a public expenditure review for paraguay - world...

87
RESTRICTED Report No. 78194-PY A Public Expenditure Review for Paraguay The quest for optimal tax and expenditure policies for shared prosperity November 25, 2013 Argentina, Paraguay and Uruguay Country Management Unit Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Latin America and the Caribbean Region Document of the World Bank Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: duongnhu

Post on 17-Mar-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

RESTRICTED

Report No. 78194-PY

A Public Expenditure Review for Paraguay

The quest for optimal tax and expenditure policies for

shared prosperity

November 25, 2013

Argentina, Paraguay and Uruguay Country Management Unit

Poverty Reduction and Economic Management

Latin America and the Caribbean Region

Document of the World Bank

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

CURRENCY AND EXCHANGE RATE

(As of November 25, 2013)

CURRENCY UNIT = GUARANIES

US$1.00 = Gs.4,423

FISCAL YEAR

January 1 – December 31

ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS

BCP Central Bank of Paraguay

(Banco Central de Paraguay)

LAC Latin America and the

Caribbean

BOOST Public Expenditure Database MDG Millenium Development Goal

CCT Conditional cash transfer MERCOSUR Southern Common Market

(Mercado Común del Sur)

CEPAL National Commission for Latin

America (Comisión Nacional

para América Latina

MICs Middle Income Countries

CGE Computable General

Equilibrium

PER Public Expenditure Review

CIT Corporate Income Tax PISA Program for International

Student Assessment

DEA Data Envelopment Analysis PPP Purchasing Power Parity

DGEEC National Institute of Statistics

(Dirección Nacional de

Encuestas Estadísticas y

Censos)

SET Department of Tax Revenue

Collection (Secretaria de

Estado de Tributación)

DINAC National Directorate of Civil

Aeronautics (Dirección

Nacional de Aeronáutica civil)

SITUFIN Public Financial Report

(Informe de la Situación

Financiera del país)

DPT Diphteria, Pertusis and Tetanus SNEPE National Evaluation System

of Educational Process

(Sistema Nacional de

Evaluación del Proceso

Educativo)

EPH National Household Survey

(Encuesta Permanente de

Hogares)

SOE State Owned Enterprise

FDI

Foreign Direct Investment TB Tuberculosis

GDP Gross Domestic Product UNESCO United Nations Educational,

Scientific and Cultural

Organization

GFS Goverment Finance Statistics USAID United State Agency for

International Development

HOI Human Opportunity Index VAT Value Added Tax

IMAGRO Agricultural Income Tax

(Impuesto a las Actividades

Agropecuarias)

WDI World Development

Indicators

IMF International Monetary Fund WHO World Health Organization

IRACIS Corporate Income Tax on

Commerce, Industry and

Services (Impuesto a la Renta

Comercial, Industrial o de

Servicios)

Vice President: Hasan A. Tuluy

Country Director: Penelope J. Brook

Sector Director: Rodrigo A. Chaves

Sector Manager: Auguste Tano Kouame

Sector Manager: Zafer Mustafaoglu

Task Team Leaders: Friederike (Fritzi) Koehler-Geib /

Jasmin Chakeri

iv

Table of Contents Acknowledgements ...................................................................................................................................... ix

Executive Summary ...................................................................................................................................... x

Chapter 1: Introduction: challenges and context .................................................................................... 1

1.1. The economic turnaround ................................................................................................................ 1

1.2. The economic stabilization program ................................................................................................ 4

1.3. The development dividend of stabilization ...................................................................................... 6

1.4. Challenge 1: Volatile macroeconomic environment ........................................................................ 7

1.5. Challenge 2: Limited fiscal resources that constrain spending on human development and growth-

enhancing policies ..................................................................................................................................... 8

1.6. Challenge 3: High levels of poverty and inequality remain ............................................................. 9

1.7. Transparency and data availability .................................................................................................. 9

1.8. Objective, methodology, and the value added of this PER ............................................................ 10

Chapter 2: Public Finances in a commodity driven economy .............................................................. 12

2.1 Fiscal consolidation with limited fiscal resources—the genesis of the current revenue structure . 12

2.2 The link between fiscal policy and macroeconomic volatility ....................................................... 21

2.3 Expenditures .................................................................................................................................. 26

2.4 Policy options ................................................................................................................................ 31

Chapter 3: Fiscal policy, poverty reduction and shared prosperity....................................................... 34

3.1 Fiscal policy and income redistribution ......................................................................................... 34

3.2 Fiscal policy and equity of opportunity ......................................................................................... 41

3.3 How progressive is Paraguay’s fiscal system with regard to the distribution of income and

opportunities? .......................................................................................................................................... 45

3.4 Policy options ................................................................................................................................ 49

Chapter 4: Efficiency of Public Spending and Service Delivery .......................................................... 51

4.1 The efficiency of public spending in Paraguay in international comparison ................................. 51

4.2 Within-country differences in the efficiency of public spending ................................................... 55

4.3 Case study: expenditure efficiency in State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs) ....................................... 61

4.4 Policy options ................................................................................................................................. 62

List of references ......................................................................................................................................... 63

v

Annexes ...................................................................................................................................................... 67

Annex 1.1. Volatility over time, international comparison ................................................................. 67

Annex 1.2. Volatility breaks of macro-economic variables in Paraguay ............................................. 68

Annex 1.3. Social development indicators ........................................................................................... 69

Annex 1.4. Poverty, Extreme Poverty, Inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean ...................... 70

Annex 4.1: Data envelopment analysis (DEA) .................................................................................... 71

Map ....................................................................................................................................................... 73

vi

List of Figures-Chapter 1

Figure 1.1: Real GDP and real GDP per capita .............................................................................. 2

Figure 1.2: Aggregate demand decomposition of growth (percent annual contribution) ............... 3

Figure 1.3: Sectoral decomposition of growth (percent annual contribution) ................................ 3

Figure 1.4: Revenues and expenditures .......................................................................................... 5

Figure 1.5: Fiscal balance ............................................................................................................... 5

Figure 1.6: Public debt .................................................................................................................... 6

Figure 1.7: Inflation ........................................................................................................................ 6

Figure 1.8: Public and private investment ...................................................................................... 6

Figure 1.9: Net capital inflows........................................................................................................ 6

Figure 1.10: Tax-to-GDP ratio 2011 ............................................................................................... 8

Figure 1.11: Social Expenditure ..................................................................................................... 8

List of Figures-Chapter 2

Figure 2.1: Revenues and expenditures (percent of GDP) .......................................................................... 13

Figure 2.2: Government revenues, average 2007- 2011 (percent of GDP) ................................................. 13

Figure 2.3: Share of agricultural tax revenue in internal tax revenues versus sectoral share in GDP ........ 14

Figure 2.4: Total internal tax revenue: Number of contributors versus average contribution by taxpayer 17

Figure 2.5: VAT: Number of contributors versus average contribution by taxpayer ................................. 17

Figure 2.6: IMAGRO: Number of contributors versus average contribution by tax payer ........................ 18

Figure 2.7: Corporate income tax: Number of contributors versus average contribution by tax payer ...... 18

Figure 2.8: Marginal rate on VAT tax ........................................................................................................ 18

Figure 2.9: Revenues from VAT over GDP, average 2007-2011 ............................................................... 18

Figure 2.10: Marginal rate on corporate income tax ................................................................................... 19

Figure 2.11: Revenues from corporate income tax over GDP, average 2007-2011 ................................... 19

Figure 2.12: Marginal tax on personal income tax ..................................................................................... 19

Figure 2.13: Revenues from personal income tax over GDP, average 2007-2011 ..................................... 19

Figure 2.14: VAT productivity, average 2007-2011 ................................................................................... 20

Figure 2.15: Corporate income tax productivity, average 2007-2011 ........................................................ 20

Figure 2.17: Business cycle fluctuations in Paraguay—Public consumption versus GDP ......................... 22

Figure 2.18: Business cycle fluctuations in Paraguay—Public investment versus GDP ............................ 22

Figure 2.19: Contribution of public and private demand components to real GDP growth ...................... 23

Figure 2.20: Public consumption and investment (quarterly y-o-y growth) ............................................... 24

Figure 2.21: Exports by product ................................................................................................................. 24

Figure 2.22: Fiscal Space ........................................................................................................................... 27

Figure 2.23: Public Expenditure in international comparison (average 2007-2011) .................................. 27

Figure 2.24: Paraguay’s public debt over time ........................................................................................... 27

Figure 2.25: Interest expenditure in Latin America .................................................................................... 27

Figure 2.26: Functional classification ......................................................................................................... 29

Figure 2.27: Education expenditure in international comparison (average 2007-2011) ............................. 29

Figure 2.28: Health expenditure in international comparison ..................................................................... 29

Figure 2.29: Economic classification .......................................................................................................... 30

Figure 2.30: Compensation of employees in international comparison (average 2007-2011) ................... 30

vii

Figure 2 31: Current versus capital expenditure in international comparison (average 2007-2011) .......... 30

List of Figures-Chapter 3

Figure 3.1: Public expenditure on health and education (% of total public expenditure) ............ 35

Figure 3.2: Public social spending in Paraguay and comparator countries (2009-11; % of GDP)35

Figure 3.3: Gini coefficient for each income concept in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Guatemala,

Mexico, Paraguay, Peru and Uruguay .......................................................................................... 36

Figure 3.4: Inequality in Paraguay (2010) – benchmark vs. sensitivity analysis ......................... 37

Figure 3.5: Percent of direct transfer beneficiaries who are poor in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil,

Guatemala, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru and Uruguay ....................................................................... 39

Figure 3.6: Percent of poor receiving at least one direct transfer ................................................. 39

Figure 3.7: HOI for Latin American Countries (proj. 2010) ........................................................ 42

Figure 3.8: Change in the HOI and coverage ............................................................................... 43

Figure 3.9: Coverage and HOI in Paraguay (2010) ...................................................................... 44

Figure 3.10:Concentration shares of taxes in Paraguay (2010) .................................................... 46

Figure 3.11: Concentration coefficients of public expenditure categories in Paraguay (2010) .... 47

Figure 3.12: Incidence of public education expenditure ............................................................... 48

Figure 3.13: Incidence of public health expenditure .................................................................... 49

List of Figures-Chapter 4

Figure 4. 1: Public expenditure on education vs. net primary enrolment rate .............................. 52

Figure 4.2: Public expenditure on education vs. secondary graduation rate ................................ 53

Figure 4.3: Health expenditure and maternal mortality rate ......................................................... 54

Figure 4.4: Public expenditure on education vs. selected education outcomes, by department ... 56

Figure 4.5: Public expenditure on health vs. selected health outcomes, by department ............... 59

List of Tables-Chapter 1

Table 1.1: Poverty and equity indicators ........................................................................................ 3

List of Tables-Chapter 2

Table 2.1: Government tax versus non-tax revenue (percent of GDP)......................................... 14

Table 2.2: Sectoral weights in gross value added ......................................................................... 14

Table 2.3: Sectoral contribution to total internal tax revenue ....................................................... 15

Table 2.4: Revenue by tax type..................................................................................................... 15

Table 2.5: Government tax revenue by tax type (percent of total unless stated otherwise) ......... 16

Table 2.6: Marginal tax rates over time ........................................................................................ 16

Table 2.7: Volatility of revenues and expenditures ..................................................................... 21

Table 2.8: Export by destination ................................................................................................... 24

Table 2.9: Volatility of different tax types (annual real growth) ................................................. 26

List of Tables-Chapter 3

Table 3.1: Taxes, transfers, inequality and poverty in Paraguay (2010) - benchmark ................. 37

viii

List of Tables-Chapter 4

Table 4.1: Characteristics of the SOE Sector in Paraguay............................................................ 62

ix

Acknowledgements

This report was prepared by a team led by Friederike (Fritzi) Koehler-Geib and Jasmin Chakeri (LCSPE)

under the overall supervision and guidance of Zafer Mustafaoglu (Lead Economist and Sector Leader,

LCSPR), Auguste T. Kouame (Sector Manager, LCSPE), Rodrigo A. Chaves (Sector Director, LCSPR)

and Penelope J. Brook (Country Director, LCC7C). The peer reviewers were David Rosenblatt

(Economic Advisor, DECOS), Dominique Van De Walle (Lead Economist, DECHD), Eduardo Ley

(Lead Economist, PRMED), Gallina Vincelette (Senior Economist, ECSP1), and Jose Molinas (Country

Sector Coordinator, ECSH4).

The core team included Carolina Diaz-Bonilla (LCSPP), Rossana Polastri (previous Country Manager,

LCCPY), Dante Mossi (Country Manager, LCCPY), (Eduardo Andres Estrada, Renato Busquets

(WBIOG), Elida Caballero Cabrera, Guillermo Cabral, Jorge Araujo, Miriam Beatriz Villarroel, Patricia

Chacon Holt, Patrick Rittenauer, Peter Siegenthaler, and Silvia Gulino (all LCSPE), Gloria Dure, Rosa

Arestivo de Cuentas Zavala, Telma Alvarenga Capurro (all LCCPY). Inputs and background papers were

also received from Edgardo Favaro, Julio Ramirez, Lisa Stewart, Martin Cicowiez, Nora Lustig, Osvaldo

Schenone, Sean Higgins, William Swanson (all consultants), Jose Antonio Cuesta and Pablo Suarez

Becerra (PRMPR), Eriko Togo (PRMED), Antonio Velandia-Rubiano (FABDM), Ana Mie Horigoshi

Rei, Fanny Weiner (all LCSPS), Luis Orlando Perez (LCSHH), Rafael de Hoyos (LCSHE), Juan Martin

Moreno (LCSHS), Agustin Indaco, Andres Lajer Baron, Carolina Saizar, Hannah Nielsen, Nathalie

Picarelli, Pia Maria Zanetti, Sona Varma (all LCSPE), Marijn Verhoeven (PRMPS), and Massimo

Mastruzzi (WBIOG).

Comments and inputs were also received from many colleagues working in the Paraguay country team,

including Alexandre Arrobbio, Raul Junquera (all LCSPS), Andrew Follmer, Carla Cutolo, Elena Feeney,

Mariela Alvarez, Tatiana Proskuryakova, Sabine Hader (all LCC7C), Richard Ferreira Candia, Ruth

Gonzalez Llamas (LCREA), and Graciela Sanchez Martinez (LCSSO).

The team is thankful for the excellent collaboration with the Ministry of Finance, in particular with the

Vice Ministry of the Economy including the Departments of Economic Studies, Macro Fiscal Policies,

Debt Policy, and Financial-Economic Information Systems, and the Ministries of Health, Education, and

Public Works.

x

Executive Summary

Paraguay has achieved significant progress in terms of fiscal policy over the past decade.

Fiscal consolidation was at the core of the economic stabilization program that contributed to the

economic turnaround beginning in 2003. It included an increase in tax revenues through the

implementation—albeit partial—of a tax reform package, as well as significant rationalization of

expenditures. Tax revenues increased from 8.7 percent of GDP in 2003 to 12.3 percent in 2012.

The overall fiscal surplus averaged 1 percent of GDP between 2004 and 2011, and public debt

fell from 41 percent of GDP in 2002 to 12 percent in 2012.

Despite this progress on fiscal reform, three major challenges remain: (i) a volatile

macroeconomic environment; (ii) still insufficient fiscal resources; and (iii) high levels of

poverty and inequality. First, while Paraguay’s growth in the past decade has exceeded its

average for the past three decades, it has also become more volatile in recent years. In the period

from 1960 to 2000 the standard deviation of GDP growth in Paraguay undershot the regional

mean and median, and in contrast in the past decade has exceeded them. Moreover, Paraguay is

one of the few Latin American countries that show an increasing trend comparing the standard

deviations of GDP growth for these two periods. The increased volatility renders fiscal policy,

especially planning and forecasting, more difficult. The second major challenge is the still

limited fiscal resources that constrain spending on human development and growth-enhancing

policies. Paraguay’s tax to GDP ratio is lower than that of any relevant peer group including the

average Latin American or lower middle income country. At the same time, the share of social

expenditure in GDP is also lower than that of the relevant peer countries and overall outcomes of

social services are improving at a slower pace than in other countries. Third, despite significant

poverty reduction since 2003, the incidence of poverty and inequality remains high in

international comparison and calls for further improvements in the future.

In light of these three challenges, the objective of this report is to examine the extent to

which fiscal policy in Paraguay has contributed to the social progress of the past decade,

and can serve the purpose of further reducing poverty and enhancing shared prosperity in

the years to come. Overall, fiscal policy can contribute to containing poverty and inequality by

buffering the negative impact of financial and economic crises on vulnerable parts of the

population. Moreover, tax and expenditure policies that redistribute from high- to low-income

households in a well-targeted manner can also contribute to these goals. In Paraguay,

Government intervention helped containing the negative impact of the 2009 crisis on poverty and

inequality, thereby contrasting earlier crisis that had large negative effects. In terms of

redistribution, the role of fiscal policy in Paraguay has been limited in the past partly due to the

low tax to GDP ratios as well as low expenditures in social sectors including social protection.

There is scope to increase the role of fiscal policy in reducing poverty and sharing prosperity in

Paraguay in the future due to the possibility of raising additional tax revenues, expanding the

coverage of social protection programs, and reducing remaining inefficiencies.

Fiscal policy in Paraguay remains constrained by limited tax revenues. Still today, Paraguay

is characterized by a low tax-to-GDP ratio by international standards. The tax reform in 2004

could not generate significant additional revenues for the following three main reasons: (ii) it

failed to introduce taxation in the agricultural sector to rise the sector’s fiscal contribution to a

xi

level that is proportional to its share of GDP; (ii) significant tax exemptions weakened some

reform measures and still do, as in the case of the reformed corporate income tax of the

agricultural sector (IMAGRO); and (iii) some measures, for example the personal income tax,

were not implemented for a long time. In addition, the reform did not change the actual structure

of the tax system, especially with regard to reliance on indirect taxes. In fact, reliance on indirect

taxes increased over time, rendering the system even more regressive.

The current structure of the tax system appears suboptimal in light of the identified

challenges. Even though the reliance on indirect taxes insulates public revenues from economic

volatility to a certain extent, it imposes high costs associated with sufficiency and equity of the

system. Other policy tools such as a fiscal rule or a stabilization fund could be used to manage

volatility more effectively. Furthermore, the regressivity of the tax system, as a result of a high

degree of indirect taxation, is particularly harmful in an economy with high poverty rates.

Adequate taxation of the agricultural sector is needed to level the playing field for business

development in all sectors and to address the insufficiency of taxes. While the full

implementation of the 2004 tax reform could still raise tax revenues, eliminating significant tax

exemptions could provide an additional source of fiscal revenue. Some elimination would have

to be accompanied by targeted spending increases to offset the potential negative effect on

poverty. This could help Paraguay generate the fiscal resources necessary to increase spending

on infrastructure and the social sectors and to implement countercyclical fiscal policies. In

addition, the low taxation of agriculture provides an incentive to be active in this economic

sector, which already has a heavy weight in the economy. Removing this distortion would foster

the diversification of the economy.

While fiscal policy contributes less to poverty reduction and shared prosperity in Paraguay

than in the other countries analyzed for this study, direct transfers are well targeted. The

nature of Paraguay’s fiscal system – low tax revenues and, consequently, relatively low

expenditure – represents important limitations for the scope of fiscal redistribution and basic

service delivery. As a result, fiscal policy in Paraguay reduces inequality only slightly, and fiscal

policy measures such as taxes and transfers have a net negative impact on the poverty headcount.

This is partly because the poor pay a large share of their income on taxes. In addition, transfers

do not increase the income of the poor by as much as they do in other countries: the extremely

poor receive, on average, just US$0.38 PPP per day in household per capita terms from direct

transfers. And while direct transfers (especially the conditional cash transfer program) are well

targeted, they reach only a quarter of the extreme poor. As a result, all income deciles, including

the poorest, are net contributors to the fiscal system.

Income inequality is partly a result of the inequity of opportunities, which has improved in

recent years. The Human Opportunity Index (HOI) measures how far a society is from universal

provision of basic services and goods, such as sanitation, clean water and education, and the

extent to which those goods and services are unevenly distributed. Paraguay performs below the

LAC average on the HOI, but has improved faster than other countries since 2003. This is

because the coverage of basic social services, the overall wellbeing of the population and the

distribution of disparities among population groups have all improved, and have improved in line

with increased spending. However, the inequity of opportunity remains particularly high in

services where coverage remains low, such as access to safe sanitation, completion of 9th

grade

and enrollment in pre-school.

xii

Overall, Paraguay’s fiscal system is less progressive than in other Latin American

countries analyzed. Paraguay’s reliance on indirect taxes makes its overall tax system

regressive. Furthermore, social expenditures are less progressive than in other countries: while

the CCT program is highly progressive (by design), education and health spending is much less

progressive than in other countries. Public spending on primary education is pro-poor with the

bottom 40 percent capturing 47 percent of total public resources. Conversely, public spending on

secondary education is pro-rich, with the bottom 40 percent capturing only 31 percent of total

public resources while the top 40 percent captures close to half of total public resources.

Similarly, the poorest benefit disproportionally from public expenditures on health centers, while

the richest benefit disproportionally from public expenditures on hospitals.

Even though some social programs are very effective, the expenditure efficiency in

education and health is relatively low. This partly explains why public spending does not

contribute much to the reduction of poverty and inequality. Given Paraguay’s limited fiscal

resources, getting the most value out of public spending is an important priority. However, not

only does Paraguay spend less on the social sectors than many other countries, it also achieves

relatively weak outcomes in education and health. Preliminary analysis based on international

comparisons suggests that Paraguay could improve the efficiency of public spending in these two

sectors. An area with scope for improvements is the oversight of state-owned enterprises which

provide a large share of public basic services. Services such as water and sanitation are relevant

for health sector outcomes, and existing inefficiencies in the sector of state-owned enterprises

thereby generate follow-on effects. There also appears to be significant variation in expenditure

efficiency among departments within Paraguay, which may be related to a number of factors.

More and better data is needed at the departmental level in order to better assess what drives

social outcomes in different parts of the country.

The sufficiency and efficiency of social expenditures have to be considered within the

context of fiscal prudence, which is a continuous task. This is especially important in light of

the recent expansionary fiscal stance. Only if the Government is able to sustain fiscal prudence in

the future, will it be able to maintain macroeconomic stability and performance. The

Government needs to revert quickly to tighter fiscal policies after the 2012 fiscal stimulus to

buffer the effect of a bad harvest and the run-up to the April 2013 Presidential elections. In

addition, further improvements in debt management and addressing weaknesses in the budget

process would be important to sustain past gains in the future.

