avidit acharya alexander lee may 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of...

26
The Cartel System of States Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019

Upload: others

Post on 20-Jan-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

The Cartel System of States

Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee

May 15, 2019

Page 2: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

2

Page 3: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Contents

1 Introduction 5

1.1 A View from the U.S.-Canada Border . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5

1.2 The Questions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

1.3 The Inadequacy of Existing Theories . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

1.3.1 Ideational Theories . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

1.3.2 Conflict and Cooperation in International Relations . . . . . . 11

1.3.3 Theories of State Building . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

1.4 The Cartel Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

1.5 The Plan of this Book . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18

3

Page 4: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

4

Page 5: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Chapter 1

Introduction

1.1 A View from the U.S.-Canada Border

Niche, North Dakota and Gretna, Manitoba are two small communities of a few

hundred people each that lie on opposite sides of the U.S.-Canada border. They are

both old communities. Gretna was settled early in the 19th century soon after the

Anglo-American convention of 1818 established the 49th parallel as the U.S.-Canada

border in that region. Although Neche was laid out several decades later, Pembina

county to which it belongs contained the first settlement of the Dakota territories,

having been settled as early as the 1780’s.

The two communities are very similar—and they each others’ nearest communities.

Their residents frequently cross the border, for example to buy gas in Neche, or eat

out at Nora’s Diner in Gretna. But at the same time, their residents face very different

political-economic circumstances. The residents of Gretna are Canadian residents, are

subject to Canadian laws, pay their taxes to the various tiers of Canadian government,

and enjoy access to Canadian public goods and services such as universal healthcare.

The residents of Neche, on the other hand, are residents of the United States, subject

to American laws, paying their taxes to various tiers of American government, and

enjoying American public goods and services such as the high quality American roads

that connect the denizens of sparsely populated plains and Western states, and access

to institutions of American education including public schools and universities.

The differences in these circumstances reflect the significance of an international

border, especially in parts of the developed world where such borders have come to

reflect sharp, discontinuous changes in political authority.

Consider another example, that of Point Roberts, Washington on the southern-

most tip of the Tsawwassen Peninsula, just across the Strait of Georgia from mainland

Washington. Residents of this enclave must cross the U.S.-Canada border twice

when traveling to other parts of the United States. Because of this inconvenience,

the residents of Point Roberts do much of their shopping for goods and services in

5

Page 6: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Canada. Nevertheless, some important Canadian services are not available to them.

For example, the town has no hospital, doctor, or dentist, and American insurers

do not pay for coverage by Canadian healthcare providers. In cases of emergency,

the residents of Point Roberts seek care in Bellingham, Washington, even though

Vancouver is much closer.

Enclaves like Point Roberts exist around the world, for example the Cooch Bihar

or West Berlin. But it is not only their status as enclaves that these places are curious

to us. Our puzzle over the challenges of life in an enclave stems from the political

importance of international borders. Were it the case that the residents of Point

Roberts could simply travel to Vancouver and easily receive all of the services not

available to them in their community, their life would be much easier and we may be

less surprised by the existence of such an enclave. But this is not the case.

1.2 The Questions

International borders represent one of the most tangible features of the international

state system, a system that exists now almost universally, and which we take for

granted. What explains this fact? Why are the citizens of border regions that happen

to lie across a political border often subject to very different governance systems?

These questions are the subject of this book.

To put these questions in perspective let us consider first the possibility of some

hypothetical counterfactuals, second that today’s territorial state system in which

borders are such sharp and meaningful political demarcations is a relatively recent

institution in human history, and third that only in a few remaining instances (mostly

parts of the developing world) borders exist but are not the sharp demarcations we

may be accustomed to in the vast majority of the world’s regions.

6

Page 7: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Imagine, for a moment, a world in which the residents of towns on the U.S.-

Canada border could decide for themselves if they wanted to pay a portion of their

taxes to the Canadian government to “buy in” to Canadian healthcare while paying

another remaining portion of their taxes to the U.S. government to enjoy access to

American public services, such as the ability to enjoy in-state tuition in their state’s

public colleges. We could even ask this question of cities, towns and communities

that are not border communities. Why can’t public services be bought piecemeal, on

an a-la-carte basis, with governments competing with one another to provide higher

quality services at the lowest cost, in a sort-of marketplace for public goods? What

impact would this competition have on citizen-welfare? Presumably, this competition

would be good for citizens since governments would be compelled to provide more

and better services at lower costs, or else be driven out of the market. Why don’t or

why haven’t citizens living in two thriving bordering democracies demanded such a

competitive market system in the provision of governance?

The idea citizens choosing their governments the way they choose their diners

or gas stations, as the residents of Neche and Gretna do, may seem nonsensical. In

the 21st century world, we are conditioned to find sharp discontinuities in political

authority as both natural and desirable. However, in not too distant history, political

boundaries did not mark the absolute changes in political authority that they do

today, and residents of border regions were, in some cases, subject to the laws and

authority of both neighboring rulers, and in other cases, subject to neither because

they could choose which of the two neighboring states’ laws they would abide by and

which they would not. The Dukes of Burgundy, for example, were vassals of both

the French monarch and the Holy Roman emperor, with obligations to both. At the

same, they were able to build up a large political unit in the 15th century in the

borderlands between France and the Holy Roman Empire by skillfully negotiating

their position between the two sides. In the medieval period in Europe, the haziness

of medieval political boundaries meant that lords and towns located between larger

polities maintained a considerable amount of autonomy.

