barboudesplaces&deffains_2004

Upload: flip-lindo

Post on 04-Apr-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    1/20

    International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    Cooperation in the shadow of regulatorycompetition: the case of asylum

    legislation in Europe

    Sgolne Barbou des Places a, Bruno Deffains b,a European University Institute, Florence, Italy, and Facult de droit et Sciences Economiques,

    Universit Nancy 2, Franceb CREDES, Facult de Droit et Sciences Economiques, Universit Nancy 2, 13 Place Carnot, c.o. #26,

    c.o. 26-13 Place Carnot, Nancy Cedex 54 035, France

    Received 15 December 2002; accepted 20 July 2003

    Abstract

    Traditional analysis considers that the granting of protection to refugees is an international public

    good, and thus explains both the heterogeneousness in refugee protection in Europe and the spiral that

    has hardened the EU Member States asylum legislation from the mid-1980s onwards as the result of

    free riding in the provision of the good. In contrast, the paper considers that the heterogeneousness

    in refugee distribution is best explained by the joint product model and that the spiral of restriction

    is best explained by the common pool resource model and regulatory competition theory. The paper

    explains, and gives empirical evidence of the emergence and development of a competitive game

    among the EU Member States, and shows the result and the consequence of this upon cooperative

    attempts among States.

    2003 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    JEL classification: K3

    Keywords: Asylum; Refugees; Regulatory competition; Joint product; Common pool resource

    1. Introduction

    The current establishment of a European common asylum policy raises two main ques-

    tions. The first question is: How can an equitable distribution of asylum seekers among EU

    Corresponding author. Tel.:+33-3-83-19-26-52; fax: +33-3-83-19-25-33.

    E-mail addresses: [email protected] (S.B. des Places), [email protected] (B. Deffains).

    0144-8188/$ see front matter 2003 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.irle.2003.07.001

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    2/20

    346 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    Member States be ensured? It is the burden sharing objective. The second question is: How

    can a European legislation that is fair to asylum seekers and refugees be enacted, i.e. that

    provides protection in accordance with the standards of the 1951 Geneva Convention on

    refugees? More generally, the issue at stake is the organisation of cooperation among Statesthat, for many decades, have unilaterally decided and implemented their national asylum

    policy.

    To encompass all these issues, it is necessary to have a complete view of the asylum

    policies in the EU before the Treaty of Amsterdam 1997, i.e. before the EU Member States

    established a European asylum regime. In particular, two striking phenomena must be

    explained. First, the unevenness in refugee distribution and protection among EU Member

    States. It is crucial to determine the causes of the heterogeneousness in asylum policy and

    to evaluate whether, when it leads to a situation of unequal distribution in Europe, it is

    problematic or compatible with the development of a European asylum policy. Second,

    we must explain the causes, and evaluate the result and effects, of the spiral of restriction

    that characterises the evolution of Member States asylum legislation from the mid-1980s

    onwards. All of the EU Member States have introduced a wide range of procedures relating

    to the arrival, admission and entitlements of people wishing to claim refugee status in their

    territory. They have enacted restrictive legislation, preventing asylum seekers from entering

    into national territory and modified the procedural guarantees for the asylum application

    examination in order to restrict them. In addition, they have withdrawn social welfare and

    legal aid entitlements, limited the right to work and to education for asylum seekers and

    their families. Finally they have developed measures to encourage the return or repatriation

    of asylum seekers to their country of origin.While this evolution has been well documented in legal literature (Bouteiller-Paquet,

    2001; Crpeau, 1995; Jeannin, Meneghini, Pauti, & Poupet, 1999; Joly, 1999; Noll, 2000),

    there is a dearth of analysis using a law and economics approach. The rare economic anal-

    ysis that study the asylum issue, generally in an international perspective, assume that the

    provision of refugee protection is an international public good (see in particular Suhrke,

    1998), and thus implicitly admit that both the heterogeneousness of asylum seekers dis-

    tribution in Europe and the spiral of restriction in asylum legislation are the result of free

    riding in the provision of the good. Yet empirical evidence does not confirm such theoreti-

    cal expectations deriving from the public good characterisation. For this reason this paper

    mobilises the joint product and the common pool resource models, together with regulatorycompetition theory, in order to explain the heterogeneousness in refugee provision and the

    spiral of restriction. The paper deliberately proposes a law and economics perspective, and

    thus stresses the consequences of legislative amendments on the choice of rational actors

    via their impact on the costs and benefits of decisions.

    The paper builds upon the chronological evolution of the EU Member States asylum

    policy. Section 1 shows that after the Second World War, European States had generous

    asylum policies and welcoming legislation, and the heterogeneousness in the reception

    towards refugees among Member States was not considered problematic. This situation can

    only be explained if we consider that the good, which is to provide protection to asylum

    seekers and refugees, is not an international public good but a joint product, i.e. States couldexpect private benefits from hosting and protecting asylum seekers and refugees. In addition,

    the joint product model permits an understanding of the formation of an alliance. But, as

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    3/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 347

    Section 2 explains, by the mid-1980s, the number of asylum applications dramatically

    increased and there was a shift in asylum policies. States started competing to prevent

    asylum seekers from accessing their territory and claiming refugee status. As benefits have

    decreased and costs increased, States have started competing for a new good: to grant as littleprotection as possible. The previous alliance was thus replaced by a process of regulatory

    competition that can be interpreted using the common pool resource model. We therefore

    explain the spiral of restriction, and show the excessive efforts by the EU Member States,

    in accordance with the common pool resource model. We then compare the theoretical

    explanation with empirical evidence and show how competition was started and developed.

    In Section 3 we evaluate the result of the competitive game and conclude that it is negative.

    In Section 4 we discuss the possible forms of cooperation among the EU Member States

    likely to replace or limit the negative competitive process. We show that the many attempts

    to set out cooperative schemes between the EU Member States have failed in the shadow of

    competition. Then we turn to the current development of the (post-Amsterdam) European

    asylum policy and evaluate what the conditions for efficient cooperation in the field of

    asylum could be. Finally, we reach some general conclusions with regards to our central

    questions: What is the optimal asylum policy both for asylum seekers and Member States

    in the EU and how should such an optimal policy be established?

    2. Heterogeneousness in the provision of refugee protection: an explanation using

    the joint product model

    There have always been important differences among the EU Member States in the

    accommodation and protection of asylum seekers and refugees. Many factors explain this

    unevenness in refugee distribution. Geographic proximity to the region in crisis, the asylum

    seekers perception of the States goals, ethnic or family ties (see Bocker & Havinga, 1998).

    The differences in asylum legislation also influence the distribution of refugees and create

    differences in burden. However, the majority of refugee law specialists explain the uneven

    distribution of refugees in Europe by free riding strategies, thus assuming that the provision

    of protection to refugees is an international public good. In contrast, we deem that the

    inequitable distribution is the result of differences in legislation that come, as the joint

    product model explains, from the existence of private benefits in providing protection torefugees.

