al-muwatta - as a source for the social and economic history of the hijaz

Upload: gumel99

Post on 13-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    1/12

    AL-MUWAA' AS A SOURCE FOR THE SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE HIJAZ

    Author(s): Farhat J. ZiadehReviewed work(s):Source: Islamic Studies, Vol. 18, No. 4 (Winter 1979), pp. 299-309Published by: Islamic Research Institute, International Islamic University, IslamabadStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/20847118.

    Accessed: 19/11/2012 20:16

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    .

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    .

    Islamic Research Institute, International Islamic University, Islamabadis collaborating with JSTOR to

    digitize, preserve and extend access toIslamic Studies.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=iriiiuhttp://www.jstor.org/stable/20847118?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/20847118?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=iriiiu
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    2/12

    AL-MUWATTA'

    AS

    A

    SOURCE

    FOR

    THE

    SOCIAL

    AND

    ECONOMIC

    HISTORY OF

    THE

    HIJAZ

    Farh?t

    J.

    Ziadeh

    It

    has been the

    practice

    among

    modern Islamic and

    Western

    histo

    rians

    to

    depend

    upon

    the

    traditional

    historical

    and

    biographical

    works

    in

    writing the history of pre-Islamic and early Islamic centuries. The gene

    ral

    history

    of

    al-Tabari

    (d.

    310

    A.H.)

    figures

    prominently

    in this

    endeavour,

    and

    so

    do

    later

    historians who followed

    his method of

    recording

    history.

    Earlier

    histories,

    like

    that

    of

    Ya'q?b?

    (d.

    277

    A.H.),

    as

    well

    as

    earlier

    to

    pical

    works

    of

    biographies

    and

    military campaigns,

    like the

    biography

    of

    the

    Prophet by

    Ibn

    Ish?q

    (d.

    151

    A.H.)

    ?

    preserved

    in

    its

    later

    recension

    by

    Ibn

    Hish?m

    (d.

    218

    A.H.)

    ?

    and the

    monumental

    biographical

    dictio

    nary

    of Ibn

    Sa'd

    (d.

    230

    A.H.),

    and

    the

    works

    on

    campaigns

    and

    conquests

    by

    al-W?qidi

    (d.

    207

    A.H.)

    and

    al-Bal?dhur?

    (d.

    279

    A.H.)

    are

    also

    cited.

    Sometimes

    one

    might

    encounter

    a

    reference

    to one

    of the

    main

    compen

    diums

    of

    btadith,

    or

    traditions

    of

    the

    Prophet,

    for the

    methodologies

    ?f both

    sciences

    are

    similar

    if

    not

    identical

    ?

    and

    one,

    history,

    can

    be said

    to

    have

    emanated

    from

    the

    other.

    One

    might

    also

    find

    a

    reference

    to

    one

    of

    the

    administrative

    or

    fiscal

    manuals

    that

    were

    intended,

    for the

    most

    part,

    for the

    edification of

    governmental

    secretaries.

    Even

    one

    might

    find

    a

    reference

    to

    a

    work

    of

    literature

    horror

    of

    horrors

    to

    a

    historian

    ?

    like

    that

    of

    al-Agh?n?.

    But he would

    look

    in

    vain

    for

    any

    reference

    to

    an

    early

    and authentically-attributed work like that of al-Muwattcf byMalik ibn

    Anas

    (d.

    179

    A.H.).

    Several

    reasons

    can

    be

    advanced

    for

    this

    neglect.

    One is

    that

    his

    torians

    have,

    in the

    main,

    been interested

    in

    political

    history,

    and

    works

    of

    law,

    like

    al-Muwatta'f

    admittedly

    do

    not

    quench

    the

    thirst of

    the

    political

    historian.

    Another

    is the

    notion

    that

    most

    works

    of

    Islamic

    law

    are

    casuist

    tic

    by

    nature,

    that

    they

    seem to

    picture

    an

    ideal

    law for

    an

    ideal Islamic

    state divorced

    from

    the

    practical

    considerations

    of

    daily

    life, and,

    therefore,

    that

    they

    do

    not

    reflect

    historical

    reality.

    A

    third

    is that

    the

    methodology

    of

    law

    is different

    from that of

    history

    in that

    it

    does

    not

    entirely depend

    upon

    the verification

    of

    accounts

    through

    isn?d,

    and

    therefore

    a

    historian

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    3/12

    300

    FARHAT

    J. Z1ADEH

    might

    not know what to do with law, or how to handle it

    Finally,

    books

    on

    law

    are

    admittedly

    difficult

    to

    understand

    by

    the

    average

    historian,

    particularly

    in the

    West,

    and

    therefore

    their

    meagre

    fare

    of

    points

    of his

    torical

    interest,

    arrived

    at

    after much

    effort,

    was

    overlooked in

    the

    scurry

    toward

    much

    greener pastures.

    The late Professor

    H.A.

    R.

    Gibb

    used

    to

    lament

    the

    fact

    that works

    on

    Islamic

    law,

    and

    particularly

    works

    on

    fat?wa,

    were

    no

    *

    being

    utilized

    for

    reconstructing

    the

    social

    and economic

    history

    of

    the

    Islamic

    era.

    A work, like al-Muwatta' which is the earliest extant work on Islamic law,

    should

    logically

    be

    among

    the firstworks

    to

    be

    so

    utilized.

