changing business cycle dynamics v2.1

Upload: willhambly

Post on 30-May-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    1/18

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    2/18

    been challenged as the economy has undergone significant changes. Macroeconomists have

    sparred over the theories explaining the reduction in business cycle volatility, but the impacts of

    the reduction in output variation are irrefutable and omnipresent. The reduction in U.S. business

    cycle volatility since 1980 has been a great boon to households, firms, and policymakers as the

    economic environment has become more certain. Reduced volatility seen in output and prices

    has several benefits, allowing people to be more consistently employed and reducing resourced

    devoted to economic planning and hedging against inflation. This paper will examine the roles

    of structural changes in the economy and monetary policymaking with regard to the recent

    reduction in business cycle volatility.

    For the most part of the 20th century, the U.S. macroeconomy performed extremely well,

    with an average growth rate of 3.5% per year.2 This average rate of annual growth, however,

    masks the fluctuations around the underlying trend, or natural rate. For much of the 1900s,

    steady output growth was punctuated by periods of dramatic contraction and expansion, known

    as the business cycle. In the last thirty years, however, these fluctuations in output have been

    less pronounced, as contractions and expansions beyond the underlying trend have become more

    short-lived and less extreme. As documented by macroeconomists Olivier Blanchard and John

    Simon, the standard deviation of output has declined markedly since 1950. Evidence of the

    decline in business cycle fluctuation is data on the frequency and length of economic expansions.

    Blanchard and Simon note that the average length of an expansion during the 1947 to 1981

    period was nineteen quarters, compared to an expansion of thirty six quarters for the 1982 to

    2000 period. Also accompanying the significant reduction in output volatility has been a

    moderation in both price variability and the unemployment rate. Essentially, the evidence has

    2 See Figure 1: Real GDP Yr. chart xls from 1930 to 2006

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    3/18

    shown that gyrations in the price level have become dampened and unemployment has been

    more consistently at its long-run natural rate.

    The persistent decline in macroeconomic volatility, known as the Great Moderation, is

    the result of both structural changes in the economy and better monetary policymaking.

    Structural changes contributing to the decline in volatility include the smoothing of the

    components of output, innovations in information technology, and the increased sophistication of

    financial markets. Related to macroeconomic policymaking, better monetary policy, specifically

    an anchoring of inflation expectations, enhanced central bank credibility, and an understanding

    of past mistakes, has contributed to the decline in volatility. Together both structural changes

    and innovations in policymaking have significantly changed the U.S. economic landscape.

    Economists Olivier Blanchard and John Simon note in their 2001 paper, The Long and

    Large Decline in U.S. Output Volatility, that the decline in output variation has largely been a

    result of the behavior of government spending, consumption, and investment activity. 3 They

    attribute volatility in the early period to erratic fiscal policies during both the Korean and

    Vietnam wars. Fiscal expansion also affected the volatility of output as spending increased

    during Johnsons Great Society program. With respect to consumption and investment activity,

    Blanchard and Simon attribute the lower volatility to increased competition and liquidity in

    financial markets. Viewed thought the intertemporal lens, with better access to credit and

    savings vehicles, firms and consumers face a more linear budget constraint through their initial

    endowment point. For the representative household, with imperfect credit markets, the interest

    rate charged on borrowing generally exceeds the yield obtainable for savings, resulting in a

    kinked budget constraint. Under these conditions, as current income changes, current

    consumption will increase proportionally, making consumption more volatile than it would be

    3 Blanchard 30

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    4/18

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    5/18

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    6/18

    variation contracted. They find through econometric modeling techniques that the volatility

    reduction in the durables sector was large enough to explain 66% of the reduction in aggregate

    output volatility.12 Furthermore, this reduction in volatility does not arise from merely a

    reduction in final sales volatility, but from production volatility. Kahn estimates that only 15%

    of the decline in output volatility in the durables sector can be attributed to a change in sales

    volatility.13 Volatility seen in sales figures provides an obvious justification for a decline in

    output volatility, as production is performed to fulfill sales orders. With much of the volatility,

    however, coming from production, the role of inventory management becomes apparent.

