analysing public-private partnership - au...

88
DEPARTMENT OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION BUSINESS AND SOCIAL SCIENCES AARHUS UNIVERSITY Analysing Public-Private Partnership Master thesis MSc in Finance and International Business Author: Jurgita Jakutyte Student ID: JJ91185 Academic supervisor: Jingkun Li September, 2012

Upload: trinhxuyen

Post on 19-Mar-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

DEPARTMENT OF BUSINESS ADMINISTRATION

BUSINESS AND SOCIAL SCIENCES

AARHUS UNIVERSITY

Analysing Public-Private Partnership

Master thesis

MSc in Finance and International Business

Author: Jurgita Jakutyte

Student ID: JJ91185

Academic supervisor: Jingkun Li

September, 2012

Page 2: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 2

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Introduction .................................................................................................................. 5

Problem statement ...................................................................................................... 6

Structure ...................................................................................................................... 7

Delimitations ................................................................................................................ 9

1. Literature review ................................................................................................. 11

1.1. Definition ................................................................................................... 11

1.2. Types of PPPs .......................................................................................... 16

1.3. Reasons for implementing PPPs ............................................................. 19

1.4. value for money ........................................................................................ 21

1.5. Advantages and disadvantages of PPP .................................................. 26

1.6. Criticism of PPPs ...................................................................................... 29

2. Analysis ............................................................................................................... 32

2.1. The project ................................................................................................ 32

2.2. Alternatives for project implementation ................................................... 32

2.3. Identifying an appropriate PPP scheme .................................................. 34

2.3.1. Overview of Lithuania’s legal PPP environment .................................. 34

2.3.2. Choosing a PPP scheme ...................................................................... 38

2.4. Cost and benefit analysis ......................................................................... 39

2.4.1. Assumptions overview ....................................................................... 40

2.4.2. Data overview .................................................................................... 46

2.4.3. Financial analysis .............................................................................. 48

2.4.4. Socio-economic analysis ................................................................... 49

2.4.5. Sensitivity analysis ............................................................................ 52

2.4.6. Overview and the discussion of the CBA results.............................. 56

2.5. Factors not covered by CBA .................................................................... 58

3. Conclusions ........................................................................................................ 63

4. Bibliography ........................................................................................................ 66

5. Appendices ......................................................................................................... 73

Page 3: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 3

CONTENT OF F IGURES

Figure 1. European PPP trend, 1990-2009 ................................................................ 6

Figure 2. Cash flows in PPP and traditional procurement mode ............................. 16

Figure 3. Structure of Public Sector Comparator ..................................................... 22

Figure 4. Optimal risk allocation point ...................................................................... 23

Figure 5. Model for risk allocation ............................................................................. 24

Figure 6. Identifying Value for Money ....................................................................... 26

Figure 7. PPP scheme under economic activity....................................................... 37

Figure 8. PPP scheme under social activities .......................................................... 38

Figure 9. Sensitivity analysis – FNPV on investment............................................... 53

Figure 10. Sensitivity analysis – FNPV on capital .................................................... 54

Figure 11. Sensitivity analysis - Socio-economic results ......................................... 55

CONTENT OF TABLES

Table 1. Distribution of investment costs, % ............................................................ 46

Table 2. Financial return on the investment costs –PPP and traditional

procurement approach .............................................................................................. 48

Table 3. The structure of financing in PPP and traditional procurement approach 48

Table 4. Financial return on capital – PPP and traditional procurement approach 49

Table 5. Assumptions for the socio-economic analysis ........................................... 51

Table 6. Net benefits of non-market impact ............................................................. 51

Table 7. Socio-economic analysis results ................................................................ 52

Table 8. Sensitivity analysis – change in demand ................................................... 55

Page 4: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 4

L IST OF ABBREVIATIONS

BBO Buy-Build-Operate

BOOT Build-Own-Operate-Transfer

BOT Build-Operate-Transfer

CBA Cost-Benefit Analysis

CO2 Carbon dioxide

CPVA Central Project Management Agency

DBFO Design-Build-Finance-Operate

DBOM Design-Build-Operate-Maintain

EPEC European Public-Private Partnership Expertise Centre

EIB European Investment Bank

ENPV Economic net present value of investment

EU15 European Union of 15 member states

FNPV/C Financial Net Present Value of the Investment

FNPV/K Financial Net Present Value of Capital

FRR/C Financial Rate of Return of the Investment

FRR/K Financial Rate of Return of Capital

IMF International Monetary Fund

Kg Kilogram

Km Kilometre

OECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development

PPP (3P) Public-Private Partnership

PSC Public Sector Comparator

PwC PricewaterhouseCoopers

SPV Special Purpose Vehicle

STPR Social Time Preference Rate

t tonne

tkm tonne-kilometre

VAT Value Added Tax

VFM Value for Money

WACC Weighted Average Cost of Capital

Page 5: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 5

INTRODUCTION

PPP (3P) – public-private partnership – a concept used widely in the public

procurement that lacks both clarity and united definition (Meidute & Paliulis, 2011).

The concept has no clear boundaries for distinguishing what kind of private and

public partnership is assumed to be a form of PPP or a form of a traditional

procurement. This results in some confusion, both in the academic literature, as

well as within the international experiences. Nevertheless, PPP, in general terms,

could be defined as a long term contractual relationship between a public and

private sectors, which is usually characterised by having features such as bundling

of functions, exchange of resources, shared responsibility, risks and rewards, and

is arranged with the aim to provide a public service/asset.

PPP is not a new phenomenon even though it is perceived as such due to its

recent popularity. Growing interest is a result of changing attitudes as well as

expectations of the society towards the government and public services (Grimsey

& Lewis, 2004). Today society expects to see the government more as a governor

and regulator rather than the direct provider of public services. In addition, it

requires infrastructure of better quality, more efficient provision of public services,

as well as better use of public money. Considering all this, PPPs are seen as a

procurement mode that may satisfy these changing needs. Nevertheless, PPPs

are not a ‘miracle’ solution (European Commission, 2003; Harris, 2004; Meidute &

Paliulis, 2011) to the problems of the conventional procurement; they are complex

and expensive and, as a result, only certain projects qualify for the use of public-

private partnerships.

The figure below shows the trend of growing interest in the use of PPP within

Europe for the period of 1990 – 2009. It is important to note that between 1990 and

2004 from all PPP projects more than half were arranged in the United Kingdom.

Only recently the trend has changed and other European countries have

experienced increased use of PPPs (EIB, 2010).

Page 6: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 6

Figure 1. European PPP trend, 1990-2009

Source: Adopted from EIB (2010, p. 7)

Even though, the numbers are increasing, the portion of PPP projects in the overall

public procurement is still not that significant (Appendix 1). For example, in the

United Kingdom, the biggest producer of PPP projects, public private partnerships

represent only 10-13% of all public infrastructure projects (Deloitte Research,

2006).

Having this in mind, the question rises, why PPPs represent such a small fraction

of all public projects if they deliver benefits such as greater efficiency, timely

delivery of public projects, better quality of service provision, etc.? In order to try to

answer this, the paper examines the concept of public-private partnership and

reviews the advantages, disadvantages, and the reasons why PPPs are

implemented. In addition, the case study is performed where the conventional

procurement approach is compared to public-private partnership. The paper

investigates what PPPs are, what they deliver and when they prevail over the

conventional procurement approach.

PROBLEM STATEMENT

The aim of the paper is to analyse the concept of public private partnership and its

suitability for a procurement of a public project. The objectives of the thesis are

achieved by reviewing the relevant literature and performing an analysis on the

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

0

5.000

10.000

15.000

20.000

25.000

30.000

35.000

Nu

mb

er

of

pro

jec

ts

Va

lue

of

pro

jec

ts,

mln

. €

Years

Value of projects Nuber of projects

Page 7: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 7

case study by examining the different procurement approaches available for the

project: PPP and conventional procurement. The analysis will answer which

procurement approach should be the appropriate one for the case study

concerned.

STRUCTURE

The paper is divided into two main parts. The thesis is structured in the way that

from the very beginning an understanding of the concept of PPP could be

developed, which is used for the second part of the thesis, where the analysis is

performed.

The first part of the thesis provides an extensive discussion on the theoretical

foundations of public private partnerships. It focuses on the discussion of the

relevant concepts, characteristics, types, advantages and disadvantages of the

PPP. The first part of the paper answers questions, such as: what PPPs are, why

such a procurement mode is practiced and how it differs from other procurement

approaches, such as conventional procurement and privatisation.

The second part of the thesis is the analysis of the case study. It is divided into two

main sections. The first section includes an overview of the project’s background

and its adequacy for a PPP. It further includes a review of the Lithuanian

environment regarding PPP law and provides a discussion on the suitable PPP

form for the infrastructure project concerned. The second section of part two

consists of the cost and benefit analysis, which involves the following steps:

Data overview (identification of costs and benefits, assumptions);

Financial analysis;

Socio-economic analysis;

Sensitivity analysis;

Overview of the results.

Page 8: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 8

In addition, the second part of the thesis is expanded with a discussion on other

factors that are not covered by CBA, however, factors that are relevant when a

PPP approach is considered.

The last part of the paper concludes the discussion on public-private partnerships

and the analysis performed.

METHODOLOGY

The paper is written by following the deductive, in other words, a “top-down”

approach. The paper begins with the general overview of the theory and then

narrows down to the analysis of a specific case study. In addition, the paper is

based on the secondary sources.

The first part of the paper emphasises on the literature review. The literature

review is based on the European Commission, EPEC, Hong Kong Efficient unit,

Victoria Partnership guidance on PPPs, reports of OECD, IMF, PwC, Deloitte, and

views provided by a variety of PPP researchers – such as Grimsey and Lewis,

Akintoye, Hodge, etc. The articles, books and reports used in the paper were

accessed through a variety of research databases, such as OECD iLibrary,

Science Direct, Business Source Complete, etc.

The second part of the paper emphasises on analysing a particular public-private

partnership project. The analysis is carried out by performing a cost-benefits

analysis (CBA) while employing guidance of the European Commission: “Guide to

Cost Benefit Analysis of Investment projects: Structural Funds, Cohesion Fund and

Instrument for Pre-Accession” (2008) and “Guide to cost benefit analysis of

investment projects” (2002). Some additional insights for the application of CBA

have been adopted from OECD (2006), Boardman, Greenberg, and Vining (2011)

and Campbell and Brown (2003).

Cost and benefit analysis is a technique used to identify, measure and compare

benefits and costs of an investment project and it is used to assist the decision

maker in choosing the most beneficial project from the alternatives available

Page 9: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 9

(Campbell & Brown, 2003). In this paper cost and benefit analysis is used as a tool

to determine the main differences between procuring a project through a traditional

procurement mode and a PPP. It should be noted that the CBA used in this paper

does not try to compare different project implementation alternatives1. The idea of

the analysis is to compare the same project financed by public and private funds.

Therefore, it could be said that the aim the cost and benefit analysis performed in

this paper is to understand whether the inclusion of the private partner in the public

procurement influences the investment decision rule – whether to proceed with the

project or abandon it instead.

The addition to CBA is an overview of other factors that are not incorporated in the

aforementioned analysis, which, however, are influential when the choice of

procurement approach is considered. The discussion on these factors is performed

in accordance to the theory overview of the first part of the thesis.

DELIMITATIONS

The concept of public-private partnership encompasses a variety of different

partnerships and relationships, which are not covered fully in the thesis. The paper

focuses on one particular PPP infrastructure approach, within which the topic is

analysed.

What concerns the second part of the paper, due to time constraints and size

limitations, the CBA is performed only to the level that is enough to identify the

most important points regarding the differences between procuring a project

through PPP and conventional procurement approach. In addition, due to the

complexity and extent of the project, the analysis has been simplified and only

most important impacts taken into account. As a result, there is possibility for some

divergence between results presented in the paper and the reality. Further

development on the CBA could be made if more specific studies were conducted:

for example, a detailed market demand analysis or more specific environmental

1 The paper does not intend to compare the usual cost and benefit analysis’ alternatives: “Business as usual”,

“Do minimum”, “Do something”, “Do something else” (European Commission, 2008).

Page 10: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 10

studies examining the CO2 emission, air pollution, etc. Moreover, due to the lack of

relevant information, which is a consequence of the absence of the analogues

projects in Lithuania, most of the assumptions are based on the foreign countries’

experience, especially of the more developed Western economies, which might be

highly inaccurate when situation in Lithuania is considered. With addition to this, it

is a nature of CBA to use a variety of assumptions, which might sometimes appear

to be imprecise, in particularly, when a long term project is analysed.

Page 11: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 11

1. L ITERATURE REVIEW

1.1. DEFINITION

Public private partnership (PPP), in simple terms, is a form of private-sector

involvement (PSI)2 in which a private partner brings its skills, capital, commercial

innovation into the provision of the services the government is responsible for. It

should be noted, however, that such an explanation covers only a part of this broad

concept. It is widely acknowledged within the relevant literature that there is no

clear definition for PPP which would cover all aspects of different relationships that

these partnerships encompass (Daube, Vollrath, & Alfen, 2007; Hodge & Greve,

2007; OECD, 2008) and at the same time restricting it to a more narrow

description. As Weihe (2006) argues, the concept of PPP is nebulous – it “allows

for great variance across parameters such as time, closeness of cooperation, types

of products/services, costs, complexity, level of institutionalization as well as

number of actors involved”, as a result, nearly any type of the relationships that

include both the private and the public sector (whether it is a service contract or a

joint venture) may be called a public-private partnership (PwC, 2005). In order to

make some distinction between the variety of definitions present, Weihe (2006)

attempted to classify them into 5 categories: local regeneration, policy,

infrastructure3, development and governance approaches. The local regeneration

and the policy approaches are similar due to perceiving PPP concept as a very

wide definition that covers changes in policies of environment, economic renewal,

development, and institutional set up. The difference between the two is that the

local regeneration approach focuses on the local level while policy approach – on

the national. The third approach – the infrastructure approach – covers the

cooperation of private and public sector in order to create and maintain

2 Private-sector involvement is a new focus of EU which has been created in order to “assist the government in

meeting its priorities, building on the clear recognition that public funds are limited” (Tanga, Shena, & Chengb, 2010, p. 684). 3 In order to define infrastructure, we use the definition provided by Grimsey and Lewis (2004, p. 20):

“investment in infrastructure on some definitions is said to provide ’basic services to industry and households ’, ‘key inputs into the economy and ‘a crucial input to economic activity and growth’”. Infrastructure approach in PPP does not cover such infrastructure as “coal or steel or motor vehicles”, it concerns infrastructure like roads, motorways, ports, airports, telecommunication, prisons, schools, etc.

Page 12: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 12

infrastructure, as well as deal with the financial and legal aspects of such projects.

The fourth approach – the development approach – concentrates on the

development of infrastructure in developing countries where corruption, social

deprivation, global disasters are present. This approach includes many forms of

cooperation between the public and private sectors such as strategic or

entrepreneurial partnerships. The last approach is the governance approach which

does not specify any context or policy as it emphasizes on organizational and

management side, as well as new ways of cooperation and governing. For the

purpose of this thesis, the concept of PPP will be limited to the infrastructure

approach.

Even thought the concept has been narrowed down, there are still many definitions

explaining what a PPP is under the approach chosen. For example, the European

Commission (2004, p. 3) defines PPPs as “forms of cooperation between public

authorities and the world of business which aim to ensure the funding,

construction, renovation, management or maintenance of an infrastructure or the

provision of a service”; whereas OECD (2008, p. 12) defines it as “an arrangement

between the government and one or more private partners (which may include the

operators and the financers) according to which the private partners deliver the

service in such a manner that the service delivery objectives of the government are

aligned with the profit objectives of the private partners and where the

effectiveness of the alignment depends on a sufficient transfer of risk to the private

partners”. Further examples of definition include the one proposed by IMF (2006, p.

