career changes and the loss of human · pdf filecareer changes and the loss of human capital...

25
Career Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munch y University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper studies the relationship between the probability of job change and tenure. Theory about worker-rm specic capital predicts that the job change haz- ard declines with time on the job, which accords with much empirical evidence. This paper nds further support for this prediction. However, a distinction between career changes, that is, job changes involving both a change of industry and occupa- tion, and other job changes reveals that the career change hazard is declining while other types of job changes exhibit a constant hazard rate. This suggests that there are no important rm-, industry- or occupation-specic elements in human capital. Instead skills are more likely to be career-specic. Keywords: Job mobility, Specic human capital, Mixed proportional hazard model. JEL Classication: C41, J41, J63 This paper is a substantially revised version of the working paper entitled "Are skills rm-specic? Evidence from Danish micro data". The paper has benetted from comments from Dale Mortensen, Gerard van den Berg and participants at the Sandbjerg conference on Labour Market Models and Matched Employer-Employee Data. Thanks to Daniel le Maire for research assistance and to Lars Skipper and Michael Svarer for sharing computer code. y Address: Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Studiestraede 6, DK - 1455 Copen- hagen K, Tel.: +45 35323019, Fax: +45 35323000, E-mail: [email protected].

Upload: lamnhi

Post on 30-Jan-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

Career Changes and the Loss of Human Capital�

Jakob Roland Munchy

University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU

April 2006

Abstract

This paper studies the relationship between the probability of job change and

tenure. Theory about worker-�rm speci�c capital predicts that the job change haz-

ard declines with time on the job, which accords with much empirical evidence.

This paper �nds further support for this prediction. However, a distinction between

career changes, that is, job changes involving both a change of industry and occupa-

tion, and other job changes reveals that the career change hazard is declining while

other types of job changes exhibit a constant hazard rate. This suggests that there

are no important �rm-, industry- or occupation-speci�c elements in human capital.

Instead skills are more likely to be career-speci�c.

Keywords: Job mobility, Speci�c human capital, Mixed proportional hazard

model.

JEL Classi�cation: C41, J41, J63

�This paper is a substantially revised version of the working paper entitled "Are skills �rm-speci�c?

Evidence from Danish micro data". The paper has bene�tted from comments from Dale Mortensen,

Gerard van den Berg and participants at the Sandbjerg conference on Labour Market Models and Matched

Employer-Employee Data. Thanks to Daniel le Maire for research assistance and to Lars Skipper and

Michael Svarer for sharing computer code.yAddress: Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Studiestraede 6, DK - 1455 Copen-

hagen K, Tel.: +45 35323019, Fax: +45 35323000, E-mail: [email protected].

Page 2: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

1 Introduction

This paper is concerned with the distinction between speci�c human capital and general

human capital. According to Becker (1964) �rm-speci�c human capital is by de�nition not

useful to the �rm or the worker outside their relationship, whereas general human capital

increases productivity of the worker also in other �rms. In empirical studies �rm-speci�c

human capital is almost always measured by the worker�s tenure at the current employer,

and a substantial literature have found large returns to tenure that are often equal in

size with the general experience e¤ect (see Farber (1999) for an overview). These positive

returns to tenure are regarded as evidence for signi�cant investments in �rm-speci�c

human capital. However, this literature has also been put into question by empirical

�ndings by e.g. Neal (1995) and Parent (2000), who show that human capital tends to be

industry-speci�c rather than �rm-speci�c. Against this �nding Kambourov & Manovskii

(2005) argue that it is more plausible that the human capital of workers is speci�c to the

type of work they do (i.e., their occupation) rather than to the industry they work in.

Based on a rich Danish micro data set I study whether there can be found evidence for

�rm-speci�c human capital, and I also investigate if the �ndings by Neal (1995), Parent

(2000) and Kambourov & Manovskii (2005) can be further supported.

The returns-to-tenure approach implicitly takes it for given that the job change prob-

ability declines with tenure, because otherwise it is not clear that tenure measures �rm-

speci�c human capital in any way. Search theory predicts that if �rm-speci�c human

capital accumulates with tenure and if the return to the speci�c capital is split between

the worker and the �rm, then the job change hazard starts out high and declines with

time on the job, since the loss associated with a job change rises (Jovanovic (1979a)). The

theory about speci�c capital in the form of worker-�rm matches also gives a prediction

about the relationship between the separation rate and tenure, cf. Jovanovic (1979b).

Early in the match the quality of the match is unknown so the separation rate is low due

to job change costs for both the worker and the �rm. The match quality of workers and

�rms reveals itself over time, and so most bad matches are ended after some time in the

job. That is, the separation rate �rst rises and then declines when mostly good matches

remain.

It is indeed a well established empirical fact that the probability of job change is

declining with tenure if the �rst few months are disregarded. Farber (1994) uses monthly

data and controls for some worker characteristics to investigate this issue and �nds that

the hazard rate peaks after 3 months of employment after which it declines. In fact in his

survey Farber (1999) notes that �virtually all of the literature uses annual data on job

1

Page 3: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

change to investigate the relationship between tenure and the probability of job change,

and, without exception, �nds a monotonic negative relationship�. Farber lists this fact as

one of three stylized facts that exist about job mobility.

