berlin journal 22

Upload: ekmixon

Post on 02-Jun-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    1/68

    In this issue:

    Peter L. Lindseth

    Michael Ignatieff

    Elizabeth Povinelli

    Richard Deming

    Karen Russell

    David Remnick

    Katherine Boo

    Daniel Hobbins

    Nicholas Eberstadt

    Michael Geyer

    Charles Bright

    A Magazine from the American Academy in Berlin|Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    THE BERLIN JOURNAL

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    2/68

    WE ARE GRATEFUL TO

    Alfred Freiherr von Oppenheim-Stiftung

    im Stifterverband fr die Deutsche Wissenschaft

    FOR ITS

    GENEROUS SUPPORT OF

    THE BERLIN JOURNAL

    AND THE

    AMERICAN ACADEMY IN BERLIN.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    3/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    1

    CONTENTSThe Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    04 Of the Peoplepeter l. lindseth,by way of AbrahamLincoln, examines democracy and theEurozone, and how even those Europeanswho favor integration may have difficul-ties experiencing it as their own.

    08 Politics for Hard Times

    michael ignatieffspeaks to the chal-lenges facing progressive politics in anage of austerity; namely, persuading themajority who are doing well that theirfuture depends on doing somethingabout the large and growing minority whoare doing badly.

    14 Emergence and Exitelizabeth povinellitheorizes neolib-eralisms collapse, the concurrent rise ofradically new forms of social governance,and the increasingly multi-polar nature ofthe global economic engine.

    18 On Lonelinessrichard demingruminates on modernisolation through the lens of horror filmsand offers two of his latest poems.

    N1 On the Waterfront

    The American Academys newsletter,with the latest on fellows, alumni, andtrustees, as well as recent events at theHans Arnhold Center

    25 The Sponge Divers of New Kalymnoskaren russellgrants a sneak peek ather new fiction and describes the eerienature of authorial intuition.

    29 Journalism as Literaturedavid remnick, joseph lelyveld,and katherine boodiscuss the novel-istic tendencies of narrative reportage.

    32 The Worlds First Media Revolutiondaniel hobbinsreveals the oft-ignoredorigins of print, and how, contrary tomost historians assumptions, a risingdemand for books came before, not after,Gutenbergs famous invention.

    36 Waning Crescent

    nicholas eberstadtexplains thedecline in fertilit y rates, traditional mar-riage patterns, and living arrangementscurrently sweeping the Muslim world.

    40 A World in Processcharles bright and michael geyerchat about their first encounters withglobalism, the curiously brief heyday ofWestern empires in the twentieth century,and the urgency of re-narrating modernglobal history.

    COURTESYSPRTHMAGERS

    ,BERLIN/L

    ONDON

    ANTHONY MCCALL, YOU AND I, HORIZONTAL, 2006, INSTALLATION VIEW

    Untangling the EU Crisis Setting the Record StraightSounding the Depths

    This issue was generously underwritten by Academy chairman A. Michael Hoffman, to whom we are very grateful.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    4/68

    2 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    DIRECTORS NOTE

    Devotions depths

    Richard Holbrooke wasnt interested in foreign

    policy; he was consumed by it, writes Jacob Heilbrunn

    in a New York Times review of The Unquiet American,

    a new collection of essays on the late diplomat and Academy

    founder. In this issue of the Berlin Journal, we offer a selection

    of articles from authors who are similarly anti-dabbling in

    their devotions, whose work reveals the deepest of dedications.

    Katherine Boo, who spent four years in the slums of

    Mumbai researching her latest book, Behind the Beautiful

    Forevers, describes her impatience with the self-congratulatory

    tendencies of narrative nonfiction; Michael Ignatieff argues

    for a progressive response to the financial crisis; and Karen

    Russell depicts a diving community whose greed drives a good

    man to invent bad technology.

    Everything was better last year, says one of Russells char-

    acters during an initiation ceremony. The cake, the boys. The

    mothers looked good last year, what happened? Everybodys

    fatter this year! Everybodys choking to death on this foul cake!

    While the austerity measures challenging the stability of

    the EU have meant less, not more, cake, Russells ornery char-

    acter serves as a chorus for a segment of the West whose confi-

    dence, pre-crisis, was unflagging. In an interview, global his-

    torians Michael Geyer and Charles Bright offer insights into

    the origins of such blind spots. Elizabeth Povinelli predicts the

    collapse of neoliberalism, and Peter Lindseth suggests that a

    little demoscould go a long way in re-unify ing the EU.

    And yet, as spring slowly warms Wannsees waters, this

    issue of theJournal also acknowledges the surprise and relief,

    each year, of a gentler season. Richard Deming points out the

    counterintuitively communal quality of loneliness; Nicholas

    Eberstadt reveals an unexpected study about plummeting

    birth rates in the Muslim world; and Daniel Hobbins suggests

    that it was a demand for books that inspired the rise of the

    printing press, rather than the reverse.

    This spring is also the Academys first under the helm of

    its new chairman, A. Michael Hoffman, who draws upon a

    substantial record of achievement in the financial world and a

    lifelong championing of non-profit organizations in the arts,

    academia, and international relations. As we look forward to

    growing with his guidance, we also take a moment to acknowl-

    edge the immeasurable contributions of our trustees over the

    past fourteen years, who have shown much wisdom, passion,

    and perseverance in building an institution from scratch. G.S. and B.L.S.

    THE BERLIN JOURNAL

    A magazine from the Hans Arnhold

    Center published by the American

    Academy in Berlin

    Number Twenty-Two Spring 2012

    PUBLISHERGary Smith

    EDITOR Brittani Sonnenberg

    IMAGE EDITOR

    R. Jay Magill Jr.

    ADVERTISING Berit Ebert

    DESIGN Susanna Dulkinys &

    Edenspiekermann

    www.edenspiekermann.com

    PRINTED BY Ruksaldruck, Berlin

    Copyright 2012

    The American Academy in Berlin

    ISSN 1610-6490

    Cover: Jenny Holzer,

    TOP SECRET 21, 2012, Jenny Holzer,

    member Artists Rights Society (ARS),

    NY/VG Bild-Kunst, Bonn 2012, Photo:Jens Ziehe, Courtesy Sprth Magers

    Berlin/London

    THE AMERICAN ACADEMY

    IN BERLIN

    EXECUTIVE DIRECTOR

    Gary Smith

    DEAN OF FELLOWS & PROGRAMS

    Pamela Rosenberg

    CHIEF ADMINISTRATIVE

    OFFICER

    Andrew J. White

    Am Sandwerder 1719

    14109 Berlin

    Tel. (49 30)80 48 3-0

    Fax (49 30)80 48 3-111

    www.americanacademy.de

    14 East 60th Street, Suite 604

    New York, NY 10022

    Tel. (1)212 588-1755

    Fax (1)212 588-1758

    FOUNDERRichard C. Holbrooke

    HONORARY CHAIRMEN Thomas L. Farmer, Henry A. Kissinger,

    Richard von Weizscker

    CHAIRMAN A. Michael Hoffman

    VICE CHAIR Gahl Hodges Burt

    TREASURER Andrew J. White

    SECRETARY John C. Kornblum

    TRUSTEES Barbara Balaj, John P. Birkelund, Manfred Bischoff, Stephen B.

    Burbank, Gahl Hodges Burt, Caroline Walker Bynum, Mathias Dpfner, NiallFerguson, Marina Kellen French, Michael E. Geyer, Hans-Michael Giesen,

    Richard K. Goeltz, C. Boyden Gray, Vartan Gregorian, Andrew S. Gundlach,

    Helga Haub, A. Michael Hoffman, Stefan von Holtzbrinck, Wolfgang

    Ischinger, Josef Joffe, Michael Klein, John C. Kornblum, Regine Leibinger,

    Lawrence Lessig, Wolfgang Malchow, Nina von Maltzahn, Wolfgang

    Mayrhuber, Julie Mehretu, Christopher von Oppenheim, Jeffery A. Rosen,

    Volker Schlndorff, Peter Y. Solmssen, Kurt Viermetz, Pauline Yu

    HONORARY TRUSTEE Klaus Wowereit (ex officio)

    CHAIRMAN EMERITUS Karl M. von der Heyden

    TRUSTEES EMERITI Diethard Breipohl, Gerhard Casper,

    Norman Pearlstine, Fritz Stern

    IN GERMANY

    Contributions may be made

    by bank transfer to:

    American Academy in Berlin

    Berliner Sparkasse

    BLZ 100 500 00

    Account: 660 000 9908

    IBAN:

    DE07 1005 0000 6600 0099 08

    BIC: BELADEBEXXX

    IN THE UNITED STATES

    Contributions may be made

    by check payable to:

    The American Academy in Berlin

    14 East 60th Street, Suite 604

    New York, NY 10022

    by bank transfer to: JPMorgan Chase

    500 Stanton Christiana Road, Newark,

    DE 19713; Account: 967 33 12 77,

    ABA: 021 00 00 21SWIFT CODE: CHASUS 33

    SUPPORT

    The Academy is entirely funded by private donations. If you like what we

    are doing, please contribute by making a tax-deductible donation:

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    5/68

    Mehr ZEIT fr Sie!Genieen Sie anspruchsvollen Journalismus.

