bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6amamef/uploads/presentations/130610_oertel.pdfcounterparty credit risk -...

203
Stochastic Modelling of Counterparty Credit Risk, CVA and DVA – with a Glimpse at the New Regulatory Framework Basel III Frank Oertel University of Southampton School of Mathematics Advances in Mathematics of Finance 6th AMaMeF and Banach Center Conference, Warsaw 10.06.2013 - 15.06.2013 1 / 60

Upload: others

Post on 23-Mar-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Stochastic Modelling of Counterparty CreditRisk, CVA and DVA – with a Glimpse at the

New Regulatory Framework Basel III

Frank Oertel

University of SouthamptonSchool of Mathematics

Advances in Mathematics of Finance6th AMaMeF and Banach Center Conference, Warsaw

10.06.2013 - 15.06.2013

1 / 60

Page 2: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Disclaimer

This presentation and associated materials are provided forinformational and educational purposes. Views expressed inthis work are the author’s views.

In particular, this presentation is by no means linked to anypresent and future wording regarding global regulation of CCRincluding EMIR and CRR (CRD IV).

2 / 60

Page 3: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Disclaimer

This presentation and associated materials are provided forinformational and educational purposes. Views expressed inthis work are the author’s views.

In particular, this presentation is by no means linked to anypresent and future wording regarding global regulation of CCRincluding EMIR and CRR (CRD IV).

2 / 60

Page 4: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Contents

1 Simultaneous defaults and total bilateral counterparty creditrisk

2 Total bilateral valuation adjustment

3 Unilateral CVA and Basel III

3 / 60

Page 5: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

1 Simultaneous defaults and total bilateral counterparty creditrisk

2 Total bilateral valuation adjustment

3 Unilateral CVA and Basel III

4 / 60

Page 6: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline I

Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio ofOTC derivative contracts such as, e. g., a portfolio of CDSs.(Bilateral) counterparty credit risk (CCR) is the risk that at leastone of those two parties in that derivative transaction willdefault prior to the expiration of the contract and will be unableto make all contractual payments to its counterpart.

Future cashflow exchanges are not known with certainty today.The main feature that distinguishes CCR from the risk of astandard loan is the uncertainty of the exposure at any futuredate. Hence, regarding the modelling of the exposure asimulation of future cashflow exchanges is necessary.

5 / 60

Page 7: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline I

Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio ofOTC derivative contracts such as, e. g., a portfolio of CDSs.(Bilateral) counterparty credit risk (CCR) is the risk that at leastone of those two parties in that derivative transaction willdefault prior to the expiration of the contract and will be unableto make all contractual payments to its counterpart.

Future cashflow exchanges are not known with certainty today.The main feature that distinguishes CCR from the risk of astandard loan is the uncertainty of the exposure at any futuredate. Hence, regarding the modelling of the exposure asimulation of future cashflow exchanges is necessary.

5 / 60

Page 8: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?

• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to aparty when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 9: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to a

party when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 10: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to a

party when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 11: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to a

party when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 12: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to a

party when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 13: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to a

party when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 14: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Counterparty credit risk - Outline II

What has to be analysed in CCR?• Modelling of the “exposure”, i. e., the expected loss to a

party when their counterparty defaults before maturity ofthe financial contract;

• Calculation of the default probability of each of the bothtrading parties (can be derived e. g. from CDS prices in themarket);

• Analysis of a dependence between exposure and defaulttime (“Wrong-Way Risk” and “Right-Way-Risk”);

• Calculation of a value adjustment on top of the “CCR free”market value of a transaction, implying a “pricing of CCR”;

• Basel III capital charge for the “value adjustment volatilityrisk”;

• Impact of central clearing through a CCP.

6 / 60

Page 15: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - The framework I

Consider two arbitrary parties who trade with each otheraccording to an underlying financial contract - “party 0” and“party 2”, say. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and T > 0 the final maturity of thisfinancial contract.

• Let X = (X(t))0≤t≤T denote a stochastic process describinga cash flow between party 0 and party 2 (or a randomsequence of prices). If, at time t, Xt is seen from the pointof view of party k, we denote its value equivalently as Xt(k)or Xt(k, 2− k) or Xk(t) - depending on its eligibility.

• We will make use of the important notation Yt(k | l) todescribe a random cash flow amount from the point of viewof party k at time t contingent on the default of party l,where l ∈ 0, 2.

7 / 60

Page 16: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - The framework I

Consider two arbitrary parties who trade with each otheraccording to an underlying financial contract - “party 0” and“party 2”, say. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and T > 0 the final maturity of thisfinancial contract.• Let X = (X(t))0≤t≤T denote a stochastic process describing

a cash flow between party 0 and party 2 (or a randomsequence of prices). If, at time t, Xt is seen from the pointof view of party k, we denote its value equivalently as Xt(k)or Xt(k, 2− k) or Xk(t) - depending on its eligibility.

• We will make use of the important notation Yt(k | l) todescribe a random cash flow amount from the point of viewof party k at time t contingent on the default of party l,where l ∈ 0, 2.

7 / 60

Page 17: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - The framework I

Consider two arbitrary parties who trade with each otheraccording to an underlying financial contract - “party 0” and“party 2”, say. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and T > 0 the final maturity of thisfinancial contract.• Let X = (X(t))0≤t≤T denote a stochastic process describing

a cash flow between party 0 and party 2 (or a randomsequence of prices). If, at time t, Xt is seen from the pointof view of party k, we denote its value equivalently as Xt(k)or Xt(k, 2− k) or Xk(t) - depending on its eligibility.

• We will make use of the important notation Yt(k | l) todescribe a random cash flow amount from the point of viewof party k at time t contingent on the default of party l,where l ∈ 0, 2.

7 / 60

Page 18: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - The framework II

• “Contingent cash flows” between two trading parties can beembedded into the model of a generalised weighted anddirected Erdos-Rényi random graph (“network”), consistingof counterparties as nodes and current exposures asedges, leading to matrix-valued stochastic processes oftype (ω, t) 7→ A(ω, t), where A(ω, t)k,l := Yt(k | l)(ω)describes a contingent cash flow between the nodes k andl, given that l will default until T (with probability 1).

• Clearing through a central counterparty (CCP) changesthis graph to a (possibly disconnected) tree.

• Notice that the permutation s : 0, 2 −→ 0, 2, k 7→ 2− kis bijective. It satisfies s s = s. (If s should permute thenumbers 1 and 2 instead, then put s(k) := 3− k.)

8 / 60

Page 19: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - The framework II

• “Contingent cash flows” between two trading parties can beembedded into the model of a generalised weighted anddirected Erdos-Rényi random graph (“network”), consistingof counterparties as nodes and current exposures asedges, leading to matrix-valued stochastic processes oftype (ω, t) 7→ A(ω, t), where A(ω, t)k,l := Yt(k | l)(ω)describes a contingent cash flow between the nodes k andl, given that l will default until T (with probability 1).

• Clearing through a central counterparty (CCP) changesthis graph to a (possibly disconnected) tree.

• Notice that the permutation s : 0, 2 −→ 0, 2, k 7→ 2− kis bijective. It satisfies s s = s. (If s should permute thenumbers 1 and 2 instead, then put s(k) := 3− k.)

8 / 60

Page 20: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - The framework II

• “Contingent cash flows” between two trading parties can beembedded into the model of a generalised weighted anddirected Erdos-Rényi random graph (“network”), consistingof counterparties as nodes and current exposures asedges, leading to matrix-valued stochastic processes oftype (ω, t) 7→ A(ω, t), where A(ω, t)k,l := Yt(k | l)(ω)describes a contingent cash flow between the nodes k andl, given that l will default until T (with probability 1).

• Clearing through a central counterparty (CCP) changesthis graph to a (possibly disconnected) tree.

• Notice that the permutation s : 0, 2 −→ 0, 2, k 7→ 2− kis bijective. It satisfies s s = s. (If s should permute thenumbers 1 and 2 instead, then put s(k) := 3− k.)

8 / 60

Page 21: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Modelling of default times

Let τ0 denote the default time of the investor and τ2 the defaulttime of the counterparty. Suppose that the underlying financialmarket model is arbitrage-free. Let (Ω,G,G,Q) be a filteredprobability space (satisfying the usual conditions) such that forall t ≥ 0 the σ-algebra Gt contains both, the market informationup to time t and the information whether the default of theinvestor or its counterpart has occurred or not up to time t. Q isa (not necessarily unique) “spot martingale measure”.

Let τ := minτ0, τ2 (i. e., the “first-to-default time”). Both, τ0 andτ2 are G-stopping times. Consider the G-stopping timeτ∗ := minτ,T. As we will see, a stochastic analysis of CCRbuilds on a consequent and repeated use of the positivefunctions x+ := maxx, 0 and x− := x+ − x = (−x)+ =max−x, 0 (x ∈ R).

9 / 60

Page 22: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Modelling of default times

Let τ0 denote the default time of the investor and τ2 the defaulttime of the counterparty. Suppose that the underlying financialmarket model is arbitrage-free. Let (Ω,G,G,Q) be a filteredprobability space (satisfying the usual conditions) such that forall t ≥ 0 the σ-algebra Gt contains both, the market informationup to time t and the information whether the default of theinvestor or its counterpart has occurred or not up to time t. Q isa (not necessarily unique) “spot martingale measure”.

Let τ := minτ0, τ2 (i. e., the “first-to-default time”). Both, τ0 andτ2 are G-stopping times.

Consider the G-stopping timeτ∗ := minτ,T. As we will see, a stochastic analysis of CCRbuilds on a consequent and repeated use of the positivefunctions x+ := maxx, 0 and x− := x+ − x = (−x)+ =max−x, 0 (x ∈ R).

9 / 60

Page 23: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Modelling of default times

Let τ0 denote the default time of the investor and τ2 the defaulttime of the counterparty. Suppose that the underlying financialmarket model is arbitrage-free. Let (Ω,G,G,Q) be a filteredprobability space (satisfying the usual conditions) such that forall t ≥ 0 the σ-algebra Gt contains both, the market informationup to time t and the information whether the default of theinvestor or its counterpart has occurred or not up to time t. Q isa (not necessarily unique) “spot martingale measure”.

Let τ := minτ0, τ2 (i. e., the “first-to-default time”). Both, τ0 andτ2 are G-stopping times. Consider the G-stopping timeτ∗ := minτ,T. As we will see, a stochastic analysis of CCRbuilds on a consequent and repeated use of the positivefunctions x+ := maxx, 0 and x− := x+ − x = (−x)+ =max−x, 0 (x ∈ R).

9 / 60

Page 24: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

All possible bilateral CCR scenarios

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Consider the following sets:

• N := τ0 > T and τ2 > T (i. e., both, party 0 and party 2 donot default until T);

• A−k := τk ≤ T and τk < τ2−k (i. e., party k defaults first -until T);

• Ak := τk ≤ T and τk = τ2−k = A2−k =: Asim (i. e., party 0and party 2 default simultaneously - until T).

Observation

Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim .

Moreover, N ∈ Gτ∗ , A−k ∈ Gτ∗ and hence alsoAsim =

(N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2

)c ∈ Gτ∗ .

10 / 60

Page 25: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

All possible bilateral CCR scenarios

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Consider the following sets:• N := τ0 > T and τ2 > T (i. e., both, party 0 and party 2 do

not default until T);

• A−k := τk ≤ T and τk < τ2−k (i. e., party k defaults first -until T);

• Ak := τk ≤ T and τk = τ2−k = A2−k =: Asim (i. e., party 0and party 2 default simultaneously - until T).

Observation

Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim .

Moreover, N ∈ Gτ∗ , A−k ∈ Gτ∗ and hence alsoAsim =

(N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2

)c ∈ Gτ∗ .

10 / 60

Page 26: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

All possible bilateral CCR scenarios

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Consider the following sets:• N := τ0 > T and τ2 > T (i. e., both, party 0 and party 2 do

not default until T);• A−k := τk ≤ T and τk < τ2−k (i. e., party k defaults first -

until T);

• Ak := τk ≤ T and τk = τ2−k = A2−k =: Asim (i. e., party 0and party 2 default simultaneously - until T).