This paper takes another look at the job change hazard rate. In doing so it is important

to control for worker heterogeneity because, as pointed out by Farber (1994), worker

heterogeneity by itself can generate a declining job change hazard, if heterogeneity is not

accounted for.1 Taken together if worker heterogeneity is accounted for and if �rm-speci�c

capital is important, then one should expect a declining job change hazard perhaps after

an initial rise during the �rst few months of tenure.

I use an exceptionally rich data set for the Danish labour market, which allows to

uncover the shape of the hazard rate and to estimate e¤ects of explanatory variables with

high precision. In particular a long list of covariates is available such that much worker

heterogeneity is accounted for, and in addition the econometric framework attempts to

control for any remaining unobserved heterogeneity. After controlling for heterogeneity I

�nd that the job change hazard �attens out, but it is still declining.

The question is now whether this decline can be attributed the accumulation of �rm-

speci�c human capital. Neal (1995) argues that skills could be speci�c to the industry

instead. He �nds that tenure with the predisplacement employer is positively correlated

with the wage earned in the post-displacement job only for those workers who stay in

the same industry. Parent (2000) �nds additional support for this view, since the return

to tenure in the earnings function is reduced substantially when within-industry labour

market experience is included. Therefore it is argued that what matters most for the

wage pro�le is not �rm-speci�c human capital but industry-speci�c human capital. To

investigate this issue a distinction between within- and between-industry job changes is

made, such that two destination speci�c job change hazard rates are estimated.

Kambourov & Manovskii (2005) expand on the approach by Parent (2000) and in-

cludes also within-occupation experience in the wage equation. This reveals substantial

returns to occupational tenure, while tenure with an industry or a �rm have little impor-

tance in explaining the wage growth from overall work experience. Again this �nding is

investigated further by estimating destination speci�c job change hazard rates for within

1This is realized by the following example. Suppose there are only two types of workers, stable and

unstable workers, with equally many of each type. The two types have a high and a low but constant

hazard rate. In the beginning the observed hazard rate is just the average of the two constant hazard

rates. However, over time more unstable than stable workers leave their jobs such that stable workers

with low hazard rates come to dominate the sample. Thus, the observed hazard rate is declining and so

failure to control for heterogeneity leads to negative duration dependence in the job change hazard rate.

2

Page 4: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

and between-occupation job changes.

I �nd that the within-industry job change hazard is roughly constant, while the

between-industry job change hazard is declining throughout the job spell. Likewise, I �nd

that the within-occupation job change hazard is constant, while the between-industry job

change hazard is declining. This questions the notion �rm-speci�c skills because that

would entail declining within-industry and within-occupation hazards. Also, there seems

to be support for both industry-speci�c and occupation-specifc human capital, but it is

not possible to say more than that.

In a �nal speci�cation I also consider career changes, that is, job changes involving

both a change of industry and a change of occupation. It turns out that, once career

changes are distinguished from other job changes, these remaining job changes exhibit a

constant hazard rate, while the career change hazard rate is declining. It is only when

workers change jobs where the type of work they do and the goods they produce change,

that they appear to lose speci�c human capital. Thus human capital tends to be career

speci�c rather than speci�c to the �rm, industry or occupation.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The next section describes the data set

and points out some distinguishing characteristics of the Danish labour market. Section

3 sets up the duration model and section 4 presents the estimation results. Section 5

concludes.

2 Data and the Danish labour market

There is access to a very rich representative matched worker-�rm panel data set based on

administrative �les covering 10 % of the Danish population for the years 1992-2001. In

each year detailed information about the labour market states of all individuals along with

information on socio economic characteristics is available. These socio economic variables

are extracted from the integrated database for labour market research (IDA) and the

income registers in Statistics Denmark. Of particular importance is that an establishment

identi�er is associated with each worker at the end of each year.2 A �rm can have more

than one establishment, so if a worker changes between two establishments within the

same �rm, then this is counted as a job change in the present analysis. Job spells are

then straightforwardly constructed from successive years at the same establishment. The

quality and validity of the IDA data is highly regarded �for more details see Abowd &

Kramarz (1999).

2Establishment identi�ers are obtained from the Danish Establishment Register. The dataset includes

all establishments that have had employees performing paid work and for whom tax has been paid.

3

Page 5: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

Here I am interested in the duration of job spells and transitions between jobs, and for

the present purposes job spells are �ow sampled such that only spells starting in 1993 and

later are included in the analysis. The destination state for all spells that end before 2001 is

known and I focus in particular on spells that end with a transition into a new job with the

possibility to distinguish between a new job in the same industry, in a di¤erent industry,

in the same occupation and in a new occupation. Since the job spells are based on annual

observations it is possible that the workers have had intermediate unemployment spells

of duration less than a year between two job spells. Thus to focus on "pure" job changes

I right censor those spells where the worker has collected UI bene�ts in the year of job

change. In addition, if job spells end with transitions into other states than employment

(e.g. unemployment, out of the labour force) or if spells are uncompleted in 2001 then

they are treated as right censored observations. Also, if job spells end because of a �rm

closure, they are treated as right censored observations. To increase the homogeneity of

the sample all part time workers and students with jobs have been excluded.

