africa

Upload: pengueno

Post on 11-Oct-2015

11 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

syllabus

TRANSCRIPT

  • INSTITUT DE HAUTES TUDES INTERNATIONALES ET DU DVELOPPEMENT

    GRADUATE INSTITUTE OF INTERNATIONAL AND DEVELOPMENT STUDIES SWITZERLAND - TEL +41 (0)22 908 57 00 - http://graduateinstitute.ch

    International History and Politics

    Academic year 2011-2012

    Power, Poverty and Wealth in Africa, 1700-1945

    HP014 - Autumn - Course - 6 ECTS

    Thursdays 10:15-12:00 Room CV 204

    Course Description

    This seminar course explores the political economy of Sub-

    Saharan Africa from the Atlantic slave trade to colonial rule,

    emphasizing the importance of Africans in shaping the

    patterns of change within this context of overseas markets and

    foreign influence.

    Themes include: theoretical and historiographical

    perspectives on Africas long-term relative poverty and on the historical obstacles to political centralization in Africa; natural

    resources and technical and institutional responses; indigenous

    economic cultures and responses to markets; the external slave

    trades; slavery, migrant labour and labour stabilization; fiscal

    and economic dimensions of the pattern of precolonial and

    colonial state formation, and consequences for ethnicity;

    African initiatives and resistance in agriculture and business in

    colonial West Africa; the struggle of African peasant

    agriculture with the state in settler economies; labour repression, mining and manufacturing in South Africa.

    PROFESSOR

    Gareth Austin [email protected]

    +41 22 908 62 18

    Reception hours:

    Tuesdays 15:00-16:00

    Thursdays 14:00-15:00

    (CV324)

    ASSISTANT

    Felix Ohnmacht [email protected]

    +41 22 908 58 03

    Reception hours:

    Wednesdays 14.30 - 16.30 or by

    appointment

    (CV311)

    Evaluation will be based on:

    1. A seminar paper of 4-6,000 words (50%).

    2. Presentation and defence of the paper (10%).

    3. Comment on a fellow participants paper (20%). 4. Class preparation and participation (20%).

    Structure:

    The introductory meeting will be followed by (depending on student numbers) about four seminars

    (weeks 2-5) led by the teacher. There will then be up to eight seminars (6-13) led by student paper-

    givers and discussants, before the concluding meeting.

    Readings:

    It is imperative that everyone reads before each seminar. So, if you decide to take the course, you need

    to commit yourself to reading the Essential items, which total about 70 pages per week. If you are discussant in a particular week, or have time to explore the topic further, please also use the Further readings. For your own paper, even the Further readings will not be enough. Please come and discuss the question to be addressed by your paper, and the readings, in my reception (office) hours. NB: The readings are intended to be very accessible to those without an economics background.

    Buying books?

    J. Iliffe, Africans: the History of a Continent (2nd

    edition: Cambridge University Press 2007) is the best

    single-volume history of the continent. A good recent text is R. Reid, A History of Modern Africa:

  • 2

    1800 to the Present (Wiley-Blackwell 2009). In economic history, the classic remains A. G. Hopkins modestly titled An Economic History of West Africa (1973, reprinted several times).

    1. INTRODUCTION: INTERPRETATIONS, THEORIES & ISSUES

    1. Introduction to the seminar 2. What papers can we write? 3. Interpretations, theories and issues

    Themes

    After discussing the organisation of the course, we will begin to consider, in the context of African

    history, the universal theme of the interaction between natural resources, political power and the

    generation and distribution of income and wealth. The literature from several disciplines has variously emphasised internal and/or external obstacles to economic development and state building in

    Africa, while being uncertain about the relationship between the latter. Rival theoretical traditions,

    notably rational-choice and dependency cum world systems, will be introduced. Finally, we need to

    reflect on the implications of two features of the literature on African history and society: so far, it has

    been written more by outsiders than by Africans; and the social science concepts used in the study of

    Africa are mostly products of work on other regions of the world.

    Essential reading

    J-F. Bayart, Africa in the world: a history of extraversion, African Affairs 99, 395 (2000), pp. 217-67.

    J. Herbst, The challenge of state-building in Africa, in Herbst, States and Power in Africa (2000), pp. 11-31.

    Further reading

    I.Wallerstein, The three stages of African involvement in the world economy, in P. Gutkind & I. Wallerstein (eds), The Political Economy of Contemporary Africa (1976), pp. 30-57. Reprinted in

    Wallerstein, Africa and the Modern World (1986).

