. Specifically, we use ShareGroupB,C orDac,

the share of deliveries by women with public insurance B, C or D by county and age

in the 2002 period, as an instrument for mother’s insurance affiliation. In terms of

equation (1), we instrument Public InsuranceB,C orDit and its interaction with

Postt using ShareGroupB,C orDac and its interaction Postt, respectively. There-

fore, our reduced form equation is

Yit = β0 + β1 ShareGroupB,C orDac × Postt

+β2 ShareGroupB,C orDac + µt + δc + λa + εit.(4)

Given that these instruments are only a function of the mother’s county of resi-

dence and age, the exogeneity condition is satisfied if those variables do not change

as a consequence of the policy. This seems plausible because: (i) policy eligibility

has no relationship to these variables, and (ii) neither fertility nor birth timing is

likely to be affected by a policy that increases options for delivery. The relevance

condition is satisfied because the mother’s county of residence and age are good

predictors of being in groups B, C, or D, a condition that we test using the first

stage.

Table 4 shows the estimates of the IV strategy, using the share of deliveries

by women with public insurance B, C, and D by county and age in 2002 as an

19

Page 20: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 6: Time-varying effects of the program (Reduced form using the share of deliveriesof women with public insurance B, C, and D by county and age in 2002)

instrument for individual insurance affiliation at the time of delivery. Columns (1)

and (2) of Table 4) show the OLS and IV estimates for our preferred specification

which includes mother’s age-year fixed effects, and column (3) and (4) show the first

stage estimates. The first stage estimates for our two endogenous variables show

that the relevance condition is satisfied. The IV results in column (2) indicate that

the probability of a c-section increased by 9.3 percentage points, similarly to our

OLS result in column (1).

To provide further evidence of the exogeneity of the instrument, Figure 6 shows

the reduced form estimates of a dynamic version of the equation (4) for the prob-

ability of a c-section. We observe that the coefficients fluctuate around zero before

and increase after the implementation of the policy. The timing of the impacts gives

additional support to the validity of the instrument, as it is unlikely that it affects

20

Page 21: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

the outcome directly and not only through the policy.

In Section C of the Appendix, we show additional robustness checks and placebo

regressions. Specifically, we first show that our results are robust to a placebo

experiment assuming that the policy took place one year earlier (April 2002). We

also show that the policy has no impact on mother characteristics, which supports

our assumptions regarding compositional changes. Finally, in Section D of the

Appendix, we use birth data and the specification in equation (4) to show that

the policy caused a decrease in birth weight and gestational age, which is consistent

with the increase in c-sections.

3 A model of maternity services

In this section, we propose a demand-smoothing mechanism that could explain why

profit-maximizing hospitals have higher c-section rates when price incentives are ab-

sent. To understand this mechanism, we develop a model of hospital decisions about

the mode of delivery without price incentives. We use this model to understand the

main trade-off between margins and quantity behind the decision about the mode

of delivery.

Although this demand-smoothing mechanism is theoretically plausible, there is a

question of whether it is quantitively relevant. To answer this question, we calibrate

an extended version of the model and run counterfactual experiments. Specifically,

we quantify the effect of limiting the c-section rate of private hospitals on their profits

and capacity utilization. In addition, we use the model to analyze the correlation

between changes in capacity utilization and changes in c-section rates during the

21

Page 22: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

pre-post policy period.

3.1 Main assumptions

An infinite lived, profit-maximizing hospital chooses the mode of delivery for women

requiring maternity services. The hospital is a price-taker and has a capacity of K,

i.e. it can make at most K deliveries in a period. In each period t, the hospital

faces a demand for maternity services of N women, with N ≤ N ≤ K.18 We define

n = NK

and, to simplify notation, normalize K to one. 19 Consequently, all variables

should be interpreted in terms of K.

We assume that women requiring maternity services: (i) do not have any medical

indication regarding the mode of delivery, (ii) are indifferent about having a vaginal

or cesarean delivery, and (iii) are willing to pay a single price p > 0 regardless of

the mode of delivery.

We also assume that performing a c-section is more costly for the hospital. Specif-

ically, we assume that the cost of a vaginal delivery is c, with 0 < c < p, and the

cost of a c-section is c (1 + y), with 0 < y < y.

The problem of the hospital each period t is to allocate αt n cases to vaginal

deliveries and (1−αt)n to c-sections, to maximize the discounted expected value of

future profits.

The timing of the model is represented in Figure 7. At the beginning of period

t, the hospital chooses αt. Cesarean deliveries can be scheduled and we assume that18N can be interpreted as the number of women who get prenatal care from doctors or midwives

working at the hospital.19In the basic model that we will present below, the hospital’s profit function is linear in K and

the solution of the problem is independent of K. In the extended model that we calibrate withthe data, the solution depends on K.

22

Page 23: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

t− 1 t t+ 1 t+ 2

αt−1

(1− αt−1)n c-sections

αt−1n vaginal deliveries

αt

(1− αt)n c-sections

αtn vaginal deliveries

αt+1

(1− αt+1)n c-sections

αt+1n vaginal deliveries

Figure 7: Timing of the model

the hospital performs the (1−αt)n c-sections in period t.20Vaginal deliveries, on the

other hand, cannot be scheduled so the actual period of delivery is uncertain.21 We

assume that a vaginal delivery allocated in t can occur in t (early-term births) or

t+ 1 (full-term births).

We assume that the hospital knows αt−1 when choosing αt but it does not have

information about the realization of vaginal deliveries in t− 1.22

The number of vaginal deliveries that the hospital performs in period t, Yt,

consists of: (i) women with full-term births from the αt−1n cases allocated to vaginal

delivery in t−1, and (ii) women with early-term births from the αtn cases allocated in

t. We assume that Yt is a continuous random variable drawn from a distribution with

density f (yt;αt−1, αt, n), such that its expectation E(Yt;αt−1, αt, n) and variance20This is a mild assumption because, with a constant demand for maternity services, i.e. constant

n, the hospital has no incentives to schedule any of the (1− αt)n c-sections in t+ 1.21Even though hospitals can schedule inductions that do end up in vaginal births, we make this

assumption in relative terms with c-sections.22Underlying this assumption is the presence of a lag between enrollment and deliveries so that

a hospital has limited information about deliveries (allocated in t− 1) when it makes an allocationdecision at t.

