balancing in the states - georgetown universityfaculty.georgetown.edu/baileyma/balancing in the...

Download Balancing in the States - Georgetown Universityfaculty.georgetown.edu/baileyma/Balancing in the States, 1978-2009... · Balancing in the States, 1978-2009 ... (in most cases)

If you can't read please download the document

Upload: dangtuyen

Post on 06-Feb-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 1

    Balancing in the States, 1978-2009

    Michael A. Bailey

    Department of Government &

    Public Policy Institute

    Georgetown University

    Intercultural Center 681

    Washington, DC 20057

    (202) 687-6021

    [email protected]

    Elliott B. Fullmer

    Department of Government

    Georgetown University

    Intercultural Center 681

    Washington, DC 20057

    (202) 687-6130

    [email protected]

    AUTHOR INFORMATION:

    Michael A. Bailey is the Colonel William J. Walsh Professor of American Government in the

    Georgetown University Department of Government and the Georgetown Institute of Public

    Policy. His research covers Congress and the Supreme Court, methodology, welfare, trade,

    and inter-state policy competition.

    Elliott B. Fullmer is completing his Ph.D. in American Government at Georgetown University.

    His research interests include state politics, voting systems, congressional behavior, and the

    presidential nomination process. His dissertation examines the effects of early and absentee

    voting laws in the U.S.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]

  • 2

    Abstract

    Since the Civil War, the presidents party has lost seats in the House of Representatives in all but

    three midterm election cycles. Many attribute this pattern to balancing by moderate voters who

    prefer a Democratic Congress when Republicans control the White House, and vice versa

    (Fiorina 1988, 1992, 1996; Alesina and Rosenthal 1995). Although a number of scholars have

    tested the balancing hypothesis, the debate remains unsettled. We argue that states provide an

    excellent way to further analyze the issue. Similar to the national government, states feature an

    executive and (in most cases) a bicameral legislature which comes up for election in both

    gubernatorial and state midterm years. If voters balance, we ought to observe such behavior in

    state elections when an executives partisanship is known and a legislative choice is necessary.

    We examine state legislative elections from 1978-2009 and find evidence consistent with the

    balancing hypothesis.

  • 3

    One of the clearest patterns in U.S. politics is that the presidents party fares poorly in

    midterm elections. In fact, since the Civil War the president has lost seats in all but three

    midterm cycles (1934, 1998, and 2002). Some scholars explain this phenomenon in terms of

    balancing, the idea that voters balance a president of one party by voting for members of

    Congress from the other party. In this view, voters expect that a Congress controlled by the

    opposite party of the president will moderate policies that emerge from the legislative process.

    For all the plausibility of the balancing hypothesis, however, doubts remain. The presidents

    party has picked up seats in two of the last three midterms. In addition, research on the issue has

    yielded differing conclusions (Beck et. al 1992; Sigelman, Wahlbeck, and Buell 1997; Burden

    and Kimball 1998; Roscoe 2003; Lewis-Beck and Nadeau 2004).

    In this paper, we explore the issue in a new way. The balancing hypothesis is not specifically

    about Congress or the presidency, but rather about voters and the interaction of their choices in

    legislative and executive branch elections. Therefore, we examine state elections in order to

    vastly increase the sample size of cases in which voters have a chance to balance. We focus on

    state legislative elections during gubernatorial midterm years, as the balancing hypothesis

    suggests that voters should reward the party opposite of that of the sitting governor in such cases.

    We assess legislative outcomes in each chamber of U.S. states from 1978 to 2009 and find

    evidence that voters balance. In most specifications, we find that Democrats in a state legislature

    are at a disadvantage in midterm elections when there is an incumbent Democratic governor and

    vice versa. The balancing effect is typically around two or three percent of a chamber, but in

    some reasonable specifications is as large as a thirteen or fourteen percentage point difference in

    the proportion of a legislature that is Democratic.

  • 4

    Balancing: the evidence so far

    The balancing hypothesis was first introduced and tested as an explanation for split-ticket

    voting (supporting one party for president and another for Congress) during presidential election

    cycles. Fiorina (1988, 1992, and 1996) argued that many moderates engage in split-ticket voting

    in presidential election years out of a desire to have divided government. Slightly right-of-center

    voters who are inclined to support Republican presidential candidates may prefer a Democratic

    House member because a divided government headed by a Republican chief-executive will

    appear to represent them better than a unified Republican one. Conversely, slightly left-of-center

    voters who are inclined to support Democratic presidential candidates may prefer a Republican

    House member because a divided government headed by a Democratic chief-executive will

    appear to represent them better than a unified Democratic one.

    Analyzing the 1984 and 1988 presidential elections, Fiorina found some support for his

    hypothesis and argues that while most voters do not consciously balance, a preference for

    divided government influences the way a small segment of voters perceive candidates and

    ultimately make voting decisions.

    Additional evidence on this question has come in one of three forms: studies of ticket

    splitting, survey experiments and analysis of national election results. The most expansive

    literature addresses ticket splitting. This literature typically assesses the degree to which self-

    reported ideology and perceptions of the ideological positions of the two major parties relate to

    split-ticket voting. Those who perceive the parties as highly polarized and themselves as fairly

    moderate, the argument goes, should be more supportive of divided government and more likely

    to split their presidential and congressional tickets on Election Day. While some have found

    support for this idea through survey research (Smith et. al 1999; Lewis-Beck and Nadeau 2004;

  • 5

    Saunders et. al 2005), most have reported little or no evidence of such behavior (Beck et. al

    1992; McAllister and Darcy 1992; Alvarez and Schousen 1993; Born 1994, 2000; Petrocik and

    Doherty 1996; Sigelman, Wahlbeck, and Buell 1997; Lacy 1998; Burden and Kimball 1998;

    Roscoe 2003).

    There have also been a number of survey analyses that focus more directly on balancing.

    Here again, we see no consensus as to whether voters balance. On the one hand are several

    papers that support the idea. Carsey and Layman (2004), for example, argue that the

    aforementioned ticket splitting findings should not represent the death knell for the balancing

    hypothesis. It is quite possible in their view that voters may possess balancing preferences and

    still engage in straight-ticket, rather than split-ticket, voting. In 1996, for example, most voters

    arguably knew that incumbent Bill Clinton was likely to be reelected. Interested in balancing the

    government, slightly right-of-center voters would be expected to vote for a Republican member

    of Congress. Knowing that Clinton would win, however, they could also vote their conscience

    for president by casting their respective ballots for Dole. Conversely, some may engage in either

    split or straight-ticket voting for reasons other than balancing.