Policy options

A number of policy options emerge from the analysis carried out in the PER:

Related to the volatile macroeconomic environment, policy options to address the pro-

cyclicality of fiscal policy include the introduction of a fiscal responsibility law or the

introduction of a stabilization fund. Other options include strengthening automatic stabilizers

such as unemployment insurance and other social protection measures.

Direct taxation could be increased through the elimination of exemptions and further

reforms of personal income and property taxes. The main exemptions currently apply to the

xiii

agricultural income tax (IMAGRO); corporate income tax (IRACIS); personal income tax and

property tax. The most important gains in terms of revenue would stem from changes to value

added tax, including the elimination of the suspension of VAT application to petrol imports;

replacement of the reduced VAT rate of 5 percent with a uniform rate of 10 percent as envisaged

during the 2004 reform; and elimination of the exemption of sales of the agricultural sector and

of paid interests. A reform of property taxes could base taxation of property on market valuation

as opposed to fiscal valuation in order to render property tax a more effective tax. This could

promote better land use, it could also increase municipal revenue, which in turn could increase

accountability and reduce dependency on central government transfers.

Such reforms would also help address the regressivity of the tax system. The regressivity of

Paraguay’s tax system is in large part due to its reliance on indirect taxes. Reforming key direct

taxes and increasing their share in tax collections will help make Paraguay’s fiscal system more

progressive.

Eliminating tax exemptions and reforming direct taxes would help generate additional

revenue, which could be used to strengthen the progressivity of public spending.

Simulations using a CGE model prepared for this report suggest that the reduction in exemptions

(especially VAT exemptions) and the use of these resources for social expenditure could be

beneficial for human development outcomes. The simulations look specifically at increases in

spending on education, health and water and sanitation, and on the effect of this increased

spending on MDGs. Such spending could be better targeted to improve access to basic services

used by particularly vulnerable groups, including those identified as households whose head

speaks only Guaranï and went to school for less than 6 years. Similarly, any additional resources

freed up could be used for the CCT program, which would have beneficial impacts on poverty

and inequality given that it is already well targeted.

In order to assess and enhance the efficiency of public expenditure, it is important to

continue to improve disaggregated data at the departmental level. In addition to improving

the accuracy of available data, breaking down data on total expenditure by department, including

at the program or even facility level (such as schools and health centers) would push progress

even further by allowing for better targeting of resources. More and better data on outcomes in

key sectors, as well as on socio-economic and demographic indicators at the departmental or

municipal level, would also be beneficial for policy making.

Paraguay would also benefit from participation in additional international assessments in

order to better gauge its performance vis-à-vis peer countries. For instance, taking part in the

PISA study could make education outcomes in Paraguay comparable to other countries, thus

providing important information that could guide policy making in that sector.

Finally, improved management and oversight of SOEs could contribute to better social

service provision. Specific measures include: (i) approval and implementation of the draft law

institutionalizing an independent SOE supervisory body; (ii) further reforms to strengthen the

SOE governance and oversight framework; (iii) assurance of sufficient supply and quality of

basic public services; (iv) preparation of a long- and medium-term investment plan to efficiently

address infrastructure gaps; (v) the set-up of an investment system for SOEs; (vi) a set of rules

xiv

for managing debt and fiscal risk of SOEs; and (vii) schemes on transfers, subsidies and

outstanding payments.

1

Chapter 1: Introduction: challenges and context

Paraguay’s economic turnaround started in 2003, driven by an economic stabilization program

and favorable external demand. Since then, the Government has achieved significant progress in

the areas of development and reform, yet three major challenges remain for fiscal policy. First,

although Paraguay’s growth in the decade has exceeded its historical average since 1980, it has

become more volatile in recent years. This increased volatility renders planning and forecasting

more difficult. The second major challenge is the limited fiscal resources that constrain spending

on human development and growth-enhancing policies. Third, despite significant poverty

reduction since 2003, levels of poverty remain high, and achievements appear more modest if the

period prior to the deep crisis of 2002 and 2003 is taken into account. In the same vein, in terms

of reducing inequality and sharing prosperity the country has achieved less than its regional

peers, remaining one of the most unequal economies in Latin America - the most unequal region

in the world.

The purpose of the current study is to answer the following question: given the structure and the

challenges of the Paraguayan economy, has fiscal policy served the purpose of reducing poverty

and sharing prosperity? Based on the findings related to this question, the study seeks to trigger

a public debate about on optimality of tax and expenditure policies for Paraguay.

The current study seeks to answer this question in four chapters. This first, introductory chapter

presents the background in economic developments over the last decade and spells out

remaining challenges. Following this review it will also provide the objective, methodology, and

the value added of this PER. The second chapter addresses fiscal policy in a volatile

macroeconomic environment; the third chapter covers the role of fiscal policy in reducing

poverty, inequality and sharing prosperity; and the fourth chapter deals with the efficiency of

public spending.

1.1. The economic turnaround

After a quarter century of chronic stagnation and crisis, an economic stabilization program

and favorable external demand have led a recovery in growth since 2003. Paraguay

experienced a period of fast economic growth and prosperity throughout the 1960s and 1970s

with real per capita income more than doubling and real GDP growth averaging 7 percent per

year. The construction of the Itaipu dam provided significant economic impulse during that

period but this faded with the dam’s completion in the fall of 1982. Subsequently, Paraguay

could not maintain the high growth rates and slipped into a period of recurring and costly

financial distress in the late 1990s. This translated into slow advances in per capita GDP, which

grew on average 1 percent per year between 1982 and 1996 and then declined by 14 percent

between 1997 and 2002. In terms of real GDP, an average annual growth of 3.8 percent

contrasted with a subsequent drop of 4.4 percent between 1997 and 2002. The crisis in the late

1990s was a result of rapid financial liberalization, which was allowed to take place in the

2

absence of prudential regulations and safeguards.1 Shortly thereafter, Paraguay was affected by

contagion from the regional crisis in 2002, which exacerbated inherent weaknesses in the

financial system. This undermined confidence and precipitated large deposit runs as well as a

deep financial crisis that depressed the economy further. In response to this crisis, the new

Duarte-Frutos administration adopted an ambitious stabilization program in 2003. Strong

external demand helped stabilization and recovery. It triggered fast export growth which in turn

translated into strong recovery of private consumption and investment, the main drivers behind

growth recovery in that period.

As a result, average annual real GDP growth reached 3.9 percent between 2003 and 2012

and was broadly shared for the most part. By 2008, real per capita GDP had recovered from

the crisis and had regained the pre-crisis levels of 1997. With strong real export growth of 5.4

percent per year on average between 2003 and 2012, private consumption and investment also

expanded rapidly, contributing on average 3.5 and 0.7 percentage points respectively to annual

growth in this period (Figure 1.2). The services sector contributed most to growth, accounting for

2.2 percentage points on average between 2003 and 2012, of which wholesale and retail trade,

followed by transport and communications, were the most important subsectors. Agriculture was

the second most important sector explaining on average 0.6 percentage points of growth,

followed by the electricity and water sector with 0.5 percentage points. As a consequence of

solid growth, unemployment fell from 8.1 percent in 2003 to 5.6 in 2011 and poverty was

reduced from 44 percent to 32 percent over the same period.

While the 2009 crisis temporarily interrupted Paraguay’s economic turnaround, the

impact on poverty was contained and fiscal policy remained prudent in contrast to earlier

crises. A severe drought exacerbated the impact of the international economic crisis in Paraguay,

triggering a 4 percent real contraction of the economy and a 25 percent drop in agricultural

production. Yet, record growth of 13.1 percent in 2010 illustrates how short-lived the impact

was. Paraguay’s external position remained stable throughout 2009, because the significant drop

in exports was balanced out by: the drop in imports; a lower than expected drop in remittances; a

1 IMF (2009) provides a detailed description.

Figure 1.1: Real GDP and real GDP per capita

Source: World Bank, WDI

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

196

0

196

2

196

4

196

6

196

8

197

0

197

2

197

4

197

6

197

8

198

0

198

2

198

4

198

6

198

8

199

0

199

2

199

4

199

6

199

8

200

0

200

2

200

4

200

6

200

8

201

0

201

2

Per

cen

t

Ind

ex (

20

05

=1

00

)

Real GDP per capita index Real GDP growth

3

relatively stable Guaraní throughout 2009; and a financial sector that proved relatively resilient.

In addition, the Government presented an Anti-Crisis Plan to Congress in January 2009 including

measures aimed at: providing a fiscal stimulus through expanded public spending programs;

ensuring sufficient liquidity in the financial system; ensuring access to financing for the

productive sectors; and accelerating the mobilization of external resources.2 Current expenditure,

up by 2.8 percent of GDP relative to 2008, included an expansion of the conditional cash transfer

as well as other social programs. Despite the crisis, the poverty rate further decreased from 38

percent in 2008 to 35 percent in 2009, and the Gini coefficient from 51 percent to 49 percent.

This is in stark contrast to the deep crisis in 2002 when the poverty rate was up 13 percentage

points relative to the previous year reaching 50 percent. The Government also remained

committed to prudent macroeconomic policies, with the fiscal balance closing in surplus in 2009

due to an increase in tax revenues.

Figure 1.2: Aggregate demand decomposition of

growth (percent annual contribution) 3

Figure 1.3: Sectoral decomposition of growth (percent

annual contribution)

Source: Central Bank of Paraguay

Table 1.1: Poverty and equity indicators

1997-

98 1999

2000-

01 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006* 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Poverty incidence

(% population) 36.1 37.3 36.8 49.7 44.0 41.3 38.6 43.7 41.2 37.9 35.1 34.7 32.4

Urban 22.5 24 23.7 39.7 37.4 35.5 34.4 35.3 33.6 30.2 24.7 24.7 23.9

Rural 51.6 52.6 52.1 62.7 52.5 48.9 44.2 55.3 51.8 48.8 49.8 48.9 44.8

Extreme poverty

incidence (% population) 18.8 17.7 16.7 24.4 21.2 18.3 16.5 23.7 23.2 19.0 18.8 19.4 18.0

Urban 7.2 5.9 6.7 13.1 13.4 12.2 10.7 14.9 15.4 10.6 9.3 10.3 10.0 Rural 32.0 31.4 28.2 39.2 31.2 26.2 24.3 35.9 34.0 30.9 32.4 32.4 29.6

GINI coefficient 48.9 53.6 53.8 53.3 54.6 52.0 51.0 52.2 52.5 50.6 48.7 51.2 52.0

urban 49.3 48.0 49.6 48.0 51.5 48.7 49.6 49.5 47.2 45.3 42.3 45.9 47.0 Rural 52.2 55.6 52.0 56.7 56.1 53.8 49.8 51.6 57.6 55.7 55.4 55.8 56.6

Unemployment 5.4 6.8 7.6 10.7 8.1 7.3 5.7 6.5 5.5 5.7 6.4 5.7 5.6

Note: 2006 data suffer methodological problems, including the delayed data collection for the household survey due

to DGEEC’s budget constraints. Source: Encuesta Permanente de Hogares (EPH), DGEEC.

2 See Annex 4. 3 GDP numbers as basis for this graph include the bi-national powerplants.

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Percen

t

Private consumption Public consumption

Private Investment Public Investment

Exports Imports

Real GDP growth

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

Pe

rce

nt

Agriculture Cattle, forestry and fishingMining and manufacturing Electricity and waterConstruction ServicesValor agregado bruto

4

1.2. The economic stabilization program

At the core of the Government’s economic stabilization program was fiscal consolidation

that allowed for the reduction of the debt-to-GDP ratio and also kept inflation in check. After high public spending in the late 1990s and early 2000s, the Government’s consolidation

resulted in overall fiscal surpluses for the eight consecutive years between 2004 and 2011. These

surpluses averaged 1 percent of GDP. The combination of continuous surpluses and solid

economic growth also reduced the debt-to-GDP ratio from 41 percent in 2002 to 12 percent in

2012. Additionally, sound fiscal policies together with the Central Bank’s focus on price stability

resulted in single-digit inflation for most years.

Table 1.2: Paraguay’s fiscal accounts (percent of GDP)

Source: Ministerio de Hacienda

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Total revenues 15.7 16.0 15.6 15.8 17.5 16.9 17.4 18.4

Current revenues 15.6 15.9 15.6 15.8 17.2 16.7 16.8 17.9

Tax revenues 10.1 10.5 10.1 10.7 11.6 12.0 12.1 12.3

Non-tax revenues 5.0 4.9 4.8 4.1 4.8 4.0 4.0 4.9

o/w contributions to pension fund 1.0 0.9 1.1 1.1 1.3 1.2 1.2 1.5

o/w royalties 3.1 3.1 2.9 2.3 2.9 2.1 2.1 2.7

Grants 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0

Transfers 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7

Capital revenues 0.1 0.1 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.2 0.6 0.4

Total expenditures and net lending 15.0 15.5 14.8 13.5 17.5 15.9 16.7 20.1

Total expenditures 15.0 15.6 14.8 13.6 17.5 15.9 16.7 20.1

Current expenditures 11.5 11.9 11.5 11.1 13.4 12.5 12.8 15.5

o/w personal services 6.2 6.5 6.4 6.5 7.7 7.3 7.4 9.3

o/w goods and services 1.0 1.1 1.0 0.9 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6

o/w interest 1.0 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2

o/w current transfers 3.3 3.3 3.3 3.1 3.7 3.4 3.6 4.3

Capital expenditures 3.5 3.7 3.3 2.5 4.1 3.4 3.9 4.7

o/w physical investment 2.7 2.6 2.2 1.5 2.6 2.4 2.2 2.5

Net lending -0.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

Overall balance 0.7 0.4 0.9 2.3 0.1 1.0 0.7 -1.7

Primary balance 1.7 1.3 1.6 2.8 0.6 1.4 1.0 -1.5

5

Figure 1.4: Revenues and expenditures Figure 1.5: Fiscal balance

Source: Ministerio de Hacienda Source: Ministerio de Hacienda

The Government’s stabilization program focused first on immediate macro-economic

imbalances and since 2006 has shifted towards medium-term growth and institutional

issues.4

Immediately after the crisis, the Government addressed fiscal consolidation on the

revenue and expenditure sides. Major reforms from 2003 to 2005 included the reform of the

public pension scheme in late 2003 together with restrictions on employment and wage increases

within selected sectors; a tax policy reform and a new legal framework for revenue

administration were implemented in 2004 as was a new customs code. Financial sector reform

started in 2003 with the adaption of the bank resolution law and the adoption of regulations by

the BCP Board of Directors on asset classification, provisioning requirements, and imputation of

accrued interest, followed by the adaption of the public banking law in 2005. As it became clear

in 2005 that the economy had been stabilized, the Government shifted focus towards structural

reforms with the objective of fostering economic growth while continuing with reforms aimed at

sustaining stability. Reforms in this second phase included: the oversight mandate of state-owned

enterprises; internal control mechanisms in the public sector; and the introduction of the

conditional cash transfer program: Tekopora in 2005; and its subsequent expansion.

4 For a comprehensive description please refer to IMF (2009).

0

5

10

15

20

25

198

0

198

2

198

4

198

6

198

8

199

0

199

2

199

4

199

6

199

8

200

0

200

2

200

4

200

6

200

8

201

0

201

2

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

Revenues/GDP Expenditures/GDP

-6

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

198

01

98

21

98

41

98

61

98

81

99

01

99

21

99

41

99

61

99

82

00

02

00

22

00

42

00

62

00

82

01

02

01

2

Per

cem

t o

f G

DP

Fiscal balance/GDP Primary balance/GDP

6

Figure 1.6: Public debt Figure 1.7: Inflation (CPI, period average)

Source: BCP Source: BCP

1.3. The development dividend of stabilization

The stabilization generated the environment for the private sector to invest with greater

confidence and grow. In the period from 2003 to 2008, investment ratios as a percentage of

GDP increased from 15 percent to 18 percent respectively. This development was partly reversed

as a result of the 2009 crisis when private investment dropped to 17 percent of GDP, but it has

been recovering since then. FDI inflows have also stabilized over the same period and

unemployment dropped from 8.1 percent in 2003 to 5.6 percent in 2011.

Figure 1.8: Public and private investment Figure 1.9: Net capital inflows

Source: BCP Source: BCP

The development dividend of this stabilization was mainly a reduction in poverty;

prosperity that was broadly shared for the most part; and a modest improvement in

inequality. Real per capita GDP increased by 22 percent between 2003 and 2011. Compared to

the crisis years of 2002 and 2003, poverty fell significantly from 49.7 percent and 44 percent

respectively, to 32.4 percent in 2011. Progress in terms of extreme poverty is similarly

significant with rates dropping from 24.4 percent in 2002 to 18 percent in 2011 (Table 1.1).

0

10

20

30

40

50

199

11

99

21

99

31

99

41

99

51

99

61

99

71

99

81

99

92

00

02

00

12

00

22

00

32

00

42

00

52

00

62

00

72

00

82

00

92

01

02

01

12

01

2

Per

cen

t

External Debt/GDP Domestic Debt/GDP

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

199

0

199

2

199

4

199

6

199

8

200

0

200

2

200

4

200

6

200

8

201

0

201

2

Per

cen

t

0

5

10

15

20

25

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Pe

rce

nt

of

GD

P

Public investment Private investment

-5

0

5

10

15

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Pe

rce

nt

of

GD

P

Foreign direct investment Portfolio investmentDerivatives Other investmentTotal

7

Between 2004 and 2011 the bottom 40 percent of the population5 also shared in this economic

growth. Their household income grew by 4.6 percent on average compared to the 3.3 percent

average for the overall population. Yet, three caveats apply to this overall positive development:

(i) income growth of the bottom 40 percent was lower than the regional average, and particularly

than that of neighboring countries; (ii) inequality among this bottom 40 percent has increased;

and (iii) recovery after the 2009 crisis was not as strong for the bottom 40 percent as it was for

the rest of the population and thus, overall inequality has risen since then. Compared to 2003,

Paraguay also witnessed a moderate reduction in inequality with the Gini coefficient falling from

0.55 in 2003 to 0.52 in 2011. It had actually dropped to 0.487 by 2009, but the crisis that year

reversed the positive benefits of this reduction and it rose to 0.52 by 2011.

Despite these critical advances, stabilization and structural reforms could not dispel a

number of major challenges so that the continuation and deepening of the reform effort

will be essential to fully unlock Paraguay’s productivity. In contrast to other Latin American

countries, as for example Peru, stabilization and structural reforms could not reduce the volatility

of the macro-economic environment in Paraguay, where volatility had in fact increased in recent

years In addition, fiscal resources remain limited and are constraining spending on human

development and growth-enhancing policies. Poverty and inequality in Paraguay remain among

the highest in the region. The next three sections describe these three major challenges.

1.4. Challenge 1: Volatile macroeconomic environment

A first key challenge for public financial management in Paraguay is the increase in

volatility of GDP growth, rendering it one of the most volatile economies in the region. In

contrast, many other countries in the region have managed to reduce volatility. In the period

from 1960 to 2000 Paraguay’s volatility was significantly below the regional mean and median,

yet in the last decade it has been above (see Table Annex 1.1). In addition, it is not only

economic growth that has become more volatile: most macroeconomic variables in Paraguay

currently share this pattern, and this poses a challenge to fiscal policy by rendering revenue and

expenditure forecasting more difficult. It also increases the risks of pro-cyclicality of fiscal

policies (see Table Annex 1.2).

The increase in volatility is concerning and needs to be understood thoroughly given its

significant costs in terms of welfare, economic growth, and equality.6 World Bank (2013)

provides an in depth analysis of the sources, effects, and options for managing volatility.

Designing policies that help mitigate the impact of shocks to the economy and that help increase

a country’s resilience is particularly relevant in the light of increased volatility. They are also

5 The time period is dictated by the availability of comparable data. For more details on the topic please refer to

Lopez-Calva, Lugo, and Barriga Cabanillas (2013) forthcoming. 6 A comprehensive economic literature has documented these impacts; for example Loayza, Ranciere, Serven, and

Ventura (2007), Athanasoulis and van Wincoop (2000), World Bank (2000) on the impact of volatility on welfare,

Hnatkovska and Loayza (2005) and Calderon and Schmitt-Hebbel (2003) and Berument, Dincer, and Mustafaoglu

(2011) on the growth impact, and Breen and Garcia Penalosa (2004), Garcia-Penalosa and Turnovsky (2004), or

Huang, Fang and Miller (2012) for the impact on equality.

8

important because Paraguay still has a low per capita income compared to its neighbors and

suffers from a persistent high degree of inequality and poverty.

1.5. Challenge 2: Limited fiscal resources that constrain spending on

human development and growth-enhancing policies

The inability to raise tax revenues has resulted in low levels of spending in social sectors

and infrastructure. Despite important improvements on the back of fiscal policy and

administration reforms, Paraguay is characterized by a low tax to GDP ratio by international

standards. It undershoots by a large margin the tax to GDP ratio of its MERCOSUR neighbors;

the ratios in Argentina and Brazil are twice as high as in Paraguay. Compared to all relevant peer

groups, be it lower middle income countries (MICs), Latin American and Caribbean countries, or

countries that have similar characteristics in terms of GDP per capita and population, Paraguay

collects very little in the way of taxes (see Figure 1.9).7 In this environment fiscal surpluses for

eight consecutive years from 2004 to 2011 explain relative caution when it comes to spending.

Despite fast growth in recent years, social expenditure in Paraguay is lower than in comparator

countries (Figure 1.11) and overall outcomes of social services are also improving at a slower

pace than in other countries. This explains Paraguay’s weak performance in terms of the Human

Development Indicator and other social development indicators (see Annex 1.3 for details).

Lack of disaggregated data on social spending and outcomes limits the ability to assess the

efficiency of public spending. Both in health and education, around 80 percent of expenditure is

classified as alcance nacional - spending at the national level. Attribution to specific departments

7 The peer group of countries with similar GDP and population characteristics comprises the ten countries for which

the equally weighted average of Population and GDP per capita is closest to Paraguay. The countries are: Bolivia,

Bulgaria, El Salvador, Georgia, Honduras, Jordan, Nicaragua, Papua New Guinea, Serbia, and Turkmenistan.

