chapter four discounting and alternative investment...

33
Chapter Four Discounting and Alternative Investment Criteria 4.1 Introduction This chapter discusses the alternative investment criteria commonly used in the appraisal of investment projects. The net present value (NPV) of a project criterion is widely accepted by accountants, financial analysts, and economists as the one that yields the correct project choices in all circumstances. However, some decision-makers have frequently relied upon other criteria, such as the internal rate of return (IRR), the benefitcost ratio (BCR), the pay-back period, and the debt service coverage ratio. The strengths and weaknesses of these criteria are examined in this chapter in order to demonstrate why the NPV criterion is the most reliable. Section 4.2 explains the concept of discounting and discusses the choice of discount rate. Section 4.3 elaborates on and compares alternative investment criteria for the appraisal investment projects. Conclusions are made in the final section. 4.2 Time Dimension of a Project Investment decisions are fundamentally different from consumption decisions. For example, fixed assets such as land and capital equipment are purchased at one point in time, and are expected to generate net cash flows, or net economic benefits, over a number of subsequent years. To determine whether the investment is worthwhile, it is necessary to compare its benefits and costs with those of alternative projects, which may occur at different time periods. A dollar spent or received today is worth more than a dollar spent or received in a later time period. It is not

Upload: others

Post on 24-Oct-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Chapter Four

    Discounting and Alternative

    Investment Criteria

    4.1 Introduction This chapter discusses the alternative investment criteria commonly used

    in the appraisal of investment projects. The net present value (NPV) of a

    project criterion is widely accepted by accountants, financial analysts,

    and economists as the one that yields the correct project choices in all

    circumstances. However, some decision-makers have frequently relied

    upon other criteria, such as the internal rate of return (IRR), the

    benefit–cost ratio (BCR), the pay-back period, and the debt service

    coverage ratio. The strengths and weaknesses of these criteria are

    examined in this chapter in order to demonstrate why the NPV criterion

    is the most reliable.

    Section 4.2 explains the concept of discounting and discusses the

    choice of discount rate. Section 4.3 elaborates on and compares

    alternative investment criteria for the appraisal investment projects.

    Conclusions are made in the final section.

    4.2 Time Dimension of a Project

    Investment decisions are fundamentally different from consumption

    decisions. For example, fixed assets such as land and capital equipment

    are purchased at one point in time, and are expected to generate net cash

    flows, or net economic benefits, over a number of subsequent years. To

    determine whether the investment is worthwhile, it is necessary to

    compare its benefits and costs with those of alternative projects, which

    may occur at different time periods. A dollar spent or received today is

    worth more than a dollar spent or received in a later time period. It is not

  • possible simply to add up the benefits and the costs of a project to see

    which are greater without taking account of the fact that amounts spent

    on investment today are worth more today than the same amount

    received as a benefit in the future.

    The time dimension of a project’s net cash flows and net economic

    benefits can be captured by expressing the values in terms of either

    future or present values. When moving forward in time to compute future

    values, analysts must allow for the compounding of interest rates. In

    contrast, when bringing future values back to the present for comparison

    purposes, it is necessary to discount them. Discounting is simply the

    inverse of compounding.

    4.2.1 Time Value of Money

    Time enhances the value of a dollar today and erodes the value of a

    dollar spent or received in the future. It is necessary to compensate

    individuals for forgoing their consumption today or lending their funds to

    a bank. In turn, banks and other financial institutions have to offer

    lenders interest in order to induce them to part temporarily with their

    funds. If the annual market interest rate is 5 percent, then 1 dollar today

    would be worth 1.05 dollars one year in the future. This means that in

    equilibrium, lenders value 1.05 dollars in one year’s time the same as 1

    dollar today.

    4.2.2 Compounding

    There are two main ways in which interest can be included in future

    values, namely simple interest and compound interest. Simple interest is

    paid only on the principal amount that is invested, while compound

    interest is paid on both the principal and the interest as it accumulates.