    F. Bernault, LAfrique et la modernit des sciences sociales, Vingtime sicle: Revue dhistoire 70 (2001), pp.127-38.

    Background reading

    J. Iliffe, Africans: the History of a Continent (2nd

    edition, 2007).

    R. Bates, Essays on the Political Economy of Rural Africa (1983), pp. 1-104.

    T. Zaleza, A Modern Economic History of Africa, vol. I, The Nineteenth Century (1993), pp. 1-22.

    R. Reid, Past and presentism: the precolonial and the foreshortening of African history, Journal of African History 52:2 (2011), pp. 135-55.

    G. Austin, Reciprocal comparison and African history: tackling conceptual euro-centrism in the study of Africas economic past, African Studies Review, 50: 3 (2007), pp. 1-28.

  • 3

    2. LONG-TERM PERSPECTIVES ON PRECOLONIAL POLITICAL ECONOMY:

    ENVIRONMENT, STATES AND DEVELOPMENT

    Themes

    Land was relatively abundant in most places at most times in precolonial Sub-Saharan Africa. Yet, in

    much of the continent, soil and rainfall patterns made it hard to use it intensively (Ethiopia being a

    notable if partial exception to both generalisations). Thus natural conditions tended to hinder the

    growth of markets, taxable surpluses, large-scale units of production, and political centralization. Yet

    by 1700 there was a perhaps surprisingly high level of market production, especially in West Africa,

    while in sub-Saharan Africa as a whole state formation was old though independent chiefdoms and

    micro-polities continued to be common. We examine the strategies of producers and state-builders;

    social attitudes to fertility and immigration; why and when conditions favoured slavery and slave

    trading; and paths and varieties of economic and political change.

    Essential reading

    G. Austin, Resources, techniques and strategies south of the Sahara: revising the factor endowments perspective on African economic development, 1500-2000, Economic History Review 61: 3 (2008), pp. 587-624.

    J. Herbst, Power and space in precolonial Africa in his States and Power in Africa (2000), pp. 35-57.

    J. Inikori, Africa and the globalization process: Western Africa, 1450-1850, Journal of Global History 2: 1 (2007), pp. 63-86.

    Further reading

    A. Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa (1973), pp. 17-27, 51-77, 124-35.

    C-H. Perrot (ed.), Lineages et territoire en Afrique aux XVIIIe et XIXe sicles : strategies,

    comptition, intgration (2000), esp. pp. 5-17.

    I. Wilks, Land, labor, gold, and the forest kingdom of Asante: a model of early change, in Wilks, Forests of Gold: Essays on the Akan and the Kingdom of Asante (1993), pp. 41-90.

    P. Curtin, The lure of Bambuk gold, Journal of African History 14 (1973), pp. 623-31.

    D. Crummey, Abyssinian feudalism, Past & Present 89 (1980), pp. 115-38.

    3. AFRICA AND THE ATLANTIC SLAVE TRADE

    Themes

    For over a thousand years slaves were exported from Sub-Saharan Africa: across the Sahara, Red Sea,

    Indian Ocean and, of course, the Atlantic. In view of the relative scarcity of labour in Africa, what

    were the political and economic conditions that made the largest forced migration in history profitable

    for European merchants and African merchants and rulers? And, despite our very limited knowledge

    of the size of the population of Africa (including, most relevantly, of west and west-central Africa)

  • 4

    during this era, what can we establish about the consequences for the nature and distribution of power,

    poverty and wealth within the continent?

    Essential reading

    J. Inikori, The struggle against the transatlantic slave trade: the role of the state, in S. Diouf (ed.), Fighting the Slave Trade: West African Strategies (2003), pp.170-98.

    J. Thornton, Industry and terms of trade, in his Africa and Africans in the Making of the Atlantic World, 1400-1680, pp. 44-53 (2

    nd edition, 1998).

    S. Fenoaltea, Europe in the African Mirror: the slave trade and the rise of feudalism, Rivista di Storia Economica, 15: 2 (1999), pp.123-65.

    Further reading

    D. Eltis et al., Voyages: the Trans-Atlantic Slave Trade Database. http://www.slavevoyages.org

    A. Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa (1973), pp. 87-112.

    W. Rodney, Gold and slaves on the Gold Coast, Transactions of the Historical Society of Ghana, 10 (1969), pp. 13-28. Classic article.

    M. Klein, The slave trade and decentralized societies, Journal of African History 42: 1 (2001), pp. 49-65.

    P. Lovejoy & D. Richardson, This horrid hole: royal authority, commerce and credit at Bonny 1600-1840, Journal of African History 45: 3 (2005), pp. 363-92. New institutional economic history.

