bargaining, reputation and strategic investment 45-976

39
Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment 45-976 Professor Robert A. Miller Mini 3, 2005-2006

Upload: wynter-mueller

Post on 31-Dec-2015

24 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

DESCRIPTION

Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment 45-976. Professor Robert A. Miller Mini 3, 2005-2006. Course website. The course website is: Website: http://www.comlabgames.com/45-976/ At the website I shall post: the course syllabus power points slide lecture notes - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Bargaining, Reputation and

Strategic Investment 45-976

Professor Robert A. Miller

Mini 3, 2005-2006

Page 2: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Course website

The course website is:

Website: http://www.comlabgames.com/45-976/

At the website I shall post:

the course syllabus

power points slide lecture notes

games you can download

handouts related to the projects

Page 3: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Textbook

Robert A. Miller and Vesna Prasnikar, “Strategic Play” Stanford University Press (forthcoming)

A draft manuscript is available at:

http://www.comlabgames.com/strategicplay/

We shall focus on upon material found in Chapters 11 through 15 and 1 through 3.

Page 4: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Course objectives

This course will help you to:

1. Recognize opportunities in bargaining and strategic investment. (Describe the problem and model it.)

2. Analyze each opportunity to assess its value, and how that value is attained. (Solve the model and simulate it.)

3. Persuade your colleagues to follow your advice. (Analyze the results and report them.)

Page 5: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Lecture 1Bargaining with complete information

This lecture focuses on the well known problem of how to split the gains from trade or, more generally, mutual interaction when the objectives of the bargaining parties diverge. In this lecture we avoid the complications of asymmetrically informed agents.

Page 6: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Resolving conflict

Bargaining is one way of resolving a conflict between two or more parties, chosen when all parties view it more favorably relative to the alternatives.

Alternative means include:

1. Capitulation

2. Predation and expropriation

3. Warfare and destruction

Bargaining also has these elements in it.

Page 7: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Examples of bargaining situations

Examples of bargaining situations include:

1. Unions bargain with their employers about wages and working conditions.

2. Professionals negotiate their employment or work contracts when changing jobs.

3. Builders and their clients bargain over the nature and extent of the work to reach a work contract.

4. Pre nuptial agreements are written by partners betrothed to be married.

5. No fault divorce law facilitates bargaining over the division of assets amongst divorcing partners.

Page 8: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Agenda for the lectureIn today’s session we:

1. begin with some general remarks about bargaining and the importance of unions

2. analyze the (two person) ultimatum game

3. extend the game to treat repeated offers

4. show what happens as we change the number of bargaining parties

5. broaden the discussion to assignment problems where players match with each other

6. turn to bargaining games where the players have incomplete information

7. discuss the role of signaling in such games.

Page 9: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Unions

Unions warrant special mention in discussions of bargaining and industrial relations.

They are defined as a continuous associations of wage earners for the purpose of maintaining or improving their remuneration and the conditions of their working lives.

In the first half of the 20th century union membership grew from almost nothing to 35% of the labor force, only to decline to less that 15% at the turn of the millennium.

Page 10: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

How their composition has changed

Hidden within these gross trends are three composition effects worth mentioning :

1. Employment in the government sector increased from 5% in the early part of the 20th century to 15% in the 1980s, and then stabilized. Union membership in this sector jumped from about 10% to about 40% between 1960 and 1975.

2. Employment in agriculture declined from 20% to 3% in the same period. This sector was not unionized at the turn of the 20th century.

3. Unionization in the nonagricultural private sector has reflected the aggregate trend, declining to about 10% of the workforce down from 35%.

Page 11: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Cross sectional characteristics

Within the U.S. membership is highest in the industrial belt connecting New York with Chicago though Pittsburgh and Detroit (20 – 30%), lower in upper New England and the west (10 – 20%), and lowest in the South and Southwest (10% or less).

Males are 50% more likely to be union members than females, mainly reflecting their occupational choices.

Union membership differs greatly across countries:

Canada 35%

France 12%

Sweden 85%

United Kingdom 40%

Page 12: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Industrial breakdown and strikes

Strikes are dramatic and newsworthy, but they are also quite rare:

Less than 5% of union members go on strike within a typical work year.

Less than 1% of potential working hours of union members are lost from strikes, before accounting for compensating overtime.

About 90% of all collective agreements are renewed without a strike, but the threat of a strike affects more than 10%.

Page 13: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Three dimensions of bargaining

We shall focus on three dimensions of bargaining:

1. How many parties are involved, and what is being traded or shared?

2. What are the bargaining rules and/or how do the parties communicate their messages to each other?

3. How much information do the bargaining parties have about their partners?

Answering these questions helps us to predict the outcome of the negotiations.