    But

    aside

    from

    modern

    works

    on

    Islamic

    law

    and

    legal

    doctrine

    which often

    refer

    to

    al

    Mulatta',

    this

    important

    and

    early

    work,

    as

    far

    as

    I

    know,

    has

    not

    been

    touched

    by

    social

    and

    economic

    historians,

    save

    for

    the

    treatment of

    qir?d

    (commenda)

    in

    a

    work

    by

    A.L.

    Udovitch.1

    The

    question

    might

    well be

    asked

    ?

    Why

    should

    a

    historian

    use

    ai-Mulatta'

    as

    a

    source if

    it be

    true

    that

    all

    legal

    works

    reflect

    an

    ideal

    state of affairs, removed from historical reality? Here we enter upon a

    controversial

    subject

    that

    might require

    several

    papers

    to

    elucidate. Scho

    lars

    are

    agreed,

    however,

    that

    not

    all

    subjects

    of

    the

    law

    were

    theoretical,

    and

    that

    certain

    subjects, particularly

    those

    concerned with

    personal

    status,

    and

    possibly

    civil and

    some

    elements

    of

    commercial

    law,

    have

    been

    applied'

    throughout

    the Islamic

    centuries.

    Besides,

    any

    reader of

    al-Muwatta*

    cannot

    but

    be

    impressed

    by

    its

    practical

    character

    ?

    unlike

    later works

    which

    casuistic

    thinking

    and

    religious

    zeal

    propelled

    into the

    idealistic

    realm.

    It

    is

    obvious

    that

    Malik

    set

    about

    to

    codify

    and

    systematize

    the

    customary law of Medina and to give an account of law and jurisprudence

    according

    to

    the

    consensus

    (ijmfr)

    and

    traditional

    practice

    (sunnah)

    of

    Medina.2

    His

    use

    of

    the

    word

    "sunnah"

    seems

    to

    have

    been

    different

    from

    its later

    use

    as

    the

    model

    sayings

    or

    behaviour

    of

    the

    Prophet.

    Pro

    fessor

    Amin

    al-Khawli

    rightly

    observes

    about sunnah:

    "We

    see

    him

    using

    it

    in

    al-Muwatta'

    for

    a

    meaning

    very

    near

    to

    its

    linguistic

    meaning,

    i.e.,

    "the

    method,"

    "the

    way,"

    as

    when

    he

    says:

    'the

    sunnah

    with

    us

    concerning

    mus?q?t

    (a

    contract

    of

    partnership involving

    trees

    and

    labour)

    is that

    it

    applies

    to

    date

    palms,

    grape

    vines,

    olive

    trees,

    etc'_or

    he

    might

    mean

    by

    sunnah the "method" and

    "way"

    of the 'ulama' as when he

    says:

    'our

    gen

    erally

    agreed

    practice

    (al-amr

    al-mujtama6 'alayh

    Andana)

    and the

    sunn&h

    on

    which

    people

    do

    not

    differ

    (al-sunnah

    aliati

    l?

    ikhtil?f lh?)

    and that

    which

    I

    attained

    from

    the 'ulamS

    in

    our

    city (alladhi

    adrakt

    'alayh

    ahi

    ai-Um

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    4/12

    al-muwatta'

    as

    a

    source

    301

    bi-baladina)

    that the Muslim does not inherit from the non-Muslim.'"3.

    Actually,

    al-Muwaffa'

    abounds

    in

    expressions

    just

    quoted

    and in

    others

    like

    the

    "practice"

    (al-amai),

    "our

    practice"

    (al-amr

    aa

    a)

    which

    point

    to

    an

    actu al

    practice

    that

    is both

    practical

    and

    accepted.4

    Al-Muwatta\

    then,

    can

    be

    depended

    upon

    to

    reflect

    an

    actual

    state

    of affair

    in

    most

    instances.

    It

    can

    also,

    through

    allusions

    to

    pre-Islamic

    practices,

    reflect

    certain

    aspects

    of

    life

    of

    the

    pre-Islamic

    period

    as

    well.

    Its

    cautious

    use

    by

    a

    historian

    as

    a

    historical

    source

    can

    therefore

    be

    warran

    ted. What I shall do in the

    following

    pages

    is to

    present

    the results of

    soundings

    I

    made

    while

    reading

    this

    work

    for

    pieces

    of

    information that

    might

    be

    of

    significance

    to

    the social

    and

    economic

    historian

    as

    well

    as

    to

    those

    interested

    in

    historical

    anthropology.

    Economic

    Information:

    As

    can

    be

    expected

    economic

    life

    should

    figure

    prominently

    in

    a

    law

    manual

    that is

    primarily

    concerned

    with

    transac

    tions

    between

    individuals,

    with

    an

    eye

    to

    having

    them

    adhere

    to

    religious

    norms,

    particularly

    those

    against

    usury,

    and

    with

    questions

    of

    taxation.

    In

    dealing

    with

    legal

    questions,

    al-Muwatta'

    presents

    ?

    as

    it

    were

    ?

    a

    lot

    of

    economic

    information

    as

    a

    by-product.

    We

    shall

    take

    up

    some

    sound

    ings

    in

    the

    law

    of

    taxation

    first

    before

    going

    on

    to

    the

    more

    complicated

    matters

    of

    contract

    law

    and

    commercial

    dealings.