    4. COLONIAL GOVERNMENT: INDIRECT RULE AND THE CULTIVATION OF

    ETHNICITY

    Themes

    From the Scramble (1879-c.1905) to the Second World War: cash-strapped colonial administrations and their need to compromise and manage as well as coerce, hence the reliance (especially by the

    British) on rule through African chiefs. We consider the reactions and initiatives of African elites and

    wider populations. How far were colonial governments responsible for the creation of tribes in Africa?

    Essential reading

    S. Berry, Hegemony on a shoestring: Indirect Rule and farmers access to resources, in Berry, No Condition is Permanent: The Social Dynamics of Agrarian Change in Sub-Saharan Africa (1993), pp.

    22-42 (or the earlier version, in the journal Africa 62: 3 (1992), pp. 327-55). Useful introduction.

    T. Spear, Neo-traditionalism and the limits of invention in British colonial Africa, Journal of African History 44:1 (2003), 1-27. Surveys the literature on the invention of tradition, especially ethnicity.

  • 5

    Further reading

    J. Iliffe, Africans: The History of a Continent (1995 or 2007 editions), chs on Colonial invasion and Colonial change (pp. 187-242 in the 1995 edition). Nuanced overview.

    M. Mamdani, Citizen and Subject: Contemporary Africa and the Legacy of Late Colonialism (1996)

    [despite late, the argument is as or more relevant for pre-1945 colonialism], pp. 16-25, 72-90, 138-79.

    J. Herbst, The Europeans and the African problem in his States and Power in Africa (2000), pp. 58-96. The colonial edition of the problem of state formation in the region.

    A. Phillips, The Enigma of Colonialism: British Policy in West Africa (1989), pp. 59-84.

    A.Hopkins, An economic model of colonialism, in his An Economic History of West Africa (1973), pp. 167-86.

    Background reading

    B. Freund, The material basis of colonial society, 1900-40, ch 6 in his The Making of Contemporary Africa (pp. 97-124 in 2

    nd edition, 1998). An overview from Marxist-influenced social history.

    5. DIFFERENT PATTERNS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, DIFFERENT PATHS OF

    CHANGE IN WHITE-RULED AFRICA: SETTLER AND PEASANT ECONOMIES

    Themes

    We consider the fundamental distinction between colonies in which much of the land was appropriated

    for European settlers or plantations, and colonies in which it remained in African hands. In both cases

    African farmers responded to price incentives to produce for the market. In the settler colonies,

    however, the state sought to drive Africans out of the produce market and into the labour market. In

    the peasant (and rural capitalist) economies, in contrast, African producers achieved an export crop revolution, which persuaded the local colonial administrators to support continued African ownership of the land. There were other, related, differences between the two/three types of colony: including in

    their implications for the distribution of income and the growth of manufacturing. Bates offers a

    rational-choice account of the significance of the distinction between settler and peasant colonies for

    the effectiveness of agricultural lobbies.

    This week will include an introduction to the debates arising from - and now much surpassing the old conventional wisdom that economic growth in both kinds of colony was based on mobilising a

    labour surplus: on getting underemployed Africans to work. That idea was formalised in the Lewis

    model, which was applied by some South African and British economists to the settler colonies, and in

    the Myint vent-for-surplus model, designed to capture the experience of the peasant colonies. Was this idea of costless economic growth justified in either or both cases? Historians have emphasised African historical agency: the capacity of the indigenous population to determine their own fates, to a

    large extent, even under colonial rule. This was exemplified by the failure of colonial governments to

    drive Africans completely out of the produce market in the settler colonies, and of French merchants to

    capture the lions share of cotton production in French Soudan (Mali).

  • 6

    Essential reading

    C. Wrigley, Aspects of economic history, in A. Roberts (ed.), The Colonial Moment in Africa: Essays on the Movement of Minds and Materials, 1900-1940 (1986), 77-139 (reprinted from the

    Cambridge History of Africa, vol. 7). Overview.

    P. Hill, Ghanaian capitalist cocoa-farmers, in Studies in Rural Capitalism in West Africa (1970), pp. 21-29 (or, in more detail, Hill, Migrant Cocoa-farmers of Southern Ghana, 2

    nd edition 1997).

    Challenging the old stereotype of African cash-crop producers as small peasants.