23

Page 24: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

V ar(Yt;αt−1, αt, n) are increasing in αt−1, αt and n. 23

In period t, after the hospital allocates a capacity of (1− αt)n to c-sections, the

remaining capacity for vaginal deliveries is:

kv(αt, n) = 1− (1− αt)n.

Due to the uncertainty in the timing of vaginal deliveries and the limited capacity

of the hospital, there are situations where the hospital is capacity constrained and

must refer some women to another hospital. Therefore, the actual number of vaginal

deliveries at t is given by:

qv (Yt, αt, n) = min{Yt, kv(αt, n)}.

We assume that referrals are costly for the hospital in terms of reputation and

includes an additional cost equal to θ times the number of referrals. The number of

referrals at t are given by:

qr (Yt,αt, n) = max{0, Yt − kv(αt, n)}.

Given the previous assumptions, the hospital’s profit function at t can be written

as

π(Yt, αt;n) = (p− c)qv (Yt, αt, n) + (p− c(1 + y))[(1− αt)n]− θ qr (Yt,αt, n) ,23These assumptions are meant to capture that expectation and variance of vaginal deliveries

must be increasing in the number of women allocated to vaginal deliveries in t and t− 1, αtn andαt−1n respectively.

24

Page 25: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

where the first term is the hospital’s profit from performing vaginal deliveries, the

second term is the profit from c-sections, and the third term is the cost of referrals.

Hospital’s problem

The hospital chooses the share of vaginal deliveries {αt}∞t=1 to maximize the expected

present value of future profits

max{αt}∞t=1

E

[∞∑t=1

δtπ(Yt, αt;n)|It

],

where 0 ≤ δ ≤ 1 is the discount factor, and It is the information available at t.

Given the recursive nature of the problem, we can solve an equivalent problem

using the Bellman equation

V (αt−1) = max0≤αt≤1

E [π(Yt, αt;n)|αt−1] + δV (αt),

where the expected profit is

E [π(Yt, αt;n)|αt−1] =(p− c)E [qv(Yt, αt;n)|αt−1] + (p− c(1 + y))[(1− αt)n]

− θ E [qr(Yt, αt;n)|αt−1] .

3.2 Basic model

To obtain an analytical solution and understand the main mechanism in the model,

first, we assume that Yt follows a uniform distribution between 0 and (αt−1 + αt)n:

25

Page 26: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Yt ∼ U(0, (αt−1 + αt)n).24 25 Under this distributional assumption, the expected

profit is:26

E [π(Yt, αt;n)|αt−1] = (p− c){kv(αt, n)

(1− kv(αt, n)

2(αt−1 + αt)n

)}+ (p− c (1 + y)) [(1− αt)n]

− θ[[(αt−1 + αt)n− kv(αt, n)]2

2(αt−1 + αt)n

].

Steady-state equilibrium

We solve the steady-state equilibrium with a constant α∗. In the steady-state equi-

librium, the first-order condition for optimality is

(p− c)[n− kv(α∗, n)

2α∗

(1− (1 + δ)kv(α∗, n)

4α∗n

)]− (p− c(1 + y))n

− θ[kv(α∗, n)

2α∗

(1− (1 + δ)kv(α∗, n)

4α∗n

)− (1− δ)n

2

]= 0. (5)

The first term in equation (5) is the increase in profits (due to an increase in αt)

from performing more vaginal deliveries in t and t+1; the second term indicates the

foregone profits due to a decrease in c-sections, and the third term is the increase

24Under Yt ∼ U(0, (αt−1+αt)n), we have that E(Yt) =(αt−1+αt)

2 n and V ar(Yt) =(αt−1+αt)

2

12 n2.The expectation is consistent with each vaginal delivery having a probability of 1

2 of being full-termand taking the expectation over the sum of vaginal deliveries allocated in t and t+ 1.

25In section 3.3 we will use a more flexible distribution to calibrate the model with the data andto run counterfactual experiments.

26This is the expected profit function when vaginal deliveries are capacity constrained, i.e.kv(αt, n) ≤ (αt−1 + αt)n. This is the relevant case because it is never optimal for the hospi-tal to choose αt such as there is excess capacity for vaginal deliveries. If that is the case, thehospital can substitute c-sections for vaginal deliveries one-to-one, without doing any referrals,increasing its profits.

26

Page 27: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

in reputational costs (with the expression in brackets being positive for a δ high

enough).

To understand the main mechanism in this model, suppose that θ = 0 and δ = 1

and rewrite the first-order condition as

(p− c)[n− kv∗(α∗, n)

2α∗

(1− kv(α∗, n)

2α∗n

)]= (p− c(1 + y))n. (6)

This equation provides the basic intuition of the mechanism. In the margin, an

increase in αt increases the number of vaginal deliveries (term between brackets in

the left-hand side) by less that it decreases c-sections (equals to n in the right-hand

side), so the total number of deliveries decreases (a negative quantity effect). How-

ever, the net effect on profits can be positive because vaginal deliveries have higher

margins (a positive price effect). Both effects cancel each other out in equilibrium.

27

The solution of the steady state α∗ is

α∗ =

1−nnz(p, c, y, θ, δ) if n ≥ n(p, c, y, θ),

1 if n < n(p, c, y, θ),

where z(p, c, y, θ, δ) = 2√

(p−c+θ)(p−c−2cy(1+δ)+δ2θ)−(1−δ)(p−c+δ)(3−δ)(p−c)+(3δ−1)θ−8cy and n(p, c, y, θ) = 1/(1+

z(p, c, y, θ, δ)).28

27Moreover, the marginal increase in vaginal deliveries is decreasing in α∗: there are decreasingreturns to scale of increasing αt.