A central issue in the analysis is the distinction between job changes within and

between industries or occupations. The industry switches are based on the NACE industry

classi�cation, and the occupation switches are based on the so-called DISCO code, which

is the Danish version of the ISCO-88 classi�cation. I use the most disaggregated de�nition

of the industry- and occupation codes, the six digit NACE code and the four digit DISCO

code. This aggregation level is chosen because the most direct test of the existence of

�rm-speci�c human capital is to consider job changes within narrowly de�ned industries

and occupations. If human capital is speci�c to the �rm this should be evident even for

such job changes.

In some countries the ISCO codes are plagued by serious measurement error, since

misleading registration sometimes happen particularly in the �rst year in employment

relationships. While such registration errors cannot be ruled out in the Danish case,

the validity and reliability of the DISCO code is considered to be high. For example

the DISCO code is used for wage-setting purposes in bargaining between trade unions

and employer confederations. The two bargaining parties at national level, The Danish

Confederation of Trade Unions (LO) and The Confederation of Danish Employers (DA),

use the code to assess the economic implications of proposals for the workers and employers

they represent. It is noteworthy that LO uses the code and appears to be con�dent in its

validity even though it is the employers who collect and register the information. Also,

the assessment of the Danish Statistical authorities is that the DISCO code is a very

useful tool to group workers according to occupation, cf. Statistics Denmark (1996).

Another potential data concern is that some job changes may be between establish-

4

Page 6: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

ments within the same �rm. However, from a separate extract of the IDA data set

with establishment and �rm identi�ers (which is only available from 1999), it is possible

to determine the proportion of between-establishments job changes that also involve a

change of �rm. It is found that among workers that change establishment 88 % also

change �rm. This holds for job changes between 1999 and 2000 and between 2000 and

2001. This suggests that only a minor part of the job changes in the present analysis

are in fact within-�rm establishment changes. To evaluate whether these within-�rm job

changes may bias the results, some further statistics from the limited data set are derived.

The within-�rm job changes are more likely to be with unchanged industry codes than

between-�rm job changes, because establishments within the same �rm are typically in

the same industry, but perhaps somewhat surprising 16 % of all within-�rm job changes

do in fact involve industry changes as opposed to 45 % of between-�rm job changes. The

di¤erence is even less pronounced for occupation changes; 28 % of all within-�rm job

changes involve a change of occupation as opposed to 41 % of between-�rm job changes.

Thus, the inclusion of within-�rm job changes in the analysis is unlikely to seriously bias

the results.

In the data set used below there are 257,325 job spells for 161,508 persons which

amounts to 646,623 observations (an observation is a year in a job spell). Table 1 displays

summary statistics for the job spells. A signi�cant proportion (14 %) of all individuals

in the sample is recorded with more than one job spell, which is useful when controlling

for unobserved heterogeneity (see next section). Slightly more than half of the spells are

treated as right censored observations, while the job changes are fairly evenly spread across

the di¤erent types of change (i.e., within-industry and within-occupation job change,

within-industry and between-occupation job change etc.).

Insert Table 1 about here

Table 2 displays descriptive statistics for all explanatory variables. Self explanatory

dummies for age, gender, the presence of children, the presence of two adults in the

household, citizenship and education are included. Also, three geographic dummies are

included to distinguish between the capital Copenhagen, 5 large cities and all other lo-

calities. Information on the hourly wage rate is used �this variable is calculated as the

annual labour income divided by hours worked. The de�nition of hours worked changed

between 1992 and 1993 and this is one reason why I have chosen to only look at job spells

starting in 1993 and later. A source of measurement error is that hours worked do not

include overtime work, so the wage rate may be biased upwards. However, it should be

noted that the wage rate is only included to control for heterogeneity, and so the estimated

5

Page 7: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

coe¢ cients to this variable are not of interest per se. Further, labour market experience

and dummies for not being a member of an unemployment insurance fund, membership

of a trade union, and dummies for the labour market state prior to the job spell with a

distinction between employment, unemployment, self-employment and out of the labour

force is included. There are also dummies for the size of the �rm (or more precisely es-

tablishment) in terms of the workforce, and �nally, to capture business cycle e¤ects the

GDP growth rate and local unemployment rates based on 51 local labour markets3 are

included.

Insert Table 2 about here

The empirical job change hazard rate, which is simply de�ned as the proportion chang-

ing jobs in year t among those surviving until that year, is depicted in Figure 1, and it is

clearly declining with time on the job. The question is to what extent this decline can be

attributed to worker heterogeneity or speci�c human capital.

Insert Figure 1 about here

Compared to other continental European labour markets the Danish labour market

is often described as being very �exible as employment protection is weak (Nicoletti,

Scarpetta & Boylaud (2000)), while at the same time replacement rates of UI bene�ts are

high. This have led to turnover rates and an average tenure which are in line with those of

the Anglo-Saxon countries. In 1995 the average tenure in the Danish labour market was

the lowest in continental Europe with 7.9 years exceeding only the numbers for Australia,

USA and UK (6.4, 7.4 and 7.8 years respectively), cf. OECD (1997). However, there

are important di¤erences with respect to institutions and wage formation. The Danish

labour market is heavily unionized and the wage structure is relatively compressed even

for European standards.

