beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational...

33
Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanism Jordana Viotto da Cruz * Université Paris 13 (CEPN, Labex ICCA) and Télécom ParisTech This version: April 2016 Abstract Over the last few years, crowdfunding has financially supported projects that were later endorsed by institutions such as the TIME 25 Best Inventions of the Year and the Museum of Modern Arts. Such acknowledgement provides evidence that crowdfunding can secure monetary resources to high-quality projects. But this new model of access to capital may bring additional advantages to entrepreneurs. In this paper, we test the hypothesis that crowdfunding also serves as an informational mechanism for project owners. It analyzes whether information from crowdfunding projects impacts their decision to release a new product in the market. We use a unique dataset built with publicly available data from several Internet-based sources. In order to isolate the effects of access to capital from the impact of information on the subsequent project owner’s decision, we benefit from the “all or nothing” rule on crowdfunding platforms which conditions access to capital to achieving a given financing threshold. Such rule creates two subsamples – one of project owners who access capital and information, and another of project owners who access information but not capital. Our results show that the probability of project owners who only access information to release the product in the market increases with the crowd’s valuation. Keywords: crowdfunding, information, uncertainty, e-commerce, new product release JEL Codes: L82, D83, G23 * I thank my supervisors, Marc Bourreau and François Moreau, for their guidance and support. Thank you to Paul Belleflamme, Martin Peitz, Christian Peukert, Greg Taylor, Yutec Sun, Marianne Lumeau, Maya Bacache, Lukasz Grzybowski, Paul Jensen, Stephane Lemairé, Annette Schminke, Patrick Wikström, Dainis Zegner and David Zvilichovsky, and the participants of the 13th Conference on the Economics of Information and Communication Technologies, 8th ICT Paris Conference, XXX Jornadas de Economía Industrial, 2015 ESNIE, 3rd Summer School of Digital Economics, 2nd Workshop on Industrial Organization and Digital Economics for their valuable comments and suggestions. All errors are my own. I gratefully acknowledge the financial support of Labex ICCA (Industries Culturelles et Création Artistique). Contact: viotto[at]enst.fr

Upload: others

Post on 01-Jun-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanism

Jordana Viotto da Cruz*

Université Paris 13 (CEPN, Labex ICCA) and Télécom ParisTech

This version: April 2016

Abstract Over the last few years, crowdfunding has financially supported projects that were later endorsed by institutions such as the TIME 25 Best Inventions of the Year and the Museum of Modern Arts. Such acknowledgement provides evidence that crowdfunding can secure monetary resources to high-quality projects. But this new model of access to capital may bring additional advantages to entrepreneurs. In this paper, we test the hypothesis that crowdfunding also serves as an informational mechanism for project owners. It analyzes whether information from crowdfunding projects impacts their decision to release a new product in the market. We use a unique dataset built with publicly available data from several Internet-based sources. In order to isolate the effects of access to capital from the impact of information on the subsequent project owner’s decision, we benefit from the “all or nothing” rule on crowdfunding platforms which conditions access to capital to achieving a given financing threshold. Such rule creates two subsamples – one of project owners who access capital and information, and another of project owners who access information but not capital. Our results show that the probability of project owners who only access information to release the product in the market increases with the crowd’s valuation. Keywords: crowdfunding, information, uncertainty, e-commerce, new product release JEL Codes: L82, D83, G23

* I thank my supervisors, Marc Bourreau and François Moreau, for their guidance and support. Thank you to Paul Belleflamme, Martin Peitz, Christian Peukert, Greg Taylor, Yutec Sun, Marianne Lumeau, Maya Bacache, Lukasz Grzybowski, Paul Jensen, Stephane Lemairé, Annette Schminke, Patrick Wikström, Dainis Zegner and David Zvilichovsky, and the participants of the 13th Conference on the Economics of Information and Communication Technologies, 8th ICT Paris Conference, XXX Jornadas de Economía Industrial, 2015 ESNIE, 3rd Summer School of Digital Economics, 2nd Workshop on Industrial Organization and Digital Economics for their valuable comments and suggestions. All errors are my own. I gratefully acknowledge the financial support of Labex ICCA (Industries Culturelles et Création Artistique). Contact: viotto[at]enst.fr

Page 2: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

2

1. Introduction

Crowdfunding is an alternative mode of financing that has provided monetary support for

projects whose high-quality was later endorsed by institutions such as the TIME 25 Best

Inventions of the Year,1 the Oscars,2 the Grammy Awards,3 and the Museum of Modern

Arts (MoMA)4. Besides monetary resources, entrepreneurs presenting their ideas on

crowdfunding platforms may obtain additional benefits from their campaigns. For

example, they can collect information about the public’s valuation of their project.

Producers face great uncertainty preceding the release of new goods in the market

(see, for example, Asplund and Sandin, 1999). Crowdfunding offers an investment

opportunity associated with a consumption experience (Schwienbacher, 2015) where

contributors choose the amount they give to a project, in a sort of incentive-aligned

mechanism (Agrawal, Catalini and Goldfarb, 2013) that allows individuals to reveal their

valuation about a certain idea. From this perspective, the aggregate contributions can be

considered as the “crowd’s valuation” and may provide a proxy about the market’s interest

on the new good, which in turn can help reducing the entrepreneurs’ uncertainty prior to

the release of the product.

Such hypothesis was evoked on past research (Agrawal et al., 2013; Belleflamme,

Lambert and Schwienbacher, 2014; Belleflamme, Omrani and Peitz, 2015), but to the best

of our knowledge not yet tested in the context of new product release on retail channels,

1 Information from the pages dedicated to “The 15 Best Inventions” in 2013 (http://ti.me/17TRn1m), 2014 (http://time.com/3594971/the-25-best-inventions-of-2014), and 2015 (http://time.com/4115398/best-inventions- 2015/). Last consulted on January 6, 2015. 2 Samantha Murphy. “Oscar Win Is a First for Kickstarter-Funded Film”. Mashable, February 25, 2013. Available at http://mashable.com/2013/02/24/inocente-oscar-kickstarter/#egRpHGYu_8q4. Last consulted on December 5, 2015. 3 Jazz musician Maria Schneider was nominated to four Grammy Awards and won in one category with her album “Concert in the Garden” (2004), which was financed through ArtistShare. Information from the artist’s website (http://www.mariaschneider.com/albuminfo.aspx?ID=60) and the Grammy Awards (https://www.grammy.com/). Last consulted on December 5, 2015. 4 Margaret Rhodes. “A CFL Bulb That Is As Practical As It Is Sculptural”. FastCoDesign, January 13, 2014. Available at http://www.fastcodesign.com/3024738/wanted/a-cfl-bulb-that-is-as-practical-as-it-is-sculptural. Last consulted on December 5, 2015.

