attacking your partners: strategic alliances and competition ......although strategic alliances are...

24
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition between partners in product markets Victor Cui 1 | Haibin Yang 2 | Ilan Vertinsky 3 1 Department of Business Administration, Asper School of Business, University of Manitoba, Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada 2 Department of Marketing/Management, College of Business, City University of Hong Kong, Kowloon, Hong Kong 3 Strategy and Business Economics Division, Sauder School of Business, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada Correspondence Haibin Yang, College of Business, City University of Hong Kong, 83 Tat Chee Avenue, Kowloon, Hong Kong. Email: [email protected] Funding information the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council (SSHRC) of Canada , Grant/Award number: 435-2017-1301; Research Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China, Grant/Award number: CityU 11508415 Research Summary: This study contributes to the litera- ture on strategic alliances by examining the impact of col- laboration on competition between partners in product markets. We integrate the alliance learning and social net- work perspectives to examine how different combinations of exploratory and exploitative alliances between a firm and its partner influence the firms competition against its partner in product markets. Using a longitudinal dataset collected in the U.S. pharmaceutical industry (19842003), we find an inverted U-shaped relationship between relative exploration (i.e., the proportion of exploratory alliances in the collaborative portfolio between a firm and its partner) and the firms competition against its partner. This rela- tionship is negatively moderated by firmsrelational and structural embeddedness, but positively moderated by their positional embeddedness. Managerial Summary: This study examines how differ- ent combinations of exploratory and exploitative alli- ances between two firms affect their competition in the product market. Using a 20-year dataset collected in the U.S. pharmaceutical industry, we find that the proportion of exploratory alliances (i.e., joint development of criti- cal innovations) in the alliance portfolio between a firm and its partner increases the firms competition against its partner, up to a tipping point at which such competi- tion starts to decline. Given a certain combination of the two types of alliances, such competition is stronger if the firm has more alternative allies than its partner but weaker if the firm and its partner have previously collab- orated or share common allies in their networks. KEYWORDS alliance, alliance learning, network embeddedness, partner competition, product market Received: 3 November 2015 Revised: 16 July 2017 Accepted: 18 July 2017 Published on: 30 January 2018 DOI: 10.1002/smj.2746 3116 Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/smj Strat Mgmt J. 2018;39:31163139.

Upload: others

Post on 30-Sep-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

S P E C I A L I S S U E ART I C L E

Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances andcompetition between partners in product markets

Victor Cui1 | Haibin Yang2 | Ilan Vertinsky3

1Department of Business Administration, AsperSchool of Business, University of Manitoba,Winnipeg, Manitoba, Canada2Department of Marketing/Management, Collegeof Business, City University of Hong Kong,Kowloon, Hong Kong3Strategy and Business Economics Division,Sauder School of Business, University of BritishColumbia, Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada

CorrespondenceHaibin Yang, College of Business, CityUniversity of Hong Kong, 83 Tat Chee Avenue,Kowloon, Hong Kong.Email: [email protected]

Funding informationthe Social Sciences and Humanities ResearchCouncil (SSHRC) of Canada , Grant/Awardnumber: 435-2017-1301; Research Grants Councilof the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region,China, Grant/Award number: CityU 11508415

Research Summary: This study contributes to the litera-ture on strategic alliances by examining the impact of col-laboration on competition between partners in productmarkets. We integrate the alliance learning and social net-work perspectives to examine how different combinationsof exploratory and exploitative alliances between a firmand its partner influence the firm’s competition against itspartner in product markets. Using a longitudinal datasetcollected in the U.S. pharmaceutical industry (1984–2003),we find an inverted U-shaped relationship between relativeexploration (i.e., the proportion of exploratory alliances inthe collaborative portfolio between a firm and its partner)and the firm’s competition against its partner. This rela-tionship is negatively moderated by firms’ relational andstructural embeddedness, but positively moderated by theirpositional embeddedness.Managerial Summary: This study examines how differ-ent combinations of exploratory and exploitative alli-ances between two firms affect their competition in theproduct market. Using a 20-year dataset collected in theU.S. pharmaceutical industry, we find that the proportionof exploratory alliances (i.e., joint development of criti-cal innovations) in the alliance portfolio between a firmand its partner increases the firm’s competition againstits partner, up to a tipping point at which such competi-tion starts to decline. Given a certain combination of thetwo types of alliances, such competition is stronger ifthe firm has more alternative allies than its partner butweaker if the firm and its partner have previously collab-orated or share common allies in their networks.

KEYWORDS

alliance, alliance learning, network embeddedness,partner competition, product market

Received: 3 November 2015 Revised: 16 July 2017 Accepted: 18 July 2017 Published on: 30 January 2018

DOI: 10.1002/smj.2746

3116 Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/smj Strat Mgmt J. 2018;39:3116–3139.

Page 2: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

1 | INTRODUCTION

Research on strategic alliances has revealed that prior collaboration often leads to further collabora-tion between firms (Barden & Mitchell, 2007; Gulati, 1995; Li & Rowley, 2002; Podolny, 1994).However, ample anecdotal evidence indicates that alliances are often followed by aggressive compe-tition between the same firms in product markets. For example, pharmaceutical firm Merck alliedwith Novartis, Pfizer, Bristol-Myers, and Depomed in the 1990s yet later competed with these firmsin product markets. Similar instances appear in the automobile (Hamel, Doz, & Prahalad, 1989),telecommunications (Hille & Taylor, 2011; Ritman, 2006), and other industries. Despite the abun-dant evidence, however, researchers have not paid adequate attention to the influence of alliances oncompetition between partners in product markets.

A thorough study of this “collaboration–competition” relationship between partners is of greattheoretical importance, contributing to the development of a more comprehensive model of inter-firm behavior rendered by strategic alliances (Kogut, 1989). Prior studies on alliance learning haveprovided some important insights into the tension between collaboration and competition (Hamelet al., 1989; Katila, Rosenberger, & Eisenhardt, 2008; Khanna, Gulati, & Nohria, 1998). For exam-ple, researchers maintain that competition within alliances stems from the misalignment of interestsbetween allies (Gulati & Singh, 1998; Hamel et al., 1989) and have identified important factors thatinfluence allies’ competitive learning within alliances, such as asymmetric learning capabilities(Hamel, 1991; Khanna et al., 1998; Yang, Zheng, & Zaheer, 2015), the ratio between private andcommon interests (Khanna et al., 1998), and knowledge similarities between allies (Dussauge, Garr-ette, & Mitchell, 2000). However, three important issues in this sphere of research remainunaddressed.

First, while researchers have examined aggressive learning between allies, whereby allies com-pete to increase private rather than common benefits (Hamel, 1991; Khanna et al., 1998; Lavie,2007), prior studies focused on the hazards of misappropriation within alliances; the effect of alli-ances on competition between partners in the realm of product markets remains poorly understood.

Second, prior studies provide insights into competitive learning between partners by focusing onresearch-based alliances while overlooking other types of collaboration (e.g., Yang et al., 2015). Itis assumed that research-based alliances entail intensive knowledge exchange and therefore createmany opportunities for competitive learning between allies, but firms often simultaneously engagein multiple types of alliances (e.g., research-based, marketing, manufacturing) that differ signifi-cantly in the incentives they generate for allies to compete with one another (Hamel, 1991; Khannaet al., 1998; Mowery, Oxley, & Silverman, 1996). The extent to which a firm competes with itspartner is arguably determined by the composition of all types of alliances binding them, which col-lectively define the overall orientation of their interactions as well as the costs and benefits of com-petitive moves against each other (Chen & Miller, 2015). Few studies have yet examined how thecomposition of the collaborative portfolio between firms affects their competition with one another.

Third, many prior studies have examined the tension between cooperation and competition byfocusing on characteristics of the allying firms per se, such as their relative learning capabilities(Yang et al., 2015) and knowledge similarities (Dussauge et al., 2000), while largely overlookingthe impact of the broad inter-firm alliance networks within which competitive learning between part-ners is embedded (Uzzi, 1996). Only a few studies have analyzed the collaboration–competitionphenomenon within alliances from the network perspective. For example, Lavie (2007) providesinsights into how a firm’s appropriation capacity within alliances is affected by factors such as theavailability of alternative alliances and multilateral competition among its partners. Polidoro, Ahuja,and Mitchell (2011) study the impact of network embeddedness on partnering firms’ competitive

CUI ET AL. 3117

Page 3: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

incentives and, in turn, on joint venture dissolution.1 Yet the focus of these studies remains centeredeither on allies’ market performance or on the survival of joint ventures; the impact of partners’ net-work embeddedness on the interplay between alliances and competition in the product market hasrarely been studied.

Our study addresses these limitations by integrating the alliance learning and network perspec-tives in order to study the mechanisms through which strategic alliances influence allies’ competi-tion in the product market. We ask, how does the composition of the collaborative portfoliobetween a firm and its partner affect the firm’s competitive aggressiveness against its partner in theproduct market, and how does network embeddedness influence this relationship?

We capture the composition of two firms’ collaborative portfolio using the concept of relativeexploration, defined as the proportion of exploratory collaborations among all collaborationsbetween a firm and its partner (Uotila, Maula, Keil, & Zahra, 2009; Yang, Lin, & Peng, 2011).2 Asconceptualized in the alliance learning literature, exploratory collaboration is oriented toward devel-oping critical innovations, which require intensive interactions, tacit knowledge sharing, and rela-tional capital building for long-term benefits (Lavie & Rosenkopf, 2006), whereas exploitativecollaboration is oriented toward transacting existing resources for short-term economic benefits(Mowery et al., 1996).