    Compound interest, which is the most commonly used way of charging

    interest, can cause the future value of 1 dollar invested today to increase

    by substantially more than simple interest over time. The difference is

    caused by the interest on the cumulative interest. The formula for

    compound interest payment is Vt = (1+r)t, where Vt stands for the value

    in Year t of 1 dollar received in Year 0, and r denotes the rate of interest.

    Interest may be compounded annually. However, it is common for

  • interest to be compounded more frequently, for example, semi-annually,

    quarterly, monthly, or even daily. The number of compounding intervals

    will also affect the future value of an amount of cash invested today.

    Thus, the two factors affecting the future value of a dollar invested today

    are the time period of the investment and the interest rate.

    Furthermore, when comparing two debt contracts, it is essential that

    they be judged on the basis of equivalent rates, for example, annual rates

    in the case of loan agreements, and semi-annual rates in the case of

    bonds. The magnitude of the interest rate is certainly a major determinant

    of the future value of a series of cash flow items.

    4.2.3 Discounting

    The discount factor allows the present value of a dollar received or paid

    in the future to be calculated. Since this involves moving backward

    rather than forward in time, the discount factor is the inverse of the

    compound interest factor. For example, an amount of 1 dollar now will,

    if invested, grow to (1+r) a year later. It follows that an amount B to be

    received in n years in the future will have a present value of B / (1+r)n.

    The greater the rate of discount used, the smaller its present value.

    The nature of investment projects is such that their benefits and costs

    usually occur in different periods over time. The NPV of a future stream

    of net benefits, (B0 − C0), (B1 − C1), (B2 − C2), …., (Bn − Cn), can be

    expressed algebraically as follows:

    = (4.1)

    where n denotes the length of life of the project. The expression 1 / (1+r)t

  • is commonly referred to as the discount factor for Year t.

    For the purposes of illustration, the present value of the stream of net

    benefits over the life of an investment is calculated in Table 4.1 by

    multiplying the discount factors, which are given in line 4, by the values

    of the net benefits for the corresponding periods, shown in line 3. The

    NPV of $1,000 is the simple sum of the present values of net benefits

    arising each period throughout the life of the project.

    Table 4.1: Calculating the Present Value of Net Benefits from an

    Investment Project (dollars)

    Items 0 1 2 3 4 5

    1. Benefits 3,247 4,571 3,525 2,339

    2. Costs 5,000 2,121 1,000 1,000 1,000 1,000

    3. Net benefits (= 1−2) −5,000

    −2,12

    1 +2,24

    7 +3,5

    71 +2,52

    5 +1,33

    9

    4. Discount factor at 6%

    (= 1 / (1+r)t) 1.000 0.943 0.890 0.840 0.792 0.747

    5. Present values (= 43) −5,000

    −2,00

    0 +2,00

    0 +3,0

    00 +2,00

    0 +1,00

    0

    6. NPV 1,000

    Equation (4.1) shows that the net benefits arising during the project’s

    life are discounted to Year 0. Instead of discounting all the net benefit

    flows to the initial year of a project, we could evaluate the project’s

    stream of net benefits as of a year k, which does not even need to fall

    within the project’s expected life. In this case, all the net benefits arising

    from Year 0 to Year k must be cumulated forward at a rate of r to Year k.

    Likewise, all net benefits associated with years k+1 to n are discounted

    back to Year k at the same rate r. The expression for the NPV as of Year

    k becomes:

  • = [(Bt − Ct) (1+r)k-t

    ]

    = [(Bt − Ct) / (1+r)t] (1+r)

    k

    (4.2)

    The term (1+r)k is a constant value as it is a function of the discount

    rate and the date to which the present values are calculated. The rankings

    of alternative projects will not be altered if the project’s net benefits are

    discounted to Year k instead of Year 0. The present values of their

    respective net benefits discounted at Year 0 are all multiplied by the

    same constant term. Hence, the ranking of the NPVs of the net benefits

    of the alternative projects will not be affected.

    4.2.4 Variable Discount Rates

    Up to this point it has been assumed that the discount rate remains

    constant throughout the life of a project. This need not be the case.

    Suppose that funds are presently very scarce relative to the historical

    experience of the country. In such circumstances, the cost of funds would

    be expected to be currently abnormally high, and the discount rate is

    likely fall over time as the supply and demand for funds return to normal.