    Over the last quarter century, both target inventory to sales ratios and deviations from

    target inventory levels have significantly declined. As calculated by the U.S. Department of

    Commerce, the inventory to sales ratio for the U.S. economy declined by nearly 16% during the

    1992 to 2007 period.14 In his 2002 paper, Kahn decomposes the inventory to sales ratio into

    trend and transitory components. The trend components is the target inventory to sales ratio,

    which is driven by the advancement of information technologies. The transitory component,

    however, is the deviation in the inventory to sales ratio from the desired trend component. He

    shows that the target inventory to sales ratio has declined markedly the early 1980s. In addition

    to the decline in the target inventory to sales target ratio, deviations of the transitory component

    around the target have dampened significantly.15 As the desired amount of inventory held by

    firms relative to sales has fallen, businesses have also become more adept at managing the

    inventory they hold and targeting their desired levels. The reduction in the target inventory to

    sales ratio shows the impact of information technology, specifically powerful computers,

    productivity applications, and telecommunications. These innovation have revolutionized how

    12 Kahn, McConnell, Perez-Quiros, 185.13 Kahn, McConnell, Perez-Quiros, 186.14 U.S. Department of Commerce, Inventory to Sales Ratio15 Kahn, McConnell, Perez-Quiros, 187.

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    7/18

    firms relate to inventory and manage their supply chains. The result of these innovations has

    been a reduction in the level of production volatility.

    To better understand the exact role inventory and supply chain management play in

    affecting output volatility and the impact of information technologies, I have created a model

    based on Kahns presentation in On the Causes of the Increased Stability of the U.S. Economy.

    In my model of inventory and production decisions, there are three firms, the Low Information

    Firm, the High Information Firm, and the Very High Information Firm. Each firm faces the same

    amount of final sales for each period, which are determined by a random number generator and

    lie between 50 and 150 units of sales.

    16

    Each firm also must make a production decision at the

    start of each period, and is unable to alter its decision after it has dedicated itself to a specific

    amount. This production decision is based partly on what each firm believes will be sales next

    period and also has an inventory accumulation or exhaustion component. Additionally, all three

    firms have a target inventory to sales ratio which is determined exogenously. With respect to

    production, the Low Information Firm bases its production decision solely off of last periods

    sales, which is based upon the underlying assumption that next periods sales are equal to this

    periods sales plus a random error term. The fact that the low information firm bases production

    off last periods sales is intuitive assuming the stochastic behavior of sales for each period. The

    other two firms, the High Information Firm and the Very High Information Firm are more

    advanced in their understanding of next periods sales. They base their production decisions with

    perfect information of the next periods final sales. That means they are able to produce exactly

    enough to meet sales, but must alter production if they deviate from their target inventory level

    given their inventory to sales ratios. Inventory to sales ratios for both the Low Information Firm

    and the High Information Firm are fixed at a level of two, while the Very High Information Firm

    16 The first four final sales figues are were determined by myself for ease of calculation and grasping the model.

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    8/18

    has a declining inventory to sales ratio to represent the adoption of inventory eliminating

    information technologies and better supply chain management. Throughout the model,

    production is used to both fill sales projections and to attain the desired inventory to sales ratio.

    Inventories are used fulfill sales in the event of a shortfall in production for the Low Information

    Firm and can be interpreted as a security buffer in the case of misjudgments in sales projections

    by both the High and Very High Information Firms. Data for each of the firms is can be seen in

    Figures 1, 2, and 3. The results of a 20 period simulation reveal exactly how new technologies

    can smooth production and offer striking implications for the role of inventories and new

    technologies.

    The results of the simulation show the standard deviations of production for the Low,

    High, and Very High firms at 176.13, 94.57, and 36.05 respectively. For the Very High

    Information, the volatility of production declined by a staggering 80% relative to the Low

    Information Firm. After the adoption of information technology, production volatility declined

    as theorized. The new technology impacted the firm in two distinct ways. Contrasting the Low

    Information Firm with the High Information Firm, the only change was that the firm equipped

    with high information was able to accurately predict future sales, mitigating the need to draw

    down on inventories in the event of a large spike in sales. Instead in volatility in production

    came from maintaining desired inventory to sales ratios. While the idea that firms can accurately

    predict future sales in the next period is a bit extreme, it is not far from reality given econometric

    modeling techniques coupled with integrated barcode systems and the emerging radio frequency

    identification (RFID) technology found at the retail and manufacturing level. With the wide

    availability of accurate data, manufacturers are able to see sales and production needs in real-