Observation

Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim .

Moreover, N ∈ Gτ∗ , A−k ∈ Gτ∗ and hence alsoAsim =

(N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2

)c ∈ Gτ∗ .

10 / 60

Page 27: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

All possible bilateral CCR scenarios

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Consider the following sets:• N := τ0 > T and τ2 > T (i. e., both, party 0 and party 2 do

not default until T);• A−k := τk ≤ T and τk < τ2−k (i. e., party k defaults first -

until T);• Ak := τk ≤ T and τk = τ2−k = A2−k =: Asim (i. e., party 0

and party 2 default simultaneously - until T).

Observation

Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim .

Moreover, N ∈ Gτ∗ , A−k ∈ Gτ∗ and hence alsoAsim =

(N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2

)c ∈ Gτ∗ .

10 / 60

Page 28: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

All possible bilateral CCR scenarios

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Consider the following sets:• N := τ0 > T and τ2 > T (i. e., both, party 0 and party 2 do

not default until T);• A−k := τk ≤ T and τk < τ2−k (i. e., party k defaults first -

until T);• Ak := τk ≤ T and τk = τ2−k = A2−k =: Asim (i. e., party 0

and party 2 default simultaneously - until T).

Observation

Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim .

Moreover, N ∈ Gτ∗ , A−k ∈ Gτ∗ and hence alsoAsim =

(N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2

)c ∈ Gτ∗ .

10 / 60

Page 29: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

All possible bilateral CCR scenarios

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Consider the following sets:• N := τ0 > T and τ2 > T (i. e., both, party 0 and party 2 do

not default until T);• A−k := τk ≤ T and τk < τ2−k (i. e., party k defaults first -

until T);• Ak := τk ≤ T and τk = τ2−k = A2−k =: Asim (i. e., party 0

and party 2 default simultaneously - until T).

Observation

Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim .

Moreover, N ∈ Gτ∗ , A−k ∈ Gτ∗ and hence alsoAsim =

(N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2

)c ∈ Gτ∗ .

10 / 60

Page 30: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Mark-to-Market value (MtM)

The trading book of a bank is based on the principle of “fairvalue accounting” (FAS 157 (US), respectively IAS 39 (EU)). Itrefers to accounting for the “fair value” of an asset or liabilitybased on the current market price. Positions are “marked tomarket” on daily basis (via calibration of models to marketdata).

Deals are “fair” at the commencement of the financialtransaction. I. e., their net present value at t = 0 equals zero:M(0) := NPV(0) := 0. However, as time goes by, the financialtransaction is “marked to market”, implying that at 0 < t ≤ TM(t) ≡ NPV(t) 6= 0.

Seen from t = 0, M(t) : Ω→ R is a real-valued random variable(which can have a negative value if the trade is “out-of-the-money”).

11 / 60

Page 31: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Mark-to-Market value (MtM)

The trading book of a bank is based on the principle of “fairvalue accounting” (FAS 157 (US), respectively IAS 39 (EU)). Itrefers to accounting for the “fair value” of an asset or liabilitybased on the current market price. Positions are “marked tomarket” on daily basis (via calibration of models to marketdata).

Deals are “fair” at the commencement of the financialtransaction. I. e., their net present value at t = 0 equals zero:M(0) := NPV(0) := 0. However, as time goes by, the financialtransaction is “marked to market”, implying that at 0 < t ≤ TM(t) ≡ NPV(t) 6= 0.

Seen from t = 0, M(t) : Ω→ R is a real-valued random variable(which can have a negative value if the trade is “out-of-the-money”).

11 / 60

Page 32: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Mark-to-Market value (MtM)

The trading book of a bank is based on the principle of “fairvalue accounting” (FAS 157 (US), respectively IAS 39 (EU)). Itrefers to accounting for the “fair value” of an asset or liabilitybased on the current market price. Positions are “marked tomarket” on daily basis (via calibration of models to marketdata).

Deals are “fair” at the commencement of the financialtransaction. I. e., their net present value at t = 0 equals zero:M(0) := NPV(0) := 0. However, as time goes by, the financialtransaction is “marked to market”, implying that at 0 < t ≤ TM(t) ≡ NPV(t) 6= 0.

Seen from t = 0, M(t) : Ω→ R is a real-valued random variable(which can have a negative value if the trade is “out-of-the-money”).

11 / 60

Page 33: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property I

We follow a basic accounting property according to which aliability for party k represents an asset for k’s counterparty 2− kitself (and conversely).

An important special case of the basicaccounting property is given by all processes satisfying the

Definition (Money Conservation Property)Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T and k ∈ 0, 2. A cash flow X = (Xt)0≤t≤T betweentwo trading parties satisfies the Money Conservation Property(MCP) at t iff there exists k ∈ 0, 2 such that

Xt(k) = −Xt(2− k) .

12 / 60

Page 34: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property I

We follow a basic accounting property according to which aliability for party k represents an asset for k’s counterparty 2− kitself (and conversely). An important special case of the basicaccounting property is given by all processes satisfying the

Definition (Money Conservation Property)Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T and k ∈ 0, 2. A cash flow X = (Xt)0≤t≤T betweentwo trading parties satisfies the Money Conservation Property(MCP) at t iff there exists k ∈ 0, 2 such that

Xt(k) = −Xt(2− k) .

12 / 60

Page 35: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property I

Moreover, we follow a basic accounting property according towhich a liability for party k represents an asset for k’scounterparty 2− k itself (and conversely). An important specialcase of the basic accounting property is given by all processessatisfying the

Definition (Money Conservation Property)Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T and k ∈ 0, 2. A cash flow X = (Xt)0≤t≤T betweentwo trading parties satisfies the Money Conservation Property(MCP) at t iff there exists k ∈ 0, 2 such that

Xt(k, 2− k) = −Xt(2− k, k) .

13 / 60

Page 36: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property I

Moreover, we follow a basic accounting property according towhich a liability for party k represents an asset for k’scounterparty 2− k itself (and conversely). An important specialcase of the basic accounting property is given by all processessatisfying the

Definition (Money Conservation Property)Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T and k ∈ 0, 2. A cash flow X = (Xt)0≤t≤T betweentwo trading parties satisfies the Money Conservation Property(MCP) at t iff there exists k ∈ 0, 2 such that(

Xt(k, 2− k) + Xt(2− k, k))∣∣A = 0 for all A ∈ A−0 ,A

−2 ,Asim,N .

14 / 60

Page 37: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property II

In particular, (at t) such “MCP processes” X satisfy the followingimportant property in relation to CCR:(

Xt(k, 2− k))+

=(Xt(2− k, k)

)− ∀k ∈ 0, 2

Standing AssumptionAny “non-vulnerable” cash flow (i. e., any cash flow which is notaccounting for CCR) is assumed to satisfy the MCP at anyt ∈ [0,T].

ExampleThe following processes do not satisfy the MCP at t:

(i) Yt(k, 2− k)(ω) := 11A−k

(ω) + 11A−2−k

(ω) sin(t)LGDk;

(ii) Λt(k, 2− k) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+.

15 / 60

Page 38: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property II

In particular, (at t) such “MCP processes” X satisfy the followingimportant property in relation to CCR:(

Xt(k, 2− k))+

=(Xt(2− k, k)

)− ∀k ∈ 0, 2Standing AssumptionAny “non-vulnerable” cash flow (i. e., any cash flow which is notaccounting for CCR) is assumed to satisfy the MCP at anyt ∈ [0,T].

ExampleThe following processes do not satisfy the MCP at t:

(i) Yt(k, 2− k)(ω) := 11A−k

(ω) + 11A−2−k

(ω) sin(t)LGDk;

(ii) Λt(k, 2− k) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+.

15 / 60

Page 39: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property II

In particular, (at t) such “MCP processes” X satisfy the followingimportant property in relation to CCR:(

Xt(k, 2− k))+

=(Xt(2− k, k)

)− ∀k ∈ 0, 2Standing AssumptionAny “non-vulnerable” cash flow (i. e., any cash flow which is notaccounting for CCR) is assumed to satisfy the MCP at anyt ∈ [0,T].

ExampleThe following processes do not satisfy the MCP at t:

(i) Yt(k, 2− k)(ω) := 11A−k

(ω) + 11A−2−k

(ω) sin(t)LGDk;

(ii) Λt(k, 2− k) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+.

15 / 60

Page 40: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property II

In particular, (at t) such “MCP processes” X satisfy the followingimportant property in relation to CCR:(

Xt(k, 2− k))+

=(Xt(2− k, k)

)− ∀k ∈ 0, 2Standing AssumptionAny “non-vulnerable” cash flow (i. e., any cash flow which is notaccounting for CCR) is assumed to satisfy the MCP at anyt ∈ [0,T].

ExampleThe following processes do not satisfy the MCP at t:

(i) Yt(k, 2− k)(ω) := 11A−k

(ω) + 11A−2−k

(ω) sin(t)LGDk;

(ii) Λt(k, 2− k) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+.

15 / 60

Page 41: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Money conservation property II

In particular, (at t) such “MCP processes” X satisfy the followingimportant property in relation to CCR:(

Xt(k, 2− k))+

=(Xt(2− k, k)

)− ∀k ∈ 0, 2Standing AssumptionAny “non-vulnerable” cash flow (i. e., any cash flow which is notaccounting for CCR) is assumed to satisfy the MCP at anyt ∈ [0,T].

ExampleThe following processes do not satisfy the MCP at t:

(i) Yt(k, 2− k)(ω) := 11A−k

(ω) + 11A−2−k

(ω) sin(t)LGDk;

(ii) Λt(k, 2− k) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+.

15 / 60

Page 42: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM value M -FTAP I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and let 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T.

Consider the randomvariable

Π(s,t]k := D(0, s)−1

∫(s,t]

D(0, u)dΦk(u) ,

where Φk (viewed from party k) denotes a non-vulnerablecumulative dividend process of the portfolio over the timehorizon [s, t] and D(0, ·) a continuous G-adapted discount factorprocess (which both are assumed to be of finite variation).D(0, s)Π(s,t]

k =∫(s,t] D(0, u)dΦk(u) represents the sum of all

cumulatively discounted future cash flows of the portfoliobetween s and t not accounting for CCR (seen from the point ofview of party k). Hence, Π

(v,t]k = 0 for all v ∈ [t,T]. Notice that

Φk = −Φ2−k and hence Π(s,t]k = −Π

(s,t]2−k for all 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T (due

to the MCP).

16 / 60

Page 43: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM value M -FTAP I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and let 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T. Consider the randomvariable

Π(s,t]k := D(0, s)−1

∫(s,t]

D(0, u)dΦk(u) ,

where Φk (viewed from party k) denotes a non-vulnerablecumulative dividend process of the portfolio over the timehorizon [s, t] and D(0, ·) a continuous G-adapted discount factorprocess (which both are assumed to be of finite variation).

D(0, s)Π(s,t]k =

∫(s,t] D(0, u)dΦk(u) represents the sum of all

cumulatively discounted future cash flows of the portfoliobetween s and t not accounting for CCR (seen from the point ofview of party k). Hence, Π

(v,t]k = 0 for all v ∈ [t,T]. Notice that

Φk = −Φ2−k and hence Π(s,t]k = −Π

(s,t]2−k for all 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T (due

to the MCP).

16 / 60

Page 44: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM value M -FTAP I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and let 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T. Consider the randomvariable

Π(s,t]k := D(0, s)−1

∫(s,t]

D(0, u)dΦk(u) ,

where Φk (viewed from party k) denotes a non-vulnerablecumulative dividend process of the portfolio over the timehorizon [s, t] and D(0, ·) a continuous G-adapted discount factorprocess (which both are assumed to be of finite variation).D(0, s)Π(s,t]

k =∫(s,t] D(0, u)dΦk(u) represents the sum of all

cumulatively discounted future cash flows of the portfoliobetween s and t not accounting for CCR (seen from the point ofview of party k).