    Carsey and Layman therefore focus simply on whether voters ideological locations and their

    perceptions of the two parties influence voter attitudes regarding partisan or divided control of

    government. The authors conduct a telephone survey of Illinois adults on the eve of the 2000

    presidential election. In the survey, they ask If [George W.] Bush is elected president, which

    type of Congress would you prefer? They later ask the same question, substituting Bush for

    Vice-President Al Gore, the Democratic nominee. Carsey and Layman find that 17% of the

    sample supports a divided government under all conditions. These respondents prefer a

    Democratic Congress if Bush were elected, but a Republican one if Gore won.

  • 6

    Lacy and Paolino (1998) reach a similar conclusion in their analysis. Echoing Downs (1957),

    they find that presidential vote choices depend more on the perceived distance between voter

    ideal points and expected policy outcomes under each candidate than on the distance between

    voter ideal points and candidate platforms. The authors analyze a 1996 Texas poll in which

    voters were asked to identify the positions of Bill Clinton and Bob Dole, along with the overall

    ideological position of the government if either was elected. While many respondents found

    Clinton to be left-of-center, a sizable number perceived that the government (given their

    expectation that Republicans would control Congress) would be decidedly more moderate under

    him than Dole. This expectation was found to aid Clintons support level with many voters closer

    to Dole on the ideological spectrum.

    On the other hand, several papers find mixed or no survey evidence for balancing. Saunders

    et. al (2005) test the degree to which balancing is more prevalent in years featuring close, or

    unpredictable, presidential elections and find mixed evidence for balancing only in 1996. Geer et.

    al (2004) expose a sample of undergraduates to varying polling data concerning the upcoming

    congressional and presidential races on the eve of the 2000 presidential election. This allowed

    them to manipulate expectations concerning the victors of the looming elections. The authors did

    not find those who believed Democrats would control the White House to be more eager to elect

    a Republican Congress, or vice versa.

    The third approach to assessing the balancing hypothesis is to look at election outcomes.

    Alesina and Rosenthal (1995) argue that balancing is more likely to occur during midterms, as

    voters no longer face uncertainty regarding control of the executive branch. In presidential

    election years, voters are (at least somewhat) uncertain who will control the presidency and

    Congress, forcing moderate voters and leaners to hedge their bets by supporting the party

  • 7

    closest to their preferences in both races. In midterm elections, this uncertainty disappears, and

    voters can act to balance the federal government.

    This, Alesina and Rosenthal predict, should lead to losses for the presidents party in

    midterm cycles. They study district-level election results in midterm elections from 1950 to 1986

    (excluding years just after redistricting) and find that

    With a Democratic president at midterm, Republicans record a higher two-party vote

    share than they did in the previous on-year election (when the presidency was

    uncertain) in a large majority of congressional districts.

    With a Republican president at midterm, Democrats record a higher two-party vote

    share than they did in the previous on-year election (when the presidency was

    uncertain) in a large majority of congressional districts.

    The authors also provide an additional analysis in which they control for incumbency effects.

    They find that voters balance in two primary ways: 1) voters send the presidents party a signal

    that the electorate wishes to moderate policies by diminishing the vote shares of some

    incumbents and 2) voters defeat the presidents party in marginal open seat races, or those seats

    in which a party won with less than 55% of the vote share in the previous contest.

    The very plausibility of these results we know, of course, that the presidents party tends to

    lose during midterms elections is also one of the ideas limitations. The hypothesis was derived

    in part based on the observation of midterm losses by the presidents party. How can we be sure

    that balancing is not simply an ex-post rationalization of a well-known behavioral pattern?

    Balancing: a state-level analysis

  • 8

    States provide an ideal opportunity for assessing the balancing hypothesis as they feature

    voters making choices in separate elections for legislative and executive branch officeholders.

    Examining balancing in the states therefore provides a new venue for testing the hypothesis a

    venue that was not the source of the idea. In addition, states provide dramatically more

    observations and variation on the circumstances of interest. At the federal level, for any given

    election, the balancing hypothesis predicts movement in the same direction (away from the

    presidents party in a midterm); at the state level, we can have numerous states with Democratic

    incumbents (where we would expect balancing to advantage Republicans in the legislature),

    other states with Republican incumbents (where Democrats would be advantaged in the

    legislature) and states with no incumbent (where neither party should have an advantage

    legislatively). This provides a much richer environment for testing the idea.

    Model

    With panel data, there are a number of different specifications that have been used in the

    literature. In particular, the literature has models with and without lagged values of dependent

    variables, with and without differencing of the dependent variable and with and without fixed

    effects. Our approach is to estimate models across the range of specification approaches;

    fortunately, the effects are generally consistent across approaches.

    One question in the literature is whether or not we should include a lagged dependent

    variable in the model. Oppenheimer, Stimson and Waterman (1986) argue that a lagged

    dependent variable is very important to include in a model of one partys legislative results, as

    this variable captures the exposure of the party. When the party has more seats than usual, it

    likely includes a number of marginal seats that it is more likely to lose in the future.

  • 9

    On the other hand, Achen (2001) counsels caution when considering inclusion of lagged

    dependent variables. He derives the asymptotic bias of coefficients on the lagged dependent

    variable and other variables and shows that there can be considerable bias when there is serial

    autocorrelation and trending in the independent variable. In this case, the lagged dependent

    variable does not conduct itself like a decent, well-behaved proxy. Instead it is a kleptomaniac,

    picking up the effect, not only of excluded variables, but also of the included variables if they are

    sufficiently trended. As a result, the impact of the included substantive variables is reduced,

    sometimes to insignificance (Achen 2001).

    Our approach on this question is to report both types of models. In the models without the

    lagged dependent variable, we control for first-order autocorrelation. As we later discuss,

    including a lagged dependent variable seldom affects the results, but it does occasionally reduce

    both statistical significance and the magnitude of coefficients.

    A second question is whether or not to difference the data. Differenced data in a panel

    context is the results for a given year and state minus the previous results in that state. The

    alternative is a level model in which the dependent variable is simply the result for a given

    year. These models are absolutely equivalent when a lagged dependent variable is included

    (Allison 1990), so there is no need to concern ourselves with this question for those

    specifications. When the lagged dependent variable is not included, both differenced and level

    models are unbiased and consistent under standard assumptions; the models do differ in their

    robustness to certain assumption violations and we follow Allisons (1990) preference for

    differenced models (see also Wooldridge 2009).

