asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate: an empirical exploration of taiwan and hong kong

13
This article was downloaded by: [Moskow State Univ Bibliote] On: 20 February 2014, At: 01:07 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Applied Economics Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20 Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate: an empirical exploration of Taiwan and Hong Kong Kuan-Min Wang a & Thanh-Binh Nguyen Thi b a Department of Finance , Overseas Chinese Institute of Technology , Taichung 407, Taiwan b College of Business, Feng Chia University , Taichung 407, Taiwan Published online: 03 Jan 2008. To cite this article: Kuan-Min Wang & Thanh-Binh Nguyen Thi (2010) Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate: an empirical exploration of Taiwan and Hong Kong, Applied Economics, 42:5, 659-670, DOI: 10.1080/00036840701704444 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840701704444 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http:// www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Upload: thanh-binh-nguyen

Post on 22-Dec-2016

212 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

This article was downloaded by: [Moskow State Univ Bibliote]On: 20 February 2014, At: 01:07Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied EconomicsPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate: anempirical exploration of Taiwan and Hong KongKuan-Min Wang a & Thanh-Binh Nguyen Thi ba Department of Finance , Overseas Chinese Institute of Technology , Taichung 407, Taiwanb College of Business, Feng Chia University , Taichung 407, TaiwanPublished online: 03 Jan 2008.

To cite this article: Kuan-Min Wang & Thanh-Binh Nguyen Thi (2010) Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate: anempirical exploration of Taiwan and Hong Kong, Applied Economics, 42:5, 659-670, DOI: 10.1080/00036840701704444

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840701704444

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) containedin the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make norepresentations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of theContent. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, andare not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon andshould be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable forany losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoeveror howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use ofthe Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematicreproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in anyform to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Applied Economics, 2010, 42, 659–670

Asymmetric pass-through and

risk of interest rate: an empirical

exploration of Taiwan and

Hong Kong

Kuan-Min Wanga,* and Thanh-Binh Nguyen Thib

aDepartment of Finance, Overseas Chinese Institute of Technology,

Taichung 407, TaiwanbCollege of Business, Feng Chia University, Taichung 407, Taiwan

This study employs the asymmetric threshold cointegration test suggested

by Enders and Siklos (2001) and creates asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-

M model to investigate the pass-through of money-market rate to banking

retail rates in Taiwan and Hong Kong. It further explores the impact of

interest volatility on interest rates. Over the period of February 1988 to

December 2004, we find that the interest pass-through mechanism of these

two markets is noncomplete. In addition, based on the asymmetric

threshold cointegration test, we discover the existence of asymmetric

cointegration relationship between retail rates and market rate in both

markets. In particular, while employing asymmetric EC-EGARCH (1, 1)-

M model to test for the influence of money-market rate adjustment and

volatility on retail rates in short-run, we find robust evidence that there

exist the upward rigidity in deposit rate and the downward rigidity in

lending rate in both Taiwan and Hong Kong. This finding supports the

hypothesis of the collusive pricing arrangements. Furthermore, interest

volatility should cause a smaller margin of variation for Taiwan’s deposit/

lending rates and wider margin for Hong Kong’s lending rate.

I. Introduction

The pass-through process of money-market rate to

retail interest rates is an important link. The Central

Bank of one country could control the money-market

interest rates through its short-term policy interest

rate. Afterward, the financial institutions and market

behaviour determine the performance of this mone-

tary policy. The interest rate transmission mechanism

first controls the short-term interest rate, and then

influences the long-term interest rates or other

retail rates. De Bondt (2005) indicates that the

deposit/lending rates determined by commercial

banks should have great effect on the investments

and expenditures of depositors/borrowers, further, on

economic growth.The pass-through process of money-market rate to

retail rates differs among countries based on their

economy policy and control degree. Moreover, the

different retail rates among banks should be caused

by a variety of pass-through processes, speeds,

markup/markdown rates. As banks have their own

characteristics, depositors, maturity structures and

interest rates. Beside, disequilibrium market caused

*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]

Applied Economics ISSN 0003–6846 print/ISSN 1466–4283 online � 2010 Taylor & Francis 659http://www.informaworld.com

DOI: 10.1080/00036840701704444

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

by business cycle should make retail rates reactasymmetrically to money-market rate. Accordingly,there exists an asymmetric pass-through process.

What is interest rate ‘pass-through’? Governmentadjusts policy rates according to business-cyclevolatility, which is followed by correction of money-market rate among banks (interbank-interest rate).Banks should transfer the change of money-marketrate to retail rates (including deposit and lendingrates). This process is so-called interest rate pass-through. If these cost adjustments are transferredcompletely to retail rates, which is called a completepass-through. However, banks are unable to transferthis cost immediately to retail rates because of theircontract maturities, financial structure, or operatingsystem. In general, one part of cost is borne bycustomers; the other part is passed through markup/markdown on fixed rates. Hence, the pass-through ofmoney-market rate to retail rates is not in 1:1proportion, which is called as noncomplete pass-through. And it is an over pass-through if thisproportion is >1. However, this pass-though isusually accompanied with markup/markdown onfixed rates.

The relationship of market rate and banking retailrates of either complete or noncomplete pass-throughmust be stable in long-run. In other words, there mustexist long-run cointegration relationship. One mone-tary policy considered to be effective or that does notdepend on the existence of interest pass-throughmechanism. Further, adjustment speed is a criticalinfluential factor during the adjustment of short-rundisequilibrium. This speed depends on asymmetricinformation costs that induce problems of adverseselection and moral hazard (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981).Accordingly, the asymmetric adjustment of interestpass-through is resulted. Adjustment speed ondeposit and lending is identical if asymmetricinformation costs do not influence speed of interest-rate adjustment. Then it becomes what is calledsymmetric rate pass-through mechanism. Moreover,the markup (markdown) of interest and pass-throughparameter, because of different speeds, should resultin different degrees of pass-through.