    Further reading

    G. Arrighi, Labour supplies in historical perspective: a study of the proletarianization of the African peasantry in Rhodesia, Journal of Development Studies 3 (1970), pp. 197-234; reprinted in Arrighi and J. Saul, Essays on the Political Economy of Africa (1973). Classic critique of the application of the

    Lewis model to Africa.

    R. Austen, African Economic History (1987), pp. 181-7. Perceptive.

    R. Bates, Pressure groups, public policy, and agricultural development: a study of divergent outcomes (Kenya/Gold Coast) in R.H. Bates & M. Lofchie (eds), Agricultural Policy in Africa (1980), pp. 61-91. Reprinted in Bates, Essays on the Political Economy of Rural Africa (1983). New

    institutional political economy.

    R. Roberts, Local processes and the world economy: imported cloth, the domestic cotton market, and the handicraft textile industry, 1918-1932, in his Two Worlds of Cotton: Colonialism and the Regional Economy in the French Soudan, 1800-1946 (1996), pp. 192-220.

    S. Bowden, B. Chiripanhura & P. Mosley. Measuring and explaining poverty in six African countries: a long-period approach, Journal of International Development 20: 8 (2008), pp. 1049-79. Quantitative evidence that African welfare rose earlier and faster in peasant than in settler colonies.

    NOTE: Most or all of the following topics (5-13) will be approached via student papers, and the

    scope and readings (and possibly the list of topics itself) may be revised closer to the time to

    reflect the design of the papers.

    6. CONSEQUENCES OF THE ATLANTIC SLAVE TRADE

    Themes

    Between 1441 and 1867 some 13-15 million people were shipped in chains from the labour-scarce

    African continent to Atlantic islands, Europe or the Americas. This is such a central process in African

    history that we should return to it, focussing this time on the consequences for economies, societies

    and polities the enslaved deportees left behind. The precise agenda will be shaped by your papers, but

    questions include: did the external trades, and specifically the Atlantic trade, strengthen or weaken

    states, or simply make them temporarily more militaristic? Did it promote or just reproduce inequality

    in the distribution of wealth and power? Did it retard or promote the expansion of markets? The

    following readings augment those given for week 3.

  • 7

    Essential reading

    J. Inikori, Ideology versus the tyranny of paradigm: historians and the impact of the Atlantic slave trade on African societies, African Economic History: 22 (1994), pp. 37-58. Also relevant is Inikoris 2007 article, on the reading list for week 2.

    E. Evans and D. Richardson, Hunting for rents: the economics of slaving in pre-colonial Africa, Economic History Review 48 (1995), pp. 665-86.

    D. Henige, Measuring the Immeasurable: the Atlantic Slave Trade, West African population and the Pyrrhonian critic, Journal of African History 27 (1986), pp. 295-313.

    Further reading

    W. Rodney, Gold and slaves on the Gold Coast, Transactions of the Historical Society of Ghana, 10 (1969), pp. 13-28.

    J. Searing, No Kings, No Lords, No Slaves: ethnicity and religion Among the Sereer-Safn of Western Bawol, 1700-1914, Journal of African History 43: 3 (2002), 407-29.

    Background reading

    J. Miller, Way of Death: Merchant Capitalism and the Angolan Slave Trade 1730-1830 (1988), Part I.

    P. Lovejoy, Transformations in Slavery: a history of slavery in Africa (pref. the 2000 edition), chs 3-7.

    7. SLAVING, STATE BUILDING AND THE MARKET IN THE PRECOLONIAL

    NINETEENTH CENTURY: WEST AFRICA

    As the Atlantic slave trade made its protracted and uneven decline (following British abolition which

    took legal effect from 1 January 1808), African rulers and merchants faced a problem of adaptation:

    what to export instead of captives to earn the means to buy imports, whether of cloth or guns. A long-

    standing thesis, given classic form by Hopkins (1973), sees the rise of what the abolitionists called

    legitimate commerce, based on palm oil and groundnut (peanut) exports, as revolutionary: the entry into the world market of small producers and traders, undermining the position of the big traders and

    rulers who had dominated the slave trade. Critics see the continuities as outweighing the changes.

    Either way, the commercial transition on the coast was not the only fundamental change that was in

    process. The early nineteenth century saw the culmination of a wave of jihadist movements that

    established strongly Muslim states across most of the savannas of West Africa, including the Sokoto

    Caliphate (whose commercial centre was the city of Kano, in northern Nigeria). As Lovejoy was

    perhaps the first to note, this religious and political movement had important economic consequences,

    notably creating a large regional market based on the Caliphate. Finally, since the 1970s research has

    increasingly shown a huge irony: the closing of the Atlantic export market for captives lowered prices

    of slaves within West Africa, and facilitated their use on an increasing scale to produce commodities

    for both overseas and regional markets. We should review the transition debate, and consider what the

    political and economic changes of this period suggest about the long-term dynamics of precolonial

    Africa.