28In the basic model, we have y = (3−δ)(p−c)+(3δ−1)θ8c . If we assume δ = 1 and θ = 0 then

27

Page 28: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Comparative statics

It is straightforward to show that the share of vaginal deliveries in steady state, α∗

is decreasing in the demand, n, the price of deliveries, p, and the cost of referrals,

θ. Moreover, α∗ is increasing in the cost of vaginal deliveries, c, and in the cost

premium of c-sections, y.

The interpretation of why α∗ decreases with the demand for maternity services n

comes again from the first-order condition in equation (6). Mathematically, the ratio

between the marginal increase in vaginal deliveries,[kv(α∗,n)

2α∗

(1− (1+δ)kv(α∗,n)

4α∗n

)]and

the marginal decrease in c-sections, n, is decreasing in n. In other words, when

n increases the hospital must sacrifice more c-sections if it wants to perform an

additional vaginal delivery. This is mainly driven by the positive relation between

and n and the variance of vaginal deliveries. 29

Figure 8 illustrates that α∗ is decreasing in n for p = 1, c = 0.7, y = 0.15,

θ = 0.5, and δ = 1.

3.3 Calibration

We extend the basic model to replicate some features in the data and run coun-

terfactual experiments. The main difference between this extended model and the

basic model is that now the optimal policy of a given hospital i will depend on its

y ≤ 14(p−c)c , that is the additional cost of a c-section should be less than 25% of the margin for

vaginal deliveries.29Specifically, when we increase n we have, on the one hand, an increase of both the mean of

the distribution of vaginal deliveries and the capacity allocated to vaginal deliveries by the samemagnitude (recall that kv(αt, n) = 1 − (1 − αt)n). However, increasing n also raises the varianceof the distribution therefore, the mean of vaginal deliveries performed increase by less than theincrease in the mean of the distribution of vaginal deliveries.

28

Page 29: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

n

α∗

12

10

1

n

Figure 8: Equilibrium α

capacity, Ki.30 We calibrate the model using data on private hospitals for the period

2006–2007. For details on the extended model and the calibration see Section E in

the Appendix.

Table 5 shows the c-section rate, capacity utilization, and standard deviation of

vaginal deliveries for the data and the model. The model replicates the moments

that σ and θ are trying to match in the data: the average c-section rate and ca-

pacity utilization. Remarkably, the model also predicts a standard deviation (SD)

of vaginal deliveries (a moment not used in the calibration) that is similar to that

observed in the data.31

Figure 9 shows the fit of the model with the cross-section of hospitals: Panel

(A) for c-section rates and Panel (B) for capacity utilization. In general, the model

captures the correlations between these variables and hospital capacity. In the case

of the c-section rate, the model predicts more dispersion than what we observe in

the data, which is not surprising given that this is a very stylized model with only30We also use a more flexible functional form for the distribution of vaginal deliveries.31As shown in the Appendix, the model does also a good job predicting the cross-sectional

distribution of SD of vaginal deliveries.

29

Page 30: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 9: Model fitNotes: The graph reports c-section rates and capacity utilization for PAD private hospitals. For each hospital, a

black circle is the mean c-section rate or capacity utilization in 2006–2007 and a blue cross is the prediction of the

same variable from the model. Hospital capacity is the 90 percentile of weekly births in the period 2006–2007.

one source of uncertainty. The negative relationship between c-section rates and

hospital capacity in Panel (A) of Figure 9 suggests that small hospitals are more

vulnerable to fluctuations in deliveries than the large hospitals and thus are more

likely to use c-sections to avoid referrals.

3.4 Counterfactual experiments

We use the calibrated model to quantify the opportunity cost of hospitals when they

reduce their c-section rates. To do so, we run two counterfactual experiments. In

both experiments, we assume that each hospital is forced to choose the allocation of

deliveries to have a c-section rate of .26, which is the average c-section rate for public

hospitals in 2006–2007. Table 6 shows summary statistics for both experiments.

Panels (A) through (D) of Figure 10 show the c-section rate, capacity utilization,

30

Page 31: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

number of referrals, and profits, respectively, for each hospital in the baseline and

the counterfactuals experiments.

In Experiment 1, we assume that each hospital must reduce its c-section rate

but keeping the demand fixed, which, in other words, means that hospitals accept

the same number of cases as in our baseline scenario.

As shown in Table 6, the limit in the c-section rates forces hospitals to decrease

their capacity utilization from 65% to 62%. Given that hospitals increase the share

of vaginal deliveries while receiving the same number of cases, they increase their

ratio of referrals to capacity from 2% to 5%. Therefore, it is more likely that

hospitals have to refer elsewhere part of the vaginal deliveries they have previously

committed to attend if a large number of them happen to occur at the same time.

Given the moderate decrease in capacity utilization, the 14% drop in profits is mainly

explained by the reputational costs due to the sharp increase in referrals. Notice

in Panel (C) and (D) of Figure 10 that the increase in referrals and their negative

effects on profits are concentrated in smaller hospitals (those with a capacity below

25 deliveries per week).

In Experiment 1 we have assumed that hospitals keep accepting the same number

of patients as in our baseline scenario despite incurring high costs in the form of

lost reputation. It seems more realistic to assume that hospitals prefer to accept

fewer cases beforehand to avoid this reputation cost. Therefore, in Experiment 2,

on top to the same limit to c-section rates than in Experiment 1 (0.26), we set an

upper bound to the ratio of referrals to capacity of 2% and adjust the demand for

maternity services n for each hospital accordingly (see Panel (C) of Figure 10).32

32In the baseline scenario, the maximum rejection rate was 1.75% so the 2% is not restrictivefor the baseline model.

31

Page 32: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 10: Counterfactual experimentsNotes: The graph reports c-section rates (A), capacity utilization (B), referrals (C) and profits (D) for PAD private

hospitals for the baseline and two counterfactual experiments.

