angeletos - macro intermedia mit 2013 geletos - macro intermedia mit 2013-01-02 introd solow model

93
14.05 Lecture Notes Introduction and The Solow Model George-Marios Angeletos MIT Department of Economics February 20, 2013 1

Upload: rhroca2762

Post on 15-Dec-2015

7 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

DESCRIPTION

Macroeconomics

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes

Introduction and The Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

MIT Department of Economics

February 20, 2013

1

Page 2: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

1 Preliminaries

• In the real world, we observe for each country time series of macroeconomic variables such as

aggregate output (GDP), consumption, investment, employment, unemployment, etc. These

are the typical data that concern the macroeconomist.

• We also observe certain patterns (correlations, stylized facts) either over time or in the cross-

section. For example, here is a pattern in the time-series dimension: during booms and

recessions, output, consumption, investment and unemployment all move together in the

same direction. And here is a pattern in the cross-section: richer countries tend to have more

capital.

• Understanding what lies beneath these patterns and deriving lessons that can guide policy is

the job of the macroeconomist. But “understanding” for the formal economist does not mean

just telling a “story” of the short you can find in the financial news or the blogosphere. It

means to develop a coherent, self-consistent, formal explanation of all the relevant observed

patterns.

2

Page 3: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• To this goal, macroeconomists develop and work with mathematical models. Any such model

abstracts from the infinity of forces that may be at play in the real world, focuses on a few

forces that are deemed important, and seeks to work out how these forces contribute towards

generating the observed patterns.

• Any such model thus features abstract concepts that are meant to mimic certain aspects of

the world. There are “households” and “firms” in our models that are meant to be proxies

for real-world people and businesses. And they are making choices whose product at the

aggregate level is some times series for aggregate output, employment, etc. We thus end up

with a mathematical model that generates the kind of times series we also observe in the real

world. And by figuring how these times series are generated in the model, we hope to also

understand some of the forces behind the actual macroeconomic phenomena.

3

Page 4: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• In this lecture note, we will go over our first, basic, mathematical model of the macroeconomy:

the Solow model. We are going to use this model extensively to understand economic growth

over time and in the cross-section of countries. But we are also going to use it to standard

understanding economic fluctuations and the economic impact of various policies. All in all,

we will thus see how a very simple—in fact, ridiculously simple—mathematical model can

give us a lot of insight about how the macroeconomy works.

• On the way, we will also familiarize ourselves with formal notions that we will use in subsequent

richer models, including the difference (or coincidence) between market outcomes and socially

optimal outcomes.

• In particular, we will start analyzing the model by pretending that there is a social planner, or

“benevolent dictator”, that chooses the static and intertemporal allocation of resources and

dictates these allocations to the households and firms of the economy. We will later show that

the allocations that prevail in a decentralized competitive market environment coincide with

the allocations dictated by the social planner (under certain assumptions).

4

Page 5: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Be aware of the following. To talk meaningfully of a benevolent social planner, we need to have

well specified preferences for the households of the economy. This is not going to be the case

in the Solow model. Nevertheless, we will establish a certain isomorphism between centralized

and decentralized allocations as a prelude to a similar exercise that we will undertake in the

Ramsey model, where preferences are going to be well specified. This isomorphism is going

to be the analogue within the Solow model of an important principle that you should know

more generally for a wide class of convex economies without externalities and other market

frictions: for such economies, the two welfare theorems apply, guaranteeing the set of Pareto

Optimal allocations coincides with the set of Competitive Equilibria.

5

Page 6: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

2 Introduction and stylized facts about growth

• How can countries with low level of GDP per person catch up with the high levels enjoyed by

the United States or the G7?

• Only by high growth rates sustained for long periods of time.

• Small differences in growth rates over long periods of time can make huge differences in final

outcomes.

• US per-capita GDP grew by a factor ≈ 10 from 1870 to 2000: In 1995 prices, it was $3300

in 1870 and $32500 in 2000.1 Average growth rate was ≈ 1.75%. If US had grown with .75%

(like India, Pakistan, or the Philippines), its GDP would be only $8700 in 1990 (i.e., ≈ 1/4 of

the actual one, similar to Mexico, less than Portugal or Greece). If US had grown with 2.75%

(like Japan or Taiwan), its GDP would be $112000 in 1990 (i.e., 3.5 times the actual one).

1Let y0 be the GDP per capital at year 0, yT the GDP per capita at year T, and x the average annual growth rate

over that period. Then, yT = (1 + x)T y0. Taking logs, we compute ln yT − ln y0 = T ln(1 + x) ≈ Tx, or equivalenty

x ≈ (ln yT − ln y0)/T.

6

Page 7: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• At a growth rate of 1%, our children will have ≈ 1.4 our income. At a growth rate of 3%, our

children will have ≈ 2.5 our income. Some East Asian countries grew by 6% over 1960-1990;

this is a factor of ≈ 6 within just one generation!!!

• Once we appreciate the importance of sustained growth, the question is natural: What can

do to make growth faster? Equivalently: What are the factors that explain differences in

economic growth, and how can we control these factors?

• In order to prescribe policies that will promote growth, we need to understand what are the

determinants of economic growth, as well as what are the effects of economic growth on social

welfare. That’s exactly where Growth Theory comes into picture...

2.1 The World Distribution of Income Levels and Growth Rates

• As we mentioned before, in 2000 there were many countries that had much lower standards

of living than the United States. This fact reflects the high cross-country dispersion in the

level of income.

7

Page 8: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Figure 3.1 in the Barro textbook shows the distribution of GDP per capita in 2000 across

the 147 countries in the Summers and Heston dataset. The richest country was Luxembourg,

with $44000 GDP per person. The United States came second, with $32500. The G7 and

most of the OECD countries ranked in the top 25 positions, together with Singapore, Hong

Kong, Taiwan, and Cyprus. Most African countries, on the other hand, fell in the bottom 25

of the distribution. Tanzania was the poorest country, with only $570 per person – that is,

less than 2% of the income in the United States or Luxemburg!

• Figure 3.2 shows the distribution of GDP per capita in 1960 across the 113 countries for which

data are available. The richest country then was Switzerland, with $15000; the United States

was again second, with $13000, and the poorest country was again Tanzania, with $450.

• The cross-country dispersion of income was thus as wide in 1960 as in 2000. Nevertheless,

there were some important movements during this 40-year period. Argentina, Venezuela,

Uruguay, Israel, and South Africa were in the top 25 in 1960, but none made it to the top 25

in 2000. On the other hand, China, Indonesia, Nepal, Pakistan, India, and Bangladesh grew

fast enough to escape the bottom 25 between 1960 and 1970. These large movements in the

8

Page 9: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

distribution of income reflects sustained differences in the rate of economic growth.

• Figure 3.3 shows the cross-country distribution of the growth rates between 1960 and 2000.

Just as there is a great dispersion in income levels, there is a great dispersion in growth rates.

The mean growth rate was 1.8% per annum; that is, the world on average was twice as rich

in 2000 as in 1960. The United States did slightly better than the mean. The fastest growing

country was Taiwan, with a annual rate as high as 6%, which accumulates to a factor of 10

over the 40-year period. The slowest growing country was Zambia, with an negative rate at

−1.8%; Zambia’s residents show their income shrinking to half between 1960 and 2000.

• Most East Asian countries (Taiwan, Singapore, South Korea, Hong Kong, Thailand, China,

and Japan), together with Bostwana (an outlier as compared to other sub-Saharan African

countries), Cyprus, Romania, and Mauritus, had the most stellar growth performances; they

were the “growth miracles” of our times. Some OECD countries (Ireland, Portugal, Spain,

Greece, Luxemburg and Norway) also made it to the top 20 of the growth-rates chart. On

the other hand, 18 out of the bottom 20 were sub-Saharan African countries. Other notable

“growth disasters” were Venezuela, Chad and Iraq.