3 Econometric model

Di¤erent econometric approaches to modelling job change transition have been undertaken

in the literature. Abraham & Farber (1987) estimate a Weibull hazard model for job

change transitions and �nd that the hazard declines sharply with tenure. However this

parametric speci�cation of the baseline hazard is not capable of handling potential non-

monotonicities in the true duration dependence. Parent (1999) also estimates a duration

3The local labour markets are socalled commuting areas that are de�ned such that the internal mi-

gration rate is 50 % higher than the external migration rate, cf. Andersen (2000).

6

Page 8: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

model which controls for unobserved heterogeneity, but he does not assess the question

of duration dependence in the hazard. Farber (1994) estimates logit models by years of

tenure to obtain a picture of the duration dependence in the hazard rate, and as previously

noted he �nds a peak in the hazard after three months of employment.

This section sets up a competing risks duration model that distinguishes between dif-

ferent types of job changes (within and between industries or occupations). As noted

earlier, in the present context it is important to control for as much individual hetero-

geneity as possible. There is access to a very detailed data set, but there might still be

some unobserved heterogeneity left, as no direct measures for e.g. ability or motivation

are available. Therefore I try to capture unobserved worker characteristics by specifying

a mixed proportional hazard model for the job-to-job transitions:

�i(tjxt; �i) = �i(t) exp(xt�i + �i); (1)

where i = 1; ::;m indicates the di¤erent destination states for the job change (i.e. within

or between industries and occupations), �i(t) is the baseline hazard capturing the time

dependence, and exp(xt�i + �i) is the systematic part giving the proportional e¤ects of

observed and time-varying characteristics, xt; and unobserved characteristics, �i. All job

spells that end with a transition to other states than a new job (e.g. unemployment and

out of the labour force) are treated as right censored observations.

The annual observations in the data imply that the duration variable T is grouped into

K +1 intervals f[0; t1); [t1;t2); ::; [tk;1)g which must be accounted for in the econometricsetup. Following Kiefer (1990) the interval speci�c survival rate is de�ned as

�k = P (T � tkjT � tk�1; x; �)

= exp

"�

mXi=1

Z tk

tk�1

�i(tjxt; �i)dt#

= exp

"�

mXi=1

exp(xk�i + �i)�i;k

#(2)

=

mYi=1

�i;k;

where �i;k =R tktk�1

�i(t)dt and �i;k = exp [� exp(xk�i + �i)�i;k] :The next step is to �nd the contribution to the likelihood function from a job spell.

The probability that a spell ends in interval k is given by the conditional probability

of failure in that interval times the probability that the spell survives until interval k; or

(1��k)Qk�1j=1 �j: Some spells are right censored and they contribute to the likelihood with

7

Page 9: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

the survivor function,Qkj=1 �j: Thus the contribution to the likelihood function from a

job spell can be written

Le =mYi=1

(1� �i;k)di�1��mi dik

k�1Yj=1

�j; (3)

where d1; ::; dm are destination state indicators. If the job spell is right censored then

d1 = :: = dm = 0: In this paper special attention is on the estimated duration dependence,

so it is important to allow for a �exible speci�cation of the baseline hazard. Therefore,

instead of imposing a functional form I simply estimate the interval speci�c baseline

parameters �i;k.

The unobserved heterogeneity is speci�ed by the stochastic variables V1; ::; Vm: It is as-

sumed that the unobserved heterogeneity is time invariant and since each worker possibly

contributes with more than one job spell, the draw from the distribution of unobservables

is restricted to be the same across job spells for the same individual. Thus, the complete

contribution to the likelihood function for a worker with J job spells is

L =JYl=1

ZV1

::

ZVm

Lle(tjxt; V1; ::; Vm)dF (V1; ::; Vm); (4)

where F is the joint CDF for the unobserved heterogeneity, which remains to be speci�ed.

It is suggested by Heckman & Singer (1984) that discrete distributions can approximate

any arbitrary distribution functions, and here I assume that each stochastic variable can

take two values (�i1 and �i2)4 each with an associated probability. Such a speci�cation of

unobservables is very �exible and widely applied.5

4 Estimation results

Before turning to the shape of the estimated baseline hazard rate I go through the e¤ects of

some of the control variables. The two columns of Table 3 display the e¤ects of covariates

and their standard errors for the model where no distinction between di¤erent types of

job changes are made, i.e. a single risk model. Most variables have the expected signs;

e.g. younger workers, men and more educated workers change jobs more frequently. A

lower wage rate seems to increase the likelihood of a job change. However, this e¤ect

4One of the support points in each destination speci�c hazard is normalized to one, i.e., �i1 = 1;

i = 1; ::;m:5See van den Berg (2001) for more details and e.g. Belzil (2001) and Jensen, Rosholm & Svarer (2003)

for applications in grouped duration models.