1) that explains the concept as the “arrangements where the private sector

supplies infrastructure assets and infrastructure-based services that traditionally

have been provided by the government”, and EIB (2004, p. 2) that views PPP as a

relationship of the two sectors which has an aim “of introducing private sector

resources and/or expertise in order to help provide and deliver public sector assets

and services…<it is> used to describe a wide variety of working arrangements

from loose, informal and strategic partnerships, to design build finance and operate

(DBFO) type service contracts and formal joint venture companies”. An overview of

the PPP definitions under the variety of international organizations draws some

Page 13: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 13

conclusions on the basic set of features that characterise PPP under the

infrastructure approach:

long term contractual arrangement between the public and private sector;

functions are bundled;

responsibility for the provision of the services is shared;

resources are shared:

o the private sector brings in capital, skills, experience, commercial

innovation, etc.;

o the public sector delivers skills, political authority, access to publicly

run services, assets, etc.;

risks and rewards are shared.

In order to understand the PPP concept fully, it is also useful to distinguish it from

the traditional procurement mode. The reason for this is that the boundaries

between the two modes are ambiguous. In order to remove this ambiguity the main

differences between the two modes are identified and explained.

First of all, the main differentiating point between PPP and traditional procurement

is that in PPPs risks are shared between the private and public partners whereas in

a conventional procurement most of the risks are retained by the government 4

(European Commission, 2005; OECD, 2008) . This is in line with the functions

included in the contracts. In a PPP different tasks are bundled together and, as a

result, private partner takes responsibility for the whole package of the associated

risks. In the conventional procurement, on the other hand, the government usually

purchases a single function from a private partner and, as a result, the private

partner is responsible only for the risks associated with this function. Consequently,

in the traditional procurement the private partner has no incentives to incorporate

decisions that may favour future operations as after completion of the task, the

private partner is no longer involved in the operations of the asset/service. For

4 Because there is no single clear definition for PPP, the most important factor that distinguishes the

procurement mode and the type of PPP used is the amount of risk and responsibility transferred to the private partner (European Commission, 2005, p. 1).

Page 14: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 14

instance, if the government proposed a tender to deliver a package of services,

such as design, build and maintain a facility, the private partner involved would be

incentivized from the very beginning to make decision that could minimize the

future risks associated with cost overruns. Such an example has been identified in

the international experience by Grimsey and Lewis (2004, p. 135), where an

innovative decision to construct 45-degrees windowsills in UK hospital was

proposed with an intention to save future cleaning costs. It is hardly likely that such

a decision would have been made in the conventional procurement case. A

government would propose a tender to design a facility with input requirements

already specified. The specific requirements can be seen as a frame from the

private partner’s point of view as these requirements restrict private partner to

innovate and come up with more efficient solutions. The aim of the private partner

responsible for a design function is to design a facility while incorporating all the

details required and within the budget stated. The review of function bundling and

risk allocation in both procurement cases help to determine what defines a PPP

and a traditional procurement approach.

Secondly, the two modes differ between each other when the function specification

is considered. What this means is that, in a PPP, government states what it

expects from the private partner in output terms, whereas in the conventional

procurement it does that through input specification. Considering the

aforementioned example, in a PPP case, government might require a hospital to

be big enough to accommodate 300 people and to be kept in a good condition by

clarifying what good condition means, whereas in the conventional procurement

option, a government would request a certain size, with a certain number of rooms,

with specific materials used, etc. In the PPP case, private partner is free to use its

skills and innovation in order to provide the outputs required in a most efficient

way, whereas the latter case does not allow such a freedom as a private sector is

restricted to the requirements specified.

Thirdly, in a PPP approach, returns to the private partner are linked to the

performance of their functions, i.e. the provision of outputs specified by the

Page 15: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 15

government, whereas in a conventional procurement approach, private partner is

remunerated for the completion of a specific function. This contributes to the level

of incentives attached to the private partner: in a PPP case, if a private partner

does not operate as expected, it might incur some sort of penalties (Harris, 2004),

if it operates better than expected, it may be awarded by, for example, receiving

higher portion of additional profits. In a traditional procurement case, on the other

hand, private partner is not awarded for an extra value added to the task it was

responsible for, however, it might be penalized for the uncompleted function.

Considering all this, the private partner in a traditional procurement is not

encouraged to provide more than the government requested for, which means

some possible gains might be overlooked.

Fourthly, the relationships involved in both of the procurement modes differ

(OECD, 2008). In the traditional procurement, in order to deliver the services and

infrastructure required, the government acts as an intermediary – on the one side it

deals with direct users of the services, taxpayers, and financial markets, and on the

other side – with other private companies. The idea behind such a relationship

structure is that the government gathers financing directly from the users of the

service, taxpayers and financial markets, and uses it to remunerate the other side

– the private companies for the capital goods provided to deliver the public service

and develope the infrastructure. If the project is handled through a public-private

partnership, the intermediary role of the government is decreased – public authority

deals with the taxpayers and the single private operator only. The role of the

private operator, on the other hand, is enhanced: private operator becomes

responsible for the intermediary role – it collects financing from the direct users of

the service and financial markets and remunerates the other side – other private

companies for the capital goods provided. If the private operator acts in

accordance to the performance standard specified, in some of the cases 5, it

receives additional payment from the government (Maski & Tirole, 2008). The

relationship structures of the two schemes are represented in the Appendix 2.

5 The private operator may be remunerated through: the collection of direct user charges only, through the

government payment only, or through a combination of both (Grimsey & Lewis, 2004).

Page 16: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 16

Finally, a crucial advantage of PPP from a government’s point of view is the

financing. In a PPP case capital is provided by the private partner. This means that

the government does not incur immediate cash outflow due to the project, which

might be an impossible task when restricted public funds are considered. In a

traditional procurement mode, on the other hand, the government finances the

project from its own funds, that is it incurs large investment costs instantly. Figure 2

represents the comparison between the two financing options in the public

procurement.

Figure 2. Cash flows in PPP and traditional procurement mode

Source: Akbiyikli, Eaton, and Turner (2006, p. 71)

All in all, the two modes differ between each other when the following factors are

considered: amount of risks transferred and tasks bundled, the way requirements

for the service delivery are specified, characteristics of private partners returns,

relationship between the parties involved and the financing flows. Nevertheless, it

is clear that sometimes these differences may be too ambiguous or too subjecitve

to state clearly which procurement approach is adopted.

1.2. TYPES OF PPPS

The spectrum of different PPPs range from the short term service contracts to

concessions. Nevertheless, as the focus of this thesis is the concept of PPP under

an infrastructure approach, the overview of different PPP modes will be limited to

the ones that are covered by the PPP approach chosen. These modes have

Page 17: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 17

common characteristics, such as: being long term, involving risk transfer, shared

responsibility, resources and rewards.

In general, private partner involvement arrangements in PPPs differ between each

other depending on the level of responsibilities and risks transferred to the private

partner (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008). The responsibilities concerned include

activities such as: designing, building, financing, maintaining, operating, and

owning the facilities. The allocation of risks will be discussed in more detail later in

the paper; however, what matters at this point is the amount of risks transferred

and retained by the government.

Most common forms in the infrastructure approaches are:

Turnkey procurement, which includes: BOT (build-operate-transfer), BBO

(buy-build-operate), etc. (European Commission, 2003, 2005);

DBFO (Design-Build-Finance-Operate), which includes: DBOM (design-

build-operate-maintain), BOOT (build-own-operate-transfer), concessions,

etc. (Deloitte Research, 2006; European Commission, 2005; IMF, 2004).

Turnkey procurement6 is described as the scheme where the private partner takes

on the responsibility to design, construct and operate the asset, whereas the public

sector retains the responsibility for the financial risks involved. Using this

procurement mode, public sector sets the quality outputs required and by doing so

it ensures that the private sector brings the necessary efficiency gains as well as

the asset is maintained to the standards expected. This mode of procurement is

used in water and waste projects as it ensures incentivized management and

maintenance of the asset through the bundling of functions passed on to the

private partner (European Commission, 2005).

DBFO scheme7 is characterized by involving a private partner with responsibilities

(financing, designing, building, constructing, and operating the asset/service)

attached to it. Public sector’s role is to set the specific output requirements for the

6 See Appendix 3 for illustration of the turnkey procurement’s scheme.

7 See Appendix 3 for illustration of the DBFO scheme.

Page 18: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 18

private partner, whereas private partner’s role is to fulfil those requirements. The

DBFO schemes are usually long term and involve bundling of functions in order to

provide private partners with the necessary incentives for it to operate in the most

efficient and innovative way. These schemes involve performance linked payment

mechanisms with an aim to ensure the presence of motivation for the private

partner to operate on its full capacity. The idea behind such schemes is that the

private partner designs, builds, operates and maintains the asset for the agreed

term. At the end of this term, the asset is either transferred back to the government

or is left under the ownership of the private partner – depending on the specific

structure of the scheme chosen. For example, one of the most common schemes

under DBFO is concession. Concession is described as a PPP scheme, where

exclusive rights to operate an asset or provide certain services are granted to a

private company (usually a SPV8), which in return has to design, build, finance and

operate the asset/service for the time agreed upon. These exclusive rights usually

permit the private partners to collect the revenues from the direct users of the

asset/service. Concessionaires typically own the rights to the asset/service during

the time of concession, however, at the end of this period the ownership of the

asset/service is usually transferred back to the public sector (Deloitte Research,

2006; European Commission, 2005; IMF, 2006). Literature overview shows that

concession is usually assumed to be a form of PPP (Deloitte Research, 2006;

European Commission, 2004; IMF, 2006; Ng, Xie, Cheung, & Jefferies, 2007;

PwC, 2005), however, OECD (2008) argues the opposite. First of all, it states, that

the amount of risk transferred differs in PPPs and concessions: concessions

involve higher level of risks allocated to the private partner, compared to other

forms of PPPs. Secondly, it is usual for concessionaires to collect revenues from

the direct users of the asset/service and, according to OECD, this feature

differentiates concession from other PPP forms. As a result, OECD concludes that

concessions should not be treated as a PPP. Nevertheless, in this paper

concession is considered as a form of PPP.

8 SPV (special purpose vehicle) – “an organization that can be established as a distinct legal entity to bring

together the companies involved in a PPP in order to manage the project and share the risks and rewards” (Grimsey & Lewis, 2004, p. xv).

Page 19: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 19

The international experience shows that most of the time DBFO schemes are used

in transport sector for building highways, bridges, railways, whereas concessions

are chosen for mobile phone services, toll roads or provision of municipal water.

The similarities between the turnkey procurement and DBFO schemes are that the

activities involved are same in both of the schemes, differing only in the amount of

functions involved in the arrangements. What differentiates the two schemes is that

in the first one the majority of risks remains within the public sector, whereas in the

latter – risks are shared between the partners, allowing for the possibility to transfer

the optimal amount of risks to the private partner.

1.3. REASONS FOR IMPLEMENT ING PPPS

The main objective of procuring a public project through a PPP mechanism is to

achieve value for money (VFM) (Grimsey & Lewis, 2004; Harris, 2004; New South

Wales Government; Quiggin, 2004; Shaoul, 2005) which as Grimsey and Lewis

(2005, p. 347) argue is “the optimum combination of whole life cycle costs, risks,

completion time and quality in order to meet public requirements”. This definition

assents to the one implied by the European Commission (2003, p. 55) which

identifies a set of factors that determine value for money: life cycle costs, allocation

of risks, time required to implement a project, quality of a service, and ability to

generate additional revenues. Following this, a general principal used to determine

whether a project should be implemented through a PPP or a traditional

procurement is to evaluate which procurement mode ensures lower life cycle costs,

better allocation of risks, quicker implementation, higher quality and additional

profits. In other words, additional value for money represents additional efficiency

gains – delivering or maintaining the same service or asset in a more cost efficient

or a more qualitative way than it would have been if the government retained the

full responsibility for delivering/maintaining service/asset concerned (EIB, 2004, p.

4; Meidute & Paliulis, 2011; Nisar, 2006). EIB (2004) argues that the critical aspect

in order to reach value for money is the ability to share risks and rewards

appropriately. OECD (2008) confirms this view recognizing that main reasons for

Page 20: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 20

PPP establishment are the appropriate risk allocation and value for money gains9.

Grimsey and Lewis (2005, p. 347), however, imply that the value for money gains

can only be achieved if the following conditions are present: a competitive

environment, optimal risk allocation and if the comparison between the financing

options is handled in a “fair, realistic and comprehensive” way. Furthermore, when

questioning PPP’s ability to deliver additional gains, one should consider the

qualitative benefits of PPPs – whether they are achievable and whether they really

provide the benefits expected. It is essential therefore to check whether the private

partner is capable of bringing in skills that the government lacks and whether it has

the expertise and know-how necessary to operate more efficiently compared to the

government (PwC, 2005).

According to the literature review, further reasons that lie behind the use of PPP as

a procurement mode differ between countries depending on the environment

present. For example, the main aim of a PPP at the early stage of its development

in the United Kingdom was to finance the public infrastructure projects (Grimsey &

Lewis, 2004; IMF, 2006; Meidute & Paliulis, 2011). The issue at that time consisted

of a growing need for public infrastructure development (as it also is the case in

Hong Kong (Cheung, Chan, & Kajewski, 2009)) and a lack of available public funds

to finance this need. As a result, a new initiative took place – Private Finance

Initiative (PFI) – with the purpose to provide additional funds for public

infrastructure projects. On the other hand, countries like Australia do not have

such an issue. They are capable of financing projects by themselves, however,

they still choose to involve the private sector for the possibility of achieving

additional value (Cheung et al., 2009). Moreover, Hong Kong and Australia involve

a private partner into the procurement of public services with the aim to ensure a

better quality of services. This, on the other hand, does not seem to be the

prioritized reason for the PPP development in the United Kingdom, which

9 The gains associated with the inclusion of the private partner are based on the assumption that the private

partner has more to offer than the public entity could realize by itself - it is assumed that the private partner will bring more innovative and cost efficient solutions in addition to a better management. Nevertheless, caution should be taken here that the mere inclusion of the private partner will not be sufficient to generate value for money required (OECD, 2008, p. 18).

Page 21: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 21

emphasizes the point that reasons to implement PPP depend on the

circumstances surrounding countries’ economic and political environment.

In many of the countries the choice for PPPs, however, is due to financial reasons

(such as lack of public funds and restricted public investment). This reason is

amplified when “a tight fiscal environment following the development of European

Monetary Union” (EIB, 2004, p. 4) is considered as due to this European countries

experience difficulties in organizing large investment sums to finance public

infrastructure projects from the public funds only.

All in all, in theory, the main reason to develop PPPs lies behind the concept of

value for money, creating additional benefits due to private partner’s expertise,

know-how, ability to operate efficiently and generate additional revenues. Despite

the theoretical foundations, it is evident that PPPs are also often used in cases

when there is a lack of public funds for the growing need for public infrastructure.