9

Page 10: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

2.2 Stylized Facts

The following are stylized facts that should guide us in the modeling of economic growth (Kaldor,

Kuznets, Romer, Lucas, Barro, Mankiw-Romer-Weil, and others):

1. In the short run, important fluctuations: Output, employment, investment, and consumptio

vary a lot across booms and recessions.

2. In the long run, balanced growth: Output per worker and capital per worker (Y/L and K/L)

grow at roughly constant, and certainly not vanishing, rates. The capital-to-output ratio

(K/Y ) is nearly constant. The return to capital (r ) is roughly constant, whereas the wage

rate (w) grows at the same rates as output. And, the income shares of labor and capital

(wL/Y and rK/Y ) stay roughly constant.

3. Substantial cross-country differences in both income levels and growth rates.

4. Persistent differences versus conditional convergence.

5. Formal education: Highly correlated with high levels of income (obviously two-direction

10

Page 11: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

causality); together with differences in saving rates can “explain” a large fraction of the

cross-country differences in output; an important predictor of high growth performance.

6. R&D and IT: Most powerful engines of growth (but require high skills at the first place).

7. Government policies: Taxation, infrastructure, inflation, law enforcement, property rights and

corruption are important determinants of growth performance.

8. Democracy: An inverted U-shaped relation; that is, autarchies are bad for growht, and democ-

racies are good, but too much democracy can slow down growth.

9. Openness: International trade and financial integration promote growth (but not necessarily

if it is between the North and the South).

10. Inequality: The Kunzets curve, namely an inverted U-shaped relation between income in-

equality and GDP per capita (growth rates as well).

11. Ferility: High fertility rates correlated with levels of income and low rates of economic growth;

and the process of development follows a Malthus curve, meaning that fertility rates initially

increase and then fall as the economy develops.

11

Page 12: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

12. Financial markets and risk-sharing: Banks, credit, stock markets, social insurance.

13. Structural transformation: agriculture→manifacture→services.

14. Urbanization: family production→organized production; small vilages→big cities; extended

domestic trade.

15. Other institutional and social factors: colonial history, ethnic heterogeneity, social norms.

The Solow model and its various extensions that we will review in this course seek to explain how

all the above factors interrelate with the process of economic growth. Once we understand better

the “mechanics” of economic growth, we will be able, not only to predict economic performance

for given a set of fundamentals (positive analysis), but also to identify what government policies or

socio-economic reforms can promote social welfare in the long run (normative analysis).

12

Page 13: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

3 The Solow Model: Centralized Allocations

• The goal here is to write a formal model of how the macroeconomy works.

• To this goal, we shall envision a central planner that takes as given the production possibilities

of the economy and dictates a certain behavior to the households of the economy. As noted

earlier, we will later see how the dynamics of this centralized, planning economy coincide with

the dynamics of a decentralized, market economy.

• The “inputs” (or “assumptions”) of the model are going to be a certain specification of the

aforementioned production possibilities and behavior.

• The “output” (or “predictions”) of the model will be the endogenous macroeconomic outcomes

(consumption, saving, output, growth, etc.).

• We will then be able to use this model to understand the observed macroeconomic phenomena,

as well as to draw policy lessons.

13

Page 14: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

3.1 The Economy and the Social Planner

• Time is discrete, t ∈ {0, 1, 2, ...}. You can think of the period as a year, as a generation, or as

any other arbitrary length of time.

• The economy is an isolated island. Many households live in this island. There are no markets

and production is centralized. There is a benevolent dictator, or social planner, who governs

all economic and social affairs.

• There is one good, which is produced with two factors of production, capital and labor, and

which can be either consumed in the same period, or invested as capital for the next period.

• Households are each endowed with one unit of labor, which they supply inelastically to the

social planner. The social planner uses the entire labor force together with the accumulated

aggregate capital stock to produce the one good of the economy.

• In each period, the social planner saves a constant fraction s ∈ (0, 1) of contemporaneous

output, to be added to the economy’s capital stock, and distributes the remaining fraction

uniformly across the households of the economy.

14

Page 15: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• In what follows, we let Lt denote the number of households (and the size of the labor force)

in period t, Kt aggregate capital stock in the beginning of period t, Yt aggregate output in

period t, Ct aggregate consumption in period t, and It aggregate investment in period t. The

corresponding lower-case variables represent per-capita measures: kt = Kt/Lt, yt = Yt/Lt,

it = It/Lt, and ct = Ct/Lt.

15

Page 16: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

3.2 Technology and Production Possibilities

• The technology for producing the good is given by

Yt = F (Kt, Lt) (1)

where F : R2+ → R+ is a (stationary) production function. We assume that F is continuous

and (although not always necessary) twice differentiable.

16

Page 17: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• We say that the technology is “neoclassical” if F satisfies the following properties

1. Constant returns to scale (CRS), a.k.a. homogeneity of degree 1 or linear homogeneity:2

F (µK, µL) = µF (K,L), ∀µ > 0.

2. Positive and diminishing marginal products:

FK(K,L) > 0, FL(K,L) > 0,

FKK(K,L) < 0, FLL(K,L) < 0.

where Fx ≡ ∂F/∂x and Fxz ≡ ∂2F/(∂x∂z) for x, z ∈ {K,L}.

3. Inada conditions:

lim FK = lim FL =∞,K→0 L→0

lim FK = lim FL = 0.K→∞ L→∞

2We say that a function g : Rn+ → R is homogeneous of degree λ if, for every vector x ∈ Rn+ and every scalar

µ ∈ R λ a1 a2+, g(µx) = µ g(x). E.g., the function g(x) = x1 x2 is homogenous of degree λ = a1 + a2.

17

Page 18: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• By implication of CRS, F satisfies

Y = F (K,L) = FK(K,L)K + FL(K,L)L

That is, total output equals the sum of the inputs times their marginal products. Equivalently,

we can think of quantities FK(K,L)K and FL(K,L)L as the contributions of capital and labor

into output.

• Also by CRS, the marginal products F 3K and FL are homogeneous of degree zero. It follows

that the marginal products depend only on the ratio K/L :

K KFK(K,L) = FK

(, 1

)FL(K,L) = FL

L

(, 1

L

)

• Finally, it must be that FKL > 0, meaning that capital and labor are complementary inputs.4

3This is because of the more general property that, if a function is homogenous of degree λ, then its first derivatives

are homogeneous of degree λ− 1.4We say that two inputs are complementary if the marginal product of the one input increases with the level of

the other input.

18

Page 19: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Technology in intensive (or per-capita) form. Let

Y Ky = and k = .

L L

denote the levels of output and capital per head (or, equivalently, per worker, or per labor).

Then, by CRS, we have that

y = f(k) (2)

where the function f is defined by

f(k) ≡ F (k, 1).

19

Page 20: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Example: Cobb-Douglas production function

F (K,L) = AKαL1−α

where α ∈ (0, 1) parameterizes output’s elasticity with respect to capital and A > 0 parame-

terizes TFP (total factor productivity).

In intensive form,

f(k) = Akα

so that α can also be interpreted as the strength of diminishing returns: the lower α is, the

more fastly the MPK, f ′(k) = αkα−1, falls with k.

Finally, as we will see soon, α will also coincide with the income share of labor (that is,

the ratio of wL/Y ) along the competitive equilibrium. This will give us a direct empirical

counterpart for this theoretical parameter.