Borio (1997) considers that Central Banks ofseveral countries implement monetary policy bymeans of control over short-term money-marketrate. Manna et al. (2001) also suggests that alterationof short-term money-market rate is an extremelyimportant step in order to execute monetary policythrough interest pass-though process. Moreover,Bredin et al. (2001) points out that the maininstrument of monetary policy is both the degree ofand speed of pass-through of short-term money-market rate to retail rates.

Focusing on reason of why the policy interest ratesare noncomplete pass-through, Cottarelli andKourelis (1994), Mojon (2000), Ehrmann et al.(2003) and Horvath et al. (2004) argue that thecompetition among banks, or among banks andnonfinancial agencies, the capitalization degree ofbank systems in each country, and the volatility ofinterest rate and so on induce the different marginand speed during pass-through process. Alternatively,Heffernan and Fuertes (2006) point to the impact ofsunk costs, borrowers/depositors’ habit and implicitcollusion among financial institutions on retail ratedetermination. Banks could select price discrimina-tion for their interest rates, making retail rates beunable to reflect the change of policy rate in shortrun.

Most of the traditional studies analyse the interestpass-through with symmetric (or linear) assumption.Thus, Central Banks are unable to effectively utilizethe policy interest rate to implement monetary policywithout the existence of this mechanism.Nevertheless, we consider that the pass-throughmechanism could actually exist but the bank retailrate adjustment, because of influence of asymmetricinformation cost, results in several forms, such asnonadjustment, slow adjustment or immediateadjustment.

There are some studies examining the existence ofmonetary mechanism and the interrelationshipbetween money and other variables with asymmetricviewpoint, such as the study of Altavilla andLandolfo (2005) that attempts to exploit whethermonetary authorities have a different behaviourduring recession and expansion. The study stronglysuggests that central banks cannot neglect the regimewhere the monetary action takes place. It follows thatthe phase of business cycle is an important matter inmonetary policy decision process. Florio (2005)discovered that the effects of positive and negativeshocks on output are statistically different from zero,and the null of symmetry between the two is rejectedin favour of negative shocks having a greater impacton real output growth, confirming an asymmetriceffect of monetary policy even for Italy. Afterward,Maki and Kitasaka (2006) use the threshold-coin-tegration test to investigate the long-run equilibriumrelationship among money, income, prices andinterest rates in Japan and provide clear evidence ofthe cointegration relationship characterized by asym-metric adjustment. The semi-structural modellingapproach that is developed by Clausen and Hayo(2006) is applied to study asymmetric monetarytransmission in Europe and find asymmetries on thedemand side in the strength of interest-rate transmis-sion and on the supply side in the effects of the output

660 K.-M. Wang and T.-B. N. Thi

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

gap on inflation. It is inferred that the financialmarket of every country has its own interest pass-through mechanism, such as the rigidity in interestadjustment, the noncomplete or complete pass-through.

The relatively dense theoretical research on rela-tionship between long-run and short-run pass-through and on interest-rate adjustment focusesmostly on analysing the long run cointegration offirst moment, adjustment of short-run error correc-tion, the traditional symmetric cointegration test.They neglect the function of short-run bias accom-panied with asymmetric adjustment. Therefore, theempirical results lead to conclusion that there is nocointegration relationship between retail rates andmarket rate. Moreover, they also ignore the long-runpass-through accompanied with asymmetry, whichcauses them to be unable effectively explain theadjustment of interest with the error-correctionmodel in short run as the adjustment of interestappears the heteroskedasticity phenomenon.

Therefore, in order to overcome the above-mentioned problems while examining the interestpass-through process, we employ the asymmetricthreshold cointegration test suggested by Enders andSiklos (2001), TAR (threshold autoregression) andMTAR (momentum-threshold autoregression) testfor whether there is an asymmetric threshold coin-tegration relationship between retail rates andmoney-market rate. To overcome the appearance ofheteroscedasticity along with interest change, withwhich the precise error correction model is not able tobe fitted, we first add the error correction term ofasymmetric adjustment to the conditional meanequation. This method allows us not only toinvestigate the short-run asymmetric adjustment,interest risk, the response of retail rates to changesin money-market rate, but also to explain the firstmoment relation of retail rates. Afterward, the secondmoment relation within EGARCH-M–model frame-work is utilized to capture the retail rate volatility andthe influence of asymmetric interest shock onvolatility, moreover, to test if model has asymmetricvolatility. Finally, we name this model asymmetricEC-EGARCH-M.

This study investigates the pass-through of money-market rate to banking-retail rates in Taiwan andHong Kong. Why the topic of interest rate pass-through is interesting? Hong Kong, at present, servesas a service platform for many Taiwanese companiesventuring into the mainland market. According to theTaipei Trade Centre in Hong Kong, there are over3000 active Taiwanese companies in the territory,with the majority having investments or otherbusiness activities in the mainland. In addition,

there are over 10 000 inactive ‘paper companies’.Among the surveyed Taiwanese companies, 80.9%indicate that they use Hong Kong banks for fundtransfers among Taiwan, the mainland and HongKong. The monetary policy, therefore, has a greatimpact on capital flows between Hong Kong andTaiwan. One of the major factors to whichGovernments, Banks and Investors play close atten-tion is policy interest rate (or official interest rate).This study aims to provide evidences of interest-ratepass-through and interest risk in these two markets,which help to evaluate and determine the effective-ness of one interest policy and help to make precisedecision on investment along with a new interestpolicy.