    2.1. Benefits of providing protection to asylum seekers and refugees

    Throughout the 20th century, and more specifically since the end of the Second World

    War, States have devoted a considerable amount of effort and resources to the task of

    providing refugees with international protection. Their purpose has been twofold: first, to

    safeguard the lives and liberty of people whose basic rights have been threatened in their

    country of origin; and second to safeguard their own interests by ensuring that large-scale

    population movements are managed in a predictable manner and in accordance with agreedprinciples (UNHCR, 1997). This description can help understand the goals of States which

    provide refugee protection. Such provision, whether it takes the form of directly granting

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    4/20

    348 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    asylum or the form of voluntary contributions to refugee agencies, can be conceptualised

    as producing two kinds of benefits for States: security and altruistic benefits.

    Security benefits can be expected because once displaced beyond their national borders,

    asylum seekers and refugees may constitute a potential threat to other States. According toAcharya and Dewitt (1997), security comes from the ability to control entry and exit so

    that the core values, institutions and processes of that system are not threatened. Increased

    security can be regarded as the principal benefit of managing the population of asylum

    seekers and granting asylum, because the accommodation of refugees potentially reduces

    the risk of refugees spreading the very conflict from which they are fleeing.

    Together with direct security benefits,1 States can also expect altruistic benefits. It is

    generally acknowledged that altruistic externality arises when the donor derives utility

    from knowing that less fortunate people are better off (Sudgen, 1982). In the field of

    asylum, such altruistic benefits result mainly from the incidence of provision for refugees

    on the reputation of the country. The image of a State that is protective of human rights

    is one of the major benefits that a State can expect when it develops a generous asylum

    policy. Germany is a significant example, where the right to asylum was incorporated into

    the Constitution in order to compensate for the shame of the Second World War acts. Suhrke

    (1998) also explains Western countries involvement in resettlement plans in the aftermath

    of the Second World War by their willingness to gain a good reputation.

    The analysis of the benefits of regulating and granting asylum permits the discussion of

    the nature of the good (i.e. providing protection to asylum seekers and refugees). As they

    consider that security and altruistic benefits are non-excludable and non-rival, the majority

    of specialists argue in favour of an international public good. According to Suhrke (1998),if one State admitted refugees, the others would benefit from the greater international order

    that ensued regardless of their own admissions, so refugees provision is an international

    public good from which all States benefit, irrespective of which country receives refugees.

    The consequences of this interpretation are important. Firstly, according to public good

    theory, cooperation produces positive-sum benefits which in turn create the will to share the

    burden among actors as the benefits of the contribution exceed the costs of the contributors.

    At an international level, cooperation should produce a level of provision of a valued public

    good which individual States cannot attain on their own. Public goods theory thus suggests

    that we should expect a significant under-provision of international public goods in the

    absence of central taxation and enforcement authorities. The problem exists because it isin the interest of an individual member to free ride on the efforts of others. Such arguments

    have been applied in the NATO context to explain not only the motives for cooperation on

    national defence but also to demonstrate that the members of an alliance have an incentive to

    cheat by free riding on the common security provided by other members. Interestingly, most

    studies adopt a similar vision for asylum and consider that by improving the well-being of

    those in need, provision for refugees yields non-excludable and non-rival benefits for the

    1

    Of course these benefits have to be balanced with indirect security burden as defined by Milner (2000) thatconcern the impact of refugees on distributive justice and political opportunity within a given State. Refugees

    may threaten governments and social harmony because they create serious financial and social burdens on the

    receiving nations.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    5/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 349

    community of nations. Free riding is logically expected because States rely on the payments

    of others by withholding some or all of their estimated expenses.

    Secondly, another consequence can be anticipated according to the exploitation

    hypothesis given by Olson and Zeckhauser (1966). According to their argument, it isceteris paribus the larger States whose action will make more of a difference to the total

    common effort than the action of small States. As a result, larger States will have an incen-

    tive to contribute a disproportionate share to the overall effort. We will therefore observe

    a systematic tendency for exploitation of the big by the small.2 In the case of refugees, it

    can be anticipated that rich nations shoulder a disproportionate burden of the good for poor

    nations in terms of the share of the GDP allotted to provision for refugees.

    Last, public good theory predicts sub-optimal public good reimbursements because a

    contributor will not account for the spill-over benefits that its contribution confers on others.

    2.2. From public good theory to joint product model

    We now have to assess these theoretical expectations in light of empirical evidence. Is

    the international provision of protection for refugees a public good?

    The rare contributions that use the OlsonZeckhausertest show that the granting of asylum

    fails to conform to the pure public good model. They indicate that if one ranks the number

    of annual asylum applications in proportion to the size of a Member States population or

    GDP, one finds that the top positions, i.e. the highest burdens, are predominantly taken by

    smaller States (Thielemann, 2002). Using a Spearman rank-correlation test, Betts (2002)

    sought to ascertain whether the GDP is rank correlated with the level of burden borne. Theidea is that if there is a positive and significant correlation between the GDP and the asylum

    provision as a proportion of the GDP amongst the EU Member States, there is exploitation

    of the big by the small such that the EU asylum provision is an international public good.3

    But in the 1990s, there was no empirical support for the exploitation hypothesis. Statistical

    insignificance suggests that the level of free riding by poorer States on wealthier States is

    limited and that provision for refugees cannot be described as a pure public good. The pure

    public good benefits thus fail to explain why some of the EU Member States unilaterally

    provide a disproportionately higher level of asylum provision than others, despite being

    smaller in terms of their GDP. Far from free riding, several economically smaller States

    such as The Netherlands and Denmark provide proportionally high levels of asylum, whilesome larger States, such as Italy and France, bear far less of the burden (Betts, 2002).

    How can such a situation be explained? The most convincing argument is that the pro-

    vision of protection is more likely to yield some private benefits (reputation of a major

    promoter of human rights and/or security benefits when the contributor is near the re-

    gion of instability). In light of the assessment of private benefits it makes sense to use

    the joint product theory developed by Sandler and Hartley (2001) whereby activities are

    2 In an effort to confirm this hypothesis, a number of studies have analysed the correlation of defence spending

    and GDP in the NATO context. They have shown that the United States, as NATOs largest State, has contributeda disproportionate share of the burden for common defence.3 The author assumes that the EU asylum provision is a normal good, for which the will to provide increases

    with the GDP.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    6/20

    350 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    characterised as yielding both pure public good benefits for the community as well as con-

    tributor specific benefits. This theory helps explain why the collective action implications, as

    regards the provision of protection for asylum seekers and refugees, differ from those result-

    ing from the pure public goods scenario. Disproportionate burden sharing need not occur,so the burden cannot simply be correlated with an income measurement. If a poorer State

    receives a large amount of nation specific benefits, such as status enhancement, then it may

    carry a relatively heavy burden. Furthermore, sub-optimality will be attenuated as the share

    of nation specific benefits increases. If, for example, all derived benefits are nation specific,

    then an efficient allocation will be achieved since the benefits will match marginal costs. 4

    If we decide to apply the joint product model to the asylum issue, we may therefore

    expect an inequitable distribution of refugees in the European Union as the private benefits

    differ from State to State. We may also understand that the country closest to a particular

    conflict from which refugees emanate has the greatest interest in stabilising the crisis through

    the accommodation of refugees (e.g. the case of Austria during the Balkan crisis). There

    is also substantive evidence for the claim that a countrys willingness to host refugees is

    positively related to its more general commitment to norms such as human rights protection

    and solidarity (Thielemann, 2002). This is well evidenced by the fact that the Scandinavian

    States and The Netherlands have, for many years, provided disproportionately high levels

    of refugee protection.

