billionaires in world politics - agents transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their...

25
1 Peter Hägel The American University of Paris [email protected] Paper prepared for the ECPR Joint Sessions St. Gallen, April 1217, 2011 Workshop 14: „Bringing the Individual Back In‟ – International Relations and the First Image Workshop directors: Astrid Carrapatoso & Bernd Schlipphak first draft work in progress please do not quote comments welcome BILLIONAIRES IN WORLD POLITICS: SUPER-AGENTS TRANSFORMING STRUCTURES? Introduction When Forbes started its famous global listing in 1987, the world‟s richest 200 individuals accounted for US$ 300 billion of wealth in 2011, they possessed US$ 2.4 trillion, and the overall number of billionaires worldwide had risen from 140 to 1210, who now collectively own US$ 4.5 trillion. 1 Though largely under-researched as a political phenomenon, 2 the rise of billionaires has already transformed electoral politics in several countries, with cases such as Berlusconi in Italy, Bloomberg in New York, Thaksin in Thailand, Piñera in Chile, or Blocher in Switzerland. As many billionaires have made their wealth in global business and finance, several of them have also entered global politics. 1 For the Forbes list and its methodology, see: http://www.forbes.com/wealth/billionaires and http://www.forbes.com/free_forbes/2007/0326/170.html . The focus on “billionaires” is somewhat arbitrary: the discussion in this paper can be applied to many millionaires just as well. However, “billions” are the common accounting unit for states and multinational corporations, and it is thus symbolically interesting that some individuals play in the same accounting league. Also, the Forbes list is the only useful list of the world‟s ultra-wealthy, and, nowadays, it only includes billionaires. 2 Besides quite insightful journalistic bestsellers like Superclass (Rothkopf 2008) or Richistan (Frank 2007), very little comparative political science research on the ultra-wealthy exists so far. Winters‟ (forthcoming, 2011) study of oligarchy will be a first remedy (see Winters & Page 2009 for a discussion of oligarchy in the USA).

Upload: others

Post on 03-Jul-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

1

Peter Hägel The American University of Paris

[email protected]

Paper prepared for the ECPR Joint Sessions St. Gallen, April 12‐17, 2011

Workshop 14: „Bringing the Individual Back In‟ – International Relations and the First Image

Workshop directors: Astrid Carrapatoso & Bernd Schlipphak

first draft – work in progress – please do not quote – comments welcome

BILLIONAIRES IN WORLD POLITICS: SUPER-AGENTS TRANSFORMING STRUCTURES?

Introduction

When Forbes started its famous global listing in 1987, the world‟s richest 200

individuals accounted for US$ 300 billion of wealth – in 2011, they possessed US$

2.4 trillion, and the overall number of billionaires worldwide had risen from 140 to

1210, who now collectively own US$ 4.5 trillion.1 Though largely under-researched as

a political phenomenon,2 the rise of billionaires has already transformed electoral

politics in several countries, with cases such as Berlusconi in Italy, Bloomberg in New

York, Thaksin in Thailand, Piñera in Chile, or Blocher in Switzerland. As many

billionaires have made their wealth in global business and finance, several of them

have also entered global politics.

1 For the Forbes list and its methodology, see: http://www.forbes.com/wealth/billionaires and

http://www.forbes.com/free_forbes/2007/0326/170.html . The focus on “billionaires” is somewhat arbitrary: the discussion in this paper can be applied to many millionaires just as well. However, “billions” are the common accounting unit for states and multinational corporations, and it is thus symbolically interesting that some individuals play in the same accounting league. Also, the Forbes list is the only useful list of the world‟s ultra-wealthy, and, nowadays, it only includes billionaires. 2 Besides – quite insightful – journalistic bestsellers like Superclass (Rothkopf 2008) or Richistan

(Frank 2007), very little comparative political science research on the ultra-wealthy exists so far. Winters‟ (forthcoming, 2011) study of oligarchy will be a first remedy (see Winters & Page 2009 for a discussion of oligarchy in the USA).

Page 2: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

2

Their status equips billionaires with qualities that turn them into singular individual

actors. Most obviously, their enormous wealth is a highly fungible power resource

that allows them to pursue their goals quite autonomously. Moreover, the very

process of accumulating these material assets appears to create a self-

understanding that emphasizes strong voluntarism. Having succeeded in conquering

the business world is likely to confer a sense of “anything is possible” to billionaires‟

ventures into politics. Or, as George Soros once put it: “Yes, I do have a foreign

policy, and now I have it more consciously. My goal is to become the conscience of

the world” (Kaufman 2002: 293). Especially through philanthropy, billionaires like

George Soros and Bill Gates have made bold attempts to transform the world‟s

political and socio-economic structures. Their activities raise important questions

about the role of individuals in world politics, which relates to a central ontological

problem of social science: the relationship between agents and structure.

For the most part, this paper will be content to remain at the pre-theoretical level,

attempting to establish how and to what an extent billionaires are “super-agents” with

extraordinary capacities to “change the world”.

Individuals, agency and structure in IR

Mostly developed by scholars within sociology and the philosophy of science, the

agent-structure discussion entered International Relations (IR), which had addressed

similar concerns less rigorously through the “levels of analysis” and “images”

perspectives, rather late (Wendt 1987, Dessler 1989, Hollis & Smith 1994). “It

emerges from two uncontentious truths about social life: first, that human agency is

the only moving force behind the actions, events, and outcomes of the social world;

and second, that human agency can be realized only in concrete historical

circumstances that condition the possibilities for action and influence its course”

Page 3: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

3

(Dessler 1989: 443). This leads to an understanding of agents and structures as

mutually constituting each other (Giddens 1984, Sewell 1992): it is agents that

establish, sustain or transform social structures, while, simultaneously, existing

structures enable or constrain agency. Taking such a co-constitution of agents and

structures seriously implies that “where both agents and structure are conditions of

possibility for the other, and each has emergent powers irreducible to the other, then

the interplay between the two could not possibly be determined in advance of the

research process” (Wight 2006: 280).