8

Page 10: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

should be interpreted with caution, since it may be endogenous. For the present purposes

I include the wage variable to control for heterogeneity. It is also seen that, if workers

were unemployed, self-employed or out of the labour force prior to the job spell, their

job spells tend to be longer when compared to workers who had another job prior to the

present job. Also, a higher GDP growth rate and local unemployment rate lead to a lower

job change hazard rate.

Insert Table 3 about here

The estimated hazard rate is depicted in Figure 2 for the reference person.6 It is seen

that when worker heterogeneity is controlled for the job change hazard rate �attens out

but it is still declining. The impact of observed and unobserved heterogeneity on the

shape of the job change hazard rate can be illustrated by comparing the decline from the

1st to the 8th year of empirical unconditional hazard rate of Figure 1 with that of the

heterogeneity corrected hazard rate of Figure 2. The empirical hazard rate declines 60

% over this eight year span while the heterogeneity corrected hazard rate only declines

39 %, so heterogeneity can explain a large part of the decline in the raw empirical job

change hazard. However, the hazard rate is still declining, which means that the notion

of �rm-speci�c human capital cannot be ruled out based on this evidence. So far, I have

just con�rmed what has previously been found in the literature �the job change hazard

rate is indeed declining with time on the job (see e.g. Farber (1999) for an overview and

Frederiksen, Honoré & Hu (2006) for another study on Danish register-data).

Insert Figure 2 about here

An important extension of the analysis is to investigate whether skills may be speci�c

to the industry instead of the �rm, since, as noted in the introduction, Neal (1995) and

Parent (2000) have found evidence showing that there is a signi�cant industry-speci�c

element in the return to tenure. This issue can be analysed in terms of the shape of the

job change hazard by distinguishing between within- and between-industry job changes.

To this end, the econometric model is extended with a distinction between within- and

between-industry job changes, such that two destination speci�c job change hazard rates

are estimated.7 The e¤ects of covariates on the within- and between-industry job change

6The reference person in Figures 2-5 is de�ned in a year with GDP growth rate of 2 % and a local

unemployment rate of 6 % and for persons with average experience and wage rate. The remaining

characteristics are given from Table 3, i.e. it is a single male between 30 and 39 years without children

aged 0-6 years etc. The estimated baseline parameters and standard errors are shown in Appendix B.7Again, the estimated baseline parameters and standard errors are shown in Appendix B. The e¤ects

of covariates are not shown for this and all subsequent models. They are availiable from the author

9

Page 11: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

hazards mostly have the same sign as in the single risk model, but there are also di¤erences.

Workers with just basic schooling and short term further education change jobs more often

between industries than workers with a vocational education, which is di¤erent compared

to the within-industry job change hazard and the overall job change hazard. Also of

interest is that experience has an opposite e¤ect on the two destination speci�c hazard

rates, such that there is a positive e¤ect on within-industry job changes and a negative

e¤ect on the propensity to switch industry.

If skills are speci�c to the industry instead of the �rm, the between-industry job change

hazard should be declining while the within-industry job change hazard could be declining

or constant depending on whether skills also to some extent are speci�c to the �rm (or

occupation) or not. Figure 3 shows that the between-industry job change hazard is indeed

declining, while, if anything, the within-industry job change hazard is mildly rising. Thus,

there seems to be support for the suggestion by Neal (1995) and Parent (2000) that skills

are speci�c to the industry. Furthermore, there is no evidence of �rm-speci�c human

capital because that would entail a declining within-industry job change hazard.

Insert Figure 3 about here

The declining within-industry job change hazard is, however, not de�nitive proof of the

existence of industry-speci�c human capital. If skills instead are speci�c to the occupation,

and if occupation switches also mostly involve a change of industry then the decline could

be driven by occupation-speci�c human capital. Kambourov & Manovskii (2005) show

that when within-occupation experience along with experience in the industry and the �rm

are included in a wage equation for the US labour market, there are substantial returns

to occupational tenure, while tenure with an industry or a �rm have little importance

in explaining the wage growth from overall work experience. Again this possibility is

investigated further by estimating destination speci�c job change hazard rates for within-

and between-occupation job changes. If skills are speci�c to the occupation, the between-

occupation job change hazard should be declining, while the within-occupation job change

hazard should be constant (or declining if �rm or industry-speci�c human capital are

relevant notions). Figure 4 shows that both hazard rates are declining, but the within-

occupation job change hazard is not declining by much, while the between-occupation job

upon request. It was not possible to estimate the full model with four mass points in the unobservables

distribution. This is not unusual in such models. To obtain reliable estimates of the mass points, I had

to restrict the correlation structure between the two destination speci�c hazard rates to be perfect. This

means that workers who, for unobserved reasons, have higher transition rates into new jobs in the same

industry also have higher transition rates into new jobs in new industries.

10

Page 12: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

change hazard displays a much more pronounced fall. Thus, from Figure 3 and 4 there

seems to be evidence for both industry-speci�c and occupation-speci�c human capital, so

at this stage there is no clear picture of the speci�city of skills.

Insert Figure 4 about here

A natural question to ask now is whether the two declining job change hazards of

Figures 3 and 4 exclusively are due to workers who both change industry and occupation.