  • 8

    Essential reading

    A. Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa (1973), pp. 124-35. Classic statement of

    transformation thesis about the impact of legitimate commerce.

    R. Law, Introduction to Law (ed.), From Slave Trade to `Legitimate' Commerce: the commercial transition in nineteenth-century West Africa (1995), pp. 1-31.

    P. Lovejoy, Plantations in the economy of the Sokoto Caliphate, Journal of African History 19 (1978), pp. 341-68.

    Further reading

    R. Law, The historiography of the commercial transition in nineteenth-century West Africa, in T. Falola (ed.), African Historiography: essays in honour of Jacob Ade Ajayi (1993), pp. 91-115.

    J. Flint and E.A. McDougall, Economic change in West Africa in the nineteenth century, in J. Ajayi & M. Crowder, History of West Africa, vol. 2, 2nd edition (1987), pp. 379-402. Overview, paying

    attention to events away from the coast.

    R. Law (ed.), From Slave Trade to `Legitimate' Commerce: the commercial transition in nineteenth-

    century West Africa (1995), especially pp. 32-77 (the chapters by Lovejoy & Richardson, & Lynn).

    G. Austin, African business in nineteenth-century West Africa, in A. Jalloh & T. Falola (eds), Black Business and Economic Power (2002), pp. 80-113.

    Background reading

    J. Ajayi & M. Crowder, History of West Africa, vol. 2, 2nd edition (1987), chs 1 & 3. Political history

    of the jihad movements and the Sokoto Caliphate.

    K. Swindell & A. Jeng, Migrants, Credit and Climate: The Gambian Groundnut Trade, 1834-1934

    (2006), pp. 1-99.

    F. Manchuelle, Willing Migrants: Soninke Labor Diasporas, 1848-1960 (1997), pp. 1-92.

    8. STATE BUILDING IN THE PRECOLONIAL NINETEENTH CENTURY: SOUTHERN

    AND EASTERN AFRICA

    In southern Africa, too, the early to mid-nineteenth century saw new waves of state-building, creating

    an apparently new kind of state: based not on extended kinship but on personal ties to a dictatorial

    king. The prototype was Shaka`s Zulu kingdom, whose violent expansion produced a chain reaction of

    state reformation or creation on the same lines, destroying or displacing earlier kingdoms from Natal to

    as far afield as southern Tanzania (the wave of violence known as the mfecane). The Africanist literature of the 1960s-70s (Omer-Cooper especially) depicted Shaka as a great African innovator. A

    generation later, Cobbing denounced both the idea that there had been so much violence, and the

    notion of the African genesis of this process. He argued that such political changes as occurred in

    African polities were responses to European encroachment from the Cape. Cobbing in turn has been

    strongly critiqued, especially by Eldredge, and there remains the question of how far the origins of the

  • 9

    Zulu kingdom, and thereby of the chain reaction that undoubtedly occurred in some form, was a

    response to ecological crisis in the pastoral economy, and commercial opportunities from trade with

    the Portuguese.

    For an East African comparison, particularly interesting is the Great Lakes area, in which a

    long-standing system of kingdoms, notably Buganda, was undergoing significant changes.

    Essential reading

    L. Ngcongco, The mfecane and the rise of new African states, in J. Ajayi (ed.), Africa in the Nineteenth Century until the 1880s (1989), pp. 90-123. (vol VI of the UNESCO General History of

    Africa). French edition LAfrique au XIXe sicle jusque vers les annes 1880. Provides a good introduction.

    J. Cobbing, The mfecane as alibi, Journal of African History 29 (1988), pp. 487-519. Controversial but complicated.

    E. Eldredge, Sources of conflict in Southern Africa, ca.1800-30: the `Mfecane' reconsidered, Journal of African History 33:1 (1992), pp. 1-36. Excellent critical synthesis. Reprinted in Hamilton, Mfecane

    Aftermath (below).

    Further reading

    M. Deflem, Warfare, political leadership, and state formation: the case of the Zulu kingdom, 1808-1879, Ethnology 38:4 (1999), pp. 3791-91. From perspective of theories of state formation.