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    9/18

    time, enabling more accurate forecasts of future sales.17 Besides the benefit of knowing exactly

    what future sales will be, the Very High Information firm had a declining inventory to sales ratio,

    reflecting innovation in supply chain management and the use of just-in-time production. Using

    information technologies, the representative firm is able to reduce the need to hold costly

    inventories, which not only take up physical space but occupy labor in completely unproductive

    activities. As telecommunications technologies have improved, coordinating inputs from various

    suppliers for production has become easier, eliminating the need for inventories and speeding up

    the production process. As inventories are eliminated, the inventory to sales ratio obviously

    falls, reducing the need to vary production widely in an effort to obtain target inventory levels.

    In addition to the inventory channel, advancements in information technology have

    affected the smoothing of output through the production function. The information technology

    boom has impacted volatility through the multifactor productivity variable. Consider a simple

    model of the production process, Y = ZLK1-, where Y is real output, Z is a measure of total

    factor productivity, and L and K are labor and capital respectively. Economists Stephen Oliner

    and Daniel Sichel note that during the 1974 to 1999 period, total factor productivity growth made

    up more than one-third of the growth in labor productivity.18 Besides the productivity enhancing

    characteristics of new technologies, they have likely influenced a moderation in output volatility.

    As new information technologies, specifically productivity applications, data management

    software, and telecommunications devices, have become more widespread, shocks to total factor

    productivity, the Z variable, have become smaller. With better data and communications devices,

    management techniques and the best practices within firms have become more consistent and

    17 Erik Brynjolfsson and Lorin Hitt discuss the impacts of computers and productivity applications at great length

    and specificity in their 2000 paperBeyond Computation: Information Technology, Organizational Transformation,

    and Business Performance. Their granular, but highly enlightening, analysis, however, is beyond the scope of this

    paper.18 Stephen Oliner and Daniel Sichel. The Resurgence of Growth in the Late 1990s: Is Information Technology the

    Story? 2000, JEP

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    10/18

    widely shared throughout firms and industries. Interactions between capital and labor have not

    only become more efficient, but have become more reliably efficient as management technique

    and know how abounds in the modern information-laden firm. Total factor productivity has also

    been affected by the decline in inventories relative to sales. With no inventories to manage, labor

    and capital resources are not distracted from productive activities to manage inventory

    accumulation and exhaustion. With the inventory shock to total factor productivity lessened or

    eliminated, output is able to grow at a smoother rate without period interruption.

    Besides the impact of structural factors which have contributed to the decline in

    macroeconomic volatility, much research has focused on how monetary policymaking has

    impacted the recent stability of macroeconomic variables. In contrast to the Great Inflation

    period of the 1970s, the subsequent Volcker-Greenspan era has been characterized by a marked

    stabilization in both inflation and output. During much of the 1970s, the U.S. economy was

    characterized by high inflation and deep recessions. The blame for the increase in inflation

    during this period falls squarely on the shoulders of an accommodative Fed. The Volcker-

    Greenspan era of policymaking, however, has brought about a distinct smoothing of

    macroeconomic variables through an enhanced understanding of inflation expectations,

    implementation of the Taylor principle, and flattening of the Phillips curve.

    The recent decline in price volatility relative to the pre-Volcker era can be characterized

    as a decrease in both inflation persistence and an anchoring of inflation expectations. Frederic

    Mishkin, member of Board of Governors, notes that since the early 1970s, the persistence of

    inflation has declined markedly. Given an inflationary shock, inflation reverts more quickly to

    its long run level than it has in the past.19 By regressing inflation on twelve lags of itself,

    Mishkin notes that the coefficients sum to approximately 0.6 and has declined significantly since

    19 Mishkin inflation expectations 2

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    11/18

    the 1970s.20 A decline in the sum of lagged coefficients signifies that the impact in inflation only

    produces a small amount of additional pressure in the future, a boon to policymakers. James

    Stock and Mark Watson explain a similar phenomenon in their 2007 paper with regard to

    inflation persistence. They decompose inflation into trend and transitory components, and note

    that trend inflation has fallen significantly while the transitory component has become less

    important in determining inflation.21 The anchoring of trend inflation signifies a reduction in

    inflation expectations. The decline in inflation expectations and actual inflation are mutually

    reinforcing. As expectations remain anchored actual inflation remains low, fulfilling the low

    expectations and offering additional credibility to the central bank. Credibility is important

    because even with a temporary rise in inflation, long-run expectations will be anchored based on

    the idea that the Fed is competent. While the decline in the variability of prices has been less

    pronounced than the moderation of output, it is a significant change to the macroeconomic

    environment that can be attributed to better monetary policymaking.