Figure 1.10: Tax-to-GDP ratio 2011 Figure 1.11: Social Expenditure

Source: SET and USAID Source: CEPAL (2009-2011)

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Par

aguay

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

Ho

ndu

ras

Ser

bia

Ecu

ado

r

Geo

rgia

Gu

atem

ala

LM

ICs

UM

ICs

Lac

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

Arg

enti

na

Boli

via

Bra

zil

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Ho

ndu

ras

Nic

arag

ua

Par

aguay

Ser

bia

Uru

gu

ay

LA

C

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

9

is only possible for 20 percent of all expenditures. Outcome data is also very limited at the

departmental level, which constrains analysis of the efficiency of public spending at this level.8

In the case of education, the national attainment test SNEPE is only representative at the national

level, so that education outcomes at the departmental level cannot be assessed. This is a serious

limitation as the discourse about performance between different departments offers an excellent

opportunity to understand differences in the administration and processes and the exchange of

best practices. A further limitation to assessing the efficiency of public spending in education in

Paraguay is that the country does not participate in international tests that would allow

comparison with other countries.

1.6. Challenge 3: High levels of poverty and inequality remain

Despite significant improvements over the past decade, Paraguay’s poverty rates and

inequality remains among the highest in Latin America and the Caribbean—the most

unequal region in the World (Annex 1.4). A major reason behind the still high poverty and

inequality is the negative impact that continuous crises between 1998 and 2002 have had on the

population. Compared to the 2002 crisis, the 2009 crisis had only a minor impact, partly due to

Government intervention that buffered the effects. As a result, overall achievements in Paraguay

appear modest, when comparing current poverty numbers with the pre-crisis year of 1997 when

poverty was at 36.1 percent and extreme poverty at 18.8. In terms of equality, results look less

favorable, with the Gini coefficient at 0.52 in 2011 exceeding that of 0.49 in 1997.

This third challenge is closely linked to the two other challenges, through the negative

impact of volatility on poverty reduction and inequality and the question of redistribution.

As argued in Lopez-Calva, Lugo, and Barriga Cabanilas (2013), the high degree of volatility

may be the weak link between solid average growth performance and employment generation.

The uncertainty resulting from volatile economic growth may reduce the incentive for firms to

employ new staff. Also, persistently high levels of inequality may be linked to high volatility

because citizens at the lower end of the income distribution have reduced access to insurance

mechanisms and therefore suffer more from negative shocks. Together, lagging employment

generation and continued high levels of inequality pose important challenges for Paraguay in the

eradication of extreme poverty. In terms of redistribution, the question is whether tax and

expenditure policies have contributed to income redistribution from high- to low-income

households in a well-targeted manner, and to what extent fiscal policy has contributed to

reducing poverty and inequality.

1.7. Transparency and data availability

The PER supported the government’s efforts to improve the transparency of economic

data through three key tools: (i) the BOOST database of comprehensive treasury data; (ii)

the Social Accountability Matrix; and (iii) the Computable General Equilibrium Model.

Each of these tools was developed as part of the PER and served as the basis for the analysis

presented in the following chapters. But their usefulness reaches beyond this report, as they can

8 For more information on data issues, please see Box 2 in Chapter 4.

10

be used by the government for a number of analytical purposes and contribute to improved

transparency and accountability.

The publication of a BOOST database represents a significant policy change towards

greater transparency of fiscal data. Available through the Ministry of Finance’s website9, the

BOOST platform provides disaggregated budget data for all levels of government in a user-

friendly format for the years 2003 to 2012. Paraguay is the first country in Latin America and the

Caribbean, and the fourth in the world to release budget data to the public using BOOST. The

tool supports government efforts to improve the quality of expenditure analysis, and shows the

government’s commitment towards greater budget transparency. The preparation of the platform

has also contributed to capacity building in the Ministry of Finance as well as to improved

information exchange within the Ministry and with the line ministries.

The preparation and planned publication of a well-documented and updated social

accountability matrix is also an important milestone. The background work for this PER

contains the preparation of a social accountability matrix as a key ingredient of a computable

general equilibrium model. The social accountability matrix has been prepared in close

collaboration with the Ministry of Finance and the Central Bank. It includes data from

Paraguay’s National Accounts, Fiscal Accounts, Balance of Payments, and Permanent

Household Survey, and builds on an Input-Output Table created by the Central Bank.10

The

publication of the matrix in itself will be another step towards greater transparency in Paraguay

and is expected to facilitate future research.

The dynamic-recursive computable general equilibrium (CGE) model allows the

government to assess the distributional and poverty impact of different policy alternatives.

The CGE model is complemented by a microsimulation model that translates the CGE results

into poverty and inequality outcomes. The model makes it possible to estimate how government

spending and taxation, foreign aid, and exogenous conditions (including world markets) together

influence and are influenced by human development.11

For both the social accountability matrix

and the preparation of the computable general equilibrium model, an important element of

capacity building has taken place and builds the basis for future collaboration. At the same time,

further improvements in data quality and availability would be important for enhanced policy

making (see Box 2 in Chapter 4 for more detail).

1.8. Objective, methodology, and the value added of this PER

Has fiscal policy served the purpose of reducing poverty and sharing prosperity? This is the

overarching question that the current PER seeks to answer in light of the developments of the

past decade and the remaining major challenges. Based on the findings related to this question

9 http://www.openlooksolutions.com/boost_paraguay/.

10 The Input-Output Table is for 1994 and was created by the Central Bank of Paraguay, which is the only official

provider of the data and is in charge of the collection and processing of National Accounts data. 11

For more information on the Social Accountability Matrix and the CGE model, see Chapter 4 of Volume II of this

report.

11

the study aims to trigger a public debate about the optimality of tax and expenditure policies for

Paraguay.

This PER has been prepared at the request of the Paraguayan authorities and in close

collaboration with them, based on a variety of economic and econometric techniques. While

this first volume of the report presents the overall storyline of the challenges to fiscal policy in

Paraguay and discusses policy options to address them. The second volume presents the research

papers that have been prepared as a background to this report in the course of the past two years.

The background papers rely on a variety of economic and econometric techniques, including

VAT estimation, incidence analysis, and the construction of a computable general equilibrium

model. Both the preparation of the BOOST database and of the social accountability matrix are

contributions of this report. The preparation of this report would not have been possible without

the invaluable collaboration with the Ministry of Finance and the Central Bank of Paraguay.

The report provides an overall narrative of remaining challenges for fiscal policy in

Paraguay and a discussion of policy options to address them. To this end, the PER pulls

together existing literature on fiscal policies and economic growth in Paraguay and combines it

with new analysis in the form of background papers presented in volume 2 of the report.

Another contribution is the quantification of characteristics of fiscal policy in Paraguay

that are generally known but have so far eluded discussion due to the lack of concrete

numbers and comparisons. The benefit of providing quantitative analysis for topics that are

widely recognized in Paraguay is that it pulls them into the arena of public discourse. Examples

of such topics in the context of the present PER are: the quantification and international

comparison of the regressivity and progressivity of taxation and expenditures; the quantification

of the dependence of children’s access to public services based on their parents’ socio-economic

background; and the quantification of tax expenditures.

12

Chapter 2: Public Finances in a commodity driven economy

While prudent fiscal policy allowed for macroeconomic stabilization, it also led to low levels of

public spending given limited fiscal resources. Still today, Paraguay is characterized by a low

tax-to-GDP ratio by international standards. A tax reform in 2004 could not generate significant

additional revenues for three main reasons: (i) it failed to introduce taxation in the agricultural

sector proportional to its share of GDP; (ii) significant tax exemptions weakened some reform

measures and still do, as in the case of reformed corporate income tax in the agricultural sector

(IMAGRO); and (iii) some reform measures were not implemented for a long time, for example

the personal income tax. In addition, the reform did not change the actual structure of the tax

system, especially with regard to indirect taxes. In fact, reliance on indirect taxes has increased

over time rendering the system even more regressive than before. While this insulates public

revenues from economic volatility to a certain extent, it imposes high costs associated with

sufficiency and equity of the system. As a result, the current structure of the tax system appears

suboptimal: Other policy tools such as a fiscal rule or a stabilization fund could be used to

manage volatility, and the regressivity is particularly harmful in an economy with high poverty

rates. While the full implementation of the 2004 tax reform could still raise tax revenues,

adequate taxation of the agricultural sector is needed to level the playing field for business

development in all sectors and to address the insufficiency of taxes. An additional source of

fiscal resources would be the elimination of significant tax exemptions. Some of these would

have to be accompanied by targeted spending increases to off-set the potential negative effect on

poverty. This could help Paraguay generate the fiscal resources necessary to increase spending

on infrastructure and on the social sectors and to implement countercyclical fiscal policies. In

terms of expenditures, and in light of the recent expansionary fiscal stance, it appears important

to ensure that fiscal prudence is considered a continuous task. Only if the Government is able to

sustain fiscal prudence in the future, will it be able to maintain macroeconomic stabilization and

performance.

This chapter is structured as follows: section 2.1 provides an overview of the fiscal consolidation

with limited fiscal resources covering the resulting structure of revenues. Section 2.2 describes

the links between fiscal policy and macro-economic volatility. Section 2.3 gives an overview of

the current structure of expenditures, kept brief to avoid overlap with the presentation of social

spending and human development outcomes in sections 1.5 and in Chapters 3 and 4. Section 2.4

concludes with policy recommendations emerging from the findings.

2.1 Fiscal consolidation with limited fiscal resources—the genesis of the

current revenue structure

The Government addressed fiscal consolidation from the perspectives of revenue and

spending, however the main adjustments fell onto spending due to limited revenue

increases. On the revenue side, major changes included the tax policy reform and a new legal

framework for revenue administration. These were implemented in 2004, as was a new customs

code. Yet, the results in terms of additional revenue collection were limited with the tax-to-GDP

13

ratio increasing from 10.3 percent in 2004 to 12.3 percent in 2012 (Table 2.1). On the spending

side, major reforms from 2003 to 2005 included the reform of the public pension scheme in late

2003 together with restrictions on employment and wage increases within selected sectors. This

helped to reign in the high spending of the late 1990s and early 2000s and also helped reduce

expenditures by an average of 2 percent per year between 2004 and 2008. This trend was only

reversed with the Government’s anti-crisis program in 2009 when expenditures increased by 29

percent relative to 2008 (Figure 2.1). A detailed description of the development of expenditures

follows in section 3 of this chapter.

The 2004 tax reform stopped short of resolving the low tax-to-GDP ratio. Law 2421/04 of

administrative reorganization and fiscal adequacy12

was aimed at creating a more effective and

revenue-generating tax system.13

The strategy was to increase the tax-to-GDP ratio gradually by

broadening the tax base, applying moderate rates, and increasing the efficiency of tax

administration. However, as noted in chapter 1, Paraguay’s tax-to-GDP ratio still undershoots

that of all relevant international peer groups (Figure 1.10).

While stable non-tax revenues of the bi-national hydro power-plants eased the fiscal

constraint, Paraguay’s overall tax revenues undershoot those of its international peers.

Non-tax revenues averaged 5.5 percent of GDP since 2004 and have remained stable over time.

After a dip in the middle of the first decade of the millennium, non-tax revenues have picked up

recently, partly because of higher revenues from Itaipu. After renegotiating the treaty on the

allocation of revenues from the power plant in 2011, Paraguay’s revenues from electricity

exports to Brazil increased by around 1 percent of GDP. As of May 2011, once the July 2009

agreement was approved by the Brazilian Senate, the amount that Brazil pays Paraguay for

electricity tripled to US$360 million per year. However, even with this additional revenue,

Paraguay’s total government revenue ranks low by international standards (Figure 2.2).

12

Ley de reordenamiento administrativo y de adecuación fiscal. 13

Refer to IMF (2009) for a comprehensive description of the reform program after the 2002-2003 crisis including

the 2004 tax reform.

Figure 2.1: Revenues and expenditures (percent of

GDP)

Figure 2.2: Government revenues, average 2007- 2011

(percent of GDP)

Source: SITUFIN Source: WDI

0

5

10

15

20

25

199

7

199

8

199

9

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

Revenues/GDP Expenditures/GDP

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

Par

aguay

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Ho

ndu

ras

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Ser

bia

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

LM

IC

UM

IC

LA

C

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

14

Box 1. Royalties from bi-national power plants

Royalties from the bi-national hydropower plants at Itaipu and Yacyreta have accounted for between 2

and 3 percent of GDP between 2005 and 2012, equivalent to between 15 and 20 percent of total revenue.

With the renegotiation of royalties from the bi-national hydroelectric power plant Itaipu, revenues have

increased by around 1 percent of GDP to reach US$ 360 million. In September 2012, the government set

up the Fondo Nacional de Inversion Publica y de Desarollo (FONACIDE) to channel this additional

revenue from the binationals to education, health and infrastructure. Some existing projections vary in a

range of five to ten years with respect to the time horizon for which revenues will remain up due to

growing electricity demand in Paraguay on the back of economic growth. These funds are earmarked by

law, with 28 percent distributed to the national treasury for infrastructure programs and projects, 30

percent to a fund for education and research, 7 percent for the Development Finance Agency (Agencia

Financiera de Desarrollo) and 10 percent for the National Health Fund (Fondo Nacional Para la Salud),

all at the national level. 25 percent of the funds are assigned to departmental governments and

municipalities out of which 50 percent are earmarked for infrastructure in education.

One of the reasons for the limited results of the 2004 tax reform was its failure to introduce

taxation in the agricultural sector proportional to its share of GDP. Prior to the 2004 reform,

the IMAGRO rate was 0.9 percent of the official land valuation. This led to very low revenues

because official land valuations fell short of real values. For example, a 100 hectare property in

14

Internal tax revenue refers to tax revenue excluding import and export duties.

Table 2.1: Tax revenue versus non-tax revenue (percent of GDP)

Source: Ministry of Finance, SITUFIN

Figure 2.3: Share of agricultural tax revenue in internal

tax revenues versus sectoral share in GDP14

Table 2.2: Sectoral weights in gross value added

Source: WDI Source: Central Bank of Paraguay

1980s 1990s 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Tax revenue 7.6 9.3 9.4 9.1 8.1 8.7 10.3 10.1 10.5 10.1 10.7 11.6 12.0 12.1 12.3

Non-tax revenue 1.3 4.5 5.5 6.7 6.0 5.6 5.6 5.5 5.5 5.5 5.1 5.9 5.1 5.3 6.0

Total revenue 8.9 13.8 14.9 15.8 14.0 14.3 15.9 15.7 16.0 15.6 15.8 17.5 17.1 17.4 18.4

0

5

10

15

20

25

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

Percen

t

Share of agriculture in internal tax revenueShare of agriculture in GDP

Share in gross value

added (average 2010 -

2012)

Agriculture 18

Cattle, forestry and fishing 7

Mining and manufacturing 11

Electricity and water 14

Construction 4

Transport and communication 8

Wholesale and retail trade 12

Financial services 2

Other services 25

15

Oviedo had a 1997 official value of Gs.116,691 per hectare. Tax was paid on 80 hectares: the

annual IMAGRO payment was Gs.101,517, or less than US$3 per month. This benefited

primarily farmers with large landholdings, which increasingly dominate the sector with the

expansion of soy cultivation. With the reform, taxes are now assessed based on a net income

criterion. Overall, the tax collection from agriculture increased from 2.7 percent of total tax

revenues in 2004 to 6.4 percent in 2011 (Figure 2.3 and Table 2.3). This low contribution to

overall tax revenues is in stark contrast with the sector’s weight in GDP which has increased

over time from about 12 percent in the second half of the 1990s to over 18 percent in 2010 and

2011 (Figure 2.3 and Table 2.2).

As with other measures of the 2004 tax reform, the new IMAGRO was immediately

weakened by significant tax exemptions and remains so. One of the main reasons behind the

continued low tax collection of the reformed IMAGRO is that VAT paid on purchases of goods

and services as inputs for agricultural production can be credited against the IMAGRO liability

of the agricultural producer. Even though this tax credit was abolished in September 2008,

accrued claims still reduced IMAGRO collections until decree 8279 was announced in 2012 and

suspended the possibility to claim back past VAT credits. Tax exemptions that stem from the

exemptions of VAT taxes to the agricultural sector amount to 0.33 percent of GDP.

Total tax exemptions are estimated to amount to 1.3 percent of GDP. This is particularly

significant when compared to Paraguay’s tax-to-GDP ratio. Besides VAT exemptions to the

agricultural sector of 0.3 percent of GDP, the other main exemptions include: exemptions on

interest related to VAT (0.25 percent of GDP); a reduced VAT rate of 5 percent as opposed to

the usual 10 percent for basic consumer goods (0.29 percent of GDP); a special tax regime for

fuels (0.3 percent of GDP); and exemptions from import duties (0.15 percent of GDP) (see

Schenone (2012) and (2010)).

Table 2.3: Sectoral contribution to total internal tax

revenue

Table 2.4: Revenue by tax type

Source: SET Source: SITUFIN

Revenue by economic activity

Average

2000 to 2004

(percent of total)

Average

2005 to 2011

(percent of total)

Industry 27 22

Wholesale and retail trade 14 24

Financial Intermediation 17 13

Electricity, gas, and water 8 5

Transport 9 12

Public admin and defense 7 4

Agrobusiness sector 2 5

Other sectors 16 15

Revenue by tax

Average

2000 to 2004

(percent of total)

Average

2005 to 2012

(percent of total)

VAT + other consumption taxes 64 66

Income taxes 17 21

Other taxes 18 13

16

Table 2.5: Government tax revenue by tax type (percent of total unless stated otherwise)

Source: Ministry of Finance, SITUFIN, SET

While the expansion of the tax base compensated for exemptions and lower marginal tax

rates relative to the pre-reform period, Paraguay still does not fully exploit its tax potential. In fact, the reform introduced a simple structure of taxes where corporate income, personal

income, agricultural income, small business income, and value added are generally all taxed with

a 10 percent uniform tax rate. In the case of the corporate income tax, this meant a 20 percentage

point reduction in the marginal tax rate (Table 2.6). The reform was successful in formalizing the

economy, as the number of contributors tripled between 2003 and 2011, and the tax revenue in

real terms more than doubled. At the same time, the average contribution per taxpayer dropped

by around 20 percent (Figure 2.4). While the broader tax base compensated for the exemptions

and the decrease in marginal tax rates, the average tax burden per contributor continues to be

relatively low by international standards and Paraguay’s marginal tax rates are lower than in

international comparator countries. Table 2.6: Marginal tax rates over time

Source: SET, CADEP, Schenone (2012)

Notes: * The basis for IMAGRO before the reform was the official valuation of the land, after the crisis the basis is net income.

An exception to the 10 percent rate is small farms with less than 300 hectares in the Eastern region or 1500 hectares in Western

part of Paraguay, to which a tax rate of 2.5 percent applies.

** Despite being created as part of the 2004 tax reform, the personal income tax was only implemented in August 2012.

*** IRPC (Corporate Income tax for small corporations) simplified procedures for small business with less than Gs 100 million

(around USD 22'500) in total sales per year.

**** ISC COMB (Consumption tax for fuels goods) has a maximum of 50 percent, but different tax rates below 50 percent apply

to different types of fuels.

****** IVA (value added tax) is in general 10 percent, however exceptions for a number of products exist for example

agriculture products of the basic food basket and pharmaceutical products to which a 5 percent rate applies.

******* The 2004 reform replaced TU (Tributo Unico--corporate income tax for small corporations).

1980s 1990s 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Income taxes 18.0 18.4 17.9 16.1 20.0 17.0 17.9 17.4 15.2 17.5 18.2 23.8 18.4 19.8 20.9

IRACIS - 17.1 16.6 14.9 16.8 15.5 16.8 16.9 15.8 17.5 17.9 23.1 18.3 18.9 -

IMAGRO - 0.3 0.9 0.9 1.0 0.0 0.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.8 -

Wealth taxes 6.3 0.9 0.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

Export taxes 1.3 0.7 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0

Import taxes 14.9 20.6 18.2 17.5 16.7 18.1 18.3 14.9 14.6 11.9 12.3 10.6 13.4 12.9 11.8

Value added tax 0.0 31.8 43.0 42.2 42.9 42.7 39.3 43.9 44.8 50.2 52.1 48.3 51.8 51.4 51.0

Consumption tax 54.6 21.3 16.5 20.3 18.4 19.3 20.6 18.8 17.6 18.7 16.1 16.3 15.7 15.3 15.5

Fuel 7.6 7.3 11.1 14.8 14.4 15.6 16.6 14.1 13.2 14.2 11.8 11.4 10.6 10.8 10.8

Other goods 47.1 14.1 5.4 5.5 4.1 3.6 3.9 4.7 4.5 4.5 4.4 4.9 5.1 4.5 4.8

Other taxes 4.9 6.2 4.4 3.8 2.0 3.0 3.9 5.0 7.8 1.7 1.3 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.7

Total tax revenue in percent of GDP 8.9 13.8 14.9 15.8 14.0 14.3 15.9 15.7 16.0 15.6 15.8 17.5 17.1 17.4 18.4

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

ACTOS Y DOCUMENTOS (Financial transaction tax) 1.25 1.25 1.25 1.25 1.25 0.01 0.01 0 0 0 0 0

IMAGRO (Corporate income tax for agriculture)* 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 10 10 10 10 10 10 10

IRACIS (Corporate income tax for commercial, industrial and services activities) 30 30 30 30 30 20 10 10 10 10 10 10

IRP (Personal Income tax)** 10 10 10 10

IRPC (Corporate Income tax for small corporations)*** 4 4 4 4 4 10 10 10 10 10 10 10

ISC COMB (Consumption tax for fuels)**** 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50 50

ISC OTROS (Consumption tax for selected goods, other than fuels)***** 9 9 9 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 10

IVA (Value added tax)****** 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10 10

TU (Tributo Unico-- Corporate income tax for small corporations)******* 4 4 4 4 4

17

The tax reform increased the number of contributors significantly for all taxes, while the

average contribution per taxpayer dropped; corporate income tax is an exception where

average contribution actually increased. For VAT, tax revenue in real terms doubled, the

average contribution per taxpayer dropped by almost 50 percent between 2003 and 2011,

however this loss was offset by a quadrupling of the number of contributors during that period.

This led to an average VAT contribution per taxpayer of around US$1,300 in current terms in

2011. IMAGRO revenues also tripled in real terms between 2003 and 2011 reaching 0.8 percent

of total tax revenue and less than 0.1 percent of GDP in 2011 (Table 2.5). The number of

contributors to this tax more than doubled over this period, while the contribution per taxpayer in

real terms dropped by 15 percent. As a result, the average contribution per taxpayer to IMAGRO

reached around US$200 in 2011. In contrast, the corporate income tax, IRACIS, is the only tax

for which both the number of contributors and the average contribution per taxpayer increased,

they increased by 100 and 40 percent respectively. As a result, the average contributor paid

around US$2,800 in 2011. IRACIS revenues displayed the highest increase in tax revenue in real

terms between 2003 and 2011 – a five-fold increase. Yet, in terms of its share in total tax revenue

it remains far behind VAT revenues (Table 2.5).