    On the other hand, if funds are abundant at present, the cost of funds and

    the discount rate would be expected to be below their long-term average.

    In this case, the discount rate would be expected to rise as the demand

    and supply of funds return to their long-term trend over time. This

    process is illustrated in Figure 4.1.

    Figure 4.1: Adjustment of Cost of Funds through Time

  • Suppose that the discount rates will vary from year to year over the

    life of a four-year project. The discount rate r1 is the cost of capital, or

    the rate of discount extending from Year 0 to Year 1. The NPV of the

    project should be calculated as:

    where r1, r2, and r3 are the discount rates for Year 1, Year 2, and Year 3,

    respectively. Each discount factor after Year 2 will be made up of more

    than one discount rate. For example, the discount factor for Year 3’s net

    benefits is 1/[(1+r1)(1+r2)(1+r3)]. The general expression for the NPV of

    the project with a life of n years, evaluated as of Year 0, becomes:

  • NPV0 = (B0 − C0) +

    (4.3)

    As in the case of the constant rate of discount, when comparing two

    or more projects, the period to which the net benefits of the projects are

    discounted does not matter, provided that the present values of the net

    benefits of each of the projects being compared are discounted to the

    same date.

    4.2.5 Choice of Discount Rate

    The discount rate is a key variable in the application of investment

    criteria for project selection. Choosing the discount rate correctly is

    critical given the fact that a small variation in its value may significantly

    alter the results of the analysis and affect the final choice of a project.

    The discount rate, stated in simple terms, is the opportunity cost of

    funds that are invested in the project. In financial analysis, the discount

    rate depends upon the viewpoints of analysis. For instance, when a

    project is being appraised from the point of view of the equity holders,

    the relevant cost of funds is the return to equity that is being earned in its

    alternative use. Thus, if the equity holders are earning a return of

    15percent on their current investments and decide to invest in a new

    project, the cost of funds, or the discount rate, from their perspective for

    the new project is 15 percent.

    When an economic analysis of a project is being conducted, the

    relevant discount rate is the economic opportunity cost of capital for the

    country. Estimating this cost starts with the capital market as the

    marginal source of funds, and involves determining the ultimate sources

    of funds obtained via the capital market and estimating the respective

    cost of each source. The funds are generally drawn from three sources.

    First, funds that would have been invested in other investment activities

    have now been displaced by the project. The cost of these funds is the

    gross-of-tax return that would have been earned by the alternative

  • investments, which have now been forgone. Second, funds come from

    different categories of savers in the economy, who postpone some of

    their consumption in the expectation of obtaining a return on their

    savings. The cost of this part of the funds is the cost of postponing this

    consumption. Third, some funds may be coming from abroad, that is,

    from foreign savers. The cost of these funds is the marginal cost of

    foreign borrowing. Thus, the economic opportunity cost of capital will

    simply be a weighted average of the costs of funds from three alternative

    sources. The detailed methodology for measuring the economic

    opportunity cost of capital will be discussed later.

    4.3 Alternative Investment Criteria

    Various criteria have been used in the past to evaluate whether an

    investment project is financially and economically viable. In this section,

    six of these criteria will be reviewed, namely the NPV, the IRR, the BCR,

    the pay-out or pay-back period, the debt service coverage ratio, and

    cost-effectiveness.

    4.3.1 Net Present Value Criterion

    The NPV is the algebraic sum of the present values of the expected

    incremental net cash flows for a project over the project’s anticipated

    lifetime. It measures the change in wealth created by the project.

    a) When to Accept and Reject Projects

    If the NPV of the project is 0, investors can expect to recover their

    incremental investment and also earn a rate of return on their capital that

    would have been earned elsewhere and is equal to the private discount

    rate used to compute the present values. This implies that investors

    would be neither worse nor better off than they would have been if they

    had left the funds in the capital market. A positive NPV for a project

    means that investors can expect not only to recover their capital

    investment but also to receive a rate of return on capital higher than the

    discount rate. However, if the NPV is less than 0, investors cannot expect

    to earn a rate of return equal to the discount rate, nor can they expect to

  • recover their invested capital, and, hence, their real net worth is expected

    to decrease. Only projects with a positive NPV are attractive to private

    investors. Such investors are unlikely to pursue a project with a negative

    NPV unless there are strategic reasons for doing so. Many of these

    strategic reasons can also be evaluated in terms of their NPVs through

    the valuation of the real options made possible by the strategic project.