At the same time, the most powerful rulers refused to accept the idea that their

authority ceased at some point in space, and claimed “universal dominion.” Under

Roman rule, most of Europe had been organized into a single polity that claimed to

rule the whole world. In the Middle Ages, both the papacy and the Holy Roman

Empire used this precedent to make similarly extravagant claims. Even after the

administrative machinery of the Empire had already become decrepit, the Latin motto

of Austriae est imperare orbi universo (“all the world is subject to Austria”) featured

prominently on Hapsburg iconography. Perhaps the most far reaching claims came

from the papacy, as for example, Pope Gregory claimed in the Dictates Papae (1075)

that he has the power “(12)... to depose emperors,” and “(27)... to absolve subjects

from their oath of fidelity to wicked rulers.” (Ogg 1907). Outside of Europe, Chinese

emperors of the Qing era claimed to be superior to all other polities, and treated their

7

Page 8: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

relations with foreign peoples as “tribute” paid by barbarians to the emperor, while

the Holy Roman Emperor claimed authority over all of central Europe while aspiring

to control the whole world.1

The system of hierarchical sovereignty in Europe and across the world looked

markedly different than the one by which states are organized today. While the

great empires claimed the world, most smaller polities claimed something less than

the “sovereignty” thought to be associated with modern states. Medieval Europe,

Tokagawa Japan and Mughal India contained hundreds of lordships and cities who

exercised autonomous political authority, raising taxes and making war much as mod-

ern states do. At the same time, these units acknowledged the partial authority of

higher level political authorities, perhaps paying them some tribute, sending contin-

gents to their wars, and allowing appeals to their courts. The Holy Roman Empire, in

1792, comprised 80 princes, 120 ecclesiastical princes and prelates, 66 imperial cities,

and some 2,000 imperial knights, all claiming to be “sovereign”, while at the same

time acknowledging that they were part of a larger whole (Lee, 2005, 71). These types

of independent local lords were particularly powerful in borderlands like Burgundy

and the transitional zone between England and Scotland, where they played larger

sovereigns off against each other to gain autonomy and low taxation for themselves.

All of this changed, gradually in the last several centuries. In this time, the world

witnessed the gradual formation of a system where borders have come to possess sig-

nificantly greater political meaning—a system of territorial states. In the words of

Stephen Krasner, “the clearest storyline of the last thousand years is the extruding

out of universal alternatives to the sovereign state” (Krasner, 1993, 261). Most bor-

ders were formally demarcated on the ground and recognized by both parties, while

universal claims have been abandoned as old fashioned and inconvenient. Border

elites were crushed, and the areas that they controlled administratively assimilated

to the rest of the polity. While the intervention of more powerful states in less power-

ful ones never ceased, these interventions have become cloaked in an elaborate regard

for the absolute, autonomous sovereignty of even powerless states.

Yet, the sharp meaning of international borders has not spread fully to all parts

of the world. In many parts of the developing world, governments attempt to exercise

some sort of political power outside the boundaries assigned them on world maps—

in fact, in some cases there may not be mutually agreed borders on world maps.

Residents of the zones of weak state presence and unclear political authority between

Afghanistan and Pakistan and the disputed and ambiguous boundary between Sudan

and South Sudan, for instance, may be able to choose to which of these governments

or their local proxies they owe their primary allegiance to, and may face demands from

both sides for taxes and military support. In these cases, the “border” is less a line

than a broad zone of disputed and ambiguous political authority. Nevertheless, these

types of border zones are usually regarded as dangerous exceptions to the “normal”

operations of the state system in most of the rest of the world.

8

Page 9: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Given these facts, the questions that we are concerned with in this book are:

What is the territorial state system? How does it maintain itself? And, perhaps

most importantly, why does it exist? These are questions that have been asked and

answered before. But the answer that we will give in this book is novel, and provides

a new lens by which we can understand this basic feature of modern political life.

1.3 The Inadequacy of Existing Theories

We are not the first to ask questions about how to understand the territorial state

system, nor are we the first to give answers. But the answers that have been given

are not quite adequate to understand the puzzles that motivate us. Some authors

have focused on explaining the origins of the system, without explaining what makes it

persist and how rulers and states have used it to organize politics. Others have focused

on understanding how the system structures relations between rulers, neglecting the

relations that citizens have with multiple rulers. While the literature provides some

useful lenses by which to view the system, no existing theory explains why citizens

of border areas like Niche and Gretna cannot acquire piecemeal public services from

neighboring governments if doing so would improve their welfare. We first cover the

existing theories before outlining our own.

1.3.1 Ideational Theories

Perhaps the most influential theory for the development of the modern state system is

the Westphalia hypothesis : the idea that the Peace of Westphalia (1648) engendered

the norm of territorial sovereignty, and therefore marked a critical juncture in the

development of the modern state system.

The origins of the Westphalia hypothesis lie in a 1948 article by Leo Gross (1948)

published in the American Journal of International Law and influenced the view of

numerous scholars of international relations from diverse camps.2 Proponents of the

Westphalia hypothesis have pointed mainly to three articles in the the Treaties of

Onasbruk and Muenster that comprise the Peace. These are Article 64, which states

the rights of princes to choose the official religion of their principalities, 65, which

states that they may conduct their own foreign policy, and 67, which states that they

can set domestic policy.

However, as Andreas Osiander (2001) and Stephen Krasner (1993) have argued,

these articles neither granted the princes rights that they did not already have, nor did

they materially change the way the princes conducted their affairs within the Empire.

They, along with other skeptics, have challenged the Westphalia hypothesis on three

grounds.3 First, the provision to allow the states to adopt their own religion had

already been stated in the Treaty of Augsburg (1555). Moreover, religious conflicts

persisted well after 1648. Second, the constituent states of the Empire had the ability

9

Page 10: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

to set domestic and foreign policy even prior to the end of the Thirty Years War,

as per the landeshoheit system practiced at least since 1519. At the same time, it

was not until the 19th century, after the Napoleonic wars abolished the Empire, that

the princes became fully sovereign. Third, and perhaps most importantly, there is no

evidence that any historian, diplomat, emissary, or ruler prior to Leo Gross cited the

Peace of Westphalia as a source for the norm of territorial sovereignty, rather than a

legal precedent affecting particular territories.

Perhaps aware of the lack of evidence that the Peace of Westphalia led to insti-

tutional changes toward territorial sovereignty, Gross (1948) himself wrote that “it

would seem appropriate to search not so much in the text of the treaties themselves

as in their implications, in the broad conceptions on which they rest and the de-

velopments to which they provide impetus” (p. 26). The argument, according to

its originator Leo Gross (1948), is therefore that the Peace of Westphalia was an

ideational watershed in which new ideas of sovereignty took shape.

