anthony cheung paper

Upload: andhi-susanto

Post on 06-Apr-2018

229 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    1/30

    Discussion draft only: Not to be cited

    The Third EASP International Conference

    Centre for East Asian Studies, Bristol University, UK,

    12-13 July 2006

    GDPism and Risk:

    Challenges for Social Development and Governance in East Asia

    The East Asian Social Policy Discourse:Policy Shift, Reversal, or Steadiness?1

    Professor Anthony B. L. Cheung

    Professor, Department of Public and Social Administration

    City University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, China

    [email protected]

    1. Introduction

    Robert Wade (1990)s study of South Korea, Taiwan and Japan resulted in an

    understanding of East Asian developmentalism as the governed market. Hong Kongarguably had developed an alternative model of growth in the name of positive non-

    interventionism. The identification of an East Asia-specific growth model is also

    matched by a similar attempt to construct an East Asian productivist model of

    welfare capitalism (Holliday 2000).

    This paper explores the substance of the East Asian social policy discourse. The first

    question addressed is whether by having undergone rapid economic growth by the

    1990s, East Asian developed societies have also trodden a path of modernization

    comparable to that in the West where post-War economic and social changes

    constituted interlinked aspects of a singular process of transformation leading to

    policy convergence in the form of the welfare state. The productivist explanation

    casts doubt on such a proposition. The secondquestion is whether since the 1997

    Asian financial crisis the pre-existing East Asian developmental model has been

    eroded because of the impact of globalization and the rise of neo-liberalism as

    prescription for the economic problems.

    Economic challenges like globalization and the Asian financial crisis, and political

    challenges like regime change with democratization (South Korea and Taiwan) or

    without democratization (Hong Kong), and the gradual rise of new politics (Japan

    included), together with increasing fiscal/budgetary pressure (notably in Japan,

    Taiwan and Hong Kong), have certainly helped to induce public policy rethinking

    among East Asian governments. However, it is observed changes so far have not

    substantially moved beyond the original policy path grounded in a developmental

    1Acknowledgement: The author is most grateful to the Governance in Asia Research Centre (GARC)

    of the City University of Hong Kong for providing financial support to enable him to travel to Bristolfor the conference at which this paper is presented. The research support of Lo Oi-yu, senior research

    assistant of GARC, is also gratefully acknowledged.

    1

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    2/30

    state with productivist goals. Path dependency is still very much at play, sustained by

    institutional continuity. Policy reversals are rare.

    Such policy steadiness in East Asian public policy governance can be explained by

    the longstanding bureaucrats-dominated nature of public policy making in addition to

    the state-led economic development approach to policy interventions. Some publicservices have historically been developed and expanded not for the sake of

    independent social policy values, but as instrumentalist complements to the

    developmental agenda and related political objectives. Welfare provisions have

    mostly been introduced not out of welfare ideology considerations, as some suggested

    to be the case in the formation of the welfare state in the West (Pinker 1979; Marshall

    and Bottomore 1992), but as a result of a fiscally and economically driven social

    development programme, in which case economic slowdown and recession could

    arguably cause a readjustment or even reversal shift, but still within the same logic.

    New social policy development in some East Asian states like South Korea after

    democratization can at best been seen as indicative of the rise of welfare

    developmentalism. If developmentalism is still the foundation of the East Asianpublic policy discourse, then its welfarist component needs to be conceptualized more

    appropriately as an offshoot of economic development and thus an outcome of fiscal

    surplus, rather than any pure ideology of collectivist welfare. Social development is

    thus part and parcel of the bigger economic development project. The role of family

    and individual efforts remains a key element of the social philosophy underpinning

    state-society interaction and the states response to social demands, even though there

    are increasing state regulatory and intervention efforts along the way.

    2. East Asian Welfare States Nature and Evolution

    The developmental state

    Before the 1997 Asian financial crisis cast doubt about the prospect of the postwar

    developmental state mode (Wong, 2004: 345-56), the conventional wisdom in

    understanding the system of governance in East Asia would start with the East Asian

    Economic Miracle thesis (World Bank, 1993). According to it, the success of the

    East Asian growth economies (Japan, Taiwan, Singapore and South Korea) until the

    1990s could be attributed largely to the presence of a strong developmental state

    (very often authoritarian and corporatist in nature). Japan was portrayed by Chalmers

    Johnson (1982) as a pioneer model of the developmental or plan-rational state. As

    Beeson (2003: 26) put it, the very idea of the developmental state was reflective ofconceptions and intellectual traditions about the purpose of public policy and the

    concomitant role of government which fundamentally differed from those prevalent in

    the Anglo-American nations. Such an idea can be traced to the Meiji Restoration in

    the 1860s, when the modern Japanese nation-state was created as a response to the

    challenge (and threat) posed by Western capitalist expansion. Wade (1990)s seminal

    study of Japan, South Korea and Taiwan analyzed the nature and operations of the

    market under East Asian developmentalism and summed them up as the governed

    market.

    Among the newly developed East Asian economies, Hong Kong under British

    colonial rule (until 1997) was arguably an exception as it had all along been held asthe last bastion of the free market (Friedman 1981: 54) practicing an official

    2

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    3/30

    philosophy of positive non-interventionism. Whether or not Hong Kong was a

    reverse proof of a successful free-market non-interventionist economy depends on

    how intervention (or non-intervention) was interpreted. Hong Kongs colonial

    government in reality had displayed some unusual instruments for influencing

    industrial activities, so that the economy worked very differently from the textbook

    picture of a free market economy or from those economies of the Anglo-Americankind (Wade 1990: 331-33). Though not of a Western welfare state type, the

    government was active in regulative controls and had extensive involvement in social

    and community services, relying on land revenue instead of heavy taxation as the

    principal means of supporting these services. To that extent Hong Kong was

    recognized by some as having developed a unique model of growth (Schiffer 1983).

    According to Wong (2004: 349-52), the East Asian developmental states had the

    following core features:

    1. Their economies had benefited from the advantages of economic

    backwardness, and hence the advantages of catch-up development, byimporting knowledge, technology, and economic know-how from abroad

    instead of starting from scratch.

    2. They used public policy instruments to allocate productive resources rather

    than relying solely on the market, sometimes playing a big leadership role in

    prospecting potentially lucrative industrial sectors.

    3. They were social welfare laggards because their economic policy, including

    industrial policy, was primarily geared toward maximizing national

    productivity, i.e. rapid economic growth, with distributive consequences being

    considered secondary.

    4. They were highly capable in economic policymaking, implementation, and

    policy monitoring and enforcement.

    5. The developmental state model was anchored in a relatively autonomous, and

    historical hard state in the case of South Korea and Taiwan, functioning

    independently of popular social forces with close linkages with industry.

    Seen in this light, the East Asian development state model attests to Evans (1989,

    1995) notion of embedded autonomy that gives the state the capacity to combine

    two apparently contradictory aspects namely Weberian bureaucratic insulation

    and intense immersion in the surrounding social structure (Evans 1989: 561).

    Similarly, Weiss (1998) argued in favour of the transformative capacity of the state

    insulated from undue special interests but firmly embedded in society, andmaintaining effective linkages with industry and other societal/economic actors to

    ensure the happening of things through what she theorized as governed

    interdependence.

    Expansion of the residualist welfare regime

    As late industrializers, Japan and subsequently other East Asian developed economies

    had historically exhibited a residual form of social welfare based more on family and

    corporate welfare than on state protection (Pierson 2004: 11). Their welfare state2

    2

    The term welfare state is used here as a general term not necessarily denoting any particular formof welfare state such as that in some European countries. As the later discussion explains, there are

    different forms of welfare state.

    3

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    4/30

    was set up and expanded over the last few decades by conservative governments

    with clear antiwelfare ideologies (Aspalter 2002a: 2). Public social expenditures in

    East Asia were considered very low on a world scale according to Gough (2004: 171),

    though he included some Southeast Asian countries within the East Asia sector. The

    figures were slightly higher in developed East Asian states, but still be low by

    Western European and North American standards see Table 1 below.

    Table 1: Total government expenditure and major social policy expenditures,

    as percentages of GDP, in late 1990s

    East Asian

    developed

    economies

    Total government

    expenditure

    1997-98

    Education

    1995-97

    Health

    1997-98

    Social security

    1990-97

    Japan

    Singapore

    Hong Kong

    Taiwan

    South Korea

    29.4

    16.8

    14.5

    22.7

    17.4

    3.7

    1.8

    2.6

    5.0

    3.7

    5.3

    1.2

    1.7

    3.5

    2.2

    6.7

    0.8 (2.2a)

    1.2

    2.2

    3.0

    Selected

    Western

    countries

    Government

    expenditure

    1999

    Education

    1998

    Health

    1998

    Social security

    transfers

    1998

    Australia 31.9b 4.34 5.9 8.4

    Sweden 55.1 6.59 7.0 19.3

    United

    States

    32.7c 4.82 6.1 12.6c

    United

    Kingdom

    37.8 4.65 5.6 13.6

    Germany 44.8 4.35 7.9 19.0

    Notes:a including social-related withdrawals from the Central Provident Fund. b 1998 figurec 1997 figureSource:Figures on the five East Asian developed economies are from Gough (2004: Table 5.2); figures on the five selectedOECD developed economies are from: OECD (2001a: 36-37, unnumbered table) (for general government

    expenditure), OECD (2001b: 80, Table B2.1a) (for public expenditure on education institutions), OECD (2001a: 8-9, unnumbered table) (for public expenditure on healthcare), and OECD (2002: 67, Table 6.3) (for social security

    transfers)

    However, rapid economic growth in the booming decades had resulted in a faster

    expansion in real resources devoted to the social sector than in most countries (Gough

    2004). Rather than an ideological offshoot, the welfare state in Japan, South Korea,Hong Kong, Taiwan and Singapore was explained as largely caused by social

    protests, political pressures, competition in democratic elections, and particular

    demographic changes (ibid). In all of these late industrialized economies, economic

    transformation did not necessarily result in an expanded state welfare regime, and

    changes in welfare expenditures had been modest compared with Western countries.