1.4. VALUE FOR MONEY

The concept of value for money is ambiguous and in order to understand it better,

it is worth analysing the estimation procedure for it. When estimating the value for

money that a partnership creates, governments have to choose between four

methodologies: CBA of public and private partner proposals, PSC-PPP comparison

before the tender, PSC-PPP comparison after the bidding process, and

identification of value for money through the competitive bidding process (Grimsey

& Lewis, 2005; Sarmento, 2010). The literature review shows that the calculation of

PSC (public sector comparator) and comparison of it with the PPP option before

the tender is the most commonly used method. The purpose of public sector

comparator is to verify that value for money is generated (Harris, 2004; Quiggin,

2004) and in order to do this “the hypothetical risk-adjusted cost if a project were to

be financed, owned and implemented by the government” (Partnerships Victoria,

2001, p. 6) should be calculated. The calculation of such costs is done by

estimating four elements: raw PSC, competitive neutrality, transferable and

retained risks, all of which are represented in the figure below:

Page 22: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 22

Figure 3. Structure of Public Sector Comparator

Source: Partnerships Victoria (2001, p. 6)

To begin with, the first component – raw PSC – includes the calculation of project’s

base costs as if the government would procure the project through the

conventional method. It includes identifying and calculating project’s direct (capital,

maintenance, operating costs) and indirect costs (overheads, administrative costs)

as well as any revenues incurred (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008). The next

component – competitive neutrality – involves adjusting the cash flows in order to

remove any competitive advantages or disadvantages that the government may

have over the private sector (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008; Partnerships Victoria,

2001). The advantages and disadvantages concerned may be due to different

aspects of the taxing system applicable to the public and private sectors. For

example, land and income tax rates may differ as government authority may

receive exemption whereas bidder may not. In addition, competitive neutrality

adjustments may rise due to differing regulatory requirements for the partners

concerned. The third and fourth elements of PSC calculation concern the

estimation of transferrable and retainable risks, where risks are identified, allocated

and priced. The price of risks transferred to the private partner should be included

in PSC value. Transferrable risk element together with retained risk element ideally

should ensure the optimal allocation of risks between the partners involved in the

project.

The allocation and valuation of project’s risks is inherent in the value for money

concept (European Commission, 2003; Grimsey & Lewis, 2004; Nisar, 2006;

Page 23: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 23

Sarmento, 2010). The aim of the risk transfer is to transfer only those risks that the

private partner could offset in a most efficient and least costly way(Grimsey &

Lewis, 2004; Harris, 2004; Nisar, 2006). Risk allocation produces highest value for

money once the optimal risk transfer point is identified (Figure 4): transferring too

much or too little risks results in either procuring an inefficient project or procuring a

project with excess costs incurred by the government (for example, if risks are

transferred to the private partner that it does not have control over or cannot

control it at least-cost, then the private partner will require higher premium for these

additional risks assumed (Hodge, 2004)), consequently, producing lower value for

money (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008).

Figure 4. Optimal risk allocation point

Source: Partnerships Victoria (2001, p. 52)

Unfortunately, there is no universal solution regarding risks allocation for every

single project, however, there is a general agreement on how different risks should

be allocated. To begin with, risks in general are allocated to different categories,

such as, for example, proposed by OECD (2008): legal and political risks in

addition to the commercial ones. Categories are differentiated on the basis of who

takes the responsibility for the risks concerned – private partner or the government

authority. For example, construction, supply and demand side risks lie under the

commercial risk category (market risk, project risk and internal risk) as they are

handled better by the private partner, whereas legal and political risks are assumed

to be handled better by the government. Other categorization is proposed by Li,

Akintoye, and Hardcastle (2001), who distribute risks into three levels: macro,

meso and micro. Macro level covers risks outside the project – environmental,

political, legal risks that are concerned with national or industry level. Meso level

Page 24: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 24

risks emerge within the project’s implementation phase – design, construction,

operation. Finally, the micro level risks concern risks that appear between the

partners involved, they rest on the idea that both of the parties have different

incentives and objectives, and therefore, risks due to power struggle, differences in

working methods and environment between the partners may emerge.

Furthermore, Grimsey and Lewis (2004) argue for more detailed risk categorisation

– they divide risks into nine categories that are suitable for the infrastructure

approach: technical, construction, operating, revenue, financial, force majeure,

regulatory/political, environmental and project default risks. This distribution is

similar to the one proposed by Gray (2004), IMF (2004) and the European

Commission (2005).

Finding the most optimal risk allocation point requires identifying what risk is

handled best by which party. As mentioned above, there is no one optimal risk

allocation solution that fits every specific project, however, some general guidance

is present in the literature on PPPs (Bing, Akintoye, Edwards, & Hardcastle, 2005;

European Commission, 2003; Grimsey & Lewis, 2004; OECD, 2008; Quiggin,

2004). For example, if Harris (2004) risk allocation model was considered, the risks

would be assigned accordingly:

Figure 5. Model for risk allocation

Source: Harris (2004)

The proposed model identifies risks that should be passed on to the supplier

(transferable risks), that should be retained by the government and the ones that

do not belong to neither of the parties. As the figure shows, risks such as design,

construction, operating performance, technology obsolescence, etc. are usually

Page 25: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 25

assigned to the private partner. The reason for that is that the private partner

receives most of these risks implicitly with the responsibilities passed on to the

private partner (Harris, 2004). When, for example, DBFO is concerned, the

responsibilities of the private partner include designing, building, financing and

operating the asset, all of these tasks include associated risks, and by contractually

agreeing to handle these tasks, the private partner, consequently, agrees to handle

the risks concerned (Akintoye, Beck, & Hardcastle, 2003). The risks that are

retained by the government authority are risks that the private partner has no

influence over while the government does (Nisar, 2006). For example, the

discriminatory regulatory risk – government might decide to change certain

regulations that may influence the success of the private partner. In order to keep

private partner safe from such possible modifications, the government has to take

responsibility for the consequences of such certain change. Risks under the shared

risk group are those that cannot be controlled at least cost or in the best way by

neither of the party, for example, inflation, exchange and interest rate risks

(Akintoye et al., 2003). An example of a more detailed risk allocation matrix,

proposed by Chan, Yeung, Yu, Wang, and Ke (2011), is presented in the Appendix

4.

After identifying and allocating the risks, the next step is to place a value on them.

There are three factors determining the price of the risk – probability of the risk

occurring, consequence of the risk and the contingent factor10. The value of the

transferable risk equals the contingent amount that the government would pay to

the private partner if a risk occurred under the conventional procurement approach

(Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008; Hodge, 2004).

Four elements: raw PSC, competitive neutrality, transferable risks as well as

retained risks, produces the value of PSC, which is then compared to the value

proposed by the private partner – estimate of PPP value. The value for money is

represented in net present value terms as a difference between the expected costs

of PSC and PPP (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008), as shown in the figure below:

10

Value of risk = consequence * probability of occurrence + contingency factor (Partnerships Victoria, 2001)

Page 26: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 26

Figure 6. Identifying Value for Money

Source: Amekudzi and Morallos (2008, p. 121)

1.5. ADVANT AGES AND DISADV ANT AGES OF PPP

As it has already been reviewed, the appropriately constructed PPPs entail the

advantage of delivering better value for money compared to the traditional

procurement approach. Delivering projects on time and on budget set (Meidute &

Paliulis, 2011) are two of the most important advantages that are hidden under the

concept of value for money. As study conducted by UK’s National Audit Office

(2003) showed, from all conventionally procured projects, 70% were delivered late

and 73% with costs exceeding the initial budget (data of 1999), whereas only 22%

of PFI projects were late and only 24% delivered project in excess of the budget

(data of 2002). The reason for such a difference lies behind the risks transferred in

line with additional responsibility and accountability attached to the private partner

in the case of PPP, what incentivizes the private partner to operate in the most

efficient way. In addition, due to the long term characteristics of the partnerships,

partners involved tend to act in a more cooperative way to each other in this case

creating additional synergy benefits. Private partner manages complex financial

arrangements as well as highly technical tasks more efficiently by using its

innovative skills, on the other hand – the public sector preferably controls the legal

system, regulation and policies. As a result, a combination of the leading features

of both of the partners produces a higher value (Harris, 2004).

Page 27: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 27

The other advantage of PPPs lies behind the construction of the proposal to

procure a public project. Government constructs PPP proposals that focus more on

outputs rather than inputs. As a result, such mindset encourages government to

perform a thorough discussion on which services should be provided, what

standards should be expected, and what is the aim of the service provided/asset

developed. Such a detailed discussion on service provision or asset development

requires a detailed analysis of the project which in some of the cases may hinder

the government from moving ahead if the project becomes inadequate. In addition,

such kind of initial discussions encourage the government to think about the project

with long term strategic goals in mind rather than focus on short term objectives.

Furthermore, PPP’s ability to spread the costs of large investments over the

lifetime of the asset is seen as an attractive advantage for the public sector. This

eases the current debt of the government sector as it does not have to incur large

cash outflows immediately. It follows, that the government can get projects

financed even though in reality there are no public funds available. This advantage

could be considered from two points of view: first – large investment costs are

spread out, and second – private funds are considered as the new financing

opportunities for the government (Meidute & Paliulis, 2011). On the other hand, this

advantage should be considered with caution as sometimes the government might

be incentivized to prove better value for money for a PPP project than it actually is

just to guarantee the financing of the project.

Finally, from the private partner’s point of view, PPPs deliver opportunity for the

private sector to get involved in the new markets (telecommunication, municipal

water systems, energy, etc.) that otherwise would be closed for the private sector’s

participation. In addition to this, the private partner involved in the new markets has

a support of the government, which may facilitate gathering the funds required.

On the other hand, one of the main disadvantages of PPPs is large bidding and

contractual costs, which refer both to the government and the private partner.

Large bidding costs of the PPP projects act as a rejecting force for the private

parties as they are unwilling to invest heavily in the bidding process just to be

Page 28: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 28

rejected later. What concerns government, large preparation costs consist of

feasibility studies, lawyers, etc. Moreover, PPP projects are highly complicated.

Usually, they involve more than two parties: public, private and banking sectors,

and all of these parties have their own contradicting aims. In order to construct a

unified agreement, a lot of time and capital needs to be invested on complex

negotiations.

Furthermore, PPPs are said to deliver benefits because they transfer a significant

amount of risks to the private partner. Nevertheless, it should be kept in mind that

even though most of the risks are transferred to the private partner, the final entity

that is responsible for providing services to the public is the government. As a

matter of fact, if the private partner goes bankrupt, solely the government has to

deal with the consequences and try to find other expedients how to keep delivering

the service to the public. This implies that even though the risks are contractually

transferred to the private partner, in practice, government retains a large portion of

them in case of the private partner’s failure.

Moreover, in a PPP agreement, government bounds itself to a single private

partner for a long term period and it agrees today for services/assets that will be in

use in further future. There is a certain amount of risk concerning the future

consumers’ need for the specific service. The idea behind the risks concerned is

that the partnership may end up delivering services that are no longer required by

the public. As a result, the partnership will appear to be less valuable than initially

expected.

Finally, PPPs work well only for specific projects, which are complex and require

specific private partner’s know-how, skills, and experience. Therefore, advantages

that are attached to PPPs are attained only if certain project characteristics are

met, whereas if the project is simple, executing it trough a PPP implies higher

preparation costs, and as a result, lower value for money.

Considering all of the above, the main idea behind the PPP option is to have a

project intricate enough that its complexity could justify additional preparation and

Page 29: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 29

negotiation costs. Developing a project through a PPP usually ensures additional

benefits such as implementing the project on time and on budget. Nevertheless,

these benefits should be considered while keeping in mind the r isks involved in

having the long term agreement between private and public sectors for a certain

service provision: who can reassure that there will still be a need for some kind of

service in, for example, 30 years?

1.6. CRITICISM OF PPPS

Even though the majority of the international institutions seem to favour the PPP

option (EC, UK Treasury, OECD, IMF), some of the researchers see PPPs as a

language game in the politics – PPP is regarded as another way of privatizing a

service/asset (Hodge & Greve, 2007). This point of view has been neglected by

many other researchers who represent arguments proving that PPPs differ from

the privatization (Grimsey & Lewis, 2004; Harris, 2004; Hong Kong Efficiency Unit,

2008; OECD, 2008). One of the first differences identified is the sale/transfer

concerned. PPP involves government granting a right to the private party to

develop and provide certain services/assets for a period of time, whereas

privatization, in general terms, involves the sale of the asset. This assents to the

amount of risks transferred. In PPP case, the amount transferred differs on the

type of PPP chosen. Concession is the mode of PPP that involves the largest

amount of risks transferred to the private partner; however, it still does not

encompass the transfer of all risks. On the other hand, privatization includes the

sale of the full package, which means the transfer of all associated risks. In this

case, government is left with no direct responsibility for the service provided/asset

developed, whereas in a PPP case, government is the one that retains the initial

control and responsibility for the service/asset (Harris, 2004). If the private partner

goes bankrupt, the service/asset is transferred back to the government. If the

private partner does not operate to the standard required, the government has a

right to intervene and punish the private partner. All in all, it is true that privatization

and PPP share some similarities, but the idea of PPP is that it shares some

superior features of the privatization as well as of the conventional procurement

Page 30: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 30

mode – as Grimsey and Lewis (2004) argue: PPP fills in the missing gap between

privatization and the traditional procurement approach.

Other critiques concentrate on the idea that the government should be fully

responsible for the services provided as this is the role of the government and not

the private sector. However, as Harris (2004, p. 3) argues, the provision of public

services (such as free education, transportation or health) by the government is

“comparatively recent development”. So the question rises whether it is the actual

provision of the services or is it the regulation and control of the service provision

(what kind of services to deliver, what kind of standard should be kept, what policy

to follow, etc.) that is the role of the government? As Harris (2004) concludes the

role of the government is to ensure that a policy is being adopted. If delivering the

policy through the parties that are able to do that in the best possible way while

additionally creating value for money to the public means that the private partner

should be involved, then the advantages of private partner’s efficiency and

innovative skills should be utilized.

Further critique concerns the view that PPPs are a ‘trendy’ politics. This means that

countries might favour PPPs over the conventional procurement due to the lack of

public funds available. Owing to this, the government is left with a choice not

between a PPP and a conventional procurement project but with a choice between

a project and no project at all as a government is unable to finance the project from

its own funds (Robinson, 2000; Shaoul, 2005). The problem of such a preference

for PPPs is that there is a high degree of possibility for approval of projects that do

not generate better value for money but are accepted for the financial resources

only – getting a project procured while having debt off government’s balance sheet

(Maski & Tirole, 2008). In addition to this, as value of PPPs are most of the times

assessed by using PSC, problems appear when hypothetical risk-adjusted nature

of the model is considered. The PSC depends highly on the assumptions

employed (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008), one of the most important one being the

rate used to discount the cash flows of the PSC. Furthermore, when risks

allocation is performed, it is criticized that not all of the risks may be identified and

Page 31: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 31

valued (Amekudzi & Morallos, 2008; OECD, 2008; Shaoul, 2005), thus leading to

inaccurate PSC estimate. As OECD (2008) argues some of the risks may be left

out and neither of the party initially agrees to take responsibility for it, however,

once the risk evolves, it is the government and the public that have to bear the

consequences and not the private partner, leaving some element of value for

money out of the initial estimate. Considering all this, the value for money estimate

may be easily adjusted in order to make the PPP proposal more attractive, which is

seen as a problem when the only reason for PPP project implementation is the lack

of public funds.

Moreover, it has been noted that an advantage of PPP is its ability to spread out

the huge initial investment costs throughout the years of the lifetime of the asset.

This means that the government avoids large investments today and is able to

incur them later on in smaller amounts. However, who may guarantee that the

government with increasing number of PPPs will be capable of financing these

payments in later years? Will it pass this contingent liability to the future taxpayers

(Harris, 2004)? In addition, who can be reassured that the same

service/infrastructure will be necessary in, for example, 30 years? In addition, will

the taxpayers be happy for paying taxes for the services that are unnecessary

anymore? These questions are especially relevant to the cases of PPPs where the

government contracts to pay availability payments for the services provided by the

private partner.

Overall, PPPs attract some significant critiques, however, it should be noted that

PPPs are not a magic solution for the conventional procurement issues. The true

experiences of PPPs have not been observed yet as it takes time to acknowledge

the full impact of each PPP, however, the initial stages of the PPP and the

theoretical foundations allow PPPs to be considered as a possible way to bring on

additional efficiency gains to the public sector.