    This leads to Decision Rule 1 of the NPV criterion, which holds under all

    circumstances.

    Rule 1: Do not accept any project unless it generates a positive NPV

    when discounted by the opportunity cost of funds.

    b) Budget Constraints

    Often, investors cannot obtain sufficient funds to undertake all the

    available projects that have a positive NPV. This is also the case for

    governments. When such a situation arises, a choice must be made

    between the projects to determine the subset that will maximize the NPV

    produced by the investment package while fitting within the budget

    constraint. Thus, Decision Rule 2 is:

    Rule 2: Within the limit of a fixed budget, choose the subset of the

    available projects that maximizes the NPV.

    Since a budget constraint does not require that all the money be spent,

    the rule will prevent any project that has a negative NPV from being

    undertaken. Even if not all the funds in the budget are spent, the NPV

    generated by the funds in the budget will be increased if a project with a

    negative NPV is dropped from consideration. It should be kept in mind

    that the funds assigned by the budget allocation but not spent will simply

    remain in the capital market and continue to generate a rate of return

    equal to the economic opportunity cost of capital.

    Suppose the following set of projects describes the investment

    opportunities faced by an investor with a fixed budget for capital

    expenditures of $4.0 million:

    Project A Project B Project C Project D

    PV investment

    costs $1.0 milli

    on $3.0 milli

    on $2.0 milli

    on $2.0 milli

    on

  • NPV of net

    benefits +$60,000 +$400,00

    0 +$150,00

    0 +$225,00

    0

    Given a budget constraint of $4 million, all possible combinations

    that fit within this constraint would be explored. Combinations BC and

    BD are not feasible as they cost too much. AC and AD are within the

    budget, but are overshadowed by the combination AB, which has a total

    NPV of $460,000. The only other feasible combination is CD, but its

    NPV of $375,000 is not as high as that of AB. If the budget constraint

    was expanded to $5 million, Project A should be dropped and Project D

    undertaken in conjunction with Project B. In this case, the NPV from this

    package of projects (BD) is expected to be $625,000, which is greater

    than the NPV of the next best alternative (BC), $550,000.

    Suppose that Project A, instead of having an NPV of +$60,000, has

    an NPV of −$60,000. If the budget constraint was still $4.0 million, the

    best strategy would be to undertake only Project B, which would yield an

    NPV of $400,000. In this case, $1 million of the budget would remain in

    the capital market, even though it is the budget constraint that is

    preventing the undertaking of potentially favourable Projects C and D.

    c) No Budget Constraints

    In evaluating investment projects, situations are often encountered in

    which there is a choice between mutually exclusive projects. It may not

    be possible for all projects to be undertaken, for technical reasons. For

    example, in building a road between two towns, there are several

    different qualities of road that can be built, given that only one road will

    be built. The problem facing the investment analyst is to choose from

    among the mutually exclusive alternatives such that the project will yield

    the maximum NPV. This can be expressed as Decision Rule 3:

    Rule 3: When there is no budget constraint but a project must be

    chosen from mutually exclusive alternatives, investors should always

    choose the alternative that generates the largest NPV.

    Consider three projects — E, F, and G — that are mutually exclusive for technical reasons and have the following characteristics:

  • Project E Project F Project G

    PV investment

    costs $1.0 million $4.0 million $1.5 million

    NPV of net

    benefits +$300,000 +$700,000 +$600,000

    In this situation, all three are good potential projects that would yield a

    positive NPV. However, only one can be undertaken.