Page 14: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Ultimatum games

We begin with one of the simplest bargaining games for 2 or more players.

One player is designated the proposer, the others are called responders.

The proposer makes a proposal. If enough responders agree to this proposal, then it is accepted and implemented.

Otherwise the proposal is rejected, and a default plan is implemented instead.

Page 15: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

2 player ultimatum games

We consider the problem of splitting a dollar between two players, and investigate three versions of it:

1. The proposer offers anything between 0 and 1, and the responder either accepts or rejects the offer.

2. The proposer makes an offer, and the responder either accepts or rejects the offer, without knowing exactly what the proposer receives.

3. The proposer selects an offer, and the responder simultaneously selects a reservation value. If the reservation value is less than the offer, then the responder receives the offer, but only in that case.

Page 16: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solution

The game theoretic solution is the same in all three cases.

Does the experimental evidence support that hypothesis?

The solution is for the proposer to extract (almost) all the surplus, and for the responder to accept the proposal.

Observe the same outcome would occur if, right at the outset, the responder had capitulated, or if the proposer had expropriated the whole surplus.

Page 17: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Two rounds of bargaining

Suppose that a responder has a richer message space than simply accepting or rejecting the initial proposal.

After an initial proposal is made, we now assume:

1. The responder may accept the proposal, or with probability p, make a counter offer.

2. If the initial offer is rejected, the game ends with probability 1 – p.

3. If a counter offer is made, the original proposer either accepts or rejects it.

4. The game ends when an offer is accepted, but if both offers are rejected, no transaction takes place.

Page 18: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solution to a 2 round bargaining game

In the final period the second player recognizes that the first will accept any final strictly positive offer, no matter how small.

Therefore the second player reject any offer with a share less than p in the total gains from trade.

The first player anticipates the response of the second player to his initial proposal.

Accordingly the first player offers the second player proportion p, which is accepted.

Page 19: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

A finite round bargaining gameThis game can be extended to a finite number of rounds, where two players alternate between making proposals to each other.

Suppose there are T rounds. If the proposal in round t < T is rejected, the bargaining continues for another round with probability p, where 0 < p < 1.

In that case the player who has just rejected the most recent proposal makes a counter offer.

If T proposals are rejected, the bargaining ends.

If no agreement is reached, both players receive nothing. If an agreement is reached, the payoffs reflect the terms of the agreement.

Page 20: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Sub-game perfection

If the game reaches round T - K without reaching an agreement, the player proposing at that time will treat the last K rounds as a K round game in which he leads off with the first proposal.

Therefore the amount a player would initially offer the other in a K round game, is identical to the amount he would offer if there are K rounds to go in T > K round game and it was his turn.

Page 21: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solution to finite round bargaining game

One can show using the principle of mathematical induction that the value of making the first offer in a T round alternating offer bargaining is:

vT = 1 – p + p2 – . . . + pT

= (1 + pT )/(1 + p)

where T is an odd number.

Observe that as T diverges, vT converges to:

vT = 1 /(1 + p)

Page 22: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Infinite horizonWe now directly investigate the solution of the infinite horizon alternating offer bargaining game.

Let v denote the value of the game to the proposer in an infinite horizon game.

Then the value of the game to the responder is at least pv, since he will be the proposer next period if he rejects the current offer, and there is another offer round.

The proposer can therefore attain a payoff of:

v = 1 – pv => v = 1/(1+p)

which is the limit of the finite horizon game payoff.

Page 23: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Alternatives to taking turns

Bargaining parties do not always take turns. We now explore two alternatives:

1. Only one player is empowered to make offers, and the other can simply respond by accepting or rejecting it.

2. Each period in a finite round game one party is selected at random to make an offer.

Page 24: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

When only one player makes offers

In this case, the proposer makes an offer in the second round, if his first round offer is rejected.

The solution reverts to the canonical one period solution.

This simply demonstrates that the rules about who can make an offer affects the outcome a lot.

Page 25: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

When the order is random

Suppose there is an equal chance of being the proposer in each period.

We first consider a 2 round game, and then an infinite horizon game.

As before p denote the probability of continuing negotiations if no agreement is reach at the end of the first round.

Page 26: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solution to 2 round random offer game

If the first round proposal is rejected, then the expected payoff to both parties is p/2.

The first round proposer can therefore attain a payoff of:

v = 1 – p/2

Page 27: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solution to infinite horizonrandom offer game

If the first round proposal is rejected, then the expected payoff to both parties is pv/2.