    Thus, we deem that the heterogeneousness of provision of refugee protection among

    Member States and the correlative uneven distribution of refugees among them is the result

    of the difference in specific benefits rather than the result of free riding. The joint product

    approach also explains why, in the decades following the Second World War, the gamewas an alliance: Member States were spontaneously contributing to the general aim of

    providing protection.

    Yet the joint product model does not offer an analytical framework that is capable of

    explaining the substantial changes that took place in the mid-1980: a spiral of restrictions

    in refugee legislation appeared. We propose to use the literature on common pool problem

    to explain this phenomenon.

    3. The spiral of restriction in refugee protection: a common pool problem

    The content of legislation not only influences the differences in the burden among the

    EU Member States but also impacts on the nature of the game. As the conditions for

    refugees reception and protection are not identical in the Member States, asylum seekers

    may choose their destination State on the basis of a preference for the country that provides

    better treatment: this is the asylum shopping strategy. We now propose to provide evidence

    4 It is important to note that the portion of the public ingredient found in joint products depends on the ratio of

    excludable benefits (i.e. State specific benefits) to the total benefits. In addition, joint products may give rise to a

    coordination game in which one of the Nash equilibria has all players contributing to the collective action. If the

    portion of jointly produced private benefits is considerable enough with regard to the total outputs, contributing tothe activity may even become the dominant strategy. This has implications for the forming of alliances if alliance

    design allows potential allies to take advantage of ally specific benefits as well as excludable public benefits. For

    example, NATO burden sharing behaviour is generally considered optimal if nation specific benefits are integrated.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    7/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 351

    and explain the development of a process of regulatory competition among the EU Member

    States asylum legislation.

    3.1. The origins of regulatory competition

    The first question is: Why did a process of competition start among Member States and

    lead to a spiral of restriction in refugee protection? As the costs and benefits are central to

    our analysis, we argue that the change in asylum policies comes from the change in costs and

    benefits of providing protection. First, benefits have significantly decreased. After the fall of

    the Iron Curtain, altruistic benefits and reputation effects have decreased. The instrumental

    use of the right to asylum granted to people fleeing persecution from communist countries

    before the fall of the Iron Curtain turned out to be meaningless. In addition, all the EU

    Member States have faced economic difficulties, recession and unemployment and the

    benefits of hosting immigrants have dropped. Secondly, costs have increased because of

    changes in migration trends. Asylum seekers who were traditionally European and skilled

    migrants have been replaced by less skilled asylum seekers coming from other regions of

    the world and of different ethnic origin. The costs of integration have thus increased.

    But most of all, the costs have grown with the number of refugees within the territory.

    The 1990s witnessed an eruption of conflicts that led to mass refugee movements, including

    some within Europe itself (ex-Yugoslavia). Table 1 highlights this major change in asylum

    seekers trends and the massive increase of asylum seekers in Europe. The number of asylum

    applications in the European Union increased six-fold from the early 1980s to the early

    1990s. However, this increase has affected Member States differently. From an EU total of5.7 million asylum applications in the period 19802000, Germany took 2.7 million alone,

    Austria, Belgium, France, The Netherlands, Sweden and the United Kingdom accounted for

    another 2.5 million while the other eight Member States dealt only with a million asylum

    applications. Therefore, as every examination of an asylum application implies financial,

    administrative and social costs, the opportunity cost for host countries became very high

    (and probably superior to perceived benefits) during the 1990s.5 In addition, the budgets of

    the government offices in charge of asylum procedures dramatically increased. In France,

    for example, it increased from FF 52.9 million in 1988 to FF 142.9 million in 1990, and in

    Germany from DM 143.5 million in 1992 to DM 486 million in 1993. According to Velling

    and Woydt (1993), the average annual cost of an asylum seeker in Germany was DM 12,000to DM 15,000 at the beginning of the 1990s, 50% of which may be accounted for by way of

    welfare benefits and 50% by way of the costs of accommodation and administration. If we

    add the social and political costs that States bear when the number of refugees increases,

    the marginal cost of asylum policy is certainly growing. Moreover, refugees have an impact

    on distributive justice and they create serious financial and social burdens on the EU States.

    As a consequence, the increase of costs has generated a change in behaviour. At this stage

    a change appeared in the game played by the States due to the emergence of a new good.

    The previous cooperative game has been replaced by a competition in legal procedure.

    5 Following Jandl (1995) and Betts (2002), we consider that the actual number of asylum seekers is a more

    accurate representation of the burden borne by a given State than any attempted estimates of expenditure levels

    that could be derived from the available data.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    8/20

    Table 1

    Asylum applications in EU Member States 19802001 (UNHCR, 1999)

    Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Luxembourg The

    Netherlands

    1980 9,260 2,730 70 n.a. 19,910 107,820 1,790 n.a. 2,130 n.a. 1,350

    1981 34,560 2,290 120 20 19,860 49,390 2,240 n.a. 3,640 n.a. 1,590

    1982 6,310 2,910 300 10 22,510 37,420 1,190 n.a. 3,140 n.a. 1,210

    1983 5,900 2,910 800 20 22,350 19,740 450 n.a. 3,040 n.a. 2,020

    1984 7,210 3,650 4,310 30 21,710 35,280 760 n.a. 4,560 n.a. 2,600

    1985 6,720 5,300 8,700 20 28,930 73,830 1,400 n.a. 5,420 n.a. 5,640

    1986 8,640 7,640 9,300 20 26,290 99,650 4,230 n.a. 6,480 n.a. 5,870

    1987 11,410 5,980 7,590 50 27,670 57,380 6,930 n.a. 11,030 n.a. 13,460

    1988 15,790 5,080 11,310 60 34,350 103,080 8,420 n.a. 1,240 n.a. 74,902

    1989 21,880 8,110 5,280 180 61,420 121,320 3,000 n.a. 2,120 n.a. 13,900

    1990 22,790 12,960 18,990 2,740 54,810 193,060 6,170 n.a. 4,830 n.a. 21,210

    1991 27,310 15,170 12,910 2,130 47,380 256,110 2,670 30 26,470 n.a. 21,620

    1992 16,240 17,650 20,070 3,630 28,870 438,190 1,850 40 6,040 n.a. 20,350

    1993 4,750 26,880 16,480 2,020 27,560 322,610 810 90 1,650 n.a. 35,400

    1994 5,080 14,350 7,990 840 25,960 127,210 1,300 360 1,790 n.a 52,570

    1995 5,920 11,420 10,050 850 20,170 127,940 1,310 420 1,730 390 29,260

    1996 6,990 12,430 7,390 710 17,410 116,370 1,640 1,180 680 260 22,170

    1997 6,720 11,790 5,570 970 21,400 104,350 4,380 3,880 1,860 430 34,440

    1998 13,810 21,970 6,080 1,270 22,380 98,640 2,950 4,630 11,120 1,710 45,220

    1999 20,100 35,780 6,950 3,110 30,910 95,110 1,530 11,090 33,360 2,910 39,300

    2000 18,280 42,690 10,350 3,170 38,590 117,650 3,080 14,800 14,000 630 43,900

    2001 30,135 24,549 12,403 1,651 47,263 88,363 4,650 10,324 9,620 689 32,579

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    9/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 353