Experiment 1 sets a c-section rate of 0.26 (the mean c-section rate for public and non-PAD private hospitals) for

each hospital. Experiment 2 sets a c-section rate of 0.26 and an upper bound on the ratio of referrals over capacity

of 0.02 for each hospital.

Hospital capacity is the 90 percentile of weekly births in the period 2006–2007.

32

Page 33: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

As shown in Table 6, in Experiment 2, profits decrease by 12% (versus 14% in

Experiment 1), but the limit in referrals implies that hospitals reduce their capacity

utilization by 24% (5% in Experiment 1). Therefore, unlike the previous experiment,

here the lower profits are explained by the decrease in capacity utilization rather

than by reputational costs. Panels (B) and (D) of Figure 10 show that, as it was

the case in Experiment 1, the drop in capacity utilization and profits occurs mainly

in smaller hospitals.

3.5 Policy analysis

The main prediction of our basic model is that c-section rates are increasing in

hospitals’ capacity utilization. In this section, we use data on hospital utilization

rates before and after the policy, and our calibrated model, to study if the demand-

smoothing mechanism can explain, at least in part, the observed behavior in the

c-section rates of PAD hospitals.

As shown in Table 7, average capacity utilization in private PAD hospitals in-

creased from 65% in 2001–2002 (before the policy) to 67% in 2006-2007 (after the

policy). An important feature of this period is that, at the hospital level, this change

in capacity utilization is positively correlated with changes in c-section rates. Fig-

ure 11, which displays changes in capacity utilization (in the horizontal axis) and

changes in c-section rates (in the vertical axis), clearly shows that hospitals that

increased their capacity utilization tend to increase their c-section rates and vice

versa.

We use the calibrated model to study the relationship between utilization and

c-section rates. To do so, we choose hospital demand for each hospital to match ca-

33

Page 34: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Figure 11: Changes in c-section rates vs changes in utilization ratesNotes: The graph reports changes in c-section rates and capacity utilization between 2001–2002 (before) and 2006–

2007 (after) for PAD private hospitals.

Figure 12: Policy simulationNotes: The graph reports changes in c-section rates and capacity utilization between 2001–2002 (before) and 2006–

2007 (after) for PAD private hospitals. For each hospital, a black circle refers to the data and a blue cross is the

prediction from the model.

34

Page 35: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

pacity utilization in 2001–2002 (before the policy) and 2006–2007 (after the policy).

Keeping each hospital capacity fixed at the 2006–2007 level, we solve the c-section

rate for each hospital before and after. Table 7 shows that the model predicts an

increase of 6 percentage points in the c-section rate, slightly over-predicting the

change observed in the data (5 percentage points). More importantly, the model

also replicates the positive correlation between changes in capacity utilization and

c-section rate across hospitals. Figure 12 compares the model with the data: black

circles represent actual data and blue crosses represent the model simulation. The

linear fits show that these changes are positively correlated in the data and the

model, even though this correlation is higher in the model.

This simulation provides further evidence that the demand-smoothing incentive

for cesarean deliveries can explain, at least, part of the effects of the policy.

4 Expected demand and scheduling of deliveries

The model of the previous section shows that a profit-maximizing hospital can use a

high c-section rate to neutralize the random component of vaginal deliveries. Here we

will provide evidence that private hospitals use c-sections to accommodate deliveries

when demand fluctuates from week to week. Therefore, our hypothesis is that high

c-section rate hospitals smooth out demand over time by moving deliveries between

high and low demand weeks.

If our hypothesis is correct, the actual date of birth of a baby should change

as a function of the expected demand for deliveries in a given hospital. That is,

hospitals may manipulate the date of birth for babies conceived at week w if they

35

Page 36: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

expect a higher than normal number of deliveries at their due date (week w + 40).

In this section, we show evidence that an early-term birth is more likely to occur if

a delivery was originally due in a high-demand week for the hospital.

4.1 Data and empirical strategy

We use birth certificates data from DEIS for the period 2002–201633, which contains

the name of the hospital, birth date and gestational age (and therefore the week of

conception). The data also include information on weight and size at birth, whether

it is a singleton birth or not, and mother’s characteristics (age, county of residence,

marital status, number of children, educational level and labor force participation).

Table 8 reports summary statistics for birth data.

To measure expected hospital demand in a week, we add all potential births in

a week for a hospital, assuming full-term delivery (at a gestational age of 40 weeks),

regardless of the actual date of birth. Then, to identify high and low expected

demand weeks, we use the 25th, 50th and 75th percentiles of the distribution of

expected demand for a hospital in a given year.

Given our definition of high and low expected demand weeks, we want to know if

the probability of an early-term birth (on week 37 or 38) depends on the hospital’s

expected demand during week 40 of that pregnancy. To do that, we estimate the

following equation:33The dataset begins in the 2nd half of 2002 because the hospital name has only been reported

consistently since that date.

36

Page 37: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Yi,h,w = β0 + β1 demand−25−50−pctlh,w+40 + β2 demand−50−75−pctlh,w+40

+β3 demand−75−moreh,w+40 + β4Xi,h,w + µh,m + δc + λa,y + εi,w

(7)

where Yi,h,w is a dummy for early-term birth (on week 37 or 38) for baby i, born in

hospital h and conceived in week w. Here, demand−25−50−pctl, demand−50−75−pctl

and demand−75−more are dummies indicating the percentile of expected demand

(between the 25th and 50th percentile, between the 50th and 75th percentile, or

above the 75th percentile, respectively) in week w+40 for hospital h, and Xi,h,w in-

cludes a singleton birth dummy and the mother’s characteristics (number of children,

educational level, and marital status), while µh,m is a hospital-month interaction,

δc is a mother’s county of residence fixed effect, and λa,y is a mother’s age-year

interaction.34

The β’s in equation (7) measure the effect of a high expected demand on the

probability of an early-term birth.