    Project F involves the highest expenditure; it also has the largest

    NPV, $700,000. Thus, Project F should be chosen. Although Project G

    has the highest NPV per dollar of investment, this is not relevant if the

    discount rate reflects the economic opportunity cost of the funds. If

    Project F is undertaken rather than Project G, there is an incremental gain

    in NPV of $100,000 over and above the opportunity cost of the

    additional investment of $2.5 million. Therefore, Project F is preferred. It

    is worth pointing out that the NPV of a project measures the value or

    surplus generated by a project over and above what would be gained or

    generated by these funds if they were not used in the project in question.

    d) Projects with Different Lifetimes

    In some situations, an investment in a facility such as a road can be

    carried out in a number of mutually exclusive ways. For example, the

    road services could be provided by a series of projects with short lives,

    such as installing a gravel surface, or by ones with longer lives, such as

    installing a paved surface. If the return on the expansion of the facility

    over its lifetime is such as to be an investment opportunity that would

    yield a significantly positive NPV, it would not be meaningful to

    compare the NPV of a project that produced road services for the full

    duration with the NPV of a project that produced road services for only

    part of the period. The same issue arises when alternative investment

    strategies are evaluated for power generation. It is not correct to compare

    the NPV of a gas turbine plant with a life of ten years to a

    coal-generation station having a life of 30 years. In such a case, the

    comparison must be between investment strategies that have

    approximately the same length of life. This may involve comparing a

    series of gas turbine projects followed by other types of generation that

    in total have the same length of life as the coal plant.

  • When projects of short duration lead to further projects that yield

    supra-marginal returns, the comparison of alternative projects of

    different lengths that will provide the same services at a point in time

    will require adjustments to be made to investment strategies so that they

    span approximately the same period of time. One such form of

    adjustment is to consider the same project being repeated through time

    until the alternative investment strategies have the same duration.

    Consider the following three types of road surface.

    Alternative Investment Projects Duration of Road

    A: Gravel surfaced road 3 years

    B: Gravel-tar surfaced road 5 years

    C: Asphalt surface road 15 years

    Comparing the NPVs of these three alternatives lasting three, five,

    and fifteen years could produce misleading results. However, it is

    possible to make a correct comparison of these projects by constructing

    an investment strategy consisting of five gravel road projects, each

    undertaken at a date in the future when the previous one is worn out. A

    comparison could then be made of five gravel road projects, extending

    15 years into the future, with three tar surface roads and one asphalt road

    of 15-year duration. This comparison can be written as follows:

    Alternative Strategies Duration of Road

    (i) (A + A + A + A +

    A) 15 years (i.e., 1–3, 4–6, 7–9, 10–12, 13–15)

    (ii) (B + B + B) 15 years (i.e., 1–5, 6–10, 11–15)

    (iii) (C) 15 years (i.e., 1–15)

    Alternatively, it might be preferable to consider investment strategies

    made up of a mix of different types of road surfaces through time, such

    as:

    Alternative Strategies Duration of Road

  • (iv) (A + A + A + B +

    C) 29 years (i.e., 1–3, 4–6, 7–9, 10–14, 15–29)

    (v) (A + B + B + C) 28 years (i.e., 1–3, 4–8, 9–13, 14–28)

    In this situation, a further adjustment should be made to the 29-year

    strategy (iv) to make it comparable to strategy (v), which is expected to

    last for only 28 years. This can be done by calculating the NPV of the

    project after dropping the benefits accruing in Year 29 from the NPV

    calculation, while at the same time multiplying the present value of its

    costs by the fraction (PVB1–28)/PVB, where PVB denotes the present

    value of the benefits of the entire strategy, including year 29, and

    PVB1–28 is the present value of the benefits that arise in the first 28 years

    of the project’s life. In this way, the present value of the costs of the

    project are reduced by the same fraction as the present value of its

    benefits so that it will be comparable in terms of both costs and benefits

    to the strategy with the shorter life.

    Although the NPV criterion is widely used in making investment

    decisions, alternative criteria are also frequently employed. Some of

    these alternatives have serious drawbacks compared with the NPV

    criterion and are therefore judged to be not only less reliable but also

    potentially misleading. When two or more criteria are used to appraise a

    project, there is a chance that they will point to different conclusions, and

    a wrong decision could be made (see, e.g., Ley, 2007). This creates

    unnecessary confusion and, potentially, mistakes.