    3.2. A new good and a new game

    Let us consider that there is a fixed number of asylum seekers and that asylum seekers

    are costly for asylum countries.6 In that case, there is a good for which the EU MemberStates compete through the designing of asylum rules: to provide as little protection as

    possible. It is important to note that this good is both rival and non-excludable. It is rival

    because lowering the number of asylum seekers enjoying protection in one country tends

    to increase the number of persons claiming protection in the other countries. The good

    is non-excludable because no State can be excluded from enacting legislation that lowers

    the level of protection granted, thus reducing the number of persons enjoying protection.

    This implies that each country is able to influence the number of asylum applications

    by changing its asylum legislation: by becoming more restrictive a country deters future

    applicants. Therefore the identified good is an international common pool resource so that

    the fundamental condition for regulatory competition is satisfied (Klliker, 2003).

    We deem that this theoretical expectation is met in practice. In the mid-1980s, States

    were responsive to asylum seekers preferences. They were convinced that asylum seekers

    were comparing the legal protection offered throughout Europe and selecting the country

    with the most generous asylum policy as a destination State. Yet, there are many obstacles

    in the way of asylum shopping and not all asylum seekers choose a destination State on

    the basis of the expected legal treatment (see Bocker & Havinga, 1998). But, if the reality

    of the arbitrage among legal norms might be a weaker factor than expected, pressure on

    law suppliers has clearly taken the form of fear of the arbitrage (Barbou des Places, 2003).

    Analyses of public opinion, together with political declarations provide evidence of theconviction that protective legislation is an attractive policy. As a consequence, the real or

    perceived threat of huge flows of migrants entering their territories gave Member States an

    incentive to adapt their legislation following the example of their direct competitors.

    The result was the emergence of a competitive game. We are not hypothesising perfect

    competition but the process of regulatory competition in its dynamic sense, as rivalry among

    jurisdictions (Deffains, 2001). The observation of the law suppliers actions shows evidence

    of the States reaction function. Taking the example of France and Germany, Rotte, Vogler,

    and Zimmermann (1996) first looked at national legal measures for asylum migration and

    their actual effects on the partner countries. They wanted to find empirical evidence for

    existing interdependence between asylum migration to France and Germany, respectively,which may be influenced by legal actions. They estimated two ordinary fixed-effects panel

    models, the number of asylum seekers in each country being the endogenous variable. The

    vector of exogenous variables included several indicators for socio-economic and political

    positions. Potential spill-over caused by national legislation was modelled by including the

    legal procedures of a country in the equation for the other one. As noted by the authors,

    the most important finding is that the French law reforms in 1991 resulted in an increase

    of asylum seekers coming to Germany instead. Despite its isolated nature, the study shows

    6

    This proposition is not incompatible with the fact that immigration of workers in principle increases the welfareof economies, due to the greater availability of a production factor, thereby shifting the supply curve to the right.

    In fact, with high unemployment and structural strains on social budgets in Europe, we simply assume that the

    costs could exceed the benefits of the reception of refugees.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    10/20

    354 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    that there is considerable interdependence of asylum policies in the EU. National legislation

    aimed at a further reduction in asylum migration contains a potential for devaluation races

    in asylum laws among Member States using a beggar-thy-neighbour effect in this field.

    This devaluation race was in fact Europe-wide. Unilaterally, each Member State triedto develop mechanisms aimed at dissuading asylum seekers from selecting it as their fu-

    ture host country and thus at redirecting the flows of asylum seekers to their neighbours.

    Member States deliberately used national regulations as a strategic weapon in international

    competition in which gains in one country were at the expense of costs imposed on others.

    Several factors provide evidence for this beggar-thy-neighbour attitude. First, the si-

    multaneity of law amendments (Jeannin et al., 1999), that tends to reveal the interdependence

    among national legislation. Second, there are striking examples of convergence within the

    content of the legislation. Three sets of techniques, invented in one country and then copied

    by the others, are particularly significant. The first took the form of sanctions imposed on

    carriers transporting improperly documented passengers (Cruz, 1995). The second example

    concerns the creation of international or transit zones in ports and airports. A third conver-

    gent evolution in Member States legislation was their incorporation of two complementary

    concepts: safe third country (Achermann & Gattiker, 1995; ECRE, 1995) and manifestly

    unfounded application, measures that permit the limitation of the access to the status of

    refugee, that justify the curtailing of the examination procedure, and that limit procedural

    rights and guarantees. All Member States have imported the three techniques into their

    national legal order. This is significant because all these measures clearly had the effect

    of redirecting asylum seekers towards the competitors and/or other States. Member States

    have designed diversion policies, and created a general market of deflection (Landgren,1999; Noll, 2000) as a result of their containment strategy. This effect is empirically

    observable: when one State implements a measure that, for instance, establishes carriers

    liability or enhances the safe third country technique, one, or several, other Member States

    become the receptacle of the asylum seekers who change destination. Therefrom the chain

    amendments can be observed during the 1980s, and 1990s (Barbou des Places, 2003;

    Rotte et al., 1996).

    4. The devaluation race as a consequence of regulatory competition

    Following the common pool resource model, the race should produce a sub-optimal

    outcome, and should lead to a tragedy in Hardins words. The competitive game in the

    field of asylum conforms with the model and we propose, first to capture the dilemma by a

    two-countries game in deterrence, then to provide empirical evidence of the negative result

    of competition among Member States asylum legislation.

    4.1. A two-countries game in deterrence

    Let us consider States which have the competence and the ability to deter asylum seekers

    by increasing the volume of administrative procedures, designated by a (i.e. norms regu-lating access to the national territory, rules organising the access to legal protection and

    legal rights and subsidies conferred upon asylum seekers and refugees). We assume that

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    11/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 355

    the greater the a the higher the bureaucratic costs to manage the system of reception and

    protection of refugees. Restrictive and non-liberal asylum policies imply costs related to

    border controls and strict asylum application examination. Note that a restrictive asylum

    policy is more costly than a liberal one. As a consequence, if a State prefers more a, it willbe less attractive to asylum seekers but the costs per asylum seeker will be higher. Suppose

    moreover that asylum seekers have to find refuge in one of the competing States: when a

    country chooses a, it does not take into account the fact that its policy imposes costs on

    other States. In other words, an increase in a imposes a negative external cost on the other

    States. The consequence is that each country will opt for a too restrictive asylum policy and

    supra-national coordination may be justified.

    To demonstrate this phenomenon, imagine a world divided into two countries, 1 and 2.