This is what Neal (1999) labels a career change. A worker making a career change is

not only moving to a �rm that produces goods that di¤er from those produced by her

previous �rm, she is also performing new tasks in her new occupation. Obviously such

career changes are the type of job changes that are most likely to involve losses of speci�c

human capital. To study this question in terms of job change hazards I estimate a

competing risks model with four risks; job change within the industry and within the

occupation, job change within the industry and between occupations, job change between

the industries and within the occupation, and �nally job change between industries and

between occupations, i.e., a career change.

The estimated hazard rates are displayed in Figure 5, and it is immediately apparent

that career changes drive the downward slope of the overall job change hazard in Figure 2

and the downward sloping hazards of Figure 3 and 4. The top left diagram shows the job

change hazard without industry and occupation moves, and it is clearly not declining. The

same goes for the within-industry, between-occupation job change hazard in the top right

diagram. The between-industry, within-occupation hazard of the bottom left diagram is

also roughly constant, although it appears to decline slightly towards the end of the eight

year interval. In contrast, the career change hazard rate in the bottom right diagram is

declining considerably over course of the job spell.

Insert Figure 5 about here

These results suggest �rst of all that human capital is not speci�c to the �rm. For

that to be the case, basically all four hazard rates should be declining, and this is clearly

not the case. The relevance of �rm-speci�c human capital has been cast into doubt by

other authors using di¤erent approaches, but to my knowledge it has not been shown in

terms of the shape of job change hazards. Further, in contrast to the �ndings of Neal

(1995), Parent (2000) and Kambourov & Manovskii (2005), human capital appears not

to be completely speci�c to the industry or the occupation. Once career changes are

distinguished from other job changes, these remaining types of job changes exhibit a

11

Page 13: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

more or less constant hazard rate. If skills were speci�c to the industry the two bottom

diagrams of Figure 5 should be declining, and if skills were speci�c to the occupation the

two right sided diagrams should be declining. It is only when workers change jobs where

the type of work they do and the goods they produce change, that they appear to lose

speci�c human capital.

This questions the substantial literature that estimate the return to tenure in the �rm,

the industry or the occupation. These tenure measures may be correlated with individual

productivity and human capital, but it does not seem to be human capital that is useless to

other �rms, in other industries or in other occupations provided the worker is not making

a career change. Instead the returns-to-tenure approach should focus on tenure within

the industry and the occupation. Speci�c human capital may accumulate as long as the

worker is not changing career, so tenure should be measured as the length of employment

spells that are uninterrupted by a job change involving both a change of industry and

occupation.

5 Conclusion

This paper has investigated the relevance of the notion of �rm-speci�c, industry-speci�c

and occupation-speci�c human capital. Instead of estimating the return to tenure in wage

equations I have taken a step back and considered the shape of the job change hazard

rate. To the best of my knowledge the paper is the �rst to investigate the speci�city of

skills in terms of the shape of the job change hazard. This is relevant because if tenure is

to measure �rm-speci�c human capital in any way, then the job change probability must

be declining with time on the job.

Job change hazard rates for workers in the Danish labour market have been estimated

by use of a very rich data set and by setting up a duration model with a �exible non-

parametric baseline hazard. In addition to much observed worker heterogeneity also

unobserved heterogeneity is accounted for and three main �ndings emerged from the

estimation results. First, it is found that after correcting for heterogeneity the job change

hazard �attens out, but it is still declining, so this leaves room for the existence of �rm-

speci�c human capital.

Second, a more detailed investigation of within- and between-industry job changes and

within- and between-occupation job changes indicates that skills may either be speci�c

to the industry or the �rm, since both the between-industry and the between-occupation

job change hazards are declining. Based on this evidence it is, however, not possible to

come up with a more precise answer. Instead it is concluded that skills are not speci�c

12

Page 14: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

to the �rm, because both the within-industry and within-occupation job change hazards

are roughly constant.

Third, and most importantly, the downward sloping shape of the overall job change

hazard can exclusively be attributed to career changes, that is job changes involving both

a change of industry and a change of occupation. Once career changes are separated out

from other job changes, these remaining types of job changes exhibit a roughly constant

hazard rate. This suggests that it is only when workers change jobs where the type of work

they do and the goods they produce change, that they tend to lose speci�c human capital.

In that light it may be fruitful in future research to revisit the returns-to-tenure literature.

The results of this paper imply that tenure should be measured as the combined length

of successive job spells with no career changes in between, and once such a variable is

included in wage regressions, the estimated coe¢ cients to other tenure variables should

be signi�cantly reduced.

13

Page 15: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

References

Abowd, J. M. & Kramarz, F. (1999), The analysis of labor markets using matched

employer-employee data, in O. Ashenfelter & D. Card, eds, �Handbook of Labor

Economics Vol. III�, North Holland, Amsterdam.

Abraham, K. G. & Farber, H. S. (1987), �Job duration, seniority and earnings�, American

Economic Review 77, 278�297.

Andersen, A. K. (2000), Commuting Areas in Denmark, AKF Forlaget, Copenhagen.

Becker, G. S. (1964), Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special

Reference to Education, Columbia University Press, New York.