We maintain that increases in the proportion of exploratory alliances within the collaborativeportfolio between a firm and its partner facilitate identification of the partner’s vulnerabilities andappropriation of its capacities, increasing the firm’s incentive to launch competitive action againstits partner (Yu, Subramaniam, & Cannella, 2009). However, there is a cost/benefit trade-offinvolved in launching competitive attacks. As the proportion of exploratory alliances increases, theescalating damage to long-term benefits and the risk of “tit-for-tat” retaliatory attacks from the part-ner may reach a threshold at which the expected cost becomes higher than the expected benefit oflaunching further competitive attacks. We accordingly propose that relative exploration demonstratesan inverted U-shaped relationship with a firm’s product-market competition with its partner.

We further argue that the cost/benefit trade-off of launching competitive attacks is bounded byfirms’ network environments. Firms’ relational embeddedness (i.e., repeated alliance ties), positionalembeddedness (i.e., relative network centrality), and structural embeddedness (i.e., common part-ners) within their alliance networks create important boundary conditions that moderate the effect ofrelative exploration on their competition in different directions. We test our hypotheses using a lon-gitudinal dataset that integrates data on firms’ alliances and product competition in the U.-S. pharmaceutical industry over a period of two decades (1984–2003).

2 | THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, anddistribute technologies and products (Gulati, 1998), partnering firms often simultaneously collabo-rate and compete within their alliances (Hamel, 1991). For example, Hamel (1991) observe thatfirms have a propensity to maximize their own benefits within alliances, even at the cost of commoninterests. Other researchers suggest that firms race to acquire valuable intellectual properties and

1Other studies have investigated the impact of embedded relationships on competition in different contexts, such as clique-levelrivalries between alliances (Gimeno, 2004) and industry-level competition not specified for a particular target (Andrevski, Brass, &Ferrier, 2016; Gnyawali & Madhavan, 2001).2Alternatively, we could use the proportion of exploitative alliances among all alliances between a firm and its partner, or relativeexploitation. The mechanisms will be the same, except that the predicted relationship will flip.

3118 CUI ET AL.

Page 4: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

organization-specific knowledge from each other so that faster learners can reap more private bene-fits (Khanna et al., 1998).

While competitive learning is an important phenomenon in various types of collaborations, thisstudy focuses on horizontal alliances established between firms operating within the same industry.Firms in horizontal alliances normally have a strong competitive inclination toward each otherbecause of either existing or potential rivalries regarding products or resources (Chen, 1996). Thecompetitive nature of their relationship underpins their alliance interactions, making horizontal col-laboration an appropriate setting for studying the mechanisms through which competitive alliancelearning leads to competition in the product market.

It is likely that aggressive learning within horizontal alliances can be translated into competitionbetween allies in product markets, for two reasons. First, proprietary technological knowledgeobtained from a partner can be applied outside the alliance when contracts do not adequately directand constrain the use of knowledge-based assets (Khanna et al., 1998). Firms can apply such knowl-edge to develop or improve their own products, constituting a threat to their partners’ existing prod-ucts. Second, learning about partners’ organizational systems, behavioral patterns, and intentionscan also help firms design calibrated attacks on their partners in the product market in order to maxi-mize their own performance (Yu & Cannella, 2007).

2.1 | Relative exploration and product competition between allies

We classify alliances into two categories: exploitative and exploratory (Koza & Lewin, 1998;March, 1991). Exploitative collaborations, such as marketing and licensing alliances, are arm’s-length relationships designed to exchange existing knowledge and resources for short-term economicreturns (Mowery et al., 1996). Firms engaged in exploitative collaborations typically do not requireclose interactions, since they can be guided by contracts to accomplish their respective duties in arelatively stand-alone fashion (Rothaermel & Deeds, 2004). In contrast, exploratory collaborationsare designed to synthesize knowledge assets from both parties to develop critical innovations ofgreat strategic importance for a firm’s long-term stakes, and consequently demand more intensiveinteractions for sharing tacit know-how (Lavie & Rosenkopf, 2006; Rothaermel & Deeds, 2004).Exploratory collaborations cannot be perfectly regulated by contracts, since they consist of non-routinized searches and learning that involves experimentation with new and often unforeseen alter-natives and outcomes.

Different compositions of the collaborative portfolio between two firms have different implica-tions for their competition in the product market. When the proportion of exploratory alliances islow, the overlap in the two firms’ long-term stakes is relatively small, so that a short-term horizonand a “transaction-oriented” perspective dominate their interactions. This orientation allows bothparties to tolerate self-serving behaviors in their interactions, or even to take them for granted. Theirinteractions then focus on maximizing immediate profits, so that each firm is motivated to use whatit learns from its partner to increase private benefits. In this type of orientation, increases in the pro-portion of exploratory alliances provide opportunities and incentives to compete in product markets.Specifically, there are two reasons.

First, increases in the proportion of exploratory alliances enhance a firm’s awareness of opportu-nities to benefit from competition. Exploratory collaborations involve more intensive interactions,which enable the firm to gain a deeper and more comprehensive understanding of its partner’s tech-nologies, organizational operations, leadership, and motives (Davis & Eisenhardt, 2011). Thisknowledge helps the firm more precisely identify the strengths and weaknesses in its partner’s

CUI ET AL. 3119

Page 5: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

organizational systems and innovation schemes (Dussauge et al., 2000; Yang et al., 2011), informa-tion that can be used to launch calibrated attacks and provides strong incentives for competitiveactions.

Second, exploratory collaboration enhances a firm’s capacity to develop competing productsbecause it requires sharing of proprietary know-how. Exploratory collaboration involves articulatingand transferring complex knowledge between allies, which requires intensive hands-on coaching tofacilitate joint problem solving. Such coaching often draws on latent knowledge bases, showing theconnections between divisional areas of knowledge and organizations (Agrawal, 2006; Uzzi, 1997).This fine-grained knowledge transfer enhances the absorption of tacit know-how (Lane and Lubat-kin, 1998) and facilitates the appropriation of fundamental knowledge that spills over during closeinteractions. Firms’ incentives to apply such technological know-how in designing substitute prod-ucts is high, since doing so can cause destructive damages to incumbent products and reward theattackers with enhanced private benefits (Chen & Hambrick, 1995; Lichtenberg & Philipson, 2002;Yu & Cannella, 2007).

The above arguments suggest that increasing the proportion of exploratory alliances in the col-laborative portfolio enhances the firm’s incentives to compete with its partner when their partnershipis transaction oriented. However, as the proportion of exploratory alliances increases, overlap in thefirms’ long-term stakes also rises, enlarging their mutual dependence in developing critical innova-tions (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978). The risk of retaliation from an attacked partner also increases, asthe partner now holds more critical information about the firm. The firms’ interdependence, on theone hand, and the risk of retaliation, on the other, may escalate to a point at which the expectedcosts exceed the benefits of launching a competitive action, suffocating the firms’ incentives to fur-ther intrude into each other’s product market domains.

Specifically, as firms engage more in exploratory collaboration, they become more reliant onone another for developing exploratory innovations. Developing such innovations involves greatuncertainty, and thus demands more cooperative efforts (March, 1991). Competition accordinglybecomes a growing threat to firms’ common stakes, curbing their incentive to launch attacks. Whenexploratory alliances dominate the collaboration between two firms, their shared stakes in develop-ing exploratory innovations rise to the point where their partnership becomes strategically importantto both parties’ long-term prosperity. A symbiotic relationship featuring a long-term perspective and“relation-oriented” interactions between them is likely to emerge (Davis & Eisenhardt, 2011; McEv-ily & Marcus, 2005). The damage caused by competition on greater long-term benefits may reach athreshold at which escalating competitive attacks would be too costly to justify. As the marginal costof competition continues to increase, the likelihood that a firm will compete with its partner isreduced.

Moreover, heavy engagement in exploratory collaboration allows both partners to hold a greatdeal of high-value information about each other’s operations (Li, Eden, Hitt, & Ireland, 2008).Information about, for example, technological pitfalls and managerial incompetence can be usedto design targeted retaliatory attacks (Chen & Hambrick, 1995). The stakes of “betrayal” becomesubstantively higher as the strategic importance of the exploratory partnership increases, so thatthe tit-for-tat retaliation risk escalates substantially. The consequences of such retaliatory attackscan be tremendously destructive, resulting in significant costs to the attacker (Chen & Hambrick,1995). An expectation of such retaliation also decreases incentives to undertake competitiveactions.

In sum, firms are likely to develop a transaction-oriented partnership when the collaborativeportfolio between them is dominated by exploitative alliances (i.e., low relative exploration), andincreases in the proportion of exploratory alliances enhance a firm’s incentives to compete with its

3120 CUI ET AL.

Page 6: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

partner. However, as the proportion of exploratory alliances increases, the two firms’ long-termstakes become more aligned, so that the damages caused by competition increase. When the collabo-rative portfolio is dominated by exploratory alliances (i.e., high relative exploration), the partnershipbecomes strategically important and a relation-oriented interaction pattern is fostered. The escalatingdamage to long-term benefits and the risk of retaliatory attacks from the partner may reach a level atwhich the cost of competition outweighs its short-term benefit, and at this level the motivation tocompete starts to decline, resulting in an inverted U-shaped relationship between relative explorationand the firm’s competition with its partner; the competition peaks at the medium level of relativeexploration (Grant & Schwartz, 2011; Hanns, Pieters, & He, 2016).

Hypothesis 1 (H1) There is a curvilinear relationship (taking an inverted U-shape)between relative exploration and the aggressiveness of a firm’s competition against itspartner in the product market.

2.2 | The moderating role of network embeddedness

We further contend that this curvilinear relationship is subject to the influence of the inter-firm alli-ance networks within which the firm and its partner are embedded. Alliance learning does not takeplace in a vacuum but is shaped by the broader social context, as firms are not atomistic players butrelational entities (Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1996). Polanyi (1957) was the first to use the concept ofembeddedness in describing the social structure of modern markets, and many studies have furtherconceptualized inter-firm embeddedness and examined how it affects economic actions (e.g., Lavie,2007; Polidoro et al., 2011; Uzzi, 1997).