Our main source of variation here is the week of conception in a month for a

given hospital. Identification relies on the week of conception being “as good as

randomly assigned” within a hospital-month of conception cell, which we believe is

a credible assumption.35

34Table F.1 in the Appendix shows similar results using a linear and a quadratic specification,being the results consistent with those from the nonlinear specification.

35This specification has the implicit assumption that there are not referrals to other hospitals.However, the results in this section are robust to an alternative specification with the “demand”variable based on the number of births in the county rather than those at a given hospital. SeeTable F.2 in the Appendix.

37

Page 38: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

4.2 Results

Table 9 shows the effects of expected demand on the probability of an early-term

birth for public and non-PAD private hospitals (column (1)), and for PAD private

hospitals (column (2)). The impact of high expected demand on early-term birth

for public and non-PAD private hospitals is close to zero, but this is not the case for

PAD private hospitals. Specifically, we find that if a baby is due on a high expected

demand week, the probability of an early-term birth increases by 0.4/0.8 percentage

points. In terms of the sample mean, this is around a 1.1/2.2% increase given that

36% of births in our sample occur on week 37 or 38. Therefore, our results point to

private hospitals scheduling deliveries as a function of their expected demand. .

Given these results, we may expect that private hospitals with high c-section

rates have greater flexibility to use c-sections to accommodate deliveries between

high and low-demand weeks. Therefore, in Table 10, we allow for heterogeneous

effects for hospitals with different c-section rates, by classifying them in terciles by

their average fraction of c-sections. Table 10 shows that we did not find an effect of

high expected demand on hospitals with low c-section rates (≤ 25%, column (1)).

Therefore, the impact of expected demand appears to be concentrated in hospitals

where c-sections represent more than 40% of deliveries. Note that the effect increases

with expected demand, as shown in column (3).36

36Our results are robust to alternative specifications, such linear and quadratic functions onexpected deliveries. See Appendix.

38

Page 39: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

5 Discussion and conclusion

In the previous sections, we have analyzed the connection between private hospitals

and c-section rates. First, in Section 2 we have shown that a policy change in Chile

that increased delivery in private hospitals by reducing the out-of-pocket cost for

women with public health insurance produced a sizable increase in c-section rates

despite private hospitals receiving the same price for cesarean or vaginal deliveries.

Given that the policy studied here implies a flat delivery price, independent of the

mode of delivery, it is unlikely that price incentives are the main channel behind

the results, as for example in Gruber et al. (1999), or more recently in Allin et al.

(2015) and Foo et al. (2017).37

The results from our model of Section 3 and the empirical evidence in Section 4

suggest that the demand-smoothing mechanism, i.e. hospitals scheduling c-sections

to increase the total number of deliveries, may be one factor behind the higher c-

section rate in private hospitals. C-sections allow hospitals to smooth the timing of

deliveries in two different dimensions. First, as shown in the model of Section 3, by

scheduling deliveries that otherwise may occur at the same time due to the random

timing of vaginal births. Second, as shown in Section 4, by rescheduling a delivery

when the demand for maternity services fluctuates from week to week.

Even though it seems that the demand-smoothing mechanism is indeed playing

a role in explaining c-section rates in private hospitals, we cannot rule out that other

mechanisms can be at work (other than a price mechanism).

One explanation for the higher number of c-sections in the private sector is37Gruber and Owings (1996) took a different approach and used changes in fertility rates in

the US from 1970 to 1982 to estimate the causal effect of decreased demand on the behavior ofobstetricians/gynecologists (performing vaginal or cesarean delivery).

39

Page 40: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

related to defensive medicine. Hospitals may react to fears of medical liability by

providing suboptimal care, performing either more or fewer procedures than what

would be medically necessary. Even though liability pressure has been traditionally

linked with a higher c-section rate (see, for example Dubay et al., 1999), some

recent evidence show lack of effects (e.g. Frakes, 2012) or even negative effects (see

for example Currie and MacLeod, 2008).38

Another possible factor is procedural skill (see Currie and MacLeod, 2016). It

may be the case that physicians at private hospitals are more likely to be surgically

skilled than those at public hospitals. However, we still need an explanation for

private hospitals being more prone to hiring more surgically skilled doctors. Even

though procedural skill may explain why there is a variation in c-section rates across

hospitals (even controlling for observed characteristics of the pregnancies), it does

not necessarily explain why some type of hospitals (private hospitals) have system-

atically higher c-section rates than other types (public hospitals).

A third explanation is related to hospital congestion. For example, Facchini

(2020), using data from a large public hospital in Italy and (unlike our case) leaving

out all scheduled deliveries, finds that c-sections are more likely when there is a high

patient/midwife ratio.39 The main difference between this paper and the literature

on hospital congestion is that, while these papers investigate whether hospitals are

more likely to perform c-sections when faced with unexpected demand, we are con-

cerned with hospitals systematically using c-sections to program their deliveries.38In a recent paper, Frakes and Gruber (2020) find, using the fact that active-duty patients

treated in military facilities cannot sue for negligent care, that liability immunity increases cesareanutilization.

39Moreover, Using data on maternity admissions for 30 hospitals in Washington state, Balakr-ishnan and Soderstrom (2000) only find a correlation between c-sections and “congested” days forpregnancies that were classified as at risk for c-section, but not for the full sample of patients.

40

Page 41: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Similar to the case of procedural skill, we also believe that the congestion argument

is unlikely to explain the permanent differences in c-section rates by type of hospital,

like those we have observed in Chile in the last two decades.

41

Page 42: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

References

Alexander, J. M., K. J. Leveno, J. Hauth, M. B. Landon, E. Thom, C. Y. Spong,

M. W. Varner, A. H. Moawad, S. N. Caritis, M. Harper, R. J. Wapner, Y. Sorokin,

M. Miodovnik, M. J. O’Sullivan, B. M. Sibai, O. Langer, and S. G. Gabbe (2006).

Fetal injury associated with cesarean delivery. Obstetrics & Gynecology 108 (4),

885–890.