    ImHa

    ndel

    erhlt

    lich!

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    6/68

    4 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    OF THE PEOPLEDemocracy, the Eurozone,and Lincolns threshold criterion

    By Peter L. Lindseth

    In a recent speech at Humboldt

    University, Herman Van Rompuy, presi-

    dent of the European Council, noted how

    the Eurozone crisis had seemingly forced

    national leaders to take center stage in

    the EU. For many observers, this has raised

    fears of a renationalization of European

    politics. Van Rompuy, however, preferred

    to look on the bright side. This was all

    indicative, he said, of the deepening of

    the Europeanization of national political

    life. He quoted Chancellor Merkel in this

    regard: In this crisis we have reached a

    whole new level of cooperation; we have

    arrived at a sort of European home affairs.

    Europa ist Innenpolitik.

    There can be no doubt that Europe has,

    indeed, become domestic politics. Yet I

    would argue that the Eurozone crisis has

    merely accelerated a trend that began at

    least twenty-five years ago, with the SingleEuropean Act (sea) of 1986, followed by

    the Treaty of Maastricht of 1992. It is no

    coincidence that concerns over Europes

    purported democratic deficit began to

    intensify at this time, because it was then

    that increasing numbers of Europeans

    became aware of how much regulatory

    power had migrated to the supranational

    level. Even though the EUs annual budget

    would remain miniscule (no more than 1%

    of total EU gdp), the EU would become a

    prodigious producer of regulatory norms

    with a major impact on domestic policy-

    making in its member states.There was, however, a funda-

    mental problem with this so-called

    Europeanization of national political li fe.

    Joschka Fischer, then Germanys foreign

    minister, identified it in his own speech

    at Humboldt in 2000: European gover-

    nance has long been afflicted indeed,

    is still afflicted by a broadly held sense

    that integration is a largely bureaucratic

    affair run by a faceless, soulless Eurocracy

    in Brussels. No matter how much

    European elites have struggled against

    this perception, European citizens still

    continue to experience the increasing

    EUROPEAN GOVERNANCE HAS

    LONG BEEN AFFLICTED BY A

    BROADLY HELD SENSE THAT

    INTEGRATION IS A LARGELY

    BUREAUCRATIC AFFAIR RUN

    BY A FACELESS, SOULLESS

    EUROCRACY IN BRUSSELS.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    7/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    5

    C

    OURTESYGALERIEEIGEN+

    ARTLEIPZIG/BERLINANDT

    HEPACEGALLERY

    .PHOTO:

    AMEDEOBENESTANTE

    CARSTEN NICOLAI, PIONIER II, 2009. SITE-SPECIFIC INSTALLATION ON PIAZZA PLEBISCITO, NAPLES, ITALY

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    8/68

    6 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    Europeanization of domestic politics, if

    not precisely as the negation of democ-

    racy on the national level, then certainly

    as the transfer of regulatory power to an

    unaccountable, distant, and ultimately

    foreign bureaucratic elite, dominated

    by national executives. This distant elite

    goes simply by the name Brussels or,

    as the German writer Hans Magnus

    Enzensberger put it in a Spiegel essay last

    year, the sanftes Monster Brssel the

    gentle monster that is Brussels.

    The official response to this broad

    political perception toward the EU, begin-ning with the se ain 1986 and continuing

    with every subsequent treaty up to Lisbon

    in 2009, has been to increase the role of

    the elected European Parliament (EP) in

    the supranational policy process. The aim

    has been to reduce integrations so-called

    democratic deficit, building on decisions

    of the European Court of Justice (ecj) in

    the 1980s. Very much in keeping with the

    constitutionalist mindset the court had

    established since the early 1960s, the ecj

    declared that the EP was the expression of

    the fundamental democratic principle that

    the peoples [of Europe] should take part

    in the exercise of [supranational] power

    through the intermediary of a representa-

    tive assembly.

    We might call this par-

    liamentary democratization

    strategy, which has been a

    fundamental feature of the understanding

    of the EU as a kind of quasi-federal consti-

    tutional polity. Alas, as subsequent events

    have shown, this strategy has ultimatelyfailed to stem the negative perception of

    the EU as fundamentally bureaucratic

    and distant. This is due to the fact that the

    strategy itself is based on a fundamental

    misunderstanding of what democracy is,

    as well as how true democratic legitimacy

    is realized over time.

    To frame the discussion, allow me to

    do something not particularly innovative

    by invoking L incolns classic formulation

    from the Gett ysburg Address democ-

    racy is government of the people, by the

    people, [and] for the people. The effort

    to democratize the EU has made sig-

    munity gains this historically grounded

    sense of democratic self-consciousness, it

    has become a demos in the sense of

    demos-kratia, or democracy.

    In other words, democratic legitimacy

    in the deepest sense depends not merely

    on democracys inputs or outputs. Rather,

    it ultimately depends on whether there

    exists this crucial sense of historical iden-

    tity between governing institutions and a

    people self-conscious of itself as such. I

    would argue that this sense of demos-legit-

    imacy is not merely essential to democracy

    but also to constitutionalism itself: it is

    on the basis of this demos-legitimacy that

    merely functional institutions of rule

    (those that might otherwise possess input

    and output legitimacy) are transformed

    into genuinely constitutional ones,

    because they have come to be understood

    as the institutional expressions of the rightof the demos to rule itself.

    As is well known today, the EU

    is riddled with multiple demoi

    across its various member states.

    This creates a great deal of democratic and

    constitutional legitimacy, unfortunately

    not for the EU, but for national constitu-

    tional bodies. (T here are exceptions, of

    course, such as in Belgium, where the

    coherence of the national demos is deeply

    contested, thus undermining the legiti-

    macy of national inst itutions.) But as is

    broadly recognized throughout Europe,

    the EU, as yet, lacks any single, over-

    arching European demos. Without such

    demos-legitimacy that is, without the

    sense that European institutions are genu-

    inely the peoples own, rather than some

    distant bureaucratic construct Europe

    will always have a great deal of difficulty

    overcoming its democratic deficit, no mat-

    ter how much input and output legitimacy

    otherwise exists.

    Indeed, the very idea of a democraticdeficit in the EU may itself reflect an elite

    misapprehension of the nature of the prob-

    lem. As my book Power and Legitimacy

    describes in some detail, the problem in

    the EU is not a democratic deficit, in the

    sense of needing increased input legiti-

    macy, but rather a democratic disconnect.

    European institutions are generally per-

    ceived as beyond the control of democratic

    and constitutional bodies in a historical ly

    recognizable sense, and this has a bearing

    on the scope of authority that Europeans

    believe supranational bodies can legiti-

    mately exercise.

    nificant achievements along the final two

    of Lincolns dimensions. Government

    by the people refers to what academics

    call input legitimacy; that is, popular

    participation, most importantly via elec-

    tions (the European Parliament clearly

    meets this criterion, as do other features

    of the EU, like the new citizens initiative

    in the Treaty of Lisbon). And, despite the

    many woes of the current crisis, my sense

    is the EU deserves significant credit in

    terms of government for the people, or

    what the German political scientist Fritz

    Scharpf has famously called output legiti-macy. This can be measured not merely

    in additional points added to net gdpas a

    consequence of market integration (if not

    of the common currency), but also by such

    things as the removal of border controls;

    the broadly shared respect for human

    rights and the rule of law; as well as, per-

    haps most importantly, the overall sense

    of peaceful coexistence that integration

    has brought to this historically troubled

    continent. (Peace, after all, was the stated

    aim of the Schuman Declaration in 1950.)

    Thus, despite its current economic travai ls,

    the EU has much to be proud of in terms of

    output legitimacy as well.

    So what, then, is the problem with the

    EUs democratic legitimacy? I would say

    the problem lies precisely in Lincolns

    threshold criterion: government of the

    people. This refers to the historical iden-

    tity between a population and a set of gov-

    erning institutions; that is, to the political-

    cultural perception that the institutions

    of government are genuinely the peoples

    own, which they have historically consti-tuted for the purpose of self-government

    over time. Europeans may favor integra-

    tion for all sorts of instrumental reasons,

    but they do not yet exper ience it as their

    own.

    This process of self-constitution is tied

    to the historical sense of the existence of a

    people itself, to the sense that there exists

    a historically cohesive political community,

    shaped by broadly shared historical memo-

    ries, in which it is legitimate for the majori-

    ty to rule over the minority in a democratic

    sense (subject, of course, to the protection

    of human rights). When a political com-

    THE PROBLEM IN THE EU IS NOT A DEMOCRATIC DEFICIT,

    IN THE SENSE OF NEEDING INCREASED INPUT LEGITIMACY,

    BUT RATHER A DEMOCRATIC DISCONNECT.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    9/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    7

    Sympathetic European commentators,

    not to mention judges on the ecj, have

    struggled for decades to reconceive the

    nature of democracy and constitutional-

    ism in the EU. They have come up with a

    whole range of network-based theories

    of transnational or cosmopolitan demo-

    cratic and constitutional legitimacy in

    order to dissociate these concepts from the

    nation-state and thus bring supranational

    governance within their conceptual ambit.