    For the reasons presented above, the countries spend resources on legal procedures in order

    to process asylum applications.7 Denote aj A as the level of legal procedures chosen by

    country j, where A denotes the set of possible legislations. a can also be interpreted as the

    costs of legal procedures. Suppose that the welfare (of citizens) of countries 1 and 2 can be

    represented by V1(a1, a2) and V2(a1, a2), respectively. Thus, the level of procedures chosen

    by country 2 has an impact on the welfare of country 1 (and vice versa). Following Marceau

    (1997), we suppose that Vj(aj, ak) is strictly concave in aj and that (Vj/ak) < 0, j= k.

    This implies that the legal procedures chosen by the States are perfect substitutes. For this

    reason, we can observe in Fig. 1 that an indifference curve for country 1 (2) is necessarily

    concave to the horizontal (vertical) axis. Moreover, the fact that procedures taking place in

    country kaffect negatively the welfare of jurisdiction j can be rationalised by the following

    argument: a more restrictive legislation in kcan hurt (in terms of direct or indirect securityburden) j because refugees find it relatively more profitable to settle in j.

    The problem of country 1 is maxa1 V1(a1, a2). The first- and second-order conditions

    of this maximisation problem are V1(a1, a2)/a1 = 0 and 2V1(a1, a2)/

    2a1 < 0, re-

    spectively. This defines a reaction function for country 1: a1 = f1(a2). For country 2, the

    analogue to the problem of country 1 leads to a reaction function a2 = f2(a1). A Nash

    equilibrium is then a pair (aN1 , aN2 ) such that a

    N1 = f1(a

    N2 ) and a

    N2 = f2(a

    N1 ). This is

    depicted in Fig. 1 in the (a1, a2) space where the reaction curves are negatively sloped. The

    Nash equilibrium pair (aN1 , aN2 ) lies at the intersection of the two reaction curves and is

    denoted by N.

    This simple case shows that the Nash equilibrium level of the actions is higher thanthe Pareto efficient level. In the context of asylum legislation, this means that the Nash

    equilibrium level of legal procedures could be higher than the Pareto efficient one. This can

    be seen in Fig. 1, where the countries indifference curves through the Nash equilibrium

    are depicted (denoted by u1 and u2, respectively). Taking into account the shape of the

    indifference curves, it is possible to observe that all the points in the hatched area to the

    southwest ofNwould improve the situations of both countries. Hence, the Nash equilibrium

    is not Pareto efficient: it entails legislation that is too restrictive.

    7 The costs of legal procedures have to be distinguished from the costs of accommodation of refugees. These

    last costs could be high but they concern only accepted refugees in a Member State. As we are interested in asylum

    seekers we focus on the administrative costs of considering the applications.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    12/20

    356 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    Fig. 1. Nash equilibrium.

    The argument behind the result of legislation which is too restrictive is that a State, when

    choosing its level of procedures, trades off its own benefits (reduced number of refugees and

    increased indirect security) and costs (forgone resources, perhaps reduced direct security),

    but does not take into account the fact that this has a negative impact on the welfare of the

    other States. There are costs to other countries that are not internalised. Finally, according

    to the model, the countries, in the absence of global regulation (or collective action) earn

    less than they potentially could if resources were properly managed.

    4.2. Evidence of a race to the bottom

    Legal scholars have dwelt on the constant and convergent restriction of legal rights con-

    ferred upon asylum seekers in the EU Member States. They have described a new asylum

    regime that reflects the emergence of a new paradigm, from a regime implementing a

    selective but integrative policy of access and full status recognition paired with full social

    rights, to one which maximises exclusion, undermines status and rights and emphasises

    short-term stay for refugees (Joly, 1999). This description indicates the existence of a race

    to the bottom. First, the actions developed by Member States have jeopardised the security

    of potential and actual asylum seekers (UNHCR, 1997). Through the use of the safe third

    country and manifestly unfounded application techniques, asylum seekers are bounced backand forth between countries until one finally accepts to host them. Lengthy procedures are

    also problematic because before their asylum application is examined and a status granted

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    13/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 357

    or refused, asylum seekers are left in a legal limbo, sometimes without subsidies. This

    situation creates difficulties for asylum seekers and for the host State.

    Second, in comparing States goal (to provide as little protection as possible) with the

    instruments used to achieve it (restrictive procedures), one discovers that the result issub-optimal. Although the array of restrictive measures may have slowed the inflow of

    asylum seekers, it has certainly failed to stop it. Moreover, in attempting to limit the num-

    ber of asylum seekers arriving and remaining on their territory, these States have actually

    damaged their own interests (UNHCR, 1997). The costs of bureaucracy have proven con-

    siderable and States, by putting the emphasis on migration control and border protection,

    have used a very high quantity of human resources (customs, police, civil servants in charge

    of asylum application examination). The systems developed to reduce costs have in fact

    generated new costs. In addition, during the competitive process, States have frequently

    amended their legislation, sometimes every year. We must underline the costs of modifying

    legislation (costs of legislative procedure, time spent by Members of Parliament and civil

    servants involved, costs of implementation of the new law, etc.).

    A third, and problematic, aspect of regulatory competition is the (non) compliance of

    certain legislation with international obligations. All Member States are bound by the pro-

    visions of the Geneva Convention, the 1967 New York Protocol and the European Conven-

    tion on Human Rights (see Bouteiller-Paquet, 2001). In order to redirect asylum seekers

    towards other countries, States have enacted measures which are not arguably in full con-

    formity with international norms (Crpeau, 1997). These potential encroachments upon the

    spirit of the international provisions are costly for States international reputations because

    part of their international image and benefits gained from hosting refugees is to be able totout themselves as protectors of human rights. In addition, when low-income countries close

    their borders to refugees, they tend to justify their actions by referring to the precedents set

    by the more affluent States. Last, the settings of containment measures can be challenged

    before national courts and important case-law indicates that States face internal criticism.

    Finally, the procedures set out by States have created side effects. The restrictive asy-

    lum practices introduced by many of the industrialised States have converted what was a

    relatively visible and quantifiable flow of asylum seekers into a covert movement of irreg-

    ular migrants that is even more difficult for States to count and control (UNHCR, 1997).

    There is also widespread agreement that in many cases, keeping asylum seekers out has

    had the side effect of allowing for the development of networks of migrant smugglers (seeGhosh, 1998; Salt & Hogarth, 2000). As a result, States are obliged to reinforce proce-

    dures and to allocate more human resources in order to fight against smuggling networks,

    and abuses of their asylum systems, which constitute significant, indirect, bureaucratic

    costs.

    5. European cooperation and efficiency at solving the race to the bottom problem

    The game is not static and institutional solutions generally emerge to solve the collective

    action problem. More precisely when the interaction among the users of a common poolresource is indefinitely repeated, the outcome does not have to be a tragedy but might be

    optimal as demonstrated by the folk theorem (Gibbons, 1992). When transaction costs are

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    14/20

    358 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    low, such self-emerging institutions imply community building, information gathering or

    sanctioning devices.