Figure 2.4: Total internal tax revenue: Number of

contributors versus average contribution by taxpayer

Figure 2.5: VAT: Number of contributors versus average

contribution by taxpayer

Source: SET Source: SET

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

Th

ou

san

ds

of

con

stri

bu

tors

Con

sta

nt

20

03

mil

lion

Gu

ara

nie

s

Number of contributors (RHS)

Average revenue per contributor

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

720

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

Th

ou

san

ds

of

con

stri

bu

tors

Con

sta

nt

20

03

mil

lion

Gu

ara

nie

s

Number of contributors (RHS)

Average revenue per contributor

18

The third reason for the limited impact of the 2004 reform concerns measures that were

not implemented, for example, the personal income tax which was postponed until August

2012. The implementation of personal income tax was postponed several times until it was

finally approved by Congress in August 2012. However, the estimated impact on tax collection is

low, around 1 percent of GDP. The reason for this is that the tax is intended as a measure for

cross-checking information on VAT compliance rather than generating additional tax revenue.

Adequately documented, personal expenditures can be claimed against the income tax liability.

Direct revenue generated by the tax is expected to reach around 0.65 percent of GDP, while the

indirect impact through the reduction of VAT evasion is expected to amount to around 0.4

percent of GDP (see Schenone (2012) for details).

Figure 2.6: IMAGRO: Number of contributors versus

average contribution by tax payer

Figure 2.7: Corporate income tax: Number of

contributors versus average contribution by tax payer

Source: SET Source: SET

Figure 2.8: Marginal rate on VAT tax Figure 2.9: Revenues from VAT over GDP, average

2007-2011

Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

Th

ou

san

ds

of

con

strib

uto

rs

Con

sta

nt

20

03

mil

lion

Gu

ara

nie

s

Number of contributors (RHS)

Average revenue per contributor

0

50

100

150

200

250

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

Th

ou

san

ds

of

con

stri

bu

tors

Con

sta

nt

20

03

mil

lion

Gu

ara

nie

s

Number of contributors (RHS)

Average revenue per contributor

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

LMICs LAC Paraguay

Per

cen

t

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Par

agu

ay

Boli

via

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Hond

ura

s

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Pap

ua

New

Guin

ea

Ser

bia

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

guay

Low

er m

iddle

Upper

mid

dle

LA

C

Percen

t of

GD

P

19

The reform did not change the structure of the tax system: the reliance on indirect taxes is

a feature that remained and has further increased over time, rendering the system more

regressive. By not addressing problems inherent to the structure of the tax system, the 2004

reform has contributed little to resolving the challenges of high poverty and inequality. As will

be explained in detail in chapter 3, tax revenue collection in Paraguay is more regressive than in

other Latin American countries, and to a large extent this stems from a strong reliance on indirect

taxes such as VAT and consumption taxes. The 2004 reform actually increased this reliance from

64 percent before the reform to 66 percent after the reform (Table 2.4). By their nature, indirect

taxes are more regressive than direct taxes.

Figure 2.10: Marginal rate on corporate income tax Figure 2.11: Revenues from corporate income tax over

GDP, average 2007-2011

Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET

Figure 2.12: Marginal tax on personal income tax Figure 2.13: Revenues from personal income tax over

GDP, average 2007-2011

Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

LMICs LAC Paraguay

Per

cen

t

01234567

Par

agu

ay

Boli

via

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Hon

dura

s

Jord

an

Pap

ua

New

Guin

ea

Ser

bia

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

Low

er m

iddle

Upp

er m

iddle

LA

C

Per

cen

t of

GD

P

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

LMICs LAC Paraguay

Per

cen

t

0123456789

Par

agu

ay

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Hon

dura

s

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Pap

ua

New

Ser

bia

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

Low

er m

iddle

Upp

er m

iddle

LA

C

Percen

t of

GD

P

20

While a strong reliance on VAT tax revenue is a feature that Paraguay shares with

emerging economies, Paraguay’s reliance is heavier than international comparators.

Despite the low marginal tax rate, VAT is Paraguay’s main source of tax revenue and

represented 5.7 percent of GDP or 51 percent of total tax revenue on average between 2007 and

2011 (Figure 2.8). This is more than in the average Latin American country (4.5 percent of GDP

or 24 percent of total tax revenue); the average low middle income country (5.3 percent of GDP

or 29 percent of total tax revenue); and also more than in the average upper middle income

country (5.7 percent of GDP or 29 percent of total tax revenue) (Figure 2.9). In the peer group of

countries with similar population and GDP per capita only in Georgia, Serbia, and Uruguay VAT

does tax revenue represent around 50 percent of GDP, in the other countries this share is lower.

At the same time, Paraguay falls short of its peer countries in terms of the revenue contribution

of corporate income taxes and personal income taxes, both relative to GDP and relative to total

tax revenue (Figure 2.11 and 2.13).

Low marginal tax rates and relatively high or average tax revenue collection in Paraguay

suggest a productive tax system by international standards. Paraguay’s marginal tax rates are

low by international comparison (Figures 2.8, 2.10, and 2.12). At the same time, VAT revenue as

a percentage of GDP is higher in Paraguay than in comparator countries and as a result, VAT

productivity in Paraguay, with a rate of 0.57 percent, is higher than in the average lower middle

income country, which has a rate of 0.4 percent, or in the average Latin American country where

the rate is 0.36 percent (Figure 2.13).15

VAT is the most productive tax in Paraguay (Figure 2.13,

2.14, and 2.15). Also, in the case of corporate income tax, Paraguay has proven to be more

productive than its peers. Paraguay only underperformed its peers from 2007 to 2011 in terms of

personal income tax, a result of the tax not having been implemented until 2012.

Tax productivity in Paraguay has been increasing, and with the implementation of

personal income tax reforms in 2012 and the suspension of VAT credit against IMAGRO,

further improvements are expected. With unchanged marginal rates and increasing tax

revenue, the Paraguayan tax system has become more productive over time. This increase in

productivity can be explained by the expansion of the tax base and also by efficiency gains

15

Productivity is measured as the ratio of revenue relative to GDP over the marginal tax rate.

Figure 2.14: VAT productivity, average 2007-2011

Figure 2.15: Corporate income tax productivity,

average 2007-2011

Source: USAID collecting taxes, SET

0.00

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.70

LMICs LAC Paraguay

Rev

enu

e over

GD

P /

ra

te

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

LMICs LAC Paraguay

Rev

enu

e over

GD

P /

ra

te

21

through improvements in tax administration. One important advance in recent years has been the

introduction and implementation of a large taxpayer unit within the tax revenue department.

While the direct revenue effect of personal income tax is estimated to be moderate, it will help

raise additional revenue through continued formalization of the economy. Additional tax revenue

can be expected by suspending the possibility to claim past VAT credits as stated in Decree 8279

of 2012.

Further reforms are needed to address the insufficiency of tax revenue to cover the public

provision of social services. Additional revenues, which are expected to come from the

introduction of personal income tax and the suspension of VAT credit against IMAGRO will not

be enough to provide fiscal resources to catch up with international peer countries in terms of the

public provision of social services. Section 2.5 provides a discussion of policy options which is

intended as a basis for further dialog on continuing the reform program.

2.2 The link between fiscal policy and macroeconomic volatility

The volatile macroeconomic environment impacts revenues and expenditures with both

variables being similarly volatile and expenditures mirroring the recent increase in overall

volatility. Measured by simple metrics as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, revenues

and expenditures show a similar degree of volatility. A significant drop in volatility in the third

quarter of 2004 can be observed when analyzing quarterly y-o-y changes of fiscal revenues with

the help of the methodology developed by Inclan and Tiao (1994) (Table Annex 1.2). The time

of the break in volatility coincides with the 2004 tax reform. In contrast, public consumption and

investment have become more volatile, with volatility of public consumption increasing twice in

the second quarter of 2000 and then again in the first quarter of 2009. Public investment

temporarily became less volatile between the second quarter of 2002 and the second quarter of

2008.

Table 2.7: Volatility of revenues and expenditures

Source: Central Bank of Paraguay

Total revenueTotal tax

revenuesExpenditures

Total

revenues

Total tax

revenuesExpenditures

1980-2012 10.3 9.4 12.2 4.3 6.9 4.4

Standard deviation of real growth rates Coefficient of variation of real growth rates

22

Revenues and expenditures have been pro-cyclical in the past 2 decades, revealing a missed

opportunity as fiscal policy can be used for counter-cyclical macro-economic management. Public revenues are pro-cyclical as measured by their positive and significant relationship with

the GDP gap during the period 1990 to 2010.16

On the expenditures side, Hnatkovska and

Koehler-Geib (2013) find pro-cyclicality of Government consumption and investment in the

period from 1994 to 2011 to be in line with a large economic literature.17

Government

consumption displays higher pro-cyclicality than investment. Pro-cyclicality is defined as a

positive response of government spending to an exogenous expansionary business cycle shock.

Gavin and Perotti (1997) showed that this is the case in Latin America. Talvi and Végh (2005)

then claimed that pro-cyclical fiscal policy is not only a Latin American phenomenon, it is

present in the entire developing world. In a recent study, Ilzetzki and Végh (2008) revisit the

evidence using a sample of 49 countries while allowing for a reverse causality running from

fiscal policy to GDP. They show that fiscal policy is indeed pro-cyclical in developing countries.

One reason for this pro-cyclicality could be frictions in international credit markets that prevent

developing countries from borrowing in bad times ((Gavin and Perotti (1997), Caballero and

Krishnamurthy (2004), Mendoza and Oviedo (2006), and others); another reason originates from

a political economy perspective, and proposes that good times encourage fiscal profligacy

((Tornell and Lane (1998), Talvi and Végh (2005), and others); the third reason rests in delays in

the implementation and execution of fiscal policies in developing economies.

16

Le Fort, Escobar, and Contreras (2013) estimate an OLS regression with yearly data from 1990 to 2010 relating

the natural log of revenues with the GDP gap and trend component. GDP gap and trend are estimated using different

filtering methods including Hodrick Prescott (HP), Christiano-Fiztgerald (CF), and Butterworth (BW) filters. 17

The authors use quarterly data from 1994 and 2011, they seasonally adjust the series using moving average filters

and de-trend the series by computing their log deviations from a log-linear trend. They then calculate the

unconditional correlations between the gaps. Public consumption displays a 0.88 correlation with GDP growth and

public investment shows a 0.08 correlation.

Figure 2.16: Business cycle fluctuations in Paraguay—

Public consumption versus GDP

Figure 2.17: Business cycle fluctuations in Paraguay—

Public investment versus GDP

Source: Hnatkovska and Koehler-Geib (2013)

-.2

-.1

0.1

.2.3

Gov C

ons (

log)

-.1

-.05

0.0

5.1

GD

P (

log)

1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1

GDP (log) Gov Cons (log)

-1-.

50

.5

Gov Inv (

log)

-.1

-.05

0.0

5.1

GD

P (

log)

1995q1 2000q1 2005q1 2010q1

GDP (log) Gov Inv (log)

23

Figure 2.18: Contribution of public and private demand components to real GDP growth

Source: Central Bank of Paraguay

Yet, while fiscal policies have appeared pro-cyclical over the past two decades, a look at the

data suggests that public demand was counter-cyclical during the contractions of 2009 and

2012. Public sector demand expanded when private demand—and as a consequence economic

growth—collapsed in the four quarters of 2009 (see Figure 2.18).18

The decomposition of real

growth into the components of aggregate demand reveals that public demand components

together contributed positively to real growth in the four quarters of 2009 while private demand

contracted heavily. The expansion of public demand was based on strong increases in both

public investment and consumption (see Figure 2.16). Public demand ceased to be anti-cyclical

by the first quarter of 2010, when it expanded at the same time as private demand was already

recovering strongly. Only in the third quarter of 2010 does public demand contribute negatively

amidst a fast private sector expansion. A similar pattern can be observed in 2012 with the same

challenge of withdrawing expansionary expenditure fast enough when private sector growth

recovers.

18

Public demand components comprise public consumption, public investment, and the share of the public sector in

imports and changes in inventories.

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

200

1 Q

1

200

1 Q

3

200

2 Q

1

200

2 Q

3

200

3 Q

1

200

3 Q

3

200

4 Q

1

200

4 Q

3

200

5Q

1

200

5Q

3

200

6 Q

1

200

6 Q

3

200

7 Q

1

200

7 Q

3

200

8 Q

1

200

8 Q

3

200

9 Q

1

200

9 Q

3

201

0 Q

1

201

0 Q

3

201

1 Q

1

201

1 Q

3

201

2 Q

1

201

2 Q

3

Per

cen

t y

-o-y

rea

l g

row

th a

nd

per

cen

tag

e co

ntr

ibu

tio

n

Public demand Private Demand GDP growth

24

Figure 2.19: Public consumption and investment (quarterly y-o-y growth)

Source: Central Bank of Paraguay

If fiscal policy were to become more counter-cyclical, it would play an important role in

Paraguay, given that a shock to international commodity prices similar to that of 2009

would threaten growth and poverty reduction. Agricultural GDP in Paraguay has become

more volatile in recent years and together with the cattle, forestry and fishing sectors is

Paraguay’s most important sector (Table 2.2 and refer to World Bank (2013), forthcoming for an

in depth analysis of this phenomenon and its impact on the economy). The agricultural sector

focuses on few products and few export destinations: soy and beef alone made up an average of

34 percent of total exports over the past 5 years and exports to Brazil and Argentina alone

-60

-40

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

200

8 Q

1

200

8 Q

2

200

8 Q

3

200

8 Q

4

200

9 Q

1

200

9 Q

2

200

9 Q

3

200

9 Q

4

201

0 Q

1

201

0 Q

2

201

0 Q

3

201

0 Q

4

201

1 Q

1

201

1 Q

2

201

1 Q

3

201

1 Q

4

201

2 Q

1

201

2 Q

2

201

2 Q

3

201

2 Q

4Per

cen

t q

ua

rter

ly y

-o-y

rea

l g

row

th

Public consumption Public Investment

Figure 2.20: Exports by product Table 2.8: Export by destination

Source: Central Bank of Paraguay

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Per

cen

t of

GD

P

Per

cen

t of

tota

l ex

port

s

Other Grains

Beef Soy beans

Electricity Total in percent of GDP(RHS)

Argentina Brazil Uruguay

Total

MERCOSUR

Continental

China

Rest of the

World

average

since 200013 47 6 66 1 33

average

since 200811 37 1 49 1 50

25

reached almost 50 percent of total exports in the period since 2008. Any decrease in the world

export price of soy and beef, similar to that observed in 2009, would have strong negative effects

on the economy. A Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model is used to track the macro

and micro economic effects that a 25 percent decrease in soy and beef prices in 2013 (maintained

through 2018) would have in Paraguay, (see Diaz-Bonilla and Cicowiez (2013)) for a detailed

description of the model, the base line scenario and simulation results). Any decrease in the

world export prices of soy and beef would result in slower GDP growth than under the baseline

scenario; accompanying negative impacts on the private sector (reduced employment growth,

reduced private consumption) means that poverty would decrease to 25.8 percent by 2018 and

not 24.5 percent as in the baseline simulation. Inequality and millennium development goals

would remain practically unchanged. If the price of all of Paraguay’s export products were to

drop, this would have a strong negative impact on the country’s progress towards the millennium

development goals and inequality, and given the persistent high levels of poverty and inequality

in Paraguay, such potential impacts would support the need for fiscal policy to buffer the effects

of any shift in international commodity prices.

The value of soy and beef exports has a positive and significant impact on fiscal revenues

and as such it is important to take commodity prices into account. A positive and significant

relationship can be established between soy and beef prices versus fiscal revenues, modeling the

relationship in a two-step approach. Favaro, Koehler-Geib, Picarelli, and Indaco (2013) find beef

and soybean exports respond strongly to prices (using the canonical Nerlove (1959) model), they

then find a positive and statistically significant relationship between tax revenue collection and

the value of exported beef and soybean. A caveat to the analysis at the first step is that due to

data restrictions export volumes instead of production volumes are used. The response in actual

production may be lower than the estimated elasticities in this approach. The result of the second

step is not trivial given the low direct taxation of the agricultural sector. The results seem to

indicate that the positive relationship is due to value added tax. Beef and soybean production

generate income that is spent inside Paraguay for the most part. Part of this expenditure generates

tax revenue via VAT and another part generates revenue through corporate income tax. The

elasticity of soy exports to price changes exceeds that of beef, which could be linked to the

limited time that soybean brokers have to hold the crop rather than commercialize it while there

is more room for timing decisions in the case of beef. When it comes to the relationship between

tax revenues versus soy and beef exports, the elasticity of revenues is higher in the case of beef.

This is in line with how much more labor intensive beef is than soy and how it is more integrated

into the value chain in Paraguay.19

While the strong reliance on indirect taxes has insulated fiscal revenues from

macroeconomic volatility to a certain extent, it comes at a high cost in terms of sufficiency

and equity of the tax system. One advantage of VAT tax collection vis-à-vis other tax revenues

is that it is has fluctuated less. In terms of the simple metrics of standard deviations and

coefficients of variation, real VAT tax collections were the most stable source of income over the

past 2 decades (Table 2.8). However, as discussed in section 2.1, collecting little in direct taxes

19

It seems to be important to take into account the indirect way in which commodity prices impact fiscal revenues,

in a cointegration analysis of fiscal revenues versus beef and soy prices with yearly data from 1990 to 2010, Le Fort

(2013) cannot detect a statistically significant relationship.

26

adds to the low tax-to-GDP ratio which is at the core of Paraguay’s challenge of low fiscal

resources that constrain spending on human development and growth-enhancing policies.

Moreover, as will be discussed in depth in Chapter 3, the cost in terms of the regressivity of the

tax system are high, a fact that prevents fiscal policy from more aggressively addressing the

persistent challenge of high poverty and levels of inequality.

Table 2.9: Volatility of different tax types (annual real growth)

Source: SITUFIN

This high reliance on indirect taxes is suboptimal given that alternative fiscal policy tools

are available to manage macroeconomic volatility. In section 2.4 policy options implemented

by other countries will be discussed including a fiscal responsibility law; the establishment of a

stabilization fund; and the strengthening of automatic stabilizers.

2.3 Expenditures

Even though Paraguay’s public expenditure has increased both in absolute terms and as a

percentage of GDP, it is low by international standards. Total public expenditure reached 20

percent of GDP in 2012, representing an increase of 5 percentage points since 2003 (Figure 2.1).

Yet, when Paraguay’s expenditure is compared with the average Latin American country; with

its peer group in terms of population and GDP per capita; or with lower middle income countries

over the past 5 years, Paraguay spends the least. This also is true when looking at figures from

2011.

The fiscal space for the expenditure increase has stemmed mainly from an increase in

revenue and a reduction in interest payments, a result of the significant reduction in public

debt. Fiscal space is measured as the flexible part of expenditure (that which remains after

interest payments, wages, pensions, and transfers to other Government entities are covered) over

total revenues. Fiscal prudence (as measured by this simple metric), together with solid growth

rates successfully reduced Paraguay’s public debt-to-GDP ratio from 41 percent in 2002 to 12

percent in 2012 (Figure 2.24). This has led to a significant decrease in interest payments. As a

1994-2012 1994-2004 2005-2012 1994-2012 1994-2004 2005-2012

Tax revenue 8.6 11.1 3.9 3.3 4.0 1.6

Income taxes 18.1 18.8 18.5 3.8 4.6 3.2

Import taxes 18.9 21.0 16.5 18.4 6.5 -8.3

Value added tax 8.0 9.7 4.6 2.1 4.0 0.8

Consumption tax 12.7 15.2 6.2 3.5 2.2 -6.0

Fuel 41.7 54.2 7.9 5.4 3.5 -2.8

Other goods 18.7 23.4 10.8 3.6 4.7 2.0

Other taxes 36.5 34.8 40.7 -14.1 77.0 -6.0

Non-tax revenue 11.8 13.4 10.1 6.2 5.6 8.2

Total Government Revenue 6.4 7.7 4.6 3.0 3.4 2.4

Coefficient of variationStandard deviation

27

result, Paraguay was the country with the lowest burden of interest as a percentage of GDP in

Latin America in 2011 (Figure 2.25).

The reduction in interest payments stem to a large extent from good debt management

practices, but three challenges remain to be addressed to sustain these past gains in the

future. First, while an implicit medium debt management strategy exists in the Ministry of

Finance, its legal formalization and the publication of annual borrowing plans would support the

predictability of public debt issuance in the domestic market and thereby increase demand.

Second, the fragmentation of debt management between the General Directorate of Public Credit

and Debt (DGCDP) and the Directorate of Debt Policy introduces frictions into the debt

management process. Third, in the absence of a strengthened legal framework and the promotion

of a more active domestic debt market, Paraguay remains dependent on international financing.

In particular, the improvement of the institutional structure for debt management and

establishing an effective debt management capacity is essential as a weak institutional structure

pose significant risks for the future.

Figure 2.21: Fiscal Space Figure 2.22: Public Expenditure in international

comparison (average 2007-2011)

Source: SITUFIN Source: IMF GFS

Figure 2.23: Paraguay’s public debt over time Figure 2.24: Interest expenditure in Latin America

Source: Central Bank of Paraguay Source: IMF GFS, 2011 or latest available

0

10

20

30

40

50

200

0

200

1

200

2

200

3

200

4

200

5

200

6

200

7

200

8

200

9

201

0

201

1

201

2

Per

cen

t

05

1015202530354045

Par

aguay

Boli

via

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Ho

ndu

ras

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Ser

bia

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

LM

IC

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

19

91

19

92

19

93

19

94

19

95

19

96

19

97

19

98

19

99

20

00

20

01

20

02

20

03

20

04

20

05

20

06

20

07

20

08

20

09

20

10

20

11

20

12

Percen

t

External Debt/GDP Domestic Debt/GDP

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Jam

aica

St. K

itts

an

d N

evis

Bra

zil

Bar

bad

os

Bel

ize

Trin

idad

an

d T

ob

ago

Bah

amas

, Th

e

Co

lom

bia

Uru

guay

St. V

ince

nt

and

th

e…

Gre

nad

a

Co

sta

Ric

a

El S

alva

do

r

Do

min

ican

Rep

ub

lic

Gu

atem

ala

Ho

nd

ura

s

Per

u

Nic

arag

ua

Ch

ile

Par

agu

ay

Pe

rcen

t o

f G

DP

28

The creation of fiscal space has also been at risk due to the unclear division of

responsibilities between the executive and the legislature in the budget approval.20 Unclear

responsibilities affect the budget preparation process and complicate planning. They have also

led to spending increases in the past. As described in detail in IMF (2009), the State Financial

Administration Law (LAFE) of 1999 and the annual budget law represent the legal framework

for the budget process. Despite Article 17 of the LAFE law, which establishes that Congress

cannot reallocate resources from capital to current spending and that it can only increase capital

spending after a proper identification of financing, Congress introduces substantial modifications

and increases to the executive budget proposal.21

Congress augments not only capital but also

current expenditure allocations, which are supposedly “financed” with unrealistic upward

revisions in revenue projections or by the authorization of improbable domestic debt issues. The

result is a budgetary process that neglects aggregate fiscal constraints and threatens

macroeconomic stability, misallocates resources, and makes the budget vulnerable to undue

influence by vested interests.