Hence, Π(v,t]k = 0 for all v ∈ [t,T]. Notice that

Φk = −Φ2−k and hence Π(s,t]k = −Π

(s,t]2−k for all 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T (due

to the MCP).

16 / 60

Page 45: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM value M -FTAP I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and let 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T. Consider the randomvariable

Π(s,t]k := D(0, s)−1

∫(s,t]

D(0, u)dΦk(u) ,

where Φk (viewed from party k) denotes a non-vulnerablecumulative dividend process of the portfolio over the timehorizon [s, t] and D(0, ·) a continuous G-adapted discount factorprocess (which both are assumed to be of finite variation).D(0, s)Π(s,t]

k =∫(s,t] D(0, u)dΦk(u) represents the sum of all

cumulatively discounted future cash flows of the portfoliobetween s and t not accounting for CCR (seen from the point ofview of party k). Hence, Π

(v,t]k = 0 for all v ∈ [t,T].

Notice thatΦk = −Φ2−k and hence Π

(s,t]k = −Π

(s,t]2−k for all 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T (due

to the MCP).

16 / 60

Page 46: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM value M -FTAP I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and let 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T. Consider the randomvariable

Π(s,t]k := D(0, s)−1

∫(s,t]

D(0, u)dΦk(u) ,

where Φk (viewed from party k) denotes a non-vulnerablecumulative dividend process of the portfolio over the timehorizon [s, t] and D(0, ·) a continuous G-adapted discount factorprocess (which both are assumed to be of finite variation).D(0, s)Π(s,t]

k =∫(s,t] D(0, u)dΦk(u) represents the sum of all

cumulatively discounted future cash flows of the portfoliobetween s and t not accounting for CCR (seen from the point ofview of party k). Hence, Π

(v,t]k = 0 for all v ∈ [t,T]. Notice that

Φk = −Φ2−k and hence Π(s,t]k = −Π

(s,t]2−k for all 0 ≤ s ≤ t ≤ T (due

to the MCP).

16 / 60

Page 47: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM M value -FTAP II

Assume throughout that our financial market model does notallow arbitrage and that each CCR free contingent claimbetween party k and party 2− k in the portfolio (or netting set)is attainable therein.

Thus, seen from party k’s point of view theCCR free mark-to-market processMk = (Mk(t))0≤t≤T ≡ (Mt(k))0≤t<T is then given by

Mk(t) = EQ[Π

(t,T]k

∣∣∣Gt

]= EQ

[∫(t,T]

D(t, u)dΦk(u)∣∣∣Gt

]= −M2−k(t) ,

where Q is a “spot martingale measure” (due to the risk-neutralvaluation formula). In the following we fix Q and occasionallyomit its extra description in the notation of (conditional)expectation operators.

17 / 60

Page 48: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Representation of the MtM M value -FTAP II

Assume throughout that our financial market model does notallow arbitrage and that each CCR free contingent claimbetween party k and party 2− k in the portfolio (or netting set)is attainable therein. Thus, seen from party k’s point of view theCCR free mark-to-market processMk = (Mk(t))0≤t≤T ≡ (Mt(k))0≤t<T is then given by

Mk(t) = EQ[Π

(t,T]k

∣∣∣Gt

]= EQ

[∫(t,T]

D(t, u)dΦk(u)∣∣∣Gt

]= −M2−k(t) ,

where Q is a “spot martingale measure” (due to the risk-neutralvaluation formula). In the following we fix Q and occasionallyomit its extra description in the notation of (conditional)expectation operators.

17 / 60

Page 49: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

The main CCR building blocks

Π(t,u]k = −Π

(t,u]2−k Random CCR free cumulative cash

flow from the claim in (t, u], discountedto time t – seen from k’s point of view

Mk(t) = EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt] Random NPV (or MtM) of Π

(t,u]k – repre-

= −M2−k(t) sented as conditional expectationw.r.t. Q, given the “information” Gt

0 ≤ Rk < 1 k’s (random) recovery rate; i. e., theportion of the payoff from the MtMpaid by party k to party 2− k incase of k’s default

0 < LGDk := 1− Rk ≤ 1 k’s (random) Loss Given DefaultD(t, u) := D(0, u)/D(0, t) discount factor at time t for time u > t

(can be random)

18 / 60

Page 50: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

The main CCR building blocks

Π(t,u]k = −Π

(t,u]2−k Random CCR free cumulative cash

flow from the claim in (t, u], discountedto time t – seen from k’s point of view

Mk(t) = EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt] Random NPV (or MtM) of Π

(t,u]k – repre-

= −M2−k(t) sented as conditional expectationw.r.t. Q, given the “information” Gt

0 ≤ Rk < 1 k’s (random) recovery rate; i. e., theportion of the payoff from the MtMpaid by party k to party 2− k incase of k’s default

0 < LGDk := 1− Rk ≤ 1 k’s (random) Loss Given DefaultD(t, u) := D(0, u)/D(0, t) discount factor at time t for time u > t

(can be random)

18 / 60

Page 51: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

The main CCR building blocks

Π(t,u]k = −Π

(t,u]2−k Random CCR free cumulative cash

flow from the claim in (t, u], discountedto time t – seen from k’s point of view

Mk(t) = EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt] Random NPV (or MtM) of Π

(t,u]k – repre-

= −M2−k(t) sented as conditional expectationw.r.t. Q, given the “information” Gt

0 ≤ Rk < 1 k’s (random) recovery rate; i. e., theportion of the payoff from the MtMpaid by party k to party 2− k incase of k’s default

0 < LGDk := 1− Rk ≤ 1 k’s (random) Loss Given DefaultD(t, u) := D(0, u)/D(0, t) discount factor at time t for time u > t

(can be random)

18 / 60

Page 52: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

The main CCR building blocks

Π(t,u]k = −Π

(t,u]2−k Random CCR free cumulative cash

flow from the claim in (t, u], discountedto time t – seen from k’s point of view

Mk(t) = EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt] Random NPV (or MtM) of Π

(t,u]k – repre-

= −M2−k(t) sented as conditional expectationw.r.t. Q, given the “information” Gt

0 ≤ Rk < 1 k’s (random) recovery rate; i. e., theportion of the payoff from the MtMpaid by party k to party 2− k incase of k’s default

0 < LGDk := 1− Rk ≤ 1 k’s (random) Loss Given Default

D(t, u) := D(0, u)/D(0, t) discount factor at time t for time u > t(can be random)

18 / 60

Page 53: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

The main CCR building blocks

Π(t,u]k = −Π

(t,u]2−k Random CCR free cumulative cash

flow from the claim in (t, u], discountedto time t – seen from k’s point of view

Mk(t) = EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt] Random NPV (or MtM) of Π

(t,u]k – repre-

= −M2−k(t) sented as conditional expectationw.r.t. Q, given the “information” Gt

0 ≤ Rk < 1 k’s (random) recovery rate; i. e., theportion of the payoff from the MtMpaid by party k to party 2− k incase of k’s default

0 < LGDk := 1− Rk ≤ 1 k’s (random) Loss Given DefaultD(t, u) := D(0, u)/D(0, t) discount factor at time t for time u > t

(can be random)

18 / 60

Page 54: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims I

Defaultable claims can be valued by interpreting them asportfolios of claims between non-defaultable counterpartiesincluding the riskless claim and mutual default protectioncontracts. Let k ∈ 0, 2. Seen e. g. from the point of view ofparty k the latter says:

Party k sells to party 2− k default protection on party 2− kcontingent to an amount specified by an ISDA close-out rule.

Let t ∈ [0,T] such that ]]t, τ∗]] 6= ∅. Let• Mt(k) be the mark-to-market value to party k in case both,

party k and party 2− k do not default until T;• CVAt(k | 2− k) be the value of default protection that party k

sells to party 2− k contingent on the default of party 2− k.

19 / 60

Page 55: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims I

Defaultable claims can be valued by interpreting them asportfolios of claims between non-defaultable counterpartiesincluding the riskless claim and mutual default protectioncontracts. Let k ∈ 0, 2. Seen e. g. from the point of view ofparty k the latter says:

Party k sells to party 2− k default protection on party 2− kcontingent to an amount specified by an ISDA close-out rule.Let t ∈ [0,T] such that ]]t, τ∗]] 6= ∅. Let• Mt(k) be the mark-to-market value to party k in case both,

party k and party 2− k do not default until T;• CVAt(k | 2− k) be the value of default protection that party k

sells to party 2− k contingent on the default of party 2− k.

19 / 60

Page 56: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k.

Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k) to start a deal with 2− k .

20 / 60

Page 57: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k.

Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k) to start a deal with 2− k .

20 / 60

Page 58: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded!

Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k) to start a deal with 2− k .

20 / 60

Page 59: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k) to start a deal with 2− k .

20 / 60

Page 60: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k) to start a deal with 2− k .

20 / 60

Page 61: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

2− k rejects and requires Mt(k)+CVAt(2− k | k) instead .

20 / 60

Page 62: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

−(Mt(k) + CVAt(2− k | k)

)?

20 / 60

Page 63: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k)+ CVAt(2− k | k)−CVAt(k | 2− k), i. e.,

20 / 60

Page 64: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

k offers a payment of Mt(k)−(CVAt(k | 2−k)−CVAt(2−k | k)

)=: Vt(k) .

20 / 60

Page 65: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

−Vt(k) = −(

Mt(k)−(CVAt(k | 2−k)−CVAt(2−k | k)

)) (!)= Vt(2−k) ;

Hence, the deal between k and 2− k is agreed!

20 / 60

Page 66: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Valuation of defaultable claims II

At t party k requires a payment of the “CCR risk premium”CVAt(k | 2− k) from party 2− k to be compensated for the risk ofa default of party 2− k. Conversely, party 2− k requires apayment of CVAt(2− k | k) from party k to be compensated forthe risk of a default of party k. Note that Asim 6= ∅ is not explicitlyexcluded! Therefore, given the MCP party k reports at t the“bilaterally CCR-adjusted” value (defined as “fair value” in FAS157):

−Vt(k) = −(

Mt(k)−(CVAt(k | 2−k)−CVAt(2−k | k)

)) (!)= Vt(2−k) ;

Hence, the deal between k and 2− k is agreed!

20 / 60

Page 67: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice I

Suppose, party k defaults (first).

The surviving party 2− k should then evaluate all terminatedtransactions to claim for at least a partial reimbursement (afterthe application of “netting rules”) to fix the transactions(including the collateral).

In order to maintain its market position, party k enters into asimilar financial contract with another counterparty.

Since the market position of k is unchanged after replacing thecontract, the loss is determined by the contract’s “replacementvalue” at (or shortly after) τk. In general, the partialreimbursement to party 2− k involves a payment of(100 LGDk)% of the “replacement value” at (or shortly after) τk.

21 / 60

Page 68: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice I

Suppose, party k defaults (first).

The surviving party 2− k should then evaluate all terminatedtransactions to claim for at least a partial reimbursement (afterthe application of “netting rules”) to fix the transactions(including the collateral).

In order to maintain its market position, party k enters into asimilar financial contract with another counterparty.

Since the market position of k is unchanged after replacing thecontract, the loss is determined by the contract’s “replacementvalue” at (or shortly after) τk. In general, the partialreimbursement to party 2− k involves a payment of(100 LGDk)% of the “replacement value” at (or shortly after) τk.

21 / 60

Page 69: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice I

Suppose, party k defaults (first).

The surviving party 2− k should then evaluate all terminatedtransactions to claim for at least a partial reimbursement (afterthe application of “netting rules”) to fix the transactions(including the collateral).

In order to maintain its market position, party k enters into asimilar financial contract with another counterparty.

Since the market position of k is unchanged after replacing thecontract, the loss is determined by the contract’s “replacementvalue” at (or shortly after) τk. In general, the partialreimbursement to party 2− k involves a payment of(100 LGDk)% of the “replacement value” at (or shortly after) τk.