Whether or not the Peace of Westphalia in particular marked an ideational water-

shed, it is possible that territorial state system nevertheless developed as a result of

an encounter with new ideas that resulted in a change in norms and ideology. This is

a widely held view in international relations theory, supported by numerous authors,

even those who do not explicitly endorse the Westphalia hypothesis. Ruggie (1993)

writes, for example, that “the mental equipment that people drew upon in imagining

and symbolizing forms of political community itself underwent fundamental change”

and that “historians of political thought have long noted the impact on the emerging

self-image held by European territorial rulers of a new model of social order” (157).

Philpott (2001) echoes this view, claiming that “revolutions in sovereignty result from

prior revolutions in ideas about justice and political authority” (4).

There are also many theories of why and when these ideological changes occurred.

Nexon (2009) discusses the role of the Reformation in changing the ideological basis of

European politics in this period in a way that made the “composite” polities common

in the early 16th century obsolete. Osiander (1994, 281) argues that the French

Revolution represented the most important watershed, but only in the context of a

gradual long-term evolution of political ideas that led the development of “a shared,

rather elaborate code of structural and procedural legitimacy” (279).

A closely related argument is that the ideas about territory and technologies for

demarcating space changed in the Early Modern period, making “modern” terri-

toriality ideologically possible. Political geographers have been especially active in

examining the ways in which ideas about territory and territoriality evolved over time

(Agnew, 2009, Larkins, 2009, Elden, 2013). They argue that territory, and particu-

larly the bounded, less hierarchical idea of sovereignty, was an idea that had to be

constructed. However, relative to Philpott (2001), the geography literature is less

explicit in stating that these ideational changes caused the state system to develop,

instead focusing on describing the ideological changes that occurred.

10

Page 11: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Despite these perspectives, some authors express skepticism about the primacy of

ideas, suggesting that state-building altered political theory rather than the reverse.

Krasner (1993) is among the skeptics, arguing that ideas were simply “legitimat-

ing rationales” that rulers could draw on to provide legitimacy to actions that they

undertook primarily in their material self-interest. He writes:

“Initially, the ideas [of sovereignty] were just hooks to justify actions that

were motivated by considerations of wealth and power, not by visions of

justice and truth. European leaders were fortunate in having many hooks

because of the diversity and richness of European intellectual traditions.”

(257)

At the same time, authors sympathetic to ideational arguments also agree that

the self-interested motives also played a role, at least for some actors. Osiander (260),

for instance, believes that private correspondence of Cardinal Richelieu and his allies

in the Thirty Years War show a desire for self-aggrandizement much more than they

do a commitment to any ideal of political order. More subtly, Nexon (2009) argues

that the ideological changes of the Reformation were important precisely because

of the way in which they interacted with existing patterns of non-religious political

contestation.

Evaluating the causal impact of new ideas is difficult. We do not deny the im-

portant possibility that the ideas that succeeded and spread were both shaped by

material interests, and in turn had an influence on the way rulers construed their

interests. But if new principles were the primary drivers of change, rulers should

have an incentive to adhere to the principles; that is, those principles should be self-

enforcing. Otherwise it becomes difficult to explain not just why these principles

spread but also why the stability of a system built upon these principles would not

gradually be undermined by rulers realizing their interests in violating them. Herein

lies the missing element of ideational theories, one that our theory will provide.

1.3.2 Conflict and Cooperation in International Relations

While the state system is a basic analytical concept of international relations, it is one

that this often taken as exogenous. Classic theories of international relations treat the

state as the a strategic actor, without examining how these actors emerge (e.g. Fearon,

1995, Waltz, 2001, Walt, 1990). Other approaches may similarly treat additional

aspects of the contemporary state system, such as norms of non-interference, formal

institutional equality, and territorial demarcation, as structural features of the system

(Agnew, 1994, Wendt, 1987, Ruggie, 1993).4

This is not to say that territoriality is an understudied subject: The literature on

boundaries and boundary disputes is enormous, and growing (Schultz, 2013, Carter

and Goemans, 2011, Abramson and Carter, 2016). However, studies of territorial

11

Page 12: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

conflict can ignore its comparative rarity in the contemporary world. Consider, for

example, the fact that outside of Antarctica, nearly every square inch of land in the

world belongs to a state, but the fraction of land that is claimed by more than one

state is less than 1.6% (based on Schultz, 2015, in the year 2000). International

relations theorists who focus most of their attention on explaining and understanding

conflict, have decided to view the glass as half empty, but in fact the glass is 98.4%

full. Similarly, interstate conflict as a whole has been in decline, though the reasons

for this are hotly debated (Gleditsch et al., 2002, Lacina et al., 2006, Pinker, 2011,

Maoz and Russett, 1993). Unlike much of international relations theory which focuses

on conflict, our task is explain the enormous cooperation between states that defines

the modern territorial state system.

One can, of course, argue that the desire to avoid conflict is the key factor in the

emergence and stability of the state system. The last several centuries have been a

period of period of rapid change in the capabilities of states to make war, administer

justice, and collect revenue (Gennaioli and Voth, 2015). Potentially, states could be

so intimidated by the escalating costs of conflict that they would cooperate to avoid it,

by adopting technologies that reduce the probability of disputes (such as demarcated

borders) or developing norms that encourage the non-violent resolution of conflict

(Wagner, 2010).5 According to this view the territorial state system exists mainly to

avoid violent conflict.

There are several reasons to be skeptical of this theory. First, it is not clear that

such an arrangement would be stable in the medium term. The more powerful player

in any dyad would have strong reasons to use the threat of conflict as a bargaining

tool, particularly against weaker neighbors and in more important disputes. Secondly,

it does not indicate why border should be territorial, rather than use one of the other

models of international organization described by Spruyt (1996). If Canada and the

United states wished to avoid conflict, they could agree not to fight each other, this

would not necessarily lead to a rigid administrative demarcation.