We build a comprehensive model examining the impact of alliance network embeddedness onthe relationship between relative exploration and product competition between allies by focusing onall three dimensions of embeddedness: relational, positional, and structural (Gulati & Gargiulo,1999). Relational embeddedness, reflected in repeated alliance ties between two firms, emphasizescohesive and reliable relationships (Gulati & Gargiulo, 1999). Positional embeddedness, reflected innetwork centrality, manifests a firm’s status and power within the overall network. Structuralembeddedness, reflected in the common ties shared by the firm and its partner, highlights the infor-mation sharing, social monitoring, and reputational effects that regulate inter-firm interactions(Gulati & Gargiulo, 1999; Polidoro et al., 2011).

2.2.1 | Relational embeddedness

We argue that repeated collaboration attenuates the inverted U-shaped relationship between relativeexploration and the firm’s competition against its partner by (a) lowering the firm’s incentive to actopportunistically when the partnership is more transaction oriented and (b) increasing the cost ofaggressive intrusions when the partnership is more relation oriented.

Specifically, at low to medium levels of relative exploration (i.e., more transaction oriented), theeffect of relative exploration on a firm’s competition is smaller when the number of repeated collab-orations increases, for two reasons. First, repeated ties foster relational capital between allies (Gulati,1995; Gulati & Singh, 1998; Kale, Singh, & Perlmutter, 2000), stifling a firm’s incentive to competewith its partner. Relational capital, such as trust, aligns the interests of allies as well as promotescooperation and reciprocity (Kogut, 1989; Uzzi, 1997; Zaheer, McEvily, & Perrone, 1998). Trustencourages firms not to abuse each other’s vulnerabilities and to respect their respective boundary

CUI ET AL. 3121

Page 7: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

of resources and proprietary knowledge (Krishnan, Martin, & Noorderhaven, 2006). The incentiveto behave opportunistically is therefore reduced as the number of repeated ties increases.

Second, repeated collaborations restrain a firm’s incentive to compete by improving the effec-tiveness of formal governance mechanisms, such as contracts, in preventing opportunistic learningin exploratory activities. Repeated ties help firms learn how to work together effectively by helpingthem discover their partners’ self-serving behaviors and patterns, which in turn leads them to antici-pate similar behavior in the future (Doz, 1996; Lioukas & Reuer, 2015). Firms normally incorporatesuch knowledge into improving their contracts and other defensive mechanisms to guard againstcompetitive behaviors from the same partners (Mayer & Argyres, 2004). Repeated collaborationscan therefore strengthen these governance mechanisms and reduce a firm’s incentives to competewith its partner.

At medium to high levels of relative exploration (i.e., more relation oriented), too, the effect ofrelative exploration on competition is reduced by the number of collaborations between allies, asrepeated collaboration increases the cost of competition in this type of partnership. First, repeatedcollaborations further enhance the symbiotic relationship between partners in joint knowledge dis-covery. Repeated collaboration facilitates the development and refinement of important bilateral sys-tems, such as problem-solving mechanisms, that typically consist of routines of negotiation andmutual adjustments. These mechanisms enable allies to reduce production errors and resolve prob-lems more flexibly (Uzzi, 1997). Repeated collaboration also fosters relational capital, whichencourages allies to share proprietary knowledge in a more fine-grained and timely fashion(Krishnan et al., 2006; Uzzi, 1997). These formal or informal mechanisms further enhance the part-nership’s synergistic benefits, thus heightening the cost of damaging such a collaboration.

Second, repeated collaborations between firms can help both parties gain more knowledge andintelligence about each other (Gulati, 1995; Podolny, 1994), further escalating the risk of retaliation.Specifically, multiple collaborations help the partner (a) see through superficial phenomena and rela-tionships to identify the firm’s underlying behavior patterns, (b) connect separate units of know-howto detect the firm’s fundamental knowledge bases, and (c) deepen understanding of the firm’s com-petencies and vulnerabilities (Uzzi, 1997). Such knowledge further increases the risks of destructiveretaliation, expanding the cost of aggressive competition.

To summarize, a firm’s incentive to compete with its partner is reduced at low to medium levelsof relative exploration, while its competition costs are enlarged at medium to high levels of relativeexploration, when the number of repeated ties is higher. The effect of relative exploration on afirm’s competition with its partner is thus attenuated at both sides of the inverted U-shape. The over-all slope of the relationship between relative exploration and a firm’s competition with its partner istherefore likely to be flattened, with the peak of the slope becoming lower.

Hypothesis 2 (H2) Repeated alliance ties between a firm and its partner negativelymoderate the relationship between relative exploration and the firm’s competitionagainst this partner in the product market, such that the inverted U-shape is flattenedwhen the number of repeated alliance ties is higher.

2.2.2 | Positional embeddedness

A firm’s centrality within the inter-firm network affects the amount of information and resourcesthat it can access (Godart, Shipilov, & Claes, 2014), which represents a significant source of bar-gaining power (Brass, 1992). Firms’ relative centrality therefore reflects the (im)balance betweenthem in terms of resource flows and power (Gnyawali & Madhavan, 2001; Yang et al., 2011). We

3122 CUI ET AL.

Page 8: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

argue that a firm’s greater centrality relative to its partner intensifies the inverted U-shaped relation-ship between relative exploration and the firm’s competition against its partner: it further enhancesthe firm’s incentive to take advantage of its less central partner when their relationship is more trans-action oriented, and also reduces the costs of aggressive intrusions when their partnership is morerelation oriented.

At low to medium levels of relative exploration, relatively greater centrality enhances the firm’sincentive to compete with its partner, for two reasons. First, the more central firm has the advantagein terms of information gathering and monitoring, and thus can cast a wider net to capture knowl-edge leakage from its partner, uncover the partner’s real intentions, and identify weaknesses in itsinnovation system (Polidoro et al., 2011; Zahra & George, 2002). Second, greater network centralityenhances the firm’s advantage in adapting acquired knowledge to develop substitute products. Situ-ated at the confluence of information flows in the network, a more central firm occupies an advanta-geous position in terms of identifying opportunities to apply specific knowledge gained from apartnership into broader areas of application. In a more transaction-oriented relationship, theseadvantages further enhance the firm’s incentive to take action against its partner (Gnyawali & Mad-havan, 2001).

At medium to high levels of relative exploration, greater relative centrality reduces a firm’s com-petition costs, for two reasons. First, when the difference in network centrality between the firm andits partner is large, the firm has more choices of alternative partners than its peripheral partner(Lavie, 2007), while the peripheral partner is more likely to maintain its collaboration with the firmfor resource access and institutional endorsement (Ahuja, 2000; Podolny, 1994). The larger the dif-ference in their centrality, the less dependent the firm is on this specific partnership (Brass, 1992).Such asymmetry enhances the firm’s bargaining power in their interactions (Shipilov, 2009), whichin turn reduces its cost of competition.

Second, when the firm’s centrality is greater than its partner’s, the risk of retaliation from theperipheral partner is lower. This partner is less likely to respond to aggressive actions of the firm,because (a) due to its lack of information sources, the partner will “find it difficult to interpret thecauses and consequences of competitive actions correctly” (Gnyawali & Madhavan, 2001, p. 436),and therefore may not be sufficiently informed to respond; (b) fear of provoking further actions fromthe more powerful firm may motivate the partner not to respond (Gnyawali & Madhavan, 2001);and (c) the partner may not be capable of mobilizing sufficient assets to orchestrate a response.

To summarize, when a firm’s alliance network centrality is greater than that of its partner, itsincentive to compete with that partner is enhanced at low to medium levels of relative exploration,while its costs of competition are reduced at medium to high levels of relative exploration. At bothsides of the inverted U-shape, that is, the effect of relative exploration on the firm’s competition isenlarged by the firm’s relative centrality. The slope in the relationship between relative explorationand competition is therefore likely to be steeper, and the peak of the slope is higher.

Hypothesis 3 (H3) A firm’s relative centrality vis-à-vis its partner positively moder-ates the relationship between relative exploration and the firm’s competition againstthis partner in the product market, such that the inverted U-shape is steepened whenthe firm’s relative centrality is higher.

2.2.3 | Structural embeddedness

The term structural embeddedness refers to the extent to which two firms are connected by commonthird parties: the more common ties the partners have, the more structurally embedded they are. We

CUI ET AL. 3123

Page 9: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

argue that structural embeddedness can attenuate the inverted U-shaped relationship between relativeexploration and a firm’s competition against its partner in the product market by (a) dampening thefirm’s incentive to compete when the partnership is more transaction oriented, and (b) heighteningthe competition costs when the partnership is more relation oriented.

At low to medium levels of relative exploration, the firm’s incentive to take advantage of itspartner is reduced when their structural embeddedness is higher. Specifically, a larger number ofcommon ties increases resource symmetry between the firm and its partner. Chen (1996) argues thata firm is more motivated to compete with others when it has superior resources. As the number ofcommon ties increases, the firm and its partner become increasingly similar in resources to whichthey both have access, which restrains the firm’s incentives to compete with its partner. In addition,if one firm “exploits the vulnerabilities of the other, the occurrence of such behavior can be revealedto common partners and, through them, reach a larger number of firms in the network” (Polidoroet al., 2011: 206). The resulting adverse effects on the firm’s reputation also reduce its incentive tocompete.