The first round proposer can therefore attain a payoff of:

v = 1 – pv/2 => 2v = 2 – pv => v = 2/(2 + p)

Note that this is identical to the infinitely repeated game for half the continuation probability.

These examples together demonstrate that the number of offers is not the only determinant of the bargaining outcome.

Page 28: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Multiplayer ultimatum games

We now increase the number of players to N > 2.

Each player is initially allocated a random endowment, which everyone observes.

The proposer proposes a system of taxes and subsidies to everyone.

If at least J < N –1 of the responders accept the proposal, then the tax subsidy system is put in place.

Otherwise the resources are not reallocated, and the players consume their initial endowments.

Page 29: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solution to multiplayer ultimatum game

Rank the endowments from the poorest responder to the richest one.

Let wn denote the endowment of the nth poorest responder.

The proposer offers the J poorest responders their initial endowment (or very little more) and then expropriate the entire wealth of the N – J remaining responders.

In equilibrium the J poorest responders accept the proposal, the remaining responders reject the proposal, and it is implemented.

Page 30: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Another multiplayer ultimatum game

Now suppose there are 2 proposers and one responder.

The proposers make simultaneous offers to the responder.

Then the responder accepts at most one proposal.

If a proposal is rejected, the proposer receives nothing.

If a proposal is accepted, the proposer and the responder receive the allocation specified in the terms of the proposal.

If both proposals are rejected, nobody receives anything.

Page 31: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

The solution to this game

If a proposer makes an offer that does not give the entire surplus to the responder, then the other proposer could make a slightly more attractive offer.

Therefore the solution to this bargaining game is for both proposers to offer the entire gains from trade to the responder, and for the responder to pick either one.

Page 32: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Heterogeneous valuations

As before, there are 2 proposers and one responder, the proposers make simultaneous offers to the responder, the responder accepts at most one proposal.

Also as before if a proposal is rejected, the proposer receives nothing. If a proposal is accepted, the proposer and the responder receive the allocation specified in the terms of the proposal. If both proposals are rejected, nobody receives anything.

But let us now suppose that the proposers have different valuations for the item, say v1 and v2 respectively, where v1 < v2.

Page 33: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Solving heterogeneous valuations game

It is not a best response of either proposer to offer less than the other proposer if the other proposer is offering less than both valuations.

Furthermore offering more than your valuation is weakly dominated by bidding less than your valuation. Consequently the first proposer offers v1 or less.

Therefore the solution of this game is for the second proposer to offer (marginally more than) v1 and for the responder to always accept the offer of the second proposer.

Page 34: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Multilateral exchange

In all our previous examples, there is at most one transaction.

In such games if more than two players were involved, they competed with each other for the right to be one of the trading partners.

We now suppose there are opportunities on both sides of the trading mechanism to form a partnership with one of a number of different players.

If the prospective partners were identical, then perhaps a market would form. (But that’s 45-975!)

Page 35: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Examples of assignment problems

We now explore an intermediate case. No two prospective bargaining partners are alike, but matching any two partners from either side of the market might be more productive than not matching them at all.

For example:1. How are a pool of MBA graduates assigned

to companies as employees?2. Who gets tenure at at what university?3. How are partners matched up across

different law firms?4. How are partners paired for marriage and

parenting?

Page 36: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

A multilateral bargaining game

We consider a bargaining game where a fraction of the players, called publishers, offers royalties to another set of players, called authors, to publish their manuscripts.

Each author has only one manuscript, so can can accept at most one offer.

Each publisher can only handle one manuscript, but can make multiple offers. If more than one offer is accepted, the publisher may select any one of the accepted offers

Page 37: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Valuing job matches

Publishers are not a perfect substitutes. Authors are not identical either.

Each publisher and each author is assigned a quality index, denoted respectively by pi and aj for the ith publisher and jth author.

In this lecture we suppose the value of forming a match between the ith publisher and jth author, denoted vij is the product of the two index values of publisher and the author. That is vij = pi aj

Page 38: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

The solution

One can show that the best publishers match up with the best authors. This is called positive sorting.

It arises because the quality of manuscripts and the reputation of publishers are production compliments.

The royalty rate to authors increases with their index. Likewise the net profits to publishers is increasing in their index.

Page 39: Bargaining, Reputation and Strategic Investment  45-976

Bargaining with full information

Two striking features characterize all the solutions of the bargaining games that we have played so far:

1. An agreement is always reached.

2. Negotiations end after one round.

This occurs because nothing is learned from continuing negotiations, yet a cost is sustained because the opportunity to reach an agreement is put at risk from delaying it.

Next week we explore the implications of relaxing these two assumptions.