Page 3: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

3

which is the objective of the present paper. We frame our research question as: how do

project owners respond to information from their crowdfunding campaigns? As

“response”, we consider the decision to release the corresponding good in the market after

a crowdfunding campaign. We posit that the probability of an entrepreneur to release the

corresponding product in the market increases with the crowd’s valuation.

One issue to test this hypothesis is that crowdfunding project owners, when

successful, access simultaneously capital and information. To disentangle both effects, we

utilize the “all or nothing” rule on crowdfunding platforms that conditions access to capital

on the achievement of a certain financing threshold during the campaign.5 Due to this rule,

even project owners that receive support remain unfinanced if their initial target is not

reached. In this case, their respective contributors are reimbursed at the end of the period.

The “all or nothing” rule creates two subsamples of project owners – those who

receive support and obtain access to the capital raised through their campaign and those

who receive support but remain unfinanced. We expect that if information is important

enough to reduce the entrepreneurs’ uncertainty, the probability of releasing the new

product among those who did not succeed will increases with the amount of contribution.

We highlight that failed projects do not necessarily lack quality. Past research

demonstrates that failure is strongly correlated with high financing goals (e.g., Mollick,

2014) and that under the uncertainty context of crowdfunding, only a part of high-quality

projects get financed, particularly if the project owner fails to inform a relative number of

potential contributors at a very early stage of the campaign (Li and Duan, 2014).

In order to test our hypothesis, we focus on projects aiming at producing music

albums. Music is one of the main categories on crowdfunding (the second on the platform

we study in terms of number of projects) and about 40% of projects within the category

5 As explained later, the financing goal and the duration of the campaign are two characteristics determined at the beginning of the campaign and that cannot be changed once the project is online.

Page 4: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

4

aim at creating an album. More importantly, the music industry confronts the same

information asymmetries issues as other markets, particularly concerning uncertainty prior

to the release of a new product. Finally, as in Bacache-Beauvallet, Moreau and Bourreau

(2014) and Agrawal, Catalini and Goldfarb (2015), we consider musicians to be artists-

entrepreneurs who need to access capital in order to release a new product in the market.

Thus we believe we provide insights to other categories.

Our analysis uses a unique dataset built with information collected from different

Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one of the prominent

crowdfunding platforms worldwide.6 Kickstarter allows project owners to offer early

access to the good or service being developed as well as prizes and “community benefits”

(Belleflamme et al., 2014) in exchange for financial support. Other data sources include

Facebook, Amazon and iTunes.

The final sample contains 707 observations, with both successful and unsuccessful

projects, and we remark that 20% of unsuccessful projects release the respective product in

the market after the crowdfunding campaign. The analysis focuses on the probability of

such project owners to release the corresponding product in the market given the “crowd’s

valuation” (i.e., the amount collected). Our results demonstrate that the likelihood of

releasing after an unsuccessful campaign increases with the amount collected. This result

allows us to conclude that entrepreneurs use not only the capital they raise on

crowdfunding but also the information obtained. In other words, crowdfunding goes

beyond financing: it is also an informational mechanism for entrepreneurs.

Our dataset reveals other interesting characteristics of crowdfunding projects. First,

while the general assumption is that project owners would start production only after

ending the campaign, if successful, our data suggests that, at least for a part of the projects,

6 We detail the four main crowdfunding models on Section 2.

Page 5: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

5

crowdfunding and production happen simultaneously, and not sequentially. Second, our

study shows that some successful projects are not released in the market. We will briefly

discuss these questions in Section 5.

We expect our paper to contribute to the growing literature on crowdfunding,

particularly the stream dedicated to the informational mechanisms arising on these

platforms. This stream has mostly dedicated to understanding the impact of information on

the demand side (contributors) and only recently started investigating the supply side

(project owners). Besides the academic contribution, we expect to provide insights to

entrepreneurs about crowdfunding as an informational mechanism.

To the best of our knowledge, ours is the first paper to study the response of

entrepreneurs to information provided by crowdfunding campaigns in the context of new

product release. It is also the first one to follow projects beyond the crowdfunding

campaigns, connecting projects to online retail outlets (e-commerce).

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 defines crowdfunding and its main

existing financing models, and reviews the relevant literature. Section 3 describes the

theoretical framework and the hypothesis. Section 4 details the dataset and the variables

used. Section 5 presents the results, and Section 6 brings the concluding remarks.

2. Crowdfunding overview

2.1. Definition and financing models

Crowdfunding can be defined as an “open call through the Internet for the provision of

financial resources either in form of donation or in exchange for some form of reward

and/or voting rights in order to support initiatives for specific purposes” (Belleflamme et

al., 2014). A complementary definition points to “the efforts by entrepreneurial individuals

Page 6: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

6

and groups – cultural, social, and for-profit – to fund their ventures by drawing on

relatively small contributions from a relatively large number of individuals using the

Internet, without standard financial intermediaries” (Mollick, 2014). Both encompass a

broad range of activities developed on distinct types of platforms, which are categorized in

four main models.

In the reward-based model, which is the focus of the present paper, contributors can

receive non-monetary compensations for their financial support, including advanced copies

of products, preferential prizes, and appreciation tokens (Belleflamme et al., 2014). The

donation-based crowdfunding facilitates private contributions to public goods, and

contributors are expected to donate out of altruism or warm glow (Andreoni, 1990). In the

lending-based crowdfunding, also referred to as peer-to-peer lending or social lending,

investors supply funds to individuals, groups or small companies, expecting to be

reimbursed after a given period, with or without interest rates. Finally, in equity-based

crowdfunding, investors become shareholders and receive dividends according to the

companies’ performance and the amount invested.

While some projects occur on the project owner’s website (Belleflamme et al.,

2013), most of the crowdfunding activity concentrates on dedicated platforms

(Belleflamme et al., 2015; Schwienbacher, 2015; Viotto, 2015). Platforms adopt specific

rules such as the “fixed funding” rule (“all or nothing”), which conditions access to capital

to the achievement of a financing threshold that is determined by the project owner at the

beginning of the campaign. Alternatively, some platforms offer the option of “flexible

funding” (“keep it all”), allowing project owners to be financed even if they do not reach

the financing goal.