Page 32: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 32

2. ANALYSIS

2.1. THE PROJECT

In the last decades the advantages of having a developed inland waterway in

Lithuania were forgotten. The politicians focused more on developing the road and

rail rather than the inland waterway network. This is understandable as the

potential for Lithuanian biggest river (Nemunas) to become domestically or an

internationally important part of the transport network is far more complicated

compared to the road or rail network. On the other hand, due to Lithuania’s

geographic position and increasing global emphasis on the environmentally friendly

modes of transportation, inland waterways are becoming a solution to many of the

European environment targets set11. As a result, the interest to encourage the

development of Lithuanian waterway is growing and one of the first steps is to

develop a wharf in the centre of Lithuania (Appendix 5). The aim of the wharf is to

stimulate the freight transportation in Lithuanian inland waterway network by

creating opportunity to accommodate barges transporting containers.

2.2. ALTERNATIVES FOR PROJECT IMPLEMENTATION

The traditional procurement approach for the delivery of public services and

facilities has been practised in Lithuania for decades already. The new rising trend,

however, is the use of public-private partnerships. Despite the fact that PPPs may

bring additional value for money, the PPP option is not always the best solution to

the provision of the public service or good. In order to assess whether PPP option

should be considered for the wharf’s project, the following circumstances, identified

by the Ministry of Municipal Affairs (1999) and adopted to this particular project,

should be reviewed:

11

For example, European Commission’s White Paper has noted that the GHGs emission should be decreased by 80-95% below 1990 levels, from which at least 60% decrease should be achieved in the transport sector by 2050; by 2030 the transport sector’s GHGs emission should be lowered to 20% below the 2008 level. In addition, freight transportation shift to other modes is advocated: the target has been set to transfer the road freight to other transportation modes – rail or waterborne – when the transportation distance exceeds 300km by at least 30% by the year of 2030, and by 50% by the year of 2050 (European Commission, 2011, pp. 3, 9).

Page 33: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 33

1. Does the government have enough know-how or financial resources to

consider the project on its own?

2. Is there a potential for the private partner to provide the public service faster

and in a better quality than the government would do on its own?

3. Is there a competitive environment for potential tender of a project?

4. Can the output of the project be identified easily? Can the performance of

the private partner be measured easily?

5. Does the project require innovative skills?

The wharf’s project is very specific and the government authority lacks the skills

and know-how required to operate the wharf effectively. As a result, due to the

expertise and experience of the private sector in the field concerned, the inclusion

of the private partner may bring additional value. Furthermore, additional value can

be enhanced by delivering the project faster than in the case of the government.

The experience of PPP projects around the world prove that PPPs most of the

times deliver the projects on time, whereas in the conventional procurement mode,

the delivery is often delayed12. Moreover, the output of the wharf can be identified

and measured easily, and as a result, monitoring private partner’s performance

should not be too problematic. The idea behind PPP is that only the outputs of the

project are specified, and the private partner has all the freedom it needs for

innovative decision making that could make the project more efficient. Following

this, it should be concluded that the PPP option is worth considering and, as a

result, the paper analyses the following procurement options:

1. Traditional procurement approach, where government takes a full

responsibility for the project and finances, designs, builds, operates and

owns it;

12

Study performed by Flyvbjerg, Holm, and Buhl (2002) proved that costs in the conventional procurement approach in 90% of transportation infrastructure projects were underestimated – actual costs exceeded the planned budget on average by 28%. Another study conducted by UK’s National Audit Office (2003) found that from all conventional procurement approach projects arranged, 70% were delivered late and 73% with costs exceeding the initial budget (1999 data), whereas only 22% of PFI projects were late and only 24% delivered project in excess of the budget.

Page 34: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 34

2. PPP approach, where the responsibility of the project delivery is shared

between the private partner and the government, and where it is the private

partner that finances, designs, builds and operates the wharf.

Which of the two options delivers better value requires a detailed analysis, which is

presented in the following sections.

2.3. IDENTIFYING AN APPROPRIATE PPP SCHEME

In order to determine which PPP scheme should be the appropriate one for the

project concerned, first of all, the overview of possible PPP forms in Lithuania is

reviewed.

2.3.1. OVERVIEW OF L ITHUANIA’S LEG AL PPP ENVIRONMENT

Currently Lithuania has no one single legal act determining all existing forms of

public-private partnerships, their characteristics, etc. (Meidute & Paliulis, 2011).

Nevertheless, some forms of PPPs are covered by Lithuanian laws, such as the

Law on Management, Use and Disposal of State and Municipal Authorities’

Property, the Law on Concessions, the Law on Investment. The problem with these

laws, however, is that some of them do not fully cover the regulations necessary

and therefore, are insufficient (Meidute & Paliulis, 2011).

In Lithuania PPP environment is not yet developed. Some of the interest has been

identified, however, it is far away from what, for example, United Kingdom or

Australia has already achieved. As Meidute and Paliulis (2011, p. 262) note "there

are virtually no PPP projects implemented at a national level that would cover

some sector of importance for the society and where the public sector would be

represented by central authorities”. Nevertheless, Lithuania is improving its PPP

environment and as of today Lithuanian law provides two classifications of public-

private partnerships: institutional and contractual partnerships.

Page 35: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 35

INSTITUT IONA L P ARTNER SH IP

Institutional partnership is a PPP mode when functions of a state or municipal

authority are granted to a joint stock company or a limited liability company, which

ownership is shared between the state or municipal authority and the private

partner. The characteristics describing the nature of this PPP form are determined

in the Law on management, use and disposal of state and municipal authorities’

property (Seimas of the Republic of Lithuania, 2012c, article 2, paragraph 12).

The main requirement for establishing an institutional partnership is the exchange

of resources between each of the party involved, i.e. the state or municipal

government invests its property in exchange for acquiring the authorized capital in

either the newly established joint stock or a limited liability company or in a

company which is increasing its share capital. The acquired authorized capital

should provide the state or municipal government (or both of them together) with

more than 50 percent of the vote.

CONTRACTUAL PARTNERSH IP

In general terms, it could be defined as cooperation between the public and private

parties on the basis of the contractual agreement. The contractual partnership can

assume the form of a concession or public and private parties’ partnership.

To begin with the concession, the characteristics describing the nature of this PPP

form are determined in the Law on Concessions (Seimas of the Republic of

Lithuania, 2012a). Concession is an engagement of a concessionaire (private party

involved in the concession agreement), in accordance to the concession

agreement and the conditions laid down by the awarding authority, in economic-

commercial activities related to infrastructure design, construction, extension,

renewal, modification, repair, management, use and (or) maintenance, as well as

the provision of public service, management and (or) use of state, municipal

property (including the operation of natural resources), when the concessionaire

assumes all or most of the risks in addition to the rights and obligations associated

Page 36: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 36

with an activity awarded under the specific concession agreement.

Concessionaire‘s remuneration for handling the activity granted consists of:

1. The right to engage in this particular activity in addition to the income

generated from such an activity; or

2. The right to engage in this particular activity in addition to the income

generated from such an activity together with the payment made by the

awarding authority, which is subject to the risks assumed.

According to the concession agreement, the concessionaire is allowed to operate

certain economic-commercial activity, which is related to infrastructure

development or the provision of public service in the following areas: water

management, waste management, railway lines and networks, road transport

infrastructure, health care system, port and wharf’s infrastructure, etc. for a period

of time no longer than 25 years. The property that could be transferred to the

concessionaire for the use or management purposes is the property belonging to

the state or municipal government in addition to the property which exclusively

belongs to the state under the Constitution.

The main point differentiating concessions from other contractual partnerships is

that revenue can be collected from the direct users of the public service or

infrastructure managed under the concession agreement.

According to the recommendations For PPP feasibility study preparation provided

by the Central Project Management Agency (CPVA), concession mode is classified

under the economic activity, which includes services of general economic interest

(CPVA, p. 20). The aim of the economic activity is to create an open and

competitive internal market. Public-private partnership for the economic activity can

be arranged when the activity concerned is of economic nature, irrespective

whether it is under the responsibility of the government or the private party. Under

such activities, users pay for the services directly to the service provider – in this

case, private party. PPP scheme under economic activity is presented in the Figure

7.

Page 37: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 37

Figure 7. PPP scheme under economic activity

Source: CPVA (p. 21)

The other mode of the contractual partnership is the public and private parties’

partnership. The characteristics describing the nature of these particular

partnerships are determined in the Law on Investment (Seimas of the Republic of

Lithuania, 2012b). Partnership is a mode of PPP in which a private party invests in

the activity that the government is responsible for and the corresponding

infrastructure (which is owned by the government) and operates within it according

to the rules defined in the Law on Investment. The government is responsible for

remunerating the private party for the operations handled.

According to the public and private parties’ partnership, the right to operate a

certain activity can be granted to the private partner, which is related to the design,

construction, reconstruction, repair, renovation, management, operation and

maintenance of infrastructure and other property that government transfers to the

private party, in addition to the provision of public services in the following areas:

transport, education, health and social care, culture and other areas determined by

the state authorities. During the time of the partnership the property can be

transferred to the private partner for the operations defined in the partnership

agreement, however, after the duration of the partnership, the whole property has

to be returned to the government: the one transferred to the private partner at the

start of the partnership period in addition to all the new property created during the

time of the partnership.

Page 38: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 38

The partnership is arranged only when it provides an effective implementation of

the state functions, public interest and public needs and it cannot be shorter than 3

years and no longer than 25 years.

According to CPVA, the public and private parties’ partnership is classified under

the social activity, which covers all non-economic activities. Some examples of

social activities under PPPs include schools, prisons, health security, and various

social services. In this PPP mode, users do not pay directly for the services. It is

the responsibility of the government to allocate public funds in order to receive the

services concerned. PPP scheme under social activities is illustrated in Figure 8.

Figure 8. PPP scheme under social activities

Source: CPVA (p. 23)

2.3.2. CHOOSING A PPP SCHEME

After reviewing present forms of PPPs in Lithuanian legal environment, the next

step is to identify which one is the most suitable one for the wharf’s project.

When considering the institutional partnership, it is important to note that the

government within the wharf’s project case seeks to transfer the day-to-day

decisions to the private partner. The reason for that is that the government

authority does not have the skills and the know-how required to operate the wharf

in the most efficient way, whereas the private business has it all. In the institutional

partnership, the day-to-day operation management is in the hands of both parties

involved as the government has at least half of the votes. As this is not the aim of

the government authority in this particular case, the institutional partnership mode

as an adequate PPP form for the project has been rejected.

Page 39: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 39

The other PPP mode is the contractual partnership, which consists of concession

(economic activity) and partnership (social activity). Partnership under the social

activity has been rejected due to its differing goals and circumstances regarding

the payment mechanism. First of all, these partnerships are developed in order to

implement projects of non-economic nature. Secondly, under the scheme agreed

on, the users of the wharf will have to pay for the services directly, whereas in the

partnership the government remunerates the private party for the services

delivered.

Finally, the last PPP form – concession, has been considered as the most suitable

PPP form due to the following reasons:

1. The wharf’s business is an economic activity, irrespective whether the wharf

operates in the hands of the government or of the private partner;

2. Economic-commercial activity of the project is identified in the Law on

Concessions as an activity related to infrastructure development – building

port and wharf’s infrastructure;

3. The payment to the private partner consist of the right granted to engage in

wharf’s business, the income generated from direct user payments as well

as the payment made by the government authority in exchange for the risks

assumed.

2.4. COST AND BENEFIT ANAL YSIS

The next section of the paper represents the cost and benefit analysis carried out

on the project. In this paper the project is analysed by comparing the two

alternatives, i.e. implementing a project through a traditional procurement and a

PPP approach. The CBA will begin from the assumptions and data overview,

followed by the financial, socio-economic and sensitivity analysis. Finally, the

results of the analysis will be reviewed and the main question – which procurement

mode generates higher welfare – will be discussed.

Page 40: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 40

2.4.1. ASSUMPTIONS OVERVIEW

T IME H OR IZON

The project is assumed to take a time horizon of 25 years. The decision regarding

the length of the project is made in line with the recommendations provided by the

European Commission (2008) for the port development projects as well as

according to Lithuanian Law on Concessions where the maximum period of time is

set to 25 years.

STANDING

In order to assess and allocate the costs and benefits generated by the project, it is

important to understand whose costs and benefits count, in other words, CBA

requires the identification of who has standing (Boardman et al., 2011). With

respect to the project analysed, the chosen point of view is the national

perspective. The reason for this is that the wharf is of a national importance and it

has effect not only on a certain region within the country, but it has influence on the

whole economy of Lithuania and its development.

PRICE LEV EL

Identification and monetization of costs and benefits relevant to the project

concerned, first of all, require some assumptions regarding inflation and relative

price changes. The costs and benefits should be valued in the same comparable

way throughout the years of the project, therefore, it is important to define the

relevant components. The choice for projecting the costs and benefits is between

using nominal and real values (Boardman et al., 2011). From one point of view, the

inflation could be incorporated into the calculations of costs and benefits. This

would require the estimation of expected future inflation rates for the next 25 years.

However, as the Belli, Anderson, Barnum, Dixon, and Tan (2001, p. 42) note,

predicting the rate of inflation is “a difficult, if not impossible task”. As a result, the

inflation is usually netted out, i.e. the costs and benefits are valued in real terms.

OECD (2006, p. 44) proposes using the real terms and valuing all costs and

Page 41: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 41

benefits from a perspective of the base year, i.e. “the year of the appraisal”. This

view is also supported by Belli, Anderson, Barnum, Dixon, and Tan (1998), who

note that the real values for costs and benefits calculation should be employed.

The reason for that is that the inflation raises the value of costs and benefits in

same levels, which means they net out each other’s impacts (Campbell & Brown,

2003). As a result, the project’s costs and benefits are valued in real terms.

Furthermore, the valuation needs to be conducted, as mentioned above, from a

base year perspective, which has been settled to be year 2012. Most of the costs

and benefits were initially valued at the price level of 2012, therefore no adjustment

was necessary. Cost and benefits that required an adjustment are represented in

the socio-economic analysis.

Moreover, it is important to consider the relative price changes, which are changes

in prices that are significantly above or below the inflation rate. The price changes

occur due to changes in demand, the scarce nature of goods, technological

development, etc. (Campbell & Brown, 2003; HM Treasury, 2003). The evaluation

of the project’s costs and benefits assumes unchanged relative prices.

Finally, monetizing costs and benefits requires a choice of the currency. All cost

and benefits have been calculated in the national currency – Lithuanian Litas,

however, some of the values used in the socio-economical analysis require

exchanged from Euro to Lithuanian Litas, and for this purpose, the official fixed

exchange rate of 3.4528 LTL/EUR13 is in use.

D ISCOUNT RAT E

The goal of comparing the two project implementation models is to assess which of

the two procurement approaches ensures higher value. In order to assess and

compare the net values, costs and benefits of each of the alternative are

discounted to the present terms. Discounting is crucial for CBA as it ensures that

the time value of money is incorporated in the valuation of costs and benefits. If

13

In use from February 2002.

Page 42: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 42

time value of money was not captured, having one dollar today would be the same

as having one dollar in a hundred years. However, this does not seem to be true as

having one dollar in one hundred years involves uncertainty and this uncertainty

decreases the value of future money. Determining the appropriate discount rate is

very complex, however, it has great impact on the CBA results, which provide

guidance on whether the project should be passed or rejected. Finding the right

discount rate also involves distinguishing how the rate differs for the private and

public sectors. This is especially relevant when PPP and conventional procurement

approaches are compared. Currently there are two opposing views regarding what

rates should be used for the sectors considered. The first one states that the rates

should be indifferent. Grimsey and Lewis (2004) make an overview of this

perspective. They represent Klein’s (1997)14 view that it does not matter what is the

source of the funds (the default risk is irrelevant), what matters is the actual project

and its specific risks. Therefore, allowing government to use a risk-free discount

rate undermines the amount of project’s risks and presents it as being less risky

than it actually is. Private sector, however, analyses the project thoroughly in order

to identify the risks inherent and, in accordance to these risks, determines the

relevant cost of capital. It is also argued that the discount rate attributable to the

government should be lower than the private sector’s one due to government’s

ability to transfer project’s risks to the taxpayers, spreading the risks out, what the

private partner is incapable of doing. However, transferring these risks to the

taxpayers is not costless. Imposing contingent liabilities on the taxpayers due to

transferred project’s risks is a cost to a society, which usually is overlooked in CBA,

and as a result, the costs of the project are undermined. Incorporating these costs

to the cost of capital might lead to the same rate used by the private partner. The

second point of view argues for differing discount rates, where the private partner

has a higher cost of capital. One of the reasons for this is the risk of default. Private

partner is more likely to default compared to the government as the latter has an

ability to increase taxes in order to avoid its bankruptcy. Consequently, the

discount rate used by the private sector is expected to be higher compared to the

14

See Klein, M. (1997), ‘The Risk Premium for Evaluating Public Projects’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 13(4), 29–42.