And in thinking about the origins of the state system, if the state system originated

in the 17th century to limit conflict, it did not really do a good job of this because

wars persisted well into the 20th century, which saw some of the most devastating

conflicts in human history. What the state system did accomplish almost from its

inception centuries prior is controlling and limiting the choices of individual autonomy

especially in border areas. This it did accomplish.

1.3.3 Theories of State Building

The existing scholarship on the growth of the state in Early Modern Europe is vast.

So-called bellicist perspectives trace variation in the formation of states to variation

in the incidence of international conflict, which incentivized the construction of an

expanded set of institutions to administer permanent armies and navies, and raise

12

Page 13: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

the taxes to support them (Tilly, 1985, 1992, Bean, 1973, Centeno, 2002, Hintze,

1975, Thies, 2004, Scheve and Stasavage, 2016, Queralt, 2018). The bellicisits have

been opposed by scholars who argue that economic factors (Abramson, 2017), chance

(Acharya and Lee, Forthcoming) or social class configurations (Anderson, 1979) were

more important in predicting the growth of state institutions, or that the effect of con-

flict was conditional on some other factor (Lee and Paine, 2018, Karaman and Pamuk,

2013). Other scholars, have focused on role of the specific institutional innovations

associated with effective states, including rationalized bureaucracies (Weber, 2015,

Brewer, 1990, Brambor et al., 2016, Beik, 1985), personal loyalties (Strayer, 1970)

constraints on the executive (Acemoglu et al., 2005, Dincecco, 2011, 2015, Downing,

1993, Ertman, 1997, Mares and Queralt, 2015).

These accounts focus on the origins of states as institutions: How the entourages

of medieval warlords evolved into elaborate and highly effective bureaucracies. They

do not provide an explanation for the emergence of a state system. Why do polities,

instead of attempting to conquer each other, make mutually recognized borders and

then refuse to administer any territory outside those borders? Why is increased effec-

tiveness in extending authority over ones own population correlated with a remarkable

forbearance in dealing with other polities?

What makes this question interesting is that the existence of effective state insti-

tutions in neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition for a state being treated as an

effective, sovereign member of the state system, and treating others as such. Contem-

porary Somaliland, for instance, has institutions for taxation and territorial control

that are as or more effective than many other African states, but is recognized by no

other state, as is treated by international system as an illegitimate interloper, despite

it’s claims to sovereignty (Lalos, 2011). similarly, out side of Europe the introduction

of Early Modern military innovations such as gunpowder was not accompanied by

the development of a sovereignty norm. In fact, the so-called “gunpowder empires”

of 17th century Asia, such as the Ottomans and Qing used the new technology to

repress local rulers and build large polities that explicitly claimed universal domin-

ion (McNeill, 1989). some of these states, particularly the Qing, also made moves

toward homogenous internal markets and administrative rationalization similar to

contemporary developments in Europe.

There are even more examples of states that are treated as sovereign by the state

system, but have little control of what goes on between their borders. Jeffrey Herbst

(Herbst, 2014) famously argued that African states have systematically failed to col-

lect taxes and monopolize force within their boundaries, a result of both geographical

difficulties and the flawed institutions inherited from colonialism. Other authors have

found extensive and deep seated variation in the capacity and “quality” of state insti-

tutions in other parts of the world (Lee and Zhang, 2017, Besley and Persson, 2009,

Lee, 2019, Migdal, 1988, La Porta et al., 1999, Evans, 1995, Fearon and Laitin, 2003)

itself partly a product of historical factors (Lee, 2018, Lee and Schultz, 2012, Gen-

13

Page 14: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

naioli and Voth, 2015, North, 1973, Michalopoulos and Papaioannou, 2013, Foa, 2016,

Sokoloff and Engerman, 2000). Many states take this weakness a step further, with

large areas controlled by rebel groups (themselves unrecognized by the state state

system), who ignore the authority of the government. At the extreme, this may mean

that the internationally recognized “government” may control little more than a few

blocks around the presidential palace. However, by a process of “organized hypocrisy”

(Krasner, 1999), other more powerful states treat these states as fully equal to them

in a juridical sense, and acknowledge their right to complete sovereignty within a set

of borders that are difficult or impossible to change.

Spruyt (1996) represents the main attempt to relate the institutional changes

emphasized in the existing literature to the question of systemic change. Spruyt

(1996) argues that differences in capabilities across institutional forms to make war,

administer justice, and collect revenue were crucial for “the victory of the sovereign

state” (154). The main portion of Spruyt’s argument shows that variations in trade

created alternative political forms in some parts of Europe during the Middle Ages.

However, in Chapter 8, he addresses our question: why these alternative political

structures were eliminated during the early modern period, in favor of the modern

territorial state system.

To answer this, Spruyt’s (1996) focuses on competition and selection among states

rather than cooperation. For him, the sovereign, territorial state had “institutionally

superior arrangements” (32) relative to city leagues and large empires, particularly

in their ability to wage war.6 Moreover, the organization of territorial states was

incompatible with other forms of political organization and authority, whose claims

they did not respect. Spruyt (1996) holds that changes in the internal structure of

states changed the state system as “sovereign states selected out and delegitimized

actors who did not fit a system of territorially demarcated and internally hierarchical

authorities.” (28). Combined with the superior resources of the sovereign state, over

time this delegitimization would lead to non-territorial polities being selected out

through “mimicry and exit” (171).