It seems clear that the rise of billionaires since the 1980s is linked to several

structural changes that have created an enabling context which allows more

individuals to become billionaires. During the 20th century, the two World Wars,

Communist revolutions, and the Great Depression had destroyed much previously

existing wealth, and progressive income taxation, combined with stricter controls of

finance, limited the accumulation of wealth post-WWII (Atkinson & Piketty 2007,

2010). Micro-economic research has examined the conditions under which a few

actors can dominate so-called “winner-take-all” markets (Frank & Cook 1995, Rosen

1981). This can happen in oligopolistic or monopolistic markets (here one can think of

the oil, gas and other natural resources billionaires), but also in highly competitive

markets when extraordinary achievement is coupled with extraordinary rewards (the

paradigmatic examples being entertainment or sports superstars). Confirmation for

this comes from statistical analysis that finds billionaires concentrated in countries

with high corruption scores, but also in countries with high economic freedom scores

(Neumayer 2004, Torgler & Piatti 2007).

Page 4: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

4

Globalization, which grew steadily since the 1950s and strongly since the 1970s, is

the structural trend that has amplified the benefits of those who succeed in “winner-

take-all” markets, if only for the simple fact that it enlarges such markets.3 Support for

this argument can be found in the fact that owners of multinational corporations form

the largest group of billionaires on the Forbes list. Within globalization, the re-

emergence of global finance since the 1970s is particularly important for two reasons:

as it links and integrates national capital markets, it facilitates the growth of

corporations and their owners‟ wealth; and it also allows greater opportunities to

financial investors/speculators to become billionaires, which is again reflected by this

profession‟s prominence on the Forbes list.

Clearly, states have been highly involved in facilitating globalization as an enabling

condition for the rise of billionaires (Helleiner 1994, Frieden 2006). They have been

even more directly responsible for another structural factor that makes capital

accumulation easier: the significant reduction of taxes on high incomes and wealth

(Roine, Vlachos & Waldenström 2009), especially since the 1990s. This is related to

the growth of tax avoidance opportunities being offered by tax havens, which have

become key nodes for private capital flows since the 1970s (Palan, Murphy &

Chavagneux 2010, Shaxson 2011). In combination, both taxation trends create an

environment that enhances the chances of some to become ultra-rich, because they

face less re-distributional state action.

None of these favorable structural conditions are uniform across countries, which

continue to differ with regards to their integration into the global economy and the tax

3 Of course, large domestic markets – like the US, China or Germany – can also produce billionaires,

even in mainly domestic economic sectors like retailing or real estate. In the literature, “winner-take-all” does not literally mean “all” as under a monopoly, but simply “a large share” – market leaders.

Page 5: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

5

regimes they apply. Still, overall they create a global context that affects most

individuals in their pursuit of wealth. Another structural factor of great consequence,

which concerns all of the other factors mentioned above, is the peacefulness that

developed countries have enjoyed since WWII. Not only, because wars are the most

potent destroyers of assets, but also, because the sacrifices of the 20th century‟s two

world wars had created strong egalitarian demands for taxing the affluent – which

appear to decrease in times of peace (Scheve & Stasavage 2010).

Individual agency in IR

Most theorizing in IR has been concentrating on systemic structures and collective

actors – and for good reasons: world politics is a crowded arena in which even great

powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even

someone as attentive to the mutual constitution of agents and structures as

Alexander Wendt to privileging third image theorizing, going as far as treating the

state as a person (Wendt 1987, 2004). The Oxford Handbook of International

Relations is exemplary in this respect: The only entry that somewhat covers

individuals‟ roles is the one on the foreign policy decision-making subfield (Stuart

2008), while the entry on moral agency is focusing mostly on collective actors,

because “[i]ndividual human beings on their own lack the power, coordination, and

resources necessary to achieve many espoused goals” (Erskine 2008: 701). Such a

statement is simply wrong when billionaires control financial resources that rival

many states‟ budgets.

Despite overall neglect, some renewed attention to the first image has occurred

within all the major IR approaches. Ironically, while liberalism could be expected to be

the approach predestined to address the first image, given its foundational thinkers‟

Page 6: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

6

focus on individual freedom and choice (Locke, Smith, …), liberal IR theory has been

surprisingly silent about the role of individuals in world politics. Following neo-liberal

institutionalism‟s over-engagement with structural realism, the reorganization of

liberal theory since the 1990s has emphasized the importance of societal preferences

that shape states‟ foreign policies (Moravcsik 1997: 517f, also 1999). While this

privileges organized interests/collective actors, such a perspective also drives studies

of individuals‟ preferences – but they matter only insofar as they are being

aggregated, explaining, for example, how higher levels of education lead to more

support for free trade within a nation (Hainmueller & Hiscox 2006, Mansfield & Mutz

2009). Realist approaches remain wedded to state power and international power

structures, but the rediscovery of “great statesmen” picks up on classical realists‟

concerns with leadership (Byman & Pollack 2001). Here, the precondition for

individuals to make a difference remains, however, their institutional position as

leaders of powerful states.

The most sophisticated attempts to “bring the individual back” into world politics have

been developed within the constructivist research agenda, which seems logical,

because the agent-structure problematique and the social interactions that construct

reality are at the heart of this approach (Berger & Luckmann 1967). Thus, various

studies of political entrepreneurs have analyzed how individuals within epistemic

communities (Adler & Haas 1992) or advocacy networks (Keck & Sikkink 1998) use

their abilities to provide expertise and/or ideas to influence politics. Stacie Goddard

has recently theorized such entrepreneurship more systematically: “[t]o study

entrepreneurs is to ask how particular actors come to realize their capacity for radical

transformation – why it is that some actors exhibit the power to effect change, while

others only reproduce the structure around them” (2009: 253). She distinguishes two

Page 7: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

7

understandings of how political entrepreneurs can effect change: (1) a strongly

agent-centered approach that emphasizes the categorical attributes of individuals,

and (2) a more structural approach that focuses on the position of entrepreneurs in

social relations. This reflects Colin Wight‟s understanding of agency as “the ability /

power to act with intention”, which is “inextricably linked to social contexts through the

relations in which it is embedded” (2006: 212+213). Yet, most individuals lack

autonomous control over resources – even “great statesmen” must adhere to

budgetary procedures and constraints. And other categorical attributes like skills or

knowledge/expertise are problematic, because most of the time one can only observe

them in action, with hindsight. For these reasons, Goddard, in line with most research

on political entrepreneurs, looks at how their capacity for change derives from their

position, especially within networks (2009: 256ff).