    Another specification issue is whether or not to include fixed effects. We generally believe

    inclusion of these controls is prudent as they capture two classes of unmeasured factors that

  • 10

    could be correlated with the included variables and cause bias. First, we include year fixed

    effects; these effects control for all factors common to a given year across all states, including

    the national economy, national scandals or simply national political moods that may make some

    years better or worse for Democrats. Second, we include state-level fixed effects. These account

    for any influence on legislative outcomes that is fixed for a state across our time frame. For

    example, the political culture of a state may make it consistently more Democratic than one

    would predict based only on our measured variables. However, some argue that fixed effects

    have some kleptomaniac tendencies as well (Beck and Katz 2001). Hence, we also report results

    without fixed effects in order to provide a sense of how dependent our results are on the use of

    these models.

    In our study, we use data on the partisan composition of state legislatures before and after

    elections since 1978 (The Book of the States 1978-2009; Klarner 2009). Our core model is

    stst4

    stst3stst2stst10st

    X

    )NotGovMTx (DemGov)GovMTx (RepGov)GovMTx (DemGovDemLeg

    where DemLeg is the percentage point change in the percent of a legislative chamber that is

    Democratic, DemGov is a dummy variable for Democratic incumbent governors, GovMT is a

    dummy variable for a gubernatorial midterm election, RepGov is a dummy variable for

    Republican incumbent governors and X is a vector of control variables, described below. The

    excluded category in our formulation is a non-gubernatorial midterm with a Republican

    incumbent. We omit elections which take place while an independent is serving as governor.

    This is not a large enough number to merit another set of variables, and there is no obvious

    reason to include independents with one party or the other.

    The balancing hypothesis predicts that Democrats in legislatures do worse when there is a

    sitting Democratic governor (1< 0 ) and better when there is a sitting Republican governor (2 >

  • 11

    0). Or, most precisely, we predict that 2> 1. This means that we test for balancing not by

    interpreting the coefficients themselves, but rather their differences. In our tables reported below,

    the test of balancing will be an F-test reported at the bottom of each table. Following Alesina

    and Rosenthal (1995), we focus on state midterm races because voters have certainty regarding

    partisan control of the executive branch.

    We include several control variables in order to account for other influences on state

    legislative composition. First, we account for possible surge and decline trends in the

    electorate. This idea, advocated by Campbell and others, contends that the electorate differs

    between presidential and midterm election cycles (A. Campbell 1966; J. E. Campbell 1985, 1987,

    1991, 1997; Born 1990). Presidential cycles are high-stimulus affairs and feature high levels of

    campaign activity and voter turnout. Conversely, national midterm cycles involve low-stimulus

    elections, and thus produce less interest and turnout (Campbell 1997).

    In midterm years, the electorate is comprised of core voters, or those highly interested in

    politics. In presidential years, however, these core voters are joined by peripheral voters, who

    are stimulated by the perceived importance and media attention inherent in presidential races.

    While core voters are likely to have stable partisan feelings and voting patterns, peripheral voters

    are often guided by short-term forces in particular campaigns. In presidential election years, the

    victorious candidate is elected largely with the help of peripheral voters, who in the process help

    members of his party perform well in congressional races. Two years later, in midterm cycles,

    these peripheral voters are absent and the core voters determine election outcomes. This

    inevitably brings losses for the presidents party, as it is no longer helped by the tide of

    peripheral voters that supported it in the previous election (Campbell 1997).

  • 12

    If surge and decline indeed affects elections, we should expect it to impact state legislative

    races which are held concurrently with national races as well. In presidential election years, we

    expect to see a surge when the Democratic candidate does well: the in-state performance of the

    presidential candidate should positively affect the performance of state Democratic legislative

    candidates. In non-presidential election years in which the previous state legislative election was

    in a presidential year, the success of a Democratic presidential candidate in the previous election

    should hurt the party in the current election. Therefore, we include the Democratic share of the

    two-party presidential vote at the state level for the current year in presidential election years. In

    non-presidential years in which the previous state legislative election occurred during a

    presidential election, we include the Democratic share of the two-party presidential vote in the

    previous election.

    We control for state economic conditions with a measure of change in state unemployment.

    We use unemployment because it is highly politically salient and data on it is available for the

    entire span of years we cover (from the Bureau of Labor Statistics). We created two variables

    unemployment change x Democratic governor and unemployment change x Republican

    governor so that unemployment increases would be allowed to have different effects depending

    on which party controlled the governorship. We prefer using change variables as we feel they

    capture the mood of the electorate; for example, while the level of unemployment was higher in

    1984 than in 2008, the trend was better in 1984 and we believe the politics of the times

    responded accordingly. Using levels of unemployment instead of changes, however, has little

    impact on the results.

    After we present a number of specifications based on the core model, we also report

    specifications with additional variables. The limitation of these variables is that they are not

  • 13

    available for the entire time period of our analysis. One factor that could be very important is that

    not all governors are created equal. Some are very popular; some are unmitigated disasters.

    Hence, the extent to which voters feel the need to balance may depend on the popularity of the

    governor. Certainly the evidence is strong that executive popularity influences the executives

    partys performance in legislative elections, both at the federal (Arcelus and Meltzer 1975;

    Bloom and Price 1975; Tufte 1975; Kernell 1977; Fiorina 1981; Kiewiet 1983; Abramowitz

    1985) and state-level (King 2001). We therefore include a measure of gubernatorial approval in

    the weeks preceding an election (Beyle et. al 2009). Because this polling data is not universally

    available, there is a considerable drop off in sample size when we include these data, causing a

    concomitant drop in statistical power.

    Changes in state partisanship and ideology could also explain legislative elections. We

    already have a number of controls that are related to such changes, but we also report results in

    which we include changes in state net Democratic identifiers (Democrats minus Republicans)

    and state net liberals (liberals minus conservatives) using data from Wright, McIver and Erikson

    (2004). This data is based on an aggregation of CBS News/New York Times national polls to

    create large state-level samples. The data is only available through 2003, again causing a

    significant drop off in sample size when included in the model.