At medium to high levels of relative exploration, costs of competition are further heightenedwhen structural embeddedness between partnering firms is higher, for two reasons. First, the partner-ship becomes more symbiotic as structural embeddedness between a firm and its partner increases.Both firms’ success depends increasingly on resource exchanges not only within the dyad but withtheir common allies, which fosters an ecosystem in which the two firms are more interconnectedand their interests more aligned. At a given level of relative exploration, the cost of competition issignificantly increased, since any competition between firms may have a multiplicative adverseeffect within the system. Second, common partners increase the risk and intensity of revenge foropportunistic behaviors. If the firm acts against its partner within this symbiotic relationship, it isnot only likely to be attacked in retaliation by the initial partner but may also experience escalatedattacks in revenge from third-party common allies, which also have (in)direct stakes in this partner-ship (Polidoro et al., 2011).

Taken together, as structural embeddedness between a firm and its partner increases, the firm’sincentive to compete is reduced at low to medium levels of relative exploration, while its competi-tion costs are increased at medium to high levels of relative exploration. Thus, at both sides of theinverted U-shape, the effect of relative exploration on the firm’s competition is reduced as firms'structural embeddedness increases. The slope in the relationship between relative exploration andthe firm’s competition with its partner is likely to be less steep when the number of common ties ishigher, and the peak of the slope is likely to be lower.

Hypothesis 4 Structural embeddedness between a firm and its partner negatively mod-erates the relationship between relative exploration and the firm’s competition againstthis partner in the product market, such that the inverted U-shape is flattened whenthe level of structural embeddedness is higher.

3 | METHODS

3.1 | Sample

We chose the U.S. pharmaceutical industry as an appropriate setting for examining our hypothesesbecause it features both extensive alliance activities and competition for new products(Lichtenberg & Philipson, 2002; Mowery et al., 1996). We first collected data on alliances withinthis industry from 1984 to 2003, using three data sources—SDC Platinum, MedTrack, and ReCap—

3124 CUI ET AL.

Page 10: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

which (a) have very similar standards for reporting information, including the year of alliance estab-lishment, partners’ names, and descriptions of alliance deals, and (b) each normally reports only afraction of all alliance activities (Schilling, 2009). Although databases that track alliances in thepharmaceutical industry are normally reliable (Schilling, 2009), we found that the SDC databasecovers more historical data while MedTrack and ReCap include more recent information. We con-structed a more comprehensive alliance database by combining these three data sources. For due dil-igence, we followed Lavie and Rosenkopf (2006), searching for alliance announcements and statusreports from LexisNexis News, corporate websites, and Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC)filings accessed via the Edgar database. Most alliance announcements were cross-validated by atleast two additional sources. By relying on multiple sources, we minimized the possibility ofdouble-counting alliances and of counting alliances that were announced but not realized.

To measure product competition, we began by selecting all FDA-approved drugs from theFDA’s National Drug Code Directory. We specifically identified drugs approved under clauses 505(b)(2) and 505(j) of the Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act (FD&C Act) with the aid of theFDA’s Approved Drug Products with Therapeutic Equivalence Evaluations (the “Orange Book”).Clause 505(j) governs generic drug applications, while clause 505(b)(2) governs the modificationsof previously approved brand-name drugs. Under the 505(b)(2) and 505(j) pathways of drug appli-cation, the timeline for most new drug launches is reduced to approximately 1 year.3 We then col-lected information on each drug’s ingredients, mechanisms of action, physiologic effect, andchemical structure from four pharmacological databases: Drugs @ FDA, Mosby’s Drug Consult,Drugs-by-Condition on Drugs.com, and AHFS Drug Information from the American Society ofHealth-System Pharmacists (Toh & Polidoro, 2013). A researcher in the pharmacology disciplinewho was not part of our team used this information to help classify all listed drugs into competinggroups. For example, Zoloft and Celexa are considered direct competitors in the antidepressant mar-ket, since they use the same mechanism of action: both are selective serotonin reuptake inhibitors(SSRIs), which boost mood by blocking the re-absorption of the neurotransmitter serotonin withinthe brain, thus helping brain cells send and receive chemical messages. Both Pristiq and Cymbaltabelong to another group of competing antidepressants using serotonin–norepinephrine reuptakeinhibitors (SNRIs), which work by inhibiting the reuptake of both serotonin and norepinephrine toboost mood (See Table A in the Appendix S1 for examples of competing antidepressants and theirunderlying mechanisms). We then linked the competing drugs to their producers and market intro-duction dates with the aid of the “Orange Book.”

We also collected firm financial information from Compustat, as well as patent data from the U.-S. Patent and Trademark Office (USPTO) and the Thomson Innovation database. We located126 public firms for which we had complete information on alliances, drugs, patents, and financialreports, and identified 3,752 observations as our sample, with an observation window ranging from1984 to 2003.

3Drug application is regulated by the FD&C Act, s. 505 of which describes three types of new drug application pathways: (1) Fullapplications under clause 505(b)(1), which requires full reports of investigations into the safety and effectiveness of a drug conductedby the applicant (what is usually known as the brand-name drug application); under this pathway the new drug development cycle isapproximately 10–15 years. (2) Generic drug applications under clause 505(j), which requires information to show that the proposedproduct is therapeutically identical or equivalent to a previously approved drug. (3) Applications under clause 505(b)(2), which allowspharmaceutical firms to submit new drug applications by referencing the literature or previous agency findings on the safety and effi-cacy of a drug, even if not developed by the applicant; typical 505(b)(2) applications include modifications of a previously approvedbrand-name drug such as a new formulation, a change in dosing regimen, a new active ingredient, or a new combination of ingredi-ents. The objective of the 505(b)(2) drug application pathway is to encourage innovation and speed up new drug introductions byeliminating the need for duplicative studies to demonstrate what is already known about a drug.

CUI ET AL. 3125

Page 11: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

3.2 | Dependent variable

3.2.1 | Competitive aggressiveness

Following prior studies, we measured the extent of competition in product markets that a firmundertakes against its partner using competitive aggressiveness, describing both the intensity anddiversity of the firm’s competitive actions (Yu et al., 2009). This variable contains three items: thenumber of competitive actions (i.e., market entries) that the firm launched against its partner follow-ing the alliance announcement and the width and depth of its competing actions. The width dimen-sion measures the number of different therapeutic areas in which the firm entered that competeagainst its partner; the depth dimension measures the number of destructive competitions(i.e., modified brand-name drugs) launched by the firm against its partner. The launch of modifiedbrand-name drugs is a more aggressive competitive action than the introduction of generic drugsbecause of the former’s much longer period of market exclusivity (Lichtenberg & Philipson, 2002).4

We ran a factor analysis of these three items and found that all three loaded high (>0.73) on onelatent factor, while the value of Cronbach’s alpha is .81, which suggests that it is a reliable con-struct. We used the average score for these three items to measure the dependent variable.

3.3 | Independent variable and moderators

Relative exploration is calculated as the ratio of the number of exploratory collaborations to the totalnumber of collaborations between the firm and its partner over a 5-year moving window (Ang,2008; Yang et al., 2011). We used a 5-year window because alliance databases seldom report thetermination dates of alliances, and the life span of an alliance is normally no more than 5 years(Yang et al., 2011). We constructed this variable using a content analysis of the deal summary toidentify the nature of alliance learning for each alliance in our sample. Specifically, research anddevelopment (R&D) alliances with the objective of exploring and creating critical new knowledgewere coded as exploratory collaborations, while alliances such as co-marketing, manufacturing, andlicensing, which mainly utilize existing knowledge and resources, were classified as exploitative col-laborations (Lavie & Rosenkopf, 2006; Rothaermel, 2001; Rothaermel & Deeds, 2004). Since part-ners may have different intentions within an alliance, we undertook this coding from the focalfirm’s perspective (Lavie & Rosenkopf, 2006). It is important to note that not all R&D collabora-tions are exploration oriented; within our data set, if two firms formed an R&D alliance for the pur-pose of making incremental changes to an existing technology, that R&D alliance was coded asexploitative. The value of this variable ranges from 0 to 1.

Repeated alliance ties reflect the relational embeddedness between two firms. We measured thisvariable by counting the number of repeated alliance ties between the firm and its partner over theprevious 5 years (Ahuja, Polidoro, & Mitchell, 2009; Gulati & Gargiulo, 1999).

Relative centrality captures the relative positional embeddedness of two firms. We first con-structed yearly alliance matrices within the pharmaceutical industry from 1984 to 2003, using a 5-year moving window. Altogether, we identified 47,862 pairs of alliances, including those startedbetween 1980 and 1983. We constructed a symmetric (non-directional) matrix of these firms foreach year using Ucinet 6 (Borgatti, Everett, & Freeman, 2002), then calculated the degree centrality

4While a generic drug can be detrimental to the market share of a brand-name drug, Lichtenberg and Philipson (2002) have shownthat creative destructions such as new forms or combinations of ingredients can be more detrimental to market share. This is partlybecause the latter may have better therapeutic effects and are granted longer market exclusivity: while generic drugs are given a maxi-mum 180 days of exclusivity, modifications to brand-name drugs are granted three to seven years of exclusivity.

3126 CUI ET AL.

Page 12: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

of each firm within the above alliance network matrices. Relative centrality is calculated as thefirm’s degree centrality minus its partner’s degree centrality.

Common ties capture the structural embeddedness between the firm and its partner. Followingprior studies, we measured this variable by counting the number of common third-party partners thatthe firm and its partner shared during the previous 5 years (Gulati & Gargiulo, 1999; Polidoroet al., 2011).

3.4 | Control variables

We controlled for sample heterogeneity by including nine variables suggested by prior studies asinfluencing the relationship between alliances and competition.

3.4.1 | R&D intensity

A firm’s R&D investment can contribute to its new product development and thus influence itscompetition against its partner in the product market. We therefore controlled for the firm’s R&Dinvestment, measured as its R&D expenditures scaled by sales (Keil, Maula, Schildt, &Zahra, 2008).