Billionaires as super-agents?

Unlike most individuals, billionaires do have “state-like” budgets under their control.

The Forbes list measures their wealth in terms of assets at market prices, and

therefore does not give a clear indication of the amount of disposable wealth or the

potential financial power of billionaires, because not all assets are liquid or could be

liquidated at market prices, which, naturally, fluctuate. The annual reshuffling and

turnover on the Forbes list – only 52 persons from the 1987 inaugural list were still on

the list twenty years later4 – indicates the volatility of many fortunes. Still, financial

assets are highly fungible and, in theory, many billionaires probably could follow Bill

Gates‟ example and transform shares in their companies into capital used for other

purposes, shifting from being an economic to becoming a social or political

entrepreneur. In line with Amartya Sen‟s (1999) approach to agency, which sees it as

4 http://www.forbes.com/free_forbes/2007/0326/170.html .

Page 8: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

8

the capability to effect change according to one‟s objectives, billionaires can

therefore be seen as super-agents. Such an understanding also reflects William

Sewell‟s discussion of agency, as he highlights the capacity of agents to mobilize and

transpose resources from one context to another (1992: 16-20).

But whether individual billionaires are in fact able to transpose their financial assets

into political power needs to be determined empirically. New sociological studies of

the wealthy in Germany emphasize exactly this difference between the purely

material capabilities that wealth offers (Reichtum) and the capacity of individuals to

use their wealth for something else than just wealth-generation (Vermögen).5

Research is showing that, at a general level, wealthy individuals do exhibit a stronger

self-understanding of having capabilities to effect change than the average middle-

class citizen (Lauterbach & Tarvenkorn 2011, Grundmann 2011). Wealthy individuals

also appear as generally more socially engaged, but this seems to depend on the

sources of their wealth: the (broadly defined) social engagement of those who earned

their wealth as entrepreneurs is 20% higher than of those who inherited their wealth

(Ströing & Kramer 2011: 104). The very experience of success in the business world

can thus be seen as building agency-capacity among billionaires, because it instills a

strong sense of voluntarism in individuals. It does not, however, guarantee that

economic entrepreneurs become successful political entrepreneurs, as the following

proposal by the CEO of a leading aircraft manufacturer vis-à-vis an American

congressman illustrates:

“I want to sell a plane to Muammar Qadddafi and he wants to buy one. But we

have sanctions in place (…). The U.S. wants this guy dead. So, (…) if you help

5 In German, both Reichtum and Vermögen mean “wealth”, but vermögen is also a verb that means

“being able to do something”. See Druyen 2011 and Lauterbach, Druyen & Grundmann 2011.

Page 9: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

9

me get the okay to sell him the plane, I‟ll build it with explosive bolts (…).

Then, one day he‟s flying over the Med and we push the button. He‟s gone. I

make my sale. Everyone‟s happy.” (Rothkopf 2007: xxiii)

In this example, the CEO exhibits an extraordinary voluntarism, and he controls the

resources to effect change, but his exclusive focus on a business logic of

consequences prevent him from seeing why an elected politician would be unable to

respond to his proposal.

Billionaires’ goals in world politics: security, material interests, and esteem

Once we have identified the autonomy of billionaires, the next research question

concerns their motives and why they choose to pursue some goals and not others.

Although notoriously difficult to assess, as they can be hidden and mixed, motives

are essential for any understanding of agency – unless one reduces motives and

goals to being structurally induced, e.g. by an anarchical state of nature. With regards

to states as actors in world politics, the discussion in IR used to be narrowed down to

how they pursue relative security and/or absolute economic gains (Grieco 1988).

Constructivist research has argued that states‟ objectives also depend on their

identities and the prevailing (inter)national norms (Checkel 1998, Finnemore &

Sikkink 1998), which imbue actors with a logic of appropriateness (March & Olson

1998).

Richard Ned Lebow has recently integrated these constructivist insights into a

cultural theory of IR, which is particularly useful here, because he distinguishes

fundamental motives and goals in politics that he assumes to exist at any level of

agency, individual or collective (Lebow 2008: 114-117). Besides security and material

interests (what he calls “satiation”), which entail the acquisition of power and wealth,

Page 10: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

10

he identifies esteem as a third goal in politics, which depends on obtaining honor or

standing (ibid. 43-121, esp. 91).6 As a relational goal that requires recognition by

others, esteem‟s precise meaning is cultural in the sense that it varies across time

and societies, depending on what is being recognized (and thus socially constructed)

to bring honor. All three goals clearly matter when billionaires act in world politics.

Billionaires do have to worry more about their security than ordinary citizens,

because their wealth makes them tempting targets for extortion, as several high-

profile kidnappings of billionaires (or their family members) have proven.7

Nevertheless, often they can rely on protection by the states in which they reside,

and they obviously have the funds to pay for supplementary private protection, so

that fear for their personal security is probably not a major concern for their

involvement in politics. They can, however, impact upon the international security

agenda if they view security not just as a personal affair, and decide to finance war or

peace efforts. Several allegations of terrorist financing by billionaires have been put

forward, e.g. concerning links between Saudi billionaire Khalid Bin Mahfouz and al-

Qaeda,8 or American billionaire Raj Rajaratnam and the Tamil Tigers in Sri Lanka.9

But they remain unproven so far, because hard evidence is hard to come by – if such

financing happens, it will happen secretly, so as not to expose the source. More in

the open, other billionaires have used their funds to support peace efforts: Ted

Turner‟s one-billion-dollar donation to the United Nations in 1997 is among the most

6 Ironically, even one of the foundational works of rational choice allows for individuals to enter politics

for “the income, power and prestige” that come with public functions (Downs 1957: 137). To what an extent each of these goals matter for an individual clearly can make huge differences for their behavior, but Downs goes on to discuss only material self-interest. For honor in IR, see also Markey 2000 and Joshi 2008. 7 Among the most famous cases are J. Paul Getty‟s grandson in 1973, Hong-Kong tycoon Li Ka-

shing‟s son in 1996, Walter Kwok in 1997, and Eddie Lampert in 2003, but the list is much longer. 8 Mahfouz sued against these allegations, and won all his lawsuits; see Ehrenfeld 2005: xi-xiv and

http://www.binmahfouz.info/en_index.html. 9 See “Sri Lanka claims Rajaratnam gave Tamil Tigers „millions‟”, Financial Times, 18 October 2009:

http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/9629749a-bc17-11de-9426-00144feab49a.html#axzz1IXbPJ1HB.