21 / 60

Page 70: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice I

Suppose, party k defaults (first).

The surviving party 2− k should then evaluate all terminatedtransactions to claim for at least a partial reimbursement (afterthe application of “netting rules”) to fix the transactions(including the collateral).

In order to maintain its market position, party k enters into asimilar financial contract with another counterparty.

Since the market position of k is unchanged after replacing thecontract, the loss is determined by the contract’s “replacementvalue” at (or shortly after) τk.

In general, the partialreimbursement to party 2− k involves a payment of(100 LGDk)% of the “replacement value” at (or shortly after) τk.

21 / 60

Page 71: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice I

Suppose, party k defaults (first).

The surviving party 2− k should then evaluate all terminatedtransactions to claim for at least a partial reimbursement (afterthe application of “netting rules”) to fix the transactions(including the collateral).

In order to maintain its market position, party k enters into asimilar financial contract with another counterparty.

Since the market position of k is unchanged after replacing thecontract, the loss is determined by the contract’s “replacementvalue” at (or shortly after) τk. In general, the partialreimbursement to party 2− k involves a payment of(100 LGDk)% of the “replacement value” at (or shortly after) τk.

21 / 60

Page 72: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice II

This process is known as “close-out”. The ISDA MasterAgreement defines the term “close-out amount” to be theamount of the losses or costs of the surviving party 2− k thatwould incur by replacement or provision of an economicequivalent. To this end, ISDA introduced so called “close-outrules”.

This leads us to the introduction of a useful definition whichgeneralises the ISDA close-out approach (as we will see verysoon).

22 / 60

Page 73: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice II

This process is known as “close-out”. The ISDA MasterAgreement defines the term “close-out amount” to be theamount of the losses or costs of the surviving party 2− k thatwould incur by replacement or provision of an economicequivalent. To this end, ISDA introduced so called “close-outrules”.

This leads us to the introduction of a useful definition whichgeneralises the ISDA close-out approach (as we will see verysoon).

22 / 60

Page 74: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice III

Definition (Generalised close-out cash flow)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and f , g : [0, 1]× R+ × R+ → R. Let Hk be thestochastic process (seen from the viewpoint of party k), definedas

Hk(t) := f(LGD2−k, (M2−k(t))−, (M2−k(t))+

)11A−

2−k

− f(LGDk, (Mk(t))−, (Mk(t))+

)11A−

k

+ g(LGD2−k, (M2−k(t))−, (M2−k(t))+

)11Asim

− g(LGDk, (Mk(t))−, (Mk(t))+

)11Asim

where 0 ≤ t ≤ T. If Hk(T) = 0, then Hk is called a (symmetric)generalised close-out cash flow.

23 / 60

Page 75: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice IV

Notice that - by construction - a generalised close-out cashflowalready satisfies the MCP (due to its symmetry!) and Hk11N ≡ 0.

Further important pieces of notation:Let τ : Ω −→ R+ ∪ ∞ be an arbitrary random “time” (e. g., astopping time) and X : R+ × Ω −→ R a (real-valued) stochasticprocess. On τ <∞ the random variable Xτ : Ω −→ R isdefined through

Xτ (ω) := Xτ(ω)(ω) = X(τ(ω), ω) .

Suppose that Ω \ N 6= ∅. Choose ω ∈ Ω \ N. Given the -simplifying - assumption that there is no strictly positive marginperiod of risk, a non-zero close-out has to be settled atτ∗(ω) = minτ0(ω), τ2(ω),T. For simplicity, let us also assumethat no collateral is exchanged between party k and party 2− k(until τ∗).

24 / 60

Page 76: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice IV

Notice that - by construction - a generalised close-out cashflowalready satisfies the MCP (due to its symmetry!) and Hk11N ≡ 0.Further important pieces of notation:

Let τ : Ω −→ R+ ∪ ∞ be an arbitrary random “time” (e. g., astopping time) and X : R+ × Ω −→ R a (real-valued) stochasticprocess. On τ <∞ the random variable Xτ : Ω −→ R isdefined through

Xτ (ω) := Xτ(ω)(ω) = X(τ(ω), ω) .

Suppose that Ω \ N 6= ∅. Choose ω ∈ Ω \ N. Given the -simplifying - assumption that there is no strictly positive marginperiod of risk, a non-zero close-out has to be settled atτ∗(ω) = minτ0(ω), τ2(ω),T. For simplicity, let us also assumethat no collateral is exchanged between party k and party 2− k(until τ∗).

24 / 60

Page 77: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice IV

Notice that - by construction - a generalised close-out cashflowalready satisfies the MCP (due to its symmetry!) and Hk11N ≡ 0.Further important pieces of notation:Let τ : Ω −→ R+ ∪ ∞ be an arbitrary random “time” (e. g., astopping time) and X : R+ × Ω −→ R a (real-valued) stochasticprocess. On τ <∞ the random variable Xτ : Ω −→ R isdefined through

Xτ (ω) := Xτ(ω)(ω) = X(τ(ω), ω) .

Suppose that Ω \ N 6= ∅. Choose ω ∈ Ω \ N. Given the -simplifying - assumption that there is no strictly positive marginperiod of risk, a non-zero close-out has to be settled atτ∗(ω) = minτ0(ω), τ2(ω),T. For simplicity, let us also assumethat no collateral is exchanged between party k and party 2− k(until τ∗).

24 / 60

Page 78: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CCR - Closing out practice IV

Notice that - by construction - a generalised close-out cashflowalready satisfies the MCP (due to its symmetry!) and Hk11N ≡ 0.Further important pieces of notation:Let τ : Ω −→ R+ ∪ ∞ be an arbitrary random “time” (e. g., astopping time) and X : R+ × Ω −→ R a (real-valued) stochasticprocess. On τ <∞ the random variable Xτ : Ω −→ R isdefined through

Xτ (ω) := Xτ(ω)(ω) = X(τ(ω), ω) .

Suppose that Ω \ N 6= ∅. Choose ω ∈ Ω \ N. Given the -simplifying - assumption that there is no strictly positive marginperiod of risk, a non-zero close-out has to be settled atτ∗(ω) = minτ0(ω), τ2(ω),T. For simplicity, let us also assumethat no collateral is exchanged between party k and party 2− k(until τ∗).

24 / 60

Page 79: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

1 Simultaneous defaults and total bilateral counterparty creditrisk

2 Total bilateral valuation adjustment

3 Unilateral CVA and Basel III

25 / 60

Page 80: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out I

In the following we fix a very important building block which willappear repeatedly. It plays a fundamental role in ISDA’s CCRfree close-out rule. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and 0 ≤ t ≤ T. We put

Λk(t) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+

(!)= f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(t))−, (M2−k(t))+)

where f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ for all

(l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+ (why?). Notice that Λk(T)(!)= 0.

26 / 60

Page 81: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out I

In the following we fix a very important building block which willappear repeatedly. It plays a fundamental role in ISDA’s CCRfree close-out rule. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and 0 ≤ t ≤ T. We put

Λk(t) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+

(!)= f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(t))−, (M2−k(t))+)

where f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ for all

(l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+

(why?). Notice that Λk(T)(!)= 0.

26 / 60

Page 82: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out I

In the following we fix a very important building block which willappear repeatedly. It plays a fundamental role in ISDA’s CCRfree close-out rule. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and 0 ≤ t ≤ T. We put

Λk(t) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+

(!)= f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(t))−, (M2−k(t))+)

where f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ for all

(l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+ (why?).

Notice that Λk(T)(!)= 0.

26 / 60

Page 83: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out I

In the following we fix a very important building block which willappear repeatedly. It plays a fundamental role in ISDA’s CCRfree close-out rule. Let k ∈ 0, 2 and 0 ≤ t ≤ T. We put

Λk(t) := Mk(t)− LGD2−k(Mk(t))+

(!)= f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(t))−, (M2−k(t))+)

where f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ for all

(l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+ (why?). Notice that Λk(T)(!)= 0.

26 / 60

Page 84: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out II

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Next, we will give a precise representation of thegeneralised close-out cash flow random variable Hk(τ

∗) (seenfrom the viewpoint of party k), if both parties “symmetrically”apply the same ISDA close-out rule.

To this end, recall that for all k ∈ 0, 2 we always have

Hk(τ∗)X= Hk(τ

∗)11A0− + Hk(τ∗)11A2− + Hk(τ

∗)11Asim ,

since no non-zero close-out is required if both parties do notdefault strictly before T. In fact, by construction, we haveHk(τ

∗)11N = Hk(T)11N = 0 X= H2−k(τ∗)11N for all k ∈ 0, 2.

27 / 60

Page 85: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out II

Let k ∈ 0, 2. Next, we will give a precise representation of thegeneralised close-out cash flow random variable Hk(τ

∗) (seenfrom the viewpoint of party k), if both parties “symmetrically”apply the same ISDA close-out rule.

To this end, recall that for all k ∈ 0, 2 we always have

Hk(τ∗)X= Hk(τ

∗)11A0− + Hk(τ∗)11A2− + Hk(τ

∗)11Asim ,

since no non-zero close-out is required if both parties do notdefault strictly before T. In fact, by construction, we haveHk(τ

∗)11N = Hk(T)11N = 0 X= H2−k(τ∗)11N for all k ∈ 0, 2.

27 / 60

Page 86: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly, suppose A−2−k 6= ∅. Let ω ∈ A−2−k. Seenfrom the viewpoint of party k the (symmetrically) bipartite ISDACCR free close-out rule (in a given netting set) is reflected inthe following table:

Mk(τ2−k)(ω) > 0 Mk(τ2−k)(ω) ≤ 0Party k receives R2−k(ω) ·Mk(τ2−k)(ω) 0from party 2− kParty k pays to 0 −Mk(τ2−k)(ω)party 2− k

Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T. Let Hk(t) := Ht(k, 2− k) denote the randomamount of the close-out cash flow at t seen from the viewpointof party k. Since in any case A−2−k ⊆ τ2−k = τ∗ (and 11∅ = 0)the above table shows that in fact Hk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k = Λk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k ,

which is equivalent to:11A−

2−kHk(τ

∗) = 11A−2−k

(R2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+−(−Mk(τ∗))+

) X= 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗) .

28 / 60

Page 87: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly, suppose A−2−k 6= ∅. Let ω ∈ A−2−k. Seenfrom the viewpoint of party k the (symmetrically) bipartite ISDACCR free close-out rule (in a given netting set) is reflected inthe following table:

Mk(τ2−k)(ω) > 0 Mk(τ2−k)(ω) ≤ 0Party k receives R2−k(ω) ·Mk(τ2−k)(ω) 0from party 2− kParty k pays to 0 −Mk(τ2−k)(ω)party 2− k

Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T. Let Hk(t) := Ht(k, 2− k) denote the randomamount of the close-out cash flow at t seen from the viewpointof party k. Since in any case A−2−k ⊆ τ2−k = τ∗ (and 11∅ = 0)the above table shows that in fact Hk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k = Λk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k ,

which is equivalent to:

11A−2−k

Hk(τ∗) = 11A−

2−k

(R2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+−(−Mk(τ∗))+

) X= 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗) .

28 / 60

Page 88: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly, suppose A−2−k 6= ∅. Let ω ∈ A−2−k. Seenfrom the viewpoint of party k the (symmetrically) bipartite ISDACCR free close-out rule (in a given netting set) is reflected inthe following table:

Mk(τ2−k)(ω) > 0 Mk(τ2−k)(ω) ≤ 0Party k receives R2−k(ω) ·Mk(τ2−k)(ω) 0from party 2− kParty k pays to 0 −Mk(τ2−k)(ω)party 2− k

Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T. Let Hk(t) := Ht(k, 2− k) denote the randomamount of the close-out cash flow at t seen from the viewpointof party k. Since in any case A−2−k ⊆ τ2−k = τ∗ (and 11∅ = 0)the above table shows that in fact Hk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k = Λk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k ,

which is equivalent to:11A−

2−kHk(τ

∗) = 11A−2−k

(R2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+−(−Mk(τ∗))+

)

X= 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗) .

28 / 60

Page 89: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly, suppose A−2−k 6= ∅. Let ω ∈ A−2−k. Seenfrom the viewpoint of party k the (symmetrically) bipartite ISDACCR free close-out rule (in a given netting set) is reflected inthe following table:

Mk(τ2−k)(ω) > 0 Mk(τ2−k)(ω) ≤ 0Party k receives R2−k(ω) ·Mk(τ2−k)(ω) 0from party 2− kParty k pays to 0 −Mk(τ2−k)(ω)party 2− k

Let 0 ≤ t ≤ T. Let Hk(t) := Ht(k, 2− k) denote the randomamount of the close-out cash flow at t seen from the viewpointof party k. Since in any case A−2−k ⊆ τ2−k = τ∗ (and 11∅ = 0)the above table shows that in fact Hk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k = Λk(τ

∗)∣∣A−2−k ,

which is equivalent to:11A−

2−kHk(τ

∗) = 11A−2−k

(R2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+−(−Mk(τ∗))+

) X= 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗) .

28 / 60

Page 90: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out II

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and suppose now that A−k 6= ∅. Let ω ∈ A−k . Seenfrom the viewpoint of party 2− k the (symmetrically) bipartiteISDA CCR free close-out rule (in a given netting set) isreflected in the following table:

M2−k(τk)(ω) > 0 M2−k(τk)(ω) ≤ 0Party 2− k receives Rk(ω) ·M2−k(τk)(ω) 0from party kParty 2− k pays to 0 −M2−k(τk)(ω)party k

Hence,

11A−k

H2−k(τ∗) = 11A−

k

(Rk(M2−k(τ

∗))+−(−M2−k(τ∗))+

)= 11A−

kΛ2−k(τ

∗) .

29 / 60

Page 91: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IIIObserve that H2−k(τ

∗) is seen from the viewpoint of party 2− k.Hence, a strict implication of our basic accounting property andthe MCP again implies the following important

ObservationFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly let us assume that there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., Asim = ∅). Then the ISDA CCR freeclose-out cash flow random variable at τ∗ seen from the pointof view of party k is given by Fk(τ

∗), where

Fk(τ∗) := 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗)− 11A−k

Λ2−k(τ∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

− 11A−k

M2−k(τ∗) + 11A−

2−kMk(τ

∗)

(MCP)= 11A−

kLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11A−2−k

LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ (11A−0 ∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗).

30 / 60

Page 92: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IIIObserve that H2−k(τ

∗) is seen from the viewpoint of party 2− k.Hence, a strict implication of our basic accounting property andthe MCP again implies the following important

ObservationFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly let us assume that there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., Asim = ∅). Then the ISDA CCR freeclose-out cash flow random variable at τ∗ seen from the pointof view of party k is given by Fk(τ

∗), where

Fk(τ∗) := 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗)− 11A−k

Λ2−k(τ∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

− 11A−k

M2−k(τ∗) + 11A−

2−kMk(τ

∗)

(MCP)= 11A−

kLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11A−2−k

LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ (11A−0 ∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗).

30 / 60

Page 93: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IIIObserve that H2−k(τ

∗) is seen from the viewpoint of party 2− k.Hence, a strict implication of our basic accounting property andthe MCP again implies the following important

ObservationFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly let us assume that there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., Asim = ∅). Then the ISDA CCR freeclose-out cash flow random variable at τ∗ seen from the pointof view of party k is given by Fk(τ

∗), where

Fk(τ∗) := 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗)− 11A−k

Λ2−k(τ∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

− 11A−k

M2−k(τ∗) + 11A−

2−kMk(τ

∗)

(MCP)= 11A−

kLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11A−2−k

LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ (11A−0 ∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗).

30 / 60

Page 94: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IIIObserve that H2−k(τ

∗) is seen from the viewpoint of party 2− k.Hence, a strict implication of our basic accounting property andthe MCP again implies the following important

ObservationFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly let us assume that there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., Asim = ∅). Then the ISDA CCR freeclose-out cash flow random variable at τ∗ seen from the pointof view of party k is given by Fk(τ

∗), where

Fk(τ∗) := 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗)− 11A−k

Λ2−k(τ∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

− 11A−k

M2−k(τ∗) + 11A−

2−kMk(τ

∗)

(MCP)= 11A−

kLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11A−2−k

LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ (11A−0 ∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗).

30 / 60

Page 95: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IIIObserve that H2−k(τ

∗) is seen from the viewpoint of party 2− k.Hence, a strict implication of our basic accounting property andthe MCP again implies the following important

ObservationFix k ∈ 0, 2. Firstly let us assume that there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., Asim = ∅). Then the ISDA CCR freeclose-out cash flow random variable at τ∗ seen from the pointof view of party k is given by Fk(τ

∗), where

Fk(τ∗) := 11A−

2−kΛk(τ

∗)− 11A−k

Λ2−k(τ∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

− 11A−k

M2−k(τ∗) + 11A−

2−kMk(τ

∗)

(MCP)= 11A−

kLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11A−2−k

LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ (11A−0 ∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗).

30 / 60

Page 96: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IV

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. The case of simultaneous defaults – seen fromthe point of view of party k - can be treated in the same way.Hence, by another application of the MCP we arrive at thefollowing ISDA CCR free close-out cash flow random variable atτ∗ (coinciding with the fourth term in formula (5) of Gregory’spaper [6]):

Gk(τ∗) := 11AsimΛk(τ

∗)− 11AsimΛ2−k(τ∗)

(MCP)= 11AsimLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ 11Asim2Mk(τ∗).

31 / 60

Page 97: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IV

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. The case of simultaneous defaults – seen fromthe point of view of party k - can be treated in the same way.Hence, by another application of the MCP we arrive at thefollowing ISDA CCR free close-out cash flow random variable atτ∗ (coinciding with the fourth term in formula (5) of Gregory’spaper [6]):

Gk(τ∗) := 11AsimΛk(τ

∗)− 11AsimΛ2−k(τ∗)

(MCP)= 11AsimLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ 11Asim2Mk(τ∗).

31 / 60

Page 98: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IV

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. The case of simultaneous defaults – seen fromthe point of view of party k - can be treated in the same way.Hence, by another application of the MCP we arrive at thefollowing ISDA CCR free close-out cash flow random variable atτ∗ (coinciding with the fourth term in formula (5) of Gregory’spaper [6]):

Gk(τ∗) := 11AsimΛk(τ

∗)− 11AsimΛ2−k(τ∗)

(MCP)= 11AsimLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ 11Asim2Mk(τ∗).

31 / 60

Page 99: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IV

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. The case of simultaneous defaults – seen fromthe point of view of party k - can be treated in the same way.Hence, by another application of the MCP we arrive at thefollowing ISDA CCR free close-out cash flow random variable atτ∗ (coinciding with the fourth term in formula (5) of Gregory’spaper [6]):

Gk(τ∗) := 11AsimΛk(τ

∗)− 11AsimΛ2−k(τ∗)

(MCP)= 11AsimLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ 11Asim2Mk(τ∗).

31 / 60

Page 100: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

+ (11A−0 ·∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗)

+ 11Asim

(2Mk(τ

∗)− LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+ + LGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+).

32 / 60

Page 101: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

+ (11A−0 ·∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗)

+ 11Asim

(2Mk(τ

∗)− LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+ + LGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+).

32 / 60

Page 102: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

= 11A−k

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−kLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

+ (11A−0 ·∪A−

2)Mk(τ

∗)

+ 11Asim

(2Mk(τ

∗)− LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+ + LGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+).

32 / 60

Page 103: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

= 11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

+ (11A−0 ·∪A−

2+ 211Asim)Mk(τ

∗) .

32 / 60

Page 104: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

= 11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

+ (1− 11N) Mk(τ∗) + 11Asim Mk(τ

∗) .

32 / 60

Page 105: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

= 11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk(M2−k(τ∗))+ − 11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k(Mk(τ

∗))+

+ Mk(τ∗) + 11Asim

((Mk(τ

∗))+ − (Mk(τ∗))−

).

32 / 60

Page 106: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out V

ObservationLet k ∈ 0, 2. The total ISDA CCR free close-out cash flowrandom variable at τ∗ seen from the point of view of party k isgiven by H∗k (τ∗) := Fk(τ

∗) + Gk(τ∗).

By considering all possible cases (including the possibility ofsimultaneous defaults) a remaining simple bit of algebratherefore gives us - step by step - the important generalrepresentation of H∗k (τ∗):

H∗k (τ∗) = Fk(τ∗) + Gk(τ

∗)

(!)= 11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ − 11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k(Mk(τ∗))+

+ Mk(τ∗) + 11Asim

((Mk(τ

∗))+ − (M2−k(τ∗))+

).

32 / 60

Page 107: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VI

Thus,

PropositionLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Seen from the viewpoint of party k,the random variable H∗k (τ∗) is given as

H∗k (τ∗) = Mk(τ∗)− Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

= Mk(τ∗)−

(X2−k(τ

∗)− Xk(τ∗)),

where Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)X= −Bτ∗(2− k, k) and

Xk(t) :=(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(t))+.

Actually, we have seen more. Namely,

33 / 60

Page 108: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VI

Thus,

PropositionLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Seen from the viewpoint of party k,the random variable H∗k (τ∗) is given as

H∗k (τ∗) = Mk(τ∗)− Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

= Mk(τ∗)−

(X2−k(τ

∗)− Xk(τ∗)),

where Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)X= −Bτ∗(2− k, k) and

Xk(t) :=(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(t))+.

Actually, we have seen more. Namely,

33 / 60

Page 109: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VI

Thus,

PropositionLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Seen from the viewpoint of party k,the random variable H∗k (τ∗) is given as

H∗k (τ∗) = Mk(τ∗)− Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

= Mk(τ∗)−

(X2−k(τ

∗)− Xk(τ∗)),

where Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)X= −Bτ∗(2− k, k) and

Xk(t) :=(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(t))+.

Actually, we have seen more. Namely,

33 / 60

Page 110: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VII

PropositionLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Seen from the viewpoint of party k,the random variable H∗k (t) is given as

H∗k (t) = (1− 11N)Mk(t)− Bt(k, 2− k)

= (1− 11N)Mk(t)−(X2−k(t)− Xk(t)

),

where Bt(k, 2− k) := X2−k(t)− Xk(t) X= −Bt(2− k, k) and

Xk(t) :=(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(t))+.

34 / 60

Page 111: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VII

PropositionLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Seen from the viewpoint of party k,the random variable H∗k (t) is given as

H∗k (t) = (1− 11N)Mk(t)− Bt(k, 2− k)

= (1− 11N)Mk(t)−(X2−k(t)− Xk(t)

),

where Bt(k, 2− k) := X2−k(t)− Xk(t) X= −Bt(2− k, k) and

Xk(t) :=(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(t))+.

34 / 60

Page 112: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VIII

Having an axiomatic approach in our sight, let us explicitly writedown the following

Observation (ISDA CCR free restrictions)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Then

(i) Bt(k, 2− k)11A−k

= −LGDk(M2−k(t))+11A−k

(ii) Bt(k, 2− k)11Asim =(Rk(M2−k(t))+ − R2−k(Mk(t))+

)11Asim

(iii) Bt(k, 2− k)11N = 0.

The ISDA CCR free restrictions simply say that both parties,party 0 and party 2 close-out their positions according to thelines of the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule by taking intoaccount precisely all - possible - default scenarios.

35 / 60

Page 113: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VIII

Having an axiomatic approach in our sight, let us explicitly writedown the following

Observation (ISDA CCR free restrictions)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Then

(i) Bt(k, 2− k)11A−k

= −LGDk(M2−k(t))+11A−k

(ii) Bt(k, 2− k)11Asim =(Rk(M2−k(t))+ − R2−k(Mk(t))+

)11Asim

(iii) Bt(k, 2− k)11N = 0.

