bertsimas 2011) fairness-efficiency kidney transplantation

Upload: panos-toulis

Post on 06-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    1/47

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    2/47

    Fairness, Efficiency and Flexibility in Organ Allocation for

    Kidney Transplantation

    Dimitris Bertsimas Vivek F. Farias Nikolaos Trichakis

    October 12, 2011

    Abstract

    We propose a scalable, data-driven method for designing national policies for the allocation

    of deceased donor kidneys to patients on a waiting list, in a fair and efficient way. We focus

    on policies that have the same form as the one currently used in the U.S. In particular, we

    consider policies that are based on a point system, which ranks patients according to some

    priority criteria, e.g., waiting time, medical urgency, etc., or a combination thereof. Rather

    than making specific assumptions about fairness principles or priority criteria, our method offers

    the designer the flexibility to select his desired criteria and fairness constraints from a broad

    class of allowable constraints. The method then designs a point system that is based on the

    selected priority criteria, and approximately maximizes medical efficiency, i.e., life year gains

    from transplant, while simultaneously enforcing selected fairness constraints.

    Among the several case studies we present employing our method, one case study designs

    a point system that has the same form, uses the same criteria and satisfies the same fairness

    constraints as the point system that was recently proposed by U.S. policymakers. In addition,

    the point system we design delivers an 8% increase in extra life year gains. We evaluate the

    performance of all policies under consideration using the same statistical and simulation tools

    and data as the U.S. policymakers use. Other case studies perform a sensitivity analysis (for

    instance, demonstrating that the increase in extra life year gains by relaxing certain fairness

    constraints can be as high as 30%), and also pursue the design of policies targeted specifically

    at remedying criticisms leveled at the recent point system proposed by U.S. policymakers.

    MIT Sloan School of Management, [email protected] Sloan School of Management, [email protected] Business School, [email protected]

    1

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    3/47

    1. Introduction

    Renal or kidney transplantation and maintenance dialysis are the only treatments for end-stage re-

    nal disease (ESRD), a terminal disease affecting over 500, 000 people currently in the United States,

    see USRDS (2009). Despite b eing a major surgical procedure, transplantation is the treatment of

    choice for ESRD patients, as a successful transplantation improves their quality of life. In particular,

    dialysis treatment requires that the patient visits a dialysis center for at least 12 hours each week,

    whereas transplantation typically allows the patient to resume regular life activities. Furthermore,

    a multitude of research and clinical studies have statistically demonstrated that transplantation

    also reduces the mortality risk for patients, see Suthanthiran and Strom (1994), Schnuelle et al.

    (1998), Port et al. (1993), Ojo et al. (1994). Thus, a kidney transplant is considered by many as a

    potentially life-saving gift.

    The two sources of kidneys for transplantation are living donors (e.g., family members or friends

    of the patient) and deceased or cadaveric donors. The majority of patients are unsuccessful in finding

    living donors, and thus join a pool of patients waiting for a deceased donor organ. Of course, while

    in the living donor case the donation is typically made to a specific patient, in the deceased donor

    case an important allocation problem arises. In particular, once an organ is procured from a

    deceased donor, there can be thousands of medically compatible and available recipients the organ

    can be allocated to. The problem becomes even more significant, if one accounts for the organ

    shortage and the size of the pool of waiting patients in the United States: On October 20th 2010,

    86, 391 patients were waiting for a kidney transplant. In 2009, there were 33 , 671 new additions, but

    only 16, 829 transplantations were performed, from which 10, 442 transplants were from deceased

    donors. For more information and statistical details we refer the reader to UNOS (2010).

    In recognition of the aforementioned allocation problem and the growing difficulty of matching

    supply and demand, the U.S. Congress passed the National Organ Transplant Act (NOTA) in 1984.

    According to this legislation, deceased donor organs are viewed as national resources in the U.S.,

    and as such, their allocation has to be based on fair and equitable policies. Moreover, the sale of

    organs as well as money transfers of any nature in the acquisition of organs are strictly prohibited.

    Instead, the policy for allocating the organs should utilize waiting lists and have the form of a

    priority method. That means that patients in need of a transplant register on waiting lists. Then,

    2

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    4/47

    once an organ is procured, all medically compatible patients are ranked according to some priority

    rules and the organ is successively offered to them according to their ranking, until it is accepted by

    a patient. Subsequent to the NOTA, the U.S. Congress established in 1984 the Organ Procurement

    and Transplantation Network (OPTN) in order for it to maintain a national registry for organ

    matching and develop allocation policies.

    Naturally, the aforementioned allocation policies are of central importance and have to accom-

    plish major objectives in alleviating human suffering, prolonging life and providing nondiscrimina-

    tory, fair and equal access to organs for all patients, independent of their race, age, blood group

    or other peculiar physiological characteristics. Some of the main challenges in designing a kidney

    allocation policy are the following:

    Fairness constraints: What does fair and equal access to organs mean? Due to the subjectivenature of fairness, there is no single fairness criterion that is universally accepted by policy-

    makers and academics alike. As such, a great challenge lies in identifying the appropriate

    fairness constraints that the allocation outcomes of a policy should ideally satisfy. An exam-

    ple of such a constraint could be a lower bound on the percentage of organs allocated to a

    particular group of patients say, requiring that at least 47% of all transplants are received by

    recipients of blood type O. In the absence of such a constraint these groups would otherwise

    be handicapped and not have access to organs because of their physiological characteristics.A number of such criteria have been studied by OPTN policymakers (see OPTNKTC (2008),

    RFI (2008)).

    Efficiency: As a successful transplantation typically prolongs the life of a patient, while also

    improving his quality of life, the policy needs to ensure that the number of quality adjusted

    life year gains garnered by transplantation activities is as high as possible. This is also in

    line with the view of organs as national resources. Again, this objective is of paramount

    importance to the current policy design, see OPTNKTC (2008).

    Prioritization criteria: The policy needs to be based on medically justified criteria and phys-

    iological characteristics of patients and organs in order to rank patients. However, ethical

    rules disallow the use of criteria that can be deemed as discriminatory (e.g., race, gender,

    etc.).

    3

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    5/47

    Simplicity: Patients need to make important decisions about their treatment options, together

    with their physicians. To this end, they need to be able to estimate the probability of receiving

    an organ, or at least understand the allocation mechanism. For that reason, the priority

    method that is used needs to be simple and easy to communicate.

    Implementation: Suppose that one has selected the desired fairness constraints, prioritization

    criteria and a simple priority method. How does he then balance the emphasis put on the

    different prioritization criteria, so as to design a policy whose allocation outcomes would

    maximize efficiency, while satisfying the fairness constraints?

    All the above challenges were faced by the OPTN policymakers in 2004, when they initiated

    the development of a new national allocation policy that will eventually replace the current one. In

    2008, the OPTN released a concrete proposal in a Request for Information publication (RFI (2008))

    that is currently under consideration by the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services.

    In this work, we deal with the implementation challenge in designing a national allocation

    policy, while accounting for all the other challenges above. In particular, we focus on perhaps the

    simplest, most common and currently in use priority method, namely a point system. We make

    the following contributions:

    1. We present a novel method for designing allocation policies based on point systems in a

    systematic, data-driven way. Our method offers the flexibility to the policymaker to select

    the fairness constraints he desires, as well as the prioritization criteria on which the point

    system will be based on. The method then outputs a conforming point system policy that

    approximately maximizes medical efficiency, while satisfying the fairness constraints.

    2. To validate our proposed method, we utilize it to design policies under different scenarios

    of interest to OPTN policymakers. Under a particular scenario, we design a policy that (a)

    matches the fairness constraints of the recently proposed policy by U.S. policymakers, and (b)

    is based on the same criteria and simple scoring rule format. Critically though, it achieves an

    8% increase in anticipated extra life year gains, as demonstrated by our numerical simulations,

    which are based on the statistical and simulation tools currently in use by U.S. policymakers

    (see below).

    4

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    6/47

    3. We use our method to perform a sensitivity analysis that explores the consequences from

    relaxing or introducing fairness constraints for instance, what is the impact of reducing the

    percentage of transplants to patients on dialysis for greater than 15 years by 1%? In the

    case of some constraints, relaxations of fairness constraints can result in life year gains on the

    order of 30%. As such, we believe this is a valuable tool in the policy design process.

    4. This paper makes a methodological contribution to the area of Approximate Dynamic Pro-

    gramming. In particular, we develop a means of designing approximately optimal policies in

    problems of dynamic allocation that are massively high dimensional. In particular, these are

    allocation problems where the number of classes of objects being allocated, and the num-

    ber of bins these objects may b e allocated to are themselves intractably large. A previous

    approach to this issue has simply been clustering these classes so as to arrive at a problemwith, say, tens of classes of objects. This approach is a non-starter in the context of designing

    real (as opposed to stylized) policies for organ allocation, and we provide a viable alternative

    that requires no clustering whatsoever.