Page 11: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

11

famous examples,10 but this can also operate on a smaller scale, such as the Irish

American Chuck Feeney‟s donations to Sinn Fein to support the peace process in

Northern Ireland during the 1990s (O‟Clery 2007: 184-194). These cases also

demonstrate the links between billionaires‟ source of wealth and their political efforts,

a global outlook in business translating into transnational political engagement:

Mahfouz used to be the partial owner of the global scandal bank BCCI, Rajaratnam

runs a hedge fund, Turner founded CNN, and Feeney made his fortune with a duty-

free shopping chain.

Billionaires also engage in world politics just to satisfy their material interests. Jeffrey

Winters and Benjamin Page (2009) have already analyzed such behavior with

regards to the specter of oligarchy in the United States. The most straightforward

examples are lobbying endeavors vis-à-vis governments and international

organizations, in order to advance individuals‟ business interests. As with billionaires

financing terrorism or war, such actions will tend to be covert and thus difficult to

research. A case in point would be the Indian steel-magnate Lakshmi Mittal, among

the world‟s ten wealthiest individuals, and his efforts to influence British, U.S. and EU

politicians in order to boost the business prospects of his company ArcelorMittal. He

apparently wants to make more money to be able to continue buying the most

expensive homes in the world, and to finance the most extravagant parties.11 Another

striking example are the Americans David and Charles Koch, each in the Forbes top

10

http://www.unfoundation.org/press-center/press-releases/2006/ret-new-committment-another-1-billion.html . An earlier example is Andrew Carnegie‟s Endowment for International Peace: http://www.carnegieendowment.org/ . 11

See: “Glimpsing a fairytale wedding”, BBC News, 22 June 2004: http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/south_asia/3830009.stm; “Mittal 'outraged' by Steelgate row”, BBC News, 22 Februayry 2002: http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/uk_news/politics/1834776.stm; “LN Mittal spent $470,000 lobbying with US on China”, The Economic Times, 7 May 2009: http://articles.economictimes.indiatimes.com/2009-05-07/news/27656957_1_arcelormittal-spokesperson-mittal-steel-largest-steel; “Carbon credits bring Lakshmi Mittal £1bn bonanza”, The Sunday Times, 6 December 2009: http://business.timesonline.co.uk/tol/business/industry_sectors/industrials/article6945991.ece.

Page 12: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

12

twenty, who co-own the petroleum- and chemicals-based Koch Industries. As their

conglomerate would be financially affected by climate change mitigation policies,

between 2005 and 2008 alone, the brothers have put around US$ 25 million into

think tanks and foundations that intervene with skepticism or denial in the global

climate change debate (Greenpeace 2010). Mittal‟s and the Kochs‟ business empires

are both truly global, with operations in around 60 countries, which explains their

transnational political activism.

The pursuit of esteem by billionaires is an easier goal to study, because honor

depends on public recognition. As Richard Ned Lebow argues, honor as the means

to achieve esteem is directly related to one‟s standing, and honor societies therefore

tend to be highly stratified (2008: 63-72, 162-164). Esteem should thus be of

particular importance in the contemporary world where the inequalities between

those at the very top and the rest have been widening over the past twenty years,

where now a good thousand billionaires own as much wealth as the poorest half of

the earth‟s adult inhabitants (Davies 2008). One can also assume that once an

individual has enough power and wealth to fulfill all security and material goals,

esteem becomes more important. Many achievements, such as winning yachts races

or assembling prestigious art collections, might bring honor. But the politically most

relevant aspect of competition for honor in today‟s world appears to be philanthropy,

at least in the American cultural context (Friedman & McGarvie 2003), as evidenced

most recently by the so-called “Giving Pledge”. Officially launched by America‟s

wealthiest individuals, Warren Buffet and Bill Gates, in June 2010, it invites American

billionaires to make a public “moral commitment to give (…) the majority of their

Page 13: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

13

wealth to the philanthropic causes (…) of their choice”.12 59 pledges have been made

so far, out of a potential 413 American billionaires on the current Forbes list. Among

such giving, international philanthropy like the Bill & Melinda Gates foundation‟s,

which has granted US$ 9 billion to global health initiatives between 1998 and 2007

(McCoy et al. 2009), can have profound impacts on world politics. It may also earn

Bill Gates a Nobel Prize for Peace in the future.

International philanthropy practices, honor and individual agency

Going back to Greek mythology – Aeschylus recounting the Titan Prometheus‟

philanthropos as he gave fire to humans – the basic meaning of philanthropy refers

to a love for humanity that manifests itself in serving others. Robert Payton and

Michael Moody define it as “moral action”, used by individuals to “implement their

moral imagination” and to “interven[e] in other people‟s lives (…) to do them good

and to advance the public good” (2008: 96). Such an agency-centered interpretation

can be useful to understand the altruistic individual, giving anonymously, only

concerned about his or her self-esteem. It cannot, however, explain why philanthropy

is being pursued more or less, during different time periods, in different societies.

Based on her fieldwork among American philanthropists, Francie Ostrower arrives at

a definition that emphasizes the socially constructed aspect of philanthropy. She

sees philanthropy as “a mark of class status that contributes to defining and

maintaining the culture and organizational boundaries of elite life”, which “takes on

meaning in the context of a cultural emphasis on individualism and private initiative

and a mistrust of governmental power and large-scale bureaucracies” (1995: 6+8).

12

See http://givingpledge.org/. Steel-baron Andrew Carnegie had made similar efforts to promote

“giving back to society” a century earlier, as advocated in his “Gospel of Wealth” (1889). Attempts by

Buffet and Gates to persuade billionaires in China and India to join or emulate the initiative have so far

yielded few results, see “Buffett and Gates Prod India‟s Wealthy to Be More Philanthropic”, The New

York Times, 24 March 2011: http://www.nytimes.com/2011/03/25/business/global/25rupee.html.