20

Page 21: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Let us now go back to a general specification of the technology. By the definition of f and

the properties of F, it is easy to show that f satisfies that following properties:

f(0) = 0,

f ′(k) > 0 > f ′′(k)

lim f ′(k) =k→0

∞, lim f ′(k) = 0k→∞

The first property means that output is zero when capital is zero. The second property means

that the marginal product of capital (MPK) is always positive and strictly decreasing in the

capital-labor ratio k. The third property means that the MPK is arbitrarily high when k is

low enough, and converges to zero as k becomes arbitrarily high.

• Also, it is easy to check that

FK(K,L) = f ′(k) and FL(K,L) = f(k)− f ′(k)k

which gives us the MPK and the MPL in terms of the intensive-form production function.

• Check Figure 1 for a graphical representation of a typical function f .

21

Page 22: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

22

yt

kt

kt

f’(k)

0

0

f(k)

ytδδkt

Graphical Representation of a Typical Function f.

Figure 1

Image by MIT OpenCourseWare.

Page 23: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

3.3 The Resource Constraint

• Remember that there is a single good, which can be either consumed or invested. Of course,

the sum of aggregate consumption and aggregate investment can not exceed aggregate output.

That is, the social planner faces the following resource constraint :

Ct + It ≤ Yt (3)

Equivalently, in per-capita terms:

ct + it ≤ yt (4)

• Suppose that population growth is n ≥ 0 per period. The size of the labor force then evolves

over time as follows:

L tt = (1 + n)Lt−1 = (1 + n) L0 (5)

We normalize L0 = 1.

• Suppose that existing capital depreciates over time at a fixed rate δ ∈ [0, 1]. The capital stock

in the beginning of next period is given by the non-depreciated part of current-period capital,

23

Page 24: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

plus contemporaneous investment. That is, the law of motion for capital is

Kt+1 = (1− δ)Kt + It. (6)

Equivalently, in per-capita terms:

(1 + n)kt+1 = (1− δ)kt + it

We can approximately write the above as

kt+1 ≈ (1− δ − n)kt + it (7)

The sum δ+n can thus be interpreted as the “effective” depreciation rate of per-capita capital:

it represents the rate at which the per-capita level of capital will decay if aggregate saving

(investment) is zero.

(Remark: The above approximation becomes arbitrarily good as the economy converges to

its steady state. Also, it would have been exact if time was continuous rather than discrete.)

24

Page 25: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

3.4 Consumption/Saving Behavior

• We will later derive consumption/saving choices from proper micro-foundations (well specified

preferences). For now, we take a short-cut and assume that consumption is a fixed fraction

(1− s) of output:

Ct = (1− s)Yt = (1− s)F (Kt, Lt) (8)

where s ∈ (0, 1). Equivalently, aggregate saving is given by a fraction s of GDP.

• Remark: in the textbook, consumption is defined as a fraction s of GDP net of depreciation.

This makes little difference for all the economic insights we will deliver, but be aware of this

minor mathematical difference.

25

Page 26: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

3.5 The Aggregate Dynamics

• In most of the growth models that we will examine in this class, the key of the analysis will

be to derive a dynamic system that characterizes the evolution of aggregate consumption and

capital in the economy; that is, a system of difference equations in Ct and Kt (or ct and kt).

This system is very simple in the case of the Solow model.

• Combining the law of motion for capital (6), the resource constraint (3), and the technology

(1), we derive the following dynamic equation for the capital stock:

Kt+1 −Kt = F (Kt, Lt)− δKt − Ct (9)

That is, the change in the capital stock is given by aggregate output, minus capital deprecia-

tion, minus aggregate consumption.

26

Page 27: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Combining conditions (8) and (9), we get a simple difference equation for the capital stock:

Kt+1 = (1− δ)Kt + sF (Kt, Lt) (10)

At the same time, the law of motion for labor gives another difference equation:

Lt+1 = (1 + n)Lt (11)

• Taken together, these two conditions pin down the entire dynamics of the labor force and

the capital stock of the economy for any arbitrary initial levels (K0, L0): starting from such

an initial point, we can compute the entire path {Kt, Lt} simply by iterating on conditions

(10) and (11 ). Once we have this path, it is straightforward to compute the paths of output,

consumption, and investment simply by using the facts that Yt = F (Kt, Lt), Ct = (1 − s)Ytand It = sYt for all t.

27

Page 28: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• We can reach a similar result in per-capita terms. Using (6), (4) and (2), we get that the

capital-labor ratio satisfies the following difference equation:

kt+1 = (1− δ − n)kt + sf(kt), (12)

Starting from an arbitrary initial k0, the above condition alone pins down the entire path

{kt}∞t=0 of the capital-labor ratio. Once we have this path, we can then get the per-capita

levels of income, consumption and investment simply by the facts that

yt = f(kt), ct = (1− s)yt, and it = syt ∀t (13)

• From this point and on, we will analyze the dynamics of the economy in per capita terms only.

Translating the results to aggregate terms is a straightforward exercise.

28

Page 29: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• We thus reach the following characterization of the planner’s allocation for the Solow economy.

Proposition 1 Given any initial point k0 > 0, the dynamics of the planner’s solution are given by

the path {kt}∞t=0 such that

kt+1 = G(kt), (14)

for all t ≥ 0, where

G(k) ≡ sf(k) + (1− δ − n)k.

Equivalently, the growth rate of capital is given by

kγt ≡ t+1 − kt

= γ(kt), (15)kt

where

γ(k) ≡ sφ(k)− (δ + n), φ(k) ≡ f(k)/k.

• This result is powerful because it permits us to understand the entire macroeconomic dynamics

simply by studying the properties of the function G (or equivalently the function γ).

29

Page 30: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

3.6 Steady State

• A steady state of the economy is defined as any level k∗ such that, if the economy starts

k0 = k∗, then kt = k∗ for all t ≥ 1. That is, a steady state is any fixed point k∗ of (14).

• A trivial steady state is k = 0 : There is no capital, no output, and no consumption.

would not be a steady state if f(0) > 0. We are interested for steady states at which capi

output and consumption are all positive (and finite). We can then easily show the followi

Proposition 2 Suppose δ + n ∈ (0, 1) and s ∈ (0, 1). A steady state with k∗ > 0 exists an

unique.

with

This

tal,

ng:

d is

30

Page 31: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

Proof. k∗ is a steady state if and only if it solves

k∗ = G(k∗)

Equivalently

sf(k∗) = (δ + n)k∗,

orδ + n

φ(k∗) = (16)s

where the function φ gives the output-to-capital ratio in the economy (equivalently, the average

product of capital):f(k)

φ(k) ≡ .k

We infer that characterizing the steady state of the economy reduces to the simple task of

characterizing the solution to equation (16). To do this, in turn, we simply need to study the

properties of the function φ.

31

Page 32: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

The properties of f , which we studied earlier, imply that φ is continuous (and twice differen-

tiable), decreasing, and satisfies the Inada conditions at k = 0 and k =∞:

f ′(k)kφ′(k) =

− f(k) F=

k2− L

< 0,k2

φ(0) = f ′(0) =∞ and φ(∞) = f ′(∞) = 0,

where the last two properties follow from an application of L’Hospital’s rule.

The continuity of φ and its limit properties guarantee that equation (16) has a solution if and

only if δ + n > 0 and s > 0, which we have assumed. The monotonicity of φ then guarantees that

the solution is unique. We conclude that a steady-state level of capital exists, is unique, and is

given by

k∗ = φ−1(δ + n

s

),

which completes the proof.

32

Page 33: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

3.7 Comparative statics of the steady state

• We now turn to the comparative statics of the steady state. In order to study the impact of

the level of technology, we now rewrite the production function as

Y = AF (K,L)

or, in intensive form,

y = Af(k)

where A is an exogenous scalar parameterizing TFP (total factor productivity).

Proposition 3 Consider the steady state.

The capital-labor ratio k∗ and the per-capita level of income, y∗ increase with the saving rate s

and the level of productivity A, and decrease with the depreciation rate δ and the rate of population

growth n.