    In addition to the taming of inflation expectations, better monetary policy has affected the

    variability of inflation through an adherence to the Taylor principle. While the principles of

    sound money were certainly well known during much of the 20th century, data shows that only

    over the last 25 years have monetary policymakers demonstrated a competence in reducing

    inflation and its volatility. Specifically, under the chairmanship of Paul Volcker, the Federal

    Reserve began to tame inflation with an adherence to the Taylor principle. Upon arriving at the

    Federal Reserve, Chairman Volcker faced double-digit rates of inflation, but his hawkish stance

    and use of the Taylor principle quickly reduced both actual inflation and inflation expectations.

    The Taylor principle is that idea that given an increase in the rate of inflation, the nominal Fed

    20 Mishkin inflation expectations 221 James Stock and Mark Watson. Why Has U.S. Inflation Become Harder to Forecast?

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    12/18

    Funds rate must increase by more than the rate of inflation for the interest rate increase to have a

    real effect. This simple principle, while well know during the Great Inflation, was not adhered to

    by the Federal Reserve. Economist Richard Clarida explains that the Feds response to inflation

    had changed significantly since the 1970s. In his 2000 study of the behavior of the Federal

    Reserve, he finds that the Feds response to inflationary pressure changed dramatically from the

    pre-Volcker period to the Volcker-Greenspan period. Using John Taylors specification of the

    Taylor Curve, Clarida constructs a model of the nominal Fed Funds rate using the equilibrium

    real rate of interest, the deviation of inflation from the implicit target rate, and a measure of the

    output gap. Clarida finds that the coefficient on the inflation term increased noticeably across

    the pre-Volcker and Volcker-Greenspan periods. Clarida finds that the coefficient increased from

    0.83 to 2.15, both statistically significant.22 Additionally, for the output gap term, Clarida shows

    that the coefficient changed from 0.27 to 0.93, with the Volcker-Greenspan coefficient

    marginally significant.23 The increase in the Feds responsiveness shows their adherence to the

    Taylor rule, as increases in inflation are met with increases in the real Fed Funds rate.

    Also contributing to the moderation in inflationary volatility has been a changing

    relationship between inflation and changes in output. This relationship is typically expressed

    through the Phillips curve, which relates inflation to unemployment. The Phillips curve can be

    expressed as, = e (U-Un) + , in which represents the rate of inflation, e is expected

    inflation, (U-Un) is the deviation of unemployment from its natural rate, is the responsiveness

    of inflation to capacity utilization, and is a supply shock. Recent evidence has shown that the

    coefficient on the unemployment term has declined since the 1980s.24 The finding that inflation

    is less responsive to changes in capacity utilization has two striking macroeconomic

    22 Richard Clarida. Monetary Policy Rules.23 Richard Clarida. Monetary Policy Rules.24 Mishkin Inflation Dynamics Page 5

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    13/18

    implications. First, if the coefficient on the unemployment gap has declined, that means the

    Phillips curve has flattened, suggesting that changes in resource utilization do not have such a

    great impact on inflation. The Feds hawkish stance on inflation has likely influenced a

    flattening of the Phillips curve, as price increases have become less frequent and the Feds ability

    to manage demand shocks has been more credible. The result is that people expect inflation to

    remain contained and deviations in resource utilization do not cause large changes in inflation.

    As discussed at great length before, output has moderated significantly since the 1980s, but there

    are still fluctuations in the business cycle. The flattening in the Phillips curve explains also why

    inflation has moderated over the same time period of output. Not only has the variability of

    output decreased which would suggest that inflation should have moderated, but inflations

    response to the business cycle has also dampened. Secondly, the decline in inflationary

    expectations has reduced the e term, shifting the Phillips curve closer to the origin. The fact

    that inflation expectations can shift a flatter Phillips curve also indicates a potential danger to

    policymakers and the economy. If inflation expectations were to increase suddenly,

    policymakers would be forced to sacrifice a large amount of output to bring price pressures back

    to an acceptable level.