3.4.2 | Return on assets (ROA)

A firm’s financial performance is positively associated with new product development (Rothaermel,2001); firms that perform better financially may be more prepared to compete in the product market.We therefore controlled for a firm’s financial performance using its return on assets.

3.4.3 | Financial slack

Since researchers have argued that competitive behaviors are dependent on resource availability(Smith, Grimm, Gannon, & Chen, 1991), we controlled for a firm’s financial slack, computed ascurrent assets divided by current liabilities (Hambrick, Cho, & Chen, 1996).

3.4.4 | Coopetition

If two firms are competing with each other in the market when they establish an alliance, this “coo-petition” relationship may contribute to the risk of their future competition in the market. We there-fore controlled for coopetition (coded as 1 if two firms were competing in the product market whenthey established an alliance and as 0 otherwise).

3.4.5 | Technological overlap

Prior research suggests that resource similarity between firms may influence their competition(Chen, 1996). We accordingly controlled for dyadic resource similarity by measuring technologicaloverlap, calculated as the percentage of patent cross-citations between a firm and its partner(Mowery et al., 1996).

3.4.6 | Alliance scope

A wide scope of collaboration increases the likelihood of both information leakage and appropria-tion within alliances (Oxley & Sampson, 2004), heightening the risk of product competition. How-ever, collaborations across a wide range of areas may also increase partners’ mutual dependence,which reduces opportunistic behavior (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978). Prior studies have not provided aclear direction for the effect of alliance scope on competition between partners in the product mar-ket. In our model, we controlled for alliance scope using a measure adapted from prior studies

CUI ET AL. 3127

Page 13: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

(Oxley & Sampson, 2004), which was coded as 0 if a collaboration does not include R&D activities,as 1 if it includes only R&D activities, and as 2 if it includes both R&D and non-R&D activities.

3.4.7 | Multiparty alliance (“Multiparty”)In cases where an alliance includes more than two firms, we split the alliance into a set of dyads.Empirically, this may result in a confounding effect with structural embeddedness (i.e., number ofcommon ties). We parceled out the possible confounding effect caused by multiparty alliances byincluding a control variable (“Multiparty”) that measures the number of additional parties (>2) to adyad within an alliance. We also ran the models using a sample excluding multiparty alliances; theresults are robust.

3.4.8 | Network density

As Coleman (1988) has noted, a dense alliance network in which a dyad is located can also facilitateinformation sharing and monitoring within the network, suffocating competition between allies. Wetherefore controlled for the density of the ego network for each dyad. This ego network includes thetwo firms within the alliance as well as all other firms that have at least one alliance with at leastone of the two firms. We first transformed the firm-by-firm alliance network into an incidence net-work (i.e., the output is a two-mode firm-by-alliance network) using the command “transform |graph theoretic | incidence” in Ucinet 6. We then transformed the two-mode incidence network intoa one-mode alliance-by-alliance square network by using the command “data | affiliations” andselecting column as the unit of interest. Finally, we calculated ego network density within this newnetwork for each alliance in our sample.

3.4.9 | Year dummies

We controlled for unobserved heterogeneity associated with years by including 19 year dummies inour models.

3.5 | Analysis

We tested our hypotheses using fixed-effects models. The unit of analysis is firm–partner–year, andwe allowed a 1-year lag between our predictor variables and the dependent variable. A fixed-effectsestimator has superior controls for time-invariant variables (Mundlak, 1978) and is an effective wayto account for possible endogeneity problems. For example, if unobserved heterogeneities, such asthe attractiveness of partners to one another and their tendencies to compete with each other, areconstant within firm–partner dyads, then there might be an endogeneity concern. A fixed-effectsestimator can rule out such a possibility by eliminating time-invariant heterogeneities. Fixed-effectsmodels also allow us to account for intra-cluster correlations caused by multiple observations of thesame dyad over time. We therefore employed dyad fixed-effects and clustered standard errors ondyads in our models.

4 | RESULTS

Table 1 reports descriptive statistics and correlations for all variables, including the quadratic andinteraction terms. We mean-centered the variables before creating quadratic and interaction terms inorder to reduce non-essential ill-conditioning between independent variables and their higher-order

3128 CUI ET AL.

Page 14: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

TABLE1

Descriptiv

estatisticsandcorrelations

Variables

Mean

S.D.

12

34

56

78

910

1112

1Com

petitiveaggressiveness

0.141

0.921

2R&D

intensity

0.897

5.874

−0.020

3ROA

0.027

0.242

0.058

−0.385

4Financialslack

3.201

3.650

0.081

0.170

−0.169

5Coopetition

0.058

0.233

0.620

−0.031

0.086

0.001

6Technological

overlap

0.000

0.012

−0.004

−0.003

−0.003

0.017

−0.006

7Alliance

scope

0.914

0.696

−0.013

0.041

−0.108

0.056

−0.011

−0.029

8Repeatedallianceties

0.343

0.702

−0.008

−0.038

0.067

−0.104

0.034

−0.012

−0.010

9Relativecentrality

−0.191

5.365

0.019

−0.133

0.364

−0.309

0.012

−0.028

−0.079

0.080

10Com

mon

ties

14.892

16.240

0.011

−0.084

0.241

−0.244

0.146

−0.018

0.022

0.321

0.067

11Multip

arty

0.039

0.193

0.021

−0.019

−0.001

0.006

0.027

−0.005

0.075

0.049

−0.032

0.03

12Networkdensity

0.642

0.090

−0.103

0.041

−0.156

0.097

−0.078

0.005

0.028

−0.083

−0.135

−0.224

−0.007

13Relativeexploration

0.320

0.366

0.014

0.021

−0.104

0.052

0.004

−0.020

0.403

0.095

−0.100

0.117

0.080

0.047

14Relativeexplorationsquared

0.236

0.338

−0.065

0.037

−0.113

0.055

−0.058

−0.006

−0.073

−0.129

−0.074

−0.004

0.007

0.069

15Relativeexploration×Repeatedallianceties

0.134

0.364

−0.014

0.004

0.011

−0.050

0.012

0.009

−0.088

0.195

0.031

0.124

0.013

−0.087

16Relativeexplorationsquared×Repeatedallianceties

0.084

0.266

0.023

−0.02

0.036

−0.106

0.064

−0.006

0.006

0.671

0.076

0.230

0.023

−0.096

17Relativeexploration×Relativecentrality

−0.257

2.714

0.020

−0.033

0.167

−0.079

0.019

0.023

−0.010

0.026

0.047

0.070

−0.016

−0.105

18Relativeexplorationsquared×Relativecentrality

−0.224

2.358

0.012

−0.122

0.365

−0.250

0.022

−0.014

−0.032

0.056

0.698

0.081

−0.024

−0.139

19Relativeexploration×Com

mon

ties

5.461

10.400

0.012

−0.023

0.119

−0.075

0.064

0.013

−0.024

0.111

0.073

0.204

−0.023

−0.077

20Relativeexplorationsquared×Com

mon

ties

3.951

8.563

0.044

−0.082

0.243

−0.210

0.137

−0.01

0.029

0.193

0.092

0.708

−0.016

−0.199

Variables

1314

1516

1718

19

13Relativeexploration

14Relativeexplorationsquared

0.650

15Relativeexploration×Repeatedallianceties

−0.151

−0.197

16Relativeexplorationsquared×Repeatedallianceties

−0.069

−0.237

0.534

17Relativeexploration×Relativecentrality

−0.073

−0.123

0.107

0.062

18Relativeexplorationsquared×Relativecentrality

−0.150

−0.173

0.070

0.100

0.521

19Relativeexploration×Com

mon

ties

−0.005

−0.032

0.296

0.21

0.136

0.142

20Relativeexplorationsquared×Com

mon

ties

0.064

−0.02

0.185

0.286

0.145

0.181

0.563

Note.(a)N=

3,752.

(b)Means

werecalculated

usingun-centeredvariable

values.

CUI ET AL. 3129

Page 15: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

TABLE 2 Fixed-effects analyses of firms’ competitive aggressiveness

1 2 3 4 5 6

Constant 39.286 37.947 38.294 36.838 39.115 38.105

(19.012) (16.323) (16.081) (15.986) (15.504) (15.493)

R&D intensity −0.001 −0.002 −0.002 −0.001 −0.002 −0.001

(0.001) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002)

ROA 0.024 −0.003 −0.005 −0.004 −0.013 −0.010

(0.029) (0.035) (0.037) (0.029) (0.036) (0.032)

Financial slack 0.041 0.040 0.040 0.040 0.040 0.040

(0.018) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017) (0.017)

Coopetition 2.832 2.786 2.776 2.785 2.775 2.769

(0.740) (0.704) (0.702) (0.704) (0.708) (0.705)

Technological overlap −0.113 −0.145 −0.129 −0.207 −0.089 −0.150

(0.184) (0.172) (0.178) (0.186) (0.167) (0.188)

Alliance scope 0.015 −0.139 −0.156 −0.138 −0.142 −0.155

(0.014) (0.036) (0.035) (0.033) (0.033) (0.030)

Repeated alliance ties 0.017 −0.054 0.032 −0.053 −0.045 0.027

(0.025) (0.015) (0.039) (0.016) (0.017) (0.038)

Relative centrality 0.010 0.010 0.009 0.005 0.010 0.005

(0.006) (0.005) (0.006) (0.006) (0.005) (0.007)

Common ties −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 −0.000 0.001 0.001

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

Multiparty −0.048 −0.047 −0.029 −0.044 −0.042 −0.021

(0.077) (0.087) (0.082) (0.084) (0.086) (0.078)

Network density −1.001 −1.005 −1.015 −0.997 −0.933 −0.984

(0.348) (0.384) (0.381) (0.392) (0.382) (0.386)

Relative exploration 1.508 1.803 1.492 1.880 2.011

(0.278) (0.273) (0.271) (0.243) (0.245)

Relative exploration sq. −1.439 −1.735 −1.430 −1.831 −1.970

(0.267) (0.252) (0.273) (0.239) (0.254)

Relative exploration × Repeated alliance ties −0.670 −0.560

(0.161) (0.148)

Relative exploration sq. × Repeated alliance ties 0.692 0.572

(0.151) (0.143)

Relative exploration × Relative centrality 0.056 0.058

(0.015) (0.014)

Relative exploration sq. × Relative centrality −0.054 −0.058

(0.023) (0.023)

Relative exploration × Common ties −0.023 −0.017

(0.008) (0.008)

Relative exploration sq. × Common ties 0.024 0.018

(0.009) (0.009)

R2 0.423 0.434 0.436 0.434 0.435 0.437

Log likelihood −3,883 −3,849 −3,843 −3,847 −3,845 −3,839

χ2 (2) (compared with the baseline) 67 79 72 75 88

Prob > χ2 2.236e−15 5.655e−18 2.914e−16 4.396e−17 9.878e−20

Note. (a) N = 3,752. (b) Robust standard errors in parentheses. (c) Year dummies included in regressions but not reported. (d) “sq.”:squared.