The per-capital level of consumption, c∗, increases with A, decreases with δ and n, and is non-

monotonic in s.

33

Page 34: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

Proof. By the same argument as in the proof of the previous proposition, the steady-state level

of the capital-labor ratio is given by

k∗ = φ−1(δ + n

.sA

)Recall that φ is a decreasing function. It follows from the Implicit Function Theorem that k∗ is

a decreasing function of (δ + n)/(sA), which proves the claims about the comparative statics of

k∗. The comparative statics of y∗ then follow directly from the fact that y∗ = Af(k∗) and the

monotonicity of f . Finally, consumption is given by

c∗ = (1− s)f(k∗).

It follows that c∗ increases with A and decreases with δ + n, but is non-monotonic in s.

34

Page 35: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Example If the production functions is Cobb-Douglas, namely y = Af(k) = Akα, then φ(k) ≡f(k)/k = k−(1−α) and therefore (

sA) 1 α

1−α sA 1−α

k∗ = .y∗ = A .δ + n

(δ + n

)Equivalently, in logs,

1 α αlog y∗ = logA+ log s

1 α 1− α− log(δ + n)

− 1− α

Note that 1 > 1, which means that, in steady state, output (and consumption) increases1−α

more than one-to-one with TFP. This is simply because capital also increases with TFP, so

that output increases both because of the direct effect of TFP and because of its indirect

effect through capital accumulation.

35

Page 36: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

3.8 Transitional Dynamics

• The preceding analysis has characterized the (unique) steady state of the economy. Naturally,

we are interested to know whether the economy will converge to the steady state if it starts

away from it. Another way to ask the same question is whether the economy will eventually

return to the steady state if an exogenous shock perturbs the economy away from the steady

state. The following propositions uses the properties of the functions G and γ (defined in

Proposition 1) to establish that, in the Solow model, convergence to the steady is always

ensured and is indeed monotonic.

36

Page 37: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

Proposition 4 Given any initial k0 ∈ (0,∞), the economy converges asymptotically to the steady

state:

lim kt = k∗t→∞

Moreover, the transition is monotonic:

k0 < k∗ ⇒ k0 < k1 < k2 < k3 < ... < k∗

and

k0 > k∗ ⇒ k0 > k1 > k2 > k3 > ... > k∗

Finally, the growth rate γt is positive and decreases over time towards zero if k0 < k∗, while it is

negative and increases over time towards zero if k0 > k∗.

37

Page 38: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

Proof. From the properties of f, G′(k) = sf ′(k) + (1 − δ − n) > 0 and G′′(k) = sf ′′(k) < 0.

That is, G is strictly increasing and strictly concave. Moreover, G(0) = 0, G′(0) =∞, G(∞) =∞,G′(∞) = (1 − δ − n) < 1. By definition of k∗, G(k) = k iff k = k∗. It follows that G(k) > k

for all k < k∗ and G(k) < k for all k > k∗. It follows that kt < kt+1 < k∗ whenever kt ∈ (0, k∗)

and therefore the sequence {kt}∞t=0 is strictly increasing if k0 < k∗. By monotonicity, kt converges

ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆasymptotically to some k ≤ k∗. By continuity of G, k must satisfy k = G(k), that is k must be

a fixed point of G. But we already proved that G has a unique fixed point, which proves that

k = k∗. A symmetric argument proves that, when k0 > k∗, {kt}∞t=0 is stricttly decreasing and again

converges asymptotically to k∗. Next, consider the growth rate of the capital stock. This is given

byk≡ t+1

γt− kt

= sφ(kt)− (δ + n)kt

≡ γ(kt).

Note that γ(k) = 0 iff k = k∗, γ(k) > 0 iff k < k∗, and γ(k) < 0 iff k > k∗. Moreover, by diminishing

returns, γ′(k) = sφ′(k) < 0. It follows that γ(kt) < γ(kt+1) < γ(k∗) = 0 whenever kt ∈ (0, k∗) and

γ(kt) > γ(kt+1) > γ(k∗) = 0 whenever kt ∈ (k∗,∞). This proves that γt is positive and decreases

towards zero if k0 < k∗ and it is negative and increases towards zero if k0 > k∗.

38

Page 39: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Figure 2 depicts G(k), the relation between kt and kt+1. The intersection of the graph of G

with the 45o line gives the steady-state capital stock k∗. The arrows represent the path {kt}∞t=for a particular initial k0.

• Figure 3 depicts γ(k), the relation between kt and γt. The intersection of the graph of γ with

the 45o line gives the steady-state capital stock k∗.

• The negative slope of the curve in Figure 3 (equivalently, the monotonic dynamics of the

growth rate stated in the previous proposition) captures the concept of conditional conver-

gence: if two countries have different levels of economic development (namely different k0

and y0) but otherwise share the same fundamental characteristics (namely share the same

technologies, saving rates, depreciation rates, and fertility rates), then the poorer country will

grow faster than the richer one and will eventually (asymptotically) catch up with it.

• Discuss local versus global stability: Because φ′(k∗) < 0, the system is locally stable. Because

φ is globally decreasing, the system is globally stable and transition is monotonic.

39

Page 40: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

40

kt+1

ktk0 k1 k2 k3 k*

45

G(k)

0

0

V V VFigure 2

Image by MIT OpenCourseWare.

Page 41: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

41

0 k*kt

kt+1-ktkt

(k)γ(δ+η)

t=γ -

-

Figure 3

Image by MIT OpenCourseWare.

Page 42: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

4 The Solow Model: Decentralized Market Allocations

• In the preceding analysis we characterized the centralized allocations dictated by a certain

social planner. We now characterize the allocations chosen by the “invisible hand” of a

decentralized competitive equilibrium.

4.1 Households

• Households are dynasties, living an infinite amount of time. We index households by j ∈ [0, 1],

having normalized L0 = 1. The number of heads in every household grow at constant rate

n ≥ 0. Therefore, the size of the population in period t is Lt = (1 + n)t and the number of

persons in each household in period t is also Lt.

• We write cjt , kjt , b

jt , i

jt for the per-head variables for household j.

• Each person in a household is endowed with one unit of labor in every period, which he supplies

inelasticly in a competitive labor market for the contemporaneous wage wt. Household j is

42

Page 43: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

also endowed with initial capital kj0. Capital in household j accumulates according to

(1 + n)kjt+1 = (1− δ)kjt + it,

which we once again approximate by

kjt+1 = (1− δ − n)kjt + it. (17)

• We assume that capital is owned directly by the households. But capital is productive only

within firms. So we also assume that there is a competitive capital market in which firms rent

the capital from the households so that they can use it as an input in their production. The

capital market thus takes the form of a rental market and the per-period rental rate of capital

is denoted by rt.

• Note that this capital market is a rental market for real, physical capital (machines, buildings),

not for financial contracts (funds). We are abstracting from this kind of market and also

abstracting from borrowing constrain and any other form of financial frictions (frictions in

how funds and resources can be channeled from one agent to another).

43

Page 44: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• The households may also hold stocks of the firms in the economy. Let πjt be the dividends

(firm profits) that household j receive in period t. As it will become clear later on, it is without

any loss of generality to assume that there is no trade of stocks. (This is because the value

of firms stocks will be zero in equilibrium and thus the value of any stock transactions will

be also zero.) We thus assume that household j holds a fixed fraction αj of the aggregate

index of stocks in the economy, so that πj j∫ t = α Πt, where Πt are aggregate profits. Of course,

αjdj = 1.

• Finally, there is also a competitive labor market, in which the households supply their labor

and the firms are renting this labor to use it in their production. The wage rate (equivalently,

the rental rate of labor) is denotes by wt.