Page 14: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

14

As such, philanthropy can be studied through the perspective of practices, the

“socially meaningful patterns of action” (Adler & Pouliot 2011: 4, see also Pouliot

2008), which link agency with structure. It is only against the background knowledge

of a culture of philanthropy that the performance of philanthropic acts brings honor to

an individual, fulfilling his or her quest for esteem by others.

Nicolas Guilhot (2007) has already applied such a Bourdieu-inspired understanding

of practices to George Soros‟ international philanthropy in establishing the Central

European University in Hungary. But just as Bourdieu‟s theory of practice leaves little

room for agency (Sewell 1992: 13ff), Guilhot‟s analysis comes close to structural

Marxism when he sees Soros‟ philanthropy as a strategy by “the new

transnationalized social strata representing the hegemony of financial capital, whose

power depends on their capacity to perpetuate the new socioeconomic order” (2007:

447). At a general level, philanthropy may indeed be interpreted as a habitus among

the ultra-wealthy to legitimate their privileged position and the capitalist system in

which they have thrived, as data on average giving in the U.S. shows. Estimates

indicate that North American high-net worth individuals give around 8% of their

wealth to philanthropy (Center for Global Prosperity 2010: 10). This is highly

correlated to the structure of the U.S. tax system, which foresees generous income

tax rebates if one donates income to one‟s private foundation. Such foundations

must, in turn, give away 5% of their wealth to charitable causes every year (Silk et al.

2003). Among such giving by Americans, international philanthropy has been

increasing steadily throughout the second half of the 20th century (Curti 1963: 506f),

tripling from US$ 12 billion in 1988 to US$ 37 billion in 2008 (Hudson Institute 2006,

2010).

Page 15: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

15

The problem for a structural understanding of practices, however, is that most

billionaires do not donate most of their wealth to philanthropy. Likewise, the decision

over which charitable causes to support relates to habitus to some degree: the arts,

disease research and universities are among the “habitual” recipients of philanthropy

in the United States. But more specific decisions about what and how to give cannot

be explained without a greater focus on the individual philanthropist‟s agency.

Friedman‟s historical analysis of American philanthropy captures as much:

“[P]hilanthropy has had much to do with a specific person who has intended at

least some measure of charitable benevolence towards others (…). To a

greater or lesser extent, the philanthropist has imposed his/her vision of a

good society (…) on others (…). Yet, the individual philanthropist has never

(…) been separable from the institutional context of his/her behavior.”

(Friedman 2003: 9)

Thus, Bill Gates‟ philanthropic focus on education and health can be seen as a

“habitual” pursuit of honor in the American cultural context, whereas his decisions to

give most of his wealth and to shift his entrepreneurship from Microsoft to his

foundation require us to take agency more seriously.13 It could even be argued that

Buffet and Gates‟ “Giving Pledge” is a voluntary attempt to create something like a

practice of “giving it all away” among the world‟s ultra-wealthy, and hence constitutes

an example of super-agents trying to transform the habitus of philanthropy. George

Soros‟ international philanthropy, which started as early as 1979 (Kaufmann 2002:

163ff), and which tries to foster “open societies”, also appears as much more creative

than a simple perpetuation of an existing habitus.

13

This connects with Marcus Kornprobst‟s notion of “judgment” (2011), who has recently argued that the scholarly categories of agent‟s logics of action are insufficient to capture the element of creativity in individual‟s choices, which are better to be analyzed with the notion of “judgement”.

Page 16: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

16

As mentioned before, a key aspect of agency is the ability of agents to mobilize

resources from one background to another – which is exactly what both Gates and

Soros have been doing. Both achieved market-leader positions with their businesses:

Gates in founding Microsoft (Wallace & Erickson 1993), Soros in founding the

Quantum fund, for many years the most profitable hedge fund. And both transferred

their material and entrepreneurial resources into their philanthropy, which is global

and results-oriented like their businesses. Such an approach to philanthropy –

dubbed social entrepreneurship (Bornstein 2004) or philanthrocapitalism (Bishop &

Green 2008) – may indeed have turned into a new practice among billionaires, but it

is individuals like Soros and Gates that created this role model.

George Soros: building civil society

George Soros‟ liberal worldview has been strongly influenced by his personal

experience of totalitarian Nazi and Stalinist rule as a teenager in his native Hungary,

and by his subsequent studies with Karl Popper at the LSE during exile in London.

As he explains himself, after a successful career in hedge fund management, during

the late 1970s,

“I determined (…) that I had enough money (…), that what really mattered to

me was the concept of an open society, based on the recognition that we all

act on the basis of imperfect understanding. (…) Therefore, (…) we need a

democratic form of government (…); we need a market economy (…); we

need to protect minorities (…), we need the rule of law.” (Soros 1995: 112f,

see also Kaufman 2002: 27-72).

He went to support dissidents in Eastern Europe (Charter 77 in Czechslovakia,

Solidarnosc in Poland), and established his first foundation in Hungary in 1984, which

promoted academic and cultural exchanges. Soros was no billionaire yet, but these

Page 17: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

17

early efforts required relatively little money to produce results – one of his operations

with the greatest impact was to send several hundred Xerox machines to Hungarian

cultural and educational institutions (Kaufman 2002: 189-200). As the Soviet Union

crumbled and his fortune reached ten digits, Soros delegated more and more of his

business to his associates and employees, and turned his philanthropy from private

side-projects into his main activity (Soros 1991). He set up an Open Society

Foundation (OSI) network all over the former Soviet Union and Warsaw Pact

countries, with the explicit goal to build open societies, funding a wide variety of

educational projects, human rights associations and independent media. Between

1994 and 2000, his personal contributions to his various foundations totaled more

than US$ 2.5 billion (Kaufman 2002: 256).