    And yet the idea of the EU as democratic

    and constitutional in its own right has

    remained deeply suspect, at least when

    measured against the perceived legitimacy

    of institutions on the national level, with

    all their many flaws.

    I should say that there are many benefits

    to this sense of supranational constitution-

    alism, notably in the protection of the indi-

    vidual against the excesses of public power,wherever located. But there are also sig-

    nificant risks, as the Eurozone crisis may

    be sadly demonstrating. Constitutional

    interpretations of integration wrongly

    bracket out the no-demos problem and thus

    effectively assume a degree of autonomous

    legitimacy in supranational governance

    that is fundamentally lacking (or at least is

    still fundamentally in dispute).

    This leads us, then, to the key point:

    overestimating the legitimacy of European

    institutions is not merely an error of aca-

    demic analysis; rather, it can lead to even

    more profound and dangerous errors

    of institutional or policy design, as the

    Eurozone crisis is demonstrating. As the

    Italian political theorist Stefano Bartolini

    presciently warned in 2005, in his book

    Restructuring Europe, the risk of miscalcu-

    lating the extent to which true legitimacy

    surrounds the European institutions and

    their decisions . . . may lead to the overes-

    timating of the capacity of the EU to over-

    come major economic and security cr ises.

    The events of the last two years suggest

    that the European Monetary Union (emu)

    was built on just such an overestimation.

    The common currency was not just flawed

    economically (although economists never

    tire of pointing out that the countries of

    the Eurozone and certainly Germany

    unclear how stable the resulting institu-

    tional settlement would be. One might call

    the resulting regime a political union, but

    its underlying socio-cu ltural and socio-

    political foundations would be tenuous.

    Does this mean there is no legitimacy for

    further integration? Of course not. But

    when contemplating further steps in inte-

    gration, Europeans must always be honest

    with themselves about this key question:

    legitimate for what?

    In a system where democratic and con-

    stitutional legitimacy remains fundamen-

    tally national, but significant normative

    power is increasingly supranationalized, it

    must be recognized that there are limits to

    the EUs legitimacy, as the Eurozone crisis

    is unfortunately indicating. Integration is

    good for certain things but not others. It

    might be very good for harmonizing regu-

    latory standards across borders. But dena-

    tionalizing tax ing and spending power to

    any significant degree, as some argue is

    the only way to solve the Eurozone crisis,

    may yet prove a step too far.

    Despite the many efforts to

    create a version of constitutional-

    ism beyond the state in the EU, the

    current crisis is a further manifestation of

    a still basic fact in Europe: government of

    the people is still wedded to the nation-

    state in crucial respects. How long that

    will last, I cannot say. But the Eurozone

    crisis seems to be reminding us of an

    insight stressed by the French philosopher

    Ernest Renan in his famous lecture What

    is a Nation? in 1882, something arguably

    still true despite all that has changed inthe intervening century and a quarter. The

    current crisis reminds us that, in extremis,

    national institutions in Europe are still

    looked upon, in terms of political culture,

    as a guarantee of liberty in a collective,

    constitutional sense, something that

    would be lost if [Europe] had only one law

    and only one master.

    Peter L. Lindseth is the Olimpiad S.

    Ioffe Professor of International and

    Comparative Law at the University

    of Connecticut and the spring 2012

    Daimler Fellow at the Academy.

    and Greece do not constitute what they

    call an optimal currency area). Rather, it

    was also flawed constitutionally, in terms

    of its lack of a foundation in demos-legit-

    imacy. Given the downside risks that the

    Eurozone crisis is now revealing, the adop-

    tion of the euro presupposed a degree of

    centralized political power and legitimacy

    most importantly relating to shared tax-

    ing and borrowing authority (Eurobonds)

    that the EU, or rather the Eurozone coun-

    tries collect ively, simply lack.

    In his speech at Humboldt,

    President Van Rompuy continually

    pointed out the fact that total debt lev-

    els and the general fiscal position of the

    Eurozone as a whole were actually pretty

    decent, at least as compared to, say, the

    United States or Britain. The problem with

    this claim is that the Eurozone as a whole,aside from the fact that it shares a common

    currency, along with some common insti-

    tutions like the European Central Bank, is

    otherwise a statistical ar tifact with no real

    political existence of its own. It certainly

    lacks shared taxing or borrowing authority

    that might take advantage of the overall

    sound position of the Eurozone as a

    whole (for example, via Eurobonds).

    So why not just more Europe? Why

    not just solve the problem by creating the

    long-sought political union to match the

    currency union? The answer is simply

    stated, even if its manifestat ions are com-

    plex: no demos. European elites cannot

    simply wave the political-cultural magic

    wand and create the necessary sense

    of democratic and constitutional self-

    consciousness across national borders that

    constructing such a union would demand.

    To do so without the requisite demos-

    legitimacy the sense of government of

    the people would be the institutional

    equivalent of pouring good money after

    bad. At this point in Europes history, it

    cannot get from here to there.

    The functional demands of this crisis

    may yet force Europeans to attempt to

    supranationalize some of its member

    states debts, at least if it wants the com-

    mon currency to surv ive. But it is quite

    OVERESTIMATING THE LEGITIMACY OF EUROPEAN INSTITUTIONS IS

    NOT MERELY AN ERROR OF ACADEMIC ANALYSIS; IT CAN LEAD TO EVEN

    MORE PROFOUND AND DANGEROUS ERRORS OF INSTITUTIONAL OR

    POLICY DESIGN, AS THE EUROZONE CRISIS IS DEMONSTRATING.

    THE ANSWER IS SIMPLY STATED,

    EVEN IF ITS MANIFESTATIONS ARE

    COMPLEX: NO DEMOS.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    10/68

    8 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    As I writ e, Europes leaders are

    gathering to try to save the com-

    mon currency yet again. They have

    failed before, and failure this time may put

    into question the destination a continent

    gave itself after 1945. Instead of progresstowards ever closer union, we must now

    envisage the possible break-up of the euro,

    the re-emergence of border controls, and

    the bubbling up of a politics of resent-

    ment and recrimination that could end in

    conflict between classes and even between

    nations.

    The strategic, economic, and social

    future of a continent is at stake. The

    European project was supposed to guaran-

    tee the future of Europe by creating a single

    market of a size to rival the Chinese and the

    Americans. A strong euro and a strong pan-

    European economy in turn would sustain

    the European welfare state as an alternative

    to the American and Chinese social models.

    A continent integrated from Ireland to the

    borders of Russia would consign to the past

    the divisions of the Cold War. The euro cri-

    sis puts all of these dreams at risk.

    We can see now, in hindsight, that a

    common currency required a common

    fiscal and budgetary regime to constrain

    sovereign imprudence and political

    fecklessness. Yet instead of locking in acommon fiscal discipline from the begin-

    ning, European governments tried to have

    the best of both worlds, monetary union

    without loss of economic sovereignty. Both

    weak and strong states then exploited the

    euro to pass their problems onto their

    neighbors. Strong states like France and

    Germany evaded their Maastricht commit-

    ment to keep their debt at three percent of

    gdp, while weaker ones like Greece, Italy,

    Portugal, Spain, and Ireland went on bor-

    rowing sprees, convinced that the Eurozone

    would bail them out and that rising asset

    prices would cover their fiscal deficits.

    Instead of transcending sovereignty, the

    European Union systematized the transfer

    of moral hazard from weaker to stronger

    sovereigns. But the bond markets are sig-

    naling that a limit has now been reached.

    The burdens of debt in weak economiesare so large that no European institution

    can pay them except by printing money,

    which frightens any European, especially a

    German, with memories of what inflation

    did to Weimar democracy.

    There is a solution: to confer veto powers

    over national budgets to European institu-

    tions in return for European guarantees on

    the sovereign debts of all states. But this

    requires both strong and weak to surren-

    der economic sovereignty, and it requires

    European electorates to transfer power

    upward to technocrats. The economic prob-

    lem can be solved but only at some consid-

    erable cost to European democracy.

    Europes democratic heritage can sur-

    vive upward transfer of fiscal and monetarypolicy only if other powers are transferred

    downward to the people through devolution

    and only if European institutions remain

    accountable to a pan-European electorate.

    Right now, neither Brussels

    nor national parliaments are in

    charge. It is the markets that are

    dictating terms to European democracy.

    Already the bond market is charging inter-

    est rates for government debt that wil l

    make it impossible for them to dig them-

    selves out of their hole without intervention

    from the ec band the im f. Sovereigns cant

    get credit from the markets, and business

    credit is drying up. The continent faces a

    credit crunch and, if its leaders dont act

    quickly, years of recession.

    Political solutions arewithin reach in

    the form of fiscal and monetary union butthere may no longer be time enough for

    the politicians. Economic solutions also lie

    within reach, but they have been left so late

    that Europe faces a lost decade of declin-

    ing productivity, unemployment, and

    stagnation.

    Crisis, as all politicians know, is an

    opportunity to be seized. Let us hope

    Europe will seize its last chance. The deep-

    er question is why Europe and Europeans

    failed to act so far. Why has a concerted

    political response taken so long? One

    might have thought that a threat of system-

    ic risk to all would coalesce the political will

    to act in common. Not so.