    Finally, redistricting could conceivably affect legislative outcomes and be correlated with our

    main variable of interest, gubernatorial control. We therefore use data from Michael McDonald

    on partisan control of the redistricting process (see Bailey and McDonald 2006). There are two

    variables one is an indicator for when Democrats controlled the most recent redistricting

    process; the other is an indicator for when Republicans controlled the most recent redistricting

    process. Often these are both zero as neither party had complete control over the process. This

  • 14

    data is not available for all years, again causing a significant drop off in sample size when these

    variables are included.

    Results

    Table 1 presents the results for the main model for state assemblies from 1978 to 2009.

    Column 1 presents an extremely sparse model; the idea here is to see the relationship in its

    rawest form, relatively free of modeling assumptions. The F-test lines at the bottom indicate that

    the Democratic share of state assemblies is 2.6 percentage points lower when there is a midterm

    and a Democratic governor compared to when there is a midterm and a Republican governor.

    This difference is highly statistically significant (p = 0.001).

    Of course, we wish to know if this result is robust to inclusion of controls for other

    determinants of state assembly elections. The next columns add increasingly more

    comprehensive controls. Column 2 adds variables for state unemployment, state-level

    presidential results and state and year fixed effects; the balancing effect is smaller, but the results

    are generally similar to column 1. Column 3 controls for first order autocorrelation. Some data

    are lost in the process, but the results do not change appreciably. Adding exposure in column 4

    lowers the effect size to 1.4 percentage points and it remains statistically significant.

    Table 2 presents results for the same specifications for state senates. The results are quite

    similar as for state assemblies. The sparse model in column 1 indicates that the difference

    between Democratic and Republican governors in gubernatorial midterms is about 2.4

    percentage points and this difference is highly statistically significant (p = 0.002). Adding

  • 15

    independent variables and fixed effects in column 2 moderates the results a bit, but they are still

    significant. Correcting for autocorrelation in column 3 maintains an effect of 2.2 percentage

    points, despite a drop in sample size. As with the assembly results, the effect drops when the

    exposure variable is added in column 4, but it remains statistically significant.

    The results so far support the idea that voters balance, albeit somewhat modestly as the effect

    size is somewhere in the neighborhood of one to three percentage points. Translating this into

    terms of the U.S. House of Representatives, this would mean that a Democratic president would,

    all else equal, expect to lose between 4 and 13 House seats in a midterm. Applying the results to

    the context of an average-sized state assembly (about 110 seats), a Democratic governor would

    lose 1 to 3 seats. The results are statistically significant, but not breathtaking.

    We now wish to see if the results are robust to alternative specifications and if there are

    conditions under which balancing effects seem to be larger or smaller. In Table 3 we add

    additional controls for state assemblies. Columns 1 and 2 report results when gubernatorial

    approval ratings are included. The magnitude of the effect in column 1 (4.7 percentage points) is

    on the high end of anything we have seen. This effect is significant, as well. While the sample

    changes with the inclusion of the governor approval data, it appears that the changes in results

    are due to including the approval data; running the model on the 384 observations for which we

    have governor approval data, but not including the approval data (a model similar to column 3 of

    Table 1), yields a balancing effect of about 2 percentage points, nearly half of what we see in

    column 1. Column 2 adds a lagged dependent variable and the balancing effect is no longer

    significant. Although the results are often similar with and without a lagged dependent variable,

    when they do differ, they differ in this way: the balancing effect is smaller and sometimes

    insignificant when the lagged dependent variable is included.

  • 16

    In columns 3 and 4, we report results in which we include state-level partisanship and

    ideology variables. This sample has cut off all years after 2003 due to data availability, but it

    does not seem to change the results from what we saw in Table 1. The partisanship and ideology

    variables are not very significant, implying they do not explain legislative results over and above

    the other controls already in the model.

    Columns 5 and 6 of Table 3 report models in which redistricting variables are included. The

    redistricting variables are available for only a subset of observations used in Table 1, but even

    with that reduction in sample size, we observe similar results as before. The balancing effect is

    between 2.5 and 3 percentage points and significant.

    In Table 4 we conduct similar exercises for state senates. Columns 1 and 2 report results

    when gubernatorial approval ratings are included. The pattern is quite similar to what happened

    with state assemblies: the balancing effect is quite large in column 1 -- 5.9 percentage points

    and statistically significant. Again, it appears the gubernatorial variables are doing the work here,

    not the change in sample: running the model on data for which we have gubernatorial approval

    data but not including it yields a balancing effect of 1.5 percentage points, something similar to

    what we saw in Table 2. The balancing effect is relatively large in column 2, which adds a

    lagged a dependent variable, but is statistically insignificant. This is the same pattern we saw for

    state assemblies.

    Columns 3 and 4 report results in which we include state-level partisanship and ideology

    variables. The results are consistent with previous analyses: the balancing effect is in the 2 to 3

    percentage point range and statistically significant. The partisanship and ideology variables are

  • 17

    insignificant, again implying they do not explain legislative results over and above the other

    controls already in the model.

    Columns 5 and 6 of Table 4 report models in which redistricting variables are included.

    Including these variables drops the sample size considerably. Column 5 reports a balancing

    effect of 2 percentage points, but it is not significant at conventional levels (p= 0.116); losing

    about half the data seems the most reasonable explanation here as the results are similar if we run

    the model on this subset of the data and do not include the redistricting data. In column 6, we

    include a lagged dependent variable and the balancing result completely disappears.

    Finally, we explore conditions under which balancing may be stronger or weaker. One

    possibility is that balancing at the state level may be stronger in non-presidential years as the

    intensity of a presidential election may so occupy voters that they pay less attention to potential

    benefits of balancing. Therefore, Table 5 presents results where the sample is limited to non-

    presidential years. The first three columns present results for assemblies. The results are indeed

    stronger. Column 1 presents a model without lagged dependent variables (it is equivalent to

    column 3 of Table 1). The balancing effect is 7.2 percentage points (compared to 1.7 percentage

    points when both presidential and non-presidential years are included). Given the strong effect

    gubernatorial approval had on results earlier, we add approval data to the model in Column 2; the

    balancing effect shoots up to 13 percentage points. Column 3 includes a lagged dependent

    variable (making is comparable to column 4 of Table 1) and the effect falls, as it has generally

    done when adding lagged dependent variables, but the effect remains very large (9.4 percentage

    points) and is highly significant.