• Note that both rt and wt are in real terms, not nominal: they are the rental prices of capital

and labor relative to the price of the consumption good (which has been normalized to one).

44

Page 45: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• The household uses its income to finance either consumption or investment in new capital:

cjt + ijt = yjt .

Total per-head income for household j in period t is simply

yjt = wt + rtkjt + πjt . (18)

Combining, we can write the budget constraint of household j in period t as

cjt + ijt = wt + rtkjt + πjt (19)

• Finally, the consumption and investment behavior of each household is assumed to follow a

simple rule analogous to the one we had assumed for the social planner. They save fraction s

and consume the rest:

cjt = (1− s)yjt and ijt = syit. (20)

45

Page 46: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

4.2 Firms

• There is an arbitrary number Mt of firms in period t, indexed by m ∈ [0,Mt]. Firms employ

labor and rent capital in competitive labor and capital markets, have access to the same

neoclassical technology, and produce a homogeneous good that they sell competitively to the

households in the economy.

• Let Kmt and Lmt denote the amount of capital and labor that firm m employs in period t.

Then, the profits of that firm in period t are given by

Πmt = F (Km

t , Lmt )− rtKm

t − wtLmt .

• The firms seeks to maximize profits. The FOCs for an interior solution require

FK(Kmt , L

mt ) = rt. (21)

FL(Kmt , L

mt ) = wt. (22)

• Remember that the marginal products are homogenous of degree zero; that is, they depend

only on the capital-labor ratio. In particular, F is a decreasing function of KmK t /L

mt and FL

46

Page 47: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

is an increasing function of Kmt /L

mt . Each of the above conditions thus pins down a unique

capital-labor ratio Km/Lmt t . For an interior solution to the firms’ problem to exist, it must be

that rt and wt are consistent, that is, they imply the same Kmt /L

mt . This is the case if and

only if there is some Xt ∈ (0,∞) such that

rt = f ′(Xt) (23)

wt = f(Xt)− f ′(Xt)Xt (24)

where f(k) ≡ F (k, 1); this follows from the properties

FK(K,L) = f ′(K/L) and FL(K,L) = f(K/L)− f ′(K/L) · (K/L),

which we established earlier.

• If (23)-(24) are satisfied, the FOCs reduce to Kmt /L

mt = Xt, or

Km mt = XtLt . (25)

That is, the FOCs pin down the capital labor ratio for each firm (Kmt /L

mt ), but not the size

of the firm (Lmt ). Moreover, because all firms have access to the same technology, they use

exactly the same capital-labor ratio.

47

Page 48: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Besides, (23)-(24) imply

rtXt + wt = f(Xt). (26)

It follows that

r Km + w Lm = (r X + w )Lm = f(X )Lm = F (Km, Lmt t t t t t t t t t t t ),

and therefore

Πmt = Lmt [f(Xt)− rtXt − wt] = 0. (27)

That is, when (23)-(24) are satisfied, the maximal profits that any firm makes are exactly zero,

and these profits are attained for any firm size as long as the capital-labor ratio is optimal If

instead (23)-(24) were violated, then either rtXt + wt < f(Xt), in which case the firm could

make infinite profits, or rtXt +wt > f(Xt), in which case operating a firm of any positive size

would entail strictly negative profits.

48

Page 49: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

4.3 Market Clearing

• The capital market clears if and only if∫ Mt 1

Kmt dm =

0

∫(1 + n)tkjtdj

0

Equivalently, ∫ Mt

Kmt dm = Kt (28)

0

Lwhere K t

t ≡∫

kjtdj is the aggregate capital stock in the economy.0

• The labor market, on the other hand, clears if and only if∫ Mt

Lmt dm =

∫ 1

(1 + n)tdj0 0

Equivalently, ∫ Mt

Lmt dm = Lt (29)0

where Lt is the size of the labor force in the economy.

49

Page 50: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

4.4 General Equilibrium: Definition

• The definition of a general equilibrium is more meaningful when households optimize their

behavior (maximize utility) rather than being automata (mechanically save a constant fraction

of income). Nonetheless, it is always important to have clear in mind what is the definition

of equilibrium in any model. For the decentralized version of the Solow model, we let:

Definition 5 An equilibrium of the economy is an allocation {(kj, cj, ij) , (Km, Lmt t t j∈[0,1] t t )m [0,Mt]}t∞ ,∈ =0

a distribution of profits {(πjt )j [0,1]}, and a price path {rt, wt}t∞ such∈ =0 that

(i) Given {rt, wt}∞t=0 and {πjt}∞t=0, the path {kjt , cjt , i

jt} is consistent with the behavior of household

j, for every j.

(ii) (Kmt , L

mt ) maximizes firm profits, for every m and t.

(iii) The capital and labor markets clear in every period

(iv) Aggregate dividends equal aggregate profits.

50

Page 51: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

4.5 General Equilibrium: Existence, Uniqueness, and Characterization

• In the next, we characterize the decentralized equilibrium allocations:

Proposition 6 For any initial positions (kj0)j [0,1], an equilibrium exists. The allocation of produc-∈

tion across firms is indeterminate, but the equilibrium is unique as regards aggregate and household

allocations. The capital-labor ratio in the economy is given by {kt}∞t=0 such that

kt+1 = G(kt) (30)

for all t ≥ 0 and k0 =∫kj0dj historically given, where G(k) ≡ sf(k) + (1 − δ − n)k. Equilibrium

growth is given byk

γt ≡ t+1 − kt= γ(kt), (31)

kt

where γ(k) ≡ sφ(k)− (δ + n), φ(k) ≡ f(k)/k. Finally, equilibrium prices are given by

rt = r(kt) ≡ f ′(kt), (32)

wt = w(kt) ≡ f(kt)− f ′(kt)kt, (33)

where r′(k) < 0 < w′(k).

51

Page 52: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

Proof. We first characterize the equilibrium, assuming it exists.

Using Km mt = XtLt by (25), we can write the aggregate demand for capital as∫ Mt t

Kmt dm = Xt

∫ M

Lmt dm0 0

From the labor market clearing condition (29),∫ Mt

Lmt dm = Lt.0

Combining, we infer ∫ Mt

Kmt dm = XtLt,

0

and substituting in the capital market clearing condition (28), we conclude

XtLt = Kt,

where Kt ≡∫ Lt kj0 tdj denotes the aggregate capital stock.

52

Page 53: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

Equivalently, letting kt ≡ Kt/Lt denote the capital-labor ratio in the economy, we have

Xt = kt. (34)

That is, all firms use the same capital-labor ratio as the aggregate of the economy.

Substituting (34) into (23) and (24) we infer that equilibrium prices are given by

rt = r(kt) ≡ f ′(kt) = FK(kt, 1)

wt = w(kt) ≡ f(kt)− f ′(kt)kt = FL(kt, 1)

Note that r′(k) = f ′′(k) = FKK < 0 and w′(k) = −f ′′(k)k = FLK > 0. That is, the interest

rate is a decreasing function of the capital-labor ratio and the wage rate is an increasing function

of the capital-labor ratio. The first properties reflects diminishing returns, the second reflects the

complementarity of capital and labor.

53

Page 54: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

Adding up the budget constraints of the households, we get

Ct + It = rtKt + wtLj

t +

∫πtdj,

where∫ Ct ≡∫cjtdj and It ≡

∫ij jtdj. Aggregate dividends must equal aggregate profits, πtdj =

Πmt dj. By (27), profits for each firm are zero. Therefore,

∫∫πjtdj = 0, implying

Ct + It = Yt = rtKt + wtLt

Equivalently, in per-capita terms,

ct + it = rtkt + wt.

From (26) and (34), or equivalently from (32) and (33), rtkt + wt = yt = f(kt). We conclude that

the household budgets imply

ct + it = f(kt),

which is simply the resource constraint of the economy.