    In

    truth

    all

    the

    sections

    on

    almsgiving

    (zak?t)

    are

    important

    because

    they

    give

    us

    a

    fairly

    clear

    picture

    as

    to

    the

    agricultural

    activity

    and

    animal

    husbandry

    at

    the

    time.

    We

    can

    know,

    for

    instance,

    what kind

    of

    cereals

    and legumes were being planted: Malik said, "Cereals (and legumes) sub

    ject

    to

    zak?t

    are:

    wheat,

    barley,

    thin-husked

    barley (suit),

    millet

    (dhurah),

    another

    millet

    (dukhri),

    rice,

    lentils,

    peas

    (julub?n),

    beans

    (l?biya)

    and

    sesame

    (juljul?n).5

    Also

    we

    can

    know

    the

    fruit

    trees

    grown,

    as

    these

    are

    mentioned

    in connection

    with taxable

    or

    nontaxable

    products.

    Aside

    from

    well-known

    fruits like

    dates,

    grapes, figs,

    etc.,

    we

    encounter

    pome

    granites

    and

    peaches

    (firsik)6.

    In

    the

    field

    of

    animal

    husbandry

    al-Muwatta'

    documents

    the

    practice

    of

    sheep or goat owners grouping their fllocks under the supervision of a single

    shepherd.

    Malik

    says,

    "If

    the

    shepherd

    be

    one,

    the stud

    one,

    the

    pastur

    age

    one,

    and

    the

    water-bucket

    one,

    then

    the

    twomen

    (owners

    of

    the

    flocks)

    are

    associates

    (khallf)

    even

    though

    each

    one

    of them differentiates

    his

    pro

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    5/12

    302

    FARHAT

    J. ZIADEH

    perty

    from that of the other."7 This becomes important for purposes of

    taxation,

    for

    such

    a

    combined

    flock

    is

    treated

    as

    one

    flock

    and

    not

    as

    sepa

    rate

    flocks.

    Likewise

    separate

    flocks should

    not

    be

    grouped together

    if

    it

    becomes

    advantageous

    to

    their

    owners

    ?

    for

    tax

    purposes

    ?

    to

    do

    so.

    Regarding

    this

    human

    failing

    of

    evasion

    of

    taxation the

    Caliph

    'Umar

    said,

    "What

    is

    separate

    should

    not

    be

    grouped together,

    and

    what

    is

    grouped

    together

    should

    not

    be

    separated."

    In

    commenting

    on

    this

    saying

    M?lik

    says,

    "This

    refers

    to

    the

    owners

    of

    livestock-(For instance)

    three

    owners,

    each owning forty goats,

    are

    legally obligated

    to

    pay

    zak?t.

    (An

    owner

    of

    a

    flock

    consisting

    of

    at last

    40

    sheep

    but

    not

    more

    than

    120

    sheep

    deli

    vers

    one

    sheeps

    as

    zak?t).

    But

    when

    the

    tax

    collector shows

    up

    they group

    them

    together

    so

    as

    to

    deliver

    only

    one

    goat-Or

    the

    two

    associates

    (khalit)

    each

    owning

    101

    goats,

    and thus

    liable

    to

    deliver

    together

    3

    goats,

    separate

    their

    flocks

    when

    the

    tax

    collector

    approaches

    so as

    to

    make

    each

    liable

    for

    only

    one

    goat.

    Such

    practice

    was

    prohibited."8

    Another

    bit

    of

    information

    ragarding

    taxation

    is that

    Christians

    from Iraq (Nabat),

    and

    possibly

    from

    Syria,

    were

    in

    the habit

    of

    trading

    in

    the

    market-place

    of

    Medina

    from

    pre-Islamic

    times

    until

    at

    least

    the

    time

    of

    'Umar,

    and

    paid

    taxes

    there.

    Malik

    reports

    on

    the

    authority

    of Ibn

    Shih?b

    on

    the

    authority

    of al-S?'ib

    ibn Yaz?d

    that

    the

    latter

    said,

    "I

    was

    a

    young

    man

    assisting

    "Abd

    Allah ibn

    'Utbah

    ibn Mas'?d

    (overseeing)

    the

    market-place

    of Medina

    in

    the time

    of

    'Umar

    ibn

    al-Khatt?b.

    We

    used

    to take

    from

    the

    Nabat

    one

    tenth"-Malik

    asked ibn

    Shih?b

    as

    to

    the

    justification

    for

    that

    practice

    and he

    answered,

    "That

    used

    to

    be taken

    from

    them

    in

    pre-Islamic

    times,

    and

    so

    'Umar

    charged

    them

    with it

    ".9

    The

    laws

    of

    sale

    and

    commerce,

    however,

    yield

    most

    of

    the informa

    tion

    on

    economic

    matters;

    and

    here

    the

    regulatory

    force

    seems

    to

    be

    the

    doctrine

    against

    usury.

    The

    Prophet,

    for

    instance,

    prohibited

    a

    practice

    that

    had

    been

    prevalent

    previously,

    known

    as

    earnest-money

    sale

    (bay'

    al-urb?n).