  • 18

    We run the same specifications for state senates in columns 4 through 6, running a series of

    models based only on non-presidential election years. The balancing effect of 3.5 percentage

    points in column 4 is large (but not as large as for assemblies) and statistically significant. The

    effect skyrockets to 13.9 percentage points in column 5 and is highly significant. The effect falls

    back to earth a bit in column 6, reaching 6.4 percentage points, but is nonetheless on the high end

    of our findings. The results are not statistically significant, but some consideration must be made

    for the fact that we have less than 1/3 of the data as in our original state senate models from

    Table 2.

    Another possible wrinkle in the estimation is that the South could somehow be distinctive. In

    particular, the realignment pattern of the region over the last 30 years could have led to different

    patterns of balancing. Therefore, we run models excluding the eleven former Confederate states.

    Our results, however, are largely the same. For example, re-running the specifications in Table 1

    without the South leads to an estimated balancing effect of between 1.6 and 2.5 percentage

    points, with p-values ranging from 0.008 to 0.032. These are highly significant even though the

    sample size is cut considerably. Re-running the tests in Table 2 without the South leads to an

    estimated effect of between 2.0 and 2.5 percentage points, with p-values spanning from 0.005 to

    0.027. Again, these are highly significant despite the reduced number of cases.

    Conclusions

    The debate over balancing remains unsettled after nearly two decades of attention. The ticket

    splitting literature is divided, although there is perhaps more weight against balancing. The

    survey-based tests of balancing are also divided, though scholars are more likely to find evidence

    consistent with balancing.

  • 19

    We seek in this work to provide new evidence on the question. Our work is premised on the

    notion that the balancing hypothesis is essentially about voters and therefore it makes sense to

    look at voting behavior at the state level to see if there are signs that voters act in the manner

    predicted. In conducting our tests, we were able to call upon the relative abundance of state data

    over thirty years.

    How should one interpret our findings? Balancing skeptics could point to some insignificant

    results and a number of other results in which the effect is around one percent. Hence even if

    there is balancing, one percent (equivalent to four seats in the U.S. House or one seat in the U.S.

    Senate) is not going to dominate election outcomes. On the other hand, balancing proponents

    may reply that the balancing hypothesis survived even in the face of demanding models that

    included fixed effects and lagged dependent variables, elements that are often suspected of

    soaking up the effects of meaningful independent variables. In addition, in some quite reasonable

    models the balancing effect is large, often near or above three percent and as high as 14 percent.

    A three-percent balancing effect is equivalent to 13 U.S. House seats and four U.S. Senate seats,

    or (in an average-sized U.S. state legislature) three assembly seats and one senate seat. A 14-

    percent effect equates to 61 U.S. House seats and 14 U.S. Senate seats, or 15 state assembly seats

    and six state senate seats. In Pennsylvania, a larger state, the effect would be 28 assembly seats

    and seven senate seats.

    We come down somewhere in the middle. We believe that the evidence suggests balancing

    effects at the state level are real. The results are significant across a broad array of specifications,

    including many which are quite demanding of a relatively small data set. And there seem to be

    two factors that make the results particularly strong. First, balancing effects are clearer during

    presidential midterm elections when the intensity of national presidential elections does not

  • 20

    dominate the political environment. Second, balancing effects are clearer when we account for

    the popularity of the governor, as popular governors mitigate balancing and unpopular governors

    intensify it.

    This last point also opens interesting directions for future research on balancing. Suppose our

    conclusion is correct and voters do indeed balance. What should rational politicians do? One

    possibility is that incumbents would temper their policy goals in the run-up to a midterm

    election, especially if legislative control of a chamber is in question. To the extent that moderate

    voters respond to such tempering of policy, this could have several interesting implications. First,

    it could cause the observed effects to be smaller; for example, Democrats may moderate in

    anticipation of balancing and thereby do better than they would have done with a more

    aggressive agenda. Second, such anticipatory policy behavior could in and of itself be an

    interesting and important topic for further analysis.

    Finally, the micro-level determinants of voter balancing could be further probed. Who is it

    that balances? Is it sophisticated voters making rational calculations? Or is it unsophisticated

    voters going with the mood of the times? Our results here imply that this line of research merits

    continued attention.

  • 21

    References

    Abramowitz, Alan I. 1985. Economic Conditions, Presidential Popularity, and Voting

    Behavior in Midterm Congressional Elections. Journal of Politics 47 (February): 31-43.

    Achen, Chris. 2001. Why Lagged Dependent Variables Can Suppress Explanatory Power of

    Other Independent Variables. Presented at American Political Science Association.

    Alesina, Alberto, and Howard Rosenthal. 1995. Partisan Politics, Divided Government,

    and the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Allison, Paul. 1990. Change Scores as Dependent Variables in Regression Analysis.

    Sociological Methodology 20: 93-114.

    Alvarez, R. Michael, and Matthew M. Schousen. 1993. Policy Moderation or Conflicting

    Expectations? Testing the Intentional model of Split-Ticket Voting. American Politics

    Quarterly 21 (October): 410-38.

    Arcelus, Francisco, and Allan H. Meltzer. 1975. The Effects of Aggregate Economic

    Variables on Congressional Elections. American Political Science Review 69 (December):

    232-39.

    Bailey, Michael and Michael McDonald. 2006. Ideological Gerrymandering: Redistricting

    Effects on State Congressional Delegations. Paper presented at Midwest Political Science

    Association Annual Meetings, April 20-23, Chicago, IL.

    Beck, Paul Allen, Lawrence Baum, Aage R. Clausen, and Charles E. Smith, Jr. 1992. Patterns

    and Sources of Ticket Splitting in Subpresidential Voting. American Political Science

    Review 86: 916928.

    Beck, Nathaniel and Jonathan N. Katz. 2001. Throwing out the Baby with the Bath Water: A

  • 22

    Comment on Green, Kim, and Yoon. International Organization, Vol. 55, No. 2 (Spring):

    487-495.

    Beyle, Thad, and Richard Niemi, Lee Sigelman. 2009. Job Approval Ratings Database,

    1958-2009. From www.unc.edu/%7Ebeyle/jars.html, updated November 2009.

    Bloom, Howard S., and H. Douglas Price. 1975. Voter Response to Short-Run

    Economic Conditions: the Asymmetric Effect of Prosperity and Recession.

    American Political Science Review 69 (December): 1240-54.