    Bringing together the two chief macroeconomic variables, output and inflation, is the

    Taylor curve, which represents the volatility tradeoff between the two variables. The downward

    sloping Taylor curve shows the different combinations of output and inflation volatility available

    to policymakers. Given an exogenous supply shock, the Taylor curve is a convenient way of

    describing the optimal choices policymakers face, as they must choose between keeping prices

    stable or output at its natural rate. Recent volatility in both prices and output can be explained by

    an inward shift of the Taylor curve. In his 2004 speech, Ben Bernanke explain, If monetary

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    14/18

    policies during the late 1960s and he 170s were sufficiently far from optimal, the result could be

    a combination of output volatility and inflation volatility lying well above the efficient frontier

    define by the Taylor curve.25 For example, during the 1970s, policymakers had an overly

    optimistic view of the economys potential, and sought to exploit a long-run version of the

    Phillips curve to attain higher output. The result was elevated prices and more volatile output as

    money growth created Using better data, having a informed idea of where potential output is,

    and competent policymaking can achieve a lower inflation and output volatility.

    The recent decline in macroeconomic variability, known as the Great Moderation, has its

    roots in both structural changes and innovations in monetary policymaking. The components of

    output have moderated significantly through the development of deeper financial markets,

    technology, and inventory management. On the monetary side, the use the anchoring of inflation

    expectations coupled with better policymaking has reduced the volatility of output and kept

    prices consistently low. The result of the decrease in macroeconomic volatility has been a great

    boon for society. The moderation in macroeconomic variables has not only affected an

    understanding of macroeconomics, but has improved the quality of life and business for all

    people. More consistent incomes, sales, employment, and prices lessened the need for economic

    planning and the amount of resources required to hedging fluctuations in the business cycle and

    the impacts of inflation.

    25 Bernanke great moderation speech 3.

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    15/18

    Correlation Between Inflation and Unemployment

    Correlation

    1960-1970 -0.7868

    1970-1980 0.3401

    1980-1990 0.0829

    1990-2007 0.2115

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    16/18

    Std. of Prices Std. of Output

    1960 1.54% 2.13%

    1970 2.90% 2.73%

    1980 3.88% 2.67%

    1990-Present 1.11% 1.41%

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    17/18

    Figure 1

    Natural Log of RGDP

    6

    6.5

    7

    7.5

    8

    8.5

    9

    9.5

    10

    1932

    1936

    1940

    1944

    1948

    1952

    1956

    1960

    1964

    1968

    1972

    1976

    1980

    1984

    1988

    1992

    1996

    2000

    2004

    Natural Log of RGDP

    Figure 2

    dFIgue

    0%

    2%

    4%

    6%

    8%

    10%

    12%

    14%

    1935

    1939

    1943

    1947

    1951

    1955

    1959

    1963

    1967

    1971

    1975

    1979

    1983

    1987

    1991

    1995

    1999

    StandardDeviationofOutput

    Changes

    (5YRP

    eriod)

    Very High Information Firm

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    160

    180

    200

    Period

    0

    Period

    2

    Period

    4

    Period

    6

    Period

    8

    Perio

    d10

    Perio

    d12

    Perio

    d14

    Perio

    d16

    Perio

    d18

    Perio

    d20

    Sales

    Production

  • 8/14/2019 Changing Business Cycle Dynamics V2.1

    18/18

    Figure 3

    Low Information Firm

    -300

    -200

    -100

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    Perio

    d0

    Perio

    d1

    Perio

    d2

    Perio

    d3

    Perio

    d4

    Perio

    d5

    Perio

    d6

    Perio

    d7

    Perio

    d8

    Perio

    d9

    Perio

    d10

    Perio

    d11

    Perio

    d12

    Perio

    d13

    Perio

    d14

    Perio

    d15

    Perio

    d16

    Perio

    d17

    Perio

    d18

    Perio

    d19

    Perio

    d20

    Sales

    Production

    Figure 4