This article chiefly examines the interest pass-through mechanism, the short-run and long-runasymmetric interest adjustment in Taiwan andHong Kong, with main purpose of (1) investigatingif the cointegration relationship between money-market rate and bank retail rates exists? (2) consider-ing the impact of long-run asymmetric adjustment,and exploring the short-run interest adjustment withthe second-moment-based method, (3) analysing theeffect of the adjustment speed of asymmetric interestin short run, the pricing behaviour in commercialbanks’ retail rates, and the impact of asymmetricinformation on interest adjustment, (4) checking ifthe interest risk influences the adjustment of retailrates.

The article is organized as follows. Section Iintroduces the motivations and purposes of thisstudy. Section II focuses on the explanatory powerof error correction term and the asymmetric volatilityof interest. Section III describes the methodology thatis employed and presents the data and empiricalmodels. Section IV reports the summary statistics,discusses the empirical results and its economicalimplication. Finally, the article is concluded inSection V.

II. The Explanatory Power of Error-Correction Term and the AsymmetricVolatility of Interest Rate

The phenomenon of price-volatility cluster, foundmost popular in studies about price of financial assets,plays an important role in financial analysis because itimplies the impact of risk on price. Earlier studies byEngle et al. (1990) shows that the informationtransmission should influence the volatility of condi-tional variance. Nelson (1991) finds that the degree ofinformation influence on conditional variance is

Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate 661

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

different if information is different. Hence, he estab-lishes the EGARCH model to explain the asymmetricphenomenon. The EGARCHmodel, therefore, is usedmost in describing the volatility-cluster phenomenonof stock price and exchange rate. To our knowledge,this is the first study to apply this model for the pass-through of money-market rate to bank retail rates.Moreover, we employ EGARCH-M to investigate theimpact of interest risk on interest rate.

Based on the above mentioned theories andempirical studies on interest, the relation betweenretail rates and money-market rate should be coin-tegration, which ensures the effectiveness of monetarypolicy. Consequently, if market price temporarilydeviates from long run equilibrium it will correctitself in the next period. Engle and Yoo (1987) andLee (1994) conclude that the error-correction termhas a great explanatory power for the conditionalmean of cointegration series. In the meanwhile, Lee(1994) applies the error-correction term in GARCHmodel. This study investigates the extension of thismodel with the asymmetric error-correction term,asymmetric volatility and the impact of interest riskon interest, which could be called EC-EGARCH-Mmodel.

III. Methodology

The data

Our analysis is based on monthly data to investi-gate the interest pass-through of money-market rateto bank retail rates in Taiwan and Hong Kong.The empirical work analyses data collected byTaiwan Economic Journal (TEJ) and InternationalFinancial Statistics (IFS), which includes informa-tion on deposit rates, lending rates and money-market rate. The description of variablesis presented in Table 1. TEJ data from February1988 to December 2004 are used for Taiwanesemarket and IFS data from January1994 to December 2004 are used for Hong Kongmarket.

Figure 1 displays the time trend of the money-

market rates, the deposit rates and the lending rates

of Taiwan and Hong Kong during study period.The interest behaviours evidently differ from

each other. It is observed that lending rates, relative

to market rates and deposit rates, are almosthighest. Money-market rates that quickly

respond to capital elasticity have higher volatilityand sometimes are even higher than the lending

rates. Taiwan’s market rates are mostly close to

lending rate while Hong Kong’s market rates,inversely, are close to deposit rate, which presents

the different behaviours of these two money

markets until 2001 when Taiwan’s market ratesbegan to be close to deposit rates. During study

period, Taiwan’s retail rates are more stable than

Hong Kong’s.

Asymmetric threshold cointegration test

While analysing time series data, determining

whether a series is stationary or not is very important,for the stationary or otherwise of a series can strongly

influence its behaviour and properties. When model-ling several unit root nonstationary time series

jointly, one may encounter the case of cointegration.

A co-integrating relationship can be seen as a long-run or equilibrium phenomenon, since it is possible

that co-integrating variables may deviate from their

relationship in the short run, but their associationwould return in the long run. Therefore, TAR and

MTAR model, suggested by Enders and Siklos

(2001), could be used for testing for the long runasymmetric cointegration.

To assume that all co-integrating ranks of variables

{y1t, . . ., ynt} are I (1). According to the cointegration

test introduced by Engle and Granger (1987), thelong-run equilibrium relationship between variables is

as follows:

y1t ¼ �_

0 þ �_

1y2t þ . . .þ �_

nynt þ et ð1Þ

In Equation (1), �i are the estimated parameters and

et is an error term. When long-run relation exists, etbecomes a stationary time series. In order to test for

Table 1. Description of variables

Country Hong Kong :HK Taiwan : TWN

Deposit rate Deposit rate :DI_HK Deposit rate: DI_TWNLending rate Lending rate: LI_HK Lending rate: LI_TWNMoney-Market rate Money-market rate: MI_HK Overnight call loan rate between banks: MI_TWN

Note: Variable DI_i denotes the deposit rate of country i, LI_i denotes the lending rate of country i, and MI_idenotes money-market rate of country i.

662 K.-M. Wang and T.-B. N. Thi

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

the cointegration between variables, we use Equation

(2) to test for unit root.

�et ¼ �et�1 þ "t ð2Þ

In Equation (2), "t is considered as a white-noise

process. There exists a long-run relationship of

symmetric stationarity if �2< �<0. In a symmetric

model, no matter what the value of et�1 is – positive

or negative– the change of et value is always �multiplied by et�1 value. Hence, the symmetric

assumption should lead to a wrong model if long-

run relationship is asymmetric stationary. To over-

come this problem, Enders and Granger (1998) and

Enders and Siklos (2001) assumed that the equili-

brium error being negative or positive is the

signal source of asymmetric adjustment. Then, the

TAR is generated to test for the existence of

asymmetric cointegration equilibrium.