Belzil, C. (2001), �Unemployment insurance and subsequent job duration: Job matching

versus unobserved heterogeneity�, Journal of Applied Econometrics 16, 619�636.

Farber, H. S. (1994), �The analysis of inter�rm worker mobility�, Journal of Labor Eco-

nomics 12, 554�593.

Farber, H. S. (1999), Mobility and stability: The dynamics of job change in labor markets,

in O. Ashenfelter & D. Card, eds, �Handbook of Labor Economics�, Vol. III, North

Holland, Amsterdam.

Frederiksen, A., Honoré, B. E. & Hu, L. (2006), Discrete time duration models with

group-level heterogeneity. SIEPR Discussion Paper No. 05-08, Stanford University.

Heckman, J. J. & Singer, B. (1984), �A method for minimizing the impact of distributional

assumptions in econometric models for duration data�, Econometrica 52, 271�320.

Jensen, P., Rosholm, M. & Svarer, M. (2003), �The response of youth unemployment to

bene�ts incentives and sanctions�, European Journal of Political Economy 19, 301�316.

Jovanovic, B. (1979a), �Firm-speci�c capital and turnover�, Journal of Political Economy

87, 1246�1260.

Jovanovic, B. (1979b), �Job matching and the theory of turnover�, Journal of Political

Economy 87, 972�990.

Kambourov, G. & Manovskii, I. (2005), Occupational speci�city of human capital. Work-

ing paper, University of Pennsylvania.

14

Page 16: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

Kiefer, N. M. (1990), Econometric methods for grouped duration data, in J. Hartog,

G. Ridder & J. Theeuwes, eds, �Panel Data and Labour Market Studies�, North

Holland, Amsterdam.

Neal, D. (1995), �Industry-speci�c human capital: Evidence from displaced workers�, Jour-

nal of Labor Economics 13, 653�677.

Neal, D. (1999), �The complexity of job mobility among young men�, Journal of Labor

Economics 17, 237�261.

Nicoletti, G. S., Scarpetta, S. & Boylaud, O. (2000), Summary indicators of product

market regulation with an extension of employment protection legislation. OECD

Economics Department Working Papers No. 226.

OECD (1997), Employment Outlook, OECD, Paris.

Parent, D. (1999), �Wages and mobility: The impact of employer-provided training�,

Journal of Labor Economics 17, 298�317.

Parent, D. (2000), �Industry-speci�c capital and the wage pro�le: Evidence from the

national longitudinal survey of youth and the panel study of income dynamics�,

Journal of Labor Economics 18, 306�323.

Statistics Denmark (1996), Introduktion Til DISCO-88, Statistics Denmark, Copenhagen.

van den Berg, G. J. (2001), Duration models: Speci�cation, identi�cation, and multiple

durations, in J. J. Heckman & E. Leamer, eds, �Handbook of Econometrics�, Vol. V,

North-Holland, Amsterdam.

15

Page 17: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

A Appendix: Tables and �gures

TABLE 1

Spell statisticsNumber of individuals 161,508

Number of spells 257,325

Proportion of individuals with multiple spells 0.14

Mean duration of spell (years) 3.04

Proportion of spells:

- right-censored spells 0.53

- within industry, within occ. job change 0.13

- within industry, between occ. job change 0.06

- between industry, within occ. job change 0.14

- between industry, between occ. job change 0.14

16

Page 18: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

TABLE 2

Sample meansVariables Mean Stdv.Age 19-24 0.1425 0.3496Age 25-29 0.1565 0.3633Age 30-39 0.2324 0.4224Age 40-49 0.3187 0.4660Age 50-59 0.1416 0.3486Age 60+ 0.0084 0.0911Female 0.4191 0.4934Children 0-6 years 0.2415 0.4280Two adults 0.6848 0.4646Citizenship: non OECD country 0.0212 0.1441Copenhagen 0.2437 0.4293Large city 0.1429 0.3499Rural area 0.6134 0.4870Homeowner 0.5940 0.4911Basic education 0.3271 0.4692Vocational education 0.4053 0.4910Further edu. short term 2 0.0511 0.2202Further edu. medium term 0.1376 0.3445Further edu. long term 0.0788 0.2695Experience (years/100) 0.1360 0.0901Non insured 0.1692 0.3749Union member 0.7967 0.4025Log wage (/10) 0.5097 0.0419Previous state: employed 0.7710 0.4202Previous state: unemployed 0.0992 0.2989Previous state: self employed 0.0259 0.1587Previous state: outside labour market 0.1040 0.3052Firm size 1-10 0.1555 0.3623Firm size 10-50 0.2984 0.4576Firm size 50-200 0.2710 0.4445Firm size 200+ 0.2752 0.4466GDP growth rate (/10) 0.2798 0.0969Local unemployment rate (/10) 0.6777 0.2332# observations 686,906