While some of the challenges in budget preparation and budget execution are being

addressed through the development of a Medium Term Fiscal Framework, further

improvements are needed.22 The Ministry of Finance has started to prepare a fiscal policy

report containing, three-year macroeconomic and fiscal projections. The first such report was

published jointly with the 2011 budget law. The ministry’s macro-fiscal unit is moving towards

preparing macro-fiscal projections, identifying contingent risks, and preparing reports on the

macro-fiscal outlook. The link between expenditures and the high level objectives defined in the

Government’s budget could be further strengthened by integrating the medium-term fiscal

framework into the budget, identifying and assessing fiscal risks and reporting them in budget

documents, and by further developing a medium-term expenditure framework.

In terms of functional classification, Paraguay spends most on education followed by public

administration and social security, and social protection. In 2012, expenditure on education

amounted to 21 percent of the budget; administration absorbed 19 percent and social security and

social protection 18. In contrast, health expenditure, with the steepest increase, has tripled since

2003, followed by justice (doubled) and education (increased by 64 percent). In 2003,

administration, followed by debt service, were the two biggest line items. These increases in

expenditure on education and health are very positive developments for Paraguay given

Paraguay’s history of low social expenditure.

Both health and education spending increased rapidly, however, while Paraguay caught up

with many international comparators on health spending this was not the case for

education. Per capita public spending on education increased at an average annual rate of 17

percent, while per capita health expenditure rose by an average of 22 percent every year between

2003 and 2011. In the same period, coverage of key education and health services improved

20

This paragraph draws on IMF (2009), chapter 9. 21

From a legal point of view, Paraguay does not have higher-ranking laws or organic laws to regulate the budget

process. The LAFE is an ordinary law, and congress has interpreted that to mean that it can be modified by another

ordinary law such as the annual budget law. The LAFE (a permanent law) should have higher hierarchy than the

annual budget law (a transitory law), in which case the executive branch could challenge the legality of congress’s

budget amendments in the courts. 22

See IMF (2011) for more details.

29

markedly. It is important to note though that a large share of the spending increase has been on

public sector wages. Paraguay has caught up with comparator countries in terms of health

spending relative to GDP, but this is not the case for overall social spending and in education for

example, where Paraguay spends less than comparator countries (Figures 1.11, 2.26, and 2.27).

Figure 2.25: Functional classification

Source: BOOST database

Figure 2.26: Education expenditure in international

comparison (average 2007-2011)

Figure 2.27: Health expenditure in international

comparison

Source: GFS

When it comes to economic classification, the most notable feature of Paraguay’s spending

is the high share of spending on wages. The share of wage spending of the total budget

increased from 38 percent in 2003 to 44 percent in 2012. The biggest increase occurred between

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

4.5

5

Ed

uca

tion

& C

ult

ure

Ad

min

istr

atio

n

So

cial

Sec

uri

ty &

pro

tect

ion

Hea

lth &

san

itat

ion

Def

ense

& n

atio

nal

sec

uri

ty

Just

ice

Deb

t se

rvic

e

Oth

ers

Tra

nsp

ort

En

erg

y &

Min

ing

Com

unic

atio

ns

Reg

ula

tio

n

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

2003 2006 2009 2012

0123456789

Par

aguay

Boli

via

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Nic

arag

ua

Ser

bia

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

LA

C

LM

IC

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Par

aguay

Boli

via

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Ho

ndu

ras

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Pap

ua

New

Ser

bia

Tu

rkm

enis

tan

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

LM

IC

LA

C

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

30

2009 and 2012 when wage spending increased by 21 percent. It had already increased by 17

percent between 2006 and 2009.

Figure 2.28: Economic classification

Source: BOOST database

While the international comparison of current versus capital expenditures reflects

Paraguay’s overall low spending levels, the country has a relatively high ratio of current

versus capital expenditure. Paraguay spends less than most of its international comparators,

both in terms of current and capital expenditures. However, current expenditure is more than

twice as high as capital expenditure, a ratio that exceeds that of the average lower middle income

country or the average Latin American country. This suggests that Paraguay has neglected public

infrastructure needs in favor of current expenditures.

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10P

erso

nn

el

Oth

er c

urr

ent

expen

dit

ure

s

Oth

er c

apit

al c

ost

s

Go

ods

& s

erv

ices

Inv

este

men

t in

non

-

fin

anci

al a

sset

s

So

cial

sec

uri

ty

Deb

t se

rvic

e

Fin

anci

al i

nv

este

men

t

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

2003 2006 2009 2012

Figure 2.29: Compensation of employees in

international comparison (average 2007-2011)

Figure 2 30: Current versus capital expenditure in

international comparison (average 2007-2011)

Source: GFS

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

Par

aguay

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Ho

ndu

ras

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Ser

bia

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

LM

IC

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Par

aguay

Boli

via

Bulg

aria

El

Sal

vad

or

Geo

rgia

Ho

ndu

ras

Jord

an

Nic

arag

ua

Pap

ua…

Ser

bia

Tu

rkm

eni…

Arg

enti

na

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

LM

IC

LA

C

Per

cen

t o

f G

DP

Current expenditure Capital expenditure

31

In light of the recent worsening of the fiscal stance, it is important to consider fiscal

prudence a continuous task. Only if the Government is able to sustain fiscal prudence in the

future, will it be able to maintain macroeconomic stabilization and performance. After 8 years of

fiscal surpluses, the government recorded its first 12-month accumulated overall fiscal deficit in

May 2012. In the fourth quarter of 2012 the fiscal deficit was nearly 3.5 times higher than in

December 2011. Yet, in terms of GDP fiscal deficits remain moderate: in 2012, the fiscal deficit

amounted to 1.7 percent of GDP, compared with a surplus of 0.7 percent of GDP in 2011.

Following expansionary fiscal policy in 2012 due to fiscal stimulus and increased spending

in the run-up to the 2013 election, an immediate return to a tighter fiscal stance would be

critical to demonstrate the commitment to fiscal prudence. Following a bad harvest and poor

economic prospects at the beginning of 2012, the government relied on its Plan de aumento de la

inversion y el consumo with a more expansionary fiscal policy to stimulate the economy. The

run-up to the April 2013 presidential election also led to higher spending. In terms of GDP, as of

December 2012, wages and salaries increased by 26 percent; capital expenditure increased by 20

percent.

2.4 Policy options

The findings of the previous sections suggest a number of measures that could increase

revenue from tax collection and could help the tax system contribute more to the reduction

of poverty and inequality. The following recommendations draw on the technical analysis and

also take into considerations institutional and other constraints that, as history has shown, present

obstacles to improvements in the country’s tax system.

In order to ensure that the agricultural sector is adequately taxed, the government could

consider making some changes to the IMAGRO. The introduction of a new IMAGRO as part

of the 2004 reforms was an important step towards incorporating the agricultural sector into the

tax base; and the phasing out of the VAT credit contributed to improved collections. However, a

number of additional measures would be important to make the tax more effective. These

include: (i) eliminating special regimes for large and medium enterprises; (ii) establishing an

obligation for all taxpayers (excluding small farms of less than 20 hectares in the eastern part of

the country and less than 100 hectares in the western part) to liquidate tax through the general

mechanism of gross income minus production costs; (iii) eliminating the exemption for losses in

cattle, currently at up to 3 percent of total income, without proof; (iv) eliminating deductions for

personal expenditures and investments; and (v) eliminating deductions for expenditures on

neighboring farms.

The most important gains from reducing exemptions would stem from changes to value

added tax. The analysis in this chapter shows that even though VAT productivity is high, there

are significant tax exemptions that create distortions and reduce revenue collections. The

following measured could be considered by the government: (i) elimination of the suspension of

VAT applied to petrol imports; (ii) elimination of all cases where a reduced VAT rate of 5

percent is applied, a uniform rate of 10 percent would be used as envisaged during the 2004

reform. This could be realized by gradually increasing the rate to 7.5 percent in the first year and

32

to 10 percent in the second year; (iii) elimination of the exemption of sales of the agricultural

sector and gradually increase the rate to 10 percent over a three year period; (iv) elimination of

exemption of paid interests.

Reforms of the IRACIS could also contribute to an increase in tax revenues. Despite the

lowering of the tax rate, revenue from the IRACIS has increased five-fold between 2003 and

2011; it now contributes 19 percent of total tax revenue, up from 17 percent in 2003. Revenue

could be further increased by replacing the 1 percent tax for exporters (Maquila regime) and

treating profits equally across corporations. In addition, the government could consider

eliminating the benefits of law 60/90 on dividends and profits and interest exemptions.

Any gains from the reduction of exemptions could be used to expand targeted social

interventions. An argument in favor of the exemption of sales in the agricultural sector is that

these are basic consumer goods and the exemption therefore benefits the poor. As pointed out in

Diaz-Bonilla and Cicowiez (2013), the elimination of VAT exemptions for agricultural goods

may indeed produce a negative impact on the incidence of poverty. It is also well established,

however that exemptions benefit the rich as well as the poor, the former may benefit even more

due to higher levels of consumption. In many cases, eliminating exemptions can have a positive

effect on the equalizing properties of the tax system. As is demonstrated with the help of the

CGE model for Paraguay, if the additional fiscal resources gained through the elimination of

expenditures are invested into expanding CCT programs, poverty and inequality reduction would

in fact be accelerated.

Reforms to the personal income tax and the property tax could contribute to higher tax

revenues and could potentially reduce the regressivity of the tax system. The personal

income tax does not currently generate much revenue, due to its design as a tool to strengthen

VAT compliance. However, it could be improved significantly by (i) eliminating the exemptions

for pensions, interest, and foreign exchange gains; and by creating final withholding taxes on

interest paid by the financial system and on dividends on the personal income tax. As for the

property tax, the challenge is to ensure that property valuations reflect actual market conditions.

Basing the taxation of property on market valuation as opposed to fiscal valuation would make

the tax more effective, promote better land use, and increase municipal revenue to enhance

accountability and reduce dependency on central government transfers.23

The following policy options could help increase the counter-cyclicality of fiscal policy and

to improve the management of macroeconomic volatility: (i) Introduce a fiscal responsibility

law and move towards fiscal management with the help of a fiscal rule. This approach is by no

means perfect and has a number of advantages and disadvantages. However, it could prove

useful if country-specific conditions are taken into account. (ii) Introduce a stabilization fund to

ensure public expenditure levels during any downturn. For resource-rich countries, stabilization

funds are designed to guard against volatility in international markets. When revenues and prices

are high, payments are made into the stabilization fund and diverted from expenditures. When

revenues are lower than expected, payments are made from the fund to the budget, avoiding

reductions in expenditure. Stabilization funds aim to reduce the impact of volatile revenue on the

government and on the economy. Country examples include Chile, Mexico, Norway. (iii)

23

See World Bank (2007).

33

Strengthen automatic stabilizers such as unemployment insurance and other social protection

measures. (iv) Expand existing transfer programs to cover a higher share of the poor and the

extreme poor, and increase transfers. This would be an important step in Paraguay to mitigate the

impact on the poor. To date only a small share of the poor is covered through the cash transfer

programs and hence is exposed to the risks. (For details refer to section 3.4).

In terms of debt management, the following policy options could be considered: (i)

institutionalizing the formulation of a medium-term debt management strategy through the

approval of the strategy as a Ministerial decree and its submission to Congress as part of the

annual budget process; (ii) creating one debt management office with clearly defined

responsibilities. A second best solution is to keep the back office with the General Directorate of

Public Credit and Debt (DGCDP) in the Subsecretaría de Estado de Administración Financiera

(SSEAF) while the front and middle office stay with Directorate of Debt Policy (DPE) in the

Subsecretaría de Estado de Economía e Integración (SSEEI)24

; and (iii) strengthening of the

domestic debt market. For details refer to IMF and World Bank (2012).

Finally, weaknesses in the budget process could be addressed with the following

measures:25

(i) strengthening the legal framework for the budget by spelling out the roles and

responsibilities of the three government branches on budget matters to ensure sustainability and

higher accountability of fiscal policy. This could be done by amending the LAFE. Ideally, the

LAFE would also be granted higher legal hierarchy than the annual budget law; and (ii)

consensus among the executive and legislative branches on possible mechanisms to define

binding and sustainable fiscal policy objectives. One possible mechanism could involve setting

up a two-stage process of budget approval, where Congress first agrees on the expenditure

envelope before voting on specific appropriations. This approach is used in a number of

industrialized countries—France, Italy, Spain, Sweden, and the United States—and in emerging

economies such as Brazil, Colombia, Mexico, Poland, and the Czech Republic. Another

mechanism would be to specify that every expenditure-increasing change introduced by congress

is accompanied by specific and credible revenue increases (balanced-budget power), and to

publish as an attachment to the approved budget all the changes introduced in the process of

legislative approval.

24

This topic was discussed in detail in World Bank and IMF (2010), pp 11-13 this is a second best solution

compared to having a consolidated debt management office. See also “Strengthening government debt and cash

management” IMF report, March 2012. 25

This Paragraph draws on IMF (2009) chapter 9.

34

Chapter 3: Fiscal policy, poverty reduction and shared prosperity

One of the reasons for limited poverty reduction in the past 15 years is that Paraguay’s fiscal

policy contributes much less to poverty reduction and shared prosperity than fiscal policy in

other countries in Latin America. It does not effectively contribute to improving the equity of

opportunity either. The overall tax system is regressive and social spending is not as progressive

as in Latin American comparator countries. Fiscal policy could become a more effective tool if

taxes were less regressive (less dependence on indirect taxes, more on progressive direct taxes),

a greater share of the extreme poor was covered by direct transfers and received higher benefits;

and if spending on health and education was better targeted towards those households with

fewer opportunities.

As discussed in Chapter 1, Paraguay has made some progress in the reduction of poverty and

inequality in recent years, which has helped reverse the negative effects of the crisis. However,

longer term trends in the reduction of poverty and inequality are weak and present a key public

policy challenge. Among other negative effects, the literature shows that higher inequality is

associated with higher poverty. Poverty, in turn, has been shown to negatively affect growth.26

Beyond the economic arguments for a reduction in inequality and poverty, there tends to be a

perception of inequality as an issue of fairness: in fact, 80 percent of Paraguayans believe that

the distribution of income in their country is unjust.27

This chapter examines the extent to which Paraguay’s fiscal policy is an effective tool for

reducing poverty and inequality. Fiscal policy impacts poverty and inequality in several ways.

Redistribution through taxes and social expenditures affects household income. The expenditure

side of fiscal policy also affects the equity of opportunity, by determining to what extent access to

basic social services is provided equitably irrespective of circumstances beyond a person’s

control. This chapter examines different aspects of the linkage between fiscal policy and the

reduction of poverty and inequality and is organized as follows: Section 3.1 will analyze the role

of fiscal policy with respect to income redistribution, and Section 3.2 will analyze the same with

respect to the equity of opportunity. Section 3.3 will examine the incidence and progressivity of

fiscal policy. The chapter concludes with recommendations on how to make fiscal policy a more

effective tool in the fight against poverty and inequality in Paraguay.

3.1 Fiscal policy and income redistribution

The nature of Paraguay’s fiscal system represents important limitations for the scope of

fiscal redistribution and basic service delivery. Tax collections have increased from 9.4

percent of GDP in 2000 to 12.3 percent in 2012, but remain among the lowest in Latin America.

Revenue from direct taxes, which represent the main instrument of redistribution in most

countries, is very limited, not least because there was no personal income tax in effect until 2012.

The tax system is therefore heavily skewed towards indirect taxes (especially the VAT), which

tend to be regressive. On the expenditure side, the scope for redistribution is limited by the

overall small government budget, with total annual expenditures reaching 16 percent of GDP on

average between 2000 and 2012. Even though public spending on the social sectors has

26

Goñi et al (2010). 27

Latinobarometro 2010

35

increased its share in total public spending significantly since 2003 (Figure 3.1), it remains below

the Latin American and Caribbean average as a share of GDP: average public expenditure on

education has been around 4.1 percent of GDP per year and on health 3.4 percent. As a result,

Paraguay spends less on social sectors as a share of GDP than comparator countries and the LAC

average (Figure 3.2).

Figure 3.1: Public expenditure on health and education (%

of total public expenditure) Figure 3.2: Public social spending in Paraguay and

comparator countries (2009-11; % of GDP)

Source: BOOST database Source: CEPAL

The breakdown of household income into different concepts makes it possible to assess the

effects of fiscal policy instruments on inequality and poverty. Lustig et al (2012) use five

“stages” of household income in relation to taxes and transfers. Market income includes wages

and salaries as well as capital and transfer income, prior to any taxes. Net market income is

market income minus direct taxes, primarily local and regional taxes as reported in the EPH

household survey. Disposable income is net market income minus direct transfers, which

includes CCT program benefits. Post-fiscal income is disposable income minus indirect taxes

(VAT and combustibles tax) and indirect subsidies (social tariff for electricity). Final income is

post-fiscal income minus user fees and co-payments (as reported in the EPH) as well as in-kind

transfers (public spending on education and health). At each stage, the analysis conducted by

Lustig et al (2012) re-calculates the Gini coefficient and poverty incidence, which allows for a

disaggregated analysis of the impact of different fiscal policy instruments on household income.

The analysis shows that, in comparison with other Latin American countries,28

fiscal policy

in Paraguay has a limited effect on inequality. The Gini coefficient for market income, i.e.

before fiscal policy, in Paraguay is 0.50, placing it at the lower end of the sample of Latin

American countries analyzed (Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Guatemala, Mexico, Paraguay, Peru,

and Uruguay) in terms of inequality before government intervention. However, direct taxes and

transfers reduce the Gini coefficient by less than one percent, and indirect taxes reverse this

progress: the post-fiscal income Gini coefficient is slightly higher than the market income Gini.

28

The comparisons with other countries come from country studies in the Commitment to Equity (CEQ) project.

These studies are synthesized in Lustig and Pessino (2013) for Argentina, Paz et al. (2013) for Bolivia, Higgins and

Pereira (2013) for Brazil, Morán and Cabrera (2012) for Guatemala, Scott (2013) for Mexico, Jaramillo (2013) for

Brazil, and Bucheli et al. (2013) for Uruguay.

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

Education Health

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Arg

en

tin

a

Bu

lgari

a

Bra

zil

Uru

gu

ay

Bo

liv

ia

Serb

ia

El

Salv

ador

Nic

ara

gu

a

Ho

nd

ura

s

Para

gu

ay

LAC average

36

Education and health spending are equalizing, but their effect is also limited compared to other

counties. In terms of final income, Paraguay is the most unequal country of the sample, with a

Gini coefficient of 0.48. From market income to final income, Paraguay only reduces inequality

by 4.1 percent, which is less than all other countries in our sample: Guatemala reduces inequality

by 5.2 percent, Peru by 7.6 percent, Bolivia by 12.4 percent, Mexico by 15.9 percent, Uruguay

by 20.2 percent, Brazil by 24.1 percent, and Argentina by 25.2 percent (Figure 3.3).

However, this positive effect on inequality depends to some extent on whether pensions are

treated as transfers in the analysis. Contributory pensions and non-contributory pensions29

are

counted as part of market income in the benchmark case (discussed above) but considered a

government transfer in the sensitivity analysis. Figure 3.4 presents the evolution of inequality

across income concepts in the benchmark case and in the sensitivity analysis. Because pensions

are unequalizing in Paraguay, and because they are large compared to other transfers, how they

are treated changes the qualitative assessment of direct transfers. When they are not included in

government transfers (the benchmark case), overall direct transfers are equalizing and the

disposable income Gini coefficient is lower than the market income coefficient. When they are

instead considered a government transfer (the sensitivity analysis), overall direct transfers are

29 The latter could not be separated from contributory pensions in the survey or by using program rules.

Figure 3.3: Gini coefficient for each income concept in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Guatemala, Mexico, Paraguay,

Peru and Uruguay

Note: The Ginis in this figure correspond to the benchmark case.

Source: For Paraguay, authors’ calculations using Encuesta Permanente de Hogares (2010) and National Accounts.

For Argentina, Lustig and Pessino (2013); for Bolivia, Paz et al. (2013); for Brazil, Higgins and Pereira (2013); for

Guatemala, Morán and Cabrera (2013); for Mexico, Scott (2013); for Peru, Jaramillo (2013); for Uruguay, Bucheli

et al. (2013).

0.360

0.410

0.460

0.510

0.560

Market Income Net Market Income Disposable Income Post-fiscal Income Final Income

Gin

i

Argentina

Bolivia

Brazil

Guatemala

Mexico

Paraguay

Peru

Uruguay

37

unequalizing, with the Gini coefficient of disposable income being higher than that of market

income.

Figure 3.4: Inequality in Paraguay (2010) – benchmark vs. sensitivity analysis

Source: Lustig et al. (2012)

Fiscal policy instruments such as taxes and transfer have a net negative impact on the

poverty headcount index. Taxes have a relatively large negative impact on poverty: a

significant number of the near-poor pay enough direct taxes to make them poor.30

The headcount

index for net market income using the US$4 PPP per day poverty line, at 28.3 percent, is over

one percentage point higher than the market income headcount index. This is unique to Paraguay

among countries in the sample: the others have much smaller increases in poverty caused by

direct taxes. This finding is particularly striking given that until 2012, Paraguay did not have a

personal income tax and direct taxes only account for 2.6 percent of GDP (equivalent to 21

percent of total tax revenue). Furthermore, direct transfers do not fully offset the negative impact

of taxes because of their limited reach and small size: post-fiscal income poverty is higher than

market income poverty using both the US$2.50 and US$4 PPP per day poverty lines (Table 3.1).