    Years of growth concealed the real

    problem the growing inequality between

    nations, classes, and regions in Europe.

    As long as European economies were all

    growing, increasing inequality could be

    contained. As soon as the economy stopped

    growing, inequality and resentment at

    other peoples better fortune or their fool-

    ishness made a coordinated response to the

    common crisis more difficult.

    It has taken me a long time to appre-

    ciate something my father, a Russian

    immigrant to Canada who came of age

    in the Depression, once told me about hard

    times. When I asked him what it was like

    in the Dirty Thirties, he said that if you had

    a job it was like being on a train: you were

    in the heated parlor car up front while the

    unemployed were in the unheated freight

    cars at the back.

    So it is today.

    When the unlamented Silvio Berlusconi

    was asked how serious the economic cr isis

    POLITICS

    FOR HARD TIMESWho pays for austerity?

    By Michael Ignatieff

    RIGHT NOW, NEITHER BRUSSELS

    NOR NATIONAL PARLIAMENTS ARE

    IN CHARGE. IT IS THE MARKETS

    THAT ARE DICTATING TERMS TO

    EUROPEAN DEMOCRACY.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    11/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    9

    CLAUS GOEDICKE, PFLASTER(FROM THE SERIES SOME THINGS), 2008, INKJET PRINT, 59,4 X 42 CM

    C

    LAUSGOEDICKE

    ,COURTESYGALERIEM

    BOCHUM

    ,GERMANY

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    12/68

    10 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    world. Resource economies like Canada

    and Australia are dependent on Chinese

    demand for commodities. Cash-rich com-

    panies in the developed world are depen-

    dent on the outsourcing opportunities

    and the consumer markets in developing

    nations. Already the outlines of a new divi-

    sion of labor are emerging. When demand

    returns in Europe and North America, jobs

    may not come back for the mil lions of mid-

    dle class North Americans and Europeans

    who grew up working in manufacturing

    and services.

    In an economic crisis, everyone is in

    a flight from risk to security, but no, we

    are not all in this together. Because we

    are not, we are lining up behind radically

    different political solutions. In the United

    States, the Republicans defend austerity

    and deficit cutting to push the costs ofrecession onto the vulnerable, with tax

    cuts designed to render the new inequality

    permanent. This solution class warfare if

    there ever was appeals, paradoxical ly, to

    those who may pay the price for it: private

    sector workers who feel that their taxes

    are being wasted bailing out big banks

    and sustaining inefficient public sector

    jobs. The Democrats want to protect pub-

    lic services and the public sector through

    tax increases on the rich. This appeals to

    workers who either work for government

    or are dependent on public services. Each

    party s approach to the cr isis is not so much

    a solution as an attempt to entrench the

    privileges of the groups that support them

    politically.

    Everywhere the crisis pits those who

    have some security whether it be highincome or protected public service jobs

    against those who do not have secure

    pensions, employment, or prospects.

    Progressive politics in an age of austerity

    comes down to this: persuading the major-

    ity who are doing well whether they are

    nations, classes, or regions that their

    future depends on doing something about

    the large and growing minority, of weaker

    states, poorer regions, and lower income

    groups who are doing badly. A progressive

    politics will have to show that if we are to

    get out of recession, we will have to stick

    together. This will not be easy.

    Germany is a case in point.

    As a result of high labor productivity

    and the welfare states automatic stabiliz-

    ers, Germany has managed the crisis better

    than its European neighbors. Now it feels

    punished for its success by being asked to

    bail out the weaker brethren on the south-

    ern periphery.

    The German political discourse on its

    southern partners recalls what Victorian

    political economists used to say about the

    undeserving poor: your bad habits are

    to blame for your misfortune. Until you

    become frugal, efficient, and abstemious,

    the Germans tell their neighbors, there will

    be no Eurobonds, no bailouts, no interest

    rate socialism, no transfer union.

    But Germany is discovering what the

    rich and strong eventually have to learn:

    the weak can bring you down. Weak states,

    in a currency union, can destroy the eco-nomic prospects of the strong.

    If the bad news is that a recession pits

    strong against weak, rich against poor,

    the good news is that eventually the rich

    whether they be nations, regions, or

    classes discover that their own prosperity

    will be threatened unless they help those

    left behind.

    This is the deeper logic behind German

    moves towards further European inte-

    gration: the strong are discovering their

    interdependence on the weak, and the weak

    are accepting that they have to live within

    disciplines prescribed by the st rong. Even

    now, it is possible to think this lesson can

    be learned in time.

    If inequality is the chief feature of the

    recession, as well as the chief obstacle to

    political action to dig us out, the questionfor progressives is what to do about it. After

    all, what defines a progressive politics,

    whether of a liberal or a social democratic

    variety, is not merely a moral concern

    for the disadvantaged, but the economic

    insight that growth requires equity in order

    to be sustainable. What then are the strate-

    gies that combine equity and growth and

    get us all out of this cr isis?

    Here we need to understand some para-

    doxes. The most serious market fai lure

    since the Great Depression has not engen-

    dered a crisis of faith in markets, sti ll less a

    return to Rooseveltian big government or

    was in Italy, he replied, What cr isis? The

    restaurants in Milan were full. The egre-

    gious Italian had a point.

    The patrons filling the Milanese restau-

    rants do not feel the pain. If you are one of

    the fortunate few with cash in hand, you

    can spend and it costs nothing to borrow. In

    a recessionary economy, cash and liquidity

    are king and these monarchs confer their

    favors on the fortunate alone. Retai lers

    catering to the wealthy have never done so

    well. The cash-rich have not only escaped

    the crisis but gained an increasing share of

    national wealth.

    They are not the only ones who have

    been insulated from hard times. Unionized

    workers in the public sector are better pro-

    tected than non-unionized workers in the

    private sector. Native-born are less likely

    to be let go than immigrants. Skilled fare

    better than unskilled, educated better thanuneducated.

    Germans are better off than Greeks,

    northern Europe is better off than south-

    ern. It is agreeable for Germans to indulge

    their schadenfreude and ressentiment

    towards their feckless southern partners,

    but these emotions may have blinded

    German voters to their true interest: deci-

    sive action to federate Europe and save the

    euro.

    Just as the recession creates winners

    and losers and fragments political consen-

    sus within Europe, it also is creating new

    winners and losers in the global economy

    at large. Just ask Brazilians. Crisis what

    crisis? They have never had it so good. Just

    ask Canadians. Their unemployment rate

    is two percent below the Americans. Their

    banks a heavily regulated oligopoly did

    not fall for the sub-prime scam. In my

    country, the full burden of hard times falls

    squarely on a few shoulders: young people

    without post-secondary education, older

    workers in declining resource and mining

    sectors, recent immigrants, and aborigi-nals. The guilty secret about recessionary

    times is that hard times for the few actually

    mean cheap money and rising house prices

    for the many.

    Yet even those who have held on to their

    jobs fear for the future, and in political

    terms, this produces a flight to security

    and retrenchment. Even the economi-

    cally secure understand that this reces-

    sion is not just a slump in demand but a

    restructur ing of the global economy. We

    are living through the first economic

    recession in which the developing world

    is gaining at the expense of the developed

    WE ARE LIVING THROUGH THE FIRST ECONOMIC RECESSION

    IN WHICH THE DEVELOPING WORLD IS GAINING AT THE EXPENSE

    OF THE DEVELOPED WORLD.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    13/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    11

    economic insecurity among the haves does

    not engender solidarity towards those who

    have not. It engenders a political flight from

    equity towards retrenchment.

    It is commonly said that Occupy Wall

    Street has changed the conversation, placed

    inequality back on the political agenda

    and improved the prospects for progres-

    sive politics. Im not so sure. The slogan

    of Occupy Wall Street, We are the 99 per-

    cent, encourages the illusion that we are

    all in it together, us against a tiny them.

    But we are not all in this together. If we

    were, liberals and progressives would be

    winning the political arguments. But we

    are not. Conservatives are winning because

    they promise stability to those who are win-

    ning. They also indulge those who want to

    punish the losers.

    That much-used phrase moral hazard

    has become a powerful alibi for a politicsof resentment. As an example, one of the

    chief reasons why the American economy

    remains mired in recession is that millions

    of homeowners either cannot pay their

    mortgages or are walking away from mort-

    gages on property that will never be worth

    more than their initial investment. A fed-

    eral program to reduce interest payments

    or write down a port ion of these mortgages

    would get the housing market functioning

    again and stimulate consumption among

    distressed homeowners. Such a measure

    would help Main Street, instead of Wall

    Street, and would be no more expensive

    than aid to the big banks.

    Interestingly, it is just as unpopular as

    measures to help bankers. Your mortgage

    is not my problem was one of the signs

    visible at a recent Tea Party rally in the US.

    A retributive politics, that refuses assis-

    tance to indebted mortgage holders on the

    grounds of moral hazard, wi ll only prolong

    recession. Yet retr ibutive politics is more

    popular than a politics of equality.