    C. Hamilton (ed.), The Mfecane Aftermath: reconstructive debates in Southern African history (1995).

    See the reassertion of the earlier orthodoxy by Omer-Cooper (The Mfecane survives its critics, pp. 277-98); the contributions by Wright (pp. 107-21) and Etherington (pp. 13-19, 35-49), both of whom

    are sympathetic to Cobbing; and Parsonss contributions on the knock-on effects of the mfecane in the interior (pp 301-6, 323-49).

    Background reading, including Great Lakes perspectives

    N. Etherington, The Great Treks: The Transformation of Southern Africa, 1815-1854 (2001). A

    revisionist overview within which (perhaps) to place the above debate.

    J-P Chrtien, LAfrique des grands lacs: deux milles ans dhistoire (2000), ch. 3.

    R. Reid, Political Power in Pre-Colonial Buganda: economy, society and warfare in the nineteenth

    century (2002). (For skimming or dipping into).

    9. ECONOMIC CHANGE IN SETTLER COLONIES: THE RISE AND FALL(?) OF THE AFRICAN PEASANTRY

    Themes

    In the 1970s Arrighi and others refuted the proposition that African agriculture in the early colonial

    period had been characterised by a surplus of labour. Instead, they argued that it was African farmers

    who responded first to the emergence of urban markets for grain. They thereby moved from being

  • 10

    subsistence cultivators to peasants, producing partly for their own consumption and partly for sale. However, the administrations of settler colonies responded to calls from European mine-owners and

    settlers by legislating to try to force Africans to offer their labour for sale, rather than their produce.

    Whereas Arrighi and his colleagues believed that these policies were successful, Mosley and others

    have documented the persistence of African production for the market. That raises the question of

    whether, as has been argued, the African rural population became increasingly polarised between a

    surplus-selling elite and a landless poor. We need to consider these issues, and also think about the

    significance of settler agriculture for the origins of modern manufacturing in Africa.

    Essential reading

    G. Arrighi, Labour supplies in historical perspective: a study of the proletarianization of the African peasantry in Rhodesia, Journal of Development Studies 3 (1970), pp. 197-234; reprinted in Arrighi and J. Saul, Essays on the Political Economy of Africa (1973).

    P. Mosley, Agricultural development and government policy in settler economies: Kenya & Southern Rhodesia, 1900-60, Economic History Review 35 (1982), pp. 390-408; and debate with S. Choate in Economic History Review 37 (1984), pp. 409-16.

    Further reading

    I. Phimister, Commodity relations and class formation in the Zimbabwean countryside, 1898-1920, Journal of Peasant Studies 13, 4 (1986), pp. 240-57.

    P. Nyambara, Colonial policy and peasant cotton agriculture in Southern Rhodesia, 1904-1953, International Journal of African Historical Studies 33 (2000), pp. 81-111.

    T. Ranger, The Great Depression and the Zimbabwean peasantry, in his Peasant Consciousness and Guerilla War in Zimbabwe (1985), pp. 54-98.

    T. Kanogo, Squatters and the Roots of Mau Mau: 1905-63 (1987). (For skimming/dipping into, not

    reading from cover to cover).

    10. LABOUR, CAPITAL AND THE STATE IN SOUTH AFRICA: EXPLOITATION AND

    INDUSTRIALIZATION?

    Themes

    The mineral discoveries of the 1860s-80s were a necessary but insufficient condition for South

    Africas transformation from a marginal exporter of wool and wine to a major force in the world market. In 1910 South Africa became effectively independent, under white minority rule. In 1924,

    building on earlier private initiatives, the newly-elected Pact government became one of the first in the

    world to adopt import-substituting industrialization as policy. There has been a long-running debate

    about whether policies of racial monopoly were essential to the growth of the economy, as radicals

    argued, or were a brake upon it, as economic liberals maintained. For this early period we need to

    examine how the mining companies and the state secured an increasing supply of African labour, and

    with what effects. The real wages of black miners in South African gold mining were higher in the

    1890s than they were to be again until the 1970s; despite technological advances which raised output

    per worker in the interim. Were low black wages and job reservation for whites a reflection of the

  • 11

    interests of the mining companies, or of white labour, and did they provide the basis for the emergence

    of an internationally-competitive manufacturing sector?

    Essential reading

    R. Austen, African Economic History (1987), pp. 162-71. South Africa in the comparative context of

    colonial regimes elsewhere in southern and central Africa.

    S. Trapido, South Africa in a comparative study of industrialisation, Journal of Development Studies 7: 3 (1971), pp. 309-20.