Table 3.1: Taxes, transfers, inequality and poverty in Paraguay (2010) - benchmark

Indicator Market

Income

Net

Market

Income

Disposable

Income

Post-

fiscal

Income

Final

Income

Gini 0.500 0.499 0.495 0.502 0.480

Headcount index at US$2.5

PPP/day

14.6% 14.9% 14.4% 16.2%

Headcount index at US$4

PPP/day

27.2% 28.3% 28.0% 30.1%

Source: Lustig et al (2012)

30

Direct taxes include property taxes, municipal taxes, and other taxes, and are asked directly in the survey.

Paraguay did not have a federal income tax at the time of the survey.

0.480

0.485

0.490

0.495

0.500

0.505

Market

Income

Net Market

Income

Disposable

Income

Post-Fiscal

Income

Gin

i

Benchmark Case

Sensitivity Analysis

38

This is partly because the poor pay a large share of their income on taxes. Although the rich

pay a higher proportion of their income in direct taxes than the poor, all deciles pay between one

and five percent of their income in direct taxes. This explains why net market income inequality

is barely lower than market income inequality, and why net market income poverty is

substantially higher. In most countries, the poorest deciles pay essentially none of their income in

direct taxes. Indirect taxes are even more detrimental to the poor: the poorest decile spends 28

percent of its income, on average, on indirect taxes (VAT and combustibles tax), compared to

6.3 percent in Mexico and 6.6 percent in Peru..31

In addition, transfers in Paraguay do not increase the income of the poor by as much as

they do in other countries. Direct transfers, indirect subsidies, and in-kind transfers in the form

of free education and health services all benefit individuals in the poorer deciles more than those

in richer deciles. However, when compared to other countries in Latin America, the percentage

increase in income for the poor from these transfers is low. For example, individuals in the

poorest decile experience an income increase of 6 percent, on average, from the CCT Tekoporã.

Although this figure is similar to the increase experienced by the poorest decile from CCTs in

Bolivia in Peru, it is much lower than the increase in other countries: in Brazil, Bolsa Família

increases the incomes of the poorest decile by 29 percent on average.32

Furthermore, it is far

below the 72 percent increase in income that the extreme poor would need, on average, to be

lifted out of extreme poverty. This is because the size of the benefit is small in Paraguay: an

extremely poor individual whose household benefits from at least one direct transfer program

receives, on average, just US$0.38 PPP per day in household per capita terms. In many cases,

this transfer will not be enough to raise the household above the US$2.50 PPP per day extreme

poverty line.

While direct transfers are well targeted, a significant share of the poor is not covered. 47

percent of direct transfers in Paraguay reach the extreme poor (those living on less than US$2.50

PPP per day, in terms of household per capita market income), which is among the highest of the

countries analyzed. Furthermore, 68 percent of direct transfers reach the moderate or extreme

poor (those living on less than US$4 PPP per day), again among the highest of the countries

analyzed. 85 percent of beneficiaries are moderately or extremely poor in Paraguay, making

direct transfers more pro-poor by this metric than in any other country (Figure 3.5). However,

just 24 percent of the extreme poor are beneficiaries of direct transfer programs in Paraguay.

This proportion is significantly lower than in any other country analyzed here. Furthermore, just

39 percent of the total poor (extreme plus moderate) are beneficiaries of direct transfer programs,

which is a lower proportion than in all of the other countries except Guatemala (Figure 3.6).

As a result, all income deciles, including the poorest, are net contributors to the fiscal

system. Considering only direct taxes and direct transfers, individuals become net payers to the

fiscal system in the second decile on average. This means that many poor individuals are paying

more in direct taxes than they receive in direct benefits, which further impoverishes them despite

the fact that they may already be unable to buy a basket of basic needs. In other countries, the

poorest three deciles are always net recipients from the fiscal system when only direct taxes and

direct transfers are taken into account: the poorest decile that is a net payer ranges from the

31 One reason why indirect taxes as a share of income are so high is that indirect taxes are computed using

consumption data, which for the poorest decile is higher than income. 32 Higgins and Pereira (2013).

39

fourth decile (Mexico) to the tenth (Brazil). When indirect taxes are taken into account, all

deciles are net payers to the fiscal system, on average, in Paraguay. This is the only country in

the sample where this occurs: in the other countries, the poorest decile that is a net payer to the

fiscal system including indirect taxes is usually the third or fourth decile.

Figure 3.5: Percent of direct transfer beneficiaries who are poor in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Guatemala, Mexico,

Paraguay, Peru and Uruguay

Note: The extreme poor have household per capita market income below $2.50 PPP per day. The moderate poor

have household per capita market income between $2.50 PPP per day and $4 PPP per day.

Source: For Paraguay, authors’ calculations using Encuesta Permanente de Hogares (2010) and National Accounts;

for Argentina, Lustig and Pessino (2013); for Bolivia, Paz et al. (2013); for Brazil, Higgins and Pereira (2013); for

Guatemala, Morán and Cabrera (2013); for Mexico, Scott (2013); for Peru, Jaramillo (2013); for Uruguay, Bucheli

et al. (2013).

Figure 3.6: Percent of poor receiving at least one direct transfer

27.2% 23.3% 32.5%

46.6%

17.2% 27.2%

34.4%

11.7%

15.5% 14.6%

18.8%

20.6%

11.7%

57.9%

22.2%

14.1%

57.3% 62.1% 48.7%

32.7%

71.1%

14.8%

43.5%

74.2%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

Arg

enti

na

Bo

livia

Bra

zil

Guat

emal

a

Mex

ico

Par

aguay

Per

u

Uru

guay

Non-poor

Moderate Poor

Extreme Poor

40

Note: The extreme poor have household per capita market income below $2.50 PPP per day. The moderate poor

have household per capita market income between $2.50 PPP per day and $4 PPP per day.

Source: For Paraguay, authors’ calculations using Encuesta Permanente de Hogares (2010) and National Accounts;

for Argentina, Lustig and Pessino (2013); for Bolivia, Paz et al. (2013); for Brazil, Higgins and Pereira (2013); for

Guatemala, Morán and Cabrera (2013); for Mexico, Scott (2013); for Peru, Jaramillo (2013); for Uruguay, Bucheli

et al. (2013).

Despite the limited effect of its fiscal policy on inequality, Paraguay is more effective at

reducing inequality than a number of other countries. The effectiveness indicator is defined

as the effect on inequality or the effect on poverty of the transfers being analyzed divided by

their relative size.33

Given Paraguay’s low spending, although it always has the lowest or second

lowest reduction in inequality among the eight countries analyzed, it is not always the least

effective. Its redistributive effectiveness indicator for disposable income is higher than that of

Bolivia and Brazil (two high-spending countries that accomplish low reduction relative to the

amount they spend). Its redistributive effectiveness indicator for final income is higher than

Bolivia and Brazil, and similar to two small-government countries that achieve low inequality

reductions given the amount they spend: Mexico and Peru. In other words, although Paraguay is

the worst performer in terms of reducing inequality, when both direct and in-kind benefits are

considered, the country performs in the middle of the pack in terms of the efficiency of each

dollar spent at reducing inequality.

33

For direct transfers, the effectiveness indicator is the proportional fall between the net market income and

disposable income Ginis, divided by the size of direct transfers as a percent of GDP. Although the size of direct

transfers is measured by budget size according to national accounts, only direct transfer programs that are captured

by the survey (or otherwise estimated by the authors) are included, since they are the only programs that can lead to

an observed change in income.33

For direct and in-kind transfers, the effectiveness indicator is the proportional fall

between the net market income and final income Ginis, divided by the size of the sum of direct transfers, education

spending, and health spending as a percent of GDP.

92% 88% 93%

45%

74%

24%

58%

97%

87% 86% 85%

36%

65%

39% 50%

95%

0.0%

10.0%

20.0%

30.0%

40.0%

50.0%

60.0%

70.0%

80.0%

90.0%

100.0%

Arg

enti

na

Bo

livia

Bra

zil

Guat

emal

a

Mex

ico

Par

aguay

Per

u

Uru

guay

Extreme Poor

Moderate orExtreme Poor

41

However, fiscal policy in Paraguay is relatively ineffective at reducing poverty. Paraguay

performs worse than the seven other countries in terms of poverty reduction, and it also has a low

effectiveness of every dollar it spends (the lowest at the US$4 PPP per day poverty line and

third-lowest at US$2.50 PPP per day).

3.2 Fiscal policy and equity of opportunity

Another way to assess to what extent fiscal policy contributes to greater equity is to focus

on the equity of opportunity. An analysis of a sample of Latin American countries (which did

not include Paraguay) found that between one-fifth and one-third of total income inequality is

explained by the inequity in opportunity, i.e. access to public services.34

Equity of opportunity is

also important because it can determine future poverty and inequality, by providing the children

of the current poor with the opportunity to unshackle themselves from circumstances such as

their region of birth and residence and parents’ educational attainments and socioeconomic

status, which may limit their ability to realize their full potential in life. These limitations on

potential could take the form of barriers to education up to a certain level, the inability to work in

an occupation befitting their level of human capital, or simply restrictions on the ability to

migrate to search for better economic opportunities.

The Human Opportunity Index (HOI) offers an alternative to the traditional concept of

income inequality. The HOI measures how far a society is from universal provision of basic

services and goods, such as sanitation, clean water and education, and the extent to which those

goods and services are unevenly distributed.35

A key feature of the HOI is that it not only takes

into account the overall coverage rates of these services, but also how equally the coverage is

distributed—by measuring the extent to which those without coverage are concentrated in groups

with particular circumstances (for example, economic status, gender, parental education,

ethnicity, and so on), the conditions into which a child is typically born. More specifically, HOI

is an inequity-sensitive coverage rate that incorporates: (i) the average coverage of a good or

service that society accepts should be universal (which implies that the individual is not held

responsible for lack of access) and (ii) whether it is allocated according to an equity of

opportunity principle.

Paraguay performs below the LAC average in terms of ensuring equity of opportunity, but

has improved faster than other countries. In 2010, Paraguay ranked 12th

out of 18 Latin

American countries in the overall HOI, which shows that there is much space for improvement

(Figure 3.7). An opportunity where Paraguay ranks particularly low is access to public sanitation

(18th

out of 18 countries). However, the pace of improvement is faster in Paraguay than in many

other countries in the region: between 1995 and 2010, Paraguay’s HOI improved by 1.1

percentage points per year, compared to 1 percentage points for the LAC region.

34

Paes de Barro et al. (2009). 35

This discussion draws from three sources: Barros et al. (2009) and Molinas et al. (2010).

42

Figure 3.7: HOI for Latin American Countries (proj. 2010)

Source: Molina et al (2010)

Coverage of basic social services and equity of opportunity have been improving in line

with increased spending. In line with the increase in the share of the budget dedicated to the

social sectors, coverage of key education and health services improved markedly. Between 2003

and 2010, coverage of all basic services improved, albeit at different speeds (Figure 3.8).

Similarly, opportunities also improved, most notably preschool attendance, on time completion

of sixth grade and completion of ninth grade. However, some opportunities experienced

significant fluctuations, such as attending pre-school, starting first grade on time and finishing

sixth grade on time. In fact, there does not appear to be a clear relationship between initial

opportunity gaps and subsequent trends in education opportunities. In the case of health

opportunities and access to water and electricity, the gap between coverage and the respective

HOI has shrunk over time, while the gap for sanitation access has not changed much.

0 20 40 60 80 100

Nicaragua

Honduras

Guatemala

El Salvador

Panama

Peru

Paraguay

Rep. Dominicana

Brazil

Ecuador

Colombia

Jamaica

Mexico

Venezuela

Costa Rica

Argentina

Uruguay

Chile

LAC Average (73)

71

43

Figure 3.8: Change in the HOI and coverage

(a) Attend school (age 5-17) (b) Finish 9th

grade

(c) Access to health care (age 0-17) (d) Access to safe sanitation (age 0-17)

Source: Cuesta and Suárez Becerra (2013).

In fact, much of the improvement in the HOI between 2003 and 2010 is due to the overall

improvement in circumstances of the population and the expansion in coverage. Changes in

HOI between 2003 and 2010 are decomposed into three effects: (i) composition - changes in the

distribution of circumstances in the population; (ii) scale - changes in coverage; and (iii)

equalization - changes in the distribution of disparities across groups. The decomposition

analysis confirms two important results with regard to access inequalities. First, the equalization

effect is typically a positive contributor to increasing the HOI across opportunities. This implies

that there has been an overall reduction in access disparities across circumstance groups for most

opportunities. Second, the contribution of equalization effects is much smaller than scale and

composition effects. Equalization explains only between 1 and 25 percent of the HOI inter

temporal changes. This implies that there is still a lot of room for equalizing policies to

effectively reduce disparities across groups for most opportunities analyzed in Paraguay.

This also means that inequity of opportunity is particularly high in services where coverage

remains low. The services that have lowest coverage are safe sanitation (48 percent of 0 to 17

81.182.3 82.2 82.0 82.3

83.284.6 85.2

84.785.7 86.3

85.1 85.8 86.487.7 87.9

70

80

90

100

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Pe

rce

nta

ge

HOI Coverage

42.7 44.042.1

46.848.5

50.854.0

51.0

51.153.5

51.4

55.757.6

60.3 62.3 59.9

35

45

55

65

75

85

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Perc

en

tag

e

HOI Coverage

40.546.0

53.7

66.0

76.4 74.5 73.6

50.354.8

63.0

75.0

81.5 79.5 78.5

20

40

60

80

100

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Po

rcen

tag

e

HOI Coverage

34.8 36.939.8 41.5

44.948.5 47.8 47.7

50.6 52.456.1 56.3

60.363.4 63.4 63.1

20

40

60

80

100

2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Pe

rcen

tag

e

HOI Coverage

44

year olds have access), 9th

grade on time (51 percent coverage for 16 to 17 year olds), preschool

(56 percent of 5 year olds), 6th

grade on time (61 percent of 13 year olds), starting school on time

(72 percent of 6 to 7 year olds), and access to health care (74 percent of 0 to 17 year olds have

access). For these services, the equity of opportunity also tends to be lower. By contrast,

inequities in those opportunities that are close to universal are very limited (Figure 3.9).

Figure 3.9: Coverage and HOI in Paraguay (2010)

Source: Cuesta and Suárez (2012)

There are a number of drivers behind these disparities in opportunities. For school

attendance and completion of 6th

and 9th

grade, the most important factor is the level of education

of the head of household. This suggests that demand and parental preferences play a role in

education decisions. On the other hand, the main language spoken in the household is the key

determinant for beginning school on time. Expressed in terms of the probability of having low

educational opportunities, children of households where the head has low level of education or

where the main language spoken is Guaraní are more likely to belong to vulnerable groups. In

the case of health and housing opportunities, the bulk of the disparities can be explained by the

geographic location of the household (urban/rural and region), which suggests that supply factors

are important in determining these opportunities.

85.2

72.2

61.1

51.056.0

73.6

93.9

47.7

95.2

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

AttendSchool(5-17)

StartSchool

on Time

(6-7)

Finish 6thGrade

on Time

(13)

Finish 9thGrade(16-17)

AttendPre-School

(5)

Access toHealthCare

(0-17)

Housing:Water(0-17)

Housing:Sanitation

(0-17)

Housing:Electricity

(0-17)

Perc

en

tag

e

HOI UB(95) LB(95)

87.9

75.0

69.3

59.961.2

78.5

95.6

63.1

97.0

40Attendschool(5-17)

Startschoolon time

(6-7)

Finish6th gradeon time

(13)

Finish9th grade(16-17)

Attendprechool

(5)

Access tohealth care

(0-17)

Access toclean water

(0-17)

Accessto safe

sanitation

(0-17)

Access toelectricity

(0-17)

UB(95) LB(95) Coverage

45

3.3 How progressive is Paraguay’s fiscal system with regard to the

distribution of income and opportunities?36

Paraguay’s reliance on indirect taxes makes its tax system regressive. Despite the burden

that direct taxes represent even for the poorest, the rich pay a higher share of their income on

these taxes, which means that these taxes are progressive. Indirect taxes, on the other hand, are

regressive. Given the relatively small role that direct taxes play in Paraguay’s fiscal system,

overall taxes are also slightly regressive (Figure 3.10). In contrast, overall taxes in some

countries, such as Guatemala, Mexico, Peru, and Uruguay, are progressive.

Furthermore, social expenditures are less progressive than in other countries. This finding

is supported by two separate analyses using household surveys from two different years (2009

and 2010) and different categorizations of expenditures. Analysis 1 uses traditional benefit

incidence analysis with respect to the distribution of household income; analysis 2 includes both

the distribution of income and of opportunities.

Analysis 1: 2010 household survey37

A detailed analysis of the concentration coefficient38

of spending categories using the 2010

household survey shows that most public expenditure is less progressive than in other

countries. Social spending overall is progressive in relative terms, with a concentration

coefficient of 0.14 (Figure 3.11). In other countries, social spending is more progressive, with a

concentration coefficient ranging from -0.17 (Uruguay) to 0.06 (Guatemala). Social spending is

progressive in absolute terms in all countries in the sample except Guatemala and Paraguay.

However, Paraguay fares well when it comes to the progressivity of its CCT program: Tekoporã

is highly progressive in absolute terms, with a concentration coefficient of -0.47; this is more

progressive than Bolivia’s universal CCT Bono Juancito Pinto (-0.25) and Guatemala’s Mi

Familia Progresa (-0.41), and less progressive than Argentina’s Asignación Universal por Hijo (-

0.52), Mexico’s Oportunidades (-0.54), Brazil’s Bolsa Família (-0.58), Uruguay’s Asignaciones

Familiares (-0.61), and Peru’s Juntos (-0.65). Overall education spending (including tertiary

education) is progressive in relative terms, with a concentration coefficient of 0.12. In contrast,

in all of the other countries included in the analysis, total education spending is progressive in

absolute terms and has a negative concentration coefficient, ranging from -0.17 in Peru to -0.01

in Guatemala. The progressivity of primary (-0.11) and secondary (0.27) education spending is

counterbalanced by the regressivity of tertiary education (0.55). It should be noted that all other

countries in the analysis have tertiary education spending that is progressive in relative terms

36

According to the definition used in this paper, taxes are progressive (regressive) if the proportion paid is lower

(higher) than the share of income for the poor and the opposite happens at the top of the income scale. A transfer is

progressive (regressive) if the proportion received is higher (lower) than the share of income for the poor and the

opposite happens at the top of the income scale. Furthermore, a transfer is progressive in absolute terms if the

proportion received is higher, not only than the share of income, but also the population share for the poorest decile

and this relationship declines as we move up to higher deciles. 37

This analysis (Lustig et al (2012)) categorizes education spending into primary, secondary and tertiary. Health

spending includes all public expenditure on public health and the IPS. 38

The concentration coefficient (CC) ranges in value from -1 (perfect progressivity) to 1 (perfect regressivity). A

CC between -1 and 0 signifies progressivity in absolute terms; a CC between 0 and the Gini coefficient signifies

progressivity in relative terms. A CC above the Gini signifies regressivity.

46

except Guatemala (0.59), ranging from only slightly progressive (0.47 in Uruguay) to

substantially progressive in relative terms (0.24 in Argentina). Total health spending is

progressive only in relative terms, with a concentration coefficient of 0.20. The public health

systems in other Latin American countries range from having similar levels of progressivity in

Guatemala and Peru to being progressive in absolute terms in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, and

Uruguay.

Figure 3.10:Concentration shares of taxes in Paraguay (2010)

(a) Direct taxes (blue) and market income (red) (b) Indirect taxes (blue) and market income

(red)

(c) Direct + indirect taxes (blue) and market income (red)

Source: Lustig et al (2012)

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Co

nce

ntr

atio

in S

har

e

Decile

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Co

nce

ntr

atio

in S

har

e

Decile

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

45%

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Co

nce

ntr

atio

in S

har

e

Decile

47

Figure 3.11: Concentration coefficients of public expenditure categories in Paraguay (2010)

Source: Lustig et al (2012).

Analysis 2: 2009 household survey39

The second analysis finds that public spending on primary education is pro-poor, while

spending on secondary (and tertiary) education is pro-rich. Public spending benefits decrease

as the consumption of household increases for primary education, while the opposite occurs in

the case of secondary education. The bottom 40 percent of the distribution of beneficiaries of

primary education capture 47 percent of total public resources on primary education. The same

percentage of public spending on secondary education goes to the top 40 percent of the income

distribution.

Considering the distribution of opportunities instead of household income, a similar

incidence is observed. For combined public spending on primary and secondary education,

having a set of circumstances, which are less favorable for attending school does not make a

large difference in the public benefits that a child will receive. Only children with the most

favorable set of circumstances receive fewer public benefits than their share in the population

would suggest. The main reason is that these children opt for private education. Results

39

This analysis categorizes education expenditure into primary and secondary education. Primary education

includes preschool as well as the first, second and third cycles of primary education. It also includes special

education for preschool and primary education and special permanent primary education. Secondary education

includes high school, permanent professional secondary education, alternative secondary education and secondary

distance education. Health expenditure includes facilities managed by the Ministry of Health as well as IPS. In

addition, this analysis includes the incidence of public education and public health care along the distribution of

opportunities (in addition to income). The distribution of opportunities is obtained by estimating the probability of

each child to access a given opportunity (such as attending school) given his or her set of circumstances.

0.55

0.51

0.50

0.50

0.50

0.48

0.47

0.39

0.20

0.14

0.12

0.09

-0.11

-0.11

-0.13

-0.47

-0.54

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8

Tertiary School

Post-fiscal Income

Market Income

Net Market Income

Disposable Income

Final Income

Final Income*

Health / IPS

Total Health

Social Spending

Total Education

Secondary School

Tariffa Social

Primary School

Free Health Care

Tekopora

Other Transfers

Concentration Coefficient (or Gini when specified)

Regressive

Progressive in absolute terms

Progressive in

relative terms

Gini

48

highlight, once again, an primary education that is close to universal and equitable access and a

slightly pro-rich distribution of public spending on secondary education (Figure 3.12).