This is not the place to analyze Soros‟ philanthropy in detail. In terms of impact, there

have been great achievements, for example his US$ 100 million intervention to

prevent Soviet science from disintegrating or his US $50 million rescue mission to

supply the besieged Sarajevo with drinking water during the Bosnian war in 1992/3

(ibid. 268ff). There also have been substantial failures, for example when trying to

advance civil society in China (ibid. 213-221) or when promoting a master plan for

economic reform of the Soviet Union (Soros 1991: 99-117). Most studies of the post-

Soviet transformations in Eastern Europe agree that Soros‟s OSI network contributed

much to foster civil societies, whose actors became key players in the transitions

toward democracy (Carothers & Ottaway 2000, Stewart 2009). Research also shows

that Soros, through his foundations, provided very targeted and critical support to the

– eventually winning – opposition groups during the so-called “color revolutions”

(Sussman & Krader 2008), especially in Georgia (Angley 2010) and Ukraine (Wilson

2006). As such, one can interpret Soros‟ philanthropy as a super-agent‟s attempt to

Page 18: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

18

transform social and political structures in a variety of countries. The best

confirmation for such an evaluation comes from the fact that, after the “color

revolutions” in Eastern Europe, several governments in Central Asia clamped down

on foreign NGOs‟ activities in their countries, specifically Soros‟s foundations, notably

in Kazakhstan and Uzbekistan, but also in Russia (Berg 2008).

In terms of agency, three central aspects run through Soros‟s philanthropic

biography. One is a strong sense of voluntarism to change the world, which he

expressed himself repeatedly:

“I was a confirmed egoist but I considered the pursuit of self-interest as too

narrow a base for my rather inflated self. If truth be known, I carried some

rather potent messianic fantasies with me from childhood which I felt I had to

control, otherwise they might get me into trouble. But when I had made my

way in the world I wanted to indulge in my fantasies to the extent that I could

afford.” (Soros 1991: 3)

Second is a strong capacity to transpose such voluntarism from his business career,

which was built on daring speculative bets, often involving political changes (Slater

2009: 69-107), to his political endeavors. “In both business and philanthropy he shied

away from permanent entanglements (…), he favored projects of limited duration but

great potential impact” (Kaufman 2002: 179). Diane Stone has argued that the very

decentralized structure of Soros‟ OSI foundation leads to institutional logics becoming

more important, rather than Soros being the great decision-making man (Stone 2008:

17f). This is certainly true to some extent, but Soros has been fully aware of this

problem from the beginning: “I don‟t like foundations. I think foundations corrupt the

impulse that lead to their formation. That is so because foundations become

institutions and institutions take on a life of their own” (Soros 1991: 130). In terms of

Page 19: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

19

strategy, setting priorities, and shifting funds accordingly, Soros always tried to “stay

ahead of the curve”. One clear instance of this is his shifting of his activities from

Eastern Europe to U.S. domestic politics (Soros 1995: 137ff + 177ff).

Finally, Soros‟s agency reveals a continuous struggle for esteem, evidenced, for

example, in the many books he has published. But he is also frankly open about this:

“I have had these illusions, or perhaps delusions, of grandeur and they have driven

me” (quoted in Kaufman 2002: 292). His biographer recounts how Soros was being

laughed at by the political establishment after advocating a Marshall Plan for Eastern

Europe at a think tank conference on European security in 1988 (ibid: 228ff, also

290ff). This quasi-traumatic episode showed him the limits of moving from finance to

politics, but four years later, his financial success helped him to overcome these. His

greatest investment feat, the speculation against the British pound in 1992, gave him

worldwide publicity as “the man who broke the Bank of England” and made a billion

dollars profit on it. “He made a conscious decision to exploit this new notoriety (…) to

gain influence among world leaders and to become what he has since described as a

stateless statesman” (Kaufman 2002: xiii, see also 235-241).

Conclusion

This paper has argued that billionaires can be super-agents in world politics, with a

large degree of autonomy that is mainly due to the fungibility of their wealth, which

can be used to pursue security, material interests or esteem. Their potential influence

depends on their capacity to transpose their resources – which also involve

entrepreneurial skills – from the economic to the political realm, which cannot be

taken for granted. In fact, the examples mentioned throughout the paper are quite

exceptional, as most billionaires on the Forbes list do not seem to move into global

Page 20: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

20

political affairs. Or, at least we have difficulties to know about this, because when

billionaires finance war efforts or lobby for their material interests, their activities will

tend to be covert and thus difficult to research. Those billionaires that pursue esteem,

mainly through international philanthropy, are easier to study, because honor relies

on public recognition. The examples of Bill Gates and George Soros, even if they

remain exceptional, show the significant impact individual billionaires can make on

world politics. Gates is reconfiguring global health (McCoy et al. 2009), while Soros is

building civil societies. They are both extraordinary agents transforming structures in

world politics.

The most potent challenges to billionaires‟ agency come from perspectives that

emphasize either agent‟s embeddedness in networks (Goddard 2009), or that their

agency simply reflects the enactment of habitual practices (Adler & Pouliot 2011).

Thus, Diane Stone (2008) has argued that Soros‟s foundations form a network in

which participating institutions have high degrees of autonomy. While certainly

important for many agents, how one is structurally positioned in networks will often

matter less for billionaires, again simply because of their wealth. Once their

willingness to support certain causes is known, billionaires are usually facing

countless requests for partnering with others who hope to gain funding. This gives

billionaires a high degree of autonomy in choosing their position within networks. The

challenge of practices is more critical. Nicolas Guilhot (2007) posits that Soros is

merely performing philanthropic practices that perpetuate the existing capitalist order.

To some degree, this appears true, except that there is not one capitalist order (Hall

& Soskice 2001), and whether capitalists pursue purely material interests or mostly

honor makes big differences. The Koch billionaires‟ interventions in world politics, as

they try to undermine climate change mitigation in order to further their material

Page 21: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

21

interests, are quite different from Soros‟s pursuit of esteem as he tries to advance

public goods like education and civil liberties. Whereas the Koch brothers‟ vision is a

libertarian variety of capitalism, Soros‟s comes closer to some kind of “social

neoliberalism” (Soros 2000: 138-166). Opting to promote this or that variety of

capitalism is an expression of agency.

Bill Gates‟s and George Soros‟s philanthropy might, however, have established role

models that turn international “social entrepreneurship” into an international practice

(Bornstein 2004). If their example becomes part of billionaires‟ habitus, we would see

a curious new form of Polanyi‟s double-movement (Polanyi 1957): the social

structures that market economies destroy (yet depend upon) would not be provided

by states anymore, but by the billionaires whose very wealth derives from their

success in the markets. Billionaires‟ philanthropy would then not simply circumvent

the state (especially its taxation), but potentially replace some of its most basic

functions. Whether this would make the world a better place is another research

question. What is certain is that citizens in democracies have good chances to

change their governments if they are unhappy with their performance. But they have

a harder time changing their billionaires.