    According to Pierson (2004: 11), Japan subordinated social policy to the logic of

    nation (re-)building through economic development, with a high economic growth

    strategy built around full (male) employment. Relying on a network of communal and

    family social support, Japanese governments were able to keep to a minimum the

    states responsibility for personal social services. Peng (2002) argued that such awelfare regime was sustained by the anti-welfare stance of the dominant parties (in

    4

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    5/30

    particular the Liberal Democratic Party), though demographic and social changes in

    recent years had seen the gradual rise of new pro-welfare women-friendly social

    policies. Until democratization in the 1990s, South Korea and Taiwan shared the

    features of a system where an authoritarian state, acting closely with business interests

    and in a weak-unions context, fashioned a strategy for national economic

    development. Though social welfare was not a priority, it was improved throughenlarging the economic pie and by way of maximizing employment and upgrading the

    skills base of the economy. In South Korea, the development of the welfare state had

    an underlying logic of politics (Kwon 2002). The government was forced by the 1997

    economic crisis to reform social security schemes and employment programmes, as a

    way to enhance its political legitimacy and broaden electoral appeal.

    In Taiwan, Ku (2002) argued that demographic changes had reduced the role and

    capacity of the family as the most important provider of welfare, and the rise of public

    pressure, social movements and ultimately party competition within a growingly

    democratic political environment following the demise of Kuomintang (KMT,

    Nationalist Party) authoritarianism had driven the state into the establishment of socialinsurance and health insurance schemes. Under the logic of positive non-

    interventionism, colonial Hong Kong had a typical system of residual welfare, though

    education and healthcare had evolved to become almost universal. Chan (2002)

    explained how political factors like pressure groups and social movements,

    politicians agitations, and the governments need for legitimacy had help expand

    welfare provision. Singapore, despite the soft paternalistic nature of its state, had

    largely depended on the contributory Central Provident Fund to provide for various

    accounts and schemes of retirement protection, healthcare and even home purchase

    (Aspalter 2002c).

    Convergence towards or deviation from Western welfare state model

    As East Asian welfare states came to maturity in the 1990s upon reaching a developed

    economy stage, an obvious question is whether they would have eventually converged

    to the typical welfare state model of the West if not for disruption by the 1997 Asian

    financial crisis. The answer depends on whether there exists some kind of established

    welfare state modernization path spurred by economic growth.

    The OECD experience, however, does not attest to such an inevitability. One would

    have presumed that there is greater policy interdependence and convergence among

    Western countries which share in civilization, have greater interaction in economiclife, enjoy similar democratic forms of political governance, and are more or less in

    the same stage of modernity. A common perception was that most OECD countries

    converged in the post-War years towards big government fuelled by rapid economic

    development. From the 1970s onwards, economic and fiscal difficulties had triggered

    a New Right political economy emphasizing rolling back the frontiers of the welfare

    state, deregulation and privatization of public services. Then development of a

    globalized economy had prompted another kind of policy convergence tending

    towards international policy benchmarking and the use of similar policy tools in face

    of perceived common challenges from such globalization.

    However, post-Second World War public policy development in European countriesin OECD had not been evolving along uniform patterns. As Castles (1998) recent

    5

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    6/30

    comparative study of OECD post-War transformation discovered, cross-national

    patterns of social and economic policy outcomes were in a constant state of flux as

    they were shaped by a wide range of economic, social, cultural, political and policy

    factors, which all altered over time. He tested the modernization theory that saw post-

    War economic and social changes as interlinked aspects of a singular process of

    societal transformation leading ultimately to policy convergence amongst nations, andin the end found that the story revealed was of a modernity fractured by major

    political, demographic and cultural fault lines, cross-cutting each other in different

    ways in different nations and, potentially, making for considerable policy diversity

    (1998: 301, italic ours). The fact was modernity could be characterized by quite

    different age and occupational structures across nations, so much so that the story

    became that of a modernity with many mansions (p. 305). Castles suggested there

    were thresholds of modernity in the sense that all these nations had moved into certain

    government programmes (such as universal health coverage and social security which

    were typical of the welfare state), but once such thresholds were reached, nations

    might differ in their policy options and outcomes even if they were of comparable

    economic development. Economic and social development thus acted more as aconstrainingfactor rather than a determining factor in public policy choices.

    Mirroring Esping-Andersons (1990) typology of three worlds of welfare capitalism

    (namely Liberal, Conservative, and Social Democratic), he identified four families of

    nations among OECD countries, whose policy development differences could be

    defined in terms of common cultural, historical and geographical features, namely:

    English-speaking; Scandinavian; continental Western European; and Southern

    European (Castles 1998: 8-9). Japan was deemed to be outside such categorization

    and belong to a new family of newly industrialized nations with East Asian cultural

    (or Confucianist) features. East Asian social policy scholars have certainly sought to

    delineate an East Asian experience distinctive, differing decisively from the Euro-

    American models current in social policy discourse (Kwon, 1998: 27). Cultural

    explanation aside, the argument for a unique East Asian social policy route rests

    mostly on an economic thesis of productivism.

    Productivist welfare capitalism

    Drawing upon Japanese and Korean experience, Kwon (1997) found the

    Conservative welfare regime as classified by Esping-Andersons three worlds

    typology unable to capture the distinctive characteristics of the East Asian welfare

    regime type. Holliday (2000) came up with the notion of a fourth world withproductivist features. This productivist world comprises three distinct subsets namely facilitative (Hong Kong), developmental-universalist (Japan, South

    Korea, Taiwan), and developmental-particularist (Singapore). Table 2 below,

    reproduced from Holliday (2000: table 2), gives the key features of the three subsets.

    Table 2: TheProductivistWorld of Welfare Capitalism

    Social Policy Social Rights Stratification

    Effects

    State-market-

    family

    Relationship

    Facilitative Subordinate to

    economic

    policy

    Minimal Limited Market

    prioritized

    6

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    7/30

    Developmental-

    universalist

    Subordinate to

    economic

    policy

    Limited;

    extensions

    linked to

    productive

    activity

    Reinforcement

    of the position

    of productive

    elements

    State underpins

    market and

    families with

    some universal

    programmes

    Developmental-particularist Subordinate toeconomic

    policy

    Minimal; forcedto individual

    provision linked

    to productive

    activity

    Reinforcementof the position

    of productive

    elements

    State directssocial welfare

    activities of

    families

    Source: Holliday (2000: 710, Table 2)

    Despite internal variations, the essence of this productivist world is that its social

    policy is placed subordinate to economic policy. Holliday argued that productivist

    welfare capitalism could not be fully explained by a unique East Asian social base of

    political superstructure (such as the typical Confucian welfare state argument

    [Jones, 1993] and developmental state argument [Ramesh, 1995; Kwon, 1997], but

    had to be seen as a result of bureaucratic politics that drive social policy development.

    The point is that those technocrats and elite policy makers who staffed key East Asian

    economic agencies were central to the pursuance of particular social and economic

    policy (Holliday 2000: 717). We shall return to this point in the later discussion.

    Citing Japans unique politics of welfare, Miyamoto (2003) disputed treating it in the

    same way as other East Asian states and argued that neither the welfare state regime

    theory a la Esping-Anderson nor the East Asian model could fully capture the

    features of the Japanese welfare state.

    3. Impact of Economic Crisis and Globalization

    Irrespective of whether and how the different East Asian developed economies

    experiences can be neatly captured by a uniform conceptual framework surrounding a

    strong or interventionist state, a key question since the 1997 Asian financial crisis has

    been whether such a previous paradigm of East Asian state model and social policy

    regime has been eroded because of the impact of globalization, economic crisis, and

    political changes (such as democratization such as in South Korea and Taiwan).