    Born, Richard. 1990. Strategic Politicians and Unresponsive Voters. American

    Political Science Review 80 (June): 599-612.

    Born, Richard. 1994. Split-Ticket Voters, Divided Government, and Fiorina's Policy-

    Balancing Model. Legislative Studies Quarterly 19 (February): 95-115.

    Born, Richard. 2000. Policy-Balancing Models and the Split-Ticket Voter, 1972-1996.

    American Politics Quarterly 28 (2): 131-62.

    Burden, Barry C., and David C. Kimball. 1998. A New Approach to the Study of Ticket

    Splitting. American Political Science Review 92 (September): 533-44.

    Campbell, Angus. 1966. Elections and the Political Order. New York: Wiley, 1966.

    Campbell, James E. 1985. Explaining Presidential Losses in Midterm Congressional

    Elections. Journal of Politics 47 (November): 1140-57.

    Campbell, James E. 1987. The Revised Theory of Surge and Decline. American

    Journal of Political Science 31 (November): 965-79.

    Campbell, James E. 1991. The Presidential Surge and its Midterm Decline in

    Congressional Elections: 1868-1988.Journal of Politics 53 (May): 477-87.

    Campbell, James E. 1997. The Presidential Pulse of Congressional Elections. Kentucky:

  • 23

    The University Press of Kentucky.

    Carsey, Thomas M., Geoffrey C. Layman. 2004. Policy Balancing and Preferences for Party

    Control of Government. Political Research Quarterly 57 (4): 541-550.

    Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.

    Fiorina, Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New

    Haven: Yale University Press.

    Fiorina, Morris P. 1988. The Reagan Years: Turning to the Right or Groping toward the

    Middle? in The Resurgence of Conservatism in Anglo-American Democracies (Edited by

    Cooper, Barry, Allan Kornberg, and William Mishler). Durham: Duke

    University Press.

    Fiorina, Morris P. 1992. Divided Government. New York: Macmillan Publishing

    Company.

    Fiorina, Morris P. 1996. Divided Government (2nd

    ed.). Needham Heights: Allyn and

    Bacon.

    Geer, John G., Amy Carter, James McHenry, Ryan Teten, and Jennifer Hoef. 2004.

    Experimenting with the Balancing Hypothesis. Political Psychology 25 (1): 49-63.

    Kernell, Samuel. 1977. Presidential Popularity and Negative Voting: An Alternative

    Explanation of the Midterm Congressional Decline of the Presidents Party.

    American Political Science Review 71 (March): 44-66.

    Kiewiet, D. Roderick. 1983. Macroeconomics and Micropolitics. Chicago: University

    of Chicago Press.

    King, James D. 2001. Incumbent Popularity and Vote Choice in Gubernatorial

    Elections. The Journal of Politics 63 (May): 585-597.

    http://0-www.jstor.org.library.lausys.georgetown.edu/view/00223816/di021234/02p0060z/0?currentResult=00223816%2bdi021234%2b02p0060z%2b0%2c7F3F&searchUrl=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.jstor.org%2Fsearch%2FBasicResults%3Fhp%3D25%26si%3D1%26gw%3Djtx%26jtxsi%3D1%26jcpsi%3D1%26artsi%3D1%26Query%3Dking%2Bgovernor%2Breferendumhttp://0-www.jstor.org.library.lausys.georgetown.edu/view/00223816/di021234/02p0060z/0?currentResult=00223816%2bdi021234%2b02p0060z%2b0%2c7F3F&searchUrl=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.jstor.org%2Fsearch%2FBasicResults%3Fhp%3D25%26si%3D1%26gw%3Djtx%26jtxsi%3D1%26jcpsi%3D1%26artsi%3D1%26Query%3Dking%2Bgovernor%2Breferendum

  • 24

    Klarner, Carl. 2009. State Partisan Balance 1959 to 2007. State Politics and Policy

    Data Resource. From http://www.ipsr.ku.edu/SPPQ/journal_datasets/klarner.shtml, updated

    February 2009.

    Lacy, Dean. 1998. Back from Intermission: The 1994 Elections and the Return to Divided

    Government. In Herbert E Weisberg and Samuel C. Patterson, eds., Great Theatre: The

    American Congress in the 1990s. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Lacy, Dean, and Philip Paolino. 1998. Downsian Voting and the Separation of Powers.

    American Journal of Political Science 42 (October): 1180-99.

    Lewis-Beck, Michael S. and Richard Nadeau. 2004. Split-Ticket Voting: The Effects of

    Cognitive Madisonianism. The Journal of Politics 66 (February): 97-112.

    McAllister, lan, and Robert Darcy. 1992. Sources of Split-Ticket Voting in the 1988 American

    Elections. Political Studies 40 (4): 695-712.

    Oppenheimer, Bruce, James Stimson and Richard Waterman. 1986. Interpreting U.S.

    Congressional Elections: The Exposure Thesis. Legislative Studies Quarterly 11, 2 (May):

    227- 247.

    Petrocik, John R., and Joseph Doherty. 1996. The Road to Divided Government: Paved without

    Intention. In Peter F. Galderisi, Roberta Q. Herzberg, and Peter McNamara, eds., Divided

    Government: Change, Uncertainty, and the Constitutional Order. Lanham, MD: Rowman &

    Littlefield.

    Roscoe, Douglas D. 2003. The Choosers or the Choices? Voter Characteristics and the Structure

    of Electoral Competition as Explanations for Ticket Splitting. The Journal of Politics 65

    (November): 1147-1164.

    Saunders, Kyle L, Alan Abramowitz, and Jonathan Williamson. 2005. A New Kind of

  • 25

    Balancing Act: Electoral Certainty and Ticket-Splitting in the 1996 and 2000 Elections.

    Political Research Quarterly 58 (March): 69-78.

    Sigelman, Lee, Paul J. Wahlbeck, and Emmett H. Buell, Jr. 1997. Vote Choice and the

    Preference for Divided Government: Lessons of 1992. American Journal of Political

    Science 41 (July): 879-94.

    Smith, Charles E., Robert D. Brown, John M. Bruce, and L. Marvin Overby. 1999. Party

    Balancing and Voting for Congress in the 1996 National Election. American Journal of

    Political Science 43 (July): 737-64.

    The Book of the States. Various years. Lexington, KY: Council of State Government.