Figure 3.12: Incidence of public education expenditure

(a) Primary education, by income quintile (b) Primary education, by opportunity

quintile

(c) Secondary education, by income quintile (d) Secondary education, by opportunity

quintile

Source: Cuesta and Suárez (2012)

The distributional incidence of public health care spending in Paraguay shows that it is

neither pro-poor nor progressive. In fact, the share of spending benefiting middle-income

groups (that is, children in households of the third quintile of the distribution) is larger than the

share of low- and high-income group quintiles. Beneficiaries in the third quintile capture 31

percent of benefits of public health care. The remaining groups, the bottom 40 percent and the

top 40 percent, capture 31 percent and 38 percent, respectively, that is, slightly below their

proportional population shares.

The disaggregation by types of attention, health centers, and hospitals shows that there are

different distributional profiles for health care in centers and hospitals: while the bottom

quintile of the distribution of incomes disproportionally benefits from health center services, it is

also disproportionally not benefiting from hospital care related public spending. The opposite is

observed for the top quintile: it does not benefit much from public spending on health care

centers, while benefits from hospital care are disproportionally large compared to its share of

beneficiaries.

20

25

20

22

20

21 20

19

20

13

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Poorest) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Richest)

Share of public expenditure on elementaleducation by quintile of incomes (2009)

Popuation (age 5 to 17) Public expenditure

20

24

20

25

20

2220

18

20

12

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

eQ1 (Least) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Most)

Share of public expenditure on elementaleducation by quintile of probability (2009)

Popuation (age 5 to 17) Public expenditure

20

11

20

20 20

22

20

24

20

23

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Poorest) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Richest)

Share of public expenditure on secondaryeducation by quintile of incomes (2009)

Popuation (age 5 to 17) Public expenditure

20

12

20

21

20

21

20

26

20

20

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Least) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Most)

Share of public expenditure on secondaryeducation by quintile of probability (2009)

Popuation (age 5 to 17) Public expenditure

49

Similarly, benefit incidence with respect to the distribution of opportunities depends on the

level of public health care. Children with the least favorable set of circumstances, i.e. the

bottom two quintiles in the probability distribution, only capture 29 percent of benefits. The

disaggregation by nature of the attention, health center, or hospital related indicates that there are

marked distributional differences as well. Medical attention in health centers benefits those with

less favorable circumstances: the bottom 40 percent captures some 54 percent of such benefits.

However, hospital care spending favors those in the higher opportunity quintiles: the bottom 40

percent of the distribution captures only 19 percent of all benefits associated with hospital care.

Figure 3.13: Incidence of public health expenditure

(a) Health center care, by income quintile (b) Health center care, by opportunity

quintile

(c) Hospital care, by income quintile (d) Hospital care, by opportunity quintile

Source: Cuesta and Suárez (2012)

3.4 Policy options

On the revenue side, the key challenge is to address the regressivity of taxes. This would

require a gradual increase in the collection of direct taxes compared to indirect taxes, and the

elimination of exemptions. For concrete suggestions refer to section 2.4 as the recommendations

to ease the fiscal restraint and to address the regressivity of the system coincide.

These measures would also help generate additional revenue, which could be used to

strengthen the progressivity of public spending. Simulations using a CGE model prepared for

20

28

20

14

20

28

20

23

20

7

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Poorest) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Richest)

Share of public expenditure on health center careby quintile of incomes (2009)

Popuation (age 0 to 17- ill only) Public expenditure

20

29

20

25

20

14

20

24

20

10

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Least) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Most)

Share of public expenditure on health center careby quintile of probability (2009)

Popuation (age 0 to 17- ill only) Public expenditure

20

8

20

1820

32

20

1920

23

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Poorest) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Richest)

Share of public expenditure on hospital careby quintile of incomes (2009)

Popuation (age 0 to 17- ill only) Public expenditure

20

8

20

11

20

36

20

21

20

24

010

20

30

40

Perc

en

tag

e

Q1 (Least) Q2 Q3 Q4 Q5 (Most)

Share of public expenditure on hospital careby quintile of probability (2009)

Popuation (age 0 to 17- ill only) Public expenditure

50

this report40

suggest that the reduction in exemptions (especially VAT exemptions) and the use

of these resources for social expenditure could have a beneficial effect for human development

outcomes, while not significantly affecting GDP growth.41

The simulations look specifically at

increases in spending on education, health and water and sanitation, and on the effect of this

increased spending on MDGs. Such spending could be better targeted to improve access to basic

services care by particularly vulnerable groups, such as households whose head speaks only

Guarani and went to school for less than 6 years. Similarly, additional resources freed up could

be used for the CCT program, which would have beneficial impacts on poverty, inequity and

inequality given that it is already well targeted

In order to ensure that additional spending is used efficiently, the monitoring of

expenditure could be improved through: (i) the geographic disaggregation of social

expenditures that are currently not attributed to a specific department but are classified as

“national level” (alcance nacional); (ii) the improvement in the quality and an increase in the

number of social outcome indicators that are available at the departmental level; and (iii)

participation in other international assessments (for example, PISA in the case of education) to

make the indicators of outcomes of public service provision in Paraguay comparable to other

countries.

40

The CGE model prepared for this PER provides a useful tool for policy makers to simulate the effect of policy

changes on poverty, inequality and MDGs. Various different policy options could be simulated this way. 41

Conversely, if the resources were spent on infrastructure, poverty rates and human development outcomes would

remain unchanged, while GDP growth would increase slightly. These alternative scenarios allow quantifying the

trade-off between higher private investment and consequently higher economic growth and lower poverty, versus

higher levels of human development expenditure in education, health, water and sanitation.

51

Chapter 4: Efficiency of Public Spending and Service Delivery

Given Paraguay’s limited fiscal resources, getting the most value out of public spending is an

important priority. Not only does Paraguay spend less on the social sectors than many other

countries, it also achieves relatively weak outcomes in education and health. Preliminary

analyses suggest that Paraguay could improve the efficiency of public spending in these two

sectors. There also appears to be significant variation in expenditure efficiency among

departments within Paraguay, which may be related to a number of factors. Improving the

efficiency of public service SOEs could contribute to better outcomes. More and better data is

needed at the disaggregated level in order to better assess what drives social outcomes in

different parts of the country.

As shown in Chapter 3, Paraguay’s public expenditure in the social sectors is low in comparison

to peer countries and to its neighbors. Even though spending on education and health as a share

of total spending has increased over time, Paraguay still spends less on these sectors (as a share

of GDP) than countries of a similar size and than the Latin American average.

The fiscal incidence analysis in Chapter 3 also shows that despite the low spending, some of

Paraguay’s social programs are very effective. The effectiveness of Paraguay’s social spending

on reducing inequality is better than in a number of other Latin American countries. Most

notably, the CCT program is well targeted and thus represents an effective tool for reducing

extreme poverty.

This chapter analyzes to what extent Paraguay uses its limited public resources efficiently for the

benefit of human development. Poverty reduction over the past two decades has been modest,

and Paraguay ranks among the lower third of comparator countries in most health and

education results. To what extent are these results due to Paraguay’s low social expenditure?

Can the limited fiscal resources be used more efficiently to achieve higher outcomes? To what

extent does expenditure efficiency vary among different regions within the country? And what

may be some of the factors contributing to low expenditure efficiency? This chapter attempts to

provide preliminary answers to these questions, based on the available data. It is organized as

follows. Section 4.1 analyzes the efficiency of public expenditure on health and education in

comparison with other countries. Section 4.2 examines the variations in efficiency among the 18

Paraguayan departments. Section 4.3 presents a case study of the expenditure efficiency in

SOEs, which provide basic public services. Section 4.4 concludes with policy recommendations.

4.1 The efficiency of public spending in Paraguay in international comparison

Education

A comparison of Paraguay’s education outcomes with that of other countries is difficult.

Paraguay does not participate in the Program for International Student Assessment (PISA) to

measure student performance. As a result, the following analysis uses proxy indicators such as

enrollment rates, average years of schooling, gender parity, drop-out and repeater rates, which

are available for a wide range of countries including Paraguay.

52

In primary education, Paraguay’s performance is relatively weak in comparison with peer

countries. Its number of years of primary schooling is close to the average for the sample of

comparator countries (5.5 years). But Paraguay has the lowest primary enrollment rate (86

percent), the second highest dropout rate at the primary level (20 percent) and the second lowest

female gross enrollment rate (96 percent).

Figure 4. 1: Public expenditure on education vs. net primary enrolment rate

Note: Data is an average for 2008-10.

Source: Paraguay BOOST, UNESCO through World Bank Open Data.

The simple comparison would suggest that efficiency of public spending on primary

education in Paraguay is low. As Figure 4.1 shows, two of the comparator countries (Georgia

and El Salvador) spend less as a share of GDP on education, but achieve higher outcomes in

terms of net primary enrollment. Similar findings apply to other indicators. For instance,

Paraguay spends more per pupil on primary education than El Salvador, but has a higher primary

drop-out rate. Georgia, on the other hand, which spends 20 percent more per pupil on primary

education than Paraguay, has a drop-out rate that is 76 percent lower than that of Paraguay.

These simple correlations suggest that for its expenditure level, Paraguay could be more

“efficient”, i.e., obtain better outcomes.

Paraguay

Bolivia

Bulgaria

El Salvador

Georgia

Nicaragua

Serbia

84

86

88

90

92

94

96

98

100

102

3 3.5 4 4.5 5 5.5 6 6.5 7 7.5 8

Ad

just

ed n

et e

nro

lmen

t ra

te (

pri

ma

ry)

Public expenditure on education (% of GDP)

53

Figure 4.2: Public expenditure on education vs. secondary graduation rate

Note: Data is an average for 2008-10.

Source: Paraguay BOOST, UNESCO through World Bank Open Data.

With regards to secondary education, Paraguay’s performance is similarly weak. It has the

second lowest graduation rate in the sample, even though per pupil spending on secondary

education is relatively high. A number of countries, such as Bolivia and Serbia, spend less per

pupil but have graduation rates of 80 and 95 percent, respectively, compared to 66 percent in

Paraguay (Figure 4.2). Secondary net enrollment rates are also comparatively low given the level

of expenditures.

A more rigorous analysis confirms that Paraguay’s expenditure efficiency in education is

low. Using Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA), which computes an efficiency frontier based on

those observations that have the lowest input for the highest output (or set of outputs), it is

possible to assess how efficient Paraguay’s public expenditure on education is in relation to a set

of education outcomes.42

These include, in the case of primary education, the average number of

years of primary schooling, gender parity in gross enrollment, gross enrollment rate and repeater

rate; and in the case of secondary education, gender parity in gross enrollment, gross enrollment

rate, repeater rate and lower secondary gross graduation rate. The results show that Paraguay is

42

See Annex 1 for more information on the methodology.

Argentina

Paraguay

Bolivia

El Salvador

Georgia

Jordan

Nicaragua

Serbia

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

Gro

ss l

ow

er s

eco

nd

ary

gra

du

ati

on

ra

te

Public expenditure per pupil in secondary education (% of per capita GDP)

54

the least efficient country in the sample with regards to primary education, and the second least

efficient in the case of secondary education.

Health

Health sector performance appears to be somewhat better. Paraguay places in the middle of

the sample group in terms of vaccination and maternal mortality rates, as well as life expectancy.

For example, at 100 per 100,000 live births, Paraguay’s maternal mortality rate is significantly

lower than that of Papua New Guinea and Bolivia, and comparable to that of Nicaragua and

Honduras (Figure 4.3). At the same time, it also spends more per capita on health (US$270) than

these four countries, as well as two countries that have lower maternal mortality rates,

Turkmenistan (US$108) and El Salvador (US$239).

Similar to the education sector, the DEA results confirm that Paraguay’s efficiency in the

health sector is among the lowest in the sample. Taking health spending as an input and three

health indicators as outputs (DPT immunization, life expectancy and infant mortality), the DEA

finds that Paraguay spends less efficiently than the other countries in the sample.

Figure 4.3: Health expenditure and maternal mortality rate

Note: Data is an average for 2008-10.

Source: Paraguay BOOST, World Bank Health Statistics and WHO Health Accounts.

Argentina

Bulgaria

Bolivia

Brazil

Georgia

Honduras

Jordan

Nicaragua

Papua New

Guinea

Paraguay

El Salvador

Serbia

Turkmenistan

Uruguay

0

50

100

150

200

250

0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 900 1000

Ma

tern

al

mo

rta

lity

ra

te (

mo

del

ed e

st., p

er 1

00

,00

0 l

ive

bir

ths)

Health expenditure per capita (current US$)

55

4.2 Within-country differences in the efficiency of public spending43

Overall, departments that spend more on education and health tend to have better

outcomes in Paraguay.44

In the health sector, those departments that spend more (in per capita

terms) are more likely to have births attended by qualified professionals; a higher share of

pregnant women receiving prenatal care; and higher vaccination rates. In the education sector,

departments with higher public spending generally have higher primary and middle school

enrollment rates and lower repetition and dropout rates. This section will examine in more detail

the differences among Paraguayan departments with regard to social spending and outcomes.

Education

Departments that spend more on primary education have higher enrollment rates.45

Higher-spending departments have better outcomes, and lower-spending ones perform less well

with regard to primary enrollment (Figure 4.4 (a)). This appears to hold true regardless of the

geographic location of the department as there is no clustering of high or low performers, with

the exception of Boquerón and Alto Paraguay, two outliers that are both located in the Chaco.

Both have relatively high enrollment rates given their per capita spending on primary education

(Gs.54,540 and Gs.284,920, respectively).46

A similar relationship between spending and

enrollment can be observed for secondary education, although for any given expenditure level,

departments in the south seem to achieve higher enrollment rates than other departments (Figure

4.4 (c)).

The association between public spending and dropout rates in primary education is less

clear (Figure 4.4 (b)). There is a large cluster of departments with similar expenditure levels but

very different dropout rates in primary schools. Canindeyú, for example, has a per pupil

spending on primary education of Gs.1 million and a dropout rate of 7.6 percent; while the

department of Central, which only spends Gs.0.8 million per primary student has a much lower

dropout rate of 4.7 percent. Again, the outliers are the three departments in the Chaco (Boquerón,

Alto Paraguay and Pdte. Hayes), which all have high dropout rates even though their per student

expenditure ranges from very low (Gs. 0.3 million) in the case of Boquerón, to very high (Gs. 1.3

million) in the case of Pdte. Hayes.

43

Paraguay is a unitary country with some level of fiscal decentralization to municipal governments. However,

municipal budgets are small and comprehensive information is not available. This report therefore only uses central

government budget data that is attributed (in the government’s information system) to a particular department. 44

Given current data limitations, the analysis in this chapter only includes current expenditure (and in the case of

education, only wage and salary current expenditure). See Box 2 for more information on data limitations. 45

Data on enrollment rates and school-aged population are not available at the department level. As a proxy for the

enrollment rate, this report uses the total number of enrolled students at the primary level divided by the total

population in the department. Depending on the SOMETHING MISSING 46

However, there are concerns over the quality of data for these two departments. See Box 2.

56

Figure 4.4: Public expenditure on education vs. selected education outcomes, by department

(a) Enrollment in primary education for public and publicly subsidized schools

(b) Dropout rates in primary schools

Asunción

Concepción

San Pedro

Cordillera

Guairá

Caaguazú

Caazapá

Itapúa

Misiones

Paraguarí

Alto Paraná

Central

Ñeembucú

Amambay

Canindeyú

Pdte. Hayes

Boquerón

Alto Paraguay

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0 50,000 100,000 150,000 200,000 250,000 300,000 350,000 400,000

En

roll

men

t in

pri

mar

y p

ub

lic

sch

ools

(sh

are

of t

he

over

all

pop

ula

tion

)

Government spending on primary edcuation per capita (Gs.)

Asunción

Concepción

San Pedro

Cordillera

Guairá

Caaguazú

CaazapáItapúa

MisionesParaguarí

Alto Paraná

Central

Ñeembucú

Amambay

Canindeyú

Pdte. HayesBoquerón

Alto Paraguay

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

9%

10%

0 200,000 400,000 600,000 800,000 1,000,000 1,200,000 1,400,000 1,600,000

Dro

po

ut

rate

Government spending on primary education per student (Gs.)

57

(c) Enrollment in secondary education for public and publicly subsidized schools

Source: Paraguay BOOST and Ministry of Education.

The DEA analysis shows that five departments have low efficiency scores for both primary

and secondary education. When various outcomes for primary and secondary education are

taken together, Pdte. Hayes (Chaco), Caaguazú (north), San Pedro (north), Itapúa (south) and

Canindeyú (north) are found to be less efficient than other departments.47

It is also noteworthy

that the low-performing departments are concentrated in the north of the country, which tends to

be poorer.

Health

Departments that spend more on health do not necessarily have better outcomes. The

departments of Misiones and Ñeembucú, both located in the south of the country, achieve high

outcomes in terms of attended births, but have vaccinations rates below 70 percent (placing them

in the lower third of all departments). A number of other departments that spend less on health

achieve similar results, suggesting that they are more efficient in the use of their resources. The

main outlier is the department of Asunción, which spends most on health and has the highest or

second highest outcomes for maternal mortality, vaccination rates and prenatal care. This is not

surprising as hospitals tend to be concentrated in the capital city, and there is greater access to

health services for the population.

47

The other two departments in the Chaco (Boquerón and Alto Paraguay) were not included in the DEA because of

concerns over the quality of their data.

Asunción

Concepción

San Pedro

Cordillera

Guairá

Caaguazú

Caazapá

Itapúa

MisionesParaguarí

Alto Paraná

Central

Ñeembucú

Amambay

Canindeyú

Pdte. Hayes

Boquerón

Alto Paraguay

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 160,000 180,000 200,000

En

roll

men

t in

sec

on

dar

y p

ub

lic

an

d p

ub

licl

y s

ub

sid

ized

sch

oo

ls

(sh

are

of

ov

era

ll p

op

ula

tion

)

Government spending on secondary education per capita (Gs.)

58

There is also no clear geographical distinction in the spending/performance relationship.

Departments in the south of the country (blue) tend to have a higher share of births attended by

professionals even though per capita expenditure on health varies widely. For northern

departments (orange), on the other hand, outcomes range from above average (Amambay) to

very low (Caindeyú). As for TB vaccination rates, departments in the north tend to have better

outcomes (ranging from 76 percent in San Pedro to 99 percent in Amambay), while those in the

south have rates between 60 and 75 percent. Departments in the Chaco, the western part of the

country, rank in the middle of the group, both in terms of health spending and outcomes. These

relationships between spending and results suggest that there is no clear pattern between health

expenditure and health outcomes in general.

Using the DEA methodology, there is no indication that inefficient departments are

concentrated in a particular part of the country. The results suggest that Ñeembucú (south) is

by far the least efficient department when public health spending is considered in conjunction

with the maternal mortality rate, DTP vaccination rate and the share of women receiving prenatal

care. Pdte. Hayes (Chaco), Paraguarí (south) and Misiones (south) are also found to be among

the least efficient departments.

The findings of the analysis of within-country differences in efficiency have to be

interpreted with care. Data limitations (see Box 2) make it difficult to assess with certainty the

relationship between public expenditure and social outcomes. The lack of other socio-economic

data at the departmental level means that more rigorous regression analysis is also difficult to

conduct. The analysis presented in this chapter therefore only offers preliminary insights into the

differences in efficiency across departments, which could be complemented by further

qualitative and quantitative work.

59

Figure 4.5: Public expenditure on health vs. selected health outcomes, by department

(a) Birth attended by skilled professionals

(b) TB vaccination rates

Note: Excludes Alto Paraguay. Colors indicate region: blue – south; organge – north; red – west;

and green – capital city.

Source: BOOST, Ministry of Health.

Asunción

Concepción

San Pedro

Cordillera

Guairá

Caaguazú

Caazapá

Itapúa

Misiones

Paraguarí

Alto Paraná

Central

Ñeembucú

Amambay

Canindeyú

Pdte. Hayes

Boquerón

75

80

85

90

95

100

0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 160,000 180,000 200,000

Att

end

ed b

irth

s (%

)

Current public health expenditure (Gs. per capita)

Asunción

Concepción

San Pedro

Cordillera

Guairá

Caaguazú

Caazapá

Itapúa

Misiones

Paraguarí

Alto Paraná

Central

Ñeembucú

Amambay

Canindeyú

Pdte. Hayes

Boquerón

50

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

100

0 20,000 40,000 60,000 80,000 100,000 120,000 140,000 160,000 180,000 200,000

TB

va

ccin

ati

on r

ate

(%

)

Current public health expenditure (Gs. per capita)

60

Box 2. Education and Health Data for Paraguay

This chapter’s analysis of performance in the education and health systems in Paraguay uses data on

expenditure and outcomes (intermediate and final) as well as socio-economic and demographic statistics.

Data were provided by the authorities.

The Ministry of Finance provided outturn (obligado) data for Central Government expenditure at the

line item level for 2003-12. For the analysis, education spending was defined by functional categories

associated with education - this covers spending by several ministries, including Education and

Culture as well as Justice and Labor.1 Spending on education was then broken down by level using

the categorization for Public Expenditure Review (Variables Clave) in primary (Educación

Elemental) and secondary education (Educación Media y Técnica). Health expenditure includes all

spending items under the functional category of health (Salud) under the Ministry of Health.

The analysis compares education spending at the primary and secondary level with indicators of

outputs and outcomes at each level broken down by Department - the results of these data were made

available by the Ministries of Education and Health.

The sources for socio-economic and demographic data on population distribution and income are

from the Ministries of Health and Education, as well as from the Directorate General of Statistics,

Surveys and Census (DGEEC).

These data are useful for analyzing the impact of government spending and policies on education and

health results across departments, and as such they provide valuable information for motivating policy

decisions. But results need to be interpreted with caution due to some data weaknesses:

1. A large portion of education and health spending is not broken down by department. The share of

health spending not broken down by department and recorded under “alcance nacional” is particularly

large, amounting for 63 percent of total health spending. In the case of education, the share of

spending not recorded under a department is smaller, approximately 20 percent - but this includes the

bulk of non-wage spending in primary and secondary education. As a result, the available data do not

provide meaningful insights into the allocation of funds between wages, goods such as teaching

supplies, and capital investment across departments. In research for other countries, the allocation

between such categories of spending has been found to be critical for understanding the impact on

outcomes of education spending.

2. Large swings from year to year in indicators of results in education and health suggest that the data

may not always be accurate. For example, the share of pregnant women receiving prenatal care in

Alto Paraguay went from 72 percent in 2006 to 12 percent in 2007; in Alto Paraná this indicator

jumped to 36 percent in 2007 while it was around 18 percent before and after. As of 2008, volatility

seems less strong and data appear more reliable - most of the analysis in this section (except the

statistical part) uses data from 2008 and later.