    Two trajectories

    If it is accepted that welfare provisions in East Asian countries had been embarked

    upon not out of welfare ideology considerations, but as a result of a fiscally-drivensocial programme funded by economic growth, then it is conceivable that economic

    slowdown and recession can easily triggered a reversal shift. In Hong Kong, Eliza Lee

    (2005) observed that financial austerity had prompted the state to adopt social policy

    reforms through re-commodification and cost containment, resulting in the

    retrenchment of the residual welfare state. The fact that Hong Kong society had never

    before engaged in real ideological debates on social policies or the role and functions

    of the state, also means that mainstream public sentiments could easily be won over to

    a fiscally-driven paradigm of public service. However, it is too early to say that such

    re-commodification process would be driven home too far partly because bureaucratic

    conservatism and caution would see that any such reversal in service provision is less

    dramatic than it would be if induced by mainly ideological or political objectives, and

    7

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    8/30

    partly because there is still a developmentalist function to be served by the welfare

    system.

    Critics of globalization considered globalization not simply as a market-driven

    economic phenomenon, but also very much a political and ideological phenomenon,

    underpinned by the transnational ideology of neoliberalism which seeks to establishits ascendancy world-wide (Mishra 1999: 7). Robison and Hewison (2005) reviewed

    the impact of neo-liberalism on East Asian and Southeast Asian states following the

    1997 Asian economic crisis. While it seemed true that the economic crisis had

    accelerated the restructuring of state and economic power, and offered an opportunity

    for neo-liberal policies to be strengthened such as more market reforms promoted by

    international financial institutions as an alternative to the Asian capitalism - such

    crisis had not succeeded in achieving a grand convergence. In reality, neo-liberalist-

    motivated processes had been highly contested, leading to contradictory, ambiguousand sometimes surprising outcomes (Robison and Hewison 2005: 191). Neo-liberal

    agendas were also found to have been subverted or hijacked by political regimes in

    some circumstances for their own policy and institutional goals.

    An alternative view, in contrast, sees the Asian crisis as actually helping to spur

    welfare expansion rather than retrenchment. The argument is this: The East Asian

    welfare regimes had relied on optimistic assumptions of decade-long high economic

    growth rates, and a high and lifelong male labour market participation (Croissant

    2004: 520). The crisis was compounded by increasing urbanization that resulted in

    demographic changes and weakened the familialistic foundations of the welfare

    regimes, democratization which brought about rising welfare demands, and

    globalization that eroded enterprise-based welfare. The previous welfare regimes

    had proved to be unsustainable in the post-crisis environment. Since no actors other

    than the state will be able to fill the gaps in the welfare system, an increasing role for

    the state is likely (ibid), to the extent that the debate about reform of the welfare

    system is already increasingly shaped by European models (ibid). Examining the

    politics of welfare in Japan, Miyamoto (2003: 21) similarly argued that post-

    industrialization and globalization did not automatically result in welfare

    retrenchment. Where it was true that there were strong tendencies towards financial

    austerity, the concern about increased social instability amidst economic uncertainties

    had given rise to pressure for welfare expansion. The ageing society had also built up

    the need for lessening the family burden and increasing welfare protection for the

    elderly who now constituted a growing portion of the electorate.

    Gough (2004), too, saw the possibility of the transformation of East Asian

    productivist welfare regimes into productivist welfarestate regimes (p. 201) with an

    increasing statist orientation. He observed the East Asian welfare regime as an

    outcome of rapid social development coupled with a residual welfare system highly

    vulnerable to external shocks (Gough 2001: 177-81). In his view, the aftershock of the

    Asian economic crisis would leave East Asian welfare states with two possible

    trajectories (Gould 2004: 199-200). One is towards privatization coupled with

    persistent informalization, such as marketization and privatization (as, for example,

    Eliza Lee [2005] alluded to above), but this route would face the resistance to de-

    statize from an essentially developmentalist regime. The other trajectory is towards a

    more universalist social investment state with more government provision and

    8

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    9/30

    redistribution. The potential for this direction lies in three reasons (Gough 2004: 200-

    01):

    1. Globalization and increased competition demand moving into higher-tech and

    higher-productivity production, requiring more public investment in social

    policy, infrastructure and planning;2. The very weakness of existing social stratification effects among welfare

    recipients and of path-dependency effects in the regime as a whole may permit

    a statist turn; and

    3. The impact of rising democracy in East Asia, notably in Taiwan and South

    Korea.

    Decline of productivism?

    Taking the line of a post-crisis transformation of East Asian welfare systems, there is

    the suggestion that even if they were previously productivist, such productivism may

    have by now outlived its time. For example, Peng (2004) questioned if the logic ofeconomy first, redistribution later which underlined the productivist thesis could

    still be sustained in light of the increasing challenge from three contending factors in

    recent years, name: political and regime changes; the expansion, rather than

    retrenchment, of social welfare programmes in response to recent economic crises,

    which are not necessarily productivistin nature; and new welfare emphasis groundedin family and demographic considerations rather than economic ones. Based on the

    experience of Japan and South Korea, she argued that the East Asian welfare state

    configuration was no longer as economically determined, but also mediated by the

    social structural and domestic political factors. In both countries, the politics of the

    welfare state changed as political regimes and political conditions changed (ibid:

    408). During the 1990s, the end of the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP)s dominant

    one-party rule in Japan had caused political realignments, creating openings for policy

    innovations and allowing new civil society groups to enter the policymaking arena;

    while the 1997 economic crisis and the onset of democracy facilitated the process of

    political realignment in South Korea which saw the Kim Dae-jung government

    embarking on both economic liberalization and welfare expansion (ibid: 415-16). The

    new social policy was thus no longer exclusively confined to protecting and

    privileging the traditional productive sectors, and financial reform necessitated by

    economic crisis had actually caused the demise of company welfare, thereby

    triggering growing political demands for state welfare interventions.

    What Peng and Gough have alluded to are of course important developments in the

    East Asian social policy discourse. However, it remains debatable if East Asian

    welfare states like Japan and South Korea have already moved beyond the stage of

    productivism and developmentalism (Peng 2004: 416) or, as Peng himself has also

    allowed for, such changes are no more than only a reorientation of the productivist

    logic under different social and structural conditions (ibid). Irrespective of the future

    shifts, if developmentalism is still the foundation of policy governance, which we

    argue has continued to be the dominant paradigm, then its welfarist component would

    remain as an offshoot of economic development and thus fiscal accumulation, rather

    than the outcome of a political ideology of collectivist welfare. After all, the role of

    family and individual efforts are still the key elements of the East Asian socialphilosophy that underpins state-society interaction and the response of the state to

    9

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    10/30

    social demands. The post-crisis emphasis on education and economic and industrial

    policy reforms are all geared towards revitalizing state-led developmentalism in the

    new environment of knowledge economy and opened-up markets. Policymaking in

    East Asia has already been dominated by a developmentalist bureaucracy keen on

    state-building. The social policy and social development agenda is determined neither

    by economics nor politics alone, but by bureaucracy-mediated goals of the politicaleconomy that embraces both economic (productivist) and political (social stability,

    distributive and redistributive) imperatives.

    4. Recent Social Policy Reforms

    Policy Shifts rather than Policy Reversals

    We now take a look at major social policy reforms, together with economic and fiscal

    policy developments, in the five East Asian states (Japan, South Korea, Taiwan,

    Singapore and Hong Kong) over the last decade, in order to detect their recent

    trajectories and any significant shifts, especially in the aftermath of the 1997 regional

    financial crisis. Table 3 highlights those salient policy changes and developments.

    [Table 3 about here]

    Education reforms

    It can be observed that across the policy sectors, all East Asian countries seem to

    have been most active in steering the education sector forward, through wide-scale

    school education reform (spanning curriculum reform, school management, and

    improvement in teacher quality), the expansion and liberalization of the tertiarysector, and the promotion of lifelong education, in order to create a larger and better

    educated workforce to cope with the challenge of the new knowledge-based economy

    in the aftermath of globalization and the information technology (IT) revolution. Both

    general education reform and higher education reform are prominent on all the

    national policy agendas. In higher education, corporatization of state universities and

    encouraging private investment seem a common direction. Though private

    involvement is enlarged in the provision of education, this has not diluted the

    proactive role of the state in education which is closely aligned with its objectives in

    achieving economic restructuring and adjustment, and building a more adaptive and

    knowledge-based workforce.Although as Gough (2004: 171) observed, while East

    Asian governments have consistently emphasised the central role of education ineconomic development, this is not matched by a higher-than-average expenditure

    for middle-income countries.

    Healthcare reforms

    In healthcare, Singapore has continued with its policy path dated from the 1980s to

    expect citizens to save more to cater to housing and medical needs through the Central

    Provident Fund (CPF) vehicle, and made compulsory health insurance and savings a

    growing feature of its healthcare system. Hong Kong still operates a predominantly

    government-funded public healthcare system, but is actively reviewing health finance

    arrangements, with an aim to introduce some form of health insurance and/or savings,and increasing user charges. Even in Taiwan, where a comprehensive national health

    10

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    11/30

    insurance system was implemented in 1995, there have been gradual increases in

    insurance premiums in order to cope with rising medical costs. Planning for a second-

    generation national health insurance system was started in 2002, though progress has

    been hampered by increasing political uncertainties facing the prospect of the

    Democratic Progressive Party (DPP) government. Similarly, South Korea and Japan

    are also facing problems of better funding insurance schemes in order to cope withrising demands and facilitate more equitable pooling of risk. The former consolidated

    various health insurance agencies into one single organization. Historically Japans

    healthcare system was highly regulated by government and combines a mainly private

    provision of services with mandatory health insurance, with medical fees approved by

    government (Imai, 2002). Employees of large companies were covered by company-

    based insurance society, while those of SMEs were covered by one big subsidized

    central government insurance scheme and most others by schemes run by

    municipalities (some 3,250 of them). Now, medical system reform is targeted at

    raising contribution rates by citizens, and incorporating long-term care insurance. A

    separate old-age nursing care insurance was introduced in April 2000 (ibid). Recently

    public-private partnership in the form of private finance was introduced to themanagement of public hospitals. In summary, all five jurisdictions have striven to

    maintain the universal coverage of their medical system, mostly through an extended

    insurance scheme, but with increasing concern about raising enough premiums and

    means-tested user fees to meet rising medical costs and patient demands. Private

    sector involvement in the provision of health care is also encouraged.