    Tufte, Edward R. 1975. Determinants of the Outcomes of Midterm Congressional

    Election. American Political Science Review 69 (September): 812-26.

    U.S. Department of Labor. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Unemployment Rates by State.

    From http://data.bls.gov/map/servlet/map.servlet.MapToolServlet?survey=la&map=stat

    e&seasonal=s, updated November 2009.

    Wooldridge, Jeffrey. 2009. Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 4th

    edition. South-

    Western.

    Wright, Gerald C., John P. McIver and Robert S. Erikson. 2004. Aggregated CBS News/New

    York Times national polls [electronic file] php.indiana.edu/~wright1/cbs7603_pct.zip.

  • 26

    Table 1: Predicting Change in Democratic Proportion of State Assemblies

    (1) (2) (3) (4)

    Balancing

    Dem. gov. x Gov. midterm -0.016* -0.003 0.001 -0.001

    (2.18) (0.44) (0.07) (0.21)

    Rep. gov. x Gov. midterm 0.01 0.016* 0.018* 0.013+

    (1.31) (2.19) (2.51) (1.88)

    Dem. gov. x Not gov. midterm -0.004 0.005 0.005 0.006

    (0.58) (0.72) (0.76) (0.99)

    Surge and Decline

    Lagged Dem presidential vote share 0.034 0.014 0.202**

    (0.58) (0.22) (3.40)

    Current Dem presidential vote share 0.105+ 0.094 0.270**

    (1.77) (1.53) (4.55)

    Economic

    Unemployment change x Dem. gov. -0.005 -0.007 -0.007

    (0.23) (0.30) (0.37)

    Unemployment change x Rep. gov. -0.029 -0.028 -0.031

    (1.12) (1.05) (1.25)

    Other

    Pre-election seat share -0.265**

    (8.53)

    Constant -0.003 0.025 -0.047 0.067

    (0.68) (0.37) (1.52) (1.04)

    Year fixed effects No Yes Yes Yes

    State fixed effects No Yes Yes Yes

    AR1 model No No Yes No

    N 740 740 691 740

    R2

    0.02 0.32 0.31 0.39

    Rep gov midterm - Dem gov midterm 0.026 0.019 0.017 0.014

    F-test: Rep gov midterm = Dem gov midterm 11.4 7.4 6.0 4.7

    (p=0.001) (p=0.007) (p=0.014) (p=0.031)

    Note: Dependent variable is change in Democratic proportion of state assembly

    t-statistics are in parentheses

    + p 0.10; * p 0.05; ** p 0.01 (all two-tailed)

  • 27

    Table 2: Predicting Change in Democratic Proportion of State Senates

    (1) (2) (3) (4)

    Balancing

    Dem. gov. x Gov. midterm -0.023** -0.015+ -0.017+ -0.012

    (3.02) (1.70) (1.95) (1.56)

    Rep. gov. x Gov. midterm 0.001 0.005 0.005 0.001

    (0.12) (0.64) (0.57) (0.10)

    Dem. gov. x Not gov. midterm -0.013+ -0.003 -0.006 -0.001

    (1.77) (0.40) (0.83) (0.15)

    Surge and Decline

    Lagged Dem presidential vote share 0.005 0.008 0.05

    (0.14) (0.22) (1.64)

    Current Dem presidential vote share 0.093* 0.103* 0.169**

    (1.98) (2.07) (3.79)

    Economic

    Unemployment change x Dem. gov. -0.016 -0.016 -0.013

    (0.54) (0.50) (0.47)

    Unemployment change x Rep. gov. -0.02 -0.018 -0.01

    (0.65) (0.57) (0.34)

    Other

    Pre-election seat share -0.274**

    (9.78)

    Constant 0.001 0.095 -0.034 0.165*

    (0.24) (1.12) (0.41) (2.10)

    Year fixed effects No Yes Yes Yes

    State fixed effects No Yes Yes Yes

    AR1 model No No Yes No

    N 689 689 640 689

    R2

    0.02 0.18 0.18 0.29

    Rep gov midterm - Dem gov midterm 0.024 0.020 0.022 0.013

    F-test: Rep gov midterm = Dem gov midterm 9.4 6.2 7.0 3.1

    (p=0.002) (p=0.013) (p=0.008) (p=0.079)

    Note: Dependent variable is change in Democratic proportion of state senate.

    t-statistics are in parentheses

    + p 0.10; * p 0.05; ** p 0.01 (all two-tailed)

  • 28

    Table 3: Predicting Change in Democratic Proportion of State Assemblies

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Balancing

    Dem. gov. x Gov. midterm -0.035 -0.016 0.004 0.001 0.000 -0.006

    (1.58) (0.85) (0.55) (0.14) (0.02) (0.58)

    Rep. gov. x Gov. midterm 0.012 0.011 0.019* 0.015* 0.030** 0.019+

    (1.19) (1.19) (2.52) (2.20) (2.95) (1.74)

    Dem. gov. x Not gov. midterm -0.022 -0.006 0.004 0.005 0.009 0.01

    (1.01) (0.33) (0.52) (0.80) (0.84) (1.06)

    Surge and Decline

    Lagged Dem presidential vote share -0.051 0.017 -0.053 0.185** 0.053 0.264**

    (0.46) (0.18) (0.79) (3.12) (0.55) (3.11)

    Current Dem presidential vote share -0.024 0.101 0.042 0.247** 0.129 0.314**

    (0.23) (1.07) (0.61) (3.94) (1.26) (3.52)

    Economic

    Unemployment change x Dem. gov. -0.017 -0.029 -0.053+ -0.027 -0.017* -0.02

    (1.22) (0.77) (1.78) (1.03) (2.12) (0.74)

    Unemployment change x Rep. gov. -0.032 -0.029 -0.050+ -0.042 -0.024 -0.025

    (0.85) (0.80) (1.73) (1.64) (0.64) (0.68)

    Other

    Pre-election seat share -0.181** -0.374** -0.268**

    (3.84) (10.59) (5.96)

    Dem. Gov approval 0.018* 0.01

    (2.41) (0.93)

    Rep. Gov approval -0.034 -0.015

    (0.92) (0.49)

    Change in net Democrats 0.00 0.00

    (0.05) (1.28)

    Change in net liberals -0.001+ -0.001+

    (1.81) (1.81)

    Dem. control redistricting 0.011 0.020+

    (0.72) (1.90)