    Equally paradoxical is the resistance of

    lower income groups to a politics of equal-

    ity that aims at redist ribution of income

    and progressive taxation. There is anger,yes, at the unprecedented percentage of

    national income that the top one percent

    of earners have secured for themselves

    over the past thirt y years. But even unprec-

    edented inequality of income continues to

    be widely accepted. Top earners argue that

    their incomes are returns on effort, sala-

    Keynesian demand management. It has not

    created a tidal wave in favor of higher taxa-

    tion for the rich, tougher regulation of capi-

    talist enterprise, and more generous social

    protection for the unemployed. On the

    contrary, left-wing governments in Spain,

    Greece, and Ireland have been driven from

    office, and the popular mood is towards

    conservative austerity and retrenchment.

    In Canada, in the federal elec tion of May

    2011, the Liberal Party and I ran on a pro-

    gram to freeze corporate tax cuts, eliminate

    tax loopholes that benefit the super-rich,invest in education, and support family care

    for the majority. It was a fiscally responsible,

    socially progressive program and we were

    rewarded with the worst electoral result

    in generations. I may not have been the

    best possible messenger but notice that the

    message also met with failure. Pervasive

    PfizerDeutschlandGmbH

    Pfizer gets involved

    Because convictionscan change the world

    Our commitment to enhancing the quality of life at every

    age goes far beyond the boundaries of our day-to-day busi-

    ness. With great can-do spirit, our people strive to improve

    the living conditions of people around the world. Here in

    Germany, for example, Pfizer volunteers serve as reading

    mentors at a Berlin primary school. We also support organi-

    zations such as the Henry Maske Foundation, which helps

    provide real prospects to children and young adults, as well

    as many health initiatives. And to protect the environment,

    we use state-of-the-art technology to produce our pharma-

    ceuticals. Every day, this is what we do to realize our vision of

    Working Together for a Healthier World. www.pfizer.de

    PERVASIVE ECONOMIC IN

    SECURITY AMONG THE

    HAVES DOES NOT ENGENDER

    SOLIDARITY TOWARDS THOSE

    WHO HAVE NOT.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    14/68

    12 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    servatives to persuade them that increased

    taxation of the few today will be followed by

    increased taxation on the many tomorrow.

    P

    rogressives should not sulk in

    their tents, believing that we are los-

    ing these arguments simply because

    the other side is more cunning or betterfunded. The fact is that disparities in

    income themselves, especially those that

    are rewards for skill, innovation, and effort

    do not seem morally problematic to most

    people. A progressive politics that attacks

    income inequality itself simply looks like a

    politics of envy to the very people it needs

    to convince.

    A progressive politics ought, I would

    argue, to make clear that income inequality

    in itself is not the issue, but rather inequal-

    ity that inflicts harm to those less fortunate.

    A company president who takes home sub-

    stantial personal compensation in base sal-

    ary plus bonuses tied to performance while

    providing employment to thousands of

    people, together with dividends to investors,

    small and large, ought not to be a morally

    problematic figure for a progressive politics.

    The company president whose compensa-

    tion package does not include any penal-

    ties for failure, and whose risk-taking and

    profit-seeking exposes his employees to

    bankruptcy, while ruining investors and

    sending shock waves throughout the rest of

    the economy is another matter entirely.

    There is overwhelming public support for

    government that protects ordinary citizens,

    as well as their jobs and savings, from the

    predatory risk-taking of the few. Nothing has

    so weakened faith in government than gov-

    ernments failure to do so. Government can-

    not and should not protect or compensate

    individuals and firms from market bets that

    go bad. But it should be there to protect pop-ulations at large from systemic risks. This

    function of government opens up an oppor-

    tunity a progressive politics must now seize.

    It is time for us to bother with the detail of

    firm level regulation regulating executive

    pay, reforming corporate governance so that

    boards protect share holders and employees

    against systemic risk, measures to force

    those who trade large volumes in the market

    to have skin in the game, personal liabili-

    ties that can be called in when their bets fail.

    Instead of fulminating against free mar-

    kets, a progressive politics should be argu-

    ing that what we need are markets that are

    actual ly free. Many of the worst excesses of

    the age of greed occurred in markets thatwere anything but free, anything but trans-

    parent, markets riven by fraud, corruption,

    insider trading, and toxic products that dif-

    fused risk and made it systemic.

    A progressive politics has almost forgot-

    ten its long-standing emphasis on the role

    of government in promoting free market

    competition. We need more, not less, com-

    petition in the market, and that means gov-

    ernments prepared to use their anti-trust,

    anti-monopoly functions going forward to

    dismantle institutions that have become

    too big to fail and whose failure may

    expose the whole economy to calamity.

    ried benefits that come from working long

    hours and taking large risks. Moreover,

    outsized incomes are justified when they

    are the result of innovations that create

    benefits and jobs for society at large. This

    may be true, though it is worth noting that

    the storied achievements of Steve Jobs are

    pressed into service to justify incomes fromthose in finance and speculat ion whose

    public benefit is, to say the least, equivocal.

    Clawing back some of these gains, through

    progressive taxation, it is claimed, would

    harm the many while eliminating valuable

    incentives for the few. The fact that one

    of the worlds most successful investors,

    Warren Buffett, has refuted the claim has

    not silenced those who persist in making it.

    The interesting political fact is that

    these arguments by the privileged few are

    persuasive to the unprivileged many. The

    latter may earn less, but they have aspira-

    tions to earn more. It is easy work for con-

    INSTEAD OF FULMINATING

    AGAINST FREE MARKETS,

    A PROGRESSIVE POLITICS SHOULD

    BE ARGUING THAT WHAT WE

    NEED ARE MARKETS THAT ARE

    ACTUALLY FREE.

    CLAUS GOEDICKE, SCHUHE, FROM THE SERIES SOME THINGS, 2010, C-PRINT

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    15/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    13

    Higher taxation of the rich has an impor-

    tant place in a progressive politics but the

    right rationale for it needs to be restated. We

    do not tax the r ich to punish them for their

    success, or to use them as a cash cow to fund

    social programs. We tax the rich so that they

    pay a fair portion of the public goods that

    account for so much of their private returns.

    Indeed, the most effective political rationale

    for higher taxation on those who can afford

    it is to reduce taxation on those who can

    least afford it. A progressive taxation policy

    is one that should be revenue neutral, i .e. it

    increases burdens on those who can carry

    them and reduces it for those who cannot.

    A free-market progressivism wants to

    reduce taxes on the hard-pressed middle

    class, but it can also reduce taxes by reduc-

    ing the proliferating tax expenditures in

    the form of rebates, credits, and reduc-

    tions in favor of simple across-the-boardcuts. This gets the government out of the

    incentive business and leaves individuals

    more free to determine what incentives to

    give themselves.

    If we want a politics of equality, we need

    to understand also that public discontent is

    not just focused on the top one percent of

    private income earners. It is also focused

    on inequality between public and private

    sector workers, between those who receive

    their income through tax revenue and those

    who do not. Look at the relative success

    that US state governors have had in attack-

    ing public sector unions and their pension

    entitlements. A progressive response has

    to focus both on protecting essential public

    services and the workers who provide them,

    while also reducing the inequality between

    public sector and private sector pension,

    redundancy, and holiday entitlements.

    We should remember that welfare states

    create inequalities of their own, and these

    may get worse in a new age of austerity. If

    we dont understand this, we wil l end up

    with a progressive politics that thinks itis attacking inequality, when it is in fact

    defending privilege, the pensions of public

    sector workers, the tenure of publicly fund-

    ed professors, the subsidies of artistic and

    creative sectors against private sec tor work-

    ers, small business owners, immigrants

    without social protection, and other groups

    who do not benefit equally or in the same

    way from the welfare state.

    The primal political batt le in the years

    ahead will be over who pays for auster-

    ity: the publicly protected or the privately

    exposed. A progressive politics that does

    not understand why retrenchment is

    necessary does not understand the public

    finances of Europe or anywhere else. For

    decades European governments have been

    borrowing more than they could afford

    to sustain the welfare state. The vaunted

    European social model was funded on cred-

    it, and a progressive politics cannot rally

    support behind the defense of the welfare

    state unless it simultaneously embraces the

    need for reform.

    Reform means taking on substantial

    interests public sector unions and pow-

    erful professions like doctors, teachers,

    and nurses, who all perform vital public

    work that must continue but who must

    reform their practices, shed some of their

    privileges, and become more efficient if

    the public goods they provide are to remain

    sustainable.

    Progressives must think through the

    necessary fiscal regime that al lows us tosafeguard equality of opportunity for all,

    while maintaining fiscal balance and a

    level of taxation that doesnt lead to a capi-

    tal strike. Yes, a capital strike is possible.

    In a global economy, welfare states must

    be tax-competitive: your own companies

    can always build Mercedes and Audis

    somewhere else. If they move production

    offshore, you can kiss your welfare state

    goodbye.

    In the face of a g lobal division of labor,

    a progressive politics that slips into protec-

    tionism and defense of declining industries

    condemns itself to the margins of politics.

    The only way forward is to invest in people,

    training, and education, from early child-

    hood right through retirement. In an era

    of declining demographics and rising skill

    levels for all well-paying jobs, a progressive

    growth strategy has to bet everything onsustained investment in education for all.

    Equality of opportunity is the key to future

    growth and the core response of govern-

    ment to the employment challenges thrown

    up by a new global economy is to invest in

    education for all.