Allin, S., M. Baker, M. Isabelle, and M. Stabile (2015). Physician incentives and

the rise in C-sections: Evidence from Canada. Working Paper 21022, National

Bureau of Economic Research.

Ananth, C. V., J. C. Smulian, and A. M. Vintzileos (1997). The association of

placenta previa with history of cesarean delivery and abortion: A metaanalysis.

American Journal of Obstetrics and Gynecology 177 (5), 1071–1078.

Angeja, A., A. Washington, J. Vargas, R. Gomez, I. Rojas, and A. Caughey (2006,

2018/12/17). Chilean women’s preferences regarding mode of delivery: which do

they prefer and why? BJOG: An International Journal of Obstetrics & Gynae-

cology 113 (11), 1253–1258.

Balakrishnan, R. and N. S. Soderstrom (2000, 09). The cost of system conges-

tion: Evidence from the healthcare sector. Journal of Management Accounting

Research 12, 97–114.

Betrán, A. P., J. Ye, A.-B. Moller, J. Zhang, A. M. Gülmezoglu, and M. R. Torloni

(2016, 02). The increasing trend in caesarean section rates: Global, regional and

national estimates: 1990-2014. PLOS ONE 11 (2), 1–12.

42

Page 43: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Borra, C., L. González, and A. Sevilla (2019). The impact of scheduling birth early

on infant health. Journal of the European Economic Association 17 (1), 30–78.

Borrescio-Higa, F. and N. Valdés (2019). Publicly insured caesarean sections in

private hospitals: a repeated cross-sectional analysis in chile. BMJ Open 9 (4).

Card, D., A. Fenizia, and D. Silver (2018). The health effects of cesarean delivery

for low-risk first births. Working paper.

Costa-Ramón, A. M., A. Rodríguez-González, M. Serra-Burriel, and C. Campillo-

Artero (2018). It’s about time: Cesarean sections and neonatal health. Journal

of Health Economics 59, 46 – 59.

Currie, J. and W. B. MacLeod (2008). First do no harm? tort reform and birth

outcomes. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123 (2), 795–830.

Currie, J. and W. B. MacLeod (2016). Diagnosing expertise: Human capital,

decision making, and performance among physicians. Journal of Labor Eco-

nomics 35 (1), 1–43.

Dubay, L., R. Kaestner, and T. Waidmann (1999). The impact of malpractice fears

on cesarean section rates. J Health Econ 18 (4), 491–522.

Facchini, G. (2020). Low staffing in the maternity wards: Keep calm and call the

surgeon. Working paper.

FONASA (2017). Boletín estadístico 2015–2016. https://www.fonasa.cl/sites/

fonasa/adjuntos/Bolet%C3%ADn%20Estad%C3%ADstico%202015-2016.

43

Page 44: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Foo, P. K., R. S. Lee, and K. Fong (2017). Physician prices, hospital prices,

and treatment choice in labor and delivery. American Journal of Health Eco-

nomics 3 (3), 422–453.

Frakes, M. (2012). Defensive medicine and obstetric practices. Journal of Empirical

Legal Studies 9 (3), 457–481.

Frakes, M. and J. Gruber (2020). Defensive medicine and obstetric practices: Evi-

dence from the military health system. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 17 (1),

4–37.

Gruber, J., J. Kim, and D. Mayzlin (1999). Physician fees and procedure intensity:

the case of cesarean delivery. Journal of Health Economics 18 (4), 473–490.

Gruber, J. and M. Owings (1996). Physician financial incentives and cesarean section

delivery. The RAND Journal of Economics 27 (1), 99–123.

Hoxha, I., L. Syrogiannouli, X. Luta, K. Tal, D. C. Goodman, B. R. da Costa, and

P. Jüni (2017). Caesarean sections and for-profit status of hospitals: systematic

review and meta-analysis. BMJ Open 7 (2).

Hyde, M. J., A. Mostyn, N. Modi, and P. R. Kemp (2012). The health implications

of birth by caesarean section. Biological Reviews 87 (1), 229–243.

Johnson, E. M. and M. M. Rehavi (2016). Physicians treating physicians: Infor-

mation and incentives in childbirth. American Economic Journal: Economic

Policy 8 (1), 115–41.

44

Page 45: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Lien, H.-M., S.-Y. Chou, and J.-T. Liu (2008). Hospital ownership and perfor-

mance: Evidence from stroke and cardiac treatment in taiwan. Journal of Health

Economics 27 (5), 1208 – 1223.

McCourt, C., J. Weaver, H. Statham, S. Beake, J. Gamble, and D. K. Creedy (2007).

Elective cesarean section and decision making: A critical review of the literature.

Birth 34 (1), 65–79.

Murray, S. F. (2000). Relation between private health insurance and high rates of

caesarean section in chile: qualitative and quantitative study. BMJ 321 (7275),

1501–1505.

Sanderson, E. and F. Windmeijer (2016). A weak instrument f-test in linear iv

models with multiple endogenous variables. Journal of Econometrics 190 (2), 212

– 221. Endogeneity Problems in Econometrics.

Shen, Y.-C. (2002). The effect of hospital ownership choice on patient outcomes after

treatment for acute myocardial infarction. Journal of Health Economics 21 (5),

901 – 922.

Villar, J., G. Carroli, N. Zavaleta, A. Donner, D. Wojdyla, A. Faundes, A. Ve-

lazco, V. Bataglia, A. Langer, A. Narváez, E. Valladares, A. Shah, L. Cam-

podónico, M. Romero, S. Reynoso, K. S. de Pádua, D. Giordano, M. Kublickas,

and A. Acosta (2007). Maternal and neonatal individual risks and benefits asso-

ciated with caesarean delivery: Multicentre prospective study. BMJ 335 (7628),

1025.

45

Page 46: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 1: Descriptive statistics for hospital discharge data,2002

Variables Mean s.d.