The overall crowdfunding market has been growing exponentially over the last

years. According to the consulting firm Massolution, in 2015 there were 1,250 platforms

Page 7: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

7

worldwide where individuals and firms transacted US$ 30 billion – twice the volume of

2014. The rapid development has attracted the attention of policymakers regarding a

number of issues, including the potential of crowdfunding to alleviate budget constraints

for new businesses, culture and media. For example, in 2015 the European Commission

signaled the need to understand the role of crowdfunding in the cultural and creative

sectors in order to “support the implementation of political objectives regarding the access

to alternative sources of finance”.7 Such interest demonstrates the relevance of

crowdfunding to regulators.

2.2. Literature review

Crowdfunding has motivated a growing body of academic literature over the past few

years. Our paper is closely related to the stream analyzing informational mechanisms

arising on crowdfunding. Concerning the demand side, research investigates how data

about past contributions (and past contributors’ characteristics) influence future

contributions and projects’ outcomes (Zhang and Liu, 2012; Burtch, Ghose and Wattal,

2013; Lin, Prabhala and Viswanathan, 2013; Parker, 2014). Regarding the supply side,

research focuses on the entrepreneurs’ learning process on crowdfunding platforms by

examining project owners who submit projects more than once (Xu, 2015). Our work also

relates to studies that theoretically evoke the possibility of entrepreneurs to use information

from crowdfunding platforms to infer the crowd’s valuation (Agrawal et al., 2013;

Belleflamme et al., 2014).

Each one of the four main models of crowdfunding present distinct dynamics, and

attract different types of participants on both sides. In this sense, we position our paper

7 See “Call for tenders EAC/03/2015 - Pilot project on “Crowdfunding for the cultural and creative sectors: kick- starting the cultural economy””. Accessible at http://ec.europa.eu/culture/calls/general/0315_en.htm. Last consulted on December 5, 2015.

Page 8: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

8

within the stream particularly interested in the reward-based crowdfunding environment.

One of the central findings in these papers is the importance of the social network for the

success of campaigns. Mollick (2014) reports that the number of project owners’ Facebook

friends (used as a proxy for the size of the social network) is positively correlated with the

probability of success of a project. Agrawal et al. (2015) finds that friends and family tend

to be the first to contribute to a project, revealing private information about the project

owner and signaling quality to “distant” investors8. Colombo, Franzoni and Rossi-

Lamastra (2015) conclude that the internal social capital is crucial in the crowdfunding

environment.

Another question concerns the project quality inferred by contributors, and how such

inference influences the project outcomes (success/failure). Using proxies such as the

choice of the model (e.g., “all or nothing” vs. “keep it all”, Cumming, Leboeuf and

Schwienbacher, 2015), videos and spelling (Mollick, 2014) authors conclude that quality

signals are positively correlated with the probability of success. But if quality and success

are positively correlated, failure does not necessarily imply lack of quality. First, success is

also correlated with lower financing goals (e.g., Mollick, 2014). Second, in an uncertain

environment such as crowdfunding, even high-quality projects may fail, particularly if the

project owner cannot inform a relatively high number of potential contributors at a very

early stage of the campaign (Li and Duan, 2014).

One interesting characteristic of reward-based crowdfunding is the timing of

contributions. The distribution of daily contributions is U-shaped, which is explained as the

result of two phenomena – a crowding out in the beginning, and a deadline effect at the end

(Kuppuswamy and Bayus, 2013). The literature also analyzes in the drivers for the

decision of contributors, and reports that intrinsic motivations (Zvilichovsky, Inbar, and

8 The paper analyzes a hybrid form of crowdfunding in the music industry, where investors could receive royalties and rewards.

Page 9: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

9

Barzilay, 2013; Boudreau, Jeppesen, Reichstein and Rullani, 2015) play a great role for

success of projects.

Finally, papers suggest that crowdfunding mitigates geography-related frictions

(Agrawal et al., 2015) facilitating the access to capital to individuals living in areas that are

less served by the traditional systems, but that it still concentrates in big cities and

industrial clusters (Kim and Hann, 2014).

2.3. Financing on reward-based crowdfunding

As we focus on reward-based crowdfunding campaigns, we find it useful to present its

process. A project owner (firm, entrepreneur, association or artist) decides to raise money

through a crowdfunding platform. She sets an account on the platform and creates a

project, describing its expected outcomes and offering rewards to each level of

contribution. As a hypothetical example, a project owner can offer a “thank you” message

on Twitter for contributions of $1 and a special dinner for contributions of $1,000 (see

Figure A.1 in the Appendix for a concrete example of a crowdfunding campaign with some

of its respective rewards).

When setting a crowdfunding project on Kickstarter, the project owner establishes

a financing goal (minimum of $1 with no upper bound) and the duration of the campaign

(1 to 60 days), two features that cannot be changed once the campaign is submitted to the

appreciation of potential online contributors. The project owner invites contributors to

participate on the project, generally using social media like Facebook. At the end of the

campaign, the project owner accesses capital if the campaign is successful, and remains

unfinanced otherwise – in which case contributors are reimbursed.

Page 10: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

10

Figure 1: Illustration of the timeline of reward-based crowdfunding

projects under the “all or nothing” model

3. Theoretical framework and hypothesis

We treat crowdfunding as a sort of incentive-aligned mechanism (Agrawal et al., 2013)

where contributors reveal their valuation on an idea by choosing how much to allocate on a

project and committing to future consumption (Schwienbacher, 2015), potentially offering

entrepreneurs information that reduces their uncertainty prior to a product release. Our

research question is: how do project owners respond to information from their

crowdfunding campaigns? The response we consider in our context is the decision to

release the corresponding good in the market after a crowdfunding campaign. We assume

that each participant expresses her valuation of the project when choosing the amount to

contribute with. Thus the total amount collected can be considered as the “crowd’s

valuation”. In this context, we consider that the probability of an entrepreneur to release

the corresponding product in the market increases with the crowd’s valuation.

The main issue in performing the empirical analysis is that the entrepreneurs’

decision can be affected simultaneously by the access to information and the access to

Project setting

Call for contributions

Contributors’ decision

Project finishes

Project owner’s decision

Project owner sets its project on a crowdfunding platform. She decides the financing objective, the campaign duration, and the rewards.

Project owner invites individuals to contribute through social network.

Contributors decide whether or not to participate, and how much to allocate on the project, thus revealing their valuation.

If the goal is achieved, the project owner accesses the capital raised. Otherwise, contributors are reimbursed.

Project owner decides whether or not to release the product in the market.