Page 22: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

22

References:

Adler, Emanuel, and Vincent Pouliot (2011). International Practices. International

Theory 3/1: 1–36. Adler, Emanuel, and Peter M. Haas (1992). Conclusion: Epistemic Communities,

World Order, and the Creation of a Reflective Research Program. International Organization 46/1: 367–390.

Angley, Robyn E. (2010). NOGs in Competitive Authoritarian States: The Role of Civil Groups in Georgia’s Rose Revolution. PhD dissertation. Boston: Boston University.

Atkinson, A.B., and Thomas Piketty (eds) (2007). Top Incomes over the Twentieth Century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Atkinson, A.B. and Thomas Piketty (eds) (2010). Top Incomes: A Global Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Berg, Andrea (2006). Who‟s Afraid of George Soros? The Conflict Between Authoritarian Rulers and International Actors in Central Asia. In: Berg, Andrea, and Anna Kreikemeyer (eds). Realities of Transformation: Democratization Policies in Central Asia Revisited. Baden-Baden : Nomos, 127-140.

Berger, Peter L., and Thomas Luckmann (1967). The Social Construction of Reality. London: Allen Lane.

Bishop, Matthew, and Michael Green (2008). Philanthrocapitalism: How the Rich Can Save the World. New York: Bloomsbury.

Bornstein, David (2004). How to Change the World: Social Entrepreneurs and the Power of New Ideas. London: Penguin.

Byman, Daniel L., and Kenneth M. Pollack (2001). Let Us Now Praise Great Men: Bringing the Statesmen Back in. International Security 25: 107-146.

Carnegie, Andrew (1889). Wealth. North American Review 148/391: 653-665. Carothers, Thomas, and Marina Ottaway (eds.) (2000). Funding Virtue: Civil Society

Aid and Democracy Promotion. Washington DC: Carnegie Endowment. Checkel, Jeffrey T. (1998). The Constructivist Turn in International Relations Theory.

World Politics 50/2: 324-348. Curti, Merle (1963). American Philanthropy Abroad: A History. New Brunswick:

Rutgers University Press. Davies, James D. (ed.) (2008). Personal Wealth from a Global Perspective. Oxford:

Oxford UP. Dessler, David (1989). What‟s at Stake in the Agent-Structure Debate. International

Organization 43/3: 441-473. Downs, Anthony (1957). An Economic Theory of Political Action in a Democracy.

Journal of Political Economy 65: 135-150. Druyen, Thomas (ed.) (2011). Vermögenskultur: Verantwortung im 21. Jahrhundert.

Wiesbaden: VS. Ehrenfeld, Rachel (2005). Funding Evil: How Terrorism is Financed and How to Stop

It. Expanded edition. Chicago: Bonus Books. Erskine, Toni (2008). Locating Responsibility: The Problem of Moral Agency in

International Relations. In: Reus-Smit, Christian and Duncan Snidal (eds). The Oxford Handbook of International Relations. Oxford: Oxford UP, 699-707.

Finnemore, Martha, and Kathryn Sikkink (1998). International Norm Dynamics and Political Change. International Organization 52: 887-917.

Frank, Robert (2007). Richistan: A Journey through the 21st Century Wealth Boom and the Lives of the New Rich. New York: Crown.

Page 23: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

23

Frank, Robert H., and Philip J. Cook (1995). The Winner-Take-All Society. New York: Free Press.

Frieden, Jeffry A. (2006). Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth Century. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.

Friedman, Lawrence J. (2003). Philanthropy in America: Historicism and its Discontents. In: Friedman, Lawrence J. and Mark D. McGarvie (eds). Charity, Philanthropy, and Civility in American History. Cambridge: Cambridge UP, 1-21.

Friedman, Lawrence J., and Mark D. McGarvie (eds) (2003). Charity, Philanthropy, and Civility in American History. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Giddens, Anthony (1984). The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Cambridge: Polity.

Goddard, Stacie E. (2009). Brokering Change: Networks and Entrepreneurs in International Politics. International Theory, 1: 249-281.

Greenpeace USA (2010). Koch Industries Secretly Funding the Climate Denial Machine. Washington, DC: Greenpeace USA.

Grieco, Joseph (1988). Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism. International Organization 42: 485-507.

Grundmann, Matthias (2011). Nur reich oder auch vermögend? Zum Handlungsvermögen Reicher. In: Lauterbach, Wolfgang, Thomas Druyen and Thomas Grundmann (eds). Vermögen in Deutschland – Heterogenität und Verantwortung. Wiesbaden: VS, 205-214.

Guilhot, Nicolas (2007). Reforming the World: George Soros, Global Capitalism and the Philanthropic Management of the Social Sciences. Critical Sociology 33: 447-477.

Hainmueller, Jens, and Michael J. Hiscox (2006). Learning to Love Globalization: Education and Individual Attitudes Toward International Trade. International Organization 60: 469-498.

Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice (eds.) (2001). Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford UP.

Hollis, Martin, and Steve Smith (1994). Two Stories About Structure and Agency. Review of International Studies 20: 241-251.

Hudson Institute (2006). The Index of Global Philanthropy 2006. Washington, DC: Hudson Institute.

Hudson Institute (2010). The Index of Global Philanthropy and Remittances 2010. Washington, DC: Hudson Institute.

Joshi, Shashank (2008). Honor in International Relations. Working Paper 2008-0146. Cambridge, MA: Weatherhead Center for International Affairs, Harvard University.

Kaufman, Michael T. (2002). Soros: The Life and Times of a Messianic Billionaire. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

Keck, Margaret, and Kathryn Sikkink (1998). Activists Beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell UP.

Kornprobst, Markus (2011). The Agent‟s Logics of Action: Defining and Mapping Political Judgement. International Theory 3: 70-104.

Lancet (2009). Editorial: What has the Gates Foundation Done for Global Health? Lancet 373: 1577.

Lauterbach, Wolfgang, Thomas Druyen and Thomas Grundmann (eds) (2011). Vermögen in Deutschland – Heterogenität und Verantwortung. Wiesbaden: VS.