    So lets have an economics equal to our

    ethics, an economics of austerity harnessed

    to an ethical conviction that a competitive

    economy absolutely requires that everyone

    gets an equal star t by way of education and

    equal help when fate befalls us, whether

    it be i llness, or unemployment, or misfor-

    tune we cannot master on our own.

    A Social Democrat is perhaps more

    trusting of the state than a liberal like

    myself. It would be good for a progressive

    politics to demystify the state and the val-

    ues of social compassion it is supposed to

    incarnate. Twenty-five years ago, in The

    Needs of Strangers, I argued that the welfare

    state did not express solidarity and compas-

    sion so much as confiscate and bureaucra-

    tize it. We administered solidarity in the

    welfare state. We did not live it or express it

    ourselves.

    We need to understand this now,

    since the welfare state needs more than

    a defense in an age of austerity; it needs

    reform: empowerment of compassion

    rather than its bureaucratization, decen-

    tralization of decision-making rather than

    centralization, market disciplines and

    competition to contain costs, a service

    ethos that treats people as citizens not asnumbers. A progressive does not want to

    end up defending the state. A progressive

    wants to end up promoting a common life

    and equal opportunity for all.

    Let us end with this idea of a com-

    mon life: the infrastructure of public

    goods roads, schools, libraries, hos-

    pitals, training institutes, public transport

    that taxpayers accept to provide because

    they understand that private welfare

    depends critically on an equal structure

    of public goods. These goods express the

    value of the equal worth of citizens, their

    right to benefit in common from facilities

    that each pays for, according to their ability.

    Let us understand the crucial role that

    public goods play in sustaining equal

    opportunity for al l, and let us also under-

    stand how important equal opportunity isfor growth. How are economies supposed

    to grow if societies entrench forms of

    inequality that convince mil lions of people

    new immigrants, ethnic minorities, and

    working-class people that the economic

    game is over for them before it star ts?

    Michael Ignatieff teaches human

    rights and international politics at the

    University of Toronto and is a former

    leader of the Liberal Party of Canada.

    This essay is adapted from a speech

    delivered by Ignatieff at the Einstein

    Forum on December 8, 2011.

    THE WELFARE STATE NEEDS MORE THAN A DEFENSE

    IN AN AGE OF AUSTERITY; IT NEEDS REFORM.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    16/68

    14 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    EMERGENCE AND EXITThe collapse of neoliberal multiculturalism

    By Elizabeth Povinelli

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    17/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    15

    H

    ow do the financial crisis of

    2008 and the ongoing manage-

    ment of the euro crisis bear wit-ness to the emergence of a new phase in

    European and Anglo-American liberal gov-

    ernance? How do these cr ises help us grasp

    what liberal governance has been and what

    it may be becoming? And, perhaps more

    cryptically, whereit has been? Where are

    the geopolitical conditions of liberal gover-

    nance to be found? Are they found within

    the internal social and cultural logics of

    Europe and Anglo-America its Judeo-

    Christian her itage? If so, can liberal gover-

    nance return to its traditions and remake

    the European and Anglo-American world

    as Other to others? Or is liberal governance

    otherwise to itself, such that this separation

    is a dangerous and futile fantasy?

    These are clearly huge social, historical,and philosophical questions. This much

    we can say with some certainty: in the

    immediate wake of the 2008 financial

    crisis, it looked as if liberal governance was

    heading for a significant reconfiguration.

    An earlier economic crisis had aided the

    ascendency of neoliberalism. In order to

    dismantle key components of Keynesian

    liberalism, neoliberal advocates, such as

    Reagan and Thatcher and their advisers,

    took advantage of, and deepened, a crisis

    in capitalism (stagflation) in the context of

    what seemed to be a robust alternative to

    capitalism (the apparently robust commu-WILLIAM CORDOVA, RUBBER, 2006, PENCIL ON PAPER, 135,5 X 179 CM

    Cour

    tesy

    ARNDTBer

    linan

    dthear

    tis

    t

    MORE INVESTED THAN SOVIET

    CITIZENS IN CREATING FAMILIES

    DURING THE WAR, GERMANS

    HAD MORE TO LOSE.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    18/68

    16 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    nist system). But although the conceptual

    underpinnings of neoliberalism were

    explicitly opposed to Keynesianism, they

    were not a return to the prelapsarian world

    of Adam Smiths laissez-faire capitalism,

    no matter how often Smith was placed

    on the neoliberal pedestal. As I put it in

    Economies of Abandonment, neoliberalism

    sought to free the market from the con-

    fines of the market. And as Amartya Sen

    noted in a New York Review of Booksessay,

    Smith never thought that the principles

    of the market should become universal

    principles of human moral sentiment

    and behavior. Indeed, Theory of Moral

    Sentimentsseems to make the case that in

    order for the invisible hand of the market

    to operate effectively and efficiently, lib-

    eralism must preserve distinct domains

    where citizens cultivate non-selfish senti-

    ments. The result of collapsing all socialdomains into a single market logic was

    captured in the opening scene of The Iron

    Lady, in which Margaret T hatcher, played

    by Meryl Streep, is roughly pushed aside in

    a convenience store. The extreme neoliber-

    alist is literally run over by neoliberalism.

    But by the 1990s, even the gov-

    erning left in the US (Clinton) and

    England (Blair) had embraced what

    John Gray of the New Statesmancalled

    the debt-fuelled free market as the

    imperative[s] of democracy . . . destined

    to spread universally. It is not surprising,

    then, that many public commenters saw

    the public humiliation of a befuddled Alan

    Greenspan before the US Congress as the

    symbolic nail in this ideological formation.

    Greenspans shock sounded the death knell

    of neoliberalism as a specific conceptual

    and practical relationship between capital

    markets and liberal governments. Surely

    some new way of organizing the states rela-

    tionship to markets was on the horizon.

    If 2008 spelled the seeming demise

    of neoliberalism, on its heels was the

    demise of state multiculturalism. Some

    forty years af ter 1968, the term we use

    to summarize the effect of a longer set of

    anticolonial and anti-capitalist struggles of

    militant new social movements, the liberal

    governance of social difference in a nation-

    al and international framework was under

    extreme stress.

    T

    o understand what was at stake,

    we need to remember that state mul-

    ticulturalism (the liberal politics of

    recognition) was not the goal of mil itant

    social movements or anti-imperialist move-

    ments. State multiculturalism was the

    response of liberal governance to the threat

    these movements posed to its fundamental

    principles. It was a politics oriented toward

    inclusion, not revolution. It was a multi-

    culturalism whose final horizon remained

    the basic principles of liberalism. Thus

    in his influential essay The Politics of

    Recognition, Charles Taylor placed enor-

    mous emphasis on the moral worth of rec-

    ognizing the cultural and social difference

    even as he placed a limit on the transforma-

    tive potential of this difference. The chal-

    lenge he notes, is how to deal with the

    substantial numbers of people who are citi-

    zens and also belong to a culture that calls

    into question our philosophical boundaries.

    The challenge is to deal with their sense

    of marginalization without compromising

    our basic principles. The desire of these

    marginalized people to be recognized by

    us, and our desire to recognize the worth

    of other cultures where such worth was

    proven worthy was supposedly the rou

    that would thicken the social stew. (Taylor

    is clear that the assumption of worth

    must be then followed by an assessment

    of cultures. If this assessment was not

    part of the dynamics of recognition, then

    recognition would be a hollow gesture.)Like Alan Greenspan, who based an entire

    career on the view of rational self-interest

    as underlying market function only to find

    himself shocked by the irrationality of self-

    interest, so Cameron, Merkel, and Sarkozy

    in Europe, and Howard in Australia, stood

    astounded that rather than the desire for

    recognition, many marginalized com-

    munities desired nothing more than to be

    left alone.

    If we want to know what liberal gover-

    nance is becoming we need to understand

    what it seems or seemed to be exit-

    ing. In the wake of 2008 and a series of

    announcements about the failure of state

    multiculturalism, liberal governance

    seemed to be exiting a nearly fifty-year

    twining of neoliberalism and multicul-

    turalism as the solution to two aspects of

    liberal governance that were in crisis from

    the 1960s through the 1970s: economic

    markets and social dif ference. But, in

    hindsight, it is unclear how this twining

    manifests itself. Let s look closer at the neo-

    liberal ascendency of the market as the sole

    bearer of social evaluation. Celebrations of

    the democratic spring in North Africa have

    occurred almost simultaneously with glob-

    al pundits lauding the ability of so-called

    technocratic governments demanded by

    the financial markets to bypass the demo-

    cratic function in Italy and Greece. And in

    China, the supposed inevitable merging

    of liberal market and liberal governance

    remains a receding horizon even as its eco-

    nomic power suggests new possibilities of

    capital governance. What if we are witness-

    ing the final recession of democracy as the

    necessary sibling of neoliberal markets?