    M?lik describes

    it

    thus:

    "When

    a

    man

    buys

    a

    slave

    or

    rents

    a mount

    and

    then

    says

    to

    the

    person

    he

    bought

    or

    rented

    from:

    I

    give

    you

    one

    din?r

    or

    one

    dirham,

    or more

    or

    less,

    on

    the

    condition

    that

    if

    I

    take

    delivery

    of

    the

    thing

    or

    ride what

    I

    rented,

    then what

    I

    advanced

    to

    you

    becomes part of the sale price or the rent of themount, but if I go back

    on

    the

    sale

    or

    rent,

    then

    what

    I

    advanced

    becomes

    yours

    without

    anything

    in

    return."10

    As

    can

    be

    seen,

    this

    is

    a

    kind

    of

    option

    known

    toother

    societies,

    but it

    was

    prohibited

    in

    Islam

    because of

    an

    "unjustifiable

    increase"

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    6/12

    ?l-muwatta'

    as

    a

    source

    303

    (riba),

    since

    something

    was

    gained

    without a consideration. The fact that

    some

    people

    were

    willing

    to

    pay

    for

    an

    option

    reflects

    a

    fairly

    advanced

    stage

    of

    commercial

    dealings.

    An

    account

    about the

    prohibition

    of

    usury

    in

    another

    instance

    yields

    information

    on

    a

    still

    more

    interesting

    economic

    institution,

    namely

    that

    of

    dealing

    with

    "futures,"

    similar

    to

    that

    of the

    Chicago

    Commodities

    Market.

    It

    seems that

    when

    Marw?n

    ibn al-Hakam

    was

    the

    governor

    of

    Medina during the caliphate of the first Umayyad caliph, Mu'?wiyah

    (41-60 A.H.)

    certain

    documents

    (sukuk)

    were

    assigned

    to

    the

    people

    of

    the

    city

    entitling

    hem

    to

    food-stuffs

    hat

    were

    being

    brought

    to

    the

    Hijaz

    (doubtless

    as

    khar?j

    and

    probably

    from

    Egypt)

    and

    collected at

    a

    place

    called

    al-J?'r

    at the seashore.

    The

    people

    of

    Medina

    started

    trading

    with

    these

    documents

    before

    they

    actually

    received their

    entitlements of

    food

    stuffs

    a

    practice

    smacking

    of

    risk

    or

    even

    rib?

    if the

    exchange

    involved

    unequal

    amounts.

    So

    Zayd

    ibn

    Th?bit

    and another

    Companion

    of

    the

    Prophet

    called

    on

    Marw?n and

    said,

    "Do

    you,

    O

    Marw?n,

    consider

    rib?

    eales

    as

    legitimate?"

    "I take

    refuge

    inGod

    (from

    that)"

    he

    said,

    "and

    what

    is

    that?"

    They

    said,

    "These

    suk?k

    are

    being bought

    and

    sold

    be

    fore

    the

    receipt

    of

    their

    equivalence."

    Whereupon

    Marw?n

    sent

    his

    guards

    to track

    down

    these

    documents,

    to remove

    them

    from

    the

    hands

    of

    their

    holders

    and

    to

    return

    them

    to

    their

    original

    owners.11

    As

    is

    well-known,

    risk

    (gharar),

    no

    less

    than

    rib?,

    might

    vitiate

    a

    contract.

    The

    Prophet

    is

    reported

    to

    have

    prohibited

    the

    practices

    of

    mul?masah

    and

    mun?badhah. M?lik

    defines

    them

    thus:

    Mul?masah is

    when

    a

    man

    touches

    or

    feels

    (yalmas)

    a

    garment,

    but

    does

    not

    unfold

    it

    nor

    ascertain

    (its

    character),

    and

    mun?badhah is

    when

    a

    man

    throws

    to

    another

    (yanbidh)

    a

    garment

    (in

    exchange

    for)

    a

    garment

    that

    the

    othei

    throws

    to

    him

    without

    both

    of them

    examining

    them.

    He therefore

    says

    that

    t is

    not

    permissible

    o

    sell

    Persian

    mantle

    (s?j

    or

    faylas?n)

    which

    is

    inside

    its

    cover

    or

    a

    Coptic

    garment

    in its fold unless

    they

    are

    unfolded

    and their

    inside

    is

    seen,

    because

    their

    sale

    (in

    their folded

    state)

    is

    a

    sale

    of

    risk.1? M?lik could not, however, disallow

    the

    well-established practice

    of

    selling

    whole

    bales

    of

    goods

    on

    the

    basis

    of

    their

    description

    in

    an

    ac

    companying;

    catalogue

    or

    list of

    contents

    (barn?maj),

    without

    actually

    unfolding

    them,

    for

    then it

    would

    become

    impossible

    to

    conduct

    wholesale

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    7/12

    304

    FARHAT

    J.

    ZIADEH

    trade. He, therefore, says, "The sale of bales

    according

    to the

    barnamaj

    is

    different

    from

    the

    sale

    of

    a

    Persian

    mantle

    in its

    cover or a

    garment

    in

    its

    fold

    ..

    .

    The difference

    between

    them

    is

    (based

    on)

    the

    actual

    practice

    and

    the

    knowledge

    of that

    in

    the

    hearts

    of

    men

    ..

    .

    nd that

    it

    continues

    to

    be

    among

    the

    allowable

    sales

    among

    the

    people

    ..

    .

    because

    the sale

    of bales

    according

    to

    the

    barnamaj,

    without

    unfolding,

    is

    not

    intended

    as a

    risk and

    has

    no

    similarity

    to

    mul?masah".1*

    Thus

    the

    legal

    provision

    against

    risk

    in

    al-Muwa\tay

    was

    able

    to

    inform

    us

    about the extensive

    whole

    sale trade

    in the

    Hijaz

    at

    the time.