Page 11: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

11

capital. In order to disentangle both effects, we benefit from the “all or nothing” rule on

crowdfunding platforms, which conditions the access to capital to the achievement of a

certain financing threshold during the period of the campaign. It implies that even if the

project owner has received support, she remains unfinanced if failing to reach the target,

and their respective contributors are then reimbursed. The condition creates a subsample of

project owners that do not have access to capital, but that can still use information on the

public’s valuation to reduce their uncertainty. The decision of this group will enable our

understanding about the role of information to reduce uncertainty. We formalize our

hypothesis as: products from unsuccessful projects will be released in the market if the

crowdfunding campaign yields information signaling public’s interest in the project. We

expect that if information is important enough to reduce the entrepreneurs’ uncertainty, the

probability that products from failed projects will be released increases with the crowd’s

valuation.

The hypothesis may sound counterintuitive so we provide the example of singer

Robyn Landis, who received $8,477, an amount within the average of projects on

Kickstarter (around $7,825; see Mollick, 2014), but with a $14,400 goal she could not

access the capital raised.9 Nevertheless, the corresponding album “Waterproof” was

released in the market.

Our model is as follows:

Pr(release=1| failure, information, previous product, production phase) =

Φ(β1failι + β2 informationι + β3failι*informationι + β4previous_productsι +

β5fail*previous_productsι + β6production_phaseι + β7fail*production_phaseι + ψι)

9 Information from the artist’s Kickstarter campaign, available at http://kck.st/1aYcCAE. Last consulted on December 5, 2015.

Page 12: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

12

The dependent variable is a dummy taking the value 1 if the product corresponding

to the crowdfunding project is identified on online retail channels after the campaign, and 0

otherwise; Φ is the cumulative distribution function of the standard normal distribution; the

variable fail equals 1 if the project was not successful on crowdfunding, and 0 otherwise;

information is the logarithmic form of the total amount collected – which we consider as

the “crowd’s valuation”; 10 previous products is the number of products the project owner

had in the market previously to the crowdfunding campaign; and production phase is a

proxy for the stage of production when the campaign ends (see explanation on Section 4).

The strategy to test our hypothesis relies on the use of the interaction term between the fail

and information, and the corresponding coefficient β3 yields the effect of the information

proxy only to failed projects. We expect that if entrepreneurs respond positively to

information, β3 will be positive.

To ensure that our results are not biased by other factors that may lead an

entrepreneur to release a product in the market after a failed campaign, we include two

other interaction terms that aim at testing alternative explanations. The first one is that

project owners who already have other products in the market may use revenues coming

from sales of these to finance the new one (Van Auken and Neeley, 1996; Ebben, J., &

Johnson, 2006). In this case, project owners with other products in the market would be

more likely to release a new product after a crowdfunding failure. We expect that the

interaction term between fail and previous products to capture this effect if it exists. In this

case, we assume that project owners incur fixed costs to maintain the product on retail

channels; an assumption that is backed by evidence from the industry – to have an album

on Amazon and iTunes, an artist-entrepreneur must pay access fees to digital distributors,

10 Alternatively we test the interaction of fail with number of contributions and average of the amount contributed. The corresponding results are reported on Tables A.1 and A.2 in the Appendix.

Page 13: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

13

for example. 11

The second alternative explanation is the stage of production of the corresponding

good. The general assumption is that crowdfunding and production happen sequentially,

but theses processes can also occur simultaneously. In this case, project owners incur fixed

costs of production, and cover such costs ex post with capital coming from the

crowdfunding campaign, if successful. Thus, if unsuccessful, once fixed costs are already

incurred, the project owner may as well release the product. We control this possibility by

introducing a third interaction term between fail and production phase.

The term ψ is a set of control variables including genre and the number of

Facebook fans, which we use as a proxy for potential public, similarly to previous works

(e.g., Mollick, 2014).

4. Data

Our primary source of information for the empirical analysis is Kickstarter, considered

one of the main reward-based crowdfunding platforms worldwide, having attracted more

than US$ 2 billion in transactions coming from 10 million contributors up to 2015. The

funding is based on the “all or nothing” principle, and the platform transfers the funds to

the project owners at the end of the funding period if the project collected at least the pre-

established financing goal. A project that cannot achieve its goal is considered

unsuccessful and the contributors are reimbursed.

All project pages on Kickstarter publicly display information on the characteristic

and the performance of the project: initial financing goal, amount collected, location (city,

state and country), number of contributors, category (e.g., film, music, theater),

subcategory (e.g., genre, in the case of music), number of updates on the campaign (by the

11 Information from digital distributor CDBaby.

Page 14: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

14

project owner), comments (by the project owner and contributors), the period of each

campaign (initial and final dates of the project), the description of each reward and the

minimum amount to access it, number of contributors choosing each type of reward, and

the estimated delivery of rewards (see Figures A.1 and A.2 in the Appendix for an

example of a crowdfunding campaign on Kickstarter with some of its respective rewards).

Once the project ends, the pages of successful and unsuccessful projects stay online with

all information as the last day of campaign.

Figure 2: Distribution of categories on Kickstarter according to the

number of projects

Reward-based crowdfunding is largely used for projects with creative, innovative

and/or technological appeal. For example, Kickstarter presents ideas related to games,

design, films, and music, among others. In order to be able to compare projects, we chose

to focus on one category offering outcomes presenting some level of similarity in terms of

product characteristics. We find the music category, more specifically on projects aiming

at producing a music album, to be suitable for our purpose. Music is one of the main

categories in crowdfunding and the second category on Kickstarter in terms of number of

Page 15: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

15

projects (see Figure 2), and about 40% of projects are dedicated to create a music album

(the word “album” appears in 18,466 projects in the Music category on Kickstarter).

As in Bacache-Beauvallet et al. (2014) and Agrawal et al. (2015), we consider

musicians to be artists-entrepreneurs who need to access capital in order to release a new

product (album) in the market. After the crowdfunding campaign, these artist-

entrepreneurs can release their products on traditional channels where consumers normally

purchase other similar goods such as Amazon or iTunes. These two channels lead the

distribution of recording music distribution the last years at the same time they impose

some barriers to non-professional artists. The distribution is done either by vertically

integrating with an incumbent (a label) or independently, through specialized distributors.

In our sample, all artists adopt the latter option, approaching an entrepreneurial attitude.

Although independent distribution imposes low barriers to artists, distributors require

fixed fees to place albums on online retail channels, thus we consider only artists-

entrepreneurs expecting to sell will have incentives to release through these channels.

The music industry faces similar issues regarding information asymmetries as other

markets. For example, on the demand side, consumers can only know the utility of the

consumption ex post. On the supply side, producers are uncertain about the public’s

response to each product until after the release. Thus we believe we provide insights to

other categories.