    4.3.2 Internal Rate of Return Criterion

    The IRR for a project is the discount rate () that is obtained by the solution of the following equation:

    [(Bj − Cj) / (1+)j] = 0

    (4.4)

    where Bj and Cj are the respective cash inflow and outflow in Year j to

  • capital. This definition is consistent with the meaning of an NPV of 0:

    that investors recover their invested capital and earn a rate of return equal

    to the IRR. Thus, the IRR and the NPV criteria are related in terms of the

    way they are derived. To calculate the NPV, the discount rate is given

    and used to find the present value of benefits and costs. In contrast, when

    finding the IRR of a project, the procedure is reversed by setting the

    NPV of the net benefit stream to 0.

    The IRR criterion has seen considerable use by both private and

    public sector investors as a way of describing the attractiveness of a

    particular project. However, it is not a reliable investment criterion, as

    there are several problems associated with it.

    Problem 1: The IRR may not be unique

    The IRR is, strictly speaking, the root of a mathematical equation. The

    equation is based on the time profile of the incremental net cash flows,

    like those in Figure 4.2. If the time profile crosses the horizontal axis

    from negative to positive only once, as in Figure 4.2 a), the root, or IRR,

    will exist. However, if the time profile crosses the axis more than once,

    as in Figure 4.2 b) and Figure 4.2 c), it may not be possible to determine

    a unique IRR. Projects whose major items of equipment must be replaced

    from time to time will give rise to periodic negative net cash flows in the

    years of reinvestment. Road projects have this characteristic, as major

    expenditures on resurfacing must be undertaken periodically for them to

    remain serviceable.

    Figure 4.2: Time Profiles of the Incremental Net Cash Flows for

    Various Types of Projects

  • There are also cases in which the termination of a project entails

    substantial costs. Examples of such situations are the land reclamation

    costs required to meet environmental standards at the closing down of a

    mine, or the agreement to restore rented facilities to their former state.

    These cases are illustrated by Figure 4.2 c). These project files may yield

    multiple solutions for the IRR; these multiple solutions, when present,

    represent a problem of proper choice of the rate of return.

    Consider the simple case of an investment of $100 in Year 0, a net

    benefit of $300 in Year 1, and a net cost of $200 in Year 2. The solutions

    for the IRR are 0 and 100 percent.

    Even when the IRR can be unambiguously calculated for each

    project under consideration, its use as an investment criterion poses

    difficulties when some of the projects in question are strict alternatives.

    This can arise in three ways: projects require different sizes of

    investment, projects are of different durations, and projects represent

    different timings for a project. In each of these three cases, the IRR can

    lead to the incorrect choice of project.

    Problem 2: Projects of different scale

    The problem of having to choose between two or more mutually

    exclusive projects arises quite frequently. Examples include two

    alternative buildings being considered for the same site and a new

    highway that could run down two alternative rights of way. Whereas the

    NPV takes explicit account of the scale of the project by means of the

    investment that is required, the IRR ignores the differences in scale.

  • Consider a case in which Project A has an investment cost of $1,000

    and is expected to generate net cash flows of $300 each year in

    perpetuity. Project B is a strict alternative and has an investment cost of

    $5,000. It is expected to generate net cash flows of $1,000 each year in

    perpetuity. The IRR for Project A is 30 percent (ρA = 300/1,000), while

    the IRR for Project B is 20 percent (ρB = 1,000/5,000). However, the

    NPV of Project A using a 10 percent discount rate is $2,000, while the

    NPV of Project B is $5,000.

    In this example, if a choice is made between Projects A and B, the

    IRR criterion would lead to Project A being chosen because it has an

    IRR of 30 percent, which is higher than the 20 percent for Project B.

    However, the fact that Project B is larger enables it to produce a greater

    NPV even if its IRR is smaller. Thus, the NPV criterion indicates that

    Project B should be chosen. This illustration demonstrates that when a

    choice has to be made among mutually exclusive projects with different

    sizes of investment, the use of the IRR criterion can lead to the incorrect

    choice of projects.