One shortcoming of this argument is that improvements in the economics of co-

ercion or taxation, even uneven ones, are not guaranteed to lead to a territorial state

system. In fact, improvements in military and administrative capacity are compatible

with both claims of universal empire and the practice of mixed sovereignty. This claim

receives support from the fact that outside of Europe, the introduction of Early Mod-

ern military innovations such as gunpowder was not accompanied by the development

of a sovereignty norm. In fact, the so-called “gunpowder empires” of the Ottomans,

Safavids, Mughals, and Qing used the new technology to repress local rulers and

build large polities that explicitly claimed universal dominion (McNeill, 1989). Some

of these states, particularly the Qing, also made moves toward homogenous inter-

nal markets and administrative rationalization similar to what Spruyt describes in

Europe.7

14

Page 15: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Therefore, while Spruyt’s selection argument provides an explanation for why

some polities (like France and Spain) succeeded while others (like the Hanseatic

League) failed, it does not explain why the successful, institutionally superior states

subsequently recognized each other’s claims rather than continuing the process of

“selecting out” the weaker states. Many states eventually ceased to claim all the

territory that they could potentially have administered, or to which they might have

laid claims. In particular, even if we accept that territorial polities are ideologically

incompatible with city leagues, Spruyt’s theory leaves unexplained why territorial

polities would be compatible with each other in the long run. This is precisely where

our theory will complements his.

1.4 The Cartel Theory

In a nutshell, our argument is that the territorial state system represents an economic

cartel. It is an agreement among rulers to divide what we refer to as the “market

for governance” in ways that reduce competition and deter entry, at the expense of

their citizens. It exists because rulers are forward-looking and self-interested revenue

maximizers, always seeking to find ways to maximize their power over their subjects,

and raise more money. Given this, their interest in creating monopoly power through

the mechanisms of oligopolistic cooperation should come as no surprise.

We set out a neoclassical theory of the state, where rulers provide “governance” (a

package of services starting from protection, to dispute resolution, to modern public

goods and infrastructure) to citizens. Since they are the only providers of coercion,

rulers can force citizens to pay the price they choose for a set of services that they

choose, constrained only by the (often high) cost of individual exit.

A key premise of our theory is the market for governance has the potential to

be competitive. Individuals facing tax demands that they consider too high relative

to the benefits they receive may instead join another polity. Individuals placed be-

tween two polities can play them against each other, demanding more services or less

taxation in return for their allegiance. The tax rates paid by individuals are thus

regulated by the availability of alternative rulers, and the costs that those rulers face

in providing services. Individuals in a competitive governance market will thus pay

a price for services determined very close to the costs of the competing states in pro-

viding those services, with the more efficient polities overing the most competitive

prices. Individuals in noncompetitive markets, however, still pay a monopoly price,

often well above the cost of providing services.

The costs of providing governance for each polity varies spatially. Each polity

possesses a zone, often (though not always) the zone around the capital, where its

ability to extract resources and apply coercive force is very high. The farther away

from this zone the state attempts to expand, the longer communications become,

15

Page 16: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

the farther armies have to travel, and the more unfamiliar local society becomes to

officials. All of these raise the costs of providing governance. Note that the increase

of cost with distance is not necessarily linear. As James Scott (2014) has pointed

out, topography can have a crucial importance for the spread of state administra-

tion, with states finding flat settled areas easy to administer but having a hard time

administering highland areas.

By itself, this variation in costs will not affect the taxes charged to citizens, though

it may lead to polities refusing to conquer areas they could not administer profitably,

as the Roman Empire did at times.However, as we move from the center of one

state, we may be moving towards the center of gravity of another. This will have

an effect on taxes, since it gives local elites an outside option. By threatening, even

if only implicitly, to switch their allegiance to a rival polity, border residents can

extract concessions, usually in the form of lower net taxes, increased services, or

increased local autonomy. Put in economic terms, the appearance of cooperation in

the governance market is accompanied by lower prices and higher levels of services.

The desire to eliminate these unstable, unprofitable border zones has been the

main factor in the creation and stability of the state system. The state system, at its

basis, is a product of cooperation by rulers against their citizens, where polities divide

the potential market among themselves, and agree to not provided governance outside

of these boundaries. Since each “state” is now a local monopolist in the provision of

governance, individuals must pay them the monopoly price, leading to tax burdens

being equalized across core and peripheral areas.

This state system, thus constituted, resembles a cartel. In the same way that

Archer Daniels Midland and its Japanese and Korean competitors distributed among

themselves the global market in lysine in the 1990s, or Osram, General Electric,

Associated Electrical Industries, and Philips divided global market in lightbulbs in

the 1920s, contemporary states divide among themselves the right to tax the world.

By limiting competition, the members of the cartel can charge citizens in border

areas much higher prices than they would be able to otherwise. However, unlike most

modern cartels the state system is, due to the anarchic nature of the international

order, untroubled by the legal restrictions on cartels that exist in most countries. Like

most modern cartels, the state system is haunted by the specter of cheating: That

one player will attempt to steal the market share of the others, either by force or by

attracting border elites.

The territorial division that is characteristic of the contemporary state system is a

means for reducing this type of cheating. Violations of the norm of non-competition

are easier to police when they are unambiguous and visible. The mutually agreed,

demarcated territorial border serves as an unambiguous way of dividing political au-

thority, and of the territory of one taxing monopoly from one another. While a

Medieval “border violation” might be difficult to separate from the legitimate exer-

cise of political authority, today any state that governs outside of its internationally

16

Page 17: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

recognized borders is clearly violating the norms of the state system.

Within these borders, a single political unit is legally supreme—or, to use the com-

monly used expression, “sovereign.” It recognizes other political units as sovereign

within their own borders, and receives their recognition in return: In both theory

and in practice, it is this mutual recognition, symbolized by the exchange of ambas-

sadors that sets “states” apart from other political units. This does not mean that

states are able to govern with equal efficiency. In fact, some states, such as those in

contemporary Africa may be so institutionally underdeveloped that they are unable

to provide much in the way of state services, or extract much in way of taxes. While

these efficiency problems might doom these states in a perfectly competitive system,

the state system guarantees them a share of the market, much as economic cartels

can guarantee the survival of inefficient producers.

Cooperation between states can be made self-enforcing with the help of strategies

that punish deviating rulers for violations of the cooperative norm. While a state

might gain revenues by collecting taxes from its neighbors’ subjects, this would lead

eventually to a loss of revenue as it reduced taxes in the face of competition for the

allegiance of its own border subjects. However, it may still be in states’ interests

to alter the border in their favor. To reduce such attempts, the state system has

developed a complicated system of norms that discourage the unilateral initiation

of conflict, and unilateral annexation of territory. In Africa, for instance, colonial

boundaries, however artificial, are widely considered to be inviolable. The losers from

the creation of the state system are thus the elites of border areas. Now unable to

play one side against the other, they have seen their legal privileges and favorable

fiscal arrangements whittled away, and replaced by the same tax rates and political

arrangements found elsewhere.