    Similarly

    the

    legal

    provision

    about

    the

    permissibility

    of

    exchanging

    goods

    for

    goods

    without

    violating

    the doctrine

    against

    risk

    yields

    much

    information

    about

    the

    types

    of

    garments,

    waist-wrappers,

    and

    pieces

    of

    cloth

    being

    imported

    into

    Hijaz

    at

    the

    time.

    We

    read

    of

    garments

    from

    the

    villages

    of

    Shat?,

    Itr?b,

    and

    Q?s

    in

    Egypt

    as

    well

    as

    those from Herat

    in

    Khurasan

    (Afghanistan)

    and

    Merv

    in

    Central Asia.

    Likewise

    we

    read

    of

    waist-wrappers

    (mal?frif)

    and

    pieces

    of

    cloth

    (shaq?'iq)

    from

    Yemen14.

    A

    seemingly

    simple

    account

    about

    the conduct

    of

    trade

    by

    means

    of

    a

    partnership

    of

    capital

    and

    labour

    (qir?d)

    or

    commenda

    might

    yield

    informa

    tion about

    a

    variety

    of other

    topics.

    Malik

    relates

    that

    'Abd

    Aliah and

    'Ub

    ?yd

    Allah,

    the

    sons

    of

    Caliph

    'Umar set

    out

    with

    an

    army

    to

    Iraq.

    On their

    way

    back

    they passed

    by

    Abn

    M?sa

    al-Ash'ari,

    the "emir

    of

    Basrah,"

    who

    welcomed

    them

    and

    asked

    if he

    could be of

    benefit

    to

    them

    in

    any

    way.

    Then

    he

    said,

    "Yes,

    indeed.

    I

    have

    here funds of

    God's

    property

    (khar?j

    ?r

    j?zy?h)

    that

    I

    want

    to

    send

    to

    the

    Commander

    of

    the

    Faithful.

    I

    shall

    lend these

    funds

    to

    you,

    then

    you buy

    with

    them

    goods

    from

    Iraq

    that

    you

    will

    sell

    inMedina.

    Whereupon

    you

    deliver

    the

    capital

    to

    the

    Commander

    of

    the

    Faithful

    and

    you

    keep

    the

    profit."

    They agreed

    to

    this

    arrangement,

    and

    Abu

    M?sa

    wrote to

    'Umar

    to

    take the

    capital

    from

    them.

    Upon

    arrival

    inMedina

    they

    sold the

    goods

    and

    made

    profit.

    When

    they

    came to

    pay

    the

    capital

    to

    'Umar

    he

    asked,

    "Did

    (Abu

    M?sa)

    lend

    money

    to

    the

    entire

    army

    ?s

    he

    lent

    to

    you?"

    They

    said,

    "No.

    'Umar

    then

    said

    "He

    lent

    it

    to

    you

    because

    you

    are

    the

    sons

    of

    the

    Commander of the

    Faithful.

    'Hand

    over

    the

    capital

    and the

    profit "..

    .

    .Then

    some

    arguments

    ensued

    between 'Ubayd Allah and his father about the proper course of action,

    whereupon

    a

    man

    sitting

    by suggested

    that the

    transaction

    be

    considered

    ?

    qir?tf.

    'Umar

    agreed;

    he

    took

    the

    capital

    and

    half of the

    profits,

    while

    the

    other

    half

    was

    left

    to

    his

    sons.15

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    8/12

    al-muwatta'

    as

    a

    source

    305

    Now,

    the

    foregoing

    account

    undoubtedly

    proves

    that the contract

    of

    qir??thad-been

    well-known

    by

    the time of

    'Umar,

    and

    presumably

    must

    have

    figured

    prominently

    in the

    Meccan

    trade before Islam.16 In

    the

    second

    place,

    the

    account

    supports

    the

    view

    that

    Ab?

    M?sa

    was

    a

    governor

    (amir)

    and

    not

    a

    judge (q??li)

    to

    whom

    *

    Umar

    was

    said

    to

    have

    addressed

    his

    famous

    instructions,

    and

    that

    in

    all

    probability

    the

    institution

    of

    the

    judiciary

    appeared

    later

    during

    the

    Umayyad

    administration

    ?

    unless

    of

    course

    one

    is

    to

    understand

    that

    at

    that

    early

    date the

    function

    of

    a

    gover

    nor

    and

    that

    of

    a

    judge

    were

    indistinguishable.17

    In

    the

    third

    place,

    it

    is

    apparent

    from

    the

    account

    that

    the

    processes

    of

    administration

    were

    at

    the

    time

    still unsettled

    and

    in

    a

    rather

    primitive

    and

    chaotic

    form,

    whereby

    a

    governor

    would

    allow

    himself

    to

    lend

    public

    money

    to

    be

    used

    in

    a

    commer

    cial

    venture

    Social

    and

    Anthropological

    Information

    Here

    again

    al-Muwafta'

    can

    be of

    immense value

    to

    the

    social his

    torian.

    Information

    on

    slavery,

    on

    preemption

    (shuf'ah),

    on

    witchcraft,

    and

    on

    funeral

    and

    burial

    practices

    can

    be

    gleaned

    from

    its

    legal

    contents.

    It

    has

    been

    assumed

    that slaves

    in Arabia

    were

    employed only

    in

    domestic

    service

    ?

    including

    chores

    in

    attending

    animals

    ?

    or

    in

    com

    mercia

    enterprises.