Page 43: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 43

public sector. Furthermore, the differing discount rates are justified by the nature of

the risks attributed to the project’s cash flows in the case of the private sector and

government (Grout, 2003). When PPP structure is considered, for example, a

Private Finance Initiative, from the government’s perspective, the discounted cash

flows are the costs incurred by the government as it pays the private partner for the

services delivered, whereas from the private partner’s point of view these cash

flows are the revenues. There are no reasons to assume that cost and revenue

cash flows are the same regarding their risk characteristics. Contrarily, Grout

(2003) argues that these cash flows have different characteristics and the one of

the private partner – the revenue cash flow – is riskier in its nature compared to the

cost cash flow. Moreover, another reason to assume why the discount rate

attributable to the private partner is higher compared to the public sector is the

premium a private partner requires for a long term nature of the PPP agreement

(PwC, 2005).

Despite the preceding discussion, practice shows that the discount rate used in the

private sector is higher than the one used in the public sector (PwC, 2005;

Stevens, 2004). Private partner’s discount rate is dependent on private partner’s

attitude towards risks and returns, whereas government’s rate usually depends on

the society’s preferences of consuming today as opposed to the future (Campbell

& Brown, 2003; HM Treasury, 2003; Stevens, 2004). In order to evaluate the

private partner’s expected return from the project proposed, the calculation of

weighted average cost of capital (WACC) has been employed (Goldbach,

Goldman, Phillips, & Seymour, 2012). The reason for this is that the private partner

will invest its funds to the project only if the project delivers the minimum rate of

return required, which is represented by the following formula:

-

, where RE – cost of equity; RD – cost of debt;

E/V – percentage of equity financing; D/V – percentage of debt financing; Tc –

corporate tax tariff.

Page 44: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 44

To begin from the cost of equity, it should be acknowledged that there is a lack of

data concerning the appropriate rate of return the private investor would expect to

receive in case of a PPP project, especially in the market of wharf or port

operations in Lithuania. Owning to this, the alternative way to value the cost of

equity was employed. The idea behind this method was to analyze returns on

equity that randomly selected Lithuanian companies, present on the stock

exchange, generate. Following this, 10 Lithuanian companies were reviewed and

data regarding their return on equity in 2011 was gathered (Appendix 6). The

average of these returns was calculated, which equals to 14,3%, and used as a

cost of equity for the private partner in a PPP project concerned. It is, however,

likely that the cost of equity could be even higher as the project is much riskier

compared to the average company currently operating in the market. Nevertheless,

due to the lack of relevant data available, the average cost of equity will be

assumed to be the appropriate rate. The other components of the WACC formula

include the cost of debt, which is equal to 6%, an interest rate used to repay the

loan, as well as proportions of equity and debt present in the private financing

structure – 40% equity and 60% debt. The last component is the income tax, which

is 15%. After incorporating all of the data in the WACC formula, the estimated cost

of capital rate is 8,78%.

When considering the appropriate discount rate for the government, the social

discount rate needs to be considered. Identifying the appropriate rate for the public

projects from the government’s point of view requires a choice of the methodology.

Boardman et al. (2011) discuss the use of four methodologies, which are based on

the market behaviour: marginal rate of return on private investment, social marginal

rate of time preference, government’s borrowing rate, and weighted average

approach. The four approaches are criticized due to their complexity in determining

one single rate, difficulties in aggregating preferences and opportunities of each

individual, their inaccuracy when market distortions and externalities are

considered, etc. The alternative methodology proposed by HM Treasury (UK) is the

Social Time Preference Rate (STPR), which is represented by the following

formula:

Page 45: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 45

, where ρ is an element of two components – the catastrophe risk (L)

and pure time preference (δ), which represent the time preference, g – the growth

of per capita consumption and μ – elasticity of marginal utility of consumption.

STPR is a rate that represents society’s preferences to consume at different points

in time. Following HM Treasury’s recommendations, the chosen social discount

rate for the conventional procurement approach in CBA is STPR. In order to

determine the rate, first of all, each of the STPR’s components should be valued.

To begin with, the social time preference implies that an extra unit of consumption

now, as opposed to the one received in the future, generates higher utility as the

future consumption involves uncertainty “which attaches to it through human

mortality” (Campbell & Brown, 2003, p. 223) . This assents to the components of

the time preference value identified by HM Treasury (2003) – catastrophe risk and

pure time preference, where catastrophe risk implies the likelihood of some

disaster happening that may alter the returns expected. As it is difficult to calculate

both of the components, HM Treasury (2003) proposes the time preference rate to

be equal to 1,5%, which will be incorporated in the calculation of a social discount

rate for the wharf’s project. The other component is the elasticity of marginal utility

of consumption, which is also difficult to calculate for every specific project,

therefore, a recommendation of HM Treasury (2003) to use a rate equal to 1 will be

followed. The last component that needs to be considered is the growth of per

capita consumption, which is evaluated by calculating the average rate of growth of

per capita household consumption in Lithuania (Evans & Sezer, 2005) in the period

of 1995-201015. The growth of per capita consumption is estimated to equal 4,4%

(Appendix 7). After including all of the components into the formula, the STPR

used as a social discount rate for the government is equal to 5,9%, a rate just

above the one used by the European Commission (5,5%) for the countries such as

Lithuanian, the ones that are entitled to the Cohesion Fund. The reason for having

higher rate in countries that are entitled for this fund is that these countries need

15

Period of 1995 – 2010 has been chosen due to the limits of the data available, i.e. data is available only for the period chosen.

Page 46: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 46

faster growth, more rapid development and, as a result, the project selectivity

should be enhanced (European Commission, 2008).

Comparing the private and public sectors’ rates derived from the calculations,

results in private partner’s cost of capital being 2,88% higher than the

government’s. This outcome appears to fit in the frame distinguished by PwC

(2005, p. 30), which note that the private sector’s cost of capital is usually 1-3%

higher compared to the public sector.

2.4.2. DAT A OVERVIEW

The project implies a construction of 200 m long wharf that is able to accommodate

three 64 m16 long barges, building administrative premises as well as constructing

an open storage area and a warehouse, acquiring the machinery and equipment

necessary for the cargo handling. The distribution of the investment costs is

represented in the table below:

Table 1. Distribution of investment costs, %

Year 1 2 3 Total

Works 0,0% 85,9% 46,3% 53,9%

Equipment 0,0% 0,0% 53,4% 43,1%

Services 0,0% 14,1% 0,0% 2,7%

Other investments 0,0% 0,0% 0,3% 0,3%

Total 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0%

Assets that have their economic life less than the time horizon of the project will be

replaced some time before the end of the project, depending on their economic life.

For example, cargo handling equipment will be purchased on the third year of the

project. The expected economic life of such assets is 12 years. As a result, the

replacement of the asset will take place on the 15th year. It has been assumed that

the value of the equipment in the year of replacement will compensate the costs of

the disposal, as a result, no net impact on the cash flows will be recognised.

Residual value is calculated according to its economic life and the market value of

the asset. It is assumed that the asset loses its value every year till the end of its

economic life.

16

A base barge has been adopted with respect to technical details of river Nemunas – its depth and width.

Page 47: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 47

Operating costs have been identified in accordance to the investments and

reinvestments planned as well as the demand projections estimated. The reason

for that is that the three components mentioned above determine what level of

maintenance, labour, marketing campaigns and other expenses is required to keep

the wharf operational and up to the standard expected. Furthermore, the demand

projections are used to determine the expected levels of revenues. The demand,

however, due to the lack of relevant statistics (which is non-existent as a result of

absence of the market concerned) and project’s specificity is fairly uncertain. The

project is new and has no analogues in Lithuania. In addition, taking other

countries’ experience in this case is irrelevant as the circumstances surrounding

the freight transportation in Lithuanian river Nemunas are too different compared to

other, already developed, European inland waterways. Consequently, forecast ing

the demand for services is complex and requires a lump of assumptions.

Determining the demand, first of all, involves identification of a range of services a

wharf is expected to provide. These services include: mooring a barge, loading and

unloading barges, storage of containers in an open warehouse area, rent of the

closed warehouse and other additional services (weighting vehicle, container,

cleaning of containers, electricity, water, etc.). Next step is to determine the

potential amount of demand for the services identified. The approach chosen was

to look at the amount of container flows from two points of view:

1. To calculate the maximum wharf’s capacity and then adjust it by the

expected rate of occupancy;

2. To forecast the expected amount of containers transported through Klaipeda

State Seaport with the destination and origin of Lithuania.

The two points give a plausibility frame for the expected demand. The idea behind

these two points is that the wharf’s expected level of demand conducts a part of

the demand levels of Klaipeda State Seaport. The estimated demand expectations

for the wharf amount to 6,8% of all containers that are expected to pass Klaipeda

State Seaport. This is held as a reasonable expectation for the future demand

projections.

Page 48: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 48

2.4.3. F INANCIAL ANALYSIS

The financial return on the investment takes into account the investment and

reinvestment costs, operating expenses and the revenues generated throughout

the years of the project. The discounted cash flow analysis presents the results

that are the basis for the investment criteria:

Table 2. Financial return on the investment costs –PPP and traditional

procurement approach

Results Traditional procurement PPP

Discount rate 5,9% 8,78%

FRR/C 11,2% 11,2%

FNPV/C 18.494,4 6.364,2

When considering the financial return on capital, the two approaches available

should be overviewed in more detail regarding their financing structure. The

traditional procurement approach is when a government uses public funds to

finance a project. When the PPP approach is taken into account, the private

partner’s funds are the source of project’s finance. However, private partner’s

funds most of the time involve a third party – a bank. As a result, a PPP option

considered will consist of equity and debt. In literature it has been observed that

the portions of financial sources usually distribute accordingly: private partner’s

equity accounts to 10 -35% while debt – 65-90% of total financing required (Gray,

2004). In the case of this particular project, it is assumed that due to the riskiness

and specificity of the project, the funds will be distributed accordingly: 40% of

private equity and 60% of bank loan (provided for a 10 year period with the interest

paid at the end of the year, equal to 6%).

Table 3. The structure of financing in PPP and traditional procurement approach

Finance source Total Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Years 4-25

Option I – Traditional procurement approach

Public funds

National grant 37.908 0 7.193 30.714 0

Replacement of short life components financing

National grant 10.387 0 0 0 10.387

Option II – PPP approach

Private funds

Equity 15.163 0 7.193 7.970 0

Page 49: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 49

Loan 22.745 0 0 22.745 0

Total 37.908 0 7.193 30.714 0

Replacement of short life components financing

Equity 10.387 0 0 0 10.387

Loan 0 0 0 0 0

With regards to the financing structures proposed, the calculation of financial return

on capital reveals the following results:

Table 4. Financial return on capital – PPP and traditional procurement approach

Results Traditional procurement

PPP

National

capital17

Private

Equity

Discount rate 5,9% 5,9% 8,78%

FRR/K 11,6% 14,1% 14,1%

FNPV/K 20.522,2 20.269,9 9.537,3

2.4.4. SOCIO-ECONOMIC ANALYSIS

Socio-economic analysis is carried out by performing fiscal corrections in addition

to corrections for externalities. Converting market into accounting prices did not

require calculation of conversion factors as the assumption was made that all

market prices represent correct accounting prices, i.e. the conversion factor used

in calculations equals to 1.

To begin with, fiscal corrections are used to correct for distortions that appear due

to financial transfers within the society that in reality create no economic value, i.e.

they represent a pure transfer only (European Commission, 2008). The procedure

of fiscal corrections consists of identifying indirect and direct taxes, as well as

certain government’s subsidies and omitting their impact from the financial

analysis’ flows. For the project considered the fiscal corrections were applied in

order to remove the impact of VAT, individual income tax and social insurance

contribution. VAT tax impact has been calculated by adjusting investment costs

17

In the case of PPP, looking at the financing structure of the project, the return on private equity and national capital needs to be distinguished. For evaluation of the financial return on national capital, the discount rate used is the one attributable to the government. The reason for that is that, from the society’s point of view, the national capital is of similar nature as public funds: it could be assumed, that society is indifferent between having an investment financed directly by the private sector, or the government first gathering the funds from them and only then investing into the project. As social discount rate used represents the society’s time preference to consume today as opposed to tomorrow, this rate is the adequate one for the evaluation of the financial return on the national capital.

Page 50: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 50

and operating expenses (except remuneration related expenses) on year by year

basis. The assumption was made that 60% of the investment costs relate to

equipment, machinery, material, while the rest 40% of investment costs relate to

labour. As a result, 60% of total investment costs in addition to operating expenses

are relevant for fiscal corrections, for which VAT rate used equals the tax rate of

2012 – 21%. The other fiscal correction is made for the individual income tax,

which has been calculated by identifying new workplaces arranged as a result of

project implementation. The remuneration associated with these workplaces

includes the individual income tax to the government, which is assumed to equal to

the tax rate settled in 2012 – 20%. In addition, the remuneration flows in the

financial analysis have been adjusted for the social insurance contribution

component, which is equal to 31%.

Next part of the socio-economic analysis consists of correction for externalities.

The analysis focused on identifying and pricing benefits that incur due to changes

caused by the project emergence. The benefits considered were changes in

external economic variables, such as CO2 emission (climate change), air pollution,

and accident costs. The calculation of these external economic effects was

conducted comparing road and inland waterway. The reason for this is that the

wharf’s development aim is to take off additional transport from the road and move

it to the river. In order to monetize the non-market impacts, the shadow prices of

the relevant external effects have been used. In addition to this, the average

amounts of CO2 emitted by both modes of transport were incorporated as it

facilitated the calculation of the average amount of CO2 emitted by road transport

in comparison to inland waterway transport. The shadow price of CO2 has been

used with respect to the guidance provided by Ministry of Transport and

Communications of the Republic of Lithuania (2011), whereas the averages

regarding amount of CO2 emitted were taken from the study conducted by The

European Chemical Industry Council (Cefic) (2011). What concerns the valuation

of the rest non-market impacts – air pollution and accident costs, the relevant

shadow prices have been taken from a study on external cost of transport

(Infras/IWW, 2004). The shadow prices used in the paper are the average costs

Page 51: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 51

calculated for air pollution and accidents. The study determined the price for air

pollution impact by considering damages it has on human health and buildings, as

well as its influence towards crop losses. Price for accidents was determined with

respect to additional costs accidents create, such as medical care, loss of

economic production, and suffering costs. The cost for accidents was conducted by

valuing “willingness to pay to reduce accident risks” (Infras/IWW, 2004, p. 169). It

should be acknowledged that the shadow prices used are the average prices

calculated for EU15 countries, nevertheless, due to lack of specific data for

Lithuania, the aforementioned shadow prices were incorporated in the calculations

of the non-market impact. The data used in calculations is represented in the table

below:

Table 5. Assumptions for the socio-economic analysis

Road Inland

waterway

Freight (t) 500.337 – 781.777

Average distance (km) 430 557

Average amount of CO2 emitted (g/tkm) 62 31

Shadow price for CO2 emitted (LTL/kg) 0,14 0,14

Shadow price for air pollution (LTL/1000tkm) 238,5 78,6

Shadow price for accident costs (LTL/1000km) 42,4 0 *Shadow prices are converted to price levels of 2012 using the GDP deflator

The comparison of the road and inland waterway transport prove inland waterway

to be more beneficial to the society compared to the road transport mode (Table 6).