    Housing reforms

    In housing, Singapore is the only country still pursuing active and extensive state-

    subsidized housing provision in line with its national development agenda since

    independence. In 2003, the government replaced the Small Families Improvement

    Scheme by a new HOPE (Home Ownership Plus Education) programme to help

    these families build up their self-reliance and break out of the poverty trap. The use of

    CPF to buy an extended range of public housing types is encouraged. In Hong Kong,

    the post-1997 housing reform agenda with an ambitious annual new build target of

    85,000 units - to bring down an overheated property market was brought to a drastic

    halt because of the Asian financial crisis. The government also made an important

    retreat by terminating its home ownership scheme (introduced in the late 1970s) and

    sale of public rental housing to sitting tenants (introduced in 1997) in 2002, in order to

    save the private property market, even though its commitment to public renting

    housing remains intact. In Taiwan, South Korea and Japan, private sector housinghas all along been dominating housing provision. The situation has not changed after

    the Asian crisis - for example, even now public renting housing represents only 3% of

    all housing units in South Korea (Lee, K. B. 2005). In cope with the post-crisis

    economic situation, though, their governments have provided various support

    measures to lower-income households mainly in the form of housing loans and some

    limited public renting housing. South Korea has also introduced measures on real

    estate stabilization, while Japan has abolished the Government Housing Loan

    Corporation in order not to be seen as competing with the private sector in the

    housing finance market. While no significant policy reversal is observed in the five

    states in relation to their pre-existing housing policy regimes, the recent trend has

    been to stabilize the housing market and to encourage more private sector provision.

    11

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    12/30

    Welfare and labour protection reforms

    In the area of welfare and labour protection, Hong Kong has been trying to contain

    the growth of social security expenditure (through the review of CSSA eligibility and

    allowance rates), though the level of welfare expenditure (including unemployment

    benefits and old age allowance) has still increased because of the economic downturn.In 2005 government was forced by political and public pressures to set up a Poverty

    Commission. Despite its non-interventionist policy orientation, the administration of

    newly installed Chief Executive Donald Tsang is prepared to support a community-

    wide debate on the issues of minimum wage and standard working hours, which trade

    unions have been pushing for a long time but which business and employer interests

    have all along resisted. In Singapore no new social security programme involving

    significant additional public expenditure has been established since the 1960s

    (Ramesh 2003: 83) and government has started wage reform and CPF reform. As

    relief measures in the aftermath of the Asian crisis, Singapore has introduced various

    shorter term initiatives such as the Eldercare Fund, Children Development Co-

    Savings Scheme (known as Baby Bonus) and CPF top-up in 2000, the EconomicDownturn Relief Scheme in 2001, and the New Singapore Shares in 2001 and

    Economic Restructuring Shares from 2003 onwards. The objective is to achieve a

    New Social Compact to cope with the challenge of a New Economy. A Workforce

    Development Agency was set up to enhance employability, and new measures were

    introduced in 2006 to support low-wage workers. Both city states are giving greater

    emphasis on voluntary and third-sector involvement in welfare and community

    service provision.

    In Japan, welfare laws have been revised, social security system revamped, and

    pension reforms and long-term care insurance reforms initiated because of

    unemployment and the ageing population. Regime change and democratization of the

    political system in South Korea and Taiwan during the late 1990s coincided with

    the advent of the Asian financial crisis and the rising challenge of globalization. As a

    result, both have engaged more actively in providing unemployment benefits and

    some form of minimum living allowance/social assistance schemes, as well as

    measures for labour protection, for political as well as social policy purposes. South

    Korea adopted a Protection First system for the elderly and unprivileged, and

    expanded the Social Safety Plan to increase financial support to low-income families.

    In Taiwan, the Employment Insurance Programme was enhanced in 2003 and an

    Employment Protection Law enacted in 2004.

    Overall, both the trends of welfare review and reform with a viewing to containing

    expenditure growth, as well as the attempts to provide relief and minimum living

    support allowance schemes, are taking place concurrently, underlining the impact of

    fiscal and economic pressures, and the states objectives to keep society sufficiently

    harmonious for the purpose of economic growth.

    Economic and fiscal policy reforms

    The 1997 regional economic crisis has also resulted in stepped-up measures in

    economic and fiscal policy reforms. Fiscal reform, deregulation, and economic

    revitalization are among key items of government policy agenda in all five EastAsian states. All have engaged actively in financial services sector regulatory reform,

    12

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    13/30

    coupled with the establishment of proper supervisory/regulatory institution (such as a

    Financial Supervisory Commission/Agency) to promote better corporate governance,

    a stronger fair competition regime, tax review or reform to secure a more steady and

    broader taxation base, and new initiatives to nurture entrepreneurship and innovation,

    especially IT development. All five have also strengthened their fair trade and pro-

    competition regimes. Singapore enacted a Competition Law in 2004 while HongKong is in the process of doing so.

    In Japan, an Industrial Revitalization Corporation was set up in 2003 to provide

    assistance to small and medium enterprises (SMEs). South Korea places the thrust of

    economic policy similarly on nurturing SMEs and their IT capabilities as the next-

    generation growth engines. Taiwan extends credit support to traditional industries

    and SMEs and establishes R&D centres and free trade zones. Singapore has set up a

    Research, Innovation and Enterprise Council in 2005 and also provides strong support

    to the internationalisation of its government-linked companies (GLCs), and even

    small government Hong Kong had established an SME Financial Assistance

    Scheme in 2001. Innovation technology is given special importance in all jurisdictionsto respond to the challenge of the new knowledge economy and to open up a new

    frontier for the next round of economic expansion as they can no longer rely on the

    traditional export-oriented manufacturing and service industries for growth and

    prosperity. Such developmentalist strategy ties in closely with the direction of

    education reforms as highlighted above.

    Policy shifts rather than policy reversals

    In short, economic challenges like globalization and the Asian financial crisis, and

    political challenges like regime change with democratization (South Korea and

    Taiwan) or without democratization (Hong Kong), and the gradual rise of new politics

    (Japan included), together with increasing fiscal/budgetary pressure (notably in Japan,

    Taiwan and Hong Kong), have together helped to induced public policy rethinking in

    the various East Asian governments. All have to rise to the demands for policy shifts

    (and some for even policy reversals). No doubt, new initiatives and modifications

    have been launched (such as towards contributory support of public healthcare,

    withdrawal from state-subsidized home ownership in Hong Kong, and a wider

    acceptance of minimum living standard and income).

    Policy shifts, certainly there are, but evidence as enumerated above does not point to

    policy reversalsper se, such as in drastically privatizing state responsibilities. Atbest, the government had only resorted more to regulating corporate and privateresources on welfare, and in imposing legislative frameworks for welfare schemes.

    The mode of policy delivery governance has, however, seen some notable changes,

    such as moving increasingly from state provision to shared responsibility (compulsory

    insurance/savings schemes, public-private partnership, and more voluntary/third-

    sector involvement) and contracted-out provision and private sector production, but

    such shifts in public management systems has not fundamentally eroded the old

    regime of East Asian governance, nor diluted (not to say negated) the state

    domination, except with reference to Hong Kong, which has all along been a muddled

    type of deviant among the East Asian states. Path dependency is still very much in

    play, sustained by institutional continuity. Policy changes have not movedsignificantly beyond the original policy path which is still essentially productivist and

    13

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    14/30

    conforms to the East Asian model of state developmentalism. State policymakers and

    managers remain to espouse strong developmentalist thinking (despite the advent of

    new democratic regimes in Taiwan and South Korea). Even Hong Kongs post-

    colonial regime has become more proactive in economic and industrial policy because

    of business pressure and political motives (Cheung 2000).

    The picture is not complete without tracking the fiscal performance of the East Asian

    states. Over the past decade, public expenditure as a percentage of GDP over the past

    decade in the five developed East Asian states had not recorded any pattern of

    substantial contraction (Table 4 below), though fiscal stress created by the fluctuating

    economic performance after the Asian financial crisis had accounted for some

    adjustments. Even Japan had managed to maintain a relatively stable level since the

    mid-1990s despite the bursting of the economic bubble in the beginning of the 1990s.