Our theory has affinities with the existing literatures in international relations,

some of which we discussed above. One is the large set work debating whether

whether the formation of the state system did or did not coincide with intellectual or

cartographical shifts in the way that states were represented, shift possibly associated

with the treaty of Westphalia.8 While there is no doubt that some ideological change

did take place, we offer an explanation for its economic foundations. We build on a

large literature on the structure of the existing international system and the mechanics

of border disputes.9 But we advance this literature by examining the origins of

the system that they take for granted. A final influence is the large literature on

state-building, which focuses on factors such as war and differences in institutional

effectiveness.10 However, unlike this literature, we focus not on the origins of states

but on the state system: not on why political units have become large or are efficient,

but on why they have chosen to cooperate with each other.

How does our theory help explain the puzzle of discontinuous political changes at

borders? The residents of Neche, cannot buy government service in Gretna because

the governments of the United States and Canada have mutually agreed that they

17

Page 18: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

cannot. This means that both governments can provide the levels of taxes and services

that they see fit, unconstrained by potential competitors. This is the argument that

we lay out and develop in this book. We explore the many consequences of viewing

the territorial state system through this economic lens. What supports its stability?

How does it respond to technological changes, and changes in norms that go against

it? How have political and economic developments like the advent of democracy, the

rise of globalization, etc., threatened or supported it? These are the questions we

explore in the subsequent chapters.

1.5 The Plan of this Book

Chapter 1 of this book lays out the questions that are to be answered, and summarizes

the theory of how and why the modern state system developed, and how and why it

has remained stable over time. Its also briefly describes the existing literature, and

the inadequacy of the answers that the literature has given to the questions that are

the focus of this project.

Chapter 2 sets out the central claims of the theory. It describes the market for

governance, the losses rulers suffer from competing in this marketplace, and the po-

tential benefits to forming a cartel. It explains the transition from a system without

cooperation to one with cooperation, in which the key changing variables are the

rising value of governance and the declining costs of governing distant territories.

To demonstrate how these dynamics work, it examines in detail two cases. In late

medieval Britain, the English and Scottish governments were able to cooperate to de-

limitate a border, eliminate conflicting claims to sovereignty, and agree on procedures

for dispute resolution. This enabled both sides to eliminate the power of previously

privileged elite groups in the border region, and assimilate them to the administrative

structure of the kingdom as a whole. On the Afghan-Pakistani border, by contrast,

both governments have granted numerous concessions to people in the border regions,

which have become an under-governed zone much like the medieval Scottish border.

However, unlike the English and Scots, the two states have not been able to limit

their ambitions to control territory on the other side of the formal frontier, leaving

both sides unable to resist the demands of local elites for subsidies and autonomy.

Chapter 3 examines how bilateral arrangements like those of the Anglo-Scottish

border gave way to a hegemonic set of norms that influence the whole world. It

discusses the emergence of multilateral cooperative arrangements in Europe, and the

emergence and importance of international institutions in sustaining the state system.

It also discusses how the state system has encouraged the persistence of states that

govern areas that would otherwise be difficult to administer, and discouraged the

entry of new states into the system.

Chapter 4 discusses why the state system has been so robust, and the threat posed

18

Page 19: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

to the system by international conflict. It discusses the role of nationalism in reifying

international boundaries. It also discusses the gradual decline of border disputes and

territorial wars, and discusses some recent exceptions to this trend.

Chapter 5 addresses the incentives and mechanics that explain the historical ori-

gins of the state system. It provides evidence for how the empirical patterns pre-

dicted by the the cartel theory emerged in Late Medieval and Early Modern Europe.

It shows how universal claims to sovereignty declined at the same time that precise

cartographic descriptions of borders increased. It provides evidence for the fact that

the emergence of the state system was associated with increased taxation in border

areas, and the equalization of the tax burden between those areas and those that were

uncontested. It discusses the formal elements of international relations that became

important in this period, particularly the exchange of diplomats and the development

of ideas of international law, and how they enhanced the stability of the system. It

also discusses how the state system spread outside of Europe during the period of

Western imperialism.

Chapter 6 lays out some ideas for how the state system may develop in the future.

The modern state system developed in a period where no nation was democratic, and

the long distance movement of both people and goods was far less common than in

today’s globalized world. All of these developments threaten the ability of the state

to remain sovereign in the classical sense, as does the rise of “regional superstates”

such as the European Union. In some sense, the most important question of the 21st

century is not how territory can be divided within the cartel of states, but whether

such a cartel can survive into the future.

19

Page 20: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Notes1See Fairbank and Chen (1968) and Ho (2002, 215).2According to Osiander (2001) the list of scholars who support this view includes David Boucher,

Seyom Brown, Hedley Bull, Kal Holsti, Hans Morgenthau and Mark Zacher, among many others.3See also De Carvalho et al. (2011).4For a classic discussion of the difficulty of studying the international system as a whole, see

(Singer, 1961).5This logic has some affinities to the large literature on nuclear deterrence, though the costs or war

are usually not as high as in this case. It might also explain why democratic, well institutionalized

states are less likely to initiate conflicts with other states, and virtually never initiate conflicts with

each other (Maoz and Russett, 1993).6This was in part a product of larger size of states, but even more closely related to their superior

ability to prevent free riding and create homogenous internal markets (Spruyt, 1996, 158-67).7Note that Spruyt does not present an argument for the ideological incompatibility with or

institutional inferiority of empires relative to sovereign states, though he does discuss the particular

problems of Medieval European examples.8See Ruggie (1993), Philpott (2001), and Nexon (2009) for arguments in the affirmative and

Krasner (1993) for a counterpoint.9See, for example, Fearon (1995), Waltz (2001), Walt (1990), Wendt (1987), Ruggie (1993),

Schultz (2013), Carter and Goemans (2011), Abramson and Carter (2016), Wagner (2010), and

many others.10See, for example, Tilly (1992), Bean (1973), Centeno (2002), Scheve and Stasavage (2016),

Abramson (2017), Acharya and Lee (Forthcoming), Anderson (1979), Weber (2015), Brewer (1990),

Dincecco (2011), Downing (1993), Ertman (1997), Spruyt (1996), and many others.