Table 6. Net benefits of non-market impact

External savings, in thou. LTL

External effect Per year In total

CO2 emission 1.015 22.845

Air pollution 43.827 986.115

Accident costs 13.568 305.290

In total 58.411 1.314.251

All in all, after conducting the full socio-economic analysis, the results obtained for

both procurement approaches are indifferent. If the project is developed in the

same way in both of the cases, then the socio-economic values of these

approaches should be the same as it does not matter whether benefits such as

Page 52: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 52

reduction in CO2 or air pollution are provided by the private partner or by the

government. The results of the socio-economic analysis are presented below:

Table 7. Socio-economic analysis results

Results

Economic rate of return of investment 108,8%

Economic net present value of investment, thou. LTL 531.595

Discounted Benefit/Cost index 7,63

The socio-economic analysis could be further expanded by taking into account

other factors that are difficult to quantify and monetize, which, however, are still

useful in order to reveal the full picture of potential impacts the project has. The

additional factors include benefits, such as: decreased levels of noise, especially in

Kaunas and Klaipėda, and introduction of new services to the transport market, as

well as costs, such as: damaged scenery, in addition to possible river degradation

problems. Nevertheless, as the aim of this paper is analysing PPP and not

performing the full socio-economic analysis, the examination of the socio-economic

factors is limited to the most important ones, the ones monetized above.

2.4.5. SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS

Most of the investment projects incur substantial amount of risk and uncertainty

and in order to understand its effect on the results expected, sensitivity analysis

was performed. The idea behind sensitivity analysis is to point out variables that

impact the base scenario of the project most, especially the ones that might turn

the results of CBA from positive to negative ones. The sensitivity analysis may be

performed to a wide variety of variables, however in the case of the project

concerned and with the aim of comparing traditional and PPP procurement

approaches, the sensitivity analysis will be based on variables that may facilitate in

the decision of which procurement approach to choose.

To begin with, CBA’s results rely heavily on the assumption made regarding the

discount rates used, therefore, the first variable examined is the discount rate

attributable to the private and public sectors. The sensitivity analysis was

Page 53: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 53

conducted by changing values of the discount rate for each of the sector analysed,

i.e. applying 5% and 10% discount rates18.

The analysis shows that increasing the discount rate lowers the financial return on

both investment and capital.

The figure below shows the relationship between the discount rate and the FNPV

on investment from the point of view of the traditional procurement approach and

PPP, as if the same rate is used for both of the procurement modes, the return on

investment will be indifferent, if the rates used differ, then the net present value

accordingly differs. For example, if the rate used for the conventional procurement

approach is 6%, then the generated financial net present value is around 20.000

thou. LTL, whereas if the rate used for the PPP is 12%, then the project, from the

point of view of the PPP, is not beneficial, and should not be undertaken.

Figure 9. Sensitivity analysis – FNPV on investment

Financial return on capital, on the other hand, differs for the two procurement

approaches even if the same discount rate is used. For example, when 5%

discount rate is applied to the traditional procurement approach, the financial return

on capital is 26.158 thou. LTL, whereas for the private partner it is 25.048 thou.

LTL. However, when the same cash flows are discounted using a rate of 10%, the

results change significantly, and the more beneficial project implementation

approach appears to be the PPP option:

18

More detailed results of the sensitivity analysis are presented in the Appendix 8.

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

-5.000 0 5.000 10.000 15.000 20.000 25.000 30.000

Dis

co

un

t ra

te,

%

FNPV, thou. LTL

Financial NPV on investment

Page 54: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 54

Figure 10. Sensitivity analysis – FNPV on capital

As the figure above shows, when the high discount rate is used, the procurement

approach that delivers higher financial return on capital is PPP, however, when a

lower discount rate is used (lower than 6,18%), the more beneficial approach

regarding the financial net present value on capital, is the conventional

procurement approach. The reason for this is that the higher discount rate favours

projects that defer the expenditure and deliver benefits in short term (Shaoul,

2005). In this case, the short term cost outweighs benefits, whereas in the PPP

approach, due to the loan, costs are spread out over the years and therefore, the

difference between short term costs and benefits is smaller compared to the public

procurement case.

Considering the particular case when the 5% discount rate is used, the two

decision-making indicators, i.e. FRR/K and FNPV/K, seem to contradict. The

financial rate of return implies that PPP is the approach that delivers higher value.

From the financial net present value point of view the public procurement is more

beneficial. Even though the two decision making indicators seem to contradict, the

priority is given to the FNPV results as the internal rate of return may be

misleading, especially in the cases when the cash flows discounted have a

significant cash outflow in the middle (in this case it is year 15th) or at the end of the

project (European Commission 2008).

Finally, what concerns the socio-economic performance the discount rates affect

the results significantly, however, as the socio-economic benefits are really high,

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

0 5.000 10.000 15.000 20.000 25.000 30.000

Dis

co

un

t ra

te,

%

FNPV, thou. LTL

On public funds (traditional procurement) On private equity (PPP)

Page 55: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 55

increasing the discount rate up to 10%, still delivers substantial benefits equal to

329.770 thou. LTL. The socio-economic benefits are highly dependent on the

social discount rate, however, in the discussed range of rates, it is likely that the

project will generate additional welfare to the society.

Figure 11. Sensitivity analysis - Socio-economic results

The next part of the sensitivity analysis emphasises on the change in demand as it

is one of the most uncertain variables in the project concerned. The method

chosen here is similar to the one proposed above – the impact of change in

demand was examined by testing how a 5% and a 10% increase or decrease in

the demand affects the final results:

Table 8. Sensitivity analysis – change in demand

Change in demand19

5% -5% 10% -10%

Difference from the base scenario Traditional procurement approach

FNPV/C) 20,86% -20,86% 41,73% -41,71%

FNPV/K) 19,61% -19,61% 39,23% -39,21%

ENPV 5,48% -5,48% 10,96% -10,96%

Difference from the base scenario PPP

FNPV/C 43,78% -43,77% 87,58% -87,53%

FNPV/K on national capital 19,86% -19,85% 39,72% -39,70%

FNPV/K on private equity 30,38% -30,38% 60,78% -60,75%

ENPV 5,48% -5,48% 10,96% -10,96%

As the above table shows, the results are significantly influenced by changes in

demand, therefore, it should be acknowledged that the project is of a risky nature.

19

More detailed calculations are provided in the Appendix 7.

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

16%

0 100.000 200.000 300.000 400.000 500.000 600.000 700.000

Dis

co

un

t ra

te,

%

ENPV, thou. LTL

Socio-economic results

Page 56: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 56

The biggest impact is in the PPP case when a 10% decrease in demand results in

nearly 88% decrease in projected financial net present value of the base scenario

(6.364,2 thou. LTL). If the demand falls by 10%, the financial net present value of

the investment would be reduced to 793,7 thou. LTL.

Overall, it could be concluded that such an investment is highly risky, and it does

not seem to provide the appropriate returns for the risks expected. When the

conventional procurement approach is compared to the PPP approach, it appears

that changes in assumptions affect the traditional procurement’s results less. The

reason for that is that the government requires smaller rate of return compared to

the private partner and that the government might be willing to accept higher

financial risks in exchange for high socio-economic benefits.

2.4.6. OVERVIEW AND THE DISCUSSION OF THE CBA RESULTS

The cost-benefit analysis was used to evaluate the project from two perspectives:

procuring project through conventional procurement approach and PPP. The

analysis’ results show that the project from the socio-economic point of view is

beneficial regardless who assumes the responsibility for its implementation. The

desirability of the project’s development is represented by significant economic net

present value, which is 531.595 thou. LTL. The sensitivity analysis shows that

socio-economic results are directly dependent on the flow of containers as a

change in demand affects the benefits significantly, nevertheless, due to the

benefits being vast, a 10% decrease in projected demand still allows a project to

deliver substantial socio-economic benefits. Furthermore, taking into account the

benefit-cost ratio, the implementation of the project will results in discounted

economic benefits exceeding costs 7,6 times. However, this measure may be

misleading in some way as it depends heavily on whether a cash flow is defined as

a benefit or a cost reduction (European Commission, 2008). From the financial

point of view, the project generates more value if the government procures it as

opposed to the private partner: FNPV on the investment costs in the case of the

traditional procurement approach is 18.494,4 thou. LTL, 2,91 times more than the

Page 57: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 57

FNPV generated in a PPP case. The reason for that is the higher rate of return the

private partner requires compared to the public sector. If the assumption was made

that the two procurement approaches use the same discount rate, for example,

equal to the private partner’s rate of return, the project would deliver the same

financial rate of return on investment and higher rate of return on the capital

employed for the private partner. Nevertheless, as practice shows the rate of return

for the private partner is higher, therefore, with such an assumption in hand, the

public procurement generates more value. In addition, the project is highly risky as

it depends heavily on the change in demand. A 10% decrease in demand results in

a 42% decrease in FNPV on the investment costs in the traditional procurement

case and in a nearly 90% decrease in the PPP case. Moreover, as there is no

analogue for similar project in Lithuania, the project’s overall riskiness is further

increased. Consequently, the project’s success is uncertain, which is compounded

by the irreversibility of most of the investments (Brent, 2009). The risk could be

diminished if better market assessment was performed, however, at this stage with

the currently available data, it is unlikely that the private partner would get involved

in the project, even when a PPP is considered, as it delivers a non sufficient return

for the risks assumed. In addition, such uncertainty may affect the bank’s

eagerness to provide debt to the private partner as the bank prefers limited

exposure to risk, especially at this time as a result of the financial crisis. In a PPP

case, the debt is usually provided with project’s cash flows being the only collateral

to the bank (Akbiyikli et al., 2006). However, in this project, the cash flows are

highly uncertain, and therefore, it is unlikely that the bank would participate. In

order to attract the private partner, as well as the bank, the government should

consider the provision of guarantees or some kind of availability payment for a

certain period of time until the risk is diminished and the market becomes clearer.

Incorporating government’s guarantees would lower the riskiness of the project

and, as a result, make project more attractive for both the private partner as well as

banking sector. Nevertheless, it should be considered that due to guarantees, the

additional PPP value may be further reduced when compared to the conventional

procurement. With all this in mind, the public procurement is the option that from

Page 58: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 58

the economic point of view should be chosen as the one generating the highest

value.

2.5. FACTORS NOT COVERED BY CBA

The comparison of two procurement modes through the CBA shows that the

conventional procurement is the option that delivers higher value. Nevertheless,

the CBA is unable to take into account many factors that constitute the main

advantages of PPP. The CBA looks at the project from the cost and benefit point of

view, and the difference between the results for two procurement approaches lies

in the choice of the discount rate. In order to provide a more extensive discussion

on the two procurement modes, other factors that are not incorporated in the cost-

benefits analysis are reviewed.

In the project considered, the aspect that the government authority lacks the

expertise and know-how required to operate the wharf efficiently, is an important

reason to consider the involvement of the private partner. The private partner may

enhance the operations of the wharf by bringing in its innovation, expertise and

know-how, as well as motivation to act efficiently, on a timely basis and within the

budget. With these at hand, the private partner can deliver significant benefits

compared to the public sector. For example, delivering project earlier than

expected means realising socio-economic benefits quicker, which results in higher

value to the present society. However, in order to ensure that the private partner

has all incentives necessary to deliver benefits considered, the transfer of risks

should be performed. The transfer of risks motivates the private partner by

attaching additional responsibility and accountability. The appropriate risk

allocation is crucial as otherwise the efficiency gains will not be achieved and, as a

result, the involvement of the private partner in the partnership will not generate

any additional value, as was shown in the CBA.

In the traditional procurement approach, most of the risks involved in building,

financing, operating and maintaining the wharf are in the hands of the government,

i.e. the public authority is responsible for delivering the facility to the standards

Page 59: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 59

specified and services of the quality required, and if it fails to deliver what was

expected, the public funds are used in order to fix the failure. On the other hand,

with concession, most of the risks are transferred to the private partner, and in a

case of a risk appearing, it is the private partner that is responsible for dealing with

the risk and any costs incurred due to its occurrence. This is a substantial benefit

of concessions that was not incorporated in the CBA.

The potential risk transfer for the wharf’s project could be reviewed with regards to

the risk allocation matrix proposed by Chan et al. (2011) (Appendix 4). The reason

for choosing Chan et al. (2011) is that the paper reviews a wide range of literature

on risk management and provides a sophisticated review of 34 risk factors with

guidance towards an appropriate risk allocation. Some additional guidance has

been adopted from CPVA and Grimsey and Lewis (2002).

To begin with, the political risk group which includes risks such as government

corruption, intervention, nationalization, public credit and poor public decision-

making process should be retained by the government. The Lithuanian corruption

perception index during the last decade has ranged between 4,6 and 520, which

means that the country is perceived as fairly corrupt, especially in levels of political

parties, parliament, legislature, and judiciary (Transparency International, 2012).

Due to government being the only one having influence over this risk, the

corruption risk should be allocated to the public sector. The government

intervention, nationalization, and public credit risks are also under the control of the

government as it can intervene in private partner’s operations, seize the project

and chose whether to fulfil the responsibilities undertaken in the initial contract. In

order to secure the private partner that it will not be penalised for such

government’s actions, the risks mentioned are allocated to the government.

Furthermore, the risk of poor public decision-making process is especially relevant

to the wharf’s project, in particular when public-private partnerships are considered.

As was mentioned above, the PPP environment in Lithuania is not yet fully

20

Scale between 0 and 10, where 0 represents highly corrupt and 10 very clean countries (Transparency International, 2012).

Page 60: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 60

developed, and as a result, lack of PPP experience in the public sector might

influence the effectiveness of the project development. Moreover, the bureaucracy

in the public sector is also an obstacle for an efficient decision making, which

further amplifies the risk. As these risks are the responsibility of the government,

they should be retained with the public sector. The next risk group – economic

risks – is expected to be handled best by the private partner. Risks that are

associated with an interest rate and foreign exchange fluctuations are allocated to

the private partner in accordance to Chan et al. (2011) and CPVA. The financing

risk is also a responsibility of the private as it is the private partner that has to

organise the financing sources. Risks associated with inflation change are

allocated to the private partner (Chan et al., 2011). However, it should be

acknowledged that government’s decisions and actions also influence the change.

Consequently, the risk should be shared in such a way that the private partner

would not benefit from slow growth of the inflation rate, but at the same time, it

should not take the full consequences of high increases in inflation rate.

Furthermore, legal risks are usually assigned to the public sector. The reason for

that is that the public sector has the exclusive right to change the law or the tax

system which may harm the private partner’s operations. Risks incurred due to the

political or public opposition should be handled by the public as it is the strategic

decision of the government what projects to develop or abandon. Force majeure

risks cannot be controlled by any of the party, whether it is an earthquake or

flooding, and as such, should be shared by both public and private parties

(Grimsey & Lewis, 2004; CPVA). Environment risks should be also shared equally

due to ability of both parties to influence the risk equally. For example, private

partner should take the responsibility for its actions that are hazardous. On the

other hand, if the government increases the requirements regarding the

environment that may influence the operations of the private party, then the

government should assume the consequences incurred. Moving on to the specific

project risks, all of construction and operation risks should be assumed by the

private partner. The reason for that is that in the concession, the private partner

receives the full responsibility for day-to-day operations and is fully responsible for

Page 61: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 61

designing, constructing and maintaining the facilities concerned, in this case – the

wharf. Private partner should assume completion, material and labour non-

availability, unproven engineering techniques, project’s operations, operation cost

overruns, as well as price change risks. These risks may be further extended to

include site condition and preparation risks, other technical risks, such as design

and keeping the facilities to the standard required. On the other hand, risk

described as market competition should be handled by the public sector due to its

ability to develop an additional project that may influence the demand projections

that the private partner has initially expected to receive. In the case of the wharf’s

project that means that if the government decides to build another wharf in

between Kaunas and Klaipeda, then the risk would occur that a part of the initial

demand might be transferred to the new project and, as a result, the private

partner’s profitability would be affected. Moving onto the changes in the market

demand, this risk should be captured by the private partner as it has control over

the business and is able to adjust it in order to keep its market share. As far as the

relationship risk group is concerned, the private partner should take the

responsibility for the third party delays and violations as it is the private partner that

deals with the third parties and it is private partner’s choice which parties to involve

in the process of delivering the service to the public. Risks such as organization

and coordination of the project should be also transferred to the private partner, as

well as concessionaire’s ability to deliver the responsibilities assumed.