    In practice, different forms of cooperation have emerged in the field of asylum legislation

    but the many obstacles that are met can explain the recently increasing role of action at theEuropean level. We propose to first explain the development and result of the spontaneous

    cooperation of the early 1990s. Then we evaluate the post-Amsterdam evolution and the

    progressive establishment of a centralised cooperation.

    5.1. Failed cooperation in the shadow of competition

    Numerous norms enacted in the early 1990s show evidence of a spontaneous and decen-

    tralised cooperation among the EU Member States. They reflect a common will to achieve

    two entangled goals: to limit the asylum shopping phenomenon that generates regulatory

    competition and to substitute burden sharing mechanisms (i.e. collective action) for unilat-

    eral strategic behaviours.

    The Schengen Implementation Convention (SIC) and the 1990 Dublin Convention that

    determined the state responsible for examining the asylum applications lodged in one of the

    Member States of the European Community were the first moves towards limiting the com-

    petitive process. The goal of the SIC and Dublin Convention was to establish mechanisms

    which would replace the asylum seekers opportunity to choose his/her destination country

    with a legal, State-oriented determination. To this aim, the Dublin Convention laid down

    criteria that determined which contracting party would be held responsible for processing

    the asylum application. By restricting a refugees ability to choose a destination State, Statesaimed at suppressing asylum shopping and thus the fuel for competition among legal norms.

    During the same period, Member States started negotiating and discussing burden shar-

    ing mechanisms (see Barbou des Places, 2002; Noll, 2000). Since 1992, they have adopted

    various measures, pushed by active and overburdened States (mainly Germany and Swe-

    den) that try to establish procedures or mechanisms favouring an equitable distribution of

    asylum seekers. It is clear that the burden-sharing objective can be understood as a strategy

    supported by over-burdened States in order to rid themselves of an excessively large number

    of protection seekers, but it can also be viewed, instead, as a means to maintain and restore

    the States admission capacity in the long term (Hailbronner, 2000; Harvey, 1998). Burden

    sharing plans, particularly in the field of asylum, were praised because they are an insurancemechanism (Suhrke, 1998) that can help States increase or maintain the protection granted

    to asylum seekers.

    The evaluation of these cooperation schemes is not easy. Some scholars stress the fact

    that Member States have used common norms to legitimise the shift towards restrictive

    asylum legislation. Referring to the two-level game metaphor, Vink (2001) concludes that

    governments have pursued restrictive policies that are perhaps not very different from those

    that they would have pursued in the absence of European cooperation. Although they could

    avoid accusation more easily by strategically profiting from the European playing field,

    especially by shifting the blame onto Europe for the tightening of their asylum policies. By

    acting at an international level, States have avoided certain national judicial constraints andhave got around opposition from parliamentarians and NGOs supporting migrants rights

    (Guiraudon, 2000). Thus, in terms of costs and benefits (mainly the costs induced by the

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    15/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 359

    loss of a good reputation and tensions within constituencies), collective action can appear

    to be slightly positive.

    Yet, our analysis is that cooperation failed because the expected results were not met. The

    Dublin Convention has not suppressed asylum shopping and faces fierce criticism: lengthyprocedures for determining which State is responsible for processing the asylum claim,

    unclear criteria, and long periods of uncertainty, all appear to be problems endemic to the

    system. From the point of view of costs, the Dublin system of responsibility allocation and

    transfer of asylum seekers was costly because it has increased human and technical resources

    requirements. Moreover, indirect costs of clandestinity have increased since asylum seekers

    prefer to disappear rather than be transferred from one country to another. Finally the Dublin

    system has not curtailed asylum shopping.

    Concerning the burden sharing aim, the results are not positive either. States never agreed

    on a common binding rule concerning uniform admission, return, or rights granted to dis-

    placed persons. While the early 1990s proposals were ambitious and suggested systems

    of people sharing, i.e. mandatory distribution of asylum seekers among Member States,

    the measures that were finally adopted have abandoned the system of allocation of people.

    They establish a very light and non-binding system. Logically, the unevenness in the burden

    borne by Member States did not diminish during the 1990s. In fact, the Dublin mechanism

    does not provide Member States with any more protection against inequitable distribu-

    tion. Hailbronner (2000) rightly concludes that the Schengen and Dublin Conventions have

    established a special type of burden shifting rather than burden sharing (see Lavenex, 1999).

    After more than a decade of cooperative attempts, it is impossible to attest that a shift

    from costly and inefficient asylum policies to a coordinated and satisfactory collective ac-tion has occurred. This result has several explanations. First, there is a problem of collective

    action insofar as cooperation benefits are endangered by the remainder of competition

    opportunities. Indeed, Member States face a paradox. On the one hand, they have incentives

    to organise burden sharing schemes at the European level because it flows from their be-

    longing to the EU (and progressive loss of competence with regard to border controls) that

    they progressively lose possibilities to insulate themselves against inflows of asylum seek-

    ers entering their territory. At the same time, they are losing capacity to compete because

    each time a common norm is enacted another part of asylum law is pacified and removed

    from the ambit of interstate competition (Noll, 2000). In other words, unilateral actions and

    competing strategies become more and more costly as they have an impact on other fields ofEuropean integration (Barbou des Places, 2002). On the other hand, Member States have not

    transferred all competence to the EC. To a certain extent, they retain the capacity to insulate

    themselves and/or to successfully compete. In the absence of a harmonisation process, they

    may compete with their neighbours by maintaining different degrees of legal protection.

    Countries that receive few asylum seekersgenerally countries offering the lowest level

    of protectionmight be dissuaded from participating in cooperation if they believe that

    unilateral action is less costly than mandatory burden sharing schemes.

    Secondly, States have disagreed about how to deal with the collective action problem.

    The intersection of collective action problems and problems of heterogeneous interests is

    difficult because both call for solution strategies that are partly contradictory. In order tosolve a problem of collective action, it is useful to extend the range of cooperators so that

    fewer and fewer actors can potentially free ride. In contrast, in order to solve problems of

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    16/20

    360 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    interest heterogeneousness, it is useful to limit the range of cooperators. Heterogeneousness

    canbe contained through the exclusion of dissenters. In fact, the best combination is achieved

    by a viable balance between inclusiveness and exclusiveness. Cooperation is relatively

    difficult to realise if the minimum sized coalition is fairly large and if cooperation makesnon-cooperation more attractive to outsiders (Schelling, 1978). If all States prefer all other

    States to cooperate but each State individually prefers to defect, non-cooperation is the

    dominant strategy and the collective equilibrium outcome conforms to the prediction of the

    regulatory competition game.

    Unsurprisingly, as spontaneous and decentralised cooperation proved to be inefficient,

    States have favoured centralised action to organise cooperation. The Treaty of Amsterdam

    1997, demonstrates the Member States intention to establish real and sustainable cooper-

    ation.

    5.2. Towards centralised action in the post-Amsterdam era

    In the Treaty of Amsterdam, States have transferred important competence to the Euro-

    pean Union level on several matters concerning asylum and refugee law. Since 1999, the

    European institutions have a very important legislative activity and they enact numerous

    measures in the field of asylum. Although the process of setting the European asylum pol-

    icy is still very young and in progress, we interpret the current legal developments as clues

    of a new tendency, whereby Member States try to set out a soft but institutionalised and

    centralised cooperation aiming at replacing the previous regulatory competition.