    Performance in all our numerical studies is evaluated using the same statistical and simulation tools,

    as well as data, as the U.S. policymakers use. Those tools and datasets were obtained directly from

    their developers, namely the United Network for Organ Sharing (UNOS), which is the non-profit

    organization that operates the OPTN, and the Scientific Registry of Transplant Recipients (SRTR).

    The structure of this paper is as follows. In the next subsection, we review relevant work in the

    literature. Section 2 provides background information on the distribution of organs, the current

    allocation policy, as well as updates on the recent development of a new proposed policy. In Section

    3, we discuss our method for designing allocation policies in detail. Section 4 includes numerical

    evidence of the usefulness of our work through the design of new policies under multiple case

    studies, including a sensitivity analysis, and the evaluation of their performance via simulation.

    We conclude in Section 5 with an overview of future prospects for the approach delineated in thispaper. A list of acronyms used appears at the end of this paper.

    1.1. Literature Review

    The model-based analysis of the organ allocation process has attracted significant interest in the

    academic literature. One of the first papers in this vain is by Ruth et al. (1985), in which the

    5

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    7/47

    authors develop a simulation model to study the problem. Shechter et al. (2005) also introduce

    a discrete event simulation model for the evaluation of potential changes to the liver allocation

    process. In this work, we utilize the simulation model developed by the SRTR, see KPSAM (2008).

    The organ allocation process was also analyzed by Righter (1989) and David and Yechiali (1995)

    via a stochastic assignment problem formulation. In their work, they analyze stylized models that

    fit into that framework. In this work, we also utilize an assignment problem formulation, but only

    for the training phase of our methodology: the output allocation policies of our framework are

    rather simple, based on scoring rules and in full compliance with policies that U.S. policymakers

    consider, unlike the above referenced work. In a similar vein, Zenios et al. (2000) introduce a fluid

    model approximation of the organ allocation process that allows them to explicitly account for

    fairness and medical efficiency in the allocation. Our framework accounts for fairness in accordance

    with the considerations of policymakers. Zenios (2002), Roth et al. (2004), Segev et al. (2005) and

    Ashlagi et al. (2011) study the problem of living donation and the allocation of kidneys. Kong et al.

    (2010), Sandikci et al. (2008) and Akan et al. (2011) also tackle the problem of liver allocation.

    Another stream of research focuses on the decision-making behavior of patients, by dealing with

    organ acceptance policies. David and Yechiali (1985) model the candidates problem as an opti-

    mal stopping problem. Similar acceptance policies are developed by Ahn and Hornberger (1996),

    Howard (2002), Alagoz (2004) and Alagoz et al. (2007). The present paper will test policies on a

    simulator developed by SRTR for OPTN; this simulator assumes a specific, exogenous acceptance

    model for patients built from historical data. While the acceptance model ignores endogeneity, it

    allows us to simulate outcomes in precisely the manner policy makers currently do.

    Recent work by Su and Zenios (2005, 2004) attempts to combine the above streams of research

    by explicitly accounting for the acceptance behavior of patients in the development of an allocation

    policy. In a similar vein, Su and Zenios (2006) propose an allocation mechanism that elicits the

    utilities of the patients. For more details, we refer the reader to the thorough review by Zenios

    (2005).

    In all the above referenced work dealing with organ allocation policies, the authors design

    general near optimal dynamic policies. These papers take the important perspective of designing

    a fundamentally new allocation system from the ground up. In our work, we restrict our attention

    to policies that comply with the precise constraints imposed by current practice. That is, we focus

    6

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    8/47

    our attention on policies based on simple point systems of the precise format as the ones currently

    in use and proposed by U.S. policymakers. Moreover, instead of designing a particular policy, we

    develop a framework that admits various fairness constraints and prioritization criteria. In other

    words, we design a mechanism that can fit directly in the current decision-making process of the

    U.S. policymakers.

    2. Distribution and Allocation Policies

    In this section, we briefly review the distribution process and the operation of the UNOS/OPTN

    as coordinators and developers of national policies for the allocation of deceased donor kidneys to

    patients. We then discuss the requirements such policies need to meet, and focus on policies that

    are based on point systems or scoring rules. Finally, we review the current policy in use in the U.S.

    (which itself is based on a scoring rule), as well as updates on the development of a new scoring

    rule based national policy.

    In the U.S., the non-profit Organ Procurement Organizations (OPOs) are directly responsible

    for evaluating, procuring and allocating donated organs within their respective designated service

    area. Once consent is obtained and an organ is procured by an OPO, the OPTN computerized

    national registry automatically generates a list of patients, who are medically compatible with the

    procured organ. Medical compatibility of patients is determined by their physiological characteris-

    tics and those of the procured organ (e.g., accounting for ABO incompatibility1, weight and size,

    unacceptable antigens, etc.). Subsequently, the priority method used by the OPO determines the

    order in which the organ will be offered to patients. Once a kidney is procured, it can be typically

    preserved for up to 36-48 hours, after which the organ can no longer be used for transplantation.

    For that reason, priority is given to local patients, although there are rules that determine when

    priority should be given to non local patients. After an offer is b eing made to a patient, he has

    to decide with his surgeon whether to accept it or not within a limited amount of time. In case

    of rejection, the organ is offered to the next patient according to the specified order and so on. In

    case no patient accepts the organ within 36-48 hours, the organ is discarded.

    In addition to using the OPTN national registry, the activities of the OPOs, and their allocation

    1ABO incompatibility is a reaction of the immune system that occurs if two different and not compatible bloodtypes are mixed together, see http://www.nlm.nih.gov/medlineplus/ency/article/001306.htm.

    7

    http://www.nlm.nih.gov/medlineplus/ency/article/001306.htmhttp://www.nlm.nih.gov/medlineplus/ency/article/001306.htm
  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    9/47

    policies in particular, are coordinated and regulated by the OPTN. That is, the OPTN provides

    general guidelines and lays out a national allocation policy that is suggested to all OPOs. The

    allocation policy of every OPO then needs to be consistent with the national policy, although

    minor alterations are possible subject to approval by the OPTN.

    2.1. National Allocation Policies

    National policies for the allocation of the deceased donor kidneys are developed by the OPTN

    Kidney Transplantation Committee (KTC), and are approved by the U.S. Department of Health &

    Human Services. Policies need to account for numerous legal, economic, institutional, ethical, and

    other societal factors; the requirements for an allocation policy are included in the OPTN Final

    Rule (DHHS (2000)). Below we summarize the most important guidelines that policies have to

    conform to as per the OPTN Final Rule. In particular, the allocation

    (a) shall seek to achieve the best use of donated organs, and avoid organ wastage;

    (b) shall set priority rankings based on sound medical judgment;

    (c) shall balance medical efficiency (extra life years) and equity (waiting time), without discrim-

    inating patients based on their race, age and blood type;

    (d) shall be reviewed periodically and revised as appropriate.

    Additionally, the priority method in place needs to be simple and easy to communicate, as

    discussed in the Introduction. As such, the ranking of patients is typically achieved by means of a

    point system or scoring rule: all national allocation policies that have been used in practice have

    been based on scoring rules. We formally define next the notion of a scoring rule based policy and

    then discuss the current national policy and suggested revisions.

    Point system or Scoring rule based policies. Under a policy based on a scoring rule, patients

    are ranked according to a calculated score, commonly referred to in this context as the Kidney

    Allocation Score (KAS). Specifically, a scoring rule consists ofscore components and scalar constant

    score weights. A score component can be any function of the characteristics of a patient and/or an

    organ. Then, once an organ is procured and needs to be allocated, one calculates the individual

    score components for each patient and the particular procured organ. The KAS for each patient

    8

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    10/47

    is evaluated as the weighted sum of his score components (using the score weights). To introduce

    some notation, given a patient p and an organ o, we denote the jth score component with fj,(p,o),

    and the jth score weight with wj . The KAS of patient p for receiving organ o, KAS(p,o), is then

    calculated as

    KAS(p,o) =j

    wjfj,(p,o).

    For instance, examples of score components can be the number of years the patient has b een

    registered on the waiting list for, the life expectancy of the patient in case he remained on dialysis,

    or the life expectancy in case he received the procured organ, etc.

    One can think of a scoring rule based policy as a priority method that awards points to patients

    based on different criteria (the score components); patients are also potentially awarded different

    amounts of p oints per criterion, based on the score weights. The ranking is then achieved based

    on the number of points collected by each patient. The current policy in use and the one recently

    proposed by U.S. policymakers are both examples of scoring rule based policies and are discussed

    next.