54

Page 55: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

Adding up the individual capital accumulation rules (17), we get the capital accumulation rule

for the aggregate of the economy. In per-capita terms,

kt+1 = (1− δ − n)kt + it

Adding up (20) across household, we similarly infer

it = syt = sf(kt).

Combining, we conclude

kt+1 = sf(kt) + (1− δ − n)kt = G(kt),

which is exactly the same as in the centralized allocation.

Finally, existence and uniqueness is now trivial. (30) maps any kt ∈ (0,∞) to a unique kt+1 ∈(0,∞). Similarly∫ , (32) and (33) map any kt

j

∈ (0,∞) to unique rt, wt ∈ (0,∞). Therefore, given any

initial k0 = k0dj, there exist unique paths {kt}∞t=0 and {rt, wt}∞t=0. Givenj

{rt, wt}∞t=0, the allocation

{kt , cjt , i

jt} for any household j is then uniquely determined by (17), (18), and (20). Finally, any

allocation (Km, Lmt t )m [0,Mt] of production across firms in period t is consistent with equilibrium as∈

long as Kmt = ktL

mt .

55

Page 56: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• An immediate implication is that the decentralized market economy and the centralized dic-

tatorial economy are isomorphic:

Corollary 7 The aggregate and per-capita allocations in the competitive market economy coincide

with those in the dictatorial economy.

• Given this isomorphism, we can immediately translate the steady state and the transitional

dynamics of the centralized plan to the steady state and the transitional dynamics of the

decentralized market allocations:

Corollary 8 Suppose δ + n ∈ (0, 1) and s ∈ (0, 1). A steady state (c∗, k∗) ∈ (0,∞)2 for the

competitive economy exists and is unique, and coincides with that of the social planner. k∗ and y∗

increase with s and decrease with δ and n, whereas c∗ is non-monotonic with s and decreases with

δ and n. Finally, y∗/k∗ = (δ + n)/s.

Corollary 9 Given any initial k0 ∈ (0,∞), the competitive economy converges asymptotically to

the steady state. The transition is monotonic. The equilibrium growth rate is positive and decreases

over time towards zero if k0 < k∗; it is negative and increases over time towards zero if k0 > k∗.

56

Page 57: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• The bottom line is that the allocations that characterize the frictionless competitive equilib-

rium coincide with those that characterize the planner’s solution. The only extra knowledge

we got by considering the equilibrium is that we found the prices (wages, rental rates) that

“support” the allocation as a decentralized market outcome, that is, that make this allocation

individually optimal in the eyes of firms and households. Keep this in mind: the planner’s

solution is merely an allocation, a market equilibrium is always a combination of an allocation

and of prices that support this allocation.

• By finding the prices that support the planner’s solution as a market equilibrium, we can

thus make predictions, not only about the real macroeconomic quantities (GDP, investment,

consumption, etc) but also about wages, interest rates, and more generally market prices.

• Finally, remember that all this presumes that we have a competitive market economy without

externalities and without any kind of friction to drive the equilibrium away from the planner’s

solution. If we were to allow for, say, externalities or monopoly power, the equilibrium would

differ from the planner’s solution—and then we could start making sense of policies that seek

to correct the underlying market inefficiencies. We will consider such situations in due course.

57

Page 58: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

5 The Solow Model: Introducing Shocks and Policies

• The Solow model can be used to understand business cycles (economic fluctuations).

• To do this, we must first extend the model in a way that it can accommodate stochasticity

in its equilibrium outcomes. This is done by introducing exogenous random disturbances in

the primitives of the model (technologies, preferences, etc). This means that we model the

“deeper origins” of booms and recession as exogenous forces and then use the model to make

predictions about how the endogenous macroeconomic variables respond over time to these

exogenous disturbances.

• In the sequel, we do this kind of exercise to predict the response of the economy to productivity

shocks (changes in the production possibilities of the economy, taste shocks (changes in the

saving rate), and policy shocks (changes in government policies).

58

Page 59: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

5.1 Productivity (TFP) Shock

• Let us introduce exogenous shocks to the Total Factor Productivity (TFP) of the economy.

To this goal, we modify the production function as follows:

Yt = AtF (Kt, Lt)

or, in intensive form,

yt = Atf(kt)

where At identifies TFP in period t.

• We thus want to consider the possibility that At varies over time and to examine how the

economy responds to changes in At, according to our model. Before we do this, let us first

show that variation in At is not merely a theoretical possibility; it is an actual fact in US

data.

• To this goal, suppose further that F takes a Cobb-Douglas form: F (K,L) = KαL1−α. It

follows that

log Yt = logAt + α logKt + (1− α) logLt

59

Page 60: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

and therefore

∆ logAt = ∆ log Yt − α∆ logKt − (1− α)∆ logLt

where ∆Xt ≡ Xt − Xt−1 for any variable X . Note that ∆ log Yt is the growth rate of

GDP, ∆ logKt is the change in capital (net investment), and ∆ logLt is the net change in

employment. For all these variables, we have readily available data in the US. Furthermore,

under the assumption of perfect competition, wt = AtFL(Kt, Lt). Given the Cobb-Douglas

specification, this gives

wt = (1− α)A α αtKt L

−t = (1− α)Yt/Lt

and thereforew

1− tLtα =

Yt

which means that 1−α coincides with the income share of labor. In the US data, the income

share of labor is about 70%. It follows that α ≈ .3. We conclude that the change in TFP can

be computed by using the available macro data along with the following equation

∆ logAt = ∆ log Yt − .3∆ logKt − .7∆ logLt

60

Page 61: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

If you do this, you get a times series for ∆ logAt, the growth rate in TFP, that looks as in

the following figure.

• There are two notable features in this figure. The first is that on average ∆At is positive.

This means that on average there is long-run technological progress: out of the same inputs,

61

Page 62: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

we get more and more output as time passes. The second is that ∆At fluctuates a lot around

its trend and tends to be lower during recessions (periods highlighted by the white areas in

the figure) as opposed to normal times (grey areas in the figure).

• This second systematic feature, that TFP tends to fall during recessions, motivates the exercise

we do here. We take for given that At fluctuates over time and study the model’s predictions

regarding how all other macroeconomic variables (output, investment, consumption) respond

to such fluctuations in At. We are thus interested to see if the model makes reasonable and

empirically plausible predictions about the cyclical behavior of these variables.

• In particular, we know that, in the data, TFP, output, consumption and investment all fall

during recessions. In the model, we will only assume that TFP falls during recession. We

then ask whether the model predicts that output, consumption, and investment must fall in

response to a fall in TFP.

62

Page 63: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Thus consider a negative shock in TFP. This shock could be either temporary or permanent.

Also, keep in mind this shock can be interpreted literally as a change in the know-how of

firms and the talents of people; but it could also be proxy from changes in the efficiency of the

financial system and more generally in the efficiency of how resources are used in the economy.

• Recall that the dynamics of capital are given by

kt+1 = G(kt;At) = sAtf(kt) + (1− δ − n)kt

As a result of the drop in At, the G function shifts down. If the drop in At is permanent, the

shift in G is also permanent; if the drop in At is transitory, the shift in G is also transitory. The

same logic applies if we look at the γ function, which gives the growth rate of the economy.

See Figure 4.

63

Page 64: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Suppose now that the economy was resting at its steady state before the drop in At. At the

moment At falls, output falls by exactly the same amount, because at the moment resources

are fixed and simply TFP has fallen. But the drop in output leads to a drop in investment,

which in turn leads to lower capital stock in the future. It follows that after the initial shock

there are further and further reductions in output, due to the endogenous reduction in the

capital stock. In other words, the endogenous response of capital amplifies the effects of the

negative TFP shock on output. Furthermore, if at some point the TFP shock disappears and

At returns to its initial value, output (and by implication consumption and investment) do

not return immediately to their initial values. Rather, because the capital stock has been

decreased, it takes time for output to transit back to its original, pre-recession value. In this

sense, the endogenous response of capital, not only amplifies the recessionary effects of the

exogenous TFP shock, but it also adds persistence: the effects of the shock are felt in the

economy long time after the shock has itself gone away. Equivalently, recoveries take time.