    One of the lessons taught by the 1990s cooperative schemes is that cooperation can beefficient only if it tries simultaneously to tackle the causes of regulatory competition and to

    organise centralised burden sharing. On the first point, an evolution is already perceptible.

    The European institutions have enacted or proposed important norms (directives) that all lay

    down minimum standards. They deal with the reception of the applicants for asylum in the

    Member States, with the asylum procedures, with the qualification and status of refugees

    and with temporary protection granted to displaced persons. These norms all purport to

    approximate the national legislation with the explicit aim to suppress or reduce the asylum

    shopping strategy. Harmonisation corresponds thus to a first step of cooperation, that Noll

    calls norm sharing (Noll, 2000). In addition, by accepting harmonisation and laying down

    minimum standards, Member States agree on a limitation to their competitive and strategicde-regulation capacities. By approximating their legislation and recognising equivalent

    rights to asylum seekers, they pacify the harmonised areas from the ambit of regulatory

    competition.

    The European cooperation differs from the 1990s system for a second reason. It aims at

    establishing centralised burden sharing. In the frame of the Freedom, Security and Justice

    Area developments, the Council has received competence to enact measures promoting a

    balance of efforts between Member States in receiving refugees and displaced persons. Since

    2000, two important norms have been enacted. The first one is the creation of a European

    Refugee Fund in September 20008 and the second if the Directive of 20 July 2001 on

    minimum standards for giving temporary protection in the event of mass influx of displaced

    8 Decision 2000/56 of September 18, 2000, OJ 6/10/2000.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    17/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 361

    persons and on minimum measures promoting a balance of efforts between Members States

    in receiving such persons.9 The European Refugee Fund Decision favours a fiscal burden

    sharing system by creating mechanisms of financial compensation to burdened States. The

    Fund will finance actions relating to conditions for reception, integration of the personsin the host society and repatriation. Progressively, the subsidies will be allocated to the

    State bearing the major costs of hosting protection seekers. Despite its limited budget, the

    Fund represents a substantive change insofar as States have agreed to institutional financial

    solidarity. As for the Temporary Protection Directive, it is an attempt to set out a people

    sharing mechanism under the Councils supervision. Both norms represent a significant

    attempt to deal collectively and comprehensively with the asylum dilemma by acting on the

    causes of regulatory competition (minimum standards), and by promoting complementary

    measures of centralised burden sharing, both for people sharing and for fiscal burden sharing.

    A third difference with the 1990s cooperation is the role of European institutions. In

    particular, the Commission plays a central role, as it proposes and promotes the development

    of new European legal instruments (harmonisation directives in particular). In addition,

    it plays a significant role in comparing national legal asylum systems, identifying and

    promoting the adoption at the European level of what it considers to be the best practices

    with regards to providing protection to asylum seekers and refugees.

    Clearly, the current setting of a European asylum policy has important limitations. Har-

    monisation is limited to the adoption of minimum standards leaving space for competition

    among States. In addition, while the Treaty calls for the adoption of burden sharing instru-

    ments, there is no time limit for the adoption of these measures, which is another flaw in

    the system.Yet, despite the limitations, the current legal developments demonstrate the States will

    to cooperate. Regulatory competition is unlikely to disappear but it might be progressively

    framed by the action of the European institutions and could be absorbed by a political

    competition for best norms inside the European political debate. In particular, we must note

    the enactment by the Commission of a communication that promotes the use of the Open

    Method of Coordination (OMC) in the field of asylum.10 This new governance method is

    interesting insofar as it may complement the legislative works. If the OMC is put in practice,

    States will have to agree on common objectives and guidelines, establish quantitative and

    qualitative indicators and benchmarks. Then European guidelines will have to be translated

    into national policies and States will have to organise periodic monitoring, evaluation andpeer review. The Commission will play an important role in the OMC mechanism as it

    will be able to stimulate open and public debate on the national asylum policies, select and

    promote best practices and oblige States to justify their individual actions. The Commission

    will be able to make extensive use of the shame leverage in order to dissuade States from

    implementing externalising measures that shift the asylum burden onto the other Member

    States. We can thus observe that, progressively, a European asylum policy is taking shape,

    that may substitute organised, institutionalised and centralised cooperation, for negative

    regulatory competition.

    9 Directive 2001/55, OJ 7/8/2001.10 Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament on the common asylum

    policy, introducing an open coordination method, COM (2001) 710 final.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    18/20

    362 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    6. Conclusion

    The law and economics perspective adopted in this paper permits an understanding of

    the very intense legislative activity in the field of asylum in Europe from the mid-1980sonwards, and the generalised shift from generous national asylum policies to restrictive

    and deterrent asylum legislation. It also explains the difficulties met by the EU Mem-

    ber States in setting out efficient cooperative schemes in the 1990s. The paper finally

    raises the issue of the efficiency of the European asylum policy as it is currently set

    out.

    To analyse these questions, we have focused on the nature of the good and departed

    from traditional analysis that characterises the provision of protection to asylum seekers

    and refugees as an international public good. We first showed that the provision of pro-

    tection after the Second World War presented the characteristics of a joint product. As

    States expected private i.e. nation specific benefits (both security and altruistic benefits),

    the provision of protection was both spontaneous and heterogeneous in Europe. Then, by

    the mid-1980s, as the costs of asylum seekers reception dramatically increased, the nature

    of the good changed and States started competing for a common pool resource that was:

    to provide as little protection as possible. We theoretically explained and gave empirical

    evidence of the emergence of a competitive regulatory game that took the form of a spiral

    of restrictions in the EU Member States asylum legislation. Positive analysis confirmed

    that the result is a race to the bottom.

    The issue now at stake is the organisation of cooperation among the EU Member States.

    The risk of a race to the bottom is generally seen as a reason which may justify centraliseddecision making, including measures of harmonisation. So, can we expect that the current

    establishment of the European asylum policy will lead to an efficient result and is it likely to

    solve the destructive competition problem? We showed that the spontaneous cooperation of

    the 1990s failed to limit negative regulatory competition. That is why the EU Member States

    have chosen a first option to solve the problem: centralised cooperation. They transferred

    important competence to the European institutions in the Amsterdam treaty and since that

    time, European institutions have set out various mechanisms that aim to limit and frame

    competition.

    However, another option to deal with the race to the bottom problem merits further

    exploration. After having considered the paper, it may be interesting to focus on the natureof the good. While current centralised cooperation organised by States aims to control the

    result of the game, a normative proposal argues instead in favour of changing the nature

    of the game. The idea would be to identify conditions that would allow for regulatory

    competition to produce a positive result. We build upon the American debate on Delaware

    and regulatory competition in the field of corporate law. Pro-competition scholars such as

    Romano (1985, 1987, 1993) show that competition does not necessarily lead to a race to

    the bottom and can instead produce a climb to the top. As for the EU, it seems interesting to

    take into consideration Reichs view (1992) that a competition for better rules is possible,

    i.e. competition that does not fall below a certain level. In the field of asylum, such a

    change is difficult to operate, but we deem that reflection is worthwhile, that would evaluatehow the perception of the good by the actors could be modified in order to change the

    game.