    It is interesting to note that in the case of South Korea, Taiwan and Hong Kong,

    public expenditure had actually taken up a higher proportion of GDP since the Asian

    crisis which hit them more severely than Singapore. The fiscal picture in a sense

    corroborates the path of public policy developments highlighted above.

    Table 4: Public expenditure as percentage of GDP, 1996-2005

    Public

    expenditure as

    percentage of

    GDP

    Japan South

    Korea

    Taiwan Singapore Hong Kong

    1996 36.5* 14.0 14.8 n.a. 17.7

    1997 35.3 14.1 15.6 18.4 17.5

    1998 42.7* 16.4 12.7 18.0 17.5

    1999 n.a. 16.6 13.8 18.1 20.82000 36.4* 15.1 15.9 c 17.5 21.6

    2001 38.0* 15.9 17.1 18.1 21.1

    2002 38.1* 15.9 15.3 17.1 20.9

    2003 n.a. 16.3 16.0 16.8 22.2

    2004 36.9* 15.2a 15.2 15.6 20.7a

    2005 n.a. 16.6a 16.0 14.8b n.a.Notes:

    n.a. = figures not available.

    All figures are for financial years except for most years in Japan, marked with*.aestimates;bpreliminary figure;

    cfrom July 1999 to December 2000.

    Sources:

    Japan Ministry of Finance (various issues); Ministry of Finance (various years); South Korea Ministry ofPlanning and Budget (2006); Taiwan Directorate-General of Budget (various years); Singapore Ministry ofTrade and Industry (various years) [figures calculated by author based on official GDP (current market prices),

    government operating expenditure, and government development expenditure figures]; Hong Kong - InformationServices Department (various years).

    5. Explanations of East Asian Policy Steadiness

    Path of East Asian public policy governance

    The developmentalist nature of East Asian states has to be understood not just as an

    economic management strategy, but historically path-dependent, which hascontributed towards policy steadiness. Public policy governance is grounded in a

    14

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    15/30

    strong tradition of centralized, politics-administration fusion. Both Singapore and

    Hong Kong are typical administrative states where either the bureaucracy runs the

    state (as clearly in colonial Hong Kong) or the ruling party and the bureaucracy are

    one (Singapore). Taiwan until the late 1990s was under the KMT one-party rule

    where bureaucrats were at the same time KMT functionaries. Things might be for a

    change after the DPP came to power in 2000, but there seems a tendency for DPP tofollow the footsteps of KMT in politicizing the bureaucracy and public corporations

    to create another interlocking model of governance. In Japan, the bureaucracy has

    been a strong staying force in government decision-making, which despite a long

    history of administrative reforms, makes the reform experience mostly a slow and

    somewhat hesitant process, because of the previously successful inter-locking array of

    institutions which were resistant to rapid change (Beeson 2003). Reforms were more

    often than not a compromise with the agency bureaucrats, known as pre-emptive

    bureaucrats (Ito 1995: 251). The same scepticism existed in South Korea where

    bureaucrats generally saw reform activities as a source of instability and uncertainty

    (Hahm and Kim 1999: 491).

    The East Asian bureaucracy is considered as a modernizing and developmental force,

    in line with the nature of the state. Public management reforms have been pursued

    mostly to secure new or reinvented structures and systems of operations that can

    improve the capacity of the state (and of the bureaucracy), so as to better lead nation-

    building and economic development efforts. Thus administrative reforms have tended

    to adopt a pro-bureaucracy or at least bureaucracy-friendly orientation, and are

    usually bureaucrats-driven. In the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis, as global

    competition intensifies resulting in more economic pressures, reform agendas might

    have embraced more overt managerial, fiscal and economic objectives that seek to

    make the bureaucracy less bloated and more efficient, and to contain fiscal pressure,

    but this is far from trying to erode public bureaucratic power. Despite the apparent

    similarity of the East Asian governance and public sector reforms to the OECD-

    pioneered new public management reforms, the political and institutional setting for

    such reforms is quite distinct from a typical Western context (Cheung 2005). Some

    key features can be identified as in Table 5 below.

    Table 5: Features of governance reform setting of East Asian governments

    Administrative

    traditions and legacies

    Strong, centralized bureaucratic tradition;

    politics-administration fusion (Singapore and Hong Kong are

    typical administrative states)

    Nature of political

    economy

    Developmental state governed market model (with the

    exception of Hong Kong which displays a semi-interventionist

    model)

    State role and capacity Historically strong capacity; highly interventionist (less so in

    Hong Kong)

    Salience of

    administrative reform

    Bureaucratic modernization and self-improvement; state

    capacity enhancement

    Forces for change Mainly bureaucrats-driven, until most recently when politics

    and societal demands push for greater pace of reform. (In

    Singapore, there is a joint politics-bureaucracy agenda)

    Outcome so far Bureaucratic domination of reform agenda, with slow

    progress. (Successful public service bargain in Singapore,hence minimum bureaucratic resistance)

    Source: Cheung (2005: Table 2)

    15

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    16/30

    Bureaucrats-dominated policymaking

    A key reason for policy steadiness in East Asian public policy governance

    including social policymaking - is thus the bureaucrats-dominated nature of public

    policy making, in addition to the state-led economic development approach to policyinterventions, which see things in economic/developmental perspectives rather than

    strict welfare vs. market dichotomies. Bureaucrats who have been the driving force in

    public policy formulations are not used to drastic changes that upset thestatus quo toomuch. Their preferred mode of operation is policy modifications and readjustments

    along the original policy path, or what Hogwood and Peters (1983) described as

    policy succession. Bureaucrats, or politicians thinking like them or in alignment

    with them, tend to see the world as more static and policies as vehicles to help achieve

    stable development. Once settled in state-led developmentalism, or in Hong Kongs

    case a kind of growth-oriented positive non-interventionism, they are unlikely to

    change course substantially even amidst economic crisis because of the complexities

    and, at times, the inertia imposed by inter-locking interests between state, society andindustry.

    Besides, the recalcitrance of bureaucrats who are inherent stakeholders of existing

    policies and the modus operandi, as well as the opposition or even open revolt by

    other stakeholders who felt affected by drastic policy changes, such as teachers, health

    care workers, social workers, and civil servants at large, would serve to prevent too

    much deviation from pre-existing policy governance. The fierce opposition of civil

    servants to pay reductions and contracting out in Hong Kong, and that of Taiwanese

    teachers to education reform, are cases in point. In Japan, as well as South Korea and

    Taiwan both of which were previously colonized by Japan and have inherited a public

    administration system whereby legislative approval of detailed policy programmes

    and administration organizational plans is mandatory, executive-legislative gridlock

    grounded in factional politics is yet another cause of slow policymaking. This has

    resulted in a high degree of policy continuity and slow incremental policy change.

    Despite the 2004 electoral system reform in Japan which some assumed to have

    weakened traditional factions within the ruling LDP, factional politics have not

    subsided. As Krauss and Pekkanen (2004:1) pointed out, [u]nexpected, kenkai [i.e.factions] have grown stronger because they perform new functions. LDPs Policy

    Research Council remains a major avenue of career advancement and specialization

    for Diet members and an important if now challenged structure for policymaking. Its

    structure and norms are still a means for specialized zoku giin (Policy Tribes Dietmembers) to function as gatekeepers over the policy and legislative agenda ofindividual members and the bureaucracy in LDPs and governments legislative

    process (ibid: 23).

    Accumulation and legitimation in East Asian capitalism

    The emergence of the welfare state as part of Western capitalism can be explained in

    various ways like functionalist theories and conflict theories of both the Marxist and

    non-Marxist orientations (Aspalter 2002b). Market and capitalism, like any

    institutions, are politically and culturally embedded in society. As Gray (1999: 191-2)

    argued, it is a mistake to assume that capitalism everywhere will come to resemblethe highly individualist culture of England, Scotland and parts of Germany and The

    16

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    17/30

    Netherlands. It has not done so in France or Italy. Polanyi (1944) had similarly

    pointed out much earlier that market institutions did not emerge spontaneously, but

    rather often depended heavily on state actions. Indeed the creation of national markets

    in the West had historically coincided with the constitution and expansion of state

    institutions (United Nations Development Programme 1999). In the same vein, the

    welfare state is a construct of state actions within a historically and nationally specificcultural, political and social context.

    There are thus different forms of welfare states, embodying different forms of social

    policy development, inasmuch as there are different forms of capitalism. As market

    capitalism is not an abstracted final stage of economic evolution (Robison 2003:

    168), so the Western welfare state model is not the ultimate destiny of a welfare state

    development trajectory that all welfare states - European, American and Asian, etc. -

    had to converge to. Even globalization does not necessarily end up in convergence,

    either towards a universalist welfare regime or a neo-liberal economic regime

    sceptical of welfare. As an old Chinese philosophical saying puts it: a white horse is

    not a horse, so the impact of globalization may bring about divergence as much asconvergence. Indigenous values and projects count more than simply emulating some

    external models even as the process of policy learning and diffusion takes place.

    Whether globalization can predetermine the specific context and agenda of policy-

    making at the national level is therefore problematic. Even if policy ideas may get

    transferred globally, policymaking and politics are always local.