    Current allocation policy. The current policy has been in existence for more than 20 years.

    It is based on a scoring rule that utilizes waiting time, a measure of the patients sensitization 2

    and tissue matching3 of the organ and the patient as score components. The rationale behind

    this rule is as follows. Points are given for waiting time and sensitization in order to serve the

    fairness objective of the allocation and to provide equal access to organs to all patients (note that

    highly sensitized patients have reduced medical compatibility with donors). On the other hand,

    since tissue matching is an indication for a successful transplantation, the points given to matched

    patients serve the medical efficiency objective of the allocation. For more details we refer the reader

    to ODADK (2010).

    Recent advances in medicine and changes in patients needs however, have rendered the current

    policy inappropriate. More specifically, these changes have rendered the current policy inconsistent2Potential recipients are sensitized if their immune system makes antibodies against potential donors. Sensitiza-

    tion usually occurs as a consequence of pregnancy, blood transfusions, or previous transplantation. Highly sensitizedpatients are more likely to reject an organ transplant than are unsensitized patients. For more information, seehttp://www.ustransplant.org/

    3When two people share the same human leukocyte antigens (abbreviated as HLA), they are said to be amatch, that is, their tissues are immunologically compatible with each other. HLA are proteins that arelocated on the surface of the white blood cells and other tissues in the body. For more information, seehttp://www.stanford.edu/dept/HPS/transplant/html/hla.html

    9

    http://www.ustransplant.org/http://www.stanford.edu/dept/HPS/transplant/html/hla.htmlhttp://www.stanford.edu/dept/HPS/transplant/html/hla.htmlhttp://www.ustransplant.org/
  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    11/47

    with the OPTN Final Rule, see Norman (2009) and RFI (2008). For instance, the long waiting

    times experienced by the patients, coupled with advances in medicine that have prolonged the

    survivability of patients on dialysis, have resulted in the accumulation of points for waiting time

    by the patients. This accumulation of points has then created an imbalance between the efficiency

    and fairness objectives of the allocation, see OPTNKTC (2007). In response to that, and in line

    with the requirement of the OPTN Final Rule for periodic review of the policy, the KTC has been

    reviewing the policy for the past few years and is currently in the process of developing a new

    policy, see OPTNKTC (2007).

    Development of a new policy. Since 2004, the KTC has considered more than 40 different

    scoring rules, which involve various score components, see OPTNKTC (2010). We first discuss

    the criteria upon which the score components are based, and then discuss the components. For a

    patient p and an organ o, the criteria are

    1. Tissue matching or HLA matches, i.e., the number of HLA shared by patient p and organ o;

    2. Age of patient p and/or donor of organ o, denoted by AGE(p) and AGE(o);

    3. Wait time, which is equal to the number of years patient p has been registered at the waitlist;

    4. Dialysis time, which is equal to the years patient p has spent on dialysis, denoted by DT(p);

    5. Blood group of patient and/or donor;

    6. Expected post transplant survival of patient p from receiving organ o;

    7. Expected waitlist survival of patient;

    8. Life years from transplant, denoted by LYFT(p,o), which is equal to the expected incremental

    quality-adjusted life years gain of patient p from receiving organ o, compared to remaining

    on dialysis (for a precise definition, we refer the reader to Wolfe et al. (2008));

    9. Donor profile index, denoted by DPI(o), which is a number between 0 and 1, indicating the

    quality of the donated organ (0 corresponds to an organ of highest quality);

    10. Calculated panel reactive antibody, denoted by CPRA(p), which is a number between 0 and

    100, measuring the sensitization of the patient (0 corresponds to the lowest level).

    10

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    12/47

    A typical scoring rule proposed by the KTC includes 3-5 score components that are functions of

    (some of) the above criteria. In most cases, the components are either linear functions (e.g., points

    are awarded per year on dialysis, or per life year from transplant, etc.), or nonlinear functions

    of one or more criteria (e.g., for patient p and organ o, points are awarded according to (1

    DPI(o)) LYFT(p, o), or DPI(o) DT(p), or |AGE(p) AGE(o)|, etc.), including stepwise or

    indicator functions (e.g., points are awarded if patient p is highly sensitized, CPRA(p) 80, or if

    he is aged less than 18 or 35, AGE(p) 18 or 35, etc). For more details, we refer the reader to

    OPTNKTC (2007), OPTNKTC (2008).

    As mentioned above, the KTC considered more than 40 different scoring rules, each of which

    utilizes a subset of the score components above. Furthermore, based on simulation experiments,

    the KTC evaluated the performance of the proposed scoring rules and identified weights that were

    deemed appropriate (see OPTNKTC (2008)). The dominant proposal up to this point, published in

    2008 in a Request For Information document (RFI (2008)), entails the following score components:

    LYFT (1 DPI), DT DPI, DT and CPRA. The associated score weights are 0.8, 0.8, 0.2 and

    0.04. That is, the Kidney Allocation Score under the dominant proposal is

    KAS(p,o) = 0.8 LYFT(p,o) (1 DPI(o))

    + 0.8DT(p) DPI(o)

    + 0.2DT(p)

    + 0.04 CPRA(p).

    The first two components are the life years from transplant and dialysis time, scaled by the donor

    profile index. The scaling ensures that in case of a high quality organ (DPI close to 0), emphasis

    is given on life years from transplant, whereas in case of a low quality organ (DPI close to 1),

    emphasis is given on dialysis time. The last two components are the dialysis time and calculated

    panel reactive antibody score of the patient. More information and motivating aspects can be found

    within the Request For Information document (RFI (2008)). As an example, consider an organ o of

    medium quality, with DPI(o) = 0.55. Then, patients are awarded 0.8 (1 0.55) = 0.36 points for

    every quality adjusted incremental life year they would gain in expectation, 0 .8 0.5 5 + 0.2 = 0.64

    points for every year they have spent on dialysis, and 0.04 points for every point of their CPRA

    11

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    13/47

    score.

    While medical expertise and the OPTN Final Rule can guide the identification of the score

    components of clinical validity, the task of finding the right selection or subset of these components

    and the appropriate weights is more involved, as the experimentation of the OPTN KTC with

    more than 40 different rules suggests. A natural question in response to the proposed scoring rule

    is whether this is the best we can do. In particular, does there exist another scoring rule of the same

    format, based on the criteria and score components considered by policymakers, that dominates

    the proposed one, i.e., is equally or more fair and more efficient? Admittedly, this is an involved

    question to answer; to illustrate this, consider only changing the weights in the proposed scoring rule

    above. The outcomes by such a change can p erhaps be evaluated only via simulation; simulating

    a single specific scoring rule takes hours. This severely curtails the efficacy of a search for a policy

    that while p ossessing the requisite fairness properties is also efficient. Our proposed methodology

    provides a valuable tool in this search and takes a step towards answering the questions posed

    above.

    3. Designing Allocation Policies

    We propose a method for designing scoring rule based policies for the allocation of deceased donor

    kidneys to patients. Specifically, we propose a data-driven method that computes in a systematicway score weights associated to pre-specified score components, so that the resulting policy achieves

    a near-optimal medical utility (measured by life years from transplant gains). In other words,

    after one has decided upon the components he wishes to include in a scoring rule, our method

    utilizes historical data to efficiently compute associated weights, so as to maximize the efficiency

    of the policy. In addition, our method can also take as input fairness constraints on the allocation

    outcomes; while we defer the precise definition of the class of admissible constraints for Section 3.1,

    we note here that our method captures a multitude of important and commonly studied constraintsof interest to policymakers. Then, the method computes the score weights, so that the resulting

    policy is as efficient as possible, and the fairness constraints are approximately satisfied.

    Figure 1 illustrates the functionality of the proposed method. Typically, policymakers select

    their desired score components that would feature in the scoring rule and constraints that the

    allocation outcomes need to satisfy. Our method provides an efficient, scalable and systematic

    12

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    14/47

    score weights

    historical data

    score components

    fairness constraints

    Figure 1: An illustration of the functionality of the proposed method.

    way of striking the right balance between the selected score components by designing a policy that

    approximately maximizes medical efficiency, subject to the selected constraints.

    As an application of our method, we use historical data from 2008, to construct multiple scoring

    rule based policies that utilize the same criteria for components as the ones considered by the OPTN

    Kidney Transplantation Committee. Within the different case studies we present, we also design a

    policy that possesses similar fairness characteristics with the KTC dominant proposal. Numerical

    studies then suggest that this policy constructed by our method achieves an 8% improvement

    in life years from transplant, using the same statistical and simulation tools and data as U.S.

    policymakers use. Furthermore, we perform a trade-off analysis by considering deviations from the

    fairness constraints of the proposed policy. In particular, we study the effect in life year gains of

    the policy, in case of emphasizing or deemphasizing the priority given to patients who have beenwaiting for a long time or are sensitized. Our method efficiently redesigns policies accordingly.