  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    19/20

    S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364 363

    Acknowledgements

    Valuable comments by two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

    References

    Acharya, A., & Dewitt, D. (1997). Fiscal burden-sharing. In C. Hathaway (Ed.),Reconceiving international refugee

    law (p. 111). Nijhoff.

    Achermann, A., & Gattiker, M. (1995). Safe third countries: European developments. International Journal of

    Refugee Law, 7, 19.

    Barboudes Places, S. (2002).Burden sharing in the field of asylum. Legal motivations and implications of a regional

    approach (pp. 134). Working Paper of the European University Institute, Florence, RSC No. 2002/66.

    Barbou des Places, S. (2003). Evolution of asylum legislation in the field of asylum. Insights from regulatorycompetition theory(pp. 137). Working Paper of the European University Institute, Florence, RSC No. 2003/16.

    Betts, A. (2002). Public Goods Theory and Refugee Provision: The Role of the Joint-Product Model in

    Burden-Sharing Theory, Paper presented at the UACES workshop on Internal and External Dimensions of

    EU Burden-Sharing, London School of Economics, 27 April 2002, on file with authors.

    Bocker, A., & Havinga, T. (1998). Asylum migration to the European Union: Patterns of origin and destination.

    Nijmegen: Institute for the Sociology of Law. Published by the Office for Official Publication of the European

    Communities.

    Bouteiller-Paquet, D. (2001). LEurope et le droit dasile. LHarmattan.

    Crpeau, F. (1995). Droit dasile, de lhospitalit aux controles migratoires. Bruylant: Collection de Droit

    International.

    Cruz, A. (1995). Shifting responsibility, carriers liability in the Member States of the European Union and North

    America. Trentham Book.Deffains, B. (2001). Competition between legalsystems, a comparative law and economics perspective. In Deffains,

    B., & Kirat, T. (Eds.), Law and economics in civil law countries. JAI Press.

    ECRE (European Council on Refuges and Exiles). (1995). Safe third countries: Myths and realities. London,

    available at www.ecre.org.

    Ghosh, B. (1998). Huddled masses and uncertain shores: Insights into irregular migration. The Hague:

    International Organization for Migration, Martinus Nijhoff.

    Gibbons, R. (1992). Game theory for applied economists. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Guiraudon, V. (2000). European integration and migration policy: Vertical policy-making as venue shopping.

    Journal of Common Market Studies, 38, 251271.

    Hailbronner, K. (2000). Immigration and asylum law and policy of the European Union . Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Harvey, C. J. (1998). The European regulation of asylum: Constructing a model of regional solidarity. European

    Public Law, 4, 561.

    Jandl, M. (1995). Structure and Costs of the Asylum Systems in Seven European Countries, International Centre

    for Migration Policy Development, September 1995.

    Jeannin, L., Meneghini, M., Pauti, C., & Poupet, R. (1999). Le droit dasile en Europe. Etude compare.

    LHarmattan.

    Joly, D. (1999). A new asylum regime in Europe. In F. Nicholson & P. Twomey (Eds.),Refugee, rights and realities.

    Evolving international concepts and regimes (pp. 336356). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Klliker, A. (2003, June). Competing for international economic commons: Towards a collective goods theory of

    regulatory competition. Paper presented at the Robert Schuman Centre and Journal of Public Policy Workshop,

    Europeanisation, Global Capital, and Regulatory Competition, Florence, on file with the author.

    Landgren, K. (1999). Deflecting international protection by treaty: Bilateral and multilateral accords on

    extradition, re-admission and the inadmissibility of asylum request. UNHCRsNew Issues in Refugee research.Working Paper No. 10, available at www.unhcr.ch.

    Lavenex, S. (1999). Safe third countries, extending the EU asylum and immigration policies to central and eastern

    Europe. Central and European University Press.

    http://www.ecre.org/http://www.unhcr.ch/http://www.unhcr.ch/http://www.unhcr.ch/http://www.ecre.org/
  • 7/30/2019 BarbouDesPlaces&Deffains_2004

    20/20

    364 S.B. des Places, B. Deffains / International Review of Law and Economics 23 (2004) 345364

    Marceau, N. (1997). Competition in crime deterrence. Canadian Journal of Economics, 30, 844854.

    Milner, J. (2000). Sharing the security burden: Towards the convergence of refugee protection and state security .

    QEH Working Paper.

    Noll, G. (2000). Negotiating asylum. The EU acquis, extraterritorial protection and the common market of

    deflection. Nijhoff.

    Olson, M., & Zeckhauser, R. (1966). An economic theory of alliances. Review of Economics and Statistics, 48,

    266279.

    Reich, N. (1992). Competition between legal orders: A new paradigm of EC law? Common Market Law Review,

    29, 861896.

    Romano, R. (1985). Law as a product: Some pieces of the incorporation puzzle. Journal of Law, Economics, and

    Organization, 1, 225283.

    Romano, R. (1987). The state competition debate in corporate law. Cardozo Law Review, 8, 709.

    Romano, R. (1993). The genius of American corporate law. AEI Press.

    Rotte, R., Vogler, M., & Zimmermann, K. F. (1996). Asylum migration and policy coordination in Europe

    (pp. 131). Discussion Papers, Munchener Wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Beitrage, 96-11.

    Salt, J., & Hogarth, J. (2000). Migrant trafficking and human smuggling in Europe: A review of the evidence withcase-studies from Hungary, Poland and Ukraine. Geneva: International Organization for Migration.

    Sandler, T., & Hartley, K. (2001). Economics of alliances: The lessons for collective action. Journal of Economic

    Literature, 39, 869896.

    Schelling, T. (1978). Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: Norton.

    Sudgen, R. (1982). On the economics of philanthropy. Economic Journal, 92, 341350.

    Suhrke, A. (1998). Burden-sharing during refugee emergencies: The logic of collective versus national action.

    Journal of Refugee Studies, 11, 396.

    Thielemann, E. (2002, January).Between interests and norms: Explaining burden-sharing in the European Union.

    Paper presented for the UACES Workshop on European Burden-Sharing and Forced Migration, LondonSchool

    of Economics, on file with the author.

    UNHCR. (1997). The state of the worlds refugees, 199798: A humanitarian agenda . Oxford: Oxford University

    Press.UNHCR. (1999). Refugees and others of concerns to UNHCR: Statistical overview. United Nations High

    Commissioner for Refugees, Geneva, July 2000, available at www.unhcr.ch.

    Velling, J., & Woydt, M. (1993). Die Migrationspolitiken in ausgewhlten Industrielndern-ein synoptischer

    Vergleich, Mannheim: ZEW-Dokumentation.

    Vink, M. (2001, November). The limited Europeanization of domestic asylum policy: EU governments and

    two-level games. Paper presented at the first YEN Research Meeting on Europeanisation, Workshop IV

    Europeanisation of Domestic Policies, Siena, on file with the authors.

    http://www.unhcr.ch/