    Social policy regimes are the outcome of institutional pathways which in themselves

    are constructs of social processes and of historical evolution. In the Western

    experience, if one were to employ the Marxist functionalist interpretation, capitalism

    came to a point where it suffered from the crisis of accumulation (i.e. continued

    growth and capital accumulation) and the crisis of legitimacy (of the capitalist mode

    of production). The role of the state in serving the ultimate interest of the logic of

    capitalism is to promote both economic growth (accumulation) and the stability of

    the social and political order (legitimation) through extensive social policy

    provisions and the construction of a welfare state that helps to reduce class

    confrontations and political challenges to the capitalist system (OConnor 1973;

    Gough 1979; Offe 1984). Among East Asian states, developmentalism (subsumingboth economic and politicalproductivism) can similarly be understood as an array of

    state actions and interventions in promoting and bolstering a unique form of market

    capitalism (which some describe as state-led for economies like South Korea and

    Singapore, and others depict as predatory or clientelist for countries likeIndonesia and Thailand).

    In the aftershock of the Asian financial crisis, facing increasing pressure from

    globalization as well as the domestic politics of democratization, the developmental

    welfare state of both South Korea and Taiwan had clearly become more inclusive.

    According to Kwon (2005: 495), the socially inclusive welfare regime helped these

    two states to come out of the economic crisis without suffering too many adverse

    social effects, such as a sharp rise of poverty or serious worsening of income

    inequality. Granted, social policy helps to mitigate the impact of economic setback

    and uncertainty, and enables the society to regain cohesion and the collective capacity

    to pursue economic development, with still strong productivist connotations. In anycase, the need for sustained growth (or accumulation in the Marxist sense) and

    17

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    18/30

    political legitimacy (legitimation) would make it imperative for an increased state

    role for East Asian states in social policy development despite a cultural and social

    context that had traditionally assigned welfare functions to the family, the clan and the

    corporate sector (as in Japan). The essence of the East Asian welfare state to facilitate

    the growth of East Asian capitalism would, like how Marxists and neo-Marxists had

    explained the relationship between Western capitalism and its welfare state, support asocial policy discourse that cannot be decoupled from the larger developmentalist

    paradigm.

    References:

    Aspalter, C. (2002a) Introduction, in C. Aspalter (ed) Discovering the Welfare State in EastAsia, Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers, pp. 1-8.

    Aspalter, C. (2002b) Exploring Old and New Shores in Welfare State Theory, in C.

    Aspalter (ed)Discovering the Welfare State in East Asia, Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers,

    pp. 9-38.

    Aspalter, C. (2002c) Singapore: A Welfare State in a Class by Itself, in C. Aspalter (ed)

    Discovering the Welfare State in East Asia , Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers, pp. 169-90.

    Beeson, M. (2003) Japans reluctant reformers and the legacy of the developmental state, in

    A. B. L. Cheung and I. Scott (eds) Governance and Public Sector Reform in Asia: ParadigmShifts or Business As Usual?, London: RoutledgeCurzon, pp. 25-43.

    Castles, F.G. (1998) Comparative Public Policy: Patterns of Post-war Transformation,Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Chan, R. (2002) The Struggle of Welfare Development in Hong Kong, in C. Aspalter (ed)Discovering the Welfare State in East Asia , Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers, pp. 81-114.

    Chen, C. (2005) Taiwans Burgeoning Budget Deficit: A Crisis in the Making?, Asian

    Survey, Vol. 45, No. 3, pp. 383-96.

    Chen, H. N. (2002), Taiwan, in R. Agus, J. F. Doling and D. Lee (eds) Housing PolicySystems in South and East Asia, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 84-103.

    Cheung, A, B, L. (2000) New Interventionism in the Making: Interpreting State

    Interventions in Hong Kong After the Change of Sovereignty, Journal of ContemporaryChina, Vol. 9, No. 24, July, pp. 291-308.

    Cheung, A. B. L. (2005) The Politics of Administrative Reforms in Asia: Paradigms and

    Legacies, Paths and Diversities, Governance, Vol. 18, No. 2, pp. 257-82.

    Croissant, A. (2004) Changing Welfare Regimes in East and Southeast Asia: Crisis, Change

    and Challenge, Social Policy and Administration, Vol. 38, No. 5, pp. 504-24.

    Directorate-General of Budget, Accounting and Statistics, Executive Yuan of Taiwan (various

    years), Zhuyao Guojia Zhongyang Zhengfu Zhichu Zhan Guonei Shengchan Maoe (GDP)Bilu [ (GDP) ],http://win.dgbas.gov.tw/dgbas03/bs8/world/expgdp.htm.

    Esping-Anderson, G. (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, Cambridge: Polity

    Press.

    18

    http://win.dgbas.gov.tw/dgbas03/bs8/world/expgdp.htmhttp://win.dgbas.gov.tw/dgbas03/bs8/world/expgdp.htmhttp://win.dgbas.gov.tw/dgbas03/bs8/world/expgdp.htm
  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    19/30

    Evans, P. B. (1989) Predatory, Developmental and Other Apparatuses: A Comparative

    Political Economy Perspective on the Third World State, Sociological Forum, No. 4, pp.233-46.

    Evans, P. B. (1995). Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation, Princeton,

    N. J.: Princeton University Press.

    Friedman, M. (1981) Free To Choose, Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.

    Fukawa, T. (2005) Some structural issues in the Japanese social security system, The

    Japanese Journal of Social Security Policy, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 67-75.

    Gough, I. (1979) The Political Economy of the Welfare State, London: Macmillan.

    Gough, I. (2004) East Asia: the limits of productivist regimes, in I. Gough, G. Wood et al

    Insecurity and Welfare Regimes in Asia, Africa and Latin America: Social Policy in

    Development Context, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp.169-201.

    Gray, J. (1999)False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism, London: Granta Books.

    Hahm, S. D. and Kim, K. W. (1999) Institutional Reforms and Democratization in Korea:

    The Case of the Kim Young Sam Administration, 1993-1998, Governance, Vol. 12, No. 4,October, pp. 479-94.

    Hayakawa, K. (2002) Japan, in R. Agus, J. F. Doling and D. Lee (eds) Housing PolicySystems in South and East Asia, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 20-37.

    Hogwood, B. W. and Peters, B. G. (1983)Policy Dynamics, Brighton: Wheatsheaf.

    Holliday, I. (2000) Productivist Welfare Capitalism: Social Policy in East Asia, PoliticalStudies, Vol. 48, pp. 706-23.

    Imai, Y. (2002) Health Care Reform in Japan, Economic Department Working Papers, No.

    321, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris: OECD.

    Information Services Department, Government Hong Kong Special Administrative Region

    (various years)Hong Kong Year Book, http://www.info.gov.hk/yearbook/.

    Ito, M. (1995) Administrative Reform, in H. K. Kim, M. Muramatsu, T. J. Pempel and K.

    Yamamura (eds) The Japanese Civil Service and Economic Development: Catalysts of

    Change, Oxford: Clarendon Press, pp. 235-60.

    Johnson, C. (1982) MITI and the Japanese Miracle, Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Jones, C. (1993) The Pacific Challenge: Confucian Welfare States, in C. Jones (ed) New

    Perspectives on the Welfare State in Europe, London: Routledge, pp. 198-217.

    Krauss, E. and Pekkanen, R. (2004) Explaining Party Adaptation to Electoral Reform: The

    Discreet Charm of the LDP?,Journal of Japanese Studies, Vol. 30, No. 1, pp. 1-34.

    Ku, Y. W. (2002) Towards a Taiwanese Welfare State: Demographic Change, Politics, and

    Social Policy, in C. Aspalter (ed)Discovering the Welfare State in East Asia, Westport, CT:Praeger Publishers, pp. 143-68.

    19

    http://www.info.gov.hk/yearbook/http://www.info.gov.hk/yearbook/http://www.info.gov.hk/yearbook/
  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    20/30

    Kwon, H. J. (1997) Beyond European welfare regimes: comparative perspectives on East

    Asian welfare systems,Journal of Social Policy, Vol. 26, pp. 467-84.

    Kwon, H. J. (1998) Democracy and the Politics of Social Welfare: A Comparative Analysis

    of Welfare Systems in East Asia, in R. Goodman, G. White, and H. J. Kwon (eds) The EastAsian Welfare Model: Welfare Orientalism and the State, London: Routledge, pp. 27-74.

    Kwon, H. J. (2002) The Korean Welfare State: Development and Reform Agenda, in C.

    Aspalter (ed)Discovering the Welfare State in East Asia, Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers,pp. 63-80.

    Kwon, H. J. (2005) Transforming the Development Welfare State in East Asia,

    Development and Change, Vol. 36, No. 3, pp. 477-97.

    Lee, D. (2002) Korea, in R. Agus, J. F. Doling and D. Lee (eds) Housing Policy Systems inSouth and East Asia, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 104-26.

    Lee, K. B. (2005) The Effects of the Aug. 31 Real Estate Measures, Korea Policy Review,October, pp. 50-53.