    C. Feinstein, An Economic History of South Africa: Conquest, Discrimination and Development

    (2005), pp. 43-142. The fullest and best account: please read as much of it as you can.

    Further reading

    P. Harries, Kinship, ideology and the nature of pre-colonial labour migration, in S. Marks & R. Rathbone (eds), Industrialisation and Social Change in South Africa (1982), pp.142-66.

    C. Van Onselen, Race and class in the South African countryside: cultural osmosis and social relations in the sharecropping economy of Transvaal, American Historical Review 95: 1 (1990), pp. 99-123.

    J. Krikler, White Rising: The 1922 Insurrection and Racial Killing in South Africa (2005), pp. 21-49,

    291-5.

    T. Maloka, Mines and labour migrants in Southern Africa, Journal of Historical Sociology 10: 2 (1997), pp. 213-24

    M. Lipton, Capitalism and Apartheid: South Africa, 1910-1986 (1986 edition), chs 5 & 7.

    .

    Background reading

    N. Worden, The Making of Modern South Africa (4th

    edition, 2007). Excellent short analytical

    narrative, very useful for broad and changing context and for summaries of complex events.

    W. Beinart, Twentieth-century South Africa (1994). Another good general history.

    11. ECONOMIC CHANGE IN PEASANT COLONIES: THE CASH CROP REVOLUTION

    Themes

    This week we analyse the cash-crop revolution in more depth (picking up from week 5). While colonial attempts to coerce Africans into growing more cotton achieved little, where export agriculture

    took off it was the essentially voluntary achievement of African farmers and merchants extending the

    pattern of land-extensive cultivation and selective adoption of exotic crops, already manifested in

    earlier periods. How far does the accumulation of evidence on labour use, food security and

    indigenous entrepreneurship confirm, complement or contradict the retrospective predictions of the vent-for-surplus models? Meanwhile colonial administrations, especially in British West Africa,

  • 12

    fearing the emergence of a landless class, resisted pressures to support or enforce a shift to a free

    market in land which some of their own officials considered the logical corollary of cash crop production.

    Essential reading

    J. Hogendorn, Economic initiative and African cash farming: pre-colonial origins and early colonial developments, in P. Duignan & L. Gann (eds), Colonialism in Africa 1870-1960, vol. 4, The Economics of Colonialism (1975), 283-328. Overview.

    M. Salau, The role of slave labor in groundnut production in early colonial Kano, Journal of African History 51:2 (2010), pp. 147-65.

    J. Tosh, The cash-crop revolution in tropical Africa: an agricultural reappraisal, African Affairs 79: 314 (1980), pp. 79-94. Important environmental critique of the vent-for-surplus approach.

    Further reading

    J. Tosh, Lango agriculture during the early colonial period: land and labour in a cash-crop economy [Uganda], Journal of African History 19 (1978), pp. 415-39.

    A.Isaacman & R. Roberts (eds), Cotton, Colonialism, & Social History in Sub-Saharan Africa (1995),

    ch. 1.

    A. Phillips, The Enigma of Colonialism: British Policy in West Africa (1989), pp. 59-84, 111-12, 118-

    35.

    M. Cowen and R. Shenton, Bankers, peasants, and land in British West Africa 1905-37, Journal of Peasant Studies 19:1 (1991), pp. 26-58.

    Background reading

    A. Hopkins, An Economic History of West Africa (1973), chs 5 & 6. Incisive overviews.

    H. Myint, The Economics of the Developing Countries (1964), ch.3. Clear presentation of the vent-for-

    surplus model.

    C. Harrison, T. Ingawa & S. Martin, The establishment of colonial rule in West Africa, c.1900-1914, in J. Ajayi and M. Crowder (eds), History of West Africa, vol. 2 (2nd ed., 1987), 517-34. Alternative

    overview.

    12. POVERTY AND SOCIAL MOBILITY IN THE EARLY TWENTIETH CENTURY: THE

    DECLINE OF SLAVERY AND AFTER

    Themes

    Arguably the greatest social change of this period in West Africa and parts of East Africa was the

    decline of slavery: often delayed, and uneven in gender and age terms. On its causes, a key question is

    how this process related to both colonial policies and the cash crop revolution. On its effects, we

  • 13

    need to consider the destinies of former slaves, the growth of migrant male wage labour, and the beginnings of urban informal sectors. All this needs to be placed in the context of a demographic

    watershed. There is evidence of population falls in some areas during the early colonial decades, but

    from about the 1920s the general trend was decisively upwards: moving Africa away from its

    traditional labour-scarcity, and potentially making access to land rather than to labour power the basic

    source of poverty. How did the sources, incidence and structure of poverty differ in 1939 or 1945 from

    the situation at the beginning of colonial rule, or indeed as of 1900?