20

Page 21: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Bibliography

Abramson, S. and D. Carter (2016): “The Historical Origins of Territorial Dis-

putes,” American Political Science Review, 110, 675–698.

Abramson, S. F. (2017): “The economic origins of the territorial state,” Interna-

tional Organization, 71, 97–130.

Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson (2005): “The rise of Europe:

Atlantic trade, institutional change, and economic growth,” American economic

review, 546–579.

Acharya, A. and A. Lee (Forthcoming): “Path Dependence in European De-

velopment: Medieval Politics, Conflict and State Building,” Comparative Political

Studies.

Agnew, J. (1994): “The territorial trap: the geographical assumptions of interna-

tional relations theory,” Review of international political economy, 1, 53–80.

——— (2009): Globalization and sovereignty, Rowman & Littlefield.

Anderson, B. (2006): Imagined Communities, Verso Books.

Anderson, P. (1979): Lineages of the Absolutist State, Verso.

Bates, R. H. (2001): Prosperity and Violence, WW Norton.

Bean, R. (1973): “War and the Birth of the Nation State,” Journal of Economic

History, 33, 203–221.

Beik, W. (1985): Absolutism and Society in 17th Century France, Cambridge UP.

Besley, T. and T. Persson (2009): “The origins of state capacity: Property

rights, taxation, and politics,” American Economic Review, 99, 1218–44.

Brambor, T., A. Goenaga, J. Lindvall, and J. Teorell (2016): “The Lay of

the Land: Information Capacity and the Modern State,” STANCE Working Paper

Series.

21

Page 22: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Brewer, J. (1990): The Sinews of Power, Harvard UP.

Campbell, B. (2002): “War and diplomacy: Rome and Parthia, 31 BC–AD 235,”

in War and society in the Roman world, Routledge, 225–252.

Carter, D. B. and H. E. Goemans (2011): “The making of the territorial order:

New borders and the emergence of interstate conflict,” International Organization,

65, 275–309.

Centeno, M. A. (2002): Blood and debt: War and the nation-state in Latin Amer-

ica, Penn State Press.

De Carvalho, B., H. Leira, and J. Hobson (2011): “The big bangs of IR:

The myths that your teachers still tell you about 1648 and 1919,” Millennium, 39,

735–758.

Debiel, T., R. Glassner, C. Schetter, and U. Terlinden (2009): “Local

State-Building in Afghanistan and Somaliland,” Peace Review, 21, 38–44.

Dincecco, M. (2011): Political transformations and public finances: Europe, 1650–

1913, Cambridge UP.

——— (2015): “The Rise of Effective States in Europe,” Journal of Economic His-

tory, 75, 901–918.

Downing, B. (1993): The military revolution and political change: Origins of democ-

racy and autocracy in early modern Europe, Princeton University Press.

Elden, S. (2013): The Birth of Territory, University of Chicago Press.

Ertman, T. (1997): Birth of the Leviathan: Building states and regimes in medieval

and early modern Europe, Cambridge UP.

Evans, P. B. (1995): Embedded autonomy: states and industrial transformation,

Cambridge UP.

Fairbank, J. K. and T. Chen (1968): The Chinese world order: traditional

China’s foreign relations, Harvard UP.

Fearon, J. D. (1995): “Rationalist explanations for war,” International organiza-

tion, 49, 379–414.

Fearon, J. D. and D. D. Laitin (2003): “Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war,”

American political science review, 97, 75–90.

Foa, R. (2016): “Ancient polities, modern states,” Ph.D. thesis, Harvard University.

22

Page 23: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Gambetta, D. (1996): The Sicilian Mafia: the business of private protection, Har-

vard University Press.

Gennaioli, N. and H.-J. Voth (2015): “State Capacity and Military Conflict,”

The Review of Economic Studies, 82, 1409–1448.

Gleditsch, N. P., P. Wallensteen, M. Eriksson, M. Sollenberg, and

H. Strand (2002): “Armed conflict 1946-2001: A new dataset,” Journal of peace

research, 39, 615–637.

Gross, L. (1948): “The Peace of Westphalia, 1648-1948,” American Journal of

International Law, 42, 20–41.

Habib, M. et al. (1963): “The agrarian system of Mughal India (1556-1707).” The

agrarian system of Mughal India (1556-1707).

Herbst, J. (2014): States and Power in Africa, Princeton UP.

Hintze, O. (1975): “Military Organization and the Organization of the State,” in

The historical essays of Otto Hintze, ed. by F. Gilbert, Oxford University Press,

175–215.

Ho, E. (2002): “Names beyond Nations. The Making of Local Cosmopolitans,”

Etudes rurales, 215–231.

Hobbes, T. (2016): Thomas Hobbes: Leviathan (Longman Library of Primary

Sources in Philosophy), Routledge.

Karaman, K. K. and S. Pamuk (2013): “Different Paths to the Modern State in

Europe,” American Political Science Review, 107, 603–626.

Krajewski, M. (2014): “The great lightbulb conspiracy,” IEEE spectrum, 51, 56–

61.

Krasner, S. (1993): “Westphalia and All That,” in Ideas and Foreign Policy, Ithaca:

Cornell UP, 235–264.

——— (1999): Sovereignty, Princeton UP.

La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny (1999):

“The quality of government,” Journal of Law, Economics, and organization, 15,

222–279.

Lacina, B., N. P. Gleditsch, and B. Russett (2006): “The declining risk of

death in battle,” International Studies Quarterly, 50, 673–680.