We obtain a sample of 1,505 US-based projects aiming at producing a music album

with estimated delivery of rewards between August 2014 and May 2015. Similarly to

previous work (Mollick, 2014; Cumming, Leboeuf and Schwienbacher, 2015), we

eliminate very low or very high financing goals. To decide the upper and lower bounds, we

consider the specificities of the music industry – project owners setting goals of less than

$3,000 will be likely to expect contributions mainly from friends and family, and those

Page 16: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

16

determining goals above $200,000 seem to be unrealistic about the market. Finally, we

discard the projects where the project owner does not have a Facebook page. The final

sample contains 707 observations from unique project owners (i.e., there is no project

owner with more than one project).

Figure 3: Distribution of projects according to the duration of campaigns (in days).

Figure 4: Distribution of projects according to the percentage obtained.

Page 17: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

17

Table 1: Summary statistics

All Sample Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Released 707 0.61 0.49 0 1 Fail 707 0.26 0.44 0 1 Supporters 707 127.55 258.87 0 3305 Collected 707 9958.02 18571.26 0 278486 Average Collected 707 85.88 69.45 0 956.25 Goal 707 10247.20 11915.44 3100 175000 Previous Albums 707 1.26 2.51 0 34 First Album 707 0.51 0.50 0 1 Production Phase 707 2.79 3.00 0 21 Facebook Fans 707 4738.29 22510.51 2 444214

Successful Projects

Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Released 522 0.74 0.44 0 1 Supporters 522 166.08 291.35 10 3305 Collected 522 12960.06 20734.42 530 278486 Average Collected 522 93.79 53.04 28.15432 467.7333 Goal 522 10159.66 12789.06 3100 175000 Previous Albums 522 1.45 2.65 0 34 First Album 522 0.44 0.50 0 1 Production Phase 522 2.65 2.83 0 21 Facebook Fans 522 5724.72 25658.51 14 444214

Unsuccessful Projects

Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Released 185 0.25 0.43 0 1 Supporters 185 18.83 25.99 0 193 Collected 185 1487.42 2882.52 0 23815 Average Collected 185 63.57 99.31 0 956.25 Goal 185 10494.21 9030.81 3150 60000 Previous Albums 185 0.72 1.98 0 17 First Album 185 0.70 0.46 0 1 Production Phase 185 3.20 3.43 0 18 Facebook Fans 185 1954.96 8340.71 2 108278

We complement the data from Kickstarter with information from other sources.

First, we consider the number of previous albums from the artists, which is a proxy for

experience and for a source of financial resources (as explained in Section 3). Then, we

obtain the number of Facebook fans, assuming that social media is the main promotion

Page 18: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

18

channel for independent artists (Bourreau, Maillard and Moreau, 2014), and that

information from social media provides a proxy for the social network of the project owner

(Mollick, 2014), or, in our case, of potential public. Finally, we follow these projects on

online retail outlets (Amazon and iTunes)12 from August 2014 until November 2015,

leaving room for delays within the period reported by previous research (Mollick, 2014;

Hauge and Chimahusky, 2016).

Table 1 brings the summary statistics with the main characteristics of the whole

sample, for successful and for unsuccessful projects, and Table 2 displays the main

variables used in the analysis. Consistent with previous research on Kickstarter (e.g.,

Mollick, 2014), campaign duration concentrates around the period of 30 days (Figure 3),

and projects succeed by small margins and fail by large margins (Figure 4). We highlight

the fact that 25% of unsuccessful projects in our sample release a product in the market

after crowdfunding while 26% of successful projects do not. We will discuss both in the

next Section.

Table 2: Main Variables

Released = 1 if project releases on retail channels (Amazon and iTunes), 0 otherwise.

Fail = 1 if project does not reach the financing objective, 0 otherwise. Information log(TotalCollected+1)13

Previous products

(1) Number of previous albums, (2) dummy for “first album” (=1 if the artist is releasing the first album through crowdfunding, and 0 otherwise).

Production phase

Period between the end of a campaign and the estimated delivery of main rewards, informed on project page (in months).

We consider it is worthy to provide details on the variable production phase, which

controls for the stage of production. Each project page on Kickstarter provides the

estimated delivery of rewards expressed in months and years. Considering that rewards

12 Figures A.1 and A.2 in the Appendix show examples of projects matching products released in the market. 13 Alternative models using log(AmountCollected+1) and log(AverageCollected+1) are reported in the Appendix.

Page 19: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

19

include the main crowdfunded good, we expect that the project owners to account for the

end of production when setting an estimated delivery. Therefore we would expect that the

period between the end of the crowdfunding campaign and the estimated delivery is an

approximation of the time needed by the project owner to access capital, launch and finish

the production, and deliver the good. The variable “production phase” is expressed in

months – a project with a “production phase” of one month is closer to completion than

another one with a “production phase” of six months.

Figure 5 displays the distribution of the production phase, showing that most

crowdfunding campaigns set the estimated delivery in the same month or one month later

than the end of the campaign. According to industry sources, a music album takes from six

months to one year to be produced, which suggests that most project owners ran the

campaign and the production simultaneously.

One potential concern in our setting is that project owners may have raised the

money outside the crowdfunding platform, but the literature suggests that it would be less

likely as the entrepreneurs come to crowdfunding as an alternative when lacking access to

traditional sources (Hann and Kim, 2014). Another potential concern regards the

possibility of raising money on other platform, but we posit that project owners do not

have incentives to hold the same projects in multiple platforms – while it is not a forbidden

practice, it implies opportunity costs due to the amount of work required to run a campaign

(Hui, Gerber and Greenberg, 2012), and it can also hurt the potential of success as publicly

available information about previous support influences future contributions

(Kuppuswamy and Bayus, 2013; Burtch et al., 2014; Agrawal et al., 2015). Still, we check

for double projects in other platforms, but cannot find any from the final sample.

Page 20: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

20

Figure 5: Percentage of crowdfunding campaigns by period between the end of

the campaign and the estimated delivery of rewards, in months.

5. Results

Our study relies on the regression of the Probit model presented on Section 3. Table 3

reports the main model with the information proxy “total amount collected”. Two

alternative models with the information proxies “number of contributors” and “average

contributed” are reported in the Appendix (Tables A.1 and A.2) as robustness checks. The

first column on each table presents the results of the estimation using the variable previous

albums as a proxy for previous products. This variable is substituted by the dummy first

album on the second column. On the third column, we use the same model as in the first one

excluding the projects that had zero contributions – project owners failing after having

attracted some contribution may behave differently than project owners that failed for

receiving no contributions at all.

Page 21: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

21

Table 3: Probit estimation results for the decision to release an album in the market. Dependent variable: dummy indicating the release on e-commerce channels.