    The results indicate that the performance gain in life years from transplant can be as high as 30%.

    Details on the case and simulation studies are included in Section 4.

    We next present our proposal in full detail.

    3.1. Methodology

    Given a list of n score components, related historical data of patients and donated organs charac-teristics, and constraints on the allocation outcomes (precisely defined below), we calculate score

    weights w1, . . . , wn, such that the resulting scoring rule policy satisfies the constraints approxi-

    mately, while maximizing life years from transplant.

    Consider a fixed time period over which we have complete (ex facto) information about all

    patients registered in the waitlist (pre-existing and arriving) in that time period. In particular,

    13

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    15/47

    we know their physiological characteristics, the time of their initial registration, as well as the

    evolution of their medical status and availability for a transplant during that time period. Suppose

    we also have complete information about the organs that are procured during the period, that is

    the time at which they are procured and their physiological characteristics. We index the patients

    by p = 1, . . . , P and the organs by o = 1, . . . , O. We say that patient p is eligible to receive organ

    o, or equivalently that the patient-organ pair (p,o) is eligible for transplantation, if at the time of

    the organ procurement all conditions below are met:

    1. The patient is registered at the waitlist for a transplant;

    2. The patient is actively waiting for a transplant and his medical status is appropriate for

    transplantation;

    3. The patient is medically compatible with the organ.

    Let C be the set of patient-organ pairs eligible for transplantation, i.e.,

    C = {(p,o) : patient p is eligible to receive o} .

    Note that one can construct C simply by using the arrival information and characteristics of the

    organs and the patients, and the evolution of the availability and medical status of the patients.

    Additionally, one can also compute the score components for each eligible patient-organ pair,

    as well as the life years from transplant. Let fj,(p,o) be the value of the jth component score,

    j = 1, . . . , n, and LYFT(p,o) the life years from transplant for pair (p,o) C.

    We now define the class of admissible constraints on the allocation outcomes, alluded to thus

    far. First, let x(p,o) be defined for every eligible patient-organ pair (p,o) as

    x(p,o) =

    1, if organ o is assigned to patient p,

    0, otherwise.

    A constraint is admissible for our method if it is linear, that is if it can be modeled as a linear

    constraint with respect to variable x. The class of constraints that can be modeled in this way is

    very broad, and captures the majority of constraints a policymaker might wish to incorporate; for

    instance, one can impose lower bounds for a specific group of patients on

    14

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    16/47

    the probability of receiving a transplant,

    the average life years from transplant gained among the actual transplant recipients,

    the average time spent on dialysis among the actual transplant recipients.

    As an example, a lower bound L on the number of organs allocated to a specific group of patients

    G {1, . . . , P }, can be expressed as

    pG

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) L.

    For instance, setting G to be the set of all patients of blood type O could enforce a lower bound on

    transplants for patients of this blood type.

    We denote the input fairness constraints with Ax b, for some matrix A and vector b. We now

    present our method which consists of three steps:

    Step 1 (An Idealized Matching Problem): Consider a social planner with foresight who has

    knowledge of the set of all eligible pairs C and the life years from transplant score for every pair in

    the set. Suppose also that patients accept all organs offered to them. In this setup, the problem of

    allocating organs to patients so as to maximize medical efficiency, i.e., life years from transplant,

    subject to fairness constraints Ax b, can be formulated as a linear optimization problem:

    maximize

    (p,o)C

    LYFT(p,o)x(p,o)

    subject to

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 1, p

    p:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 1, o

    Ax b

    x 0.

    (1)

    Note that a fractional value for x(p,o) can be interpreted as the probability of assigning organ o

    to patient p in a randomized policy. Its solution suggests an allocation with perfect hindsight

    (as opposed to an implementable policy). The next two steps will use this idealized solution to

    construct an implementable policy in a unique way.

    Step 2 (Dual Information): By linear optimization duality, if y is the vector of optimal dual

    15

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    17/47

    multipliers associated with the constraints Ax b for problem (1), then problem (1) is equivalent

    with the one below:

    maximize

    (p,o)C

    LYFT(p,o)x(p,o) yTAx + yTb

    subject to

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 1, p

    p:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 1, o

    x 0.

    (2)

    Note that problem (2) is a matching problem. We equivalently rewrite the objective of (2) as

    cTx + yTb, utilizing the cost vector c defined as

    c(p,o) = LYFT(p,o)

    yTA(p,o)

    , (p,o) C.

    We next use this dual information to construct an implementable policy.

    Step 3 (Approximate Dynamic Programming): Note that our goal is to design a policy that

    approximately solves the above matching problem online, i.e., a policy that sequentially matches

    organs at their time of procurement to available patients without utilizing any future information.

    An implementable policy will require the following:

    1. An estimate of the value of assigning a particular organ, o to a particular patient, p (tech-

    nically, one may think of this as a differential value function for the associated stochastic

    optimization problem).

    2. An interpretable formula for the above differential value that uses permissible features of the

    patient and organ in a clinically acceptable way. Our goal is to rank patients not by any

    artificial score coefficients, but rather based on the selected score components.

    One possible policy is scoring potential allocations on the basis of the coefficients c(p,o) computed

    above. Unfortunately, the c(p,o) coefficients are calculated for patients on the waiting list and

    received organs from some historical data set and as such it is likely that we will not have access

    to c(p,o) for all pairs (p,o) moving forward. More importantly, a scoring policy based on these

    coefficients will not satisfy the second requirement above. As such, we consider using the coefficients

    16

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    18/47

    to inform the calibration of an acceptable scoring rule. In particular we find acceptable score weights

    w by solving the optimization problem

    minimize (p,o)C

    c(p,o) w0 n

    j=1

    wjfj,(p,o)

    2

    subject to w S,

    where the set S enforces clinical and ethical requirements (for instance, by requiring that the

    resulting policy be continuous or monotone in certain score components, etc.).

    The method is summarized as Procedure 1.

    Procedure 1 Computation of score weights

    Input: list of n score components, data for linear constraints (A, b), historical data: set of eligible

    patient-organ pairs C, life years for transplant LYFT(p,o) and values of score components,fj,(p,o), j = 1, . . . , n, for every eligible pair (p,o).Output: weights for scoring rule, w1, . . . , wn.

    1: solve problem (1)2: y vector of optimal dual multipliers associated with constraints Ax b

    3: c(p,o) c(p,o) = LYFT(p,o)

    yTA(p,o)

    , (p,o) C

    4: use (potentially constrained) linear regression to find w0, w1, . . . , wn, such that for all (p,o) C

    c(p,o) w0 + w1f1,(p,o) + . . . + wnfn,(p,o).

    3.2. Discussion

    In this section, we discuss (a) why one should expect the proposed method to perform well in

    practice, and (b) the relative merits of our contribution.

    Consider the airline network revenue management setting analyzed in Talluri and van Ryzin

    (1998). In that setting, an airline is operating flights and is selling different itinerary tickets

    to incoming customers, so as to maximize net expected profits from sales subject to capacity

    constraints (which correspond to the numbers of seats on the different aircrafts operating the

    flights). The authors analyze a simple control policy that decides whether to sell an itinerary

    ticket to a passenger or not, and demonstrate that the policy is asymptotically optimal under some

    conditions. For the organ allocation problem, a simplified version of the policy that we described

    in the previous section can be cast in the same framework as in Talluri and van Ryzin (1998);

    17

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    19/47

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    20/47

    3. From a methodological p erspective our approach can b e seen as a contribution to approxi-

    mate dynamic programming techniques in general and bid-pricing methodologies for dynamic

    allocation in particular. More precisely, bid pricing methodologies exist for the dynamic allo-

    cation of a potentially large set of objects arriving randomly over time and each of which can

    be classified into a smallnumber of distinct types, to a small set of bins, each with potentially

    large capacity. In the kidney allocation context the heterogeneity in patients and organs pre-

    cludes classifying either into a small number of types. Our methodology shows how to deal

    with this problem and in general extends bid price methodologies to scenarios where arriving

    objects and bins are highly heterogeneous.

    4. The failure of the current kidney allocation policy in place to keep up with advances in

    medicine and the changes in patients needs throughout the years, has demonstrated that insuch a dynamic and complex environment, revisions to policies are likely to be required in the

    future as well, a fact that is also recognized by the OPTN Final Rule. Furthermore, even in

    the current process of developing a new policy, there is no guarantee that the Office of Civil

    Rights will approve the criteria of life years from transplant, dialysis time, etc., suggested by

    the OPTN policymakers. In both cases, our method will expedite the development of a new

    policy, as it would require only an updated list of score components and fairness properties

    to be specified.