3130 CUI ET AL.

Page 16: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

terms (Aiken & West, 1991). The dependent and independent variables show considerable variance,and the correlation coefficients are consistent with our expectations.

We ran fixed-effects models following a hierarchical approach: Model 1 includes only the con-trol variables, while Models 2 through 5 add the independent and interaction variables. Model 6 isthe full model, including all independent and interaction variables. Variance inflation factor (VIF)scores were calculated for all models; none of the maximum VIFs exceed the value of 2.5, which issubstantially lower than the rule-of-thumb cut-off of 10 (Ryan, 1997). We then used the “coldiag”procedure in Stata to conduct the Belsley, Kuh, and Welsch (1980) multicollinearity diagnostic test,which showed that the condition number for our complete model is 7.53, well below the thresholdof 30. We also ran the fixed-effects models using non-centered data; the results are consistent. Sincecentered estimations can make interpretation of the results less straightforward (Echambadi & Hess,2007), we report estimations using the original variable values in Table 2.

In Model 2 of Table 2, we tested Hypothesis 1 by introducing both the linear and quadraticterms of relative exploration. The result shows that competitive aggressiveness first increases signifi-cantly with relative exploration (b = 1.508, p = 8E−08), then decreases significantly as relativeexploration continues to increase (b = − 1.439, p = 1E−07). This result indicates a curvilinear rela-tionship (inverted U-shape) between relative exploration and competitive aggressiveness, with amedium effect size (Cohen’s d = 0.428). We examined the marginal effects of this relationship

0.1

.2.3

.4C

ompe

titiv

e Ag

gres

sive

ness

0 1Relative Exploration

FIGURE 1 The relationship between relativeexploration and competitive aggressiveness

0.1

.2.3

.4C

ompe

titiv

e Ag

gres

sive

ness

0 1Relative Exploration

Repeated Ties = mean - 1 s.d. Repeated Ties = mean + 1 s.d.FIGURE 2 The moderation effect of repeatedalliance ties

CUI ET AL. 3131

Page 17: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

following the three steps suggested by Lind and Mehlum (2010). First, we examined whether or notthe second-order term is significant and of the expected sign; this is confirmed by the result. Second,we tested whether the slope is indeed sufficiently steep at both ends of the data range of relativeexploration. Using the “margins” command in Stata 12, we confirmed that when relative explora-tion = 0, the slope dy/dx = 1.701 (p = 4E−05), and when relative exploration = 1, the slope dy/dx= − 1.561 (p = 3E−05). Third, we tested whether or not the turning point is located within the datarange of relative exploration. We confirmed this using the “nlcom” command in Stata 12 by show-ing that the inverted U-shape turns when relative exploration = 0.522 and that the 95% confidenceinterval for the turning point [0.504, 0.539] is within the value range of relative exploration. Weprovide additional support by plotting this relationship in Figure 1. These findings suggest thatHypothesis 1 is supported.

In Model 3, the interaction terms between repeated alliance ties (relational embeddedness) andboth the linear and quadratic terms of relative exploration are introduced in order to test Hypothesis2: whether repeated alliance ties negatively moderates the inverted U-shaped relationship. Thismoderation effect is supported if the second-order interaction term is significantly positive (Hannset al., 2016). As confirmed by our results, the second-order interaction term is indeed positive(b = 0.692, p = 6E−06), with a small-to-medium effect size (Cohen’s d = 0.364). Figure 2 illus-trates this moderation effect, showing that the inverted U-shape is flattened when the value ofrepeated alliance ties is higher, supporting Hypothesis 2.

0.1

.2.3

.4

Com

petit

ive

Agg

ress

iven

ess

0 1Relative Exploration

Relative Centraltiy = mean - 1 s.d. Relative Centraltiy = mean + 1 s.d.FIGURE 3 The moderation effect of relativecentrality

0.2

.4.1

.3C

ompe

titiv

e Ag

gres

sive

ness

0 1Relative Exploration

Common Ties = mean - 1 s.d. Common Ties = mean + 1 s.d.FIGURE 4 The moderation effect ofcommon ties

3132 CUI ET AL.

Page 18: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

Model 4 introduces the interaction terms between relative centrality (positional embeddedness)and both the linear and quadratic terms of relative exploration in order to test Hypothesis 3: whetherthe firm’s relative centrality positively moderates the inverted U-shaped relationship. This modera-tion effect is supported if the second-order interaction term is significantly negative (Hanns et al.,2016). We found that indeed the second-order interaction term is negative (b = − 0.054,p = 0.019), with a small-to-medium effect size (Cohen’s d = 0.226). Figure 3 illustrates this moder-ation effect, indicating that the inverted U-shape is steepened when the firm’s relative centrality ishigher, supporting Hypothesis 3.

Model 5 introduces the interaction terms between common ties (structural embeddedness) andboth the linear and quadratic terms of relative exploration in order to test Hypothesis 4: whethercommon ties negatively moderates the inverted U-shape. As indicated in our results, the second-order interaction term is positive (b = 0.024, p = .009), with a small-to-medium effect size(Cohen’s d = 0.318). Figure 4 illustrates this moderation effect, showing that the inverted U-shapeis flattened when the value of common ties is higher, supporting Hypothesis 4. Model 6 is the fullmodel, including all control, independent, and interaction variables; all results from Models2–5 hold.

4.1 | Post-hoc analyses

We conducted six additional analyses, either as robustness checks or to gain additional insights intothe primary relationships. These analyses investigated (a) whether the results are robust to alternativemeasures for relative exploration; (b) which firm in a dyad is more likely to initiate competitiveactions; (c) what factors determine a firm’s response to its partner’s actions; (d) the extent to whichthe technological know-how acquired in one area and knowledge of a partner’s managerial systemcan be applied to competition against the same partner in different technological areas; (e) whetherthe results are robust to different paradigms of competition; and (f) the potential moderating effectsof network density and multiparty. Details of these analyses are available in the Appendix S1.

5 | DISCUSSION

This study contributes to a core research area in strategic alliances: the influence of collaboration oninter-partner dynamics (Gulati, 1995; Kogut, 1989). While previous studies provide importantinsights into how prior collaboration can promote further collaboration between partners (Gulati,1995; Gulati & Singh, 1998), we add to this line of research by investigating whether collaborationcan lead to intense product market competition between partners. We approach this question by ana-lyzing the composition of the collaborative relationships between two firms as well as by studyingthe impact of their interconnectedness in the context of alliance networks. We find that in additionto the path-dependent paradigm of partners’ interactions whereby prior collaboration leads to futurecollaboration (Gulati, 1995), certain compositions of collaborative relationships between two firmscan lead to a new path of interaction—a transition from collaboration to competition in product mar-kets. Furthermore, the firms’ network embeddedness can modify this transition process.

Our research contributes to this line of investigation on three fronts. First, our research extendsthe literature on the tension between collaboration and competition within alliances. Prior studieshave long argued that firms race to appropriate knowledge from each other within alliances (Hamel,1991; Khanna et al., 1998). We extend this literature by identifying (a) the composition of collabora-tive portfolios and (b) network embeddedness between allies as important mechanisms through

CUI ET AL. 3133

Page 19: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

which learning within alliances is translated into competitive interactions in the product market. Ourstudy thus bridges two streams of research: learning races within alliances and competitive dynamicsin the product market.

Second, we extend prior studies on learning races, which tend to focus on competition withinresearch-based alliances. We examine the roles played by all types of alliance between two firms, interms of their combinations, in determining a firm’s competition with its partner. Our findings sug-gest that a firm’s product market competition with its partner is not necessarily high in research-intensive collaborations; in fact, the firm is more likely to adopt a long-term outlook that encouragesrelationship building and cooperation when the collaboration portfolio is dominated by exploratoryalliances, reducing its motivation to compete with its partner. Our finding of a curvilinear relation-ship between relative exploration and competitive aggressiveness highlights the role that the overallcollaborative portfolio between partners plays in determining their competitive interactions.

Third, this research contributes to the literature by studying the moderating role of allies’ net-work embeddedness in the “collaboration–competition” relationship. We demonstrate that networkembeddedness—namely relational, positional, and structural embeddedness—affects the relationshipbetween relative exploration and product market competition. Our research speaks directly to theimportance of looking beyond dyadic interactions when examining dyadic competition, representinga valuable addition to the growing body of studies exploring how allies’ network characteristicsinfluence their interaction patterns and performance (Lavie, 2007; Polidoro et al., 2011).