Information proxy: total amount collected.

(1) (2) (3) Fail -1.329*** -1.161*** -1.259***

(0.253) (0.286) (0.262) Fail*Log(Collected+1) 0.228** 0.178* 0.335***

(0.106) (0.103) (0.116) Log(Collected+1) -0.167* -0.123 -0.158

(0.099) (0.095) (0.100) Previous Albums 0.065*

0.0639*

(0.034) (0.0340) Fail*PreviousAlbums 0.060

0.0624

(0.057) (0.0612) First Album

-0.260**

(0.130) Fail*FirstAlbum

-0.114

(0.259) Production Phase -0.056*** -0.056*** -0.055**

(0.0213) (0.0214) (0.0213) Fail*ProductionPhase 0.005 0.010 0.019

(0.0457) (0.0441) (0.047) Log(FB Fans) 0.067 0.0653 0.0625

(0.042) (0.041) (0.043) Constant 0.611 0.792 0.625

(0.543) (0.566) (0.549)

Observations 707 707 689 Wald chi2 (17) 168.3 (17) 166.7 (17) 164.6 Prob>chi2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Pseudo R2 0.2105 0.2081 0.2111

Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The first column presents the results of the estimation of the main model. On the second column, the variable previous albums is substituted by the dummy first album. On the third column, we run the first regression excluding the projects that had zero contributions – project owners failing after having attracted some contribution may behave differently than project owners that failed for receiving no contributions at all.

The coefficient of the interaction term fail*log(collected+1) is positive and

Page 22: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

22

statistically significant for all specifications, meaning that the probability of releasing an

album after a failed crowdfunding campaign increases with the public’s valuation. Such

result is reinforced by the alternative model using average amount collected (Table A.2),

where the interaction term fail*log(average_collected+1) is also positive and statistically

significant. Interestingly enough, the coefficient for the interaction term

fail*log(supporters+1) is only positive and statistically significant when eliminating the

projects that had no contributions (third column of Table A.1). We infer that project

owners care about the crowd’s valuation (measured by the proxy log(collected+1)) and the

individual valuation (measured by the proxy log(average_collected+1)), and less about the

total number of contributors (log(supporters+1)) in order to decide on the product release.

Our results lack evidence that releases after failing on crowdfunding can be explained

by alternative explanations. The coefficients of the interaction terms fail*PreviousAlbums,

fail*FirstAlbum and fail*ProductionPhase are not significantly different from zero.

As we are interested in the release of crowdfunded products in the market, it may

be interesting to note that 26% of the successful projects are not released (see Table 1).

We must highlight that the project owners only commit to deliver rewards, not to release

the product in the market – and we observe the release in the market, not the delivery of

rewards. The literature suggests that fraud is rare but delays are common (see, for

example, Mollick 2014 and Hauge and Chimahusky, 2016). Intrigued by such apparent

inconsistency, we analyzed some successful but not released projects from our sample and

we could identify two main reasons for the non-releasing. The first one is that project

owners deliberately did not place the corresponding product released in the market after

delivering the rewards.14 It is a puzzling finding given that a reward-based crowdfunding

14 For example, Grammy award winner Kenny Loggins raised US$121,797 to record an album of his band Blue Sky Riders, which was distributed to contributors in September 2015, according to updates on the crowdfunding campaign page (and not contested on the comments by contributors). Remaining physical copies of album were available on the band's website, but the product was not made available on Amazon or iTunes, even if the

Page 23: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

23

campaign followed by a release on traditional channels can expand the market for the

project owner (Belleflamme et al., 2014). The second reason is that projects were more

than six months late in relationship to the estimated delivery.15 This situation suggests that

risks for contributors may be greater than what is accounted for, which can put into

question the reputation of artists and platforms. Such questions, though, go beyond the

scope of this paper and may be explored in future work.

6. Conclusion

In this paper, we provide empirical evidence that the benefits of crowdfunding to

entrepreneurs go beyond the provision of financial support to projects lacking access to

traditional sources of capital. It can also be a valuable source of information about the

“crowd’s” valuation on the presented idea, helping entrepreneurs to reduce their uncertainty

regarding the acceptance of a new product or service, and ultimately providing support for

their decision to release a product in the market.

We depart from the hypothesis that crowdfunding contributors reveal their valuation

about the presented project when deciding whether or not to contribute to the campaign, and

at which amount. The sum of allocations of all contributors provides then information about

the aggregated valuation of the project by the crowd.

The entrepreneurial decision after a crowdfunding campaign can come from two

simultaneous effects: information and access to capital. To ensure that the response we

observe is due to the latter but not the former, we need to isolate both effects. We benefit

from the “all or nothing” rule on crowdfunding platforms, which conditions the access to

previous albums were. The reasons for that go beyond the scope of this paper. 15 For example, musician Paula Fuga (who has worked with names like Jack Johnson, and thus has a reputation) raised $27,797 in June 2014, and posted an updated in November 2015 with the title “Hang in there guys!! I haven't forgotten and No, I didn't rip you off!!” (update only available to supporters). Information from the artist’s crowdfunding campaign available at http://kck.st/1jAq2UX. Last consulted on March 27, 2016.

Page 24: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

24

capital to the achievement of a given financing threshold. In this setting, projects that

achieve or overcome this financing goal are “successful” and have access to the capital

raised while those that stay below this threshold are considered “unsuccessful” and remain

unfinanced, with contributors being reimbursed. Due to this rule, even if project owners

receive support, they remain unfinanced if they do not reach the financing threshold.

We focus our analysis on the decision of the subsample of unsuccessful project

owners, and how it is affected by the crowd’s valuation on their project (i.e., the amount

they collected). With this strategy, we isolate the effect of information from the effect of

access to capital on the likelihood of releasing a product. The results of our empirical

analysis show that the greater the valuation, the more likely the entrepreneur will be to take

the project to a next level, for example, releasing it in traditional retail channels after the

campaign. We thus conclude that that entrepreneurs respond not only to the access to

capital, but also to information from their crowdfunding campaign. In other words,

crowdfunding goes beyond financing: it is also an informational mechanism for project

owners.

We highlight that failing on crowdfunding do not necessarily mean lack of quality.

Past research shows that projects with smaller financing goals are more likely to be

successful and that under uncertainty, only a part of high-quality projects get financed,

particularly if the project owner fails to inform a relative number of potential contributors at

a very early stage.