• The aforementioned dynamics are illustrated in Figure 5. The solid lines represent the response

of the economy to a transitory negative TFP shock, which only lasts between t1 and t2 in the

figure. The dashed lines show what the response would have been in the case the shock were

64

Page 65: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

permanent, starting at t1 and lasting for ever.

either temporarily or permanently. What are the effects on the steady state and the transi-

tional dynamics, in either case?

• See Figures 4 and 5 for a graphical representation of the impact of a (temporary) negative

productivity shock.

• Taste shocks: Consider a temporary fall in the saving rate. The γ(k) function shifts down for

a while, and then return to its initial position. What the transitional dynamics?

65

Page 66: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

66

kt+1

kt

kt

γt

Figure 4

Image by MIT OpenCourseWare.

Page 67: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

67

kt

yt

kt

t

tt1 t2

yt = At f(kt)

Figure 5

Image by MIT OpenCourseWare.

Page 68: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

5.2 Unproductive Government Spending

• Let us now introduce a government in the competitive market economy. The government

spends resources without contributing to production or capital accumulation.

• The resource constraint of the economy now becomes

ct + gt + it = yt = f(kt),

where gt denotes government consumption. It follows that the dynamics of capital are given

by

kt+1 − kt = f(kt)− (δ + n)kt − ct − gt

• Government spending is financed with proportional income taxation, at rate τ ≥ 0. The

government thus absorbs a fraction τ of aggregate output:

gt = τyt.

68

Page 69: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Disposable income for the representative household is (1− τ)yt. We continue to assume that

consumption and investment absorb fractions 1− s and s of disposable income:

ct = (1− s)(1− τ)yt.

• Combining the above, we conclude that the dynamics of capital are now given by

kt+1γt =

− kt= s(1 τ

t

− )φ(kt)k

− (δ + n).

where φ(k) ≡ f(k)/k. Given s and kt, the growth rate γt decreases with τ.

• A steady state exists for any τ ∈ [0, 1) and is given by

k∗ = φ−1(

δ + n

s(1− τ)

).

Given s, k∗ decreases with τ.

• Policy Shocks: Consider a temporary shock in government consumption. What are the tran-

sitional dynamics?

69

Page 70: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

5.3 Productive Government Spending

• Suppose now that production is given by

yt = f(kt, gt) = kαt gβt ,

where α > 0, β > 0, and α + β < 1. Government spending can thus be interpreted as

infrastructure or other productive services. The resource constraint is

ct + gt + it = yt = f(kt, gt).

• We assume again that government spending is financed with proportional income taxation at

rate τ, and that private consumption and investment are fractions 1 − s and s of disposable

household income:

gt = τyt.

ct = (1− s)(1− τ)yt

it = s(1− τ)yt

70

Page 71: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Substituting gt = τyt into yt = kαt gβt and solving for yt, we infer

α β

yt = k 1−β τ 1 a bt

−β ≡ kt τ

where a ≡ α/(1 − β) and b ≡ β/(1 − β). Note that a > α, reflecting the complementarity

between government spending and capital.

• We conclude that the growth rate is given by

kt+1γt =

− kt= s(1− τ)τ bka−1

k tt

− (δ + n).

The steady state is1/(1

s(1 τ)τ b−a)

k∗ =

(−

).

δ + n

71

Page 72: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Consider the rate τ that maximizes either k∗, or γt for any given kt. This is given by

d[(1

dτ− τ)τ b] = 0⇔

bτ b−1 − (1 + b)τ b = 0⇔

τ = b/(1 + b) = β.

That is, the “optimal” τ equals the elasticity of production with respect to government ser-

vices. The more productive government services are, the higher their optimal provision.

72

Page 73: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

6 The Solow Model: Miscellaneous

6.1 The Solow Model in Continuous Time

• Recall that the basic growth equation in the discrete-time Solow model is

kt+1 − kt= γ(kt) k

t

≡ sφ( t)k

− (δ + n).

We would expect a similar condition to hold under continuous time. We verify this below.

• The resource constraint of the economy is

C + I = Y = F (K,L).

In per-capita terms,

c+ i = y = f(k).

• Clearly, these conditions do not depend on whether time is continuous or discrete. Rather, it

is the law of motions for L and K that slightly change from discrete to continuous time.

73

Page 74: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Population growth is now given byL

= nL

and the law of motion for aggregate capital is

K = I − δK

• Let k ≡ K/L. Then,˙ ˙ ˙k K L

= − .k K L

Substituting from the above, we infer

k = i− (δ + n)k.

Combining this with

i = sy = sf(k),

we conclude

k = sf(k)− (δ + n)k.

74

Page 75: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Equivalently, the growth rate of the economy is given by

k= γ(k) ≡ sφ(k)− (δ + n). (35)

k

The function γ(k) thus gives the growth rate of the economy in the Solow model, whether

time is discrete or continuous.

75

Page 76: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

6.2 Mankiw-Romer-Weil: Cross-Country Differences

• The Solow model implies that steady-state capital, productivity, and income are determined

primarily by technology (f and δ), the national saving rate (s), and population growth (n).

• Suppose that countries share the same technology in the long run, but differ in terms of saving

behavior and fertility rates. If the Solow model is correct, observed cross-country income and

productivity differences should be explained by observed cross-country differences in s and n,

• Mankiw, Romer and Weil tests this hypothesis against the data. In it’s simple form, the Solow

model fails to explain the large cross-country dispersion of income and productivity levels.

• Mankiw, Romer and Weil then consider an extension of the Solow model, that includes two

types of capital, physical capital (k) and human capital (h). The idea is to take a broader

perspective on how to map the model to reality.

76

Page 77: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Output is given by

y = kαhβ,

where α > 0, β > 0, and α + β < 1. The dynamics of capital accumulation are now given b

k = sky − (δ + n)k

h = shy − (δ + n)h

where sk and sh are the investment rates in physical capital and human capital, respectivel

The steady-state levels of k, h, and y then depend on both sk and sh, as well as δ and n.

• Proxying sh by education attainment levels in each country, Mankiw, Romer and Weil fin

that the Solow model extended for human capital does a pretty good job in explaining th

cross-country dispersion of output and productivity levels.

y

y.

d

e

77

Page 78: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

6.3 Log-linearization and the Convergence Rate

• Define z ≡ ln k − ln k∗. We can rewrite the growth equation (35) as

z = Γ(z),

where

Γ(z) ≡ γ(k∗ez) ≡ sφ(k∗ez)− (δ + n)

Note that Γ(z) is defined for all z ∈ R. By definition of k∗, Γ(0) = sφ(k∗) − (δ + n) = 0.

Similarly, Γ(z) > 0 for all z < 0 and Γ(z) < 0 for all z > 0. Finally, Γ′(z) = sφ′(k∗ez)k∗ez < 0

for all z ∈ R.

• We next (log)linearize z = Γ(z) around z = 0 :

z = Γ(0) + Γ′(0) · z

or equivalently

z = λz

where we substituted Γ(0) = 0 and let λ ≡ Γ′(0).

78

Page 79: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Straightforward algebra gives

Γ′(z) = sφ′(k∗ez)k∗ez < 0

f ′(k)kφ′(k) =

− f(k) f ′(k)k f(k)= − 1

k2−

f(k) k2

sf(k∗) = (δ + n)k∗

[ ]

We infer

Γ′(0) = −(1− εK)(δ + n) < 0

where εK ≡ FKK/F = f ′(k)k/f(k) is the elasticity of production with respect to capital,

evaluated at the steady-state k.