    Rep. control redistricting 0.004 -0.016

    (0.24) (1.31)

    Constant -0.161 -0.059 0.037 0.108+ -0.161 -1.158

    (1.34) (0.28) (0.49) (1.83) (1.11) (0.73)

    Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    State fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    AR1 model Yes No Yes No Yes No

    N 384 433 528 575 358 407

    R2

    0.34 0.40 0.35 0.46 0.32 0.39

    Rep gov midterm - Dem gov midterm 0.047 0.027 0.015 0.014 0.030 0.025

    F-test: Rep gov midterm = Dem gov midterm 4.3 2.1 3.3 4.1 7.1 5.6

    (p=0.039) (p=0.151) (p=0.071) (p=0.042) (p=0.008) (p=0.019)

    Note: Dependent variable is change in Democratic proportion of state assembly

    t-statistics are in parentheses

    + p 0.10; * p 0.05; ** p 0.01 (all two-tailed)

  • 29

    Table 4: Predicting Change in Democratic Proportion of State Senates

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Balancing

    Dem. gov. x Gov. midterm -0.063+ -0.043 -0.023* -0.018* -0.013 -0.012

    (1.85) (1.62) (2.11) (1.97) (1.05) (1.16)

    Rep. gov. x Gov. midterm -0.004 -0.004 0.002 0.001 0.007 -0.006

    (0.35) (0.35) (0.16) (0.08) (0.61) (0.54)

    Dem. gov. x Not gov. midterm -0.051 -0.029 -0.009 -0.005 -0.001 0.005

    (1.49) (1.11) (0.97) (0.62) (0.11) (0.53)

    Surge and Decline

    Lagged Dem presidential vote share -0.013 0.022 0.007 0.045 0.057 0.115**

    (0.26) (0.58) (0.17) (1.32) (0.97) (2.86)

    Current Dem presidential vote share 0.158+ 0.228** 0.086 0.116* 0.144+ 0.231**

    (1.95) (3.42) (1.39) (2.18) (1.84) (3.81)

    Economic

    Unemployment change x Dem. gov. -0.015 -0.006 -0.052 -0.038 -0.035 -0.034

    (0.27) (0.14) (1.30) (1.16) (0.83) (0.97)

    Unemployment change x Rep. gov. 0.008 0.011 -0.025 -0.002 -0.022 -0.024

    (0.17) (0.27) (0.63) (0.07) (0.49) (0.63)

    Other

    Pre-election seat share -0.370** -0.364** -0.299**

    (8.86) (10.38) (7.74)

    Dem. gov. approval 0.035 0.023

    (0.79) (0.66)

    Rep. gov. approval -0.046 -0.031

    (1.07) (0.97)

    Change in net Democrats 0.00 0.00

    (0.73) (0.10)

    Change in net liberals 0.00 0.00

    (0.53) (0.04)

    Dem. control redistricting 0.017 0.042**

    (1.06) (3.89)

    Rep. control redistricting 0.003 -0.011

    (0.16) (0.90)

    Constant -0.154 0.229+ 0.032 0.212** -0.093 0.049

    (1.45) (1.89) (0.30) (2.61) (0.60) (0.73)

    Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    State fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    AR1 model Yes No Yes No Yes No

    N 350 399 488 535 328 377

    R2

    0.31 0.42 0.18 0.33 0.14 0.30

    Rep gov midterm - Dem gov midterm 0.059 0.039 0.025 0.019 0.020 0.006

    F-test: Rep gov midterm = Dem gov midterm 2.9 2.2 5.3 4.5 2.5 0.3

    (p=0.090) (p=0.138) (p=0.023) (p=0.035) (p=0.116) (p=0.559)

    Note: Dependent variable is change in Democratic proportion of state senate.

    t-statistics are in parentheses

    + p 0.10; * p 0.05; ** p 0.01 (all two-tailed)

  • 30

    Table 5: Predicting Level Differences in Democratic Proportion of State Legislatures

    in Presidential Midterms

    1 2 3 1 2 3

    Balancing

    Dem. gov. x Gov. midterm 0.001 -0.184 -0.11 0.013 -0.203+ -0.132

    (0.01) (1.52) (1.34) (0.19) (1.80) (1.57)

    Rep. gov. x Gov. midterm 0.073 -0.055 -0.016 0.048 -0.064 -0.068

    (0.65) (0.49) (0.21) (0.67) (0.66) (0.95)

    Dem. gov. x Not gov. midterm 0.000 -0.06 -0.046 -0.004 -0.057 -0.023

    (0.03) (1.43) (1.44) (0.33) (1.01) (0.59)

    Surge and Decline

    Lagged Dem presidential vote share -0.125 -0.364 -0.13 -0.154 -0.105 0.039

    (0.72) (1.39) (0.95) (1.45) (0.63) (0.40)

    Economic

    Unemployment change x Dem. gov. 0.125** -0.117 -0.099 -0.065 -0.164 -0.032

    (3.38) (1.40) (1.62) (1.16) (1.59) (0.47)

    Unemployment change x Rep. gov. 0.072 0.042 0.005 0.036 0.089 0.094

    (1.52) (0.57) (0.08) (0.70) (1.07) (1.61)

    Other

    Pre-election seat share -0.043 -0.412**

    (0.55) (6.03)

    Dem. gov. approval 0.081** 0.027+ 0.036 0.014

    (4.25) (1.80) (0.48) (0.28)

    Rep. gov. approval -0.038 -0.069 -0.069 -0.036

    (0.55) (1.31) (0.96) (0.68)

    Constant -0.513** -0.319** -0.758 0.121 0.023 0.310**

    (5.18) (4.88) (1.39) (0.57) (0.12) (4.28)

    Year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    State fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

    AR1 model Yes Yes No Yes Yes No

    N 353 192 241 312 166 217

    R2

    0.32 0.48 0.46 0.24 0.39 0.51

    Rep gov midterm - Dem gov midterm 0.072 0.129 0.094 0.035 0.139 0.064

    F-test: Rep gov midterm = Dem gov midterm 10.0 7.3 6.0 2.8 5.0 2.0

    (p=0.002) (p=0.008) (p=0.016) (p=0.096) (p=0.027) (p=0.162)

    Note: Dependent variable is change in Democratic proportion of state legislative body.

    t-statistics are in parentheses

    + p 0.10; * p 0.05; ** p 0.01 (all two-tailed)

    Assembly Senate