    Butin

    Medina,

    where date

    plantations

    were

    plentiful,

    slaves

    were

    employed

    in

    cultivation

    as

    well.

    In

    fact these

    slaves

    seem

    to

    have

    been attached

    to

    the

    plantations

    in

    the

    same

    way

    that

    slaves

    were

    an

    integral

    part

    of the

    plantations

    in

    the

    American

    South

    prior

    to

    the

    Civil

    War.

    This is

    evident

    from

    a

    legal provision concerning

    slaves in

    a

    contract

    of

    trees and labour

    (mus?q?t).

    M?lik

    says,

    "The best

    that has

    been

    heard

    concerning

    slave

    labourers

    in

    a

    contract

    of

    mus?q?t

    where the

    labour

    con

    tractor

    makes

    them

    a

    condition

    binding

    on

    the

    owner

    of

    the

    capital

    (asl,

    meaning

    plantation)

    is that

    it is

    perfectly

    legal,

    because

    they

    are

    the

    labourers

    of the

    capital,

    and

    therefore,

    are

    on

    the

    same

    footing

    as

    the

    capital

    ...

    If

    a

    slave should

    die,

    absent

    himself,

    or

    fall

    sick,

    it is the

    duty

    of

    the

    owner

    of the

    capital

    to

    replace

    him."18

    When slaves are manumitted a special relationship called walff

    continues

    to

    exist

    between

    the

    previous

    master

    and the freed

    slave.

    Apart

    from the

    sentiments of

    loyalty

    and

    support

    that

    the term

    implies,

    and

    that

    are

    so

    important

    in

    a

    society

    that is

    organized

    on

    kinship

    groups,

    whether

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    9/12

    306

    FARHAT

    J.

    ZIADEH

    actual or fictional, wa?ff can be financially important in that by virtue of

    his

    act

    of manumission

    the

    master

    acquires

    the

    right

    to

    inherit

    from

    his

    freedman

    if

    the

    latter dies

    without

    any

    heirs

    by

    blood.19

    Still,

    this

    right

    to

    wala*

    was not

    a

    proprietary right

    to

    be

    bought

    or

    sold

    or

    given

    as

    a

    gift;

    it

    was

    akin

    to

    a

    family

    relationship

    that

    was

    inalienable. The

    Prophet

    was

    reported

    to

    have

    said that

    walff

    belonged

    to

    the

    manumitter,

    and he

    prohibited

    the

    sale

    of walff

    or

    giving

    it

    as a

    gift.20

    But

    what

    bcomes

    of

    walS when

    the

    manumitter dies? Does

    it

    devolve

    upon

    the

    heirs

    in

    the

    same

    way

    that

    his

    estate

    does?

    It is

    indicative

    of

    the

    personal relationship

    that

    this

    institution

    suggests

    as

    opposed

    to

    a

    proprietary

    relationship

    ?

    that the

    devolution

    of

    wal?'

    was

    held

    to

    be

    different

    from

    that

    of

    the

    general

    estate of

    the

    deceased,

    and

    that it

    devolved

    not to

    the heirs

    at

    law

    but

    to

    the

    people

    who

    were

    held

    nearest

    to

    the

    ex-slaves

    in

    a

    personal

    way.

    Malik

    illustrates

    this

    from

    an

    actual

    case.

    Several

    people

    from

    the

    tribe of

    Juhaynah,

    near

    Medina,

    and several

    others from

    the

    clan of

    Bani

    al-fl?rith

    of

    al-Khazraj

    tribe

    of

    Medina

    submitted

    a

    dispute

    to

    Ab?n

    ibn

    'Uthman.21

    A

    woman

    from

    Juhaynah

    was

    married

    to

    one

    Ibrahim ibn

    Kulayb

    of

    Bani

    al-H?rith. When she died she left property and ex-slaves (maw?li).

    Her

    son

    inherited her

    estate. But

    the

    son soon

    died,

    and

    his

    heirs

    at

    law

    said,

    "the

    wal?'

    of the

    ex-slaves

    belongs

    to

    us;

    her

    son

    had

    acquired

    it,"

    and

    the

    people

    from

    Juhayuah

    said,

    "Not

    so;

    they

    were

    the

    ex-slaves

    of

    our

    "daughter"

    (??bibatun?)\

    when

    her

    son

    died

    we

    acquired

    their

    wal?\

    and

    we

    (therefore)

    will

    be

    their

    heirs."

    Ab?n

    gave

    judgment

    in

    favor

    of the

    people

    of

    Juhaynah22,

    presumably

    because there

    was no

    personal

    rela

    tionship

    or

    "kinship"

    between

    the son's

    heirs,

    who

    must

    have

    been

    colla

    terals,

    and

    the

    ex-slaves,

    whereas

    such

    a

    relationship

    existed

    between

    the

    ex-slaves and the blood relatives of the women.

    An

    institution

    which

    has had

    a

    chequered

    history

    in

    Islam

    and

    which

    still

    holds

    sway

    in

    some

    Islamic

    countries

    is that of

    preemption

    (shuf'ah)

    whereby

    a

    person

    would substitute himself for the

    buyer

    in

    a

    completed

    sale

    of real

    property.