Our post hoc analyses (see Appendix S1) make further contributions to the research on collabo-ration and competition by unpacking the competitive dynamics (i.e., actions and responses) betweenallies. For example, post hoc analysis 2 found an asymmetry between allies with respect to who willbe more likely to “defect” from collaboration: in addition to firms with relatively great network cen-trality, those with more experience competing with other allies are also more likely to compete withtheir current partners. This suggests that the likelihood that allies will compete against each other isnot evenly distributed within a dyad: the firm with either more advantageous network positioning orricher experience in managing the transition from collaboration to competition is more likelyto do so.

Post hoc analysis 3 revealed an interesting relationship with respect to responses to competitiveactions: more aggressive actions tend to provoke more acts of retaliation. This finding seems to bedifferent from suggestions by traditional studies on competitive dynamics that aggressive competi-tion (e.g., irreversible actions) tends to suffocate reactions (Chen & MacMillan, 1992). This is likelybecause those studies assume that competitors have no knowledge of each other ex ante, and thuscompete as if they were strangers each time they encounter one another (Ketchen, Snow, & Hoover,2004). As recent research indicates, traditional competitive dynamics studies assume a Markov ormemory-less process of competition, in which only the current state matters in predicting subsequentstates (Kilduff, Elfenbein, & Staw, 2010). Prior studies on competitive dynamics have overlookedthe role of inter-firm learning (Nelson & Winter, 1982) in determining firms’ competitive interac-tions. Our finding suggests that when firms are alliance partners, the attacked firm is likely torespond to the aggressor’s actions, having developed the capacity to do so through alliance learning.This observation is echoed by two additional findings: first, that the attacked firm is more likely torespond if the number of repeated ties with the aggressor is high, because these ties can provide theattacked firm with ample knowledge regarding the aggressor, and therefore enable it to take effec-tive retaliatory action; and, second, that the attacked firm is less likely to respond if it is either lesscentrally located within the alliance network or less experienced in managing the transition from col-laboration to competition than the aggressor—situations in which the attacked firm is less informed

3134 CUI ET AL.

Page 20: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

and/or less capable of retaliating. Our findings thus complement the classic literature on competitivedynamics.

Our findings provide strong support for the recent conceptualization of competition as “rela-tional” (Chen & Miller, 2015). Different from the traditional “rivalrous view” of competitive dynam-ics, which highlights a firm-centric perspective (Chen & Miller, 2015), the “relational” viewemphasizes the necessity of understanding others’ needs and preferences, as well the interdepen-dencies between self and others, before deciding on competitive moves. Our research extends thisline of argument by suggesting that firms can increase their “relational” savvy through learning invarious forms of interactions, including alliances (Lioukas & Reuer, 2015), competitions (Tsai,Su, & Chen, 2011), and the transition between the two; all of these relationships may inform subse-quent competitive encounters.

5.1 | Limitations and directions for future research

The findings of our study should be interpreted in light of its limitations, which suggest opportuni-ties for future research. First, we examined our hypotheses only in the context of horizontal alliancesin the U.S. pharmaceutical industry. Although the findings are strongly supportive of our hypothe-ses, we must be cautious about generalizing them to other collaboration types (e.g., vertical alli-ances) and other industries. Researchers may further advance this emerging research paradigm byconsidering the roles of alliance- and industry-specific conditions in the relationship between collab-oration and competition.

Second, while the alliance learning perspective has provided important insights for the develop-ment of our theoretical framework, we are also aware that alliances are complex partnerships. Thislearning approach can be well complemented by other relevant theories, such as transaction-costeconomics and the resource-based view. For example, researchers might explore how firms structuretheir alliances by taking governance and resources into consideration in order to prevent competitionfrom allies.

Third, while we studied an important dimension of inter-firm competition (i.e., competitiveaggressiveness) that has been extensively examined in the competitive dynamics literature, there areother dimensions of competition that are currently not included in our research. For example, we didnot study competitive actions using such variables as action execution speed, action visibility, andcompetitor’s acumen (Chen & Hambrick, 1995; Tsai et al., 2011). There are also ample opportuni-ties to study how alliance learning may affect different paradigms of product competition, such asthe “racing” and “incumbent” types of competition (see Appendix S1 for descriptions of these para-digms). While our preliminary analysis suggests that the relationship between collaboration andcompetitive aggressiveness does not differ between these two scenarios, it may prove fruitful toexamine whether and how the relationship between collaboration and the other dimensions of com-petition (e.g., speed, visibility, and acumen) may differ in these two scenarios or in other competi-tive paradigms. Studying these characteristics of competition will enrich our understanding of thecompetitive consequences of alliances.

Finally, while we compiled a comprehensive longitudinal dataset depicting alliances and compe-titions, the use of second-hand data constrained our ability to interpret the micro-level processesthrough which information and knowledge are leaked or appropriated through interactions amongindividuals, as well as the mechanisms through which decisions regarding new product introductionsare made. For example, we were not able to measure tacit technological and managerial know-howin our data because of its low codifiability and visibility. Nor were we able to investigate the extentto which such tacit knowledge travels across technological and organizational boundaries. Despite

CUI ET AL. 3135

Page 21: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

our modest attempts to address this issue in a post hoc analysis, we acknowledge that this is animportant limitation of our study. Field research, such as intensive case studies and interviews,might uncover some of the latent and important processes that cannot be completely revealed by ourpresent work. Future studies in this direction will be warranted.

6 | CONCLUSION

This study investigates an important yet overlooked relationship in the alliance literature: the impactof alliances on partners’ competition in the product market. Integrating alliance learning and net-work perspectives, we argue that the composition of the collaborative relationship between a firmand its partner affects the firm’s competition against this partner. We found an inverted U-shapedrelationship between the firm’s relative exploration and its competitive aggressiveness against itspartner in the market. This curvilinear relationship is flattened by their relational embeddedness(i.e., repeated ties) and structural embeddedness (i.e., common ties), but steepened by their posi-tional embeddedness (i.e., relatively great centrality of the firm) within the alliance network. Thisstudy contributes to the literature on inter-firm dynamics between collaboration and competition,calling for more studies to investigate this intriguing area.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

We thank our guest editors, anonymous reviewers, and participants in the 2016 SMJ special issueworkshop in Rome for their constructive feedback and comments. This research is supported by theSocial Sciences and Humanities Research Council (SSHRC) of Canada (grant number 435-2017-1301) and the Research Grants Council of the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region, China(CityU 11508415).

REFERENCES

Agrawal, A. (2006). Engaging the inventor: Exploring licensing strategies for university inventions and the role of latent knowledge.Strategic Management Journal, 27, 63–79.

Ahuja, G. (2000). Collaboration networks, structural holes, and innovation: A longitudinal study. Administrative Science Quarterly,45, 425–455.

Ahuja, G., Polidoro Jr., F., & Mitchell, W. (2009). Structural homophily or social asymmetry? The formation of alliances by poorlyembedded firms. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 941–958.

Aiken, L. S., & West, S. G. (1991). Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions. Newbury Park, CA: SAGE.Andrevski, G., Brass, D. J., & Ferrier, W. J. (2016). Alliance portfolio configurations and competitive action frequency. Journal of

Management, 42, 811–837.Ang, S. H. (2008). Competitive intensity and collaboration: Impact on firm growth across technological environments. Strategic

Entrepreneurship Journal, 29, 1057–1075.Barden, J. Q., & Mitchell, W. (2007). Disentangling the influences of leaders’ relational embeddedness on interorganizational

exchange. Academy of Management Journal, 50, 1440–1461.Belsley, D. A., Kuh, E., & Welsch, R. E. (1980). Regression diagnostics: Identifying influential data and sources of collinearity.

New York, NY: Wiley.Borgatti, S. P., Everett, M. G., & Freeman, L. C. (2002). Ucinet for windows: Software for social network analysis. Harvard, MA:

Analytic Technologies.Brass, D. J. (1992). Power in organizations: A social network perspective. In G. Moore & J. A. Whitt (Eds.), Research in politics and

society (pp. 295–323). Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.Chen, M. (1996). Competitor analysis and interfirm rivalry: Toward a theoretical integration. Academy of Management Review, 21,

100–134.Chen, M., & Hambrick, D. C. (1995). Speed, stealth, and selective attack: How small firms differ from large firms in competitive

behavior. Academy of Management Journal, 38, 453–482.

3136 CUI ET AL.

Page 22: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

Chen, M. J., & MacMillan, I. C. (1992). Nonresponse and delayed response to competitive moves: The roles of competitor depen-dence and action irreversibility. Academy of Management Journal, 35, 539–570.

Chen, M. J., & Miller, D. (2015). Reconceptualizing competitive dynamics: A multidimensional framework. Strategic ManagementJournal, 36, 758–775.

Coleman, J. S. (1988). Social capital in the creation of human capital. American Journal of Sociology, 4, 95–120.Davis, J. P., & Eisenhardt, K. M. (2011). Rotating leadership and collaborative innovation: Recombination processes in symbiotic

relationships. Administrative Science Quarterly, 56, 159–201.Doz, Y. L. (1996). The evolution of cooperation in strategic alliances: Initial conditions or learning processes? Strategic Management

Journal, 17, 55–83.Dussauge, P., Garrette, B., & Mitchell, W. (2000). Learning from competing partners: Outcomes and durations of scale and link alli-

ances in Europe, North America and Asia. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 99–126.Echambadi, R., & Hess, J. D. (2007). Mean-centering does not alleviate collinearity problems in moderated multiple regression

models. Marketing Science, 26, 438–445.Gimeno, J. (2004). Competition within and between networks: The contingent effect of competitive embeddedness on alliance forma-

tion. Academy of Management Journal, 47, 820–842.Gnyawali, D. R., & Madhavan, R. (2001). Cooperative networks and competitive dynamics: A structural embeddedness perspective.