Concessionaire should deliver the service as agreed and in case of a failure,

financial penalties should be considered. Other risks – land acquisition, delay in

project approvals and permits and lack of supporting infrastructure – should be

assumed by the government as it is the government that is in the perfect position to

control them. In addition, public sector should also take the responsibility for

collecting the approvals and permits necessary for projects’ implementation, as

well as it should ensure that the private partner has an access to the supporting

infrastructure that the government promised to the private partner. Finally, the risk

of residual value should be attached to the private partner as it is the private

partner that operates the asset for the period of concession and then transfers it

Page 62: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 62

back to the government. In order to ensure that value is captured, the responsibility

should be assigned to the private partner as otherwise the private partner may

have an incentive to overuse the assets concerned.

It should be acknowledged that the risk identification and allocation presented

above is a pure recommendation towards the project considered. The proposed

risk allocation model could change when the pricing of the risks comes into the

consideration. This may happen if a public sector desires to transfer a certain risk

to the private partner. However, private partner believes that it is not in the most

suitable position to manage the risk effectively and at least costs, and due to that,

requires a premium for taking the risk concerned. The premiums required for the

risks transferred may influence the risk allocation model and, consequently,

decrease the initial estimate of value for money.

Comparing the proposed risk allocation model in the case of PPP with the

traditional procurement approach proves that a significant part of risks may be

removed from the government’s hands and transferred to the private partner’s.

This has a value that would change the results of the CBA, however, it is

questionable whether the value would be high enough to outweigh the benefits of a

traditional procurement approach valued in CBA. In order to answer this question,

the PSC should be conducted and in such a way that the estimate for VFM could

be determined.

The final note that needs to be considered is a potential aim of the government

authority to have a project implemented by using private sector’s funds as opposed

to the publics’. The reason for that is that the government authority may lack the

funds required to implement the project immediately. However, such an aim should

not prevail as it gives incentives for the government authority to favour PPPs even

though they do not deliver the necessary value for money. It is especially a crucial

note when the long term characteristics of the contracts are considered, and from

this it follows that the PPP in the long term may turn out to be a more expensive

option compared to the traditional procurement approach.

Page 63: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 63

All in all, factors that are not covered by CBA have a high value when PPP

advantages are considered. The valuation of these advantages may have an

impact on the CBA decision whether to implement a project through PPP or

conventional procurement approach. Therefore, it is recommended to conduct a

PSC and compare it to PPP, and the difference in values of the two will facilitate

the more extensive decision.

3. CONCLUSIONS

Public private partnership is a way to procure public projects in order to achieve

additional value for money in terms of efficiency and higher quality of services.

Interest in delivering projects through PPPs is increasing as the advantages they

deliver seem to overcome the issues currently outstanding: inefficient provision of

public services, wasteful use of public funds, delivering projects late and over the

budget expected, etc. Nevertheless, PPPs are very complex and expensive. In

order to construct a PPP, large preparation and bidding costs arise and, as a

result, only very specific and complex projects are granted the option to be

considered for PPPs.

As a result of such contrasting arguments for and against PPPs, the thesis aimed

to explore the concept of public private partnership and its implication for the

procurement of public projects. This has been achieved by reviewing the relevant

literature and performing an analysis on a particular project. The analysis consisted

of two parts: first, the project was analyzed through the CBA technique, where the

conventional procurement approach was compared to the public-private

partnership, a concession, second, where other PPP relevant factors, which were

not incorporated in the CBA, were reviewed and discussed.

The literature overview defined and explained the PPP concept and illustrated what

PPP is, and what advantages and disadvantages this kind of partnership delivers.

In addition, the reasons for PPP implementation were reviewed and circumstances

surrounding them were explored. The question raised in the introduction part of the

paper – why PPPs represent such small fraction of all public projects if they deliver

Page 64: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 64

benefits such as greater efficiency, timely delivery of public projects, better quality

of service provision, etc. – was answered by identifying significant shortcomings

and criticisms these partnerships encompass.

The analysis part of the paper focused on the particular project, comparing the two

procurement options available – conventional procurement approach and PPP.

The paper investigated whether PPP scheme was a suitable procurement

approach for the particular Lithuanian infrastructure project and identified the

concession as the adequate PPP form. The comparison of two procurement

approaches was carried out by employing a CBA technique. The CBA results

proved that from the financial point of view, the conventional procurement

approach delivered higher value than a PPP. The reason for such an outcome lies

in the assumption that private and public sectors employ different discount rates,

i.e. private partner using a higher one. Sensitivity analysis showed that when the

discount rates are indifferent, the PPP delivers higher benefits in case of high

discount rates (above 6,18%), whereas the traditional procurement approach

prevails over PPP when low discount rates are in use (below 6,18%). The next

component of CBA was the socio-economic analysis, which proved project’s socio-

economic benefits to be substantial. The outcome of the analysis showed that the

society is indifferent of who delivers the project, whether the public or private

sector, as long as the project is implemented in the same way.

The second part of the analysis overviewed other factors’, which were not covered

by CBA, impact on the decision based on CBA results. CBA assumes that both

procurement approaches develop the project in the same way, with the same

materials, technologies, time necessary to implement a project, etc. However, what

PPP offers is the possibility to implement a project through a different way where

private partner’s skills, innovation, expertise, and know-how are utilized. In order to

ensure the realization of PPPs’ advantages, the appropriate risk allocation has to

be employed as it motivates the private partner to deliver the project on time, at

least-cost, to the quality requested, as well as to provide services to the standard

expected. The transfer of risks can be valued and attached to the results generated

Page 65: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 65

by CBA. However, in order to do this, the techniques of evaluating PSC should be

employed.

To conclude, the paper provides an overview and discussion on the concept of

PPP and its effects on the procurement of public projects. The analysis part,

dedicated to a particular infrastructure project, recognised that if only the CBA is

considered, the project should be implemented through the traditional procurement

approach, however, when other PPP related factors, that were not incorporated in

the CBA, are considered, then a more detailed analysis should be carried out in

terms of conducting a PSC and comparing it to the potential PPP proposal, as a

PPP option in the wharf’s project seems to deliver a variety of potential advantages

that were overlooked in the CBA.

Page 66: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 66

4. B IBLIOGRAPHY

Akbiyikli, R., Eaton, D., & Turner, A. L. (2006). Project Finance and the Private

Finance Initiative (PFI). The Journal of Structured Finance, 12(2), 65-75.

Akintoye, A., Beck, M., & Hardcastle, C. (2003). Public-Private partnerships.

Managing risks and opportunities. Oxford: Blackwell Science Ltd.

Amekudzi, A., & Morallos, D. (2008). The State of the Practice of Value for Money

Analysis in Comparing Public Private Partnerships to Traditional

Procurements. Public Works Management & Policy, 13(2), 114-125.

Belli, P., Anderson, J., Barnum, H., Dixon, J., & Tan, J.-P. (1998). Handbook on

Economic Analysis of Investment Operations. Washington D.C.: Operational

Core Services Network Learning and Leadership Center, World Bank.

Belli, P., Anderson, J., Barnum, H., Dixon, J., & Tan, J.-P. (2001). Economic

Analysis of Investment Operations. Analytical Tools and Practical

Applications. Washington D.C.: WBI, World Bank.

Bing, L., Akintoye, A., Edwards, P. J., & Hardcastle, C. (2005). The allocation of

risk in PPP/PFI construction projects in the UK. International Journal of

Project Management, 23(1), 25-35.

Boardman, E., Greenberg, D. H., & Vining, A. R. (2011). Cost-Benefit Analysis:

concepts and practice (4 ed.). New Jersey: Pearson Education.

Brent, R. J. (2009). Handbook of Research on Cost-Benefit Analysis. Cheltenham:

Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

Campbell, H. F., & Brown, P. C. B. (2003). Benefit-Cost Analysis: Financial and

Economic Appraisal using Spreadsheets. Cambridge, United Kingdom:

Press Syndicate of the University of Cambridge.

Chan, A., Yeung, J., Yu, C., Wang, S., & Ke, Y. (2011). Empirical Study of Risk

Assessment of Public-Private Partnership Projects in China. Journal of

Management in Engineering, 27(3), 136-148.

Page 67: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 67

Cheung, E., Chan, A. P. C., & Kajewski, S. (2009). Reasons for implementing

public private partnership projects: Perspectives from Hong Kong, Australian

and British practitioners. Journal of Property Investment & Finance, 27(1),

81-95.

CPVA. Rekomendacijos viešojo ir privataus sektorių partnerystės (VPSP) projektų

galimybių studijų rengimui. (Journal Article). Retrieved from

http://www.ppplietuva.lt/images/files/metodikos/07_21_PGS_rengimo_reko

mendacijos.pdf

Daube, D., Vollrath, S., & Alfen, H. W. (2007). A comparison of Project Finance

and the Forfeiting Model as financing forms for PPP projects in Germany.

International Journal of Project Management, 26(4), 376-387.

Deloitte Research. (2006). Closing the infrastructure gap: the role of public-private

partnerships: Deloitte Development LLC.

EIB. (2004). The EIB's role in Public-Private Partnerships (PPPs). Retrieved from

http://www.eib.org/attachments/thematic/eib_ppp_en.pdf

EIB. (2010). Public-Private Partnerships in Europe - before and during the recent

financial crisis Economic and Financial Report. European Investment Bank.

European Commission. (2003). Guidelines for successful public-private

partnerships. Brussels: Directorate-General Regional Policy.

European Commission. (2004). Green Paper on Public-Private Partnerships and

Community Law on Public Contracts and Concessions. Brussels.

European Commission. (2005). Public-Private Partnerships: Models and Trends in

the European Union. Brussels: DG Internal Policies of the Union.

European Commission. (2008). Guide to Cost-Benefit Analysis of investment

projects: Structural Funds, Cohesion Fund and Instrument for Pre-

Accession Retrieved from

http://ec.europa.eu/regional_policy/sources/docgener/guides/cost/guide2008

_en.pdf

Page 68: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 68

European Commission. (2011). White Paper: Roadmap to a Single European

Transport Area – Towards a competitive and resource efficient transport

system Retrieved from http://eur-

lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=COM:2011:0144:FIN:EN:PDF

Evans, D. J., & Sezer, H. (2005). Social discount rates for member countries of the

European Union. Journal of Economic Studies, 32(1), 47-59.

Flyvbjerg, B., Holm, M. S., & Buhl, S. (2002). Underestimating Costs in Public

Works Projects: Error or Lie? Journal of the American Planning Association,

68(3), 279 - 295.

Goldbach, C., Goldman, V., Phillips, R., & Seymour, A. (2012). Public Cost

Comparator for Public-Private Partnerships. National Council for Private-

Public Partnerships(Journal Article).

Gray, M. (2004). Discounted Cash Flow (DCF) International Benchmark: Australian

Public Private Partnerships-Model Public Private Partnerships: Gestaltung

aus ökonomischer und juristischer Sicht (pp. 53-100). Wien: LexisNexis

ARD ORAC.

Grimsey, D., & Lewis, M. K. (2002). Evaluating the risks of public private

partnerships for infrastructure projects. International Journal of Project

Management, 20(Journal Article), 107-118.

Grimsey, D., & Lewis, M. K. (2004). Public Private Partnerships: The Worldwide

Revolution in Infrastructure Provision and Project Finance. Cheltenham:

Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

Grimsey, D., & Lewis, M. K. (2005). Are Public Private Partnerships value for

money? Evaluating alternative approaches and comparing academic and

practitioner views. Accounting Forum, 29(4), 345-378.

Grout, P. A. (2003). Public and Private Sector Discount Rates in Public-Private

Partnerships. The Economic Journal, 113(486), C62-C68.

Page 69: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 69

Harris, S. (2004). Public Private Partnerships: Delivering Better Infrastructure

Services. Working Paper, Inter-American Development Bank, Working

Paper(Journal Article).

HM Treasury. (2003). The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central

Governmnet Retrieved from http://www.hm-

treasury.gov.uk/d/green_book_complete.pdf

Hodge, G. A. (2004). The risky business of public-pivate partnerships. Australian

Journal of Public Administration, 63(Journal Article), 37-49.

Hodge, G. A., & Greve, C. (2007). Public-Private Partnerships: An International

Performance Review. Public Administration Review, 67(3), 545-558.

Hong Kong Efficiency Unit. (2008). Serving the community by using the private

sector: An introductory guide to public private partnerships (PPP): Hong

Kong Special Administrative Region Government.

IMF. (2004). Public Private Partnerships. Washington, DC: IMF Fiscal Affairs

Departments.

IMF. (2006). Public-Private Partnerships. In R. Hemming (Ed.). Tunis: Fiscal Affairs

Department, International Monetary Fund.

Infras/IWW. (2004). External Costs of Transport: Update Study. Zurich/Karlsruhe

Li, B., Akintoye, A., & Hardcastle, C. (2001, 2001). Risk analysis and allocation in

public private partnership projects. Paper presented at the 17th Annual

ARCOM Conference.

Lithuanian Inland Waterway Authority. (2008). Inland waterways, from

http://www.liwa.lt/lt/menu/internal_waters#

Maski, E., & Tirole, J. (2008). Public-private partnerships and government

spending limits. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 26, 412-420.

Meidute, I., & Paliulis, N. K. (2011). Feasibility study of public-private partnership.

International Journal of Strategic Property Management, 16(5), 257-274.

Page 70: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 70

Ministry of Municipal Affairs. (1999). Public Private Partnership: A Guide for Local

Government. Canada: The Government of British Columbia Retrieved from

http://europeandcis.undp.org/files/uploads/PPP/PPP_GuideFor%20Local%2

0Gov.pdf

Ministry of Transport and Communications of the Republic of Lithuania. (2011).

Order No.3-100 on the Procedure attibutable to acquisition of road vehicles

where energy efficiency and environmental protection requirements are set

situations, when these must be applied, are identified Vilnius.

National Audit Office. (2003). PFI: Construction Performance Report by the

Comptroller and Auditor General. London: HMSO.

New South Wales Government. Working with Government: Guidelines for Privately

Financed Projects. 2001(Journal Article).

Ng, T., Xie, J., Cheung, Y., & Jefferies, M. (2007). A simulation model for

optimizing the concession period of public–private partnerships schemes.

International Journal of Project Management, 25, 791-798.

Nisar, T. M. (2006). Risk Management in Public-Private Partnership Contracts.

Public Organization Review(Journal Article).

OECD. (2006). Cost-Benefit Analysis and the Environment: recent developments.

Paris: OECD.

OECD. (2008). Public-Private Partnerships: in pursuit of risk sharing and value for

money. Paris: OECD.

Partnerships Victoria. (2001). Public Sector Comparator Technical Note. Victoria,

Australia: Department of Treasury Finance.

PwC. (2005). Delivering the PPP promise: a review of PPP issues and activity:

PricewaterhouseCoopers.

Quiggin, J. (2004). Risk, PPPs and the Public Sector Comparator. Australian

Accounting Review, 14(2), 51-61.

Page 71: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 71

Robinson, P. (2000). The Private FInance Initiative: the real story. Consumer

Policy Review, 10(3), 82-85.