Cesarean section rate 0.28 0.45

in PAD private hospitals 0.56 0.50

in non-PAD private hospitals 0.30 0.46

in public hospitals 0.23 0.42

Delivery at a PAD private hospital 0.15 0.36

Delivery at a non-PAD private hospital 0.03 0.17

Delivery at a public hospital 0.82 0.38

Public insurance A 0.48 0.50

Public insurance B, C or D 0.38 0.49

Private insurance 0.14 0.34

Age 26.8 6.8

Patient’s length of stay 3.3 1.9

Observations 850, 007

Source: Departamento de Estadísticas e Información deSalud (DEIS), Ministerio de Salud, Chile.

46

Page 47: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 2: Effect of decreasing copayments on PAD delivery

Delivery at a PAD hospital Cesarean section

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Public Insurance B, C or D

× Post

0.150∗∗∗ 0.145∗∗∗ 0.070∗∗∗ 0.087∗∗∗ 0.086∗∗∗ 0.031∗∗∗

[0.001] [0.001] [0.002] [0.002] [0.002] [0.004]

Age-Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

County-Year FE No Yes Yes No Yes Yes

Linear trend Public Ins. A No No Yes No No Yes

Linear trend Public Ins. B, C, D No No Yes No No Yes

Mean DV 0.067 0.252

R-squared 0.431 0.445 0.446 0.114 0.121 0.122

Observations 850,004 849,991 849,991 850,004 849,991 849,991

Note: This table reports DID estimates of the effect of decreasing copayments on PAD delivery on

the probability of delivery at a PAD private hospital and the probability of a cesarean delivery. PAD

private hospitals are hospitals that participate in the PAD program but are not in the public

healthcare system. Public Insurance’s B, C or D is a dummy for a delivery by a woman with public

insurance’s B, C or D, and Post is a dummy that equals one after April 2003.

All regressions include mother’s county of residence and age fixed effects, and month fixed effects.

Columns (3) and (6) include linear trends in public insurance A and in public insurance B, C or D.

The mean of dependent variable corresponds to the treated in the pre-treatment period.

Robust standard errors reported in brackets.

∗∗∗ Significant at the 1 percent level.

∗∗ Significant at the 5 percent level.

∗ Significant at the 10 percent level.

47

Page 48: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 3: Effect of decreasing copayments on the probability of a c-section: Robustness

Different windows Public insurance A Private insurance

± 12 months ±6 months ± 3 months as control as treatment

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Treatment × Post 0.051∗∗∗ 0.035∗∗∗ 0.028∗∗∗ 0.072∗∗∗ 0.046∗∗∗

[0.003] [0.004] [0.006] [0.002] [0.002]

Mean DV 0.261 0.265 0.271 0.252 0.322

R-squared 0.121 0.121 0.117 0.102 0.120

Observations 343,737 171,378 84,304 733,095 849,991

Notes: This table reports estimates of the effect of decreasing copayments on PAD delivery on the probability of a

c-section. PAD private hospitals are hospitals that participate in the PAD program but are not in the public healthcare

system. Public Insurance B, C or D is a dummy for a delivery by a woman with public insurance B, C or D, and Post is

a dummy that equals one after April 2003.

All regressions include Public Insurance A, Public Insurance B, C or D, and mother’s age-year, county, and month fixed

effects. Column (1) to (3) use different time windows around the policy (12, 6 and 3 months), columns (4) restricts the

comparison group only to women with public insurance A, and column (5) uses women with private insurance and public

insurance B, C or D as the treatment group.

The mean of dependent variable corresponds to the treated in the pre-treatment period.

Robust standard errors reported in brackets.

∗∗∗ Significant at the 1 percent level.

∗∗ Significant at the 5 percent level.

∗ Significant at the 10 percent level.

48

Page 49: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 4: IV/2SLS estimates of the effect of decreasing copayments on PAD delivery on the proba-bility of a c-section

Cesarean section First stage

OLS IV/2SLS Treatment Treatment × Post

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Public Insurance B, C or D × Post 0.087∗∗∗ 0.093∗∗∗

[0.002] [0.030]

Share Public Insurance B, C or D 0.416∗∗∗ −0.180∗∗∗

[0.012] [0.016]

Share Public Insurance B, C or D

× Post

−0.282∗∗∗ 0.401∗∗∗

[0.023] [0.036]

F stat (weak inst.) 617.2 132.3

p-value (weak inst.) 0.000 0.000

Mean DV 0.251

Observations 843,375 843,375 843,375 843,375

Notes: This table reports IV estimates of the effect of decreasing copayments on PAD delivery on the probability of a

c-section. PAD private hospitals are hospitals that participate in the PAD program but are not in the public healthcare

system. Public Insurance B, C or D is a dummy for a delivery by a woman with public insurance B, C or D, and Post is

a dummy that equals one after April 2003.

The instruments are Share Public Insurance B, C or D and its interactions with Post, where Share Public Insurance B, C

or D is the share of deliveries in 2002 by women with public insurance B, C or D of age a and living in county c.

All regressions include Public Insurance B, C or D, and mother’s age-year, county-year, and month fixed effects.

The test for weak instruments uses the F statistics and p-values from Sanderson and Windmeijer (2016).

The mean of dependent variable corresponds to the treated in the pre-treatment period.

Robust standard errors for column (1), and standard errors, clustered by mother’s county of residence, for column (2) - (4)

reported in brackets.

∗∗∗ Significant at the 1 percent level.

∗∗ Significant at the 5 percent level.

∗ Significant at the 10 percent level.

49

Page 50: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 5: Model fit: Data versus model

Data Model

C-section rate 0.63 0.64

Capacity utilization 0.67 0.65

SD(weekly deliveries) 5.95 4.16

Notes: This table reports means weighted by hospital capacity

for c-section rates, capacity utilization, and standard deviation of

weekly deliveries computed from the data and predicted by the

model.