�et ¼ It�1et�1 þ ð1� ItÞ�2et�1 þ "t ð3Þ

It of Equation (3) is an indicator variable,

It ¼1 if et�1 � �0 if et�1 < �

�ð4Þ

Equation (4) shows that if et�1 value is greater (or

equal) than the threshold value �, the adjustment

coefficient is �1 and adjustment margin is �1et�1 And

if et�1 value is smaller than the threshold value �, theadjustment coefficient is �2 and adjustment margin is

�2et�1 Since the actual characteristics of nonlinear

model is unknown, Enders and Siklos (2001) assume

further that �et�1, which is the first differential of

et�1, represents the momentum of interest adjust-

ment. It is also possible that an indicator variable,

which causes the interest asymmetric adjustment

under asymmetric structure. Thus, the asymmetric

TAR model could be called MTAR model. MTAR is

generated as below:

�et ¼Mt�1et�1 þ ð1�MtÞ�2et�1 þ "t ð5Þ

0

4

8

12

16

20

88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

DI MI LI

TAIWAN

0

4

8

12

16

20

88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

DI MI LI

HONG KONG

Fig. 1. The time trend of deposit rate (DI), money-market rate (MI), lending rate (LI)

Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate 663

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

The indicator variable Mt, at this moment, is:

Mt ¼1 if �et�1 � �0 if �et�1 < �

�ð6Þ

Equation (6) demonstrates that if �et�1 value is

greater (or equal) than the threshold value �, the

adjustment coefficient is �1 and adjustment margin is

�1et�1 and if �et�1 value is smaller than the thresholdvalue �, the adjustment coefficient is �2 and adjust-

ment margin is �2et�1.In addition, if the residuals are correlated in

Equation (3) and (5), TAR and MTAR model

might be corrected as:

�et ¼ It�1et�1 þ ð1� ItÞ�2et�1 þXp

j¼1�j�et�j þ "t

ð7Þ

�et ¼Mt�1et�1 þ ð1�MtÞ�2et�1 þXp

j¼1�j�et�j þ "t

ð8Þ

In order to get {et} series of both Equations (7) and

(8) to be stationary, the abundant condition,

�2< (�1, �2)<0, must be satisfied. When {et} is

stationary and the threshold value is known, the

asymptotic distribution of parameter �1 and �2converges to a multivariate normal. Enders and

Siklos (2001) use the statistic � to test for theasymmetric threshold cointegration. And statistic �

test for the null hypothesis �1¼ �2¼ 0 with F

distribution. If the null hypothesis is rejected, then

there exists cointegration. Thus, F test could be

further utilized to investigate if the null hypothesis

(�1¼ �2) is true. If the null hypothesis of symmetric

adjustment is accepted, then the long-run relationship

between variables, resulted by Engle–Granger coin-tegration test, is symmetric. If the null hypothesis

�1¼ �2 is rejected, there, consequently, exists an

asymmetric cointegration. Hence, Engle–Granger’s

symmetric cointegration test is a special case of

Enders and Siklos (2001)’s threshold cointegration

testBeside, in order to estimate a suitable threshold

value, we employ the method of Chan (1993) toestimate the threshold value � of TAR and MTAR

model. Based on this �, we establish the indicator

variables of TAR or MTAR to proceed with

asymmetric cointegration test. Relating to threshold

critical value, see the simulation results of Wane et al.

(2004) for reference.When there exist the cointegration between

interest rates, analysing the adjustment of short-

run deviation should use the error correctionmodel. However, when the conditional heteroske-

dasticity appears in interest rates, using the error

correction model to estimate the adjustment ofshort-run deviation could result in bias.Interestingly, EC-EGARCH-M could overcome allproblems stated above.

Asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-M model

This study constructs an univariate asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-M model to take the conditionalmean equation of one-period lag asymmetric error-correction term into account. Firstly, the long-runnoncomplete pass-through of market rate to bankretail rates is built:

Rt ¼ d0 þ d1MIt þ et ð9Þ

Rt of Equation (9) represents bank deposit rate orlending rate. MIt is money-market rate, et is long-runerror term. d0 is defined as the fixed markup(markdown) of retail rates. It is a partial pass-through if the pass-through parameter, d1 is smallerthan 1; a complete pass-through if d1 is ¼1; and overpass-through if d1 is >1.

According to the interest pass-through explanationof Borio (1997), Bredin et al. (2001), Manna et al.(2001) and De Bondt (2005), the central bank of onecountry could execute the monetary policy withtransmission mechanism. In other words, the adjust-ment in policy interest rate affects the retail ratesthrough the market rate. The interest pass-throughmeans that the change of money-market (interbank)rate is followed by the adjustment in policy interestrate, and then banks try to shift this cost to the retailrates (deposit and lending rate). This process is chieflyconcerned with the relationship between two vari-ables, money-market rate and retail rates. We,therefore, examine the relationship of each coupleof variables–money-market rate and deposit rate,money-market rate and lending rate. We can notsimultaneously examine the relationship of threevariables because of biased result possibly caused bythe displacement or offset of exogenous effect ofmoney-market rate, or because the pass-throughprocess is from deposit rates to lending rate or viceversa.

