chapter five

74
Chapter Five Choice

Upload: ogden

Post on 24-Feb-2016

27 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Chapter Five. Choice. Economic Rationality. The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it. The available choices constitute the choice set. How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Chapter Five

Chapter Five

Choice

Page 2: Chapter Five

Economic Rationality

The principal behavioral postulate is that a decisionmaker chooses its most preferred alternative from those available to it.

The available choices constitute the choice set.

How is the most preferred bundle in the choice set located?

Page 3: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Page 4: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2Utility

Page 5: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility x2

x1

Page 6: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Utility

Page 7: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Page 8: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Page 9: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Page 10: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Page 11: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle.

Page 12: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Utility

Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable bundle.

The most preferredof the affordablebundles.

Page 13: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Utility

Page 14: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Page 15: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utility

x1

x2

Page 16: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Utilityx1

x2

Page 17: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Page 18: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

Page 19: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

Page 20: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

Affordablebundles

More preferredbundles

Page 21: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

Affordablebundles

x1

x2

More preferredbundles

Page 22: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

Page 23: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is the mostpreferred affordablebundle.

Page 24: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

The most preferred affordable bundle is called the consumer’s ORDINARY DEMAND at the given prices and budget.

Ordinary demands will be denoted byx1*(p1,p2,m) and x2*(p1,p2,m).

Page 25: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0 the demanded bundle is INTERIOR.

If buying (x1*,x2*) costs $m then the budget is exhausted.

Page 26: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.

(x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget.

Page 27: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior.(a) (x1*,x2*) exhausts thebudget; p1x1* + p2x2* = m.

Page 28: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

x1

x2

x1*

x2*

(x1*,x2*) is interior .(b) The slope of the indiff.curve at (x1*,x2*) equals the slope of the budget constraint.

Page 29: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice (x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions: (a) the budget is exhausted;

p1x1* + p2x2* = m (b) the slope of the budget constraint,

-p1/p2, and the slope of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Page 30: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands

How can this information be used to locate (x1*,x2*) for given p1, p2 and m?

Page 31: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Page 32: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas preferences.

Then

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

MU Ux

ax xa b1

1112

MU Ux

bx xa b2

21 2

1

Page 33: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

MRS dxdx

U xU x

ax xbx x

axbx

a b

a b

21

12

112

1 21

21

//

.

Page 34: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

MRS dxdx

U xU x

ax xbx x

axbx

a b

a b

21

12

112

1 21

21

//

.

Page 35: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So the MRS is

At (x1*,x2*), MRS = -p1/p2 so

MRS dxdx

U xU x

ax xbx x

axbx

a b

a b

21

12

112

1 21

21

//

.

axbx

pp

x bpap

x2

1

12

2121

*

** * . (A)

Page 36: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

(x1*,x2*) also exhausts the budget so

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

Page 37: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

x bpap

x2121

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

Page 38: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

x bpap

x2121

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

Substitute

Page 39: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So now we know that

x bpap

x2121

* * (A)

p x p x m1 1 2 2* * . (B)

p x p bpap

x m1 1 2121

* * .

Substitute

and get

This simplifies to ….

Page 40: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x ama b p1

1

*( )

.

Page 41: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x bma b p2

2

*( )

.

Substituting for x1* in p x p x m1 1 2 2

* *

then gives

x ama b p1

1

*( )

.

Page 42: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

So we have discovered that the mostpreferred affordable bundle for a consumerwith Cobb-Douglas preferences

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

is( , )

( ),( )

.* * ( )x x ama b p

bma b p1 2

1 2

Page 43: Chapter Five

Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas Example.

x1

x2

x ama b p1

1

*( )

xbm

a b p

2

2

*

( )

U x x x xa b( , )1 2 1 2

Page 44: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0

and (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget,and indifference curves have no ‘kinks’, the ordinary demands are obtained by solving:

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = y (b) the slopes of the budget constraint,

-p1/p2, and of the indifference curve containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).

Page 45: Chapter Five

Rational Constrained Choice

But what if x1* = 0? Or if x2* = 0? If either x1* = 0 or x2* = 0 then the

ordinary demand (x1*,x2*) is at a corner solution to the problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget constraint.

Page 46: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Page 47: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Page 48: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Page 49: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

x yp22

*

x1 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 > p2.

Page 50: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

x yp11

*

x2 0*

MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 < p2.

Page 51: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

So when U(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, the mostpreferred affordable bundle is (x1*,x2*)where

0,py)x,x(1

*2

*1

and

2

*2

*1 p

y,0)x,x(

if p1 < p2

if p1 > p2.

Page 52: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2MRS = -1

Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 = p2.

yp1

yp2

Page 53: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect Substitutes Case

x1

x2

All the bundles in the constraint are equally the most preferred affordable when p1 = p2.

yp2

yp1

Page 54: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2Better

Page 55: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

Page 56: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

Which is the most preferredaffordable bundle?

Page 57: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Page 58: Chapter Five

Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex Preferences Case

x1

x2

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Notice that the “tangency solution”is not the most preferred affordablebundle.

Page 59: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 60: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = 0

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 61: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = - ¥

MRS = 0

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 62: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2

MRS = - ¥

MRS = 0

MRS is undefined

U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 63: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Page 64: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

Which is the mostpreferred affordable bundle?

Page 65: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

The most preferredaffordable bundle

Page 66: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

Page 67: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m

Page 68: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x1*

x2*

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m(b) x2* = ax1*

Page 69: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Page 70: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = m

Page 71: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives

21

*1 app

mx

Page 72: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives .

appamx;

appmx

21

*2

21

*1

Page 73: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.

Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives p1x1* + p2ax1* = mwhich gives

A bundle of 1 commodity 1 unit anda commodity 2 units costs p1 + ap2;m/(p1 + ap2) such bundles are affordable.

.app

amx;app

mx21

*2

21

*1

Page 74: Chapter Five

Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions -- the Perfect Complements Case

x1

x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}

x2 = ax1

x mp ap11 2

*

xam

p ap

2

1 2

*