In order to ensure that our interpretation is not biased by other factors, we test

alternative explanations for the release of products coming from unsuccessful crowdfunding

projects. The first one is the use of finance from existing products. We use the number of

previous albums as a proxy for this test. The second one is the fact that the project can be

actually close to completion – or completed – which means that fixed costs are incurred and

Page 25: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

25

that the project owner would try to cover such costs with traditional sales. Our results do not

allow us to conclude that such reasons can be the explanations for a release of a product

coming from an unsuccessful crowdfunding project.

Although we focus on the music category on crowdfunding, we are confident that the

insights are extensible to other categories. Uncertainty prior to the release of a new product

is a traditional issue in many industries. We believe that our study provides contributions to

the understanding of the uses of crowdfunding other than its primary objective of funding

new projects, with empirical evidence to entrepreneurs that this mechanism can be used to

test and validate their ideas on the Internet. Finally, the paper follows the results of

crowdfunding projects in the market, connecting crowdfunding and e-commerce activities.

Page 26: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

26

References

Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2013). Some Simple Economics of

Crowdfunding. In Innovation Policy and the Economy (Vol. 14).

Agrawal, A., Catalini, C., & Goldfarb, A. (2015). Crowdfunding: Geography, Social

Networks, and the Timing of Investment Decisions. Journal of Economics and

Management Strategy, 24(2).

Aguiar, Luis & Martens, B. (2013). Digital Music Consumption on the Internet: Evidence

from Clickstream Data. JRC Technical Reports, 24(2), 446–465.

Ahlers, G. K. C., Cumming, D., Günther, C., & Schweizer, D. (2015). Signaling in Equity

Crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice, 39(4), 955-980.

Alexander, P. J. (1994). Entry Barriers, Release Behavior, and Multi-product Firms in the

Music Recording Industry. Review of Industrial Organization, 9(1), 85–98.

Allison, T. H., McKenny, A. F., & Short, J. C. (2013). The effect of entrepreneurial

rhetoric on microlending investment: An examination of the warm-glow effect. Journal

of Business Venturing, 28(6), 690–707.

Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure Altruism and Donations to Public Goods: A Theory of Warm-

Glow Giving. The Economic Journal, 100(401), 464-477.

Asplund, M., & Sandin, R. (1999). The Survival of New Products. Review of Industrial

Organization, 15(3), 219–237.

Bacache-Beauvallet, M., Bourreau, M., & Moreau, F. (2014). Digitization and

Entrepreneurship: Self-releasing in the Recorded Music Industry. Working Paper.

Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T., & Schwienbacher, A. (2013). Individual Crowdfunding

Practices. Venture Capital: An International Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance, 15(4),

313-333.

Page 27: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

27

Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T., & Schwienbacher, A. (2014). Crowdfunding: Tapping the

Right Crowd. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(5), 585–609.

Belleflamme, P., Omrani, N., & Peitz, M. (2015). The economics of crowdfunding

platforms. Information Economics and Policy. 33, 11-18.

Bernstein, S., Korteweg, A. G., & Laws, K. (2015). Attracting Early Stage Investors:

Evidence from a Randomized Field Experiment. Journal of Finance. forthcoming.

Boudreau, K., Jeppesen, L. B., Reichstein, T., & Rullani, F. (2015). Crowdfunding as

“Donations”: Theory & Evidence. (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2669545)

Bourreau, M., Maillard, S., & Moreau, F. (2014). Stars vs. Underdogs in Online Music

Markets: The Effect of IT on Visibility, Artists’ Broadcasting, and Fans' Activities.

(SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2441976).

Burtch, G., Ghose, A., & Wattal, S. (2013). An Empirical Examination of the Antecedents

and Consequences of Contribution Patterns in Crowd-Funded Markets. Information

Systems Research, 24(3), 499-519.

Burtch, G., Ghose, A., & Wattal, S. (2014). An Empirical Examination of Peer Referrals in

Online Crowdfunding. ICIS 2014 Proceedings.

Burtch, G., Ghose, A., & Wattal, S. (2015). The Hidden Cost of Accommodating

Crowdfunder Privacy Preferences: A Randomized Field Experiment. Management

Science, 61(5), 949–962.

Byrne, D. (2012). How Music Works. Canongate Books.

Cassar, G. (2004). The financing of business start-ups. Journal of Business Venturing, 19,

261–283.

Chemin, M., & De Laat, J. (2013). Can Warm Glow Alleviate Credit Market Failure?

Evidence from Online Peer-to-Peer Lenders. Economic Development and Cultural

Change, 61(4), 825–858.

Page 28: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

28

Cholakova, M., & Clarysse, B. (2014). Does the Possibility to Make Equity Investments in

Crowdfunding Projects Crowd Out Reward-Based Investments? Entrepreneurship

Theory and Practice, 39(1), 145–172.

Colombo, M. G., Franzoni, C., & Rossi-Lamastra, C. (2015). Internal Social Capital and

the Attraction of Early Contributions in Crowdfunding. Entrepreneurship Theory and

Practice, 39(1), 75–100.

Connolly, M., & Krueger, A. B. (2006). Rockonomics: The Economics of Popular Music.

In Victor A. Ginsburg and David Throsby (Ed.), Handbook of the Economics of Art and

Culture (Vol. 1, p. 667-719). Elsevier.

Cumming, D. J., Leboeuf, G., & Schwienbacher, A. (2015). Crowdfunding Models: Keep-

It-All vs. All-Or-Nothing (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2447567).

Doshi, A. (2014). The Impact of High Performance Outliers on Two-Sided Platforms:

Evidence from Crowdfunding (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2422111).

Ebben, J., & Johnson, A. (2006). Bootstrapping in small firms: An empirical analysis of

change over time. Journal of Business Venturing, 21(6), 851–865.

Edelman, B. (2012). Using Internet Data for Economic Research. The Journal of Economic

Perspectives, 26(2), 189-206.

Essling, C., Koenen, J., & Peukert, C. (2014). Loudness War: How Record Labels

Compete for Consumer Attention. (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2444708)

Hauge, J. A., & Chimahusky, S. (2016). Are promises meaningless in an uncertaint

crowdfunding environment? Economic Inquiry, 2016.

Hildebrand, T., Puri, M., & Rocholl, J. (2013). Adverse Incentives in Crowdfunding.

SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 1615483.

Hui, J. S., Gerber, E. M., & Greenberg, M. (2012). Easy Money? The Demands of

Crowdfunding Work. Technical Report No. 4, (4), 1–11.

Page 29: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

29

Kim, K., & Hann, I.-H. (2014). Crowdfunding and the Democratization of Access to

Capital: A Geographical Analysis. Robert H. Smith School Research Paper.

Kuppuswamy, V., & Bayus, B. L. (2013). Crowdfunding Creative Ideas: The Dynamics of

Project Backers in Kickstarter (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2234765).