Based on Equation (9), when there is cointegra-tion and the adjustment of asymmetric errorcorrection model is not able to get the residual oferror correction model to be a white noise, wecreate the asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-Mmodel:

�Rt ¼ a0 þXp

i¼1ai�Rt�i þ

Xq

j¼1bj��t�j

þm�MIt þ s�t þ �1Mtet�1

þ �2ð1�MtÞet�1 þ �t�tj�t�1 � Nð0, �2t Þ ð10Þ

664 K.-M. Wang and T.-B. N. Thi

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

1: logð�2t Þ ¼ !þ �t�1�t�1

��������þ � �t�1�t�1

þ � logð�2t�1Þ ð11Þ

Equation (10) is referred to as conditional meanequation of asymmetric EC-EGARCH (1, 1)-Mmodel. The impact of interest risk (the conditionalSD �t) on interest rates is taken into consideration.The interest risk causes an increase of interestvolatility margin if s value is significant positive;and a decrease, on the contrary. �1 and �2 representthe adjustment speed of the positive and negativeerror correction term. e

_

t�1 is the error correction termof previous period long-run equilibrium. The volati-lity of retail rate adjustment, following the long-runequilibrium error, presents a positive adjustment ifthe adjustment speed coefficient is positive; and anegative adjustment if it is negative. In addition, weadd the lag autoregressive AR(p) and the moving-average MA(q) to rectify the remaining autocorrela-tion. The maximum-likelihood method is applied toestimate the asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-Mmodel. Taking the logarithm of the maximum like-lihood function is as follows:

logL ¼ �ðT=2Þ logð2Þ � ð1=2ÞXT

t¼1logð�2t Þ

� ð1=2ÞXT

t¼1ðv2t =�

2t Þ ð12Þ

The formation of Equation (10) could be used toexamine whether the rigidity in retail rates exists.�e

_

it�1 � � implies that the adjustment of retail ratesis higher than the change of equilibrium error afterthe money-market rate changed. Therefore, theadjustment margin of retail rates must be downward.�e

_

it�1 < �, in contrast, suggests an upward adjust-ment. The variation margin of retail rates can beadjusted upward or downward via the error correc-tion term Mite

_

it�1 and ð1�MitÞe_

it�1. When �1 and �2are not equal, the adjustment of rigidity appears inretail rates. |�1|>|�2| indicates an upward rigidity inretail rates. Naturally, |�1|<|�2| indicates a down-ward rigidity in retail rates.

Equation (11) is called the conditional variableequation. The conditional variable of a logarithmensures a positive value. When � 6¼ 0, the condition

variable possesses an asymmetric effect. When �<0,the condition variable possesses a leverage effect. Themodel of this study is different from others in: (1)considering the existence of asymmetric interest pass-

through, (2) speculating on interest short-run adjust-ment that possesses heteroskedasticity phenomenon,(3) analysing the impact of interest risk on interestrates, (4) first creating asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1,1)-M and examining the adjustment of short-runinterest asymmetry.

Diagnostic checking on asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1,1)-M model

With regard to how adequate the asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-M model is fitted, we adopt the signbias test, negative size bias test, positive size bias testetc. introduced by Engle and Ng (1993) to check if the

standard residual is an asymmetry. The diagnosticmodel is as follows:

�t�t

� �2

¼ �þ c1S�t þ c2S

�t �t�1 þ c3S

þt �t�1 þ �t ð13Þ

Where ð�t=�tÞdenotes the standard shock. �t repre-sents the error term. S�t ðS

þt Þ is the dummy variable,

which is 1 if �t�1 is smaller or greater than 0, and is 0if otherwise. The adequate fitted model must satisfythe null hypothesis H0:ci¼ 0 and the joint testH0:ci¼ c2¼ c3¼ 0.

IV. Empirical Evidence and Analysis

Unit root test and cointegration test

Table 2 reports the variable levels and the firstdifferential of Augmented Dickey Fuller(ADF) unitroot test. The lag selection is determined by the

minimum Akaike’s information criterion (AIC). Allinterest variables are I(1) series under 5% significantlevel.

The long-run parameter estimation of retail ratesis revealed in Table 3. It is discovered that, with

Table 2. ADF unit root test

Country HK TWN HK TWN

Variables Level First differentialDI_i �0.620 (0) 0.407 (2) �10.48***(0) �6.878***(1)LI_i �1.415 (3) �2.367 (1) �9.606***(0) �5.640***(3)MI_i �1.332 (2) �0.660 (8) �12.63***(1) �8.582***(7)

Notes: ADF equation includes constant, (.) is the adequate lag determined by the minimum AIC, the maximum lag is 12period.*** represent 1% significant level. Concerning the critical value, see MacKinnon (1996).

Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate 665

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

parameter d0, a raise of interest in both markets is

significant with lending model; but not with deposit

model. The estimation of pass-through parameter

d1 indicates the noncomplete pass-through of both

deposit and lending model. When the pass-through

degree is below 1, the increase of bank’s financing

costs are not complete passed through to its retail

rates. The test results of TAR and MTAR

presented in Table 4 exhibit the asymmetric

cointegration of interest models in both Taiwan

and Hong Kong.

Summary statistics of interest variables

Table 5 focuses on the summary statistics of first

differential interest variables. The means of deposit

and lending rates are negative except Taiwan’s

lending rate. The SD shows that Hong Kong’s

interest risk is greater than Taiwan’s. Hong Kong’s

deposit rate risk, opposite to Taiwan’s, is greater

than its lending rate. Beside, all skewness, kurtosis

and Jarque–Bera statistics reject the normality

hypothesis.If one series is an independent and identically

distributed (i.i.d), it is still an i.i.d. after transform-

ing through any linear or nonlinear. We infer that

reason of rejecting the normality hypothesis could

be interest change accompanied with correlation.

Therefore, the interest change level and square

Ljung–Box Q-statistic(LB) test, stated in Table 5,

display the existence of autocorrelation in both

change level and square of interest variables. The

Table 5. The summary statistic of first differential of interest variable

Variable DI_HK DI_TWN LI_HK LI_TWN

Mean �0.017 �0.008 �0.030 0.002SD 0.447 0.047 0.243 0.181Skewness �0.463 �3.042 �0.031 6.179Kurtosis 9.074 24.33 8.680 62.591J-B 206.0*** 4142.9*** 225.8 31173.3LB(12) 29.47*** 47.23*** 45.17*** 56.47***LB2(12) 62.23*** 24.10** 22.20** 33.24***

Notes: Variable DI_i denotes the deposit rate of country i, LI_i denotes the lending rate of country i, and MI_i denotes themoney-market rate of country i.J-B is the statistic Jarque-Bera normal distribution test. LB(12) is Ljung-Box statistic of 12month lags of return. LB2(12) is Ljung-Box statistic of 12 month lags of square return.*** and ** respectively 1% and 5% significant level.