17

Page 19: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

TABLE 3

Effects of covariatesJob change

Variables Coe¤. Std. err.Age 19-24 0.4236 0.0125Age 25-29 0.1716 0.0098Age 40-49 -0.2157 0.0102Age 50-59 -0.4249 0.0140Age 60+ -0.4307 0.0405Female -0.1350 0.0071Children 0-6 years 0.0155 0.0086Two adults -0.0270 0.0079Non OECD country -0.2346 0.0230Large city -0.1538 0.0107Rural area -0.1564 0.0078Home owner -0.0894 0.0078Basic education -0.0300 0.0079Further edu. short -0.0007 0.0154Further edu. medium -0.0714 0.0109Further edu. long 0.0597 0.0134Experience 0.3107 0.0638Non insured 0.0969 0.0093Union member -0.0403 0.0082Log wage 2.1172 0.0935Unemployed -0.4096 0.0128Self employed -0.4376 0.0245Outside -0.2905 0.0120Firm size 10-50 -0.0522 0.0095Firm size 50-200 -0.0533 0.0100Firm size 200+ -0.0142 0.0100GDP growth -0.1627 0.0285Local unempl. -0.0412 0.0139

18

Page 20: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

Figure 1: The empirical job change hazard rate

Figure 2: The estimated job change hazard rate.

19

Page 21: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

Figure 3: Within and between industry job change hazard rates.

Figure 4: Within and between occupation job change hazard rates.

20

Page 22: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

Figure 5: Destination speci�c job change hazard rates

21

Page 23: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

B Appendix: Supplementary tables

TABLE B1

Baseline parameters and unobservablesJob change

Parameters Coe¤. Std. err.1. year, �1 0.0796 0.00472. year, �2 0.0716 0.00423. year, �3 0.0663 0.00394. year, �4 0.0600 0.00355. year, �5 0.0566 0.00336. year, �6 0.0510 0.00317. year, �7 0.0511 0.00328. year, �8 0.0489 0.0035

�2 0.9556 0.0142P (�1) 0.6661 0.0215P (�2) 0.3339 0.0215

22

Page 24: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

TABLE B2

Baseline parameters and unobservablesJob changewithinindustry

Job changebetweenindustries

Parameters Coe¤. Std. err. Coe¤. Std. err.1. year, �1 0.0148 0.0014 0.1081 0.00712. year, �2 0.0151 0.0014 0.1019 0.00673. year, �3 0.0157 0.0015 0.0976 0.00644. year, �4 0.0156 0.0015 0.0908 0.00605. year, �5 0.0170 0.0016 0.0830 0.00566. year, �6 0.0154 0.0015 0.0794 0.00567. year, �7 0.0160 0.0016 0.0802 0.00598. year, �8 0.0165 0.0019 0.0693 0.0062

�w2 1.8222 0.0161�b2 1.1763 0.0146P (�w1; �b1) 0.7641 0.0052P (�w2; �b2) 0.2359 0.0052

TABLE B3

Baseline parameters and unobservablesJob changewithin

occupation

Job changebetween

occupationsParameters Coe¤. Std. err. Coe¤. Std. err.1. year, �1 0.0432 0.0032 0.0375 0.00312. year, �2 0.0441 0.0032 0.0350 0.00293. year, �3 0.0439 0.0032 0.0346 0.00284. year, �4 0.0420 0.0031 0.0324 0.00275. year, �5 0.0430 0.0032 0.0293 0.00256. year, �6 0.0368 0.0028 0.0295 0.00267. year, �7 0.0393 0.0031 0.0272 0.00268. year, �8 0.0383 0.0035 0.0245 0.0028

�w2 1.4619 0.0147�b2 1.5141 0.0174P (�w1; �b1) 0.7852 0.0050P (�w2; �b2) 0.2148 0.0050

23

Page 25: Career Changes and the Loss of Human · PDF fileCareer Changes and the Loss of Human Capital Jakob Roland Munchy University of Copenhagen, CEBR and EPRU April 2006 Abstract This paper

TABLE B4

Baseline parameters and unobservablesJob changewithin ind.within occ.

Job changewithin ind.between occ.

Job changebetween ind.within occ.

Job changebetween ind.between occ.

Parameters Coe¤. Std. err. Coe¤. Std. err. Coe¤. Std. err. Coe¤. Std. err.1. year, �1 0.0087 0.0010 0.0018 0.0003 0.0557 0.0051 0.0319 0.00302. year, �2 0.0096 0.0010 0.0019 0.0003 0.0596 0.0055 0.0306 0.00293. year, �3 0.0104 0.0011 0.0020 0.0003 0.0608 0.0056 0.0307 0.00294. year, �4 0.0106 0.0012 0.0019 0.0003 0.0578 0.0054 0.0292 0.00285. year, �5 0.0116 0.0013 0.0019 0.0003 0.0572 0.0054 0.0251 0.00256. year, �6 0.0095 0.0011 0.0020 0.0003 0.0516 0.0051 0.0253 0.00267. year, �7 0.0101 0.0012 0.0017 0.0003 0.0550 0.0056 0.0232 0.00258. year, �8 0.0099 0.0013 0.0018 0.0004 0.0501 0.0060 0.0170 0.0024

�ww2 1.9264 0.0177�wb2 2.1028 0.0270�bw2 1.6507 0.0188�bb2 1.5845 0.0190P (�ww1; �wb1; �bw1; �bb1) 0.8126 0.0029P (�ww2; �wb2; �bw2; �bb2) 0.1874 0.0029

24