    5. Our method allows for sensitivity analysis; specifically, one can efficiently evaluate the out-

    comes of relaxing some or introducing new fairness constraints. In the next section, we provide

    such an analysis that reveals the dependence of medical efficiency on fairness concepts, and

    illustrate how it can be used in practice by policymakers. In particular, note that one of the

    main goals that the OPTN policymakers have set for a new national policy is to deempha-

    size the role of waiting time and increase medical efficiency (see Section 2.1). Our analysis

    provides a characterization of the trade-offs involved.

    In the next section, we provide numerical evidence of the usefulness of the described method. In

    particular, we use historical data to design multiple new scoring policies under different scenarios

    and also perform a sensitivity analysis.

    19

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    21/47

    4. Numerical Evidence and the Design of New Allocation Policies

    We utilize the method described in the previous section to design new scoring-rule based policies

    for kidney allocation that have different fairness requirements and/or are based on different score

    components. Specifically, we consider various fairness requirements and score components derived

    from policies that have been proposed by the OPTN Kidney Transplantation Committee (see

    Section 2.1), to set up 4 realistic case studies. Briefly, the intent and outcomes of these case studies

    are as follows:

    1. Case Study 1: Here we demonstrate the utility of our approach in finding policies using

    precisely the set of score components utilized by the current dominant proposal considered

    by the KTC (referred to also as the KTC p olicy or proposal in this section). Using the

    methodology of the previous section we require the approach to preserve the fairness properties

    of the dominant proposal. In addition to finding a policy that is de facto clinically valid in an

    automated fashion, the policy designed provides life year gains of approximately 3% relative

    to the dominant proposal, in spite of being so heavily constrained. This demonstrates the

    value of the approach in designing policies given requirements on fairness, and a small set of

    score-components.

    2. Case Study 2: Here we allow policies that can potentially be based on all score components

    considered by policy makers but continue to require the fairness properties of the dominant

    proposal. As described in the previous Section, we impose constraints on our methodology

    to guarantee that the resulting scoring rule is clinically valid. Our methodology produces a

    policy that in addition to being clinically valid and exhibiting similar fairness properties as

    the dominant proposal provides an 8% increase in life year gains relative to that proposal. In

    addition to the merits exhibited via the first case study, this demonstrates the value of the

    approach vis-a-vis the task of guiding the selection of a small but appropriate set of score

    components from a large family of potential score components.

    3. Case Studies 3 and 4: Similar to the previous study, this study requires fairness criteria

    that correspond to a perhaps more balanced allocation of organs among different age groups

    of patients (as opposed to the dominant proposal which has been criticized as providing too

    few transplants to older age groups). Surprisingly, we develop a clinically acceptable p olicy

    20

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    22/47

    that allays these criticisms of the dominant proposal while providing essentially the same

    life years gains as the dominant proposal. This demonstrates the value of our methodology

    vis-a-vis designing policies that must satisfy stringently specified fairness criteria. We further

    consider various relaxations of the fairness criteria and construct corresponding policies to

    show how our approach allows policy makers to perform a sensitivity analysis relative to

    fairness requirements.

    To ensure a fair comparison, we evaluate the performance of all policies we study by using the

    same statistical models and tools, as well as datasets with the OPTN KTC policymakers. We first

    provide details about the data and models, and then present our methodology and results.

    4.1. Data, Statistical Models and Tools

    This work uses highly detailed historical data from the Scientific Registry of Transplant Recipients

    (SRTR). The SRTR data system includes data on all donor, wait-listed candidates, and transplant

    recipients in the U.S., submitted by the members of the Organ Procurement and Transplantation

    Network (OPTN). The datasets include all the various physiological and demographic characteris-

    tics of wait-listed patients and donors that are needed for our study, as well as the evolution of the

    medical status of the patients, and the arrival process of the donated organs.

    In addition, the SRTR has developed sophisticated survivability models for ESRD patientsusing historical survival rates. The models provide an estimate for the anticipated lifespan of a

    patient in case he remained on dialysis, or in case he received a particular kidney, based on a

    plethora of physiological attributes (e.g., the patients age, body mass index, diagnosis, as well

    as tissue matching, the donors age, cause of death, etc.). For more information and a detailed

    study of the statistical performance of the models, we refer the reader to Wolfe et al. (2008) and

    Wolfe et al. (2009). The SRTR has also developed an acceptance model that predicts the probability

    of a particular patient accepting a particular organ offered to him, based on the physiologicalcharacteristics of the patient and the donor, the distance, etc.

    The above datasets and statistical models have also been utilized by the SRTR in the devel-

    opment of the Kidney-Pancreas Simulated Allocation Model (KPSAM). The KPSAM is an event-

    driven simulator that simulates the entire allocation process using historical data, for different

    allocation policies. It was developed in order to support studies of alternative policies. The KP-

    21

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    23/47

    SAM is the platform that the OPTN KTC is utilizing to evaluate the performance of their proposed

    policies, see OPTNKTC (2007). For more details on the data and the simulator, we refer the reader

    to Waisanen et al. (2004) and KPSAM (2008).

    For the purposes of this study, we obtained the KPSAM and utilized its simulation engine

    in order to obtain realistic allocation outcomes of the policies we consider. The life years from

    transplant gains are estimated using the aforementioned survivability models, embedded in the

    KPSAM.

    4.2. Methodology

    We perform 4 case studies of designing scoring rules that have different fairness requirements

    and/or are based on different score components. In all studies we design allocation policies using

    our method described in Section 3. Recall that our method outputs scoring rules, given as input

    historical data, fairness requirements and score components. We discuss the specific fairness re-

    quirements and score components of each case study separately (see below). For historical data, we

    use the first 6 months of data of the 2008 SRTR database as input to our method (training data).

    To evaluate the performance of a policy, we use the KPSAM to simulate the allocation outcomes

    of that policy 100 times, over the remaining 6 months of the 2008 dataset that were not used as

    training data. To evaluate efficiency, we record the average number of transplantations occurring

    and the average net expected life years from transplant (along with sample standard deviation).

    To compare fairness properties across different policies, we compare the percentage distribution of

    transplant recipients across different races, age groups, blood types, sensitization groups, as well as

    diagnosis types and years spent on dialysis. Note that this practice is in line with the comparison

    criteria studied by the OPTN policymakers (see OPTNKTC (2008), RFI (2008)). As such, we also

    record the average aforementioned percentage distributions for the 100 simulation runs (along with

    sample standard deviations).

    We next present the case studies and discuss our results. In the first study, we design a policy

    that utilizes the exact same score components as the dominant KTC policy, while exhibiting the

    same fairness properties. Similarly, we also design a policy that is based on the exact same score

    components as another policy considered by the KTC. In the second and third case studies, we

    consider all score components and criteria studied by the KTC (see Section 2.1), and actually use

    22

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    24/47

    our method to select a subset of them, while enforcing the same fairness properties as the KTC

    policy (Case Study 2), or alternative fairness properties (Case Study 3). The fourth case study

    deals with a trade-off analysis, where we further study deviations from the fairness properties of

    the KTC proposed policy and their consequenses to efficiency.

    4.3. Case Study 1

    We design two policies that are based on the same score components as two specific policies proposed

    by KTC, including the dominant proposal. We enforce the policies to have the same fairness

    properties as the dominant KTC proposal.

    Score components. We use (a) the same score components as in the KTC policy, namely (1

    DPI) LYFT, DPI DT, DT, CPRA, and (b) the same score components as in another KTC

    proposed policy5, namely (1 DPI2) LYFT, DPI2 DT, DT, CPRA.

    Fairness constraints. We require the two policies to have the same fairness properties as the

    dominant KTC proposal. To enforce that, we simulate the KTC policy and record the percentage

    distribution of transplant recipients across the different groups discussed above. We then use those

    recorded percentage distributions as input constraints. More specifically we use them to input

    lower bound constraints on the percentage of organs allocated to the following groups: Caucasian,

    African-American, Hispanic or patients of another race; patients aged between 18-35, 35-50, 50-

    65 and above 65 years; patients who have spent less than 5, 5-10, 10-15 or more than 15 years

    on dialysis; blood type O, A, B, AB patients; patients diagnosed with nephritis, hypertension,

    polycystic kidney disease, diabetes or other disease; patients with a sensitization level (CPRA) of

    0-10, 10-80 or 80-100. For instance, consider the fairness constraints pertaining to dialysis time.