3. Some of the data for Alto Paraguay and Boquerón strongly differs from other departments. For

example, the 2005-10 average spending per student in primary education reported for Boquerón is

only 10 percent of the average across departments. Meanwhile, spending on secondary education per

student in Alto Paraguay seems too high - over the same period it is 225 percent of the average

spending level across departments and almost twice as high as Presidente Hayes, the next high-

spending department. All three of these departments are located in the Chaco, the sparsely populated

and less developed western part of the country. To prevent outliers from driving findings, Alto

Paraguay and Boquerón have been excluded from the DEA and statistical analysis.

__________________________ 1These categories are: 341–Educación Elemental, 342-Educación Media y Técnica, 343–Educación Superior y

Universitaria, 346–Asistencia a Excepcionales, and 349–Educación y Cultura sin Discriminar.

61

4.3 Case study: expenditure efficiency in State-Owned Enterprises (SOEs)

Paraguay’s state-owned enterprises (SOEs) deliver a significant share of basic public

services, and the efficiency of their expenditure is important for social outcomes. They

provide electricity distribution (Administración Nacional de Electricidad, ANDE),

telecommunications (Compañía Paraguaya de Comunicaciones, COPACO) and water and

sanitation (Empresa de Servicios Sanitarios del Paraguay, ESSAP) in urban areas.48

In rural

areas or cities with less than 10,000 inhabitants, water and sanitation services are provided by

SENASA, part of the Ministry of Health. Yet other municipalities have water associations

(Juntas de Saneamiento). Both ANDE and ESSAP offer subsidized tariffs to low-income

customers. SOEs have thus contributed to the expansion in access to services and improvements

in the Human Opportunity Index analyzed in Chapter 3.

While the Government has started a thorough reform process to improve the monitoring

and oversight of SOEs, the transparency and adequate oversight of public spending

remains a challenge. Significant progress has been made in the areas of oversight, ownership

arrangements, disclosure of audited financial statements, and improvements in SOE

management, but shortcomings remain in procurement processes, merit-based appointments of

directors, managers and staff, and an accountability framework which are not yet sufficiently

embedded in the corporate governance framework. This has led to mismanagement, inefficiency

and an inflated payroll in some SOEs. Similarly, procurement processes lack transparency and

rigorous processes to ensure value-for-money in the acquisition of goods and services.

The operational performance of SOEs remains weak. They are struggling to meet the

demands arising from population growth and increasing urbanization. In addition, technical and

non-technical losses are high in electricity and water distribution due to outdated infrastructure.

Investment needs are significant but SOEs are currently not in a position to adequately anticipate

and plan for these needs.

Finally, the financial links with the central government are opaque. Paraguay’s SOEs have

contributed more than US$130 million to the national budget in recent years, with ANDE alone

accounting for US$80 million. However, these transfers are not predictable and can vary from

year to year. In addition, Government institutions have significant outstanding debt for non-

payment of utility bills with SOEs, which affects their financial viability.

48 Other SOEs are operating in petroleum import and distribution, transport management, and cement and beverage

production.

62

Table 4.1: Characteristics of the SOE Sector in Paraguay

Sector SOE

Budget of SOEs

As a % of the national

budget As a % of GDP

Petroleum Petróleos Paraguayos (PETROPAR) 13.8 6.3

Electricity Administración Nacional de Electricidad

(ANDE)

11.4 5.2

Telecommunications Compañía Paraguaya de Comunicaciones

(COPACO)

3.2 1.5

Construction Industria Nacional del Cemento (INC) 1.7 0.7

Water and

Sanitation

Empresa de Servicios Sanitarios del Paraguay

(ESSAP)

0.8 0.4

Transport

Dirección Nacional de Aeronáutica Civil (DINAC) 0.5 0.2

Administración Nacional de Navegación y Puertos

(ANNP)

0.3 0.1

Ferrocarriles del Paraguay (FEPASA) 0.0 0.0

Beverages Cañas Paraguayas (CAPASA) 0.1 0.0

TOTAL 31.8 14.4

Source: UMEP, Ministry of Finance

4.4 Policy options

More and better disaggregated data at the department level would significantly improve

inputs for public policy making. In addition to improving the accuracy of available data,

breaking down data on total expenditure by department, including at the program or even facility

level (such as schools and health centers) would push progress even further by allowing for

better targeting of resources. More and better data on outcomes in key sectors, as well as on

socio-economic and demographic indicators at the departmental or municipal level, would also

be important.

Paraguay would also benefit from the participation in international assessments in order to

better gauge its performance vis-à-vis peer countries. Paraguay participated in the Second

Regional Comparative and Explanatory Study (SERCE), which evaluates learning achievements

in 17 Latin American countries. Taking part in the PISA study could make indicators of

education outcomes in Paraguay comparable to more countries, thus providing important

information that could guide policy making in that sector.

Improved management and oversight of SOEs could contribute to better social service

provision. Specific measures include: (i) approval and implementation of the draft law

institutionalizing an independent SOE supervisory body; (ii) further reforms to strengthen the

SOE governance and oversight framework; (iii) assurance of sufficient supply and quality of

basic public services; (iv) preparation of a long- and medium-term investment plan to efficiently

address infrastructure gaps; (v) the set-up of an investment system for SOEs; (vi) a set of rules

for managing debt and fiscal risk of SOEs; and (vii) schemes on transfers, subsidies and

outstanding payments.

63

List of references

Athanasoulis, S., and E. van Wincoop (2000). “Growth Uncertainty and Risk-Sharing.” Journal

of Monetary Economics 45(3):477–505.

Berument, H., Dincer, N. and Z. Mustafaoglu (2011). “Total factor productivity and

macroeconomic instability”, The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, Vol.

20, No. 5, pp. 605–629.

Breen, R. and C. García-Peñalosa (2005). "Income Inequality and Macroeconomic Volatility: An

Empirical Investigation,"Review of Development Economics, Wiley Blackwell, vol. 9(3), pages

380-398.

Bucheli, Marisa, Nora Lustig, Máximo Rossi and Florencia Amábile (2013). “Social Spending,

Taxes and Income Redistribution in Uruguay.” Public Finance Review, forthcoming.

Calderon, C. and K. Schmidt-Hebbel (2003). "Macroeconomic policies and performance in Latin

America,"Journal of International Money and Finance, Elsevier, vol. 22(7), pages 895-923,

December.

Cuesta, Jose and Pablo Suárez Becerra (2013). Equality of Opportunities and Public Spending in

Paraguay. Background paper prepared for the Paraguay PER.

Diaz Bonilla, C. and Cicowiez, M. (2013). “Assessing the Poverty and Social Impact of Tax

Exemptions and World Price Shocks in Paraguay”, Volume 2, Paraguay Public Expenditure

Review, The World Bank, Washington D.C..

Favaro, E., Koehler-Geib, F., Picarelli, N., and A. Indaco (2013). Paraguay: Agriculture

commodity prices and tax revenue collection, background paper for Paraguay Public Expenditure

Review (2013), World Bank, forthcoming

Garcia-Penalosa, C. and Turnovsky, S. (2004). “Macroeconomic Volatility and Income

Inequality in a Stochastically Growing Economy”, conference volume of “Economic Growth and

Income Distribution: On the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations,” conference held in

Lucca, Italy, June 16-18.

Gavin, Michael and Roberto Perotti (1997). “Fiscal Policy in Latin America,” NBER

Macroeconomics Annual.

Goñi, E., J.H. López and Luis Servén (2008). Fiscal Redistribution and Income Inequality in

Latin America. Policy Research Working Paper No. 4487. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Higgins, Sean and Claudiney Pereira (2013). “The Effects of Brazil’s Taxation and Social

Spending on the Distribution of Household Income.” Public Finance Review, forthcoming.

64

Hnatkovska, V. and F. Koehler-Geib (2013). “Business Cycle Accounting for Paraguay“,

Volume 2 of World Bank report:”Growth volatiltity in Paraguay—sources, effects, options”,

World Bank 2013, Washington D.C., (forthcoming).

Hnatkovska, V., Loayza, N. (2003). “Volatility and growth”. World Bank Policy Research

Working Paper No. 3184

Huang, H., Fang, W. and S. Miller (2012). “The Effect of Growth Volatility on Income

Inequality”, University of Nevada Working paper.

Ilzetzki, Ethan and Carlos A. Vegh (2008). "Procyclical Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries:

Truth or Fiction?," NBER Working Papers 14191, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

IMF (2009). “Paraguay, addressing the stagnation and instability trap”, edited by Alejandro

Santos, Washington DC.

IMF (2011). “Paraguay Article IV consultations—staff report”, IMF, August 2011.

IMF (2012). “Strengthening government debt and cash management”, IMF report, March 2012.

Inclan, C. and G. Tiao: “Use of Cumulative Sums of Squares for Retrospective Detection of

Changes of Variance”, 1994

Jaramillo, Miguel (2013). “The Incidence of Social Spending and Taxes in Peru.” Public

Finance Review, forthcoming.

Le Fort, G., Escobar, G., and D. Contreras (2013). “Paraguay: Estimation of the Structural Fiscal

Balance and Fiscal Rule Proposal”, Volume 2, Paraguay Public Expenditure Review, The World

Bank, Washington D.C..

Lopez-Calva, L., Lugo, M. and O. Barriga Cabanillas (2013). “Paraguay Equity Assessment”,

The World Bank, Washington, D.C., forthcoming.

Lustig, Nora and Sean Higgins (2012). “Commitment to Equity Assessment (CEQ): Estimating

the Incidence of Social Spending, Subsidies and Taxes Handbook.” Tulane University

Department of Economics Working Paper 1219.

Lustig, Nora, Sean Higgins, Julio Ramirez and Billy Swanson (2012). Social Spending, Taxes

and Income Redistribution in Paraguay. Background paper prepared for the Paraguay PER.

Lustig, Nora and Carola Pessino (2013). “Social Spending and Income Redistribution in

Argentina During the 2000s: the Rising Role of Noncontributory Pensions.” Public Finance

Review, forthcoming.

65

Lustig, Nora, Carola Pessino, and John Scott (2013). “The Impact of Taxes and Social Spending

on Inequality and Poverty in Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico and Peru: An Overview.” Public

Finance Review, forthcoming.

Mendoza, Enrique G. and P. Marcelo Oviedo (2006). "Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic

Uncertainty in Developing Countries: The Tale of the Tormented Insurer," NBER Working

Papers 12586, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Morán and Cabrera (2012) for Guatemala

Paes de Barros, R., F.H.G. Ferreira, J.R. Molinas Vega and J. Saavedra Chanduvi (2009).

Measuring Inequality of Opportunities in Latin America. Washington, DC: World Bank.

Paz Arauco, Verónica, George Gray Molina, Wilson Jiménez Pozo, and Ernesto Yáñez Aguilar

(2013). “Explaining Low Redistributive Impact in Bolivia.” Public Finance Review,

forthcoming.

Schenone, O. (2010). “El Gasto Tributario en Paraguay”, Mimeo, The World Bank, Washington

D.C., August 2010.

Schenone, O. (2013). “Evolution and composition of tax revenues in Paraguay—Effects of the

tax reform of 2004”, Volume 2, Paraguay Public Expenditure Review, The World Bank,

Washington D.C.

Scott, John (2013). “Redistributive Impact and Efficiency of Mexico's Fiscal System.” Public

Finance Review, forthcoming.

Talvi, E., and Carlos A. Végh, 2005. “Tax Base Variability and Procyclical Fiscal Policy in

Developing Countries,” Journal of Development Economics 78, pages 156-190.

Verhoeven, M., Gunnarson, V., and S. Lugaresi (2007). ” The Health Sector in the Slovak

Republic: Efficiency and Reform”, IMF Working Paper, 07/226.

World Bank (2000). “Securing Our Future in a Global Economy”, The World Bank,

Washington, D.C.

World Bank (2007). “Paraguay Real Property Tax – Key to Fiscal Decentralization and Better

Land Use”, The World Bank, Washington D.C.

World Bank (2012). “Public Expenditure Review for Peru—Spending for Results”, The World

Bank, Washington D.C.

World Bank (2013). “Growth Volatility in Paraguay—Sources, Effects, Options”, The World

Bank, Washington D.C., forthcoming.

World Bank and IMF (2010). “Paraguay-Compendium of recommendations on debt

management”. Joint WB-IMF MTDS report, December, 2010.

66

World Bank and IMF (2012). Joint WB-IMF MTDS report, October, 2012.

Zhu (2003). Quantitative models for performance evaluation and benchmarking: data

envelopment analysis with spreadsheets and DEA excel solver. Massachusetts: Kluwer

Academic Publisher.

67

Annexes

Annex 1.1. Volatility over time, international comparison

Standard deviation of Paraguay’s growth and output gap in international comparison

std dev (GDP growth)

std dev (GDP gap)

1960-

2011

1960-

2000

2001-

2011

1960-

2011

1960-

2000

2001-

2011

Argentina 5.83 5.52 6.73

5.66 5.15 6.86

Bahamas, The 7.16 7.81 2.62

7.87 8.75 2.95

Barbados 4.54 4.55 3.51

4.46 4.73 3.62

Belize 4.03 4.27 3.56

4.81 5.24 2.60

Bolivia 3.52 3.88 1.31

3.98 4.43 1.37

Brazil 4.11 4.45 2.29

3.84 4.25 1.63

Chile 4.64 5.14 2.02

4.50 4.99 1.73

Colombia 2.21 2.32 1.77

2.31 2.23 2.56

Costa Rica 3.34 3.48 2.85

3.32 3.46 2.77

Cuba 6.36 6.92 3.65

6.52 7.17 3.90

Dominican

Republic 5.26 5.68 3.36

4.63 4.97 3.41

Ecuador 3.55 3.77 2.48

3.17 3.35 2.94

El Salvador 4.18 4.60 1.84

4.63 5.14 1.89

Guatemala 2.49 2.70 1.46

2.56 2.81 1.40

Guyana 5.22 5.69 2.84

5.18 5.62 2.61

Honduras 3.04 3.21 2.42

3.09 3.14 2.92

Jamaica 5.03 5.11 0.33

5.20 5.26 0.26

Mexico 3.78 3.75 3.34

3.25 3.43 2.82

Nicaragua 6.23 6.98 1.96

5.70 6.36 2.12

Panama 4.40 4.52 3.67

4.14 4.30 3.43

Paraguay 4.28 4.03 5.50

4.31 4.19 4.45

Peru 5.03 5.32 3.14

5.01 5.46 2.69

Puerto Rico 3.55 3.07 2.78

2.79 2.70 3.06

Suriname 5.24 5.57 2.10

4.50 5.13 2.68

Trinidad and

Tobago 4.99 4.67 5.71

5.36 4.92 6.62

Uruguay 4.44 4.26 5.12

5.37 5.25 5.53

Venezuela, RB 5.32 4.30 7.90

5.17 3.86 8.24

Mean 4.51 4.65 3.19

4.49 4.68 3.23

Median 4.44 4.52 2.84

4.50 4.92 2.82

Source: Hnatkovska and Koehler-Geib (2013)

68

Annex 1.2. Volatility breaks of macro-economic variables in Paraguay

Breakpoint date for change in volatility for selected variables

Source: World Bank (2013), forthcoming

GDP single breakpoint 2008-IV Increase

Agriculture sector single breakpoint 2008-IV Increase

Non -agriculture sector No change No change

Private investment No change No change

first breakpoint 2002-II Decrease

second breakpoint 2008-II Increase

Total investment No change No change

Private consumption No change No change

first breakpoint 2000-II Increase

second breakpoint 2009-I Increase

Inflation single breakpoint 1995-II Increase

Soy price single breakpoint 2003-III Increase

Oil prices No change No change

Beef price No change No change

first breakpoint 2001-III Increase

second breakpoint 2003-II Decrease

third breakpoint 2008-I Increase

RER No change No change

TOT No change No change

Current account balance single breakpoint 2007-I Increase

World real interest rate single breakpoint 2007-IV Increase

Interest rate No change No change

first breakpoint 2002-IV Decrease

second breakpoint 2004-II Increase

Central government expenditure single breakpoint 2001-III Decrease

Fiscal revenue single breakpoint 2004-III Decrease

Total revenue No change No change

Credit to private sector

Nominal Exchange rate

Variable Date

Public consumption

Direction of

change in

volatility

Public investment

69

Annex 1.3. Social development indicators

Development indicators

Source: WDI and Doing Business

Pension system coverage School enrolement, secondary (percent gross)

Source: CEPAL WDI

Human Opportunity Index Doing Business Human Development Index

Chile Chile Chile

Uruguay Peru Argentina

Mexico Colombia Panama

Costa Rica Mexico Mexico

Venezuela Panama Costa Rica

Argentina Jamaica Venezuela

Jamaica Guatemala Peru

Ecuador Paraguay Jamaica

Colombia Costa Rica Brazil

Brazil El Salvador Ecuador

Dominican Republic Dominican Republic Colombia

Paraguay Nicaragua Dominican Republic

Peru Argentina El Salvador

Guatemala Honduras Paraguay

El Salvador Brazil Honduras

Nicaragua Ecuador Nicaragua

Honduras Venezuela Guatemala

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

Ch

ile

Co

sta

Ric

a

Uru

guay

Bra

zil

Pan

ama

Arg

enti

na

Mex

ico

Ve

nez

uel

a

Co

lom

bia

El S

alva

do

r

Gu

atem

ala

Ecu

ado

r

Do

min

ican

Rep

ub

lic

Ho

nd

ura

s

Nic

arag

ua

Per

u

Par

agu

ay

Bo

livia

Pe

rcen

t

1996 2006

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

Bra

zil

Co

sta

Ric

a

Co

lom

bia

Per

u

Uru

guay

Arg

enti

na

Ch

ile

Mex

ico

Ecu

ado

r

Ve

nez

uel

a

Bo

livia

Do

min

ican

Rep

ub

lic

Pan

ama

Ho

nd

ura

s

Nic

arag

ua

Par

agu

ay

El S

alva

do

r

Gu

atem

ala

Pe

rcen

t

70

Improved access to sanitation (percent of

population)

Improved water source (percent of population)

Source: WDI Source: WDI

Annex 1.4. Poverty, Extreme Poverty, Inequality in Latin America and the

Caribbean

Poverty, Extreme Poverty, and Inequality in Latin American countries

(ranked from 1: lowest poverty, extreme poverty, and inequality to 18: highest)

Source: World Bank, SEDLAC database

0

20

40

60

80

100

120U

rugu

ay

Ch

ile

Co

sta

Ric

a

Ecu

ado

r

Ve

nez

uel

a

Arg

enti

na

El S

alva

do

r

Mex

ico

Do

min

ican

Rep

ub

lic

Bra

zil

Gu

atem

ala

Co

lom

bia

Ho

nd

ura

s

Par

agu

ay

Per

u

Pan

ama

Nic

arag

ua

Bo

livia

Pe

rcen

t

75

80

85

90

95

100

105

Uru

guay

Bra

zil

Arg

enti

na

Co

sta

Ric

a

Ch

ile

Mex

ico

Ecu

ado

r

Pan

ama

Ve

nez

uel

a

Co

lom

bia

Gu

atem

ala

Bo

livia

El S

alva

do

r

Ho

nd

ura

s

Do

min

ican

Rep

ub

lic

Par

agu

ay

Nic

arag

ua

Per

u

Pe

rcen

t

Rank Poverty Extreme Poverty Inequity (Gini)

1 Chile Uruguay Argentina

2 Uruguay Chile Uruguay

3 Argentina Argentina Bolivia

4 Costa Rica Costa Rica Peru

5 Panama Bolivia El Salvador

6 Brasil Panama Nicaragua

7 Peru Mexico Ecuador

8 Mexico Venezuela Republica Dominicana

9 Bolivia Brasil Mexico

10 Venezuela Peru Costa Rica

11 Ecuador Ecuador Panama

12 Paraguay Republica Dominicana Chile

13 Colombia Colombia Paraguay

14 Republica Dominicana Paraguay Brasil

15 El Salvador El Salvador Colombia

16 Nicaragua Nicaragua Guatemala

17 Honduras Honduras Honduras

18 Guatemala Guatemala

Inequality (Gini)

71

Annex 4.1: Data envelopment analysis (DEA)

Relative efficiency of spending is assessed by comparing expenditure levels and outcomes in

Paraguay and a sample of countries with a similar population and per capita income as well as in a

within country comparison at the departmental level. As described and applied in Verhoeven,

Gunnarson, and Lugaresi (2007), this is done using DEA, which was developed for estimating best-

practice frontiers and relative efficiency in business applications. In this case, DEA is used to assess

the relationship between spending (inputs) and outcomes (production) across countries or in the

second analysis across departments.

Efficiency and the Best-Practice Frontier

Verhoeven, Gunnarson, and Lugaresi (2007)

The framework of production efficiency can be used to assess the relative efficiency with which

production units convert input items into production items (i.e., technical efficiency). In the figure

above, as production unit A achieves the same or more product items as production unit E with fewer

input items, unit A is more efficient16 than unit E. Similarly, unit E is less efficient than units B, C,

and D. The difference between the input items used by units A and E can be used to measure the

inefficiency of unit E relative to unit A. (Alternatively, this could be measured by the difference in

production items.) The most efficient units in a sample provide the parameters for an initial estimate

of the best-practice frontier. One of the most common ways for determining the best-practice (or

production possibility) frontier is DEA (a more detailed discussion of DEA can be found in Zhu,

2003). The best-practice frontier is illustrated in the figure above by the solid line that connects the

best-practice units A, B, C, and F. Because these are the most efficient units in the sample, they are

assigned an efficiency score of 1. The efficiency scores of the less efficient units (D and E) depend

on their distance to the best-practice frontier. Several measures of the distance to the frontier can be

used. In the current analysis the Farrell input efficiency score is used.

72

The analysis in this chapter applies input-oriented DEA with one input and multiple outputs

assuming variable returns-to-scale (VRS). Input oriented implies that the efficiency score

measures the input (expenditure) saving that can be achieved by moving from unit E to the

production frontier. Given that the chapter is interested how the same outputs could be achieved

at lower cost, the focus is on input-oriented DEA. Alternatively, the output-oriented efficiency

score for unit E can be calculated as the ratio of the number of outputs achieved at a maximum

(i.e., at the frontier) to the number of input items actually used by unit E. The output-oriented

efficiency score reflects the improvement in outputs that could be achieved from efficiency

enhancement. Variables returns to scale implies that the analysis assumes that the frontier is not a

straight line (as in the case of constant returns to scale) but a concave combination of inputs and

outputs.

73

Map