    As

    fully

    developed

    this institution would

    give

    the

    right

    of

    substitution

    to

    the

    following

    persons

    in order: the

    co-owner,

    the

    owner

    of

    a

    servitude

    in the

    property,

    and

    the

    owner

    of

    an

    adjoining

    pro

    perty.23 Doubtless, the basic reason for this institution is the natural

    desire

    to

    keep

    an

    outsider

    or

    a

    stranger

    out

    of

    a

    family property

    or

    a

    tightly

    knit

    neighbourhood.

    This

    desire

    must

    have

    become

    gradually

    stranger

    with

    the

    passage

    of

    time,

    the

    spread

    of

    Islam,

    and

    the

    development

    of

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    10/12

    al-muwatta'

    as

    a

    source

    307

    cosmopolitan

    centres with an

    admixture

    of

    populations

    of

    many

    races.

    Later

    Hanafi

    works

    devote

    large

    sections

    to

    the

    legal

    incidents

    of

    this

    ins

    titution

    and

    to

    the

    strict

    procedure

    to

    be

    followed

    if

    a

    claimant

    is

    to

    be

    successful.

    But

    al-Muwafta*

    devotes

    only

    four

    pages

    to

    it,

    and

    what

    is

    more,

    it

    limits the

    right

    of

    preemption

    to

    the

    co-owner.24

    There

    is

    no

    mention

    of

    a

    khalff

    ?

    or

    owner

    of

    a

    servitude

    in

    the

    property

    ?

    or

    of

    a

    neighbour.

    A

    social

    historian

    should

    not

    be

    surprised

    at

    this. Medina's

    milieu is

    mostly

    Arab

    ?

    except

    for

    traders,

    singers,

    slaves

    and ex-slaves

    etc., and the

    owners of real

    property

    are

    still the old families of Medina.

    The need

    for

    a

    well-developed

    doctrine of

    preemption

    to

    keep strangers

    out

    had

    not

    arisen

    as

    it

    had

    in

    Iraq,

    with

    its

    cosmopolitan

    population,

    where

    Hanafi

    law

    was

    being

    expounded.

    Other

    questions

    of

    anthropological

    interest

    that

    illuminate

    the

    Hijazi

    scene for

    the social historian deal

    with funeral

    and

    burial

    practices.

    Malik

    reports

    that

    Ab?

    Hurayrah,

    a

    well-known

    Companion

    of

    the

    Prophet,

    "forbade

    that

    he

    be

    followed

    by

    fire

    after

    his

    death,"

    and

    Malik

    himself

    censures

    this

    practice.25

    Now,

    what

    is

    this

    fire?

    Was

    it

    a

    pre-Islamic

    heathen

    practice

    that

    was

    continued

    for

    a

    brief

    time

    during

    Islam,

    or

    was

    it

    a

    Zoroastrian

    practice

    that

    left its

    traces

    in

    Arabia? Other

    surces

    have

    no

    explanation

    for

    this

    enigmatic

    reference.

    In

    burial

    practices

    there

    seems

    to

    have been

    a

    difference

    between

    those

    of

    Mecca and

    those of

    Medina

    going

    back into

    pre-Islamic

    times. This

    is

    apparent

    in

    the

    report

    given

    by

    M?lik

    ?

    and doubtless

    by

    many

    badlth

    and

    slrah

    works

    ?

    about

    the

    interment

    of

    the

    Prophet. According

    to

    this

    report

    there

    were

    in

    Medina two men who buried the dead, one of whom prepared burial

    niches

    (yalbad),

    while

    the

    other

    did

    not

    so

    prepare.

    They

    (the

    Muslims)

    said.

    "Whoever

    comes

    first

    will

    be

    allowed

    to

    follow his

    own

    practice."

    The

    man

    who

    prepared

    niches

    came

    first,

    so

    he

    prepared

    a

    niche for the

    Messenger

    of

    God.26 In

    commenting

    on

    this

    text,

    al-Suy?fi

    says

    that

    one

    man

    was

    from

    Mecca where the

    practice

    was

    to

    dig

    a

    ditch

    (shaqq),

    and

    the

    other,

    who

    prepared

    the tomb for

    the

    Prophet,

    was

    from

    Medina

    where

    the

    practice

    was

    to

    build

    niches.27

    Why

    the

    difference

    between

    the two

    Hijazi

    cities?

    One

    can

    speculate

    that

    Medina,

    being

    an

    oasis,

    had

    a

    more

    settled

    existence going back in time; its tombs, therefore, reflected this permanence

    and settlement.

    Mecca,

    on

    the

    other

    hand,

    even

    though

    engaged

    in

    com

    merce,

    was

    very

    close

    to

    Bedouin

    life

    where

    the

    more

    austere

    nomadic

    existence

    would

    permit

    only

    a

    ditch

    in

    the

    ground

    for

    burying

    the

    dead.

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    11/12

    308

    FARHAT J.

    ZIADEH

    finally,

    matters

    of

    witchcraft,

    and

    popular

    beliefs

    might

    be

    of

    interest

    to

    the

    social historian.

    Abhorrence

    of witchcraft

    must

    have

    been

    justas

    strong

    in

    early

    Islam

    as

    it

    was

    in

    Salem,

    Massachusetts,

    in

    Colonial

    Ame

    rica,

    with similar

    results.

    Malik

    reports

    that

    Hafsah,

    the

    wife

    of

    the

    Prophet,

    ordered the

    killing

    of

    a

    slave

    girl

    she

    had

    tentatively

    freed

    (with

    freedom

    to

    take

    effect

    after Hafsah's

    death)

    because

    the slave

    girl

    had

    prac

    ticed witchcraft

    against

    her.