Table 4. TAR and MTAR cointegration test

TAR test MTAR testCountry Interest model lags � F � lags � F �

HK DI_HK 1 13.31*** 5.742(0.018)** �0.889 1 15.40*** 9.360(0.002)*** �0.410LI_HK 1 15.05*** 5.822(0.017)** �0.756 1 17.29*** 9.602(0.002)*** �0.313

TWN DI_TWN 6 6.691* 4.432(0.036)** 0.317 8 19.07*** 33.78(0.000)*** 0.081LI_TWN 5 12.63*** 15.47(0.000)*** �0.601 3 12.82*** 16.68(0.000)*** �0.127

Notes: We take the maximum lag as 12 periods. The principle of lag determination is ensuring residuals being white noise.The differential lag results via the interest model TAR and MTAR test is represented above. The values in (.) are p-value.***, ** and * respectively 1%, 5% and 10% significant level. The critical value of test statistic � is stated in table 2 of Waneet al. (2004).

Table 3. The Long-term parameter estimation

Country HK TWN HK TWN

Parameter Deposit rate model Lending rate modeld0 �0.113 (0.579) 0.510 (0.130) 4.921 (0.000) 6.712 (0.000)d1 0.855 (0.000) 0.163 (0.004) 0.627 (0.000) 0.250 (0.000)

Note: The long-term relationship equation of deposit (lending) rate model is Rt¼ d0þ d1MItþ et, (.) denotes p-value.

666 K.-M. Wang and T.-B. N. Thi

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

autocorrelation of square means the interdepen-

dence of nonlinear, which could be caused by the

conditional heteroscedasticity.

Asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-M model

The estimations of asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-

M are reported in Table 6. The diagnostic checking

model Q12(uh�1/2) and Q12(u

2h�1) are employed to

test for the correlation of retail rate models in each

country. The results of sign bias test, negative size

bias test, positive size bias test and joint test,

introduced by Engle and Ng (1993) show that the

standard residuals do not remain any asymmetry

effect. It proves an equate model fitted for interest in

both markets.Due to estimation of parameter m, the influence of

change in Hong Kong current money-market rates on

retail rates is positive. Moreover, the impact on the

deposit rate (0.054) is greater than on the lending rate

(0.049). The situation is quite different from Taiwan,

the impact on deposit rate is negative (�0.0002), and

on lending rate is positive (0.038). Analysing the

influence of interest volatility (risk), based on

estimation of parameter s, documents that the

impact on Hong Kong lending rate is significantly

positive and the impact on Taiwanese lending/deposit

rate is significantly negative.

Analysing the effect of the asymmetric error

correction term on retail rates could be progressed

through �1 and �2 parameter. Based on the test result

of H0:�1¼ �1, the deposit/lending model of both

markets rejects H0, which indicates that the adjust-

ment of interest in short-run disequilibrium is

asymmetry. Comparing the adjustment speed via

absolute value of �1 to �2, we discover, in both

regions, the upward rigidity adjustment in deposit

rate (|�1|>|�2|) and the downward rigidity adjust-

ment in lending rate (|�1|<|�2|). This finding supportsthe hypothesis of the collusive pricing arrangements.

Furthermore, testing for the asymmetry of condi-

tional variance through � parameter, it is found that

the asymmetry is significant in both regions.

However, � of Taiwanese lending rate model is

negative, which implies a leverage effect. The

empirical results are categorized in Table 7.

Empirical evidence and its economical implication

Why does the monetary market rate pass-through

noncompletely to retail rates? According to classical

theory, with perfect competition and sufficient

information, the price is equal marginal cost.

Therefore, the ratio of price change to marginal

cost change is ¼1. In other words, the interest pass-

through mechanism is symmetric and complete.

Table 6. Estimation of EC-EGARCH(1,1)-M model

Country HK TWN

DI_HK LI_HK DI_TWN LI_ TWN

Interest modelEstimatedvalue p-value

Estimatedvalue p-value

Estimatedvalue p-value

Estimatedvalue p-value

a1 0.229 0.013 0.494 0.000 0.102 0.000m 0.054 0.000 0.049 0.000 �0.0002 0.000 0.038 0.000s �0.009 0.747 1.214 0.000 �0.329 0.000 �0.121 0.055�1 0.044 0.005 �0.1226 0.000 �0.004 0.000 �0.010 0.023�2 0.009 0.247 0.1227 0.000 �0.002 0.000 �0.088 0.000! �0.906 0.000 �6.268 0.000 �5.699 0.000 �2.793 0.000 1.150 0.000 1.349 0.000 6.380 0.000 1.193 0.000� 0.481 0.000 0.363 0.000 5.128 0.000 �0.137 0.063� 0.979 0.000 �0.459 0.000 0.697 0.000 0.575 0.000H0: �1¼ �2 4.978 0.025 59.32 0.000 10.06 0.001 63.70 0.000Q12(uh

�1/2) 9.561 0.654 12.55 0.323 7.284 0.776 8.736 0.725Q12(u

2h�1) 5.808 0.886 15.91 0.144 1.175 1.000 3.636 0.989SB 0.643 0.279 0.928 0.129NSB 0.898 0.829 1.000 0.105PSB 0.343 0.372 0.941 0.914Joint 0.814 0.746 0.996 0.351Log L 20.16 49.70 692.2 203.3

Note: Q12(uh�1/2) and Q12(u

2h�1) represent the standardized residual and its squared Ljung–Box statistic of 12 month lags.SB,NSB and PSB denote the sign bias test, negative size bias test, and positive size bias test suggested by Engle and Ng (1993), ofwhich p-value of t-test is presented. And p-value of Chi-square test belongs to Joint test.Log L is the value of maximumlikelihood function.

Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate 667

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

Table

7.Empiricalresultsandcomparison

Country

Interest

model

Degreeof

Interest

markup

(markdown)(d

0)

Degreeof

interest

pass-through(d

1)

Interest

pass-through

mechanism

(MTAR

test)

Impact

of

interest

volatility

(s)

Asymmetric

effect

of

conditional

variable

(�)

Interest

rigidity

adjustment(�

1,�

2)

Conform

ing

with

theory

HK

DI_HK

—Noncomplete

Asymmetric

—Positive

Upward

rigidity

Collusivepricing

arrangem

ents

LI_HK

markup

Noncomplete

Asymmetric

Positive

Positive

Downward

rigidity

TWN

DI_TWN

—Noncomplete

Asymmetric

Negative

Positive

Upward

rigidity

Collusivepricing

arrangem

ents

LI_TWN

markup

Noncomplete

Asymmetric

Negative

Negative(leverageeffect)

Downward

rigidity

Note:Symbol‘—

’showsthenonsignificanteffect.

668 K.-M. Wang and T.-B. N. Thi

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

Nevertheless, when market is distant from the perfectcompetition and near to monopoly, the ratio of pricechange to marginal cost change is 6¼1. There arenumber of theories proving these outcomes, such asadverse selection, switching cost, consumer irration-ality and risk sharing etc. (Lowe and Rohling, 1992).Under certain circumstances and assumptions, asshown in Horvath et al. (2004), the bank rates mighteven overreact or forego changes in the policy rate.According to one argument, bank rates can changeprior to changes in marginal funding. Banks may, forinstance, anticipate a rise in funding costs andincrease loan rates in advance. This argument hashigher relevance if banks finance longer-term loanswith shorter-term deposits, which is usually the case.

Interest volatility is defined as interest risk. Thus,interest change could get risk of one asset vary. Ourempirical evidence points out that the effect ofinterest risk on interest rate is not consistent in bothmarkets. In other words, the levels of evaluatingbank’s interest risk by Financial SupervisoryAgencies and the risk degrees reflected in bank’sinterest pricing are different. Beside, we discover theleverage effect of Taiwanese lending rate whilemeasuring the asymmetry of volatility, which meansthat the negative shock of interest adjustment isgreater than positive shock. This discovery couldpartly explain the margin of lending rate changedecreases as interest risk increases. Why does interestrates of both markets exist the asymmetric adjust-ment? According to bank behaviour, collusive pricingarrangements and reverse customer reaction, asym-metric information costs should cause the rigidityadjustment of deposit and lending rates. Evidently,Taiwan and Hong Kong conform to the theory ofcollusive pricing arrangements.

Literature comparison

Sander and Kleimeier (2002) discover, with imperfectcompetitive market and cost adjustment framework,the upward rigidity in deposit rate and the downwardrigidity in lending rate in European countries, whichis consistent with the evidence of this study. Thesefindings supports hypothesis that interest rigidity iscaused by bank’s collusive pricing arrangements.Based on data of Malaysia, Singapore, the empiricalresults of Scholnick (1996) are not able to reject thehypothesis of bank’s collusive pricing arrangements.

Additionally, Lim (2001) finds the upward rigidityadjustment in both lending and deposit rate withAustralia. Iregui et al. (2002) discover the downwardrigidity adjustment in both lending and deposit ratewith Colombia and Mexico. These two findingssupport the hypothesis of bank’s collusive pricing

arrangements. The empirical result of Iregui et al.(2002) might relate with assumption of completepass-through of Interbank Call Loan Rates to retailrates. Utilizing Johansen cointegration test, Hofmann(2002) concludes that the adjusting time of lendingrate, in France, Germany, Italy and Spain is ratherslow, which possess the characteristic of rigidityadjustment. This study uses the asymmetric cointe-gration model to examine the asymmetry of interestadjustment, which is different from Hofmann (2002)who use Johansen cointegration model with sym-metric assumption.

Recently, De Graeve et al. (2007) analyse the pass-through from market interest rates to retail bankinterest rates in Belgium. The study advocates aheterogeneous approach and applies it to the Belgianbanking market. The results find that the long-termpass-through is typically less than one-for-one,rejecting the completeness hypothesis. The situationof Belgian banking market is consistent with those ofTaiwan and Hong Kong. They also discover someevidence that deposit rates adjust faster downwardthan upward.

V. Conclusion

This study utilizes the asymmetric threshold cointe-gration test and creates asymmetric EC-EGARCH(1,1)-M model to examine the pass-through of money-market rate to retail rates and the relationshipbetween interest volatility and interest rate inTaiwan and Hong Kong. We find that there is anoncomplete pass-through in both markets. We alsodiscover the asymmetry cointegration in deposit andlending-interest model. The results estimated byasymmetric EC-EGARCH(1, 1)-M for both marketsconform with the hypothesis of collusive pricingarrangements. Moreover, according to results ofconditional variance, there exists a leverage effect inTaiwanese lending rate model.

The study makes several contributions. First, weprovide more evidences for understanding the beha-viour of interest pricing in financial market viaanalysing the interest pass-through of money-market rates to bank retail rates in Taiwan andHong Kong. Then, the capital cost and income sourceof lending/borrowing agencies or of individual areclearer. Second, the asymmetric information mightcause the asymmetric adjustment during interest pass-through process, from which derive the differentadjustment speed. Therefore, in order to timely adjustthe policy rate, the Central Bank must be deeplyconcerned about the influence of information

Asymmetric pass-through and risk of interest rate 669

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014

variation on bank’s interest adjustment and pricingmethod. Third, according to this study’s evidence,banks might have the interest risk in hand by meansof interest rigidity adjustment so as to control theircosts.