The ISDA CCR free restrictions simply say that both parties,party 0 and party 2 close-out their positions according to thelines of the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule by taking intoaccount precisely all - possible - default scenarios.

35 / 60

Page 114: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VIII

Having an axiomatic approach in our sight, let us explicitly writedown the following

Observation (ISDA CCR free restrictions)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Then

(i) Bt(k, 2− k)11A−k

= −LGDk(M2−k(t))+11A−k

(ii) Bt(k, 2− k)11Asim =(Rk(M2−k(t))+ − R2−k(Mk(t))+

)11Asim

(iii) Bt(k, 2− k)11N = 0.

The ISDA CCR free restrictions simply say that both parties,party 0 and party 2 close-out their positions according to thelines of the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule by taking intoaccount precisely all - possible - default scenarios.

35 / 60

Page 115: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VIII

Having an axiomatic approach in our sight, let us explicitly writedown the following

Observation (ISDA CCR free restrictions)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Then

(i) Bt(k, 2− k)11A−k

= −LGDk(M2−k(t))+11A−k

(ii) Bt(k, 2− k)11Asim =(Rk(M2−k(t))+ − R2−k(Mk(t))+

)11Asim

(iii) Bt(k, 2− k)11N = 0.

The ISDA CCR free restrictions simply say that both parties,party 0 and party 2 close-out their positions according to thelines of the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule by taking intoaccount precisely all - possible - default scenarios.

35 / 60

Page 116: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VIII

Having an axiomatic approach in our sight, let us explicitly writedown the following

Observation (ISDA CCR free restrictions)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Then

(i) Bt(k, 2− k)11A−k

= −LGDk(M2−k(t))+11A−k

(ii) Bt(k, 2− k)11Asim =(Rk(M2−k(t))+ − R2−k(Mk(t))+

)11Asim

(iii) Bt(k, 2− k)11N = 0.

The ISDA CCR free restrictions simply say that both parties,party 0 and party 2 close-out their positions according to thelines of the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule by taking intoaccount precisely all - possible - default scenarios.

35 / 60

Page 117: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out VIII

Having an axiomatic approach in our sight, let us explicitly writedown the following

Observation (ISDA CCR free restrictions)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Then

(i) Bt(k, 2− k)11A−k

= −LGDk(M2−k(t))+11A−k

(ii) Bt(k, 2− k)11Asim =(Rk(M2−k(t))+ − R2−k(Mk(t))+

)11Asim

(iii) Bt(k, 2− k)11N = 0.

The ISDA CCR free restrictions simply say that both parties,party 0 and party 2 close-out their positions according to thelines of the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule by taking intoaccount precisely all - possible - default scenarios.

35 / 60

Page 118: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IX

DefinitionLet k ∈ 0, 2, t ∈ [0,T] and

f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ ,

where (l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+.

Then the stochasticprocess H∗, defined via

H∗k (ω, t) := 11A−2−k ·∪Asim

(ω) f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(ω, t))−, (M2−k(ω, t))+

)− 11A−

k ·∪Asim(ω) f ∗

(LGDk, (Mk(ω, t))−, (Mk(ω, t))+

)is called a symmetrically bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outcash flow (seen from the viewpoint of party k).Hence, H∗ is a special case of a generalised close-out cashflow in our sense.

36 / 60

Page 119: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IX

DefinitionLet k ∈ 0, 2, t ∈ [0,T] and

f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ ,

where (l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+. Then the stochasticprocess H∗, defined via

H∗k (ω, t) := 11A−2−k ·∪Asim

(ω) f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(ω, t))−, (M2−k(ω, t))+

)− 11A−

k ·∪Asim(ω) f ∗

(LGDk, (Mk(ω, t))−, (Mk(ω, t))+

)is called a symmetrically bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outcash flow (seen from the viewpoint of party k).

Hence, H∗ is a special case of a generalised close-out cashflow in our sense.

36 / 60

Page 120: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Bipartite ISDA CCR free close-out IX

DefinitionLet k ∈ 0, 2, t ∈ [0,T] and

f ∗(l,m−,m+) := m−(1− l)− m+ ,

where (l,m−,m+) ∈ [0, 1]× R+ × R+. Then the stochasticprocess H∗, defined via

H∗k (ω, t) := 11A−2−k ·∪Asim

(ω) f ∗(LGD2−k, (M2−k(ω, t))−, (M2−k(ω, t))+

)− 11A−

k ·∪Asim(ω) f ∗

(LGDk, (Mk(ω, t))−, (Mk(ω, t))+

)is called a symmetrically bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outcash flow (seen from the viewpoint of party k).Hence, H∗ is a special case of a generalised close-out cashflow in our sense.

36 / 60

Page 121: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Let t ≤ τ∗(ω). Based on ourprevious representation of H∗k (τ∗)(ω) discounting to timmediately implies

Theorem and DefinitionLet t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗ the t-discounted bipartite ISDA CCRfree close-out cash flow amount seen from the point of view ofparty k at t is given by D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗). I. e.,

D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗) = D(t, τ∗) Mk(τ∗)− D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

on t ≤ τ∗, where (as before) Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)and

Xk(τ∗) =

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+ .

37 / 60

Page 122: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Let t ≤ τ∗(ω). Based on ourprevious representation of H∗k (τ∗)(ω) discounting to timmediately implies

Theorem and DefinitionLet t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗ the t-discounted bipartite ISDA CCRfree close-out cash flow amount seen from the point of view ofparty k at t is given by D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗).

I. e.,

D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗) = D(t, τ∗) Mk(τ∗)− D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

on t ≤ τ∗, where (as before) Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)and

Xk(τ∗) =

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+ .

37 / 60

Page 123: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Let t ≤ τ∗(ω). Based on ourprevious representation of H∗k (τ∗)(ω) discounting to timmediately implies

Theorem and DefinitionLet t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗ the t-discounted bipartite ISDA CCRfree close-out cash flow amount seen from the point of view ofparty k at t is given by D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗). I. e.,

D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗) = D(t, τ∗) Mk(τ∗)− D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

on t ≤ τ∗,

where (as before) Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)and

Xk(τ∗) =

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+ .

37 / 60

Page 124: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows I

Fix k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Let t ≤ τ∗(ω). Based on ourprevious representation of H∗k (τ∗)(ω) discounting to timmediately implies

Theorem and DefinitionLet t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗ the t-discounted bipartite ISDA CCRfree close-out cash flow amount seen from the point of view ofparty k at t is given by D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗). I. e.,

D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗) = D(t, τ∗) Mk(τ∗)− D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k)

on t ≤ τ∗, where (as before) Bτ∗(k, 2− k) = X2−k(τ∗)− Xk(τ

∗)and

Xk(τ∗) =

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+ .

37 / 60

Page 125: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IIFix k ∈ 0, 2. Let 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T. Recall that Π

(t,u]k defines the

random CCR free cumulative cash flow from the claim in (t, u],discounted to time t (seen from k’s point of view).

Let ussimilarly denote by Π

(t,T]k the random cumulative cash flow from

the claim in (t,T], discounted to time t (seen from k’s point ofview), yet accounting for CCR now.

By construction Π(t,T]k should include both first-to-default

scenarios and the scenario of a simultaneous default of bothparties. To derive the structure of Π

(t,T]k , we again assume that

the MCP holds, as well as our basic accounting principle, andthat each party applies the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outrule.Hence, on t ≤ τ∗ we put

Π(t,T]k := Π

(t,τ∗]k + D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗)

38 / 60

Page 126: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IIFix k ∈ 0, 2. Let 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T. Recall that Π

(t,u]k defines the

random CCR free cumulative cash flow from the claim in (t, u],discounted to time t (seen from k’s point of view). Let ussimilarly denote by Π

(t,T]k the random cumulative cash flow from

the claim in (t,T], discounted to time t (seen from k’s point ofview), yet accounting for CCR now.

By construction Π(t,T]k should include both first-to-default

scenarios and the scenario of a simultaneous default of bothparties. To derive the structure of Π

(t,T]k , we again assume that

the MCP holds, as well as our basic accounting principle, andthat each party applies the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outrule.Hence, on t ≤ τ∗ we put

Π(t,T]k := Π

(t,τ∗]k + D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗)

38 / 60

Page 127: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IIFix k ∈ 0, 2. Let 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T. Recall that Π

(t,u]k defines the

random CCR free cumulative cash flow from the claim in (t, u],discounted to time t (seen from k’s point of view). Let ussimilarly denote by Π

(t,T]k the random cumulative cash flow from

the claim in (t,T], discounted to time t (seen from k’s point ofview), yet accounting for CCR now.

By construction Π(t,T]k should include both first-to-default

scenarios and the scenario of a simultaneous default of bothparties. To derive the structure of Π

(t,T]k , we again assume that

the MCP holds, as well as our basic accounting principle, andthat each party applies the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outrule.

Hence, on t ≤ τ∗ we put

Π(t,T]k := Π

(t,τ∗]k + D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗)

38 / 60

Page 128: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IIFix k ∈ 0, 2. Let 0 ≤ t ≤ u ≤ T. Recall that Π

(t,u]k defines the

random CCR free cumulative cash flow from the claim in (t, u],discounted to time t (seen from k’s point of view). Let ussimilarly denote by Π

(t,T]k the random cumulative cash flow from

the claim in (t,T], discounted to time t (seen from k’s point ofview), yet accounting for CCR now.

By construction Π(t,T]k should include both first-to-default

scenarios and the scenario of a simultaneous default of bothparties. To derive the structure of Π

(t,T]k , we again assume that

the MCP holds, as well as our basic accounting principle, andthat each party applies the bipartite ISDA CCR free close-outrule.Hence, on t ≤ τ∗ we put

Π(t,T]k := Π

(t,τ∗]k + D(t, τ∗)H∗k (τ∗)

38 / 60

Page 129: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows III

Recall that we also assume that the No-Arbitrage Principle issatisfied. Hence, under inclusion of all those listedassumptions, we obtain the following

Lemma (Representation of Π(t,T]k )

Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗, the random variableΠ

(t,T]k can be written as

Π(t,T]k = Π

(t,T]k −D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k) + D(t, τ∗)

(Mk(τ

∗)−Π(τ∗,T]k

).

In particular, we have Π(t,T]k

(MCP)= −Π

(t,T]2−k .

Hence, a consequent application of the conditional expectationEQ[ · ∣∣Gτ∗] to Π

(t,T]k , together with some stochastic analysis

lead to the following crucial

39 / 60

Page 130: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows III

Recall that we also assume that the No-Arbitrage Principle issatisfied. Hence, under inclusion of all those listedassumptions, we obtain the following

Lemma (Representation of Π(t,T]k )

Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗, the random variableΠ

(t,T]k can be written as

Π(t,T]k = Π

(t,T]k −D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k) + D(t, τ∗)

(Mk(τ

∗)−Π(τ∗,T]k

).

In particular, we have Π(t,T]k

(MCP)= −Π

(t,T]2−k .

Hence, a consequent application of the conditional expectationEQ[ · ∣∣Gτ∗] to Π

(t,T]k , together with some stochastic analysis

lead to the following crucial

39 / 60

Page 131: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows III

Recall that we also assume that the No-Arbitrage Principle issatisfied. Hence, under inclusion of all those listedassumptions, we obtain the following

Lemma (Representation of Π(t,T]k )

Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗, the random variableΠ

(t,T]k can be written as

Π(t,T]k = Π

(t,T]k −D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k) + D(t, τ∗)

(Mk(τ

∗)−Π(τ∗,T]k

).

In particular, we have Π(t,T]k

(MCP)= −Π

(t,T]2−k .

Hence, a consequent application of the conditional expectationEQ[ · ∣∣Gτ∗] to Π

(t,T]k , together with some stochastic analysis

lead to the following crucial

39 / 60

Page 132: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows III

Recall that we also assume that the No-Arbitrage Principle issatisfied. Hence, under inclusion of all those listedassumptions, we obtain the following

Lemma (Representation of Π(t,T]k )

Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. On t ≤ τ∗, the random variableΠ

(t,T]k can be written as

Π(t,T]k = Π

(t,T]k −D(t, τ∗)Bτ∗(k, 2− k) + D(t, τ∗)

(Mk(τ

∗)−Π(τ∗,T]k

).