    The recorded p ercentage distribution of recipients for the KTC policy is as follows: 54% of the

    recipients have spent less than 5 years on dialysis, 29 .5% between 5-10 years, 11.1% between 10-15

    5One of the policies considered by the KTC entailed an allocation score similar to the score of the dominant KTC

    policy, but with the DPI term replaced by DPI

    2

    .

    23

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    25/47

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    26/47

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    27/47

    percentage of transplant recipients

    65 yr

    nephritis

    hypertension

    polycystic

    other

    diabetes

    CPRA 0-10

    CPRA 10-80

    CPRA 80-100

    0 20 40 60

    Figure 3: Simulated average percentage distributions of recipients across different sensitization, diag-nosis and age patient groups for the benchmark KTC policy (blue) and the policies designed in Sections4.3-4.4, i.e., in Case Study 1(a) (cyan), in Study 1(b) (yellow) and in Study 2 (red). The results are foran out-of-sample period of 6 months in 2008.

    26

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    28/47

    This case then demonstrates that our method reliably designs policies that perform well based on

    input that is directly related to outcomes (fairness constraints) and permissible score components.

    In contrast, given a set of score components, the approach of policymakers in designing policies has

    traditionally been to first identify weights and then observe (simulation based) outcomes; and then

    go through those steps multiple times if necessary. This is obviously not ideal; a fact demonstrated

    amply by policy (a) designed via our methodology above. Thus, our contribution enables the design

    of policies in a more natural and powerful way by considering the desired outcomes directly. In the

    next case study we show how our method can be used to select appropriate score components as

    well.

    4.4. Case Study 2

    In this case study, we design a policy that has the same fairness properties as the dominant KTC

    policy and is based on criteria and score components considered by the KTC. Specifically, we allow

    the policy to use any (small) subset of those criteria and components. In addition by imposing

    the appropriate constraints in the third (regression) phase of our methodology we ensure that

    the resulting policies are clinically valid (i.e., they conform qualitatively to features of past KTC

    policies/ recommendations).

    Score components. Rather than pre-selecting specific score components, we feed the regression

    step of our method with virtually all score components considered by the KTC (see Section 2.1).

    However, in accordance with the format of KTC policies, we eventually pick only the 4 most

    significant components, which prove to be: LYFT, a continuous piece-wise linear function of DT

    (with potential break points at 5 and 10 years), CPRA and a step-wise function of patient age

    (with potential break points at 50 and 65 years) that gives additional points for passing 50 years of

    age, and 65 years of age. These last two score components are in line with KTC proposals, and in

    fact, make the policy highly desirable by addressing certain ethical issues raised over equity across

    age groups as we discuss later.

    Fairness constraints. As in Case Study 1, we enforce the policy to have the same fairness

    properties as the dominant KTC policy.

    Results. The output of our method is the scoring rule assigning the Kidney Allocation Score to a

    27

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    29/47

    KTC policy Case Study 2 Case Study 3

    number of transplantations (std) 5, 799 (23) 5, 807 (22) 5, 822 (24)net life years from transplant (std) 34, 217 (185) 36, 890 (219) 34, 065 (212)

    Table 2: Simulation results of the KTC policy and the policies designed in Case Studies 2 and 3 inSections 4.4-4.5, for an out-of-sample period of 6 months in 2008 and 100 runs.

    patient-organ pair (p,o) of

    KAS(p,o) = LYFT(p,o) + g (DT(p)) + 0.08 CPRA(p) + 0.5 I (AGE(p) 50) ,

    where I is the indicator function and

    g (DT) =

    0.65DT, 0 DT 5,

    DT 1.75, 5 DT 10,

    0.2 DT + 6.25, 10 DT.

    According to the above scoring rule, patients are awarded 1 point for every life year from transplant

    gain, 0.08 points per point of their sensitization score, 0.5 points if aged more than 50 and points

    based on their dialysis time as follows: 0.65 points for the first 5 years, 1 point for every additional

    year up to 10 years and 0.2 points for every additional year beyond that.

    The simulation results are reported in Table 2 and Figures 2, 3. Sample standard deviations

    for the percentage distributions are included in the Appendix.

    Discussion. In this case study we attempt to address the question: given all the score components

    and criteria we can use and the fairness properties of the KTC policy, can we design a policy

    that is based on some of those components, has the same fairness properties but is more efficient?

    The results demonstrate that our method is indeed capable of doing so, as the policy we design

    delivers an 7.8% increase in life year gains in comparison to the KTC policy. The score components

    our policy uses are all based on components and criteria the KTC has already considered and are

    discussed next.

    The designed policy awards points according to life years from transplant (LYFT), dialysis

    time (DT), sensitization level (CPRA). The policy also uses a step-wise score component based

    on patient age that has the same form as the component pertaining to sensitization in the current

    28

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    30/47

    policy in use, see UNOS (2010). Note also that the policy uses patient age in a manner that

    allays critiques of earlier KTC proposals. In particular, age has b een used by the KTC primarily

    to direct more or higher quality organs to younger patients for efficiency purposes. For instance,

    the allocation policy currently in use in the U.S. gives priority to pediatric patients (aged less

    than 18 years) for organs procured from donors aged less than 35, whereas proposals suggest to

    extend priority to patients aged less than 35 as well. This may be perceived as providing an undue

    advantage to younger patients. In contrast, the way our policy utilizes age is in the other direction.

    That is, to impose fairness, the policy awards points to patients aged more than 50 to compensate

    for the fact that they typically obtain smaller LYFT scores.

    Futhermore, note that the score component pertaining to DT is continuous piece-wise linear.

    We present here the use of a piece-wise linear function for the following reasons: (a) to illustrate

    how our method can deal with a variety of functions for score components, and (b) the preference of

    some members of the KTC for continuous functions6, due to the concern that discontinuities might

    grant patients who are slightly above a particular threshold (or breakpoint) a disproportionate

    advantage compared with patients slightly below that threshold, see OPTNKTC (2007). Note

    however, we found that in all policies presented in this work, one can interchangeably use step-wise

    and piece-wise functions (delivering statistically indistinguishable performance).

    Finally, this case study demonstrates how our method is capable of calibrating multiple score

    components simultaneously and distilling the ones that are important. In the absence of an algo-

    rithmic method, such a task might be strenuous or even impossible to carry out.

    4.5. Case Study 3

    We present a case study similar to Case Study 2, but with different fairness requirements. We

    enforce the same fairness properties with the KTC policy, but require the percentages of recipients

    aged 50-65 and above 65 to be equal to the percentages of patients at the waitlist aged 50-65 and

    above 65 respectively. This requirement results in an (additive) increase of around 17 p ercentage

    points for organs allocated to patients aged 50 and above. This increase is balanced by a pro-rata

    decrease in the number of organs allocated to recipients aged between 18 and 50. We require

    this at the outset in response to comments made by a UNOS Ethics Committee in OPTNKTC

    6However, note that step-wise score components are utilized in the current allocation policy.

    29

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    31/47

    (2008) that observed that the dominant KTC proposal resulted in a decrease in the proportion of

    transplants among patients in the 50-65 and 65 and older age groups. The question that remains

    is whether the life year gains provided by the dominant proposal can be retained using a clinically

    acceptable policy that unlike the dominant proposal, does notresult in a large change in the fraction

    of transplants among older age groups.

    Score components. As in Case Study 2, we use LYFT, a piece-wise linear function of DT (with

    break points at 5 and 10 years), CPRA and a step-wise function of patient age (with break points

    at 50 and 65 years).

    Fairness constraints. We enforce the policy to have the same fairness properties as the domi-

    nant KTC policy, but with a different age distribution requirement. In particular, the p ercentage

    distribution of patients according to age for the KTC policy is: 5% for patients aged less than 18,

    20.4% for patients aged 18-35, 32.4% for patients aged 35-50, 30.7% for patients aged 50-65 and

    11.5% for patients aged above 65. For our policy, we require the percentages of organs allocated to

    patients aged 50-65 and above 65 to be 41% and 17.8% respectively (note that those were preci-

    cely the percentages of patients aged 50-65 and above 65 in the waitlist in 2008). Accordingly, we

    require the percentages of organs allocated to patients aged 18-35 and 35-50 to be 14% and 22 .2%

    respectively.

    Results. The output of our method is the scoring rule assigning the Kidney Allocation Score to a

    patient-organ pair (p,o) of

    KAS(p,o) = LYFT(p,o) + h (DT(p)) + 0.12 CPRA(p) + 2.5 I (AGE(p) 50) + I (AGE(p) 65) ,

    where

    h (DT) =

    0.75DT, 0 DT 5,

    DT 1.25, 5 DT 10,

    0.5 DT + 3

    .75

    ,10 DT

    .