Together with economic integration day by daybetween two markets, the empirical evidence of thisstudy really provides various evaluations and deter-mination on interest policy for investors, banks andgovernments. From an academic perspective, thisarticle creates and applies the methods and modelsthat have not been used before on the same subject.Accordingly, several new evidences, that are usefulfor real world, are discovered.

References

Altavilla, C. and Landolfo, L. (2005) Do central banks actasymmetrically? Empirical evidence from the ECB andthe Bank of England, Applied Economics, 37, 507–19.

Borio, C.V. (1997) The implementation of monetary policyin industrial countries: a survey, BIS EconomicsPapers, No.47.

Bredin, D., Fitzpatrick, T. and O’Reilly, G.. (2001) Retailinterest rate pass-though: the Irish experience, CentralBank of Ireland Technical Paper, No.6.

Chan, K. S. (1993) Consistency and limiting distribution ofthe least squares estimator of a threshold autoregres-sive model, The Annals of Statistics, 21, 520–33.

Clausen, V. and Hayo, B. (2006) Asymmetric monetarypolicy effects in EMU, Applied Economics, 38,1123–134.

Cottarelli, C. and Kourelis, A. (1994) Financial structure,bank lending rates, and the transmission mechanism ofmonetary policy, IMF Staff Papers, 41, 587–623.

De Bondt, G. (2005) Interest rate pass-through: empiricalresults for the euro area, German Economic Review, 6,37–78.

De Graeve, F., De Jonghe, O. and Vander Vennet, R.(2007) Competition, transmission and bank pricingpolicies: evidence from Belgium loan and depositMarkets, Journal of Banking and Finance, 31, 259–78.

Ehrmann, M., Gambacorta, L., Martinez-Pages, J.,Sevestre, P. and Worms, A. (2003) The effects ofmonetary policy in the euro area, Oxford Review ofEconomic Policy, 19, 58–72.

Enders, W. and Granger, C. W. J. (1998) Unit-root test andasymmetric with an example using the structure ofinterest rates, Journal of Business and EconomicStatistics, 16, 304–11.

Enders, W. and Siklos, P. (2001) Cointegration andthreshold adjustment, Journal of Business andEconomic Statistics, 19, 166–76.

Engle, R. F. and Granger, C. W. J. (1987) Cointegrationand error correction: representation, estimation, andtesting, Econometrica, 55, 251–76.

Engle, R. F., Ito, T. and Lin, W. L. (1990) Meteor showersor heat waves? heteroscedastic intra-daily volatility inthe foreign exchange market, Econometrica, 58,525–42.

Engle, R. F. and Ng, V. (1993) Measuring and testing of theimpact of news on volatility, Journal of Finance, 48,1749–778.

Engle, R. F. and Yoo, B. S. (1987) Forecasting and testingin co-integrated systems, Journal of Econometrics, 35,143–59.

Florio, A. (2005) Asymmetric monetary policy: empiricalevidence for Italy, Applied Economics, 37, 751–64.

Heffernan, S. A. and Fuertes, A. (2006) Bank heterogene-ities in the interest rate transmission mechanism,Working Paper, 2006 Finance Faculty WorkingPaper Series.

Hofmann, B. (2002) The pass-through of money-marketrates to business loan rates in the euro area countries,mimeo, Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI),University of Bonn, Bonn.

Horvath, C., Kreko, J. and Naszodi, A. (2004) Interest ratepass-through in Hungary, MNB working paper.

Iregui, A. M., Milas, C. and Otero, J. (2002) On thedynamics of lending and deposit interest rates inemerging markets: a non-linear approach, Studies inNonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, 6.

Lee, T. (1994) Spread and volatility in spot and forwardexchange rates, Journal of International Money andFinance, 13, 375–83.

Lim, G. C. (2001) Bank interest rates adjustment: are theyasymmetric?, Economic Record, 77, 135–47.

Lowe, P. and Rohling, T. (1992) Loan rate stickiness:theory and evidence, Research Discussion Paper,Reserve Bank of Australia.

Maki, D. and Kitasaka, S. (2006) The equilibrium relation-ship among money, income, prices, and interest rates:evidence from a threshold cointegration test, AppliedEconomics, 38, 1585–592.

Manna, M., Pill, H. and Quiros, G. (2001) The eurosystemsoperational framework in the context of the ECB’smonetary policy strategy, European Central Bank,mimeo.

Mojon, B. (2000) Financial structure and the interestchannel of the ECB monetary policy, ECB WorkingPaper, No. 40.

Nelson, D. B. (1991) Conditional heteroskedasticity inasset pricing: a new approach, Econometrica, 59,347–70.

Sander, H. and Kleimeier, S. (2002) Asymmetric adjust-ment of commercial bank interest rates in the euroarea: an empirical investigation into interest rate pass-through, Kredit und Kapital, 35, 161–92.

Scholnick, B. (1996) Asymmetric adjustment of commercialbank interest rates: evidence from Malaysia andSingapore, Journal of International Money andFinance, 15, 485–96.

Stiglitz, J. E. and Weiss, A. (1981) Credit rationing inmarkets with imperfect information, AmericanEconomic Review, 71, 917–26.

Wane, A., Gilbert, S. and Dibooglu, S. (2004) Criticalvalues of the empirical F-distribution for threshold,Calendar Year 2004 Discussion Papers for theDepartment of Economics Southern IllinoisUniversity at Carbondale, Illinois.

Winker, P. (1999) Sluggish adjustment if interest rates andcredit rationing: an application of unit root testing anderror correction modelling, Applied Economics, 31,267–77.

670 K.-M. Wang and T.-B. N. Thi

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Mos

kow

Sta

te U

niv

Bib

liote

] at

01:

07 2

0 Fe

brua

ry 2

014