In particular, we have Π(t,T]k

(MCP)= −Π

(t,T]2−k .

Hence, a consequent application of the conditional expectationEQ[ · ∣∣Gτ∗] to Π

(t,T]k , together with some stochastic analysis

lead to the following crucial

39 / 60

Page 133: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IV

Theorem (Market prices of total bipartite CCR)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]=

Mt(k)

+ EQ[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]− EQ

[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k − 11Asim

)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

40 / 60

Page 134: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IV

Theorem (Market prices of total bipartite CCR)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)

+ EQ[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]− EQ

[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k − 11Asim

)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

40 / 60

Page 135: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IV

Theorem (Market prices of total bipartite CCR)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)

+ EQ[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]

− EQ[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k − 11Asim

)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

40 / 60

Page 136: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows IV

Theorem (Market prices of total bipartite CCR)Let k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)

+ EQ[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

k ·∪AsimLGDk − 11Asim

)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]− EQ

[D(t, τ∗)

(11A−

2−k ·∪AsimLGD2−k − 11Asim

)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

40 / 60

Page 137: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows VLatter result contains an important and well-known specialcase. Namely the first appearance of “FTDCVA” and “FTDDVA”:

Corollary (Brigo-Capponi (2009))Let k ∈ 0, 2, t ∈ [0,T] and assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. Further assume thatboth, the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP are satisfied andthat the basic accounting rule holds. If there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., if Asim = ∅ Q-a. s.) then ont ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

] (!)= Mt(k)

+ EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)

(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]− EQ

[11A−

2−kLGD2−kD(t, τ∗)

(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

41 / 60

Page 138: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Vulnerable cash flows VLatter result contains an important and well-known specialcase. Namely the first appearance of “FTDCVA” and “FTDDVA”:

Corollary (Brigo-Capponi (2009))Let k ∈ 0, 2, t ∈ [0,T] and assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. Further assume thatboth, the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP are satisfied andthat the basic accounting rule holds. If there are nosimultaneous defaults (i. e., if Asim = ∅ Q-a. s.) then ont ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

] (!)= Mt(k)

+ EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)

(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]− EQ

[11A−

2−kLGD2−kD(t, τ∗)

(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

41 / 60

Page 139: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 140: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k)

:= EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 141: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 142: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 143: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 144: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k)

:= TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 145: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) :=

TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 146: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k)

(??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 147: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 148: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA I

DefinitionLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗. Put

TCVAt(k|2− k) := EQ[(

11A−2−k ·∪Asim

LGD2−k−11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(Mk(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

],

TBVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(k|2− k)− TCVAt(2− k|k),

and...

TDVAt(k, 2− k) := TCVAt(2− k|k) (??)

:= EQ[(

11A−k ·∪Asim

LGDk − 11Asim

)D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

].

42 / 60

Page 149: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA II

Definition (ctd.)

(i) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTCVAt(k | 2− k) is called Total Credit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(ii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTBVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Bilateral ValuationAdjustment at t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(iii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTDVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Debit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

The word “Total” should reflect the total coverage of all fourpossible cases: Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim.

43 / 60

Page 150: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA II

Definition (ctd.)

(i) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTCVAt(k | 2− k) is called Total Credit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(ii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTBVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Bilateral ValuationAdjustment at t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(iii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTDVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Debit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

The word “Total” should reflect the total coverage of all fourpossible cases: Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim.

43 / 60

Page 151: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA II

Definition (ctd.)

(i) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTCVAt(k | 2− k) is called Total Credit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(ii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTBVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Bilateral ValuationAdjustment at t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(iii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTDVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Debit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

The word “Total” should reflect the total coverage of all fourpossible cases: Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim.

43 / 60

Page 152: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA II

Definition (ctd.)

(i) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTCVAt(k | 2− k) is called Total Credit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(ii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTBVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Bilateral ValuationAdjustment at t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

(iii) The real-valued Gt-measurable random variableTDVAt(k, 2− k) is called Total Debit Valuation Adjustmentat t, seen from the viewpoint of party k.

The word “Total” should reflect the total coverage of all fourpossible cases: Ω = N ·∪ A−0 ·∪ A−2 ·∪ Asim.

43 / 60

Page 153: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself,

yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 154: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.

Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 155: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo!

A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 156: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)?

So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 157: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here?

Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 158: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”?

Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 159: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”?

Confused!

44 / 60

Page 160: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA III

Note that TDVAt(k, 2− k) is defined contingent of the default ofparty k itself, yet not contingent of the default of party 2− k.Thus, “TDVAt(k, 2− k)” is not a typo! A proper (and more“network-adequate”) notation probably could be the followingone:

“ TDVAt(k, 2− k∣∣k) := TCVAt(2− k, k

∣∣k) ′′

(where by definition Xt(a, b|m) is seen from the viewpoint of thetrading party a, given arbitrary trading parties a, b andm ∈ a, b)? So, aren’t we actually confronted with thebeginning of an “accounting paradox” here? Even morepuzzling: don’t we simply ignore the right sign here and justview on k’s double ledger k’s paid default protection premiumTCVAt(2− k|k) as a received amount, simply by renamingTCVAt(2− k|k) as “TDVAt(k, 2− k)”? Shouldn’t it be“TDVAt(k, 2− k) := −TCVAt(2− k|k)”? Confused!

44 / 60

Page 161: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA IV

ObservationLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗.

(i) If Asim = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≥ 0

(ii) If A−k = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = −EQ[11Asim Rk D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≤ 0

So, what would (ii) say if in addition both parties did defaultsimultaneously? Does then (ii) just state that the requiredpartial reimbursement Rk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ of party 2− k by party kcould be ignored by party k then?

45 / 60

Page 162: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA IV

ObservationLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗.

(i) If Asim = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≥ 0

(ii) If A−k = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = −EQ[11Asim Rk D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≤ 0

So, what would (ii) say if in addition both parties did defaultsimultaneously? Does then (ii) just state that the requiredpartial reimbursement Rk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ of party 2− k by party kcould be ignored by party k then?

45 / 60

Page 163: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA IV

ObservationLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗.

(i) If Asim = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≥ 0

(ii) If A−k = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = −EQ[11Asim Rk D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≤ 0

So, what would (ii) say if in addition both parties did defaultsimultaneously? Does then (ii) just state that the requiredpartial reimbursement Rk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ of party 2− k by party kcould be ignored by party k then?

45 / 60

Page 164: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA IV

ObservationLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗.

(i) If Asim = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≥ 0

(ii) If A−k = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = −EQ[11Asim Rk D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≤ 0

So, what would (ii) say if in addition both parties did defaultsimultaneously? Does then (ii) just state that the requiredpartial reimbursement Rk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ of party 2− k by party kcould be ignored by party k then?

45 / 60

Page 165: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

TCVA, TDVA and TBVA IV

ObservationLet k = 0 or k = 2, t ∈ [0,T] and t ≤ τ∗.

(i) If Asim = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = EQ[11A−

kLGDkD(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≥ 0

(ii) If A−k = ∅ Q-a. s., then we have (Q-a. s.)

TCVAt(k | 2− k) = −EQ[11Asim Rk D(t, τ∗)(M2−k(τ

∗))+∣∣Gt

]≤ 0

So, what would (ii) say if in addition both parties did defaultsimultaneously? Does then (ii) just state that the requiredpartial reimbursement Rk(M2−k(τ

∗))+ of party 2− k by party kcould be ignored by party k then?

45 / 60

Page 166: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR I

Recall that we also have assumed that the discount factorprocess D(0, ·) is G-adapted.

Let’s sum up what we have seenso far:

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TBVAt(k),

where the stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) is a

G-martingale under Q (seen from the viewpoint of party k),satisfying TBVAτ

∗(k, 2− k) = −TBVAτ

∗(2− k, k).

46 / 60

Page 167: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR I

Recall that we also have assumed that the discount factorprocess D(0, ·) is G-adapted. Let’s sum up what we have seenso far:

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TBVAt(k),

where the stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) is a

G-martingale under Q (seen from the viewpoint of party k),satisfying TBVAτ

∗(k, 2− k) = −TBVAτ

∗(2− k, k).

46 / 60

Page 168: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR I

Recall that we also have assumed that the discount factorprocess D(0, ·) is G-adapted. Let’s sum up what we have seenso far:

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TBVAt(k),

where the stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) is a

G-martingale under Q (seen from the viewpoint of party k),satisfying TBVAτ

∗(k, 2− k) = −TBVAτ

∗(2− k, k).

46 / 60

Page 169: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR I

Recall that we also have assumed that the discount factorprocess D(0, ·) is G-adapted. Let’s sum up what we have seenso far:

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. Assume that each party applies thebipartite ISDA CCR free close-out rule. If both, the No-ArbitragePrinciple and the MCP is satisfied, and if the basic accountingrule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TBVAt(k),

where the stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) is a

G-martingale under Q (seen from the viewpoint of party k),satisfying TBVAτ

∗(k, 2− k) = −TBVAτ

∗(2− k, k).

46 / 60

Page 170: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR II

Theorem (ctd.)Moreover,

TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) = Bτ∗(k, 2− k),

where B·(k, 2− k) is a G-adapted stochastic process, satisfyingthe ISDA CCR free restrictions and B·(k, 2− k) = −B·(2− k, k).

In particular, we have EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= −EQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt], implying

that both parties 0 and 2 would then agree on the “Q-marketprice of total bilateral CCR”.

In fact, we not only have an existence result. The listedproperties already lead to the following “uniqueness” result:

47 / 60

Page 171: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR II

Theorem (ctd.)Moreover,

TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) = Bτ∗(k, 2− k),

where B·(k, 2− k) is a G-adapted stochastic process, satisfyingthe ISDA CCR free restrictions and B·(k, 2− k) = −B·(2− k, k).

In particular, we have EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= −EQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt], implying

that both parties 0 and 2 would then agree on the “Q-marketprice of total bilateral CCR”.

In fact, we not only have an existence result. The listedproperties already lead to the following “uniqueness” result:

47 / 60

Page 172: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR II

Theorem (ctd.)Moreover,

TBVAτ∗(k, 2− k) = Bτ∗(k, 2− k),

where B·(k, 2− k) is a G-adapted stochastic process, satisfyingthe ISDA CCR free restrictions and B·(k, 2− k) = −B·(2− k, k).

In particular, we have EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= −EQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt], implying

that both parties 0 and 2 would then agree on the “Q-marketprice of total bilateral CCR”.

In fact, we not only have an existence result. The listedproperties already lead to the following “uniqueness” result:

47 / 60

Page 173: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T].

ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 174: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k.

Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 175: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that

• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 176: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];

• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR freerestrictions at τ∗;

• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 177: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;

• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 178: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,

• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàgG-martingale.

If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 179: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.

If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 180: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Market price of total bilateral CCR III

TheoremLet k ∈ 0, 2 and t ∈ [0,T]. ConsiderZt(k) := Mt(k)−∆t(k, 2− k), where (as usual in this talk)Mt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt]

denotes the CCR free mark-to-marketvalue of the portfolio to party k. Assume that• ∆τ∗(0, 2) = −∆τ∗(2, 0) for all s ∈ [0,T];• Both, ∆·(0, 2) and ∆·(2, 0) satisfy the ISDA CCR free

restrictions at τ∗;• D(0, ·) is G-adapted,• The stopped process D(0, · ∧ τ∗)∆τ∗(k, 2− k) is a càdlàg

G-martingale.If the No-Arbitrage Principle and the MCP is satisfied, and if thebasic accounting rule holds, then on t ≤ τ∗, we have∆t(k, 2− k) = TBVAt(k, 2− k) and Zt(k) = EQ[Π(t,T]

k |Gt].