    The simulation results are reported in Table 2 and Figure 4. Sample standard deviations for the

    percentage distributions are included in the Appendix.

    Discussion. This case study, alongside the next one, illustrates how our method deals with

    alternative fairness constraints. In particular, we consider the same setup as in Case Study 2,

    30

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    32/47

    percentage of transplant recipients

    65 yr

    nephritis

    hypertension

    polycystic

    other

    diabetes

    CPRA 0-10

    CPRA 10-80

    CPRA 80-100

    A

    AB

    B

    O

    0-5 yr

    5-10 yr

    10-15 yr

    >15 yr

    african american

    hispanic

    caucasianother

    0 20 40 60

    Figure 4: Simulated average percentage distributions of recipients across different race, dialysis time,blood type, sensitization, diagnosis and age patient groups for the policy designed in Section 4.5, i.e.,in case study 3 (yellow). The target distributions are also depicted (blue). The results are for anout-of-sample period of 6 months in 2008.

    31

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    33/47

    but introduce a change in the required age percentage distribution of recipients. Our method

    successfully redesigns a conforming policy.

    The change in the age distribution we consider is motivated by comments made by a UNOS

    Ethics Committee in OPTNKTC (2008). Based on the fact that, in comparison with current

    practice, the new KTC policy would direct a higher number of organs, or organs of higher quality, to

    younger patients, the committee argued that the KTC policy might have an unintended consequence

    of a decrease in living donor transplants for younger patients, who typically have higher LYFT

    scores. In response to that, in this case study we design a policy that has a more balanced age

    distribution, which actually resembles the age distribution of patients in the waitlist. Perhaps this

    consideration is just only one plausible way of addressing the concern raised by the committee.

    Nevertheless, it is presented here only to illustrate the flexibility of our method, rather than tackle

    this particular issue.

    Finally, note that in comparison with the KTC policy our policy allocates more organs to elder

    patients, a fact that could significantly undermine efficiency. However, both policies deliver almost

    identical life year gains (see Table 2), which again illustrates that our method is capable of designing

    efficient policies.

    4.6. Case Study 4

    In our final case study we demonstrate how our method can be used to perform a sensitivity analysis

    with respect to imposed fairness constraints. Specifically, we explore the dependence of life years

    from transplant gains on the priority given for dialysis time and sensitization.

    To this end, we consider a similar setup as in Case Study 2, but we relax the constraints

    pertaining to patient groups of different dialysis time, i.e., constraints (3), as well as to patient

    groups of different sensitization level. The relaxation is controlled by a slack parameter. We then

    study the dependence of life year gains on that parameter.

    Score components. As in Case Study 2, we use LYFT, a piece-wise linear function of DT (with

    break points at 5 and 10 years), CPRA and a step-wise function of patient age (with break points

    at 50 and 65 years).

    Fairness constraints. We use the same fairness properties with the dominant KTC policy, but

    we first relax only the constraints pertaining to dialysis time. The relaxation is performed by

    32

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    34/47

    introducing a slack parameter s in the percentage requirements of recipients of different groups,

    that is, the relaxed constraints take the form

    p: 0DT(p)5

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 54 s

    100

    (p,o)C

    x(p,o),

    p: 5DT(p)10

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 29.5 s

    100

    (p,o)C

    x(p,o),

    p: 10DT(p)15

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 11.1 s

    100

    (p,o)C

    x(p,o),

    p:DT(p)15

    o:(p,o)C

    x(p,o) 5.4 s

    100

    (p,o)C

    x(p,o).

    (4)

    Clearly, for s = 0 one would recover the policy that was designed in Case Study 2. For s > 0,

    the requirement on matching the percentage distribution (with regard to patient groups of different

    dialysis time) achieved by the KTC policy is relaxed. Thus one should expect that policies designed

    with such relaxed requirements would achieve higher life years from transplant gains. Using our

    method, we design policies for various values of the slack parameter s and quantify how the gains

    in medical efficiency depend on deviations from the selected fairness constraints. Secondly, we

    follow the same procedure to examine the dependence of medical efficiency on the priority given to

    sensitized patients. We again use all the constraints as in Case Study 2, but this time relax only

    the constraints pertaining to patient groups of different sensitization levels. The relaxation is again

    performed using a slack parameter s. Note that one can potentially perform a sensitivity analysis

    through many other different ways of relaxing the constraints; for illustration purposes we focus

    here only on the described method of uniformly relaxing the constraints by a slack parameter.

    Results. The results we obtain in the aforementioned scenarios are depicted in Figure 5. The

    figure shows the life years from transplant gains (for the 6 month period we consider) of policies

    designed with relaxed constraints on patient groups of different dialysis time or sensitization, for

    various values of the slack parameter s. The figures also depicts the operational point of the KTC

    policy, that is for s = 0.

    Discussion. Comparing the two scenarios we considered, one can observe that the dependence of

    medical efficiency is stronger on dialysis time. Also, the life years from transplant gains can be as

    high as 44, 300 years, which are 30% larger than the gains of the KTC policy. Note that although

    such a policy might not be implementable, the analysis can provide insights to policymakers and

    33

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    35/47

    slack parameter s (in %)

    lifeyearsfrom

    transplantgains(inthousandsofyears)

    50

    0

    10

    10 15

    20

    20 25

    30

    40

    50

    Figure 5: Simulated life years from transplant gains for policies (designed by our method) with relaxedconstraints on all patient groups of different dialysis time (solid) or sensitization (dashed), for variousvalues of the slack parameter s; for more details see Section 4.6. The results are for an out-of-sampleperiod of 6 months in 2008. The marker corresponds to the operational point of the policy proposed bythe UNOS policymakers.

    34

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    36/47

    facilitate their decision process.

    Nevertheless, this case study illustrates how our method can be used to perform a trade-off

    analysis that could assist policymakers in quantifying the impact of certain fairness requirements.

    5. Discussion and Future Directions

    We dealt with the important problem of allocating deceased donor kidneys to waitlisted patients,

    in a fair and efficient way. We focused on national allocation policies in the United States and the

    recent effort to revise the current policy in place.

    Particularly, we studied allocation policies that are based on point systems; under those policies

    patients are awarded points according to some priority criteria, and patients are then prioritized by

    the number of points awarded. We identified the challenges in designing a point system, specifically

    the relative emphasis put on each criterion such that the resulting policy strikes the right balance

    between efficiency and fairness.

    Our main contribution was a scalable, data-driven method of designing point system based

    allocation policies in an efficient and systematic way. The method does not presume any particular

    fairness scheme, or priority criterion. Instead, it offers the flexibility to the designer to select his

    desired fairness constraints and criteria under which patients are awarded points. Our method then

    balances the criteria and extracts a near-optimal point system policy, in the sense that the policy

    outcomes yield approximately the maximum number of life years gains (medical efficiency), while

    satisfying the fairness constraints.

    To validate our method and demonstrate its usefulness, we presented 4 case studies in which

    we designed new policies under different scenarios. In one of them, we designed a new policy

    that matches in fairness properties the one that was recently proposed by the U.S. policymakers,

    while being based on a format and criteria already considered by policymakers. Critically, our

    policy delivers an 8% relative increase in life years gains. The performance gain was established

    via simulation, utilizing the same statistical tools and data as the U.S. policymakers.

    Finally, we presented a trade-off analysis that revealed the dependence of medical efficiency on

    the important fairness concepts of prioritizing patients who have either spent a lot of time waiting,

    or are medically incompatible with the majority of donors.

    As a pointer for future work, consider the policies that OPTN policymakers have proposed in

    35

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    37/47

    which patients and/or organs are categorized into different groups according to some criteria and

    then specific groups receive priority in the allocation, see Section 2.1. For instance, a proposal

    presented in OPTNKTC (2007) suggests to categorize patients in 5 different groups according to

    their expected life year gains: top 20% goes to the first group, bottom 20% goes to the last group,

    etc. Similarly, organs are categorized according to their quality (DPI). In the allocation then,

    group 1 patients are given priority for group 1 organs, groups 2 patients are given priority for group

    2 organs and so on. Ranking within those groups is again achieved via a scoring rule, so our model

    would again be applicable and useful. Another interesting question however is, how can should

    one decide on the right categorization? In the example we gave, how does one exactly partition

    patients into those 5 groups? As an extension and future work, one can potentially use modified

    versions of our framework to guide such decisions. We present a related case study in the Appendix.