For each hospital, a c-section rate is the ratio between the mean

of weekly cesarean deliveries and the mean of weekly deliveries,

and capacity utilization is the ratio between the mean of weekly

deliveries and hospital capacity. Hospital capacity is the 90

percentile of weekly births in the period 2006–2007.

The data uses sample means and standard deviations for the

period 2006–2007.

The model uses expectations and standard deviations for a

hospital with the same capacity as the data.

50

Page 51: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 6: Counterfactual experiments

Baseline Counterfactual 1 Counterfactual 2

Mean Change (in %) Mean Change (in %)

C-section rate 0.64 0.26 −60 0.25 −61

Capacity utilization 0.65 0.62 −5 0.50 −24

SD(weekly deliveries) 4.16 5.42 30 5.37 29

Referrals (over capacity) 0.02 0.05 200 0.02 22

Profits (over capacity) 0.80 0.69 −14 0.71 −12

Notes: This table reports means weighted by hospital capacity for different variables in the base model and

two counterfactual experiments.

Experiment 1 sets a c-section rate of 0.26 (the mean c-section rate for public and non-PAD private hospitals)

for each hospital. Experiment 2 sets a c-section rate of 0.26 and an upper bound on the ratio of transfers

over capacity of 0.02 for each hospital. c-section rate is the ratio between the mean of cesarean deliveries and

the mean of total deliveries, capacity utilization is the mean of total deliveries over the hospital capacity,

SD(weekly deliveries) is the standard deviation of weekly deliveries, transfers is the ratio between mean

transfers and hospital capacity, and profits is the ratio between mean profits and hospital capacity. Hospital

capacity is the 90 percentile of weekly births in the period 2006–2007.

Table 7: Policy simulation

Data Model

Before After Change Before After Change

C-section rate 0.57 0.63 0.05 0.64 0.70 0.06

Capacity utilization 0.65 0.67 0.02 0.65 0.67 0.02

Notes: This table reports c-section rates before (period 2001–2002) and after (2006–2007) the

policy change.

The policy simulation fix hospital capacity using the capacity in the data in 2006–2007, and

set the hospital demand for each hospital to match capacity utilization in 2001–2002 (before)

and 2006–2007 (after).

51

Page 52: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 8: Descriptive statistics for birth data, 2002-2016

Variables Mean s.d.

Delivery at a PAD private hospital 0.27 0.44

Delivery at a non-PAD private hospital 0.05 0.22

Delivery at a public hospital 0.68 0.47

Gestational age at birth (in weeks) 38.6 1.5

Early-term birth (on week 37 or 38) 0.36 0.48

Preterm 0.07 0.25

Multiple births 0.02 0.13

Mother’s age 27.4 6.7

Mother’s labor force participation 0.39 0.49

N. of children 1.9 1.0

Observations 3, 442, 284

Source: Departamento de Estadísticas e Información deSalud (DEIS), Ministerio de Salud, Chile.

52

Page 53: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 9: Effect of expected hospital demand on the probability of early-term birth

Public and

Non-PAD Private Hospitals PAD Private Hospitals

(1) (2)

25th pctl < Demand ≤ 50th pctl −0.001 0.002

[0.001] [0.002]

50th pctl < Demand ≤ 75th pctl 0.001 0.005∗∗

[0.001] [0.002]

Demand > 75th pctl 0.000 0.009∗∗∗

[0.001] [0.002]

Mean DV 0.315 0.496

R-squared 0.042 0.076

Observations 2,445,726 895,403

Notes: This table reports OLS estimates of expected hospital demand on early-term birth (gestational

age 37 or 38 weeks) for the period 2002–2016. Demand is the expected hospital demand in week w of

year y for hospital h. 25th pctl < Demand ≤ 50th pctl is a dummy that indicates if that expected

demand is in the 25 to 50 percentile of the distribution of expected demand for the hospital h in year y.

Similar definitions apply for other dummies.

All regressions control for single birth, sex of the baby, number of children, mother’s educational level,

and mother’s age-year, mother’s county of residence, and hospital-month fixed effects.

The mean of dependent variable corresponds to the treated in the pre-treatment period.

Standard errors, clustered by hospital, reported in brackets.

∗∗∗ Significant at the 1 percent level.

∗∗ Significant at the 5 percent level.

∗ Significant at the 10 percent level.

53

Page 54: A demand-smoothing incentive for cesarean deliveries

Table 10: Effect of expected hospital demand on the probability of early-termbirth by hospital c-section rate intensity

C-section rate C-section rate C-section rate

≤ 25% 25 - 40% ≥ 40%

(1) (2) (3)

25th pctl < Demand ≤ 50th pctl −0.000 −0.002 0.001

[0.002] [0.002] [0.002]

50th pctl < Demand ≤ 75th pctl 0.002∗ −0.001 0.004∗∗

[0.001] [0.002] [0.002]

Demand > 75th pctl 0.001 −0.001 0.008∗∗∗

[0.002] [0.002] [0.002]

Mean DV 0.304 0.325 0.463

R-squared 0.037 0.040 0.089

Observations 1,138,885 1,095,011 1,107,133

Notes: This table reports OLS estimates of expected hospital demand on early-term birth

(gestational age 37 or 38 weeks) for all hospitals in the period 2002–2016. Demand is the

expected hospital demand in week w of year y for hospital h. 25th pctl < Demand ≤ 50th pctl is

a dummy that indicates if that expected demand is in the 25 to 50 percentile of the distribution

of expected demand for the hospital h in year y. Similar definitions apply for other dummies.

C-section rate is the average c-section rate for a hospital in 2002–2016.

All regressions control for single birth, sex of the baby, number of children, mother’s educational

level, and mother’s age-year, mother’s county of residence, and hospital-month fixed effects.

The mean of dependent variable corresponds to the treated in the pre-treatment period.

Standard errors, clustered by hospital, reported in brackets.

∗∗∗ Significant at the 1 percent level.

∗∗ Significant at the 5 percent level.

∗ Significant at the 10 percent level.

54