Sarmento, J. M. (2010). Do Public-private Partnerships Create Value for Moeny for

the Public Sector? The Portuguese Experience. OECD Journal on

Budgeting, 1.

Seimas of the Republic of Lithuania. (2012a). Republic of Lithuania: Law on

Concessions No.I-1510. Vilnius.

Seimas of the Republic of Lithuania. (2012b). Republic of Lithuania: Law on

Investment, No.VIII-1312. Vilnius.

Seimas of the Republic of Lithuania. (2012c). Republic of Lithuania: Law on

Management, Use and Disposal of State and Municipal Authorities’

Property, No.VIII-729. Vilnius.

Shaoul, J. (2005). A critical financial analysis of the Private Finance Initiative:

selecting a financing method or allocating economic wealth? Critical

Perspectives on Accounting, 16, 441-471.

Stevens, A. (2004). The application and limitations of cost-benefits assessment

(CBA) for intelligent transport systems. Research in Transportation

Economics, 8, 91-111.

Tanga, L., Shena, Q., & Chengb, E. W. L. (2010). A review of studies on Public-

Private Partnership projects in the construction industry. International

Journal of Project Management, 28(7), 683-694.

The European Chemical Industry Council (Cefic). (2011). Guidelines for Measuring

and Managing CO2 Emissions from Freight Transport Operations. (1).

Retrieved from http://www.cefic.org/Documents/IndustrySupport/Transport-

and-Logistics/Best%20Practice%20Guidelines%20-

%20General%20Guidelines/Cefic-

ECTA%20Guidelines%20for%20measuring%20and%20managing%20CO2

%20emissions%20from%20transport%20operations%20Final%2030.03.201

1.pdf

Page 72: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 72

Transparency International. (2012). Corruption by country/territory Retrieved

23.07.2012, from http://www.transparency.org/country#LTU_PublicOpinion

Weihe, G. (2006). Public-Private Partnerships: Addressing a Nebulous Concept

(Vol. Working Paper No.16). Copenhagen: International Center for Business

and Politics, Copenhagen Business School.

Page 73: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 73

5. APPENDICES

AP P ENDI X 1: Comparison of public investment and PPP as a percentage of GDP

in European countries ............................................................................................... 74

AP P ENDI X 2: Relationship structure of a conventional procurement approach and

PPP ............................................................................................................................ 75

AP P ENDI X 3: The structure of PPP agreements: turnkey delivery and concession

................................................................................................................................... 77

AP P ENDI X 4: Risk allocation model adopted from Chan et al. (2011, p. 140):...... 78

AP P ENDI X 5: Location of a wharf ............................................................................ 83

APPEND IX 6: The average cost of equity (rate of return) ....................................... 84

APPEND IX 7: GDP deflator and the average growth of per capita consumption ... 85

APPEND IX 8: Sensitivity analysis ............................................................................ 87

Page 74: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 74

APPENDIX 1: Comparison of public investment and PPP as a percentage of

GDP in European countries

Source: Adopted from EIB (2010, p. 17)

*FR – France, DE – Germany, EL – Greece, ES – Spain, HU – Hungary, IE – Ireland, IT – Italy, NL – Netherlands, PT – Portugal, UK – United Kingdom; **UK/1 estimate of EIB, UK/2 estimate of HMT.

Page 75: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 75

APPENDIX 2: Relationship structure of a conventional procurement approach

and PPP

In the traditional procurement in order to deliver the services and infrastructure

required, the government acts as an intermedeary – on the one side it deals with

direct users of the services, taxpayers, and financial markets, and on the other side

– with other private companies (the scheme represented below). The idea behind

such a flow of relationships is that the government gathers financing from side A

and uses it to remunerate side B which provides capital goods necessary for the

public service provision and infrastructure development.

Source: OECD (2008, p. 41)

If the project is handled through a public-private partnership, the intermediary role

of the government is decreased – public authority deals with the taxpayers and the

single private operator only. The role of the private operator, on the other hand, is

enhanced: private operator becomes responsible for handling relationships

between side A and side B. Here private operator takes the main role of the

intermediary – it collects financing from side A (direct users of the service and

financial market) and remunerates side B (other private companies) for the capital

goods provided (the scheme represented below). If the private operator acts in

Page 76: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 76

accordance to the performance standard specified, in some of the cases 21, it

receives additional payment from the government (Maski & Tirole, 2008).

Source: OECD (2008, p. 41)

21

The private operator may be remunerated in three ways: through direct user charges only, through government payment only, or through a combination of both of the payments (Grimsey & Lewis, 2004).

Page 77: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 77

APPENDIX 3 : The structure of PPP agreements: turnkey delivery and

concession

Source: European Commission (2003, p. 18)

Page 78: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 78

APPENDIX 4 : Risk allocation model adopted from Chan et al. (2011, p. 140):

Risk group Risk Risk description Risk allocation

Systematic risk category

Political risks Government corruption

The behaviour of the corruption of government

officials will increase the cost of keeping the relationships between the government and the project company. Meanwhile, it will increase the

risk of contract breaking by the government.

Public

Government intervention

Government officials intervene in the project operations directly, which will affect the autonomy of private investors’ decision making.

Public

Nationalization/expropriation Central or local government seizes the projects. Public

Public credit

The rejection of government to implement the responsibilities agreed in the contract, which brings direct or indirect damages

Public

Poor public decision-making process

Non-standardized procedures, bureaucracy, lacking of PPP project experience and ability, insufficient preparation and information asymmetry,

leading to poor decision making.

Public

Economic risks Interest rate fluctuation

The loss of PPP projects arising from the

uncertainties of the interest rate volatility.

Private

Foreign exchange fluctuation

The risk of the variability of foreign currencies exchange and the foreign currencies

exchangeability risk.

Private

Inflation

The increase of the price level of the commodities,

the decrease of purchasing power of currencies, which cause the increase of cost and other consequence.

Private

Page 79: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 79

Financing risk

The risk arising from the irrational financing structure, unsound financial market, and difficulty in financing.

Private

Legal risks Legislation change

Change of law and regulations and other government macroscopic economic policies will cause the increase in project costs and decrease

in revenue, etc.

Public

Imperfect law and supervision

system

The damage arising from the current PPP

legislation which is low level, low effectiveness, conflict bearing, and poor operability.

Public

Change in tax regulation The change in tax regulation of central or local government.

Public

Social risks Political/public opposition

For various reasons leading to the public interest being unprotected and damaged, which, as a

consequence, causes political and even public opposition to the risk of the project construction.

Public

Natural risks Force majeure

Before signing contract, the contract party cannot control or prevent reasonably. When the events happen, the situation cannot be escaped or

conquered, such as a worker strike, or other unforeseen items that are not “natural” risks.

Public

Unforeseen weather/geotechnical conditions

Because of the project site’s bad natural conditions, for example, climate condition, special geographical environment, and poor site

conditions, etc.

Private

Environment risk

Because of the increasing requirement of the

government or social organization regarding the environment protection, risk generated from the project cost increase, delay in work schedule, or

other loss.

Equally shared

Specific project risk category

Page 80: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 80

Construction risks Completion risk

Project delay and cost overrun, etc., which cause insufficient cash flow and inability to pay off debts on time.

Private

Material/labour non-availability Loss because of delay in raw materials, resources, machines and equipment, or energy supply.

Private

Unproven engineering

techniques

The techniques adopted are immature and cannot

fulfil the standards and requirements as expected, or the techniques are of poor applicability which makes private investors to reinvest for the

technology improvement.

Private

Operation risks Project/operation changes

Poor constructability in design phase, design error or vagueness, standards and contracts variation, owners’ variation leading to the project, or

operation changes.

Private

Operation cost overrun

Government raises the standard of the products or

services leading to the cost overrun by the non-commercial factors such as increase in interest rates, exchange rates or force majeure, or poor

operation management.

Private

Price change

Price of PPP products or services are too high, too low, or inflexible to adjust, leading to the revenue of the project company lower than expected.

Private

Expense payment risk Infrastructure of the project or the process of the service provision is affected by other factors which

prevents the timely payment of the client’s (or government’s) fees.

Private

Market risks Market competition (uniqueness)

An actual market competition of the existing project caused by the new project or rebuild project of government or other investors.

Public

Page 81: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 81

Change in market demand Apart from the risk from arising from market competition, factors attributed to macroeconomics, social environment, change in population,

adjustment of laws, and regulations leading to the change in market demand.

Private

Relationship risks Third-party delay/violation

Apart from government or private investors, other

project participants do not implement the responsibilities agreed in the contract or project delay.

Private

Organization and coordination risk

Because of the insufficient coordination ability of project company, the cost of communication

among project participants increases and conflicts occurs.

Private

Inability of the concessionaire

The insufficient ability of the concessionaire leading to low productivity of project construction and operation.

Private

Other risks Land acquisition

The increase in project cost and extension of project duration caused by the difficulty of acquiring the rights of the land. The cost and time

for land acquisition exceeds the original plans.

Public

Delay in project approvals and permits

Complicated procedures are required for project approval with high cost and long time. Upon

approval, it is very difficult to proceed business adjustments regarding the project scope and nature.

Public

Conflicting or imperfect

contract

The risk of the contract with inaccuracy,

vagueness, inflexibility, inconsistency, inequitable risk-sharing, unclear division of responsibility, etc.

Private

Lack of supporting infrastructure

The risks generated by the unavailability of the supporting facilities of the project.

Public

Page 82: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 82

Residual risk

Investors overuse the resources like equipment or other technical conditions, etc., which cause insufficient materials and equipment with

depreciation at the end of the concession period. As a consequence, it affects the continuous operation of the projects.

Private

Inadequate competition for tender

The risk includes unfair, non-transparent tendering process, incomplete tender information, insufficient

number of tenders, vicious market competition, and bidding lowest price to win the tenders.

Public

Page 83: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 83

APPENDIX 5 : Location of a wharf

The wharf is going to be located in Kaunas (green star in the figure), in such a way

connecting Kaunas and Klaipėda, where the most important Lithuanian transport

point, connecting road, rail and sea transport, locates.

Source: Adopted from Lithuanian Inland Waterway Authority (2008)

Page 84: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 84

APPENDIX 6: The average cost of equity (rate of return)

Company name ROE, 2011 m.

1. TEO LT 15,4%

2. Klaipėdos Nafta 9,5%

3. Utenos Trikotažas 16,4%

4. Lietuovs Dujos 4,6%

5. Apranga 20,2%

6. Rokiškio sūris 9,6%

7. Grigiškės 13,8%

8. City Service 16,5%

9. Kauno energija 5,1%

10. Vilniaus baldai 31,9%

Average 14,3% *All data has been extracted from the financial accounts of the corresponding companies, available at http://www.nasdaqomxbaltic.com

Page 85: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 85

APPENDIX 7: GDP deflator and the average growth of per capita consumption

I. GDP deflator:

Year GDP deflator

Base year 2000* Base year 2000*

1995 70.353 0,436

1996 84.548 0,524

1997 95.044 0,589

1998 99.647 0,617

1999 98.812 0,612

2000 100.000 0,620

2001 99.745 0,618

2002 99.795 0,618

2003 98.875 0,613

2004 101.510 0,629

2005 107.259 0,664

2006 114.314 0,708

2007 124.171 0,769

2008 136.122 0,843

2009 145.416 0,901

2010 151.438 0,938

2011 155.944 0,966

2012 161.418 1,000

2013 165.556 1,026 * Data is extracted from Data and Statistics database of the International Monetary Fund (http://www.imf.org); ** Own calculations based on the data extracted from International Monetary Fund database.

II. The average growth of per capita consumption:

Year

Household

consumption at current

prices,

Mln. LTL*

Household

consumption at constant prices (base year - 2012 ),

Mln. LTL**

Average number of

inhabitants*

Household income per

capita,

Mln. LTL

Change, %

1995 17.051 39.122 3.629.100 0,010780

1996 21.792 41.605 3.601.600 0,011552 7%

1997 25.025 42.501 3.575.200 0,011888 3%

1998 28.132 45.571 3.549.300 0,012840 8%

1999 29.220 47.733 3.524.200 0,013544 5%

2000 30.437 49.131 3.499.500 0,014040 4%

2001 32.572 52.712 3.481.300 0,015142 8%

2002 34.583 55.938 3.469.100 0,016125 6%

Page 86: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 86

2003 37.709 61.562 3.454.200 0,017822 11%

2004 41.819 66.499 3.435.600 0,019356 9%

2005 47.578 71.602 3.414.300 0,020971 8%

2006 54.329 76.716 3.394.100 0,022603 8%

2007 63.153 82.097 3.375.600 0,024321 8%

2008 72.285 85.718 3.358.100 0,025526 5%

2009 62.605 69.494 3.339.400 0,020810 -18%

2010 61.101 65.128 3.286.800 0,019815 -5%

Average 4,41%

* Data extracted from The Lithuanian Department of Statistics (Statistics Lithuania) at http://www.stat.gov.lt/lt/; ** Own calculations based on data extracted from The Lithuanian Department of Statistics.

Page 87: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 87

APPENDIX 8: Sensitivity analysis

Change in discount rate:

Traditional

procurement

PPP Traditional

procurement

PPP

Discount rate, % 5% 10%

Financial return on investment

FRR/C , % 11,2% 11,2% 11,2% 11,2%

FNPV/C, thou. LTL 23.812,1 23.812,1 2.843,2 2.843,2

Financial return on capital

FRR/K , % 11,6% 14,1% 11,6% 14,1%

FNPV/K, thou. LTL 26.158,1 25.047,8 3.868,2 6.478,7

Economic performance indicators

ERR, % 108,8% 108,8%

ENPV, thou. LTL 595.602,5 329.770,3

Discounted B/C index 7,91 6,51

Changes in demand, PPP and traditional procurement approach:

Base scenario

Change in demand

5% -5% 10% -10%

Traditional Procurement

FRR/C 11,2% 12,2% 10,2% 13,2% 9,1%

FNPV/C, thou. LTL 18.494 22.353 14.636 26.212 10.780

FRR/K 11,6% 12,6% 10,6% 13,6% 9,5%

FNPV/K, thou. LTL 20.522 24.547 16.497 28.573 12.474

ERR 108,8% 113,1% 104,3% 117,4% 99,8%

ENPV, thou. LTL 531.594 560.717 502.471 589.840 473.349

Discounted B/C index 7,63 7,91 7,35 8,18 7,06

Difference from the base scenario

FNPV/C 20,86% -20,86% 41,73% -41,71%

FNPV/C 19,61% -19,61% 39,23% -39,21%

ENPV 5,48% -5,48% 10,96% -10,96%

Public-private partnership

FRR/C 11,2% 12,2% 10,2% 13,2% 9,1%

FNPV/C, thou. LTL 6.364 9.150 3.578 11.937 793

FRR/K on national capital 14,1% 15,7% 12,5% 17,3% 10,9%

FNPV/K on national capital, thou. LTL 20.269 24.295 16.245 28.321 12.222

FRR/K on private equity 14,1% 15,7% 12,5% 17,3% 10,9%

FNPV/K on private equity, thou. LTL 9.537 12.435 6.640 15.333 3.743

ERR 108,8% 113,1% 104,3% 117,4% 99,8%

Page 88: Analysing Public-Private Partnership - AU Purepure.au.dk/portal/files/48150942/MSc_thesis_Jurgita_Jakutyte.pdf · Analysing Public-Private Partnership ... Problem statement ... WACC

Page | 88

ENPV, thou. LTL 531.594 560.717 502.471 589.840 473.349

Discounted B/C index 7,63 7,91 7,35 8,18 7,06

Difference from the base scenario

FNPV (C) 43,78% -43,77% 87,58% -87,53%

FNPV (K) on national capital 19,86% -19,85% 39,72% -39,70%

FNPV (K) on private equity 30,38% -30,38% 60,78% -60,75%

ENPV 5,48% -5,48% 10,96% -10,96%