48 / 60

Page 181: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

1 Simultaneous defaults and total bilateral counterparty creditrisk

2 Total bilateral valuation adjustment

3 Unilateral CVA and Basel III

49 / 60

Page 182: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Basel III and unilateral CVA

The confusion continues since:

Special Case (Basel III only one party defaults!)

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. Assume that in addition τk = +∞ (i. e., no defaultof party k). Then A−2−k = τ2−k ≤ T, A−k = ∅ and Asim = ∅.Consequently, TDVAt(k, 2− k) = 0,

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TCVAt(k | 2− k) ,

andEQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt]

= Mt(2− k)+TDVAt(2− k, k).

Hence, if party k were the investor, and if τk = +∞ theunilateral CVA UCVAt(k | 2− k) := TCVAt(k | 2− k) would haveto be paid by party 2− k to the default free party k at t to covera potential default of party 2− k after t.

50 / 60

Page 183: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Basel III and unilateral CVA

The confusion continues since:

Special Case (Basel III only one party defaults!)

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. Assume that in addition τk = +∞ (i. e., no defaultof party k). Then A−2−k = τ2−k ≤ T, A−k = ∅ and Asim = ∅.Consequently, TDVAt(k, 2− k) = 0,

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TCVAt(k | 2− k) ,

andEQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt]

= Mt(2− k)+TDVAt(2− k, k).

Hence, if party k were the investor, and if τk = +∞ theunilateral CVA UCVAt(k | 2− k) := TCVAt(k | 2− k) would haveto be paid by party 2− k to the default free party k at t to covera potential default of party 2− k after t.

50 / 60

Page 184: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Basel III and unilateral CVA

The confusion continues since:

Special Case (Basel III only one party defaults!)

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. Assume that in addition τk = +∞ (i. e., no defaultof party k). Then A−2−k = τ2−k ≤ T, A−k = ∅ and Asim = ∅.Consequently, TDVAt(k, 2− k) = 0,

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TCVAt(k | 2− k) ,

andEQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt]

= Mt(2− k)+TDVAt(2− k, k).

Hence, if party k were the investor, and if τk = +∞ theunilateral CVA UCVAt(k | 2− k) := TCVAt(k | 2− k) would haveto be paid by party 2− k to the default free party k at t to covera potential default of party 2− k after t.

50 / 60

Page 185: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Basel III and unilateral CVA

The confusion continues since:

Special Case (Basel III only one party defaults!)

Fix k ∈ 0, 2. Assume that in addition τk = +∞ (i. e., no defaultof party k). Then A−2−k = τ2−k ≤ T, A−k = ∅ and Asim = ∅.Consequently, TDVAt(k, 2− k) = 0,

EQ[Π(t,T]k |Gt

]= Mt(k)− TCVAt(k | 2− k) ,

andEQ[Π(t,T]

2−k |Gt]

= Mt(2− k)+TDVAt(2− k, k).

Hence, if party k were the investor, and if τk = +∞ theunilateral CVA UCVAt(k | 2− k) := TCVAt(k | 2− k) would haveto be paid by party 2− k to the default free party k at t to covera potential default of party 2− k after t.

50 / 60

Page 186: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Excerpt from Basel III (ACVA, Para 98)

51 / 60

Page 187: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CVA risk in Basel III: Flaws I

An analysis of “CVA volatility risk” and its capitalisation shouldparticularly treat the following serious flaws:

(i) CVA risk (and hedges) extend far beyond the risk of creditspread changes. It includes all risk factors that drive theunderlying counterparty exposures as well as dependentinteractions between counterparty exposures and thecredit spreads of the counterparties (and their underyings).By solely focusing on credit spreads, the Basel III UCVAVaR and stressed VaR measures in its advanced approachfor determining a CVA risk charge do not reflect the realrisks that drive the P&L and earnings of institutes.Moreover, banks typically hedge these non-credit-spreadrisk factors. The Basel III capital calculation does notinclude these hedges.

52 / 60

Page 188: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CVA risk in Basel III: Flaws II

(ii) The non-negligible and non-trivial problem of a morerealistic inclusion of WWR should be analysed deeply. Inparticular, the “alpha” multiplier 1.2 ≤ α should be revisited,and any unrealistic independence assumption should bestrongly avoided.

(iii) Credit and market risks in UCVA are not different from thesame risks, embedded in many other trading positionssuch as corporate bonds, CDSs, or equity derivatives. CVArisk can be seen as just another source of market risk.Consequently, it should be managed within the tradingbook. Basel III requires that the CVA risk charge iscalculated on a stand alone basis, separated from thetrading book. This seems to be an artificial segregation. Asuitable approach would be to include UCVA and all of itshedges into the trading book capital calculation.

53 / 60

Page 189: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

CVA risk in Basel III: Flaws III

(iv) Basel III considers unilateral CVA only. More precisely, theregulatory calculation of the ACVA is based on UCVA0 – asopposed to the calculations of CVA in FAS 157 respectivelyIAS 39! Latter explicitly include the (U)DVA0. Hence, thereexists a non-trivial mismatch between regulation andaccounting! Moreover, as we have seen a thorough andappropriate treatment of a market price of (bilateral) CCRleads to TBVA0 and not to UCVA0. Consequently, furtherresearch is necessary. There is work in progress such ase.g. the running “Fundamental Review of the Trading Book”or running projects in the RTF subgroup of the BCBS –hopefully leading to necessary improvements of Basel III.

54 / 60

Page 190: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Structure of TCVAt(k | 2− k)

Although we write “TCVAt(k | 2− k)” it always should be kept inmind that we actually are working with a very complex object,namely:

TCVAk(t,T,LGD2−k, τk, τ2−k,D(t, τ∗),Mk(τ∗)) !

Basel III considers the case t = 0 “only”. Why? The case0 < t ≤ τ∗ requires an in depth analysis of the conditional jointdefault process(

Q(τk ≤ T and τ2−k ≤ τk

∣∣Gt))

t∈[0,T].

To cover dynamically changing stochastic dependence betweenall embedded risk factors, a truly dynamic copula model has tobe constructed ( Bielecki, Crépey, Frey, Jeanblanc and manymore).

55 / 60

Page 191: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Structure of TCVAt(k | 2− k)

Although we write “TCVAt(k | 2− k)” it always should be kept inmind that we actually are working with a very complex object,namely:

TCVAk(t,T,LGD2−k, τk, τ2−k,D(t, τ∗),Mk(τ∗)) !

Basel III considers the case t = 0 “only”. Why?

The case0 < t ≤ τ∗ requires an in depth analysis of the conditional jointdefault process(

Q(τk ≤ T and τ2−k ≤ τk

∣∣Gt))

t∈[0,T].

To cover dynamically changing stochastic dependence betweenall embedded risk factors, a truly dynamic copula model has tobe constructed ( Bielecki, Crépey, Frey, Jeanblanc and manymore).

55 / 60

Page 192: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Structure of TCVAt(k | 2− k)

Although we write “TCVAt(k | 2− k)” it always should be kept inmind that we actually are working with a very complex object,namely:

TCVAk(t,T,LGD2−k, τk, τ2−k,D(t, τ∗),Mk(τ∗)) !

Basel III considers the case t = 0 “only”. Why? The case0 < t ≤ τ∗ requires an in depth analysis of the conditional jointdefault process(

Q(τk ≤ T and τ2−k ≤ τk

∣∣Gt))

t∈[0,T].

To cover dynamically changing stochastic dependence betweenall embedded risk factors, a truly dynamic copula model has tobe constructed ( Bielecki, Crépey, Frey, Jeanblanc and manymore).

55 / 60

Page 193: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Structure of TCVAt(k | 2− k)

Although we write “TCVAt(k | 2− k)” it always should be kept inmind that we actually are working with a very complex object,namely:

TCVAk(t,T,LGD2−k, τk, τ2−k,D(t, τ∗),Mk(τ∗)) !

Basel III considers the case t = 0 “only”. Why? The case0 < t ≤ τ∗ requires an in depth analysis of the conditional jointdefault process(

Q(τk ≤ T and τ2−k ≤ τk

∣∣Gt))

t∈[0,T].

To cover dynamically changing stochastic dependence betweenall embedded risk factors, a truly dynamic copula model has tobe constructed ( Bielecki, Crépey, Frey, Jeanblanc and manymore).

55 / 60

Page 194: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Further important topics (not discussedhere)

Finally let us list further – important – topics which could not beconsidered in this talk (due to time limitation).

• Risk mitigants such as collateral and margins;• Re-hypothecation of collateral and funding;• Margin period of risk;• TBVA and clearing through a CCP (a CCP could also

default) systemic risk?!

56 / 60

Page 195: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Further important topics (not discussedhere)

Finally let us list further – important – topics which could not beconsidered in this talk (due to time limitation).• Risk mitigants such as collateral and margins;

• Re-hypothecation of collateral and funding;• Margin period of risk;• TBVA and clearing through a CCP (a CCP could also

default) systemic risk?!

56 / 60

Page 196: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Further important topics (not discussedhere)

Finally let us list further – important – topics which could not beconsidered in this talk (due to time limitation).• Risk mitigants such as collateral and margins;• Re-hypothecation of collateral and funding;

• Margin period of risk;• TBVA and clearing through a CCP (a CCP could also

default) systemic risk?!

56 / 60

Page 197: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Further important topics (not discussedhere)

Finally let us list further – important – topics which could not beconsidered in this talk (due to time limitation).• Risk mitigants such as collateral and margins;• Re-hypothecation of collateral and funding;• Margin period of risk;

• TBVA and clearing through a CCP (a CCP could alsodefault) systemic risk?!

56 / 60

Page 198: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Further important topics (not discussedhere)

Finally let us list further – important – topics which could not beconsidered in this talk (due to time limitation).• Risk mitigants such as collateral and margins;• Re-hypothecation of collateral and funding;• Margin period of risk;• TBVA and clearing through a CCP (a CCP could also

default) systemic risk?!

56 / 60

Page 199: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

A very few references I[1] C. Albanese, D. Brigo and F. Oertel.Restructuring counterparty credit risk.Discussion Paper, Deutsche Bundesbank, No 14/2013.

[2] S. Assefa, T. Bielecki, S. Crépey and M. Jeanblanc.CVA computation for counterparty risk assessment in creditportfolios.Credit Risk Frontiers. Editors T. Bielecki, D. Brigo and F.Patras, John Wiley & Sons (2011).

[3] T. F. Bollier and E. H. Sorensen.Pricing swap default risk.Financial Analysts Journal Vol. 50, No. 3, pp. 23-33 (1994).

[4] D. Brigo and A. Capponi.Bilateral counterparty risk valuation with stochasticdynamical models and application to credit default swaps.Working Paper, Fitch Solutions and CalTech (2009).

57 / 60

Page 200: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

A very few references II

[5] J. Gregory.Counterparty Credit Risk.John Wiley & Sons Ltd (2010).

[6] J. Gregory.Being two-faced over counterparty credit risk.Risk, February 2009 (2009).

[7] J. Hull and A. White.CVA and Wrong Way Risk.Working Paper, Joseph L. Rotman School of Management,University of Toronto (2011).

[8] M. Pykhtin.A Guide to Modelling Counterparty Credit Risk.GARP Risk Review, 37, 16-22 (2007).

58 / 60

Page 201: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

A very few references III

[9] H. Schmidt.Basel III und CVA aus regulatorischer Sicht.Kontrahentenrisiko. S. Ludwig, M. R. W. Martin und C. S.Wehn (Hrsg.), Schäfer-Pöschel (2012).

59 / 60

Page 202: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Thank you for your attention!

Are there any questions, comments or remarks?

60 / 60

Page 203: bcc.impan.plbcc.impan.pl/6AMaMeF/uploads/presentations/130610_Oertel.pdfCounterparty credit risk - Outline I Suppose there are two parties who are trading a portfolio of OTC derivative

Thank you for your attention!

Are there any questions, comments or remarks?

60 / 60