    He

    defines

    a

    witch

    or

    sorcerer

    as a

    person

    who himself

    practices

    witchcraft

    and

    not

    a

    person

    who

    procures

    another

    so to do. He further opines that a witch or sorcerer should be killed.28

    It

    is

    obvious that

    the

    motive

    of the

    supposed

    witch

    in

    Hafsah's

    case was

    to

    cause

    the

    death

    of

    Hafsah

    so

    that

    she would

    hasten

    her

    freedom after

    such

    death,

    but is

    every

    practice

    of

    witchcraft,

    short

    of

    causing

    death,

    to

    be

    punished

    by

    death?

    The

    Commentators

    do

    not

    enlighten

    us on

    that,

    nor

    do

    we

    know

    of other

    instances where

    witches

    were

    killed.

    As

    can

    be

    seen,

    these

    soundings

    in

    al-Muwatta'

    can

    produce

    some

    substantial

    information

    and

    some

    information

    which is

    tantalizing

    because

    of

    its

    brevity.

    But

    in

    either

    case

    such

    information,

    added

    sometimes

    to

    information

    from other

    sources,

    might

    be

    very

    valuable

    and

    might

    fill

    some

    gaps

    in

    our

    understanding

    of

    the

    social

    and

    economic

    history

    of

    the

    Hijaz.

    NOTES

    1.

    Partnership

    nd

    Profit

    in

    Medieval

    Islam,

    Princeton,

    1970,

    pp.

    16,

    142-143,

    175

    et

    passim.

    For

    his

    summary

    n

    English

    of

    the

    "Book of

    Qir??l"

    of

    al-Muwafta'

    see

    Speculum

    37

    (1962),

    pp.

    204-207.

    2.

    Joseph

    Schacht, E.I.,

    1st ed.

    III,

    pp.

    206-207.

    3.

    Amin

    al-Khawli,Malik,

    Tar

    amah

    Muharrarah,

    Cairo

    1951,

    Vol.

    Ill,

    p.

    705.

    4

    See; Joseph

    Schacht,

    Origins

    of

    Muhammadan

    Jurisprudence,

    xford,

    1950,

    pp.

    62*63.

    5.

    M?lik ihn

    Anas,

    al-Muwaffa'mth

    commentary

    ntitled

    anwtr

    l-ffaw?lik

    by

    'Abd

    al-Rahm?n

    a?-Suy?ti, airo, 1951,

    Vol.

    I,

    p.

    203.

    6.

    Ibid.,

    p.

    206.

    7.

    Ibid.,

    p.

    198.

    8.

    Ibid.,

    pp..

    198-199.

    9.

    Ibid.,

    p.

    208.

    10.

    Ibid.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p,

    46.

    This content downloaded by the authorized user from 192.168.52.62 on Mon, 19 Nov 2012 20:16:02 PMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/27/2019 Al-muwatta - As a Source for the Social and Economic History of the Hijaz

    12/12

    al-muwatta'

    as

    a

    source

    309

    11.

    Ibid.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p.

    63,

    and

    Mubammad

    al-Zurq?ni,

    Shark

    Muwafta'

    aUIm?m

    Malik,

    Cairo,

    1961,

    Vol.

    IV,

    p.

    239.

    12.

    Zurq?ni,

    Vol.

    IV,

    p.

    276.

    13.

    Ibid.

    14. M?lik

    ibn

    Anas,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p.

    72,

    and

    Zurq?ni,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    IV,

    p.

    263.

    15. M?lik

    ibn

    Anas,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p.

    88.

    16.

    See

    Udovitch,

    op.

    cit.,

    pp.

    172-173 for

    other

    instances

    where

    qir?i

    was

    employed.

    17.

    On

    these

    points,

    see

    D.S.

    Margoliouth,

    'Omar's

    Instructions

    to

    the

    Q??to."

    J.R.A.S.

    Vol.42

    (1910)

    pp.

    307-326,

    and E.

    Tyan,

    Histoire de

    L'Organisation

    Judiciaire

    en

    Pays

    d'Islam,

    Paris, 1938,

    Vol.

    I, pp.

    104-113.

    For

    an

    instance where

    Marw?n, the mayyad governor fMedina acted also as judge, seeM?lik ibnAnas,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p.

    112.

    18.

    Ibid.,

    pp.

    101-102.

    19. See

    N.

    J.

    Coulson,

    Succession

    in

    the

    uslim

    Family,

    Cambridge,

    1971,

    p.

    10.

    n.

    1

    20.

    M?lik ibn

    Anas.,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    2,

    p.

    143.

    21. He

    had

    been

    appointed

    governor

    of

    Medina

    by

    the

    Umayyad Caliph

    'Abdulmalik

    ibn

    Marw?n.

    He

    died

    in

    105A.H.

    22.

    M?lik

    ibn

    Anas,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p.

    145.

    23.

    See

    Joseph chacht,

    An

    Introduction

    o

    slamic

    Law,

    Oxford, 1964,

    p.

    142.

    24.

    M?lik

    ibn

    Anas,

    op.

    cit.,

    Vol.

    II,

    pp.

    103-106, specially

    105.

    25. Ibid., Vol. I, p. 176.

    25.

    Ibid.,

    Vol.

    I,

    p.

    180.

    27.

    Ibid.

    28.

    Ibid.,

    Vol.

    II,

    p.

    193.