23

Page 24: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Lall, M. (2008): “Educate to hate: The use of education in the creation of antago-

nistic national identities in India and Pakistan,” Compare, 38, 103–119.

Lalos, D. (2011): “Between statehood and Somalia: Reflections of Somaliland state-

hood,” Wash. U. Global Stud. L. Rev., 10, 789.

Larkins, J. (2009): From Hierarchy to Anarchy, Springer.

Lee, A. (2018): “Land, State Capacity, and Colonialism: Evidence From India,”

Comparative Political Studies.

——— (2019): Development in Multiple Dimensions: Social Power and Regional

Policy in India, University of Michigan Press.

Lee, A. and J. Paine (2018): “The Great Fiscal Divergence,” Working Paper.

Lee, A. and K. Schultz (2012): “Comparing British and French Colonial Lega-

cies,” Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 7.

Lee, M. M. and N. Zhang (2017): “Legibility and the Informational Foundations

of State Capacity,” Journal of Politics, 79, 118–132.

Lee, S. J. (2005): Aspects of European history 1494-1789, Routledge.

Low, A. D. (1974): The Anschluss Movement, 1918-1919, and the Paris Peace

Conference, vol. 103, American Philosophical Society.

Luttwak, E. (1979): The Grand Strategy of the Roman Empire, JHU Press.

Maoz, Z. and B. Russett (1993): “Normative and structural causes of democratic

peace, 1946–1986,” American Political Science Review, 87, 624–638.

Mares, I. and D. Queralt (2015): “The Non-Democratic Origins of Income

Taxation,” Comparative Political Studies, 48, 1974–2009.

Mbembe, J. and S. Rendall (2000): “At the edge of the world: Boundaries,

territoriality, and sovereignty in Africa,” Public culture, 12, 259–284.

McNeill, W. (1989): The Age of Gunpowder Empires, 1450-1800, Amer Historical

Assn.

Michalopoulos, S. and E. Papaioannou (2013): “Pre-Colonial Ethnic Institu-

tions and Contemporary African Development,” Econometrica, 81, 113–152.

Migdal, J. S. (1988): Strong societies and weak states: state-society relations and

state capabilities in the Third World, Princeton UP.

24

Page 25: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Miguel, E. (2004): “Tribe or nation? Nation building and public goods in Kenya

versus Tanzania,” World politics, 56, 327–362.

Nexon, D. (2009): The Struggle for Power in Early Modern Europe, Princeton UP.

Nicolaidis, K. and G. Shaffer (2004): “Transnational mutual recognition

regimes: governance without global government,” Law & Contemp. Probs., 68,

263.

North, D. C. (1973): The Rise of the Western World, Cambridge UP.

Olson, M. (1993): “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Politi-

cal Science Review, 87, 567–576.

Osiander, A. (1994): The States System of Europe, 1640-1990, Clarendon Press

Oxford.

——— (2001): “Sovereignty, International Relations, and the Westphalian Myth,”

International organization, 55, 251–287.

Philpott, D. (2001): Revolutions in Sovereignty, Princeton UP.

Pinker, S. (2011): The better angels of our nature: A history of violence and hu-

manity, Penguin.

Posen, B. R. (1993): “Nationalism, the mass army, and military power,” Interna-

tional security, 18, 80–124.

Queralt, D. (2018): “The Legacy of War on Fiscal Capacity,” Working paper.

Rousseau, J.-J. and G. May (2002): The social contract: And, the first and second

discourses, Yale University Press.

Rowe, W. T. (2010): China’s last empire: the great Qing, vol. 6, Harvard University

Press.

Ruggie, J. (1993): “Territoriality and Beyond,” International organization, 47, 139–

174.

Scheve, K. and D. Stasavage (2016): Taxing the Rich, Princeton University

Press.

Schultz, K. (2013): “What’s in a Claim? De Jure versus De Facto Borders in

Interstate Territorial Disputes,” Journal of Conflict Resolution.

——— (2015): “Mapping Interstate Territorial Conflict,” Journal of Conflict Reso-

lution, 61, 1565–1590.

25

Page 26: Avidit Acharya Alexander Lee May 15, 2019...ni cantly greater political meaning|a system of territorial states. In the words of Stephen Krasner, \the clearest storyline of the last

Scott, J. (2014): The Art of Not Being Governed, Yale UP.

Scott, J. C. (1998): Seeing like a state: How certain schemes to improve the human

condition have failed, Yale University Press.

Singer, J. D. (1961): “The level-of-analysis problem in international relations,”

World Politics, 14, 77–92.

Sokoloff, K. L. and S. L. Engerman (2000): “History lessons: Institutions,

factors endowments, and paths of development in the new world,” The Journal of

Economic Perspectives, 217–232.

Spruyt, H. (1996): The Sovereign State and its Competitors, Princeton UP.

Strayer, J. R. (1970): On the medieval origins of the modern state, Princeton UP.

Thies, C. G. (2004): “State Building, Interstate and Intrastate Rivalry,” Interna-

tional Studies Quarterly, 48, 53–72.

Tilly, C. (1985): “War Making and State Making as Organized Crime,” in Bringing

the State Back In, ed. by P. Evans, Cambridge UP Cambridge, 169–185.

——— (1992): Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992, Blackwell.

Tripodi, C. (2016): Edge of Empire: The British Political Officer and Tribal Ad-

ministration on the North-West Frontier 1877–1947, Routledge.

Upton, A. F. (1998): Charles XI and Swedish Absolutism, 1660-1697, Cambridge

UP.

Wagner, R. H. (2010): War and the state: The theory of international politics,

University of Michigan Press.

Walt, S. M. (1990): The origins of alliance, Cornell University Press.

Waltz, K. N. (2001): Man, the state, and war: A theoretical analysis, Columbia

University Press.

Weber, E. (1976): Peasants into Frenchmen, Stanford UP.

Weber, M. (2015): “Bureaucracy,” in Working in America, Routledge, 29–34.

Wendt, A. E. (1987): “The agent-structure problem in international relations the-

ory,” International organization, 41, 335–370.

26