    Even as this dynamic between

    democracy and market is being

    played out, the governance of social

    difference is increasingly an idiom for

    the uneven global distributions resulting

    from the financial cr isis. In Greece we

    see German figureheads of the economic

    bailout portrayed in the idiom of national

    difference. In the US, the Supreme Court

    is poised to dismantle the last of the affir-

    mative action redoubts in higher educa-

    tion, and Republicans are set to roll back

    advances in feminist health and choice

    through the demonization of the sexualrevolution. In France, Muslims; in England,

    members of the African-Caribbean com-

    munity; in Germany, Turks (and those

    assigned to these groups through nothing

    more then epidermal resemblance, as

    recently seen in Germany through the so-

    called Dner Kil lings) are now subject

    to new experiments in liberal governance,

    having not agreed to the denuding of com-

    munity through the techniques of recogni-

    tion. What these experiments will add up

    to and how the experiments of a post-

    neoliberal market will be tall ied remains

    to be seen.

    IF WE WANT TO KNOW WHAT

    LIBERAL GOVERNANCE IS

    BECOMING WE NEED TO

    UNDERSTAND WHAT IT SEEMS

    OR SEEMED TO BE EXITING.

    WHAT IF WE ARE WITNESSING THE FINAL RECESSION OF DEMOCRACY

    AS THE NECESSARY SIBLING OF NEOLIBERAL MARKETS?

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    19/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    17

    But one thing is abundantly clear: the

    transformation of liberal governance does

    not originate from Anglo-American or

    European worlds. Many political scientists

    like to narrate Western liberalism in such a

    way that its logic emerges from the internal

    civilizational dynamics of the West. And

    yet, as I have suggested elsewhere, neolib-

    eral economic theory was able to take root

    in Britain and the US precisely because

    stagnation gripped the Western economies

    in the 1970s. The cause of this stagna-

    tion was, at least in large part, due to the

    Middle East oil embargo and the counter-

    hegemonic power of the Soviet Union and

    its sphere of influence. Moreover, state

    multiculturalism was promoted as a means

    of integrating national difference, not due

    to liberalisms own internal dialectic. State

    multiculturalism was a strategic response

    to the sustained cr itique of Western impe-rialism and colonialism and their influence

    on militant social movements. German

    Chancellor Angela Merkel could attempt

    to create an internal ly coherent Germany

    and a Europe with Christ ian roots pro-

    viding the difference of Western liberalism,

    but these roots were always already react-

    ing to their extension in other worlds. The

    people Merkel lambasts as living among

    Germans are living there because Europe

    and the Anglo-American worlds were made

    as a result of their living through and on

    the material worlds of others.

    In other words, if we wish to understand

    the internal dynamics of liberal governance

    in the West, we must look at its external

    conditions. The authors of liberalisms

    Other are outside liberalism. From the1960s through 2008, liberals could avoid

    the somewhat unpleasant thought that they

    were not the agents of history but the effect.

    After all, the US was ascendant. West

    Germany was testimony to the resilience

    of liberal democracies. Japans threat faded

    into series of lost decades. The South Asian

    Tigers were tamed. And soon the Wall fell

    and a series of pundits, most notoriously

    Francis Fukuyama, announced the End of

    History.

    T

    he West no longer has this

    luxury. The global economic engine

    is shifting and becoming multi-polar.

    Social protests and massive youth unem-

    ployment are the norm. Social dif ference

    is being securitized as the US Congress

    approves the use of drones over US cities.

    The forms of liberal economic and social

    governance emerging in the wake of the

    collapse of neoliberal multiculturalism are

    as likely to come from outside as they are

    from within.

    Elizabeth Povinelli is a professor of

    anthropology and gender studies at

    Columbia University and was the fall2011 German Transatlantic Program

    Fellow at the American Academy.

    MANY POLITICAL SCIENTISTS

    LIKE TO NARRATE WESTERN

    LIBERALISM IN SUCH A WAY

    THAT ITS LOGIC EMERGES FROM

    THE INTERNAL CIVILIZATIONAL

    DYNAMICS OF THE WEST.

    DOMBERT RECHTSANWLTE www.dombert.de

    t g e ts ere c e

    Abfallwirtschaftsrecht

    Agrar-, Forst und Jagdrecht

    Gesundheitsrecht

    Kommunalrecht

    Bauordnungs-, Bauplanungs-

    und FachplanungsrechtRecht der Erneuerbaren Energien

    Energiewirtschaftsrecht

    Emissionshandelsrecht

    Immissionsschutzgesetz

    Recht der Infrastrukturund der ffentl. Daseinsvorsorge

    Recht des ffentl. Dienstes

    Schul-, Hochschul- und Prfungsrecht

    Umweltrecht

    Verfassungsrecht

    Vergaberecht

    Mangerstrae 26 14467 Potsdam Tel.: 0331 - 620 42 70 Fax: 0331 - 620 42 71 [email protected]

    Prof. Dr. Matthias Dombert Janko Gener Dr. Margarete Mhl-Jckel, LL.M. (Harvard) Dr. Helmar Hentschke

    Dr. Klaus Herrmann Dr. Jan Thiele Dr. Konstantin Krukowski Dr. Martin Jansen

    Dombert Rechtsanwltesind bundesweit

    ausschlielich in Fragen des Verwaltungs-

    und Verfassungsrechts ttig.

    Wir beraten private Unternehmen, Verbnde

    und Kammern ebenso wie Landesregierungen,

    Landkreise, Gemeinden und Zweckverbnde.

    Wir sind Anwlte von Unternehmen der

    Ernhrungs- und Lebensmittelindustrie, der

    Energie- und Entsorgungswirtschaft und

    sind fr Planungs- und Bautrger ttig, wie

    fr Umwelt- und Gesundheitsbehrden.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    20/68

    18 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    NAT MEADE, LOCAL HERO, 2011, GOUACHE, WATERCOLOR ON PAPER, 10 X 8 INCHES

    COURTESYTHEARTISTANDFROELICKGALLERY

    ,PORTLAND

    ,OREGON

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    21/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    19

    FOR JOHN LYSAKER

    Horror films have the char-

    acter of dreams. The cinematic

    phantasmagorias hide those

    secret faces we do not willingly or con-

    sciously approach and yet carry within us

    all the time. What we see in such films

    is the mask projected by what we really

    fear. The power of a horror film or the

    best ones, anyway rarely comes from

    the specific events depicted onscreen. Or

    rather, it isnt literally what we see that is

    so disturbing, but what deeper fears the

    figures and events allegorize in the shad-

    ow plays flitting and trembling before the

    audiences eyes. Watching a horror movie

    is a bit like the makeshift pinhole devices

    people use to see an eclipse while avoiding

    looking directly at the event. With a movie

    one realizes that those unspeakable fears

    are not merely ones own merely private

    terrors; we see that others have these as

    well. That means we need not feel so alone.

    Joy we tend to share, but we often keep

    quiet about what terrifies us. Watching a

    horror film provides a means of sharingdarkness both literally and figuratively.

    But what if the fear that we see enacted

    onscreen is a projection of what, at its core,

    is a profound, existential dread of loneli-

    ness? What might that fear of loneliness

    tell us about modern l ife, about how we

    conceptualize who we are and how we

    stand to others?

    Although it first appeared in 1999, The

    Sixth Sense, one of the most popular andlucrative horror movies ever made, has

    remained lodged in the general conscious-

    ness. There are any number of reasons why

    it continues to linger, but I suggest it lies in

    the specific anxiety that the film not only

    represents, but also engages. Thus, the

    horror of The Sixth Sense really has little to

    do with the ghosts that appear onscreen

    these might surprise from time to time,

    but they arent that terrify ing. And unlike

    The Exorcist orThe Omen, the theology or

    metaphysics arent likely to be too unset-

    tling or dredge up a latent dread of forces

    beyond our control, to which we are none-

    theless subject. Instead, the horror ofThe

    Sixth Senseis born of the familiarity with

    loneliness that the film represents. Beyond

    that, perhaps the pervasive condition of

    loneliness represented on the screen and

    reflected back to the audience is not only

    recognizable, but we are already lost within

    its folds. This dread, this profound, creep-

    ing fear is worth looking at.

    The Sixth Sensebegins with trauma, a

    trauma that the protagonist only learnsto recognize at the very end, and yet what

    might be more harrowing is not that

    moment of crisis, but rather the revela-

    tion of what his life has become. Near the

    beginning of the film, child psychologist

    Malcolm Crowe (played by Bruce Wil lis)

    is gunned down in his own home after

    celebrating with his wife, Anna (Olivia

    Williams), the fact that he had been given

    a prestigious award in recognition of sig-nificant contributions to his field and to the

    families and children in his care. Crowes

    wife makes clear to her husband, and to the

    audience, that the award means others had

    noticed all the sacrifices Crowe had made,

    putting everything after his work, even

    their marr iage. Given the movies popular

    success, I will not recount the plot in its

    entirety, and it is sufficient to say that in the

    midst of this celebration, the Crowes are

    surprised by a former patient, now an adult,

    who has broken into their home and who

    is brandishing a pistol. The intruder fires

    at Crowe, wounding him, and then shoots

    himself. With the next scene the film

    jumps to some later point in time whether

    it be days, weeks, or years later, we cannot

    say when Crowe is seated outside on abench reviewing his notes on a new case.

    What we do not yet know is that Crowe is

    now already dead. His new case, the one

    he is reviewing, concerns a little boy who

    we know the famous line sees dead

    people. The boy, Cole (played by Haley Joel

    Osment), will later tell Crowe that he sees

    the dead everywhere, and their problem is

    that they do not know they are dead. This

    information will become poignant when

    it is revealed in the movies final act that

    Crowe is himself one of these revenants

    lacking any realizat ion of what he has

    become.