• We conclude thatk

= λ lnk

(k

k∗

)where

λ = −(1− εK)(δ + n) < 0

The quantity λ is called the convergence rate.−

79

Page 80: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Note that, around the steady state˙y k

= εKy

·k

and

y k= ε

y∗K ·

k∗

It follows that

y y= λ ln

y

(y∗

)Thus, −λ is the convergence rate for either capital or output.

• In the Cobb-Douglas case, y = kα, the convergence rate is simply

−λ = (1− α)(δ + n),

where α is the income share of capital. Note that as λ → 0 as α → 1. That is, convergence

becomes slower and slower as the income share of capital becomes closer and closer to 1.

Indeed, if it were α = 1, the economy would a balanced growth path.

80

Page 81: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• In the example with productive government spending, y = kαgβ = kα/(1−β)τβ/(1−β), we get

−λ =

1−1− β

)(δ + n)

The convergence rate thus decreases with β, the productivity of government services. And

λ→ 0 as β → 1− α.

• Calibration: If α = 35%, n = 3% (= 1% population growth+2% exogenous technological

process), and δ = 5%, then −λ = 6%. This contradicts the data. But if α = 70%, then

−λ = 2.4%, which matches the date.

81

Page 82: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

6.4 Barro: Conditional Convergence

• Recall the log-linearization of the dynamics around the steady state:

y y= λ ln .

y y∗

A similar relation will hold true in the neoclassical growth model a la Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans.

λ < 0 reflects local diminishing returns. Such local diminishing returns occur even in

endogenous-growth models. The above thus extends well beyond the simple Solow model.

• Rewrite the above as

∆ ln y = λ ln y − λ ln y∗

Next, let us proxy the steady state output by a set of country-specific controls X, which

include s, δ, n, τ etc. That is, let

−λ ln y∗ ≈ β′X.

We conclude

∆ ln y = λ ln y + β′X + error

82

Page 83: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• The above represents a typical “Barro” conditional-convergence regression: We use cross-

country data to estimate λ (the convergence rate), together with β (the effects of the saving

rate, education, population growth, policies, etc.) The estimated convergence rate is about

2% per year.

• Discuss the effects of the other variables (X).

83

Page 84: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

6.5 The Golden Rule and Dynamic Inefficiency

• The Golden Rule: Consumption at the steady state is given by

c∗ = (1− s)f(k∗) =

= f(k∗)− (δ + n)k∗

Suppose the social planner chooses s so as to maximize c∗. Since k∗ is a monotonic function

of s, this is equivalent to choosing k∗ so as to maximize c∗. Note that

c∗ = f(k∗)− (δ + n)k∗

is strictly concave in k∗. The FOC is thus both necessary and sufficient. c∗ is thus maximized

if and only if k∗ = kgold, where kgold solve

f ′(kgold)− δ = n.

Equivalently, s = sgold, where sgold solves

sgold · φ (kgold) = (δ + n)

The above is called the “golden rule” for savings, after Phelps.

84

Page 85: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• Dynamic Inefficiency: If s > sgold (equivalently, k∗ > kgold), the economy is dynamically

inefficient: If the saving raised is lowered to s = sgold for all t, then consumption in all periods

will be higher!

• On the other hand, if s < sgold (equivalently, k∗ > kgold), then raising s towards sgold will

increase consumption in the long run, but at the cost of lower consumption in the short run.

Whether such a trade-off between short-run and long-run consumption is desirable will depend

on how the social planner weight the short run versus the long run.

• The Modified Golden Rule: In the Ramsey model, this trade-off will be resolved when k∗

satisfies the

f ′(k∗)− δ = n+ ρ,

where ρ > 0 measures impatience (ρ will be called “the discount rate”). The above is called

the “modified golden rule.” Naturally, the distance between the Ramsey-optimal k∗ and the

golden-rule kgold increase with ρ.

85

Page 86: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Abel et. al.: Note that the golden rule can be restated as

Yr − δ = .

Y

˙Dynamic inefficiency occurs when r − δ < Y /Y, dynamic efficiency is ensured if r − δ >

Y /Y. Abel et al. use this relation to argue that, in reality, there is no evidence of dynamic

inefficiency.

• Bubbles: If the economy is dynamically inefficient, there is room for bubbles.

86

Page 87: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

6.6 Poverty Traps, Cycles, etc.

• Discuss the case of a general non-concave or non-monotonic G.

• Multiple steady states; unstable versus stable ones; poverty traps.

• Local versus global stability; local convergence rate.

• Oscillating dynamics; perpetual cycles.

• See Figures 6 and 7 for examples.

87

Page 88: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

88

kt+1

kt

kt

G(k)

G(k)

45o

Kt+1

v v v

v v v v v

v v v

Figure 7

Figure 6

Image by MIT OpenCourseWare.

Page 89: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

6.7 Introducing Endogenous Growth

• What ensures that the growth rate asymptotes to zero in the Solow model (and the Ramsey

model as well) is the vanishing marginal product of capital, that is, the Inada condition

limk f ′(k) = 0.→∞

• Continue to assume that f ′′(k) < 0, so that γ′(k) < 0, but assume now that limk f ′(k) =→∞

A > 0. This implies also limk φ(k) = A. Then, as k→∞ →∞,

k kt ≡ t+1γ

− t

kt→ sA− (n+ δ)

• If sA < (n+ δ), then it is like before: The economy converges to k∗ such that γ(k∗) = 0. But

if sA > (n+ x+ δ), then the economy exhibits diminishing but not vanishing growth: γt falls

with t, but γt → sA− (n+ δ) > 0 as t→∞.

89

Page 90: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Consider the special case where f(k) = Ak (linear returns to capital). This is commonly

referred as the AK model. The economy then follows a balanced-growth path from the very

beginning. Along this path, the growth rate of consumption, output and capital are all equal

to γ = sA− (n+ δ) in all dates.

• Note then that the growth rate depends both on “preferences” (through s) and on “technol-

ogy” (through A). Hence, the same forces that determined the long-run level of income in the

Solow model now also determine the long-run rate of growth.

• We will later “endogenize” A in terms of policies, institutions, markets, etc.

• For example, Romer/Lucas: If we have human capital or spillover effects,

yt = Atkαt h

1−αt .

If (for reasons that we will study later) it happens that h is proportional to k, then we get

that y is also proportional to k, much alike in the simple AK model that we briefly mentioned

earlier (i.e., the version of the Solow model with f(k) = Ak).

90

Page 91: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

14.05 Lecture Notes: The Solow Model

• In particular, let

kt ≡ kt + ht

denote the ”total” capital of the economy and suppose that there exists a constant λ ∈ (0, 1)

such that

˜ ˜kt = λkt ht = λkt.

The we can write output as

˜ ˜yt = Atkt.

where

At ≡ Atλα(1− λ)1−α.

represent the effective productivity of the ”total” capital of the economy. Finally, assuming

that households save a fraction s of their income to ”total” capital, the growth rate of the

economy is then simply

˜γt = sAt − (δ + n).

91

Page 92: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

George-Marios Angeletos

• Clearly, this is the same as in the simple AK model, except for the fact that effective produc-

tivity is now endogenous to the allocation of savings between the two types of capital (that

˜is, At depends on λ).

• Question: what is the λ that maximizes effective productivity and growth?

92

Page 93: Angeletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013 geletos - Macro Intermedia MIT 2013-01-02 Introd Solow Model

MIT OpenCourseWarehttp://ocw.mit.edu

14.05 Intermediate MacroeconomicsSpring 2013

For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.