Lehner, O. M. (2013). Crowdfunding social ventures: a model and research agenda.

Venture Capital, 15(4), 289–311.

Li, Z. & Duan, J. (2014). Dynamic Strategies for Successful Online Crowdfunding. (SSRN

Scholarly Papers 2506352.)

Lin, M., Prabhala, N. R., & Viswanathan, S. (2013). Judging Borrowers by the Company

They Keep: Friendship Networks and Information Asymmetry in Online Peer-to-Peer

Lending. Management Science, 59(1), 17–35.

Lin, M. & Wei, Z. (2015). Market Mechanisms in Online Crowdfunding. (SSRN Scholarly

Paper No. ID 2328468).

Loginova, O., Wang, X. H., & Zeng, C. (2012). Learning in Advance Selling with

Heterogeneous Consumers. NET Institute Working Paper.

Ly, P., & Mason, G. (2012). Competition Between Microfinance NGOs: Evidence from

Kiva. World Development, 40(3), 643‑655.

Maillard, S. (2013). Consumer Information in the Digital Age: Empirical Evidence from

the Spillovers in the Music Industry. Working Paper.

Mollick, E. (2014). The dynamics of crowdfunding: An exploratory study. Journal of

Business Venturing, 29(1), 1-16.

Onnée S. & Renault S. (2014), Crowdfunding : vers une compréhension du rôle joué par la

foule. Management & Avenir, 74, p. 117-133.

Parker, S. C. (2014). Crowdfunding, cascades and informed investors. Economics Letters,

125(3), 432–435.

Page 30: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

30

Strausz, R. (2015). Crowdfunding, Demand Uncertainty, and Moral Hazard - a

Mechanism Design Approach. Working Paper.

Schwienbacher, A. (2015). Entrepreneurial Risk-Taking in Crowdfunding Campaigns

(SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2506355).

Schwienbacher, A., & Larralde, B. (2010). Crowdfunding of Small Entrepreneurial

Ventures. Handbook of Entrepreneurial Finance, 2010, 1–23.

Van Auken, H. E., & Neeley, L. (1996). Evidence of bootstrap financing among small

start-up firms. The Journal of Entrepreneurial and Small Business Finance, 5(3), 235–

249.

Viotto, J. (2015). « Competition and regulation of crowdfunding platforms: a two-sided market

approach », Communications & Strategies, 99, p. 33-50

Waldfogel, J. (2011). Bye, Bye, Miss American Pie? The Supply of New Recorded Music

Since Napster (Working Paper No. 16882). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Xu, T. (2015). The Informational Role of Crowdfunding. Working Paper.

Zhang, J., & Liu, P. (2012). Rational Herding in Microloan Markets. Management Science,

58(5), 892–912.

Zvilichovsky, D., Inbar, Y., & Barzilay, O. (2013). Playing Both Sides of the Market:

Success and Reciprocity on Crowdfunding Platforms. (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID

2304101).

Page 31: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

31

Appendix

Table A.1: Probit estimation results for the decision to release an album in the market. Dependent variable: dummy indicating the release on e-commerce channels.

Information proxy: total number of supporters.

(1) (2) (3) Fail -1.101*** -0.936*** -1.071***

(0.253) (0.280) (0.262) Fail* Log(Supporters+1)

0.142 0.115 0.257* (0.124) (0.123) (0.132)

Log(Supporters+1) -0.008 0.0137 -0.009 (0.094) (0.091) (0.095)

Previous Albums 0.0494

0.0490 (0.0333) (0.0331)

Fail*PreviousAlbums 0.0738

0.0744 (0.058) (0.061)

First Album

-0.242* (0.129)

Fail*FirstAlbum

-0.137 (0.261)

Production Phase -0.059*** -0.059*** -0.057*** (0.0212) (0.0214) (0.0212)

Fail*ProductionPhase 0.00687 0.0105 0.0217 (0.0453) (0.0437) (0.0457)

Log(FB Fans) 0.0479 0.0442 0.0475 (0.0413) (0.0410) (0.0423)

Constant 0.639 0.841 0.641 (0.551) (0.572) (0.557)

Observations 707 707 689

Wald chi2 (17) 167.4 (17) 169.5 (17) 169.2

Prob>chi2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Pseudo R2 0.2082 0.2071 0.2061 Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The first column presents the results of the estimation of the main model. On the second column, the variable previous albums is substituted by the dummy first album. On the third column, we run the first regression excluding the projects that had zero contributions – project owners failing after having attracted some contribution may behave differently than project owners that failed for receiving no contributions at all.

Page 32: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

32

Table A.2: Probit estimation results for the decision to release an album in the

market. Dependent variable: dummy indicating the release on e-commerce channels. Information proxy: average collected.

(1) (2) (3) Fail -2.805*** -2.493*** -3.545***

(0.744) (0.762) (0.834) Fail*Log(Av. Collected+1)

0.353** 0.323* 0.517*** (0.168) (0.167) (0.189)

Log(Av. Collected+1) -0.254* -0.245* -0.244* (0.140) (0.140) (0.140)

Previous Albums 0.047

0.047 (0.0322) (0.0322)

Fail*PreviousAlbums 0.082

0.084 (0.0551) (0.0562)

First Album

-0.233* (0.129)

Fail*FirstAlbum

-0.179 (0.253)

Production Phase -0.0592***

-0.0586***

-0.0585***

(0.0215) (0.0217) (0.0215) Fail*ProductionPhase 0.0120 0.0152 0.0291

(0.0464) (0.0447) (0.0463) Log(FB Fans) 0.0477 0.0477 0.0459

(0.0389) (0.0378) (0.0397) Constant 1.785** 1.917** 1.759**

(0.838) (0.846) (0.842)

Observations 707 707 689 Wald chi2 (17) 169.3 (17) 169.7 (17) 162.1 Prob>chi2 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 Pseudo R2 0.2107 0.2091 0.2089 Robust standard errors in parentheses; *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. The first column presents the results of the estimation of the main model. On the second column, the variable previous albums is substituted by the dummy first album. On the third column, we run the first regression excluding the projects that had zero contributions – project owners failing after having attracted some contribution may behave differently than project owners that failed for receiving no contributions at all.

Page 33: Beyond financing: crowdfunding as an informational mechanismunice.fr/laboratoires/gredeg/contenus-riches/... · Internet-based sources. The main one is Kickstarter, considered one

33

Figure A. 1: Toad the Wet Sproacket’s Kickstarter campaign

and examples of rewards in detail (right).

Figure A.2: Toad the Wet Sproacket’s crowdfunded album on Amazon.