    ON LONELINESSThe unbearable lightness of being alone

    By Richard Deming

    WATCHING A HORROR MOVIE IS A BIT LIKE THE MAKESHIFT

    PINHOLE DEVICES PEOPLE USE TO SEE AN ECLIPSE WHILE

    AVOIDING LOOKING DIRECTLY AT THE EVENT.

    THE HORROR OFTHE SIXTH SENSE

    IS BORN OF THE FAMILIARITY

    WITH LONELINESS THAT

    THE FILM REPRESENTS.

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    22/68

    20 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    Throughout the fil m, Cole

    and Crowe ask each other what they

    would most like to change about

    their respective lives. Crowe poses this as

    part of his methodology; Cole poses the

    question to his interlocutor. Cole wishes

    he did not see the dead; Crowe wishes he

    and his wife could communicate. Even

    as a ghostly counselor, however, Crowe

    teaches Cole that he must listen to the

    ghosts, as they crave acknowledgment.

    Cole learns to listen to the dead, and as

    a result they no longer attack him. He is

    able to do the things that provide them

    some measure of peace, as when he

    delivers a videotape to a grieving father

    of a murdered (by poison) little girl that

    incriminates the girls own mother. Cole

    not only speaks to the dead, he speaks for

    them as well. At some level, we might see

    Cole as embodying a form of wish fulfill-ment. Who wouldnt want to be able to

    have some proxy who would deliver bad

    news or confront people for us?

    While the movie presents this as a

    better existence for Cole, in reality he

    is not given much choice. He can either

    not listen to the dead and be attacked by

    them and shunned by the living, or he

    can devote his li fe how is this not a sac-

    rifice? to undertake their affairs in order

    to let them come to rest, a burden he can-

    not rightly be said to have taken up on his

    own. Cole becomes popular at school with

    his new relationship to himself and to his

    own burdens; he no longer avoids people

    either living or dead. Is this a happy end-

    ing? Cleary, it is meant to be, but the fact

    that he has no real choice complicates that

    happiness.

    Coles insights into others, insights

    that come with his acknowledging the

    ghosts, lead him to suggest to Crowe a

    method of how Crowe, who as yet still

    hasnt discovered he is dead, might speak

    with his wife. Cole suggests talking to herwhile she is asleep, presumably thereby

    permeating the boundaries between

    dreaming and wakefulness.

    What makes Th e Sixt h Sense

    something more than just a big-

    budget version of a Hollywood

    B movie is how it presents loneliness and

    isolation as a source of horror. At first, lone-liness seems to be a generalized condition,

    an atmosphere permeating everything that

    happens. Throughout the movie, before it

    is revealed that Crowe himself is actually a

    ghost, we see a growing distance between

    Crowe and his wife they do not speak,

    never make eye contact, never touch. In

    one poignant scene, he arrives late anddistracted to what seems to be an annual

    visit to their restaurant, the spot where he

    first proposed to Anna. He misses dinner

    entirely and yet instead of dealing with the

    significance of his being late, all he can talk

    about is how the work with his patient Cole

    is not going well. She gives absolutely no

    response. Later, we discover why.

    Such missed opportunities recur

    throughout the film. Anna is often found

    asleep in front of the television, the vid-

    eotape of their wedding and reception

    flickering on the screen. At one point, she

    receives and begins to return romantic

    Nat Meade builds upon historic painting genre and technique with modern references

    drawn from television and other entertainment sources. His character studies deliver

    quirky fellow humans with frailty and humor. If Edward Hopper is presenting a scene

    that recalls a theatrical per formance, Meade says, my paintings recall a televised

    Sunday afternoon movie. . . . My figures are sympathetic victims, victims of light and

    shadow, as well as victims of a scenario that exists outside the captured moment.

    Meade teaches drawing and painting at the graduate and undergraduate levels at the

    Pratt Institute in Brooklyn, New York.

    NAT MEADE, SNEAKER, 2012 OIL ON LINEN, 18 X 14 INCHES

    COURTESYTHEARTISTANDFROELICKGALLERY

    ,PORTLAND

    ,OREGON

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    23/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    21

    intentions of a young man. These events

    are all recontextualized when we discover

    that the entire time Crowe is a ghost that

    only Cole, and the audience, can see. This

    revelation stuns not only Crowe, but theviewer as well. The moment Crowe real-

    izes this, we are reminded in a voiceover

    that Cole had said the dead do not real-

    ize they are dead, because they only see

    what they want or expect to see. This is

    meant to be a comment about Crowe, of

    course, but the implications extend past

    the screen. Just as Crowe missed all the

    signals, the audience has also missed

    certain clues, in part because the silence

    and emotional distance between Crowe

    and his wife seem completely recogniz-

    able. Their behavior serves, we think, as

    evidence of any marriage that is disinte-

    grating. Because the two partners cannot

    or simply do not know how to communi-

    cate, they lose the capacity to acknowledge

    one another. Most viewers will perceive

    the emotional distance throughout thefilm as being so familiar it need not be

    questioned, so much so that the revelation

    that Crowe was dead comes as a stun-

    ning surprise. How could we miss the

    cues? Perhaps because we are like Crowe

    already; we see only what we expect . This

    implies two things: 1) that such utter lack

    of acknowledgment is a kind of death; 2)

    we are each of us intimately knowledge-

    able about how such distance looks and

    feels; and 3) not only may things not be

    what we take them for, we may not be who

    we take ourselves to be. Crowes blindness

    becomes our insight.

    This identification betw een

    Crowe and the viewer goes deep, and

    this is where the horror comes forth.

    That is to say, Crowes crisis is a shared

    one. Crowe doubles the audience in another

    way: just as he cannot directly engage the

    living world, the audience cannot disturb

    what happens onscreen. While it is true

    that films often make viewers into voyeurs,

    in this case, the members of the audience

    are not peeping toms, but ghosts haunt-

    ing a world we can watch but not take part

    in, just like the ghosts Cole sees. In other

    words, our loneliness, which is the mea-

    sure of distance between ones self, sitting

    there in a darkened theater or at home, and

    the others that one sees despite the fact

    that these others are, in this case, figures

    onscreen becomes manifest in our rela-

    tionship to the events we can observe and

    have feelings about, yet cannot affect.It is important to think about how we

    respond to Crowe and his disconnection

    from his wife and from Coles mother

    because this impacts how we think of the

    ending of the film. Crowe is able to move on

    once he has accepted that he is in fact dead;

    he all but states as much. The movie clearly

    offers what is supposed to be a sentimental

    ending that resolves the tensions we have

    just witnessed. And yet what kind of reso-

    lution is this? Are we meant to think, Ah,

    they werent unable to communicate their

    feelings, he was just a ghost. It is too late to

    really accept such a reading of the end since

    the audience has to reckon with the fact

    that the gulf between Crowe and his wife

    looked just like an all too ordinary emotion-

    al gulf. The loneliness that we have seen

    and accepted all along, that alienation and

    estrangement equated to a kind of death, isonly resolved when Crowe acknowledges

    that there is nothing more that he can do

    about it.

    Ultimately w e could see

    Crowes acknowledgement as an

    acceptance of that which most

    people continually deny as much as pos-

    sible mortality. Crowe can move on when

    he acknowledges that there is nothing he

    can do about his being limited by the flesh.

    In a sense he becomes cured of this denial

    of his limitations, that which makes us

    human something each of us wrestles

    NAT MEADE, LOCAL HERO, 2012, OIL ON LINEN, 18 X 14 INCHES

    CROWES BLINDNESS

    BECOMES OUR INSIGHT.

    COURTESYTHEARTISTANDFROELICKGALLERY

    ,PORTLAND

    ,OREGON

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    24/68

    22 | The Berlin Journal | Number Twenty-Two | Spring 2012

    NAT MEADE, STUDY (PANTRY), 2011, GOUACHE, WATERCOLOR ON PAPER

    COURTESYTHEARTISTANDFROELICKGALLERY

    ,PORTLAND

    ,OREGON

  • 8/10/2019 Berlin Journal 22

    25/68

    Spring 2012 | Number Twenty-Two | The Berlin Journal

    |

    23

    with or outright denies al l of the time. Yet,

    the sentimentality of the ending doesnt

    seem to offer real satisfaction. In part, the

    ending is not consoling because Crowe

    and his wife only acknowledge one another

    and she not consciously because she is

    asleep in order to move into further sepa-

    ration. Just as the film ends, the audience

    too is allowed to leave the haunted space of

    the theater and return to the waking world.

    Yet do we move back into the general con-

    dition of estrangement from others that

    we have just seen depicted? Crowe had to

    die in order to acknowledge his condition,

    to transform that isolation into a kind of

    solitude. The choice, the movie could sug-

    gest, might be ours. Will we be like Crowe

    and accept our profound alienation? Or are

    we meant to be like Cole and be mediators

    between the estranged and the situations

    that cause others such grief that they can

    neither accept a given situation of loneli-

    ness and separation or leave it? But again,

    what is more