Lauterbach, Wolfgang, and Alexander Tarvenkorn (2011). Homogenität und Heterogenität von Reichen im Vergleich zur gesellschaftlichen Mitte. In: Lauterbach, Wolfgang, Thomas Druyen and Thomas Grundmann (eds).

Page 24: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

24

Vermögen in Deutschland – Heterogenität und Verantwortung. Wiesbaden: VS, 57-94.

Lebow, Richard Ned (2008). A Cultural Theory of International Relations. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.

Mansfield, Edward D., and Diana C. Mutz (2009). Support for Free Trade: Self-Interest, Sociotropic Politics, and Out-Group Anxiety. International Organization 63 : 425-457.

March, James G., and Johan P. Olsen (1998). The Institutional Dynamics of International Political Orders. International Organization 52/4: 943-969.

Markey, Daniel (2000). The Prestige Motive in International Relations. PhD dissertation. Princeton: Princeton University.

McCoy, David, Gayatri Kembhavi, Jinesh Patel, Akish Luintel (2009). The Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation‟s Grant-Making Programme for Global Health. Lancet 373: 1645-1653.

Moravcsik, Andrew (1997). Taking Preferences Seriously: A Liberal Theory of International Relations. International Organization 51: 513-553.

Moravcsik, Andrew (1999). A New Statecraft? Supranational Entrepreneurs and International Cooperation. International Organization 53/2: 267-306.

Neckel, Sighard (2010). Refeudalisierung der Ökonomie: Zum Strukturwandel kapitalistischer Wirtschaft. MPIfG Working Paper 10/6. Cologne: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.

Neumayer, Eric (2004). The Super-Rich in Global Perspective: A Quantitative Analysis of the Forbes List of Billionaires. Applied Economics Letters 11: 793-796.

O‟Clery, Conor (2007). The Billionaire Who Wasn't: How Chuck Feeney Secretly Made and Gave Away a Fortune. New York: PublicAffairs.

Ostrower, Francie (1995). Why the Wealthy Give: The Culture of Elite Philanthropy. Princeton: Princeton UP.

Palan, Ronen, Richard Murphy and Christian Chavagneux (2010). Tax Havens: How Globalization Really Works. Ithaca: Cornell UP.

Payton, Robert L., and Moody, Michael P. (2008). Understanding Philanthropy: Its Meaning and Mission. Bloomington: Indiana UP.

Polanyi, Karl (1957) [1944]. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time. Boston: Beacon.

Pouliot, Vincent (2008). The Logic of Practicality: A Theory of Practice of Security Communities. International Organization 62: 257–288.

Reus-Smit, Christian, and Duncan Snidal (eds) (2008). The Oxford Handbook of International Relations. Oxford: Oxford UP.

Roine, Jesper, Jonas Vlachos and Daniel Waldenström (2009). The Long-Run Determinants of Inequality: What Can We Learn from Top Income Data? Journal of Public Economics 93: 974–988.

Rosen, Sherwin (1981). The Economics of Superstars. American Economic Review 71: 845-858.

Rothkopf, David (2008). Superclass: How the Rich Ruined our World. New York: Farrar, Straus and Grioux.

Scheve, Kenneth, and David Stasavage (2010). The Conscription of Wealth: Mass Warfare and the Demand for Progressive Taxation. International Organization 64: 529-561.

Sen, Amartya (1999). Development as Freedom. New York: Knopf. Sewell, William H., Jr. (1992). A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and

Transformation. American Journal of Sociology 98/1: 1–29.

Page 25: Billionaires in World Politics - Agents Transforming ... · powers face strong constraints on their behavior (Waltz 1959). This leads even someone as attentive to the mutual constitution

25

Shaxson, Nicholas (2011). Treasure Islands: Tax Havens and the Men who Stole the World. London: Bodley Head.

Silk, Roger D., James W. Lintott, Andrew R. Stephens and Christine M. Silk (2003) Creating a Private Foundation: The Essential Guide for Donors and Their Advisers. Princeton: Bloomberg.

Slater, Robert (2009). Soros: The World’s Most Famous Investor. 2nd edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Soros, George (1991). Underwriting Democracy. New York: Free Press. Soros, George (1995). Soros on Soros: Staying Ahead of the Curve. New York: John

Wiley & Sons. Soros, George (2000). Open Society: The Crisis of Global Capitalism Reconsidered.

London: Little, Brown & Company. Stewart, Susan (ed.) (2009). Special Issue: Democracy Promotion Before and After

the „Colour Revolutions‟. Democratization 16/4. Ströing, Miriam, and Melanie Kramer (2011). Reichtum und die Übernahme sozialer

Verantwortung. In: Lauterbach, Wolfgang, Thomas Druyen and Thomas Grundmann (eds). Vermögen in Deutschland – Heterogenität und Verantwortung. Wiesbaden: VS, 95-142.

Stuart, Douglas T. (2008). Foreign Policy Decision-Making. In: Reus-Smit, Christian and Duncan Snidal (eds). The Oxford Handbook of International Relations. Oxford: Oxford UP, 576-593.

Sussman, Gerald, and Sascha Krader (2008). Template Revolutions: Marketing U.S. Regime Change in Eastern Europe. Westminster Papers in Communication and Culture 5/3: 91-112

Torgler, Benno, and Marco Piatti (2007). Extraordinary Wealth, Globalization, and Corruption. Working Paper No. 2009-04. Basel: Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts (CREMA).

Waltz, Kenneth N. (1959). Man, the State and War: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Columbia UP.

Wendt, Alexander (2004). The State as Person in International Theory. Review of International Studies 30: 289-316.

Wendt, Alexander (1987). The Agent-Structure Problem in International Relations. International Organization 41/1: 335–370.

Wight, Colin (2006). Agents, Structures and International Relations: Politics as Ontology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Wilson, Andrew (2006). Ukraine‟s Orange Revolution, NGOs and the Role of the West. Cambridge Review of International Affairs 19/1: 21-32.

Winters, Jeffrey A., and Benjamin I. Page (2009). Oligarchy in the United States? Perspectives on Politics 7/4: 731-751.

Winters, Jeffrey A. (forthcoming, 2011). Oligarchy. Cambridge: Cambridge UP.