    Essential reading at least one of:

    J. Iliffe, The African Poor: A History (1987), pp. 143-213.

    G. Austin, Cash crops and freedom: export agriculture and the decline of slavery in colonial West Africa, International Review of Social History, 54: 1 (2009), pp.1-37.

    Further reading: perspectives from a range of themes and places

    C. Robertson & I. Berger, Introduction: analyzing class and gender African perspectives, in their (eds), Women and Class in Africa (1986), pp. 3-24.

    B. Fall, Le travail forc en Afrique Occidentale franaise (1900-1946) (1993), pp. 11-52.

    F. Cooper, Decolonization and African Society: the Labor Question in French and British Africa

    (1996), chapter on the International Labour Offices campaign against forced labour.

    S. Bowden, B. Chiripanhura & P. Mosley. Measuring and explaining poverty in six African countries: a long-period approach, Journal of International Development 20: 8 (2008), pp. 1049-79.

    J-G. Deutsch, Emancipation without Abolition in German East Africa, c.1884-1914 (2006).

    S. Doyle, Crisis and Decline in Bunyoro; Population and Environment in Western Uganda 1860-1955

    (2006), 134-63, 210-250. Disease, famine and population.

    D. Ohadike, When the slaves left, owners wept: entrepreneurs and emancipation among the Igbo people, in S. Miers & M. Klein (eds), Slavery and Colonial Rule in Africa (1999), 189-207.

    G. Austin, Labour, Land and Capital in Ghana: From Slavery to Free Labour in Asante, 1807-1956

    (2005), chapters 13, 16, 19.

    13. AFRICAN ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND EUROPEAN MONOPOLISTS: THE BUSINESS

    STRUGGLE IN COLONIAL WEST AFRICA

    Themes

    There was a strongly asymmetric tendency in the trade and services sector of colonial peasant economies: by the 1920s a multitude of mostly small African enterprises, often sole-traders,

    confronted a small number of European firms who often formed cartels. African resistance occurred

    within the market and also through collective action to resist taxation (e.g. the Women Riot in southeast Nigeria), to fight for more equal terms in the market (the cocoa hold-ups in what became

  • 14

    Ghana). Economic nationalism also inspired attempts to adopt Western business structure, in the form

    of the indigenous banking movement in Nigeria. What were the implications of the competitive

    asymmetry for the growth and distribution of income, and how effective was the resistance? Did it

    foreshadow the post-1945 era of political nationalism and decolonization?

    Essential reading

    A. Nwabughuogu, From wealthy entrepreneurs to petty traders: the decline of African middlemen in eastern Nigeria, 1900-1950, Journal of African History 23 (1982), pp. 365-79.

    A. Hopkins, Innovation in a colonial context: African origins of the Nigerian cocoa-farming industry, 1880-1920, in C. Dewey & Hopkins (eds), The Imperial Impact (1978), pp. 83-96 (endnotes at pp. 341-2).

    A. Hopkins, Economic aspects of political movements in Nigeria and in the Gold Coast, 1918-1939, Journal of African History 7 (1966), pp. 133-52.

    J. Miles, Rural protest in the Gold Coast: the cocoa hold-ups, 1908-1938, in C. Dewey and A. Hopkins (eds), The Imperial Impact (London, 1978), pp. 152-70 (endnotes at pp. 353-7).

    Further reading

    O. Georg, La destruction de un rseau dchange prcoloniale : lexample de la Guine, Journal of African History 21 (1980), 467-84.

    O. Ayodeji. Elder Dempster and the shipping trade of Nigeria during the First World War, Journal of African History 33: 2 (1992), pp. 255-71.

    S. Martin, Production and protest: the Women Riot, 1929, in her Palm Oil and Protest: An Economic History of the Ngwa Region, South-eastern Nigeria, 1800-1980 (1988), pp. 106-18.

    G. Austin & C. Uche, Collusion and competition in colonial economies: banking in British West Africa, 1916-1960, Business History Review 81 (2007), pp. 1-26.

    J. Byfield, The Bluest Hands: A Social and Economic History of Women Dyers in Abeokuta (Nigeria),

    1890-1940 (2002). (To dip into).

    14. REVIEW AND REFLECTION