    Lee, E. W. Y. (2005) The Renegotiation of the Social Pact in Hong Kong: Economic

    Globalization, Socio-economic Change, and Local Politics, Journal of Social Policy, Vol.34, No. 2, pp. 293-310.8

    Marshall, T. H. and Tom Bottomore (1992) Citizenship and Social Class, London: PlutoPress.

    Ministry of Finance, Government of Japan (various issues) Public Finance RelatedInformation [], http://www.mof.go.jp/jouhou/syukei/siryou/sy_new.htm.

    Ministry of Finance, Government of Japan (various years) Understanding the JapaneseBudget (previous under series name The Japanese Budget in Brief),http://www.mof.go.jp/english/budget/budget.htm.

    Ministry of Planning and Budget, Government of Republic of Korea (various years) Annual Budget Expenditures, FY 1996-FY2006, http://www.mpb.go.kr/english.html (MPB Data:Statistics section).

    Ministry of Trade and Industry, Government of Singapore (various years) Economic Surveyof Singapore, http://app.mti.gov.sg/default.asp?id=123&cat=2

    Mishra, R. (1999) Globalization and the Welfare State, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Miyamoto, T. (2003) Dynamics of the Japanese Welfare State in Comparative Perspective:

    Between Three Worlds and the Developmental State, The Japanese Journal of SocialSecurity Policy, Vol. 2, No. 2, pp. 12-24.

    OConnor, J. (1973) The Fiscal Crisis of the State, New York: St. Martins Press.

    Offe, C. (1984) Contradictions of the Welfare State (ed. by J. Keane), Cambridge, MA.: MITPress.

    OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development) (2001a) OECD inFigures 2001, Paris: OECD,http://www.sourceoecd.org/.

    20

    http://www.mof.go.jp/jouhou/syukei/siryou/sy_new.htmhttp://www.mof.go.jp/english/budget/budget.htmhttp://www.mof.go.jp/english/budget/budget.htmhttp://www.mpb.go.kr/english.htmlhttp://app.mti.gov.sg/default.asp?id=123&cat=2http://www.sourceoecd.org/http://www.mof.go.jp/jouhou/syukei/siryou/sy_new.htmhttp://www.mof.go.jp/english/budget/budget.htmhttp://www.mpb.go.kr/english.htmlhttp://app.mti.gov.sg/default.asp?id=123&cat=2http://www.sourceoecd.org/
  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    21/30

    OECD (2001b) Education at a Glance: OECD Indicators, Paris: OECD,http://www.sourceoecd.org/.

    OECD (2002) OECD Historical Statistics 1997-2000, Paris: OECD,http://www.sourceoecd.org/.

    Peng, Ito (2002) Gender and Welfare State Restructuring in Japan, in C. Aspalter (ed)

    Discovering the Welfare State in East Asia , Westport, CT: Praeger Publishers, pp. 39-62.

    Peng, Ito (2004) Postindustrial Pressures, Political Regime Shifts, and Social Policy Reform

    in Japan and South Korea,Journal of East Asian Studies, Vol. 4, pp. 389-425.

    Pierson, C. (2004) Late Industrializers and the Development of the Welfare State, Social

    Policy and Development Programme Paper No. 16, September, United Nations: UN Research

    Institute for Social Development.

    Pinker, R. A. (1979) The Idea of Welfare, London: Heinemann Educational.

    Polanyi, K. (1944) The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of OurTime, Boston: Beacon Press.

    Ramesh, M. (1995) Social security in South Korea and Singapore: Explaining the

    differences, Social Policy and Administration, Vol. 29, pp. 228-40.

    Ramesh, M. (2003) Globalization and social security expansion in East Asia, in L. Weiss

    (ed) States in the Global Economy: Bringing Domestic Institutions Back In, Cambridge:Cambridge University Press, pp. 83-100.

    Robison, R. (2003) Looking Back on the Asian Crisis: The Question of Convergence,

    Asian Journal of Social Science, Vol. 31, No. 2, pp. 162-71.

    Robison, R. and Hewison, K. (2005) Introduction: East Asia and the Trials of Neo-

    liberalism, The Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 41, No. 2, pp. 183-96.

    Schiffer, J. R. (1983) Anatomy of a Laissez-faire Government: The Hong Kong GrowthModel Reconsidered, Hong Kong: Centre of Urban Studies and Urban Planning, University ofHong Kong.

    Shin, C. and Shaw, I. (2003) Social Policy in South Korea: Cultural and Structural Factors in

    the Emergence of Welfare, Social Policy and Administration, Vol. 37, No. 4, pp. 328-41.

    United Nations Development Programme (1999) China Human Development Report 1999:Transition and the State, New York: United Nations.

    Wade, R. (1990) Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government inEast Asian Industrialization, Princeton, N. J.: Princeton University Press.

    Weiss, L. (1998) The Myth of the Powerless State, Ithaca, N. Y.: Cornell University Press.

    Wong, J. (2004) The Adaptive Developmental State in East Asia, Journal of East AsianStudies, Vol. 4, pp. 345-62.

    World Bank (1993) The East Asian Economic Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy,New York: Oxford University Press.

    21

    http://www.sourceoecd.org/http://www.sourceoecd.org/http://www.sourceoecd.org/http://www.sourceoecd.org/
  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    22/30

    Government website sources for Tables 3:

    Japan

    Office of the Cabinet Public Relations, Cabinet Secretariat (Japan), Speeches and Statements

    by Prime Minister Junichiro Koizumi,http://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/koizumispeech/index_e.html

    Office of the Cabinet Public Relations, Cabinet Secretariat (Japan), Archives of PreviousCabinets (Since 1996), http://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/archives_e.html

    South Korea

    Cheong Wa Dae Office of the President, Republic of Korea, Cheongwadae Archives List -

    Speeches, http://english.president.go.kr/warp/app/en_speeches/list?group_id=en_archive&meta_id=en_speeches

    Taiwan

    Research, Development and Evaluation Commission, Executive Yuan, Tuidong Gongying

    Shiye Minyinghua [],http://www.rdec.gov.tw/public/Attachment/521217123871.doc

    State-owned Enterprise Commission, Ministry of Economic Affairs, Executive Yuan,

    http://www.moeacnc.gov.tw

    The Executive Yuan of the Republic of China (Taiwan), Shizheng Jihua [] (variousyears since 2001),http://www.ey.gov.tw/web92/n_policies_list.asp.htm

    Singapore

    Government of Singapore,Prime Ministers National Day Rally Speech (various years since2000), http://www.gov.sg/pressreleases.htm

    Ministry of Finance, Budget Archives (various years since 1996),http://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_archives/index.html

    Ministry of Finance, Budget Speech 2005,http://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_2005/index.html

    Hong Kong

    Government of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, Peoples Republic of China,

    Policy Address by the Chief Executive (various years since 1997),http://www.policyaddress.gov.hk/

    22

    http://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/koizumispeech/index_e.htmlhttp://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/archives_e.htmlhttp://english.president.go.kr/warp/app/en_speeches/list?group_id=en_archive&meta_id=en_speecheshttp://english.president.go.kr/warp/app/en_speeches/list?group_id=en_archive&meta_id=en_speecheshttp://www.rdec.gov.tw/public/Attachment/521217123871.dochttp://www.moeacnc.gov.tw/http://www.ey.gov.tw/web92/n_policies_list.asp.htmhttp://www.ey.gov.tw/web92/n_policies_list.asp.htmhttp://www.gov.sg/pressreleases.htmhttp://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_archives/index.htmlhttp://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_2005/index.htmlhttp://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_2005/index.htmlhttp://www.policyaddress.gov.hk/http://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/koizumispeech/index_e.htmlhttp://www.kantei.go.jp/foreign/archives_e.htmlhttp://english.president.go.kr/warp/app/en_speeches/list?group_id=en_archive&meta_id=en_speecheshttp://english.president.go.kr/warp/app/en_speeches/list?group_id=en_archive&meta_id=en_speecheshttp://www.rdec.gov.tw/public/Attachment/521217123871.dochttp://www.moeacnc.gov.tw/http://www.ey.gov.tw/web92/n_policies_list.asp.htmhttp://www.gov.sg/pressreleases.htmhttp://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_archives/index.htmlhttp://www.mof.gov.sg/budget_2005/index.htmlhttp://www.policyaddress.gov.hk/
  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    23/30

    Table 3: Salient public policy changes in Japan and East Asian NICs since 1990s

    Japan South Korea Taiwan Singapore Hong Kong

    Education Amendment ofSchool Education

    Law to promote

    flexibility and

    diversity in schooleducation system

    Education Reform

    Plan for the 21st

    Century launched in

    2001 (National

    Commission onEducation Reform)

    National universitiesto be converted to be

    National University

    Corporations

    CompulsoryEducation Reform

    (2004) more

    flexibilities in current

    9-year compulsoryeducation, new

    licensing and renewal

    system for teachers,

    and involvement ofparents and local

    authorities in school

    management

    Higher EducationReform to merge 10

    national universities

    into 5

    Brain Korea (BK)21 a 7-year project

    to develop world-

    class research-centreduniversities (2005)

    Comprehensivereform of education

    system started in 1996

    (curriculum reform,

    expansion of highereducation, quality

    assurance,

    encouraging non-governmentinvestment, autonomy

    of universities, and

    corporatization of

    public universities)

    Amendment to

    University Law in2005 to enable public

    universities to select

    their own presidents

    Provision ofkindergarten

    education vouchers

    Emphasis ondeveloping workforce

    for knowledge

    economy and

    promotion of R&D

    Curriculum reform

    Establishment of

    Lifelong LearningEndowment Fund(2000)

    Upgrading

    universities and

    creating higheducation hub in the

    region (build a 5th

    polytechnic and 3

    new junior colleges)

    More autonomy to

    public universities

    and corporatization of

    National Universityof Singapore and

    Nanyang

    Technological

    University

    Education reform amajor agenda of new

    Tung administration

    (1997) (holistic

    education, curriculumreform, academic

    structure reform,

    teacher qualityupgrading, ITeducation, and

    promotion of lifelong

    education

    Increasing highereducation rate through

    associate degree

    education

    Encouraging privateschools and Direct

    Subsidy Schools

    (DSS).