Academy of Management Review, 26, 431–445.Godart, F. C., Shipilov, A. V., & Claes, K. (2014). Making the most of the revolving door: The impact of outward personnel mobility

networks on organizational creativity. Organization Science, 25(2), 377–400.Granovetter, M. S. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91,

1360–1380.Grant, A. M., & Schwartz, B. (2011). Too much of a good thing: The challenge and opportunity of the inverted U. Perspective on

Psychological Science, 6(1), 61–76.Gulati, R. (1995). Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in alliances. Academy of Man-

agement Journal, 38, 85–112.Gulati, R. (1998). Alliances and networks. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 293–317.Gulati, R., & Gargiulo, M. (1999). Where do interorganizational networks come from? American Journal of Sociology, 104,

1439–1493.Gulati, R., & Singh, H. (1998). The architecture of cooperation: Managing coordination costs and appropriation concerns in strategic

alliances. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43, 781–814.Hambrick, D. C., Cho, T. S., & Chen, M. (1996). The influence of top management team heterogeneity on firms’ competitive moves.

Administrative Science Quarterly, 41, 659–684.Hamel, G. (1991). Competition for competence and interpartner learning within international strategic alliances. Strategic Manage-

ment Journal, 12, 83–103.Hamel, G., Doz, Y. L., & Prahalad, C. K. (1989). Collaborate with your competitors and win. Harvard Business Review, 67,

133–139.Hanns, R. F. J., Pieters, C., & He, Z. L. (2016). Thinking about U: Theorizing and testing U- and inverse U-shaped relationships in

strategy research. Strategic Management Journal, 37, 1177–1195.Hille, K., & Taylor, P. (2011, April 13). Relief for Huawei as it settles with Motorola. Financial Times. Retrieved from http://www.ft.

com/cms/s/0/9b767044-65f6-11e0-9d40-00144feab49a.html#axzz1ebSG34pJKale, P., Singh, H., & Perlmutter, H. (2000). Learning and protection of proprietary assets in strategic alliances: Building relational

capital. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 217–237.Katila, R., Rosenberger, J. D., & Eisenhardt, K. (2008). Swimming with sharks: Technology ventures, defense mechanisms and cor-

porate relationships. Administrative Science Quarterly, 53, 295–332.Keil, T., Maula, M., Schildt, H., & Zahra, S. A. (2008). The effect of governance modes and relatedness of external business develop-

ment activities on innovative performance. Strategic Management Journal, 29, 895–907.Ketchen, D. J., Snow, C. C., & Hoover, V. L. (2004). Research on competitive dynamics: Recent accomplishments and future chal-

lenges. Journal of Management, 30, 779–804.Khanna, T., Gulati, R., & Nohria, N. (1998). The dynamics of learning alliances: Competition, cooperation, and relative scope. Strate-

gic Management Journal, 19, 193–210.Kilduff, G. J., Elfenbein, H. A., & Staw, B. M. (2010). The psychology of rivalry: A relationally dependent analysis of competition.

Academy of Management Journal, 53, 943–969.Kogut, B. (1989). The stability of joint ventures: Reciprocity and competitive rivalry. Journal of Industrial Economics, 38, 183–198.Koza, M., & Lewin, A. (1998). The co-evolution of strategic alliances. Organization Science, 9, 255–264.Krishnan, R., Martin, X., & Noorderhaven, N. G. (2006). When does trust matter to alliance performance? Academy of Management

Journal, 49, 894–917.Lane, P. J., & Lubatkin, M. (1998). Relative absorptive capacity and interorganizational learning. Strategic Management Journal, 19,

461–477.Lavie, D. (2007). Alliance portfolios and firm performance: A study of value creation and appropriation in the U.S. software industry.

Strategic Management Journal, 28, 1187–1212.

CUI ET AL. 3137

Page 23: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

Lavie, D., & Rosenkopf, L. (2006). Balancing exploration and exploitation in alliance formation. Academy of Management Journal,49, 797–818.

Li, D., Eden, L., Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. (2008). Friends, acquaintances, or strangers? Partner selection in R&D alliances. Acad-emy of Management Journal, 51, 315–334.

Li, S. X., & Rowley, T. J. (2002). Inertia and evaluation mechanisms in interorganizational partner selection: Syndicate formationamong U.S. investment banks. Academy of Management Journal, 45, 1104–1119.

Lichtenberg, F., & Philipson, T. (2002). The dual effects of intellectual property regulations: Within- and between-patent competitionin the U.S. pharmaceutical industry. Journal of Law & Economics, 45, 643–672.

Lind, J. T., & Mehlum, H. (2010). With or without U? The appropriate test for a U-Shaped relationship. Oxford Bulletin of Economicsand Statistics, 72, 109–118.

Lioukas, C. S., & Reuer, J. J. (2015). Isolating trust outcomes from exchange relationships: Social exchange and learning benefits ofprior ties in alliances. Academy of Management Journal, 58, 1826–1847.

McEvily, B., & Marcus, A. (2005). Embedded ties and the acquisition of competitive capabilities. Strategic Management Journal, 26,1033–1055.

March, J. G. (1991). Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science, 2, 71–87.Mayer, K. J., & Argyres, N. S. (2004). Learning to contract: Evidence from the personal computer industry. Organization Science,

15, 394–410.Mowery, D. C., Oxley, J. E., & Silverman, B. S. (1996). Strategic alliances and interfirm knowledge transfer. Strategic Management

Journal, 17, 77–91.Mundlak, Y. (1978). On the pooling of time series and cross section data. Econometrica, 46, 69–85.Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Oxley, J. E., & Sampson, R. C. (2004). The scope and governance of international R&D alliances. Strategic Management Journal,

25, 723–749.Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. (1978). The external control of organizations. New York, NY: Harper & Row.Podolny, J. M. (1994). Market uncertainty and the social character of economic exchange. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39,

458–483.Polanyi, K. (1957). The economy as instituted process. In K. Polanyi, C. M. Arensberg, & P. HW (Eds.), Trade and market in the

early empires (pp. 243–270). Mankato, MN: The Free Press.Polidoro, F., Ahuja, G., & Mitchell, W. (2011). When the social structure overshadows competitive incentives: The effects of network

embeddedness on joint venture dissolution. Academy of Management Journal, 54, 369–392.Ritman, A. (2006, July 27). Motorola and Huawei collaborate on 3G. ITPe.net, Retrieved from http://www.itp.net/487110-motorola

and-huawei-collaborate-on-3gRothaermel, F. T. (2001). Incumbent’s advantage through exploiting complementary assets via interfirm cooperation. Strategic Man-

agement Journal, 22, 687–699.Rothaermel, F. T., & Deeds, D. L. (2004). Exploration and exploitation alliances in biotechnology: A system of new product develop-

ment. Strategic Management Journal, 25, 201–221.Ryan, T. Y. (1997). Modern regression analysis. New York, NY: Wiley.Schilling, M. A. (2009). Understanding the alliance data. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 233–260.Shipilov, A. V. (2009). Firm scope experience, historic multimarket contact with partners, centrality, and the relationship between

structural holes and performance. Organization Science, 20, 85–106.Smith, K. G., Grimm, C., Gannon, M., & Chen, M. (1991). Organizational information processing, competitive responses and perfor-

mance in the U.S. domestic airlines industry. Academy of Management Journal, 34, 60–85.Toh, P. K., & Polidoro, F. (2013). A competition-based explanation of collaborative invention within the firm. Strategic Management

Journal, 34, 1186–1208.Tsai, W. P., Su, K., & Chen, M. J. (2011). Seeing through the eyes of a rival: Competitor acumen based on rival-centric perceptions.

Academy of Management Journal, 54, 761–778.Uotila, J., Maula, M., Keil, T., & Zahra, S. A. (2009). Exploration, exploitation, and financial performance: Analysis of S&P 500 cor-

porations. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 221–231.Uzzi, B. (1996). The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: The network effect.

American Sociological Review, 61, 674–698.Uzzi, B. (1997). Social structure and competition in interfirm networks: The paradox of embeddedness. Administrative Science Quar-

terly, 42, 35–67.Yang, H., Lin, Z., & Peng, M. W. (2011). Behind acquisitions of alliance partners: Exploratory learning and network embeddedness.

Academy of Management Journal, 54, 1069–1080.Yang, H., Zheng, Y., & Zaheer, A. (2015). Asymmetric learning capabilities and stock market returns. Academy of Management Jour-

nal, 58, 356–374.Yu, T., & Cannella, A. A. (2007). Rivalry between multinational enterprises: An event history approach. Academy of Management

Journal, 50, 665–686.Yu, T. Y., Subramaniam, M., & Cannella Jr., A. A. (2009). Rivalry deterrence in international markets: Contingencies governing the

mutual forbearance hypothesis. Academy of Management Journal, 52, 127–147.

3138 CUI ET AL.

Page 24: Attacking your partners: Strategic alliances and competition ......Although strategic alliances are inter-firm partnerships formed to jointly develop, manufacture, and distribute technologies

Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., & Perrone, V. (1998). Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and interpersonal truston performance. Organization Science, 9, 141–159.

Zahra, S. A., & George, G. (2002). Absorptive capacity: A review, reconceptualization, and extension. Academy of ManagementReview, 27, 185–203.

SUPPORTING INFORMATION

Additional Supporting Information may be found online in the supporting information tab for thisarticle.

How to cite this article: Cui V, Yang H, Vertinsky I. Attacking your partners: Strategic alli-ances and competition between partners in product markets. Strat Mgmt J. 2018;39:3116–3139. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2746

CUI ET AL. 3139