    List of Acronyms

    CPRA Calculated Panel Reactive Antibody

    DPI Donor Profile Index

    DT Dialysis Time

    ESRD End-Stage Renal Disease

    KAS Kidney Allocation ScoreKPSAM Kidney-Pancreas Simulated Allocation Model

    KTC Kidney Transplantation Committee

    LYFT Life Years From Transplant

    NOTA National Organ Transplant Act

    OPO Organ Procurement Organization

    OPTN Organ Procurement and Transplantation Network

    RFI Request For InformationSRTR Scientific Registry of Transplant Recipients

    UNOS United Network for Organ Sharing

    36

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    38/47

    Disclaimer

    The data reported here have been supplied by the Arbor Research Collaborative for Health (Arbor

    Research) as the contractor for the Scientific Registry of Transplant Recipients (SRTR). The inter-

    pretation and reporting of these data are the responsibility of the authors and in no way should be

    seen as an official policy of or interpretation by the SRTR or the U.S. Government.

    References

    J. Ahn and J. C. Hornberger. Involving patients in the cadaveric kidney transplant allocation process: A

    decision-theoretic perspective. Management Science, 42(5):pp. 629641, 1996.

    M. Akan, O. Alagoz, B. Ata, and F. S. Erenay. Optimizing liver allocation system incorporating disease

    evolution. Submitted to Operations Research, 2011.

    O. Alagoz. Optimal policies for the acceptance of living and cadaveric-donor livers. Ph.D. dissertation,

    University of Pittsburgh, Pittsburgh, 2004.

    O. Alagoz, L. M. Maillart, A. J. Schaefer, and M. S. Roberts. Determining the acceptance of cadaveric livers

    using an implicit model of the waiting list. Operations Research, 55(1):2436, 2007.

    I. Ashlagi, D. S. Gilchrist, A. E. Roth, and M. A. Rees. Nonsimultaneous chains and dominos in kidney

    paired donation revisited. American Journal of Transplantation, 11(5):984994, May 2011.

    I. David and U. Yechiali. A time-dependent stopping problem with application to live organ transplants.Operations Research, 33(3):pp. 491504, 1985.

    I. David and U. Yechiali. One-attribute sequential assignment match processes in discrete time. Operations

    Research, 43(5):pp. 879884, 1995.

    DHHS. Organ Procurement and Transplantation Network Final Rule. 2000. Electronic Code of Federal

    Regulations, Title 42Public Health, Chapter IPublic Health Service, Department of Health and

    Human Services, Subchapter KHealth Resources Development, Part 121.

    D. H. Howard. Why do transplant surgeons turn down organs?: A model of the accept/reject decision.

    Journal of Health Economics, 21(6):957 969, 2002.

    N. Kong, A. J. Schaefer, B. Hunsaker, and M. S. Roberts. Maximizing the efficiency of the u.s. liver allocation

    system through region design. Management Science, 56(12):21112122, 2010. doi: 10.1287/mnsc.1100.

    1249.

    KPSAM. Kidney-Pancreas Simulated Allocation Model. 2008. Arbor Research Collaborative for Health.

    Scientific Registry of Transplant Recipients.

    37

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    39/47

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    40/47

    X. Su and S. A. Zenios. Patient choice in kidney allocation: A sequential stochastic assignment model.

    Operations Research, 53(3):443445, May-June 2005.

    X. Su and S. A. Zenios. Recipient Choice Can Address the Efficiency-Equity Trade-off in Kidney Transplan-

    tation: A Mechanism Design Model. Management Science, 52(11):16471660, 2006.

    X. Su and S.A. Zenios. Patient choice in kidney allocation: The role of the queueing discipline. Manufacturing

    Service Operations Management, 6(4):280301, 2004. doi: 10.1287/msom.1040.0056.

    M. Suthanthiran and T.B. Strom. Renal transplantation. N Engl J Med, page 331:365, 1994.

    K. Talluri and G. van Ryzin. An analysis of bid-price controls for network revenue management. Management

    Science, 44(11):15771593, November 1998.

    UNOS. United Network for Organ Sharing. 2010. http://www.unos.org/.

    USRDS. U.S. Renal data system, annual data report: Atlas of chronic kidney disease and end-stage renal

    disease in the united states. 2009. National Institutes of Health, National Institute of Diabetes and

    Digestive and Kidney Diseases, Bethesda, MD.

    L. Waisanen, R.A. Wolfe, R.M. Merion, K. McCullough, and A. Rodgers. Simulating the allocation of organs

    for transplantation. Health Care Management Science, 7(4):331338, 2004.

    R.A. Wolfe, K.P. McCullough, D.E. Schaubel, J.D. Kalbfleisch, S. Murray, M.D. Stegall, and A.B. Leichtman.

    2007 SRTR report on the state of transplantation: Calculating life years from transplant (LYFT):

    Methods for kidney and kidney-pancreas candidates. Am J Transplant, 8(2):9971011, 2008.

    R.A. Wolfe, K.P. McCullough, and A.B. Leichtman. Predictability of survival models for waiting list and

    transplant patients: Calculating LYFT. Am J Transplant, 9(7):15231527, 2009.

    S. A. Zenios. Optimal control of a paired-kidney exchange program. Management Science, 48(3):328342,

    2002.

    S. A. Zenios. Models for kidney allocation. In Margaret Brandeau, Franois Sainfort, and William Pierskalla,

    editors, Operations Research and Health Care, volume 70 ofInternational Series in Operations Research

    and Management Science, pages 537554. Springer New York, 2005.

    S. A. Zenios, G. M. Chertow, and L. M. Wein. Dynamic allocation of kidneys to candidates on the transplant

    waiting list. Operations Research, 48(4):pp. 549569, 2000.

    39

    http://www.unos.org/http://www.unos.org/http://www.unos.org/
  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    41/47

    Appendix

    A. Simulation Results

    Table 3 includes the simulated average percentage distributions (and sample deviations) of recipients

    across different race, dialysis time, blood type, sensitization, diagnosis and age patient groups for

    the policies designed in the case studies in Section 4, alongside the KTC proposed policy. The

    results are for an out-of-sample period of 6 months in 2008.

    B. Category-based Policies

    As discussed in Section 5, OPTN policymakers have proposed policies in which patients and/or

    organs are categorized into different groups according to some criteria. Then, specific groups

    receive priority in the allocation of kidneys. For instance, a proposal presented in OPTNKTC

    (2007) suggests to categorize patients in 5 different groups according to their expected life year

    gains (LYFT): top 20% goes to the first group, bottom 20% goes to the last group, etc. Similarly,

    organs are categorized according to their quality (DPI). In the allocation then, group 1 patients

    are given priority for group 1 organs, groups 2 patients are given priority for group 2 organs and

    so on. In this section we illustrate how one can use a modified version of the framework developed

    in Section 3 to decide how one should partition patients and/or organs to such groups.

    Suppose we want to design a policy that categorizes patients and organs into groups A and

    B, according to their (average) LYFT and DPI scores. Specifically, the top q% of patients are

    categorized into group A and the remaining into group B, where q is a policy parameter that needs

    to be determined. Similarly we categorize the top q% of organs into group A and the remaining

    into group B. Then, once an organ of group A is procured, patients from group A have priority

    over group B patients. Patients are then ranked by the time they have spent on dialysis (DT).

    If q = 0, the allocation policy is essentially a first-come first-serve policy (FCFS), with respect

    to dialysis time. As q increases and we depart from a pure FCFS policy, more emphasis is given

    to efficiency as high quality organs are first offered to patients who are likely to benefit more from

    them (in terms of life year gains). Thus, one expects higher LYFT gains. As q approaches 100

    however, we again recover FCFS. Below we discuss a way of guiding the selection of q based on our

    40

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    42/47

  • 8/2/2019 Bertsimas 2011) Fairness-Efficiency Kidney Transplantation

    43/47

    framework.

    For the case of FCFS, i.e., q = 0 or q = 100, one can solve problem (1) without any fairness

    constraints and with objective coefficients equal to DT(p) for every (p,o) pair, to obtain an ap-

    proximate expected allocation. Suppose we now consider 0 < q < 100. Let AP(q) and AO(q) be

    the sets of all group A patients and organs respectively. We then define an adjusted set of eligible

    patient-organ pairs C(q) (see Section 3.1), in which group A organs are only allocated to group A

    patients (according to the selected value of q), i.e.,

    C(q) = {(p,o) : (p,o) C and p AP(q) if o AO(q)} .

    One can then solve the following problem to obtain an approximate expected allocation for any

    selection of q:

    maximize

    (p,o)C(q)

    DT(p)x(p,o)

    subject to

    o:(p,o)C(q)

    x(p,o) 1, p

    p:(p,o)C(q)

    x(p,o) 1, o

    x 0.

    (5)

    Let x(q) denote an optimal solution of (5) for any selection of q.

    To quantitavely characterize the efficiency of each of those policies (as we vary q), one can

    calcu