    School-basedManagement

    Establishment ofQuality Education

    Fund

    Health Revision of HealthInsurance Law

    (1997) - 80% of

    medical costs to be

    paid to the insured;

    National HealthInsurance extended

    to universal coverage

    in 1989

    Consolidation of

    Introduction ofnational health

    insurance scheme

    aimed at universal

    coverage in 1995

    Introduction ofMedisave

    (compulsory savings

    scheme) and

    Medisheld (insurance

    Review of HealthcareFinance in 1999 -

    Harvard Study

    advocated compulsory

    health insurance-cum-

    23

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    24/30

    introduction of

    prescription drugs

    Increase of patientscost-sharing in 2000

    Implementation ofthe Long Term Care

    Insurance in 2000,

    and subsequent

    reform in 2005

    Medical System

    Reform in 2002 to

    increase contributionrate of citizensinsured by Society-

    managed Health

    Insurance from 20%

    to 30%, to be on apar with the same

    rate underGovernment-

    managed Health

    Insurance; repeal of

    the patient charge onprescription drugs

    Introduction ofpublic-private

    partnership in public

    hospitals: first public

    hospital managed byprivate sector opened

    in 2005 under

    framework of Private

    Finance Initiative

    various health

    insurance agencies

    into one singleorganization to

    facilitate more

    equitable risk

    pooling in 2000

    Planning for second-

    generation national

    health insurancesystem began in

    2002, in order to

    cope with funding

    deficits

    scheme) in order to

    make individual

    citizens bear a largepart of health

    expenditure

    Reform of Medishield

    in 2004 to raiseclaims for deductibles

    and prevent medical

    insurance industry

    from being too

    selective, thus leavingMedisheld to protect

    the disadvantaged

    Extending meanstesting to general

    hospitals

    savings schemes;

    government counter-

    plan for compulsoryhealth savings,

    supplemented by

    increase in fees and

    charges (e.g. inAccident &

    Emergency services)

    Recent (2005)

    proposal

    Healthcare Reform Future Healthcare

    Delivery Model

    Consultation - toallow more public-

    private interface in

    provision of

    healthcare and tointroduce family

    doctor scheme

    Hospital Authority

    introduced standarddrug formulatory to

    help reduce

    prescription

    expenditure

    Housing Amendment of Public

    Housing Law in June

    1996 to tighten

    eligibility for public

    Temporary measures

    for improvement of

    low income housing

    (1989-1999) to

    Encouraging private

    sector to build

    housing units for

    labourers (some 20

    Stepping up state

    housing through

    provision of new

    categories such as

    Housing reform as

    major agenda of new

    Tung administration

    (1997): Short-lived

    24

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    25/30

    housing

    The 7th Housing

    Construction Five-year Plan (1996): to

    promote building of

    good quality housing,

    with target of 7.3million units by 2000,

    of which 3.5 million

    funded through pubic

    finance

    Housing and UrbanDevelopmentCorporation

    reorganized into the

    Urban Development

    Corporation in 1999

    Amendment of

    Building Code andCity Planning Law in

    1997: High Rise

    Housing Promotion

    Zones designated incentre of large cities;

    Fixed term Rental

    Rights System

    introduced in 1999

    Ending of directhousing financing bythe Government

    Housing Loan

    Corporation (GHLC)

    in 2004, following theabolition of the

    corporation which

    ceased to issue new

    loans in 2001

    facilitate low income

    housing

    redevelopmentprojects

    Price ceiling of new

    residential housing

    units introduced in1997

    Privatization of Korea

    Housing Bank in

    1998

    Establishment ofKorea Housing

    Finance Credit

    Guarantee Fund in1998

    Korea HousingFinance Co-operative

    established in 1999:

    government

    participation inhousing consumer

    protection measures

    New Real Estate

    Reform Policy

    stabilizing housing

    for ordinary peopleand curbing real

    estate speculation

    More budgetary

    allocations toNational Housing

    Fund

    Increasing public

    rental housing supply

    Vitalizing long-term

    loan systems for

    designated categories

    of workers, ranging

    from miners to mediaworkers) since early

    1990s, with terms

    similar to those for

    public housing

    Focus of central

    government civil

    servants housing

    shifted from direct

    provision to offeringof subsidized loans

    (1995)

    Six-Year Housing

    Plan 1996-2001: with

    majority of publichousing units to be

    purchased from the

    market, and

    government providingsubsidised loans

    Executive Yuanproposed to set up a

    single organisation in

    1999 to tackle

    housing problems,instead of having the

    responsibility

    fragmented across

    various branches ofgovernment

    Executive Yuan

    acknowledged

    problem of housingoversupply and

    inadequate land

    luxurious apartments

    for higher-income

    citizens, andupgrading of existing

    public housing estates

    Introduction of

    Special HousingAssistance

    Programme, to bring

    together various home

    ownership schemes

    for lower incomehouseholds

    A new CPF Housing

    Grant Scheme forlower income families

    who buy HDB

    (Housing

    Development Board)flats

    post-1997 pledge of

    85,000 new build

    target to preventmarket overheating

    Reducing waiting

    time for public renting

    housing, improvingmanagement &

    maintenance, and rent

    relief scheme

    Establishment of

    Urban RenewalAuthority

    Termination of public

    provision of

    ownership housing

    through HomeOwnership Scheme

    (HOS) and Tenant

    Purchase Scheme

    (TPS) in 2002 due toproperty market

    collapse

    Review of Domestic

    Rent Policy for Public

    Housing in 2006

    25

  • 8/3/2019 Anthony Cheung Paper

    26/30

    small-sized rental

    houses for needy

    citizens, and formiddle-class citizens

    to enjoy stable life in

    rental housing

    system in 1999

    Home Finance Loan

    scheme to benefit120,000 households

    (2004)

    Welfare and

    labour

    protection

    Revision of eight

    welfare laws in 1990,

    including WelfareLaw for the Elderly

    Child Allowance for

    the first childintroduced in 1991

    Advisory Council on

    Social Security

    recommended

    rebuilding socialsecurity system

    (1995)

    Enactment of Long-

    term Care InsuranceLaw) in 1997, taking

    effect in 2000

    Pension Reform -

    raising the startingage for payment of

    employees pension

    in 1994; amendment

    to Public PensionLaw in 1998 to set

    maximum pension

    premium, increase

    pensionable age, stopwage-indexation, and

    introduce old-age

    pension for active

    workers in late 60s,

    Implementation ofEmployment

    Insurance Programme

    by integrating

    unemployment

    benefit scheme withjob-training in 1995

    Establishment of

    tripartite Employees-Employers-

    Government

    Commission in 1998

    Labour Standard Lawexpanded, and

    Labour-Management-

    Government

    Committeeestablished

    Introduction ofminimum living

    standard guarantee

    scheme in 2000 Protection-first

    system (2005) for

    elderly and other

    disenfranchised

    citizens

    Review of National

    Pension Programmewith new fiscal

    measures

    Passage of Social

    Assistance Law in

    1997

    Introduction of

    Employment

    InsuranceProgrammein 1999

    Reform of labour

    pension system in

    2001

    Attempts to amendthe three labour

    laws (Trade Union

    Law, Collective

    Bargaining Law, andIndustrial Disputes

    Settlement Law)

    (currently still

    pending in thelegislature because of

    partisan

    disagreement)

    TemporaryProvisions for

    Elderly Welfare

    Subsidy (2002)

    Reform to retirementpension system, and

    provision of

    unemployment

    benefits in 2002

    Wage Reform and

    CPF (Central

    Provident Fund)Reform

    Promote voluntary

    help through charityorganizations

    Setting up of

    Eldercare Fund,

    Children

    Development Co-Savings Scheme (or

    Baby Bonus), and

    granting of CPF Top-

    up to all citizens in2000

    Economic Downturn

    Relief Scheme (2001)

    Emphasis on New

    Social Compact to

    cope with the NewEconomy

    Issue of New

    Singapore Shares to

    less well-off citizensin 2001, with

    guaranteed dividend

    payment and

    redeemable for cash.

    Issue of Economic

    Restructuring Shares

    Introduction of new

    Man