    Problem 3: Projects with different lengths of life

    In this case there are two projects, C and D. Project C calls for the

    planting of a species of tree that can be harvested in five years, while

    Project D calls for the planting of a type of tree that can be harvested in

    ten years. The investment costs are the same for both projects at $1,000.

    It is also assumed that neither of the projects can be repeated. The two

    projects can be analyzed as follows:

    Project C Project D

    Investment costs: $1,000 in Year 0 $1,000 in Year 0

    Net benefits: $3,200 in Year 5 $5,200 in Year 10

    NPV criterion @ 8%:

    = $1,178 =

    $1,409

  • <

    IRR criterion: C

    = 26.2% D

    = 17.9%

    C>

    D

    According to the NPV criterion, Project D is preferred. However, the

    IRR of Project D is smaller than that of Project C. Thus, the IRR

    criterion is unreliable for project selection when alternative projects have

    different lengths of life.

    Problem 4: Projects with different timing

    Suppose two projects, E and F, are started at different times and both last

    for one year. Project F is started five years after Project E. Both projects

    have investment costs of $1,000. They are summarized as follows:

    Project E Project F

    Investment costs: $1,000 in Year 0 $1,000 in Year 5

    Net benefits: $1,500 in Year 1 $1,600 in Year 6

  • NPV criterion @ 8%:

    = $389 =

    $328

    >

    IRR criterion: E

    = 50% F

    = 60%

    E<

    F

    Evaluating these two projects according to the NPV criterion would

    indicate that Project E should be chosen over Project F because

    > . However, the fact that E<

    F

    suggests that Project F should be chosen if the IRR criterion is used.

    Again, because Projects E and F are strict alternatives, use of the IRR

    criterion can result in the incorrect choice of project being made.

    Problem 5: Irregularity of cash flows

  • In many situations the cash flows of a project may be negative in a single

    (investment) period, though this does not occur at the beginning of the

    project. An example of such a situation would be a

    build–operate–transfer (BOT) arrangement from the point of view of the

    government. During the operating stage of this project, the government is

    likely to receive tax benefits from the private operator. At the point when

    the project is turned over to the public sector, the government has agreed

    to pay a transfer price. Such a cash flow from the government’s point of

    view can be illustrated as Project A in Table 4.2, where the transfer price

    at the end of the contract is $8,000.

    Table 4.2: IRR for Irregular Cash Flows

    Year 0 1 2 3 4 IRR

    Project A 1,000 1,200 800 3,600 −8,000

    10%

    Project B 1,000 1,200 800 3,600 −6,400

    −2%

    Project C 1,000 1,200 800 3,600 −4,800

    −16

    %

    Project D −1,000

    1,200 800 3,600 −4,800

    4%

    Project E −1,325

    1,200 800 3,600 −4,800

    20%

    Results:

    Project B is obviously better than Project A, yet

    IRRA > IRRB.

    Project C is obviously

    better than Project B, yet IRRB > IRRC.

    Project D is worse than Project C, yet IRRD >

    IRRC.

    Project E is worse than

    Project D, yet IRRE >

    IRRD.

  • This four-year project has an IRR of 10 percent. However, suppose

    the negotiators for the government were successful in obtaining a lower

    transfer price at the end of the private sector’s contract period. The

    situation where the contract price is reduced to $6,400 is shown as

    Project B. Everything else is the same as Project A except for the lower

    transfer payment at the end of that period. In this case, the IRR falls from

    10 to −2 percent. It is obvious that the arrangement under Project B is

    better for the government than Project A, yet it has a lower IRR. If the

    transfer price were reduced further to $4,800, the IRR falls to −16

    percent, yet it is obvious that it is a better project than either Project A or

    Project B.

    Now consider the situation if the government were required to pay an

    amount of $1,000 at the start of the project in addition to a final transfer

    price of $4,800 at the end. It is obvious that this is an inferior

    arrangement (Project D) for the government over the previous one

    (Project C), in which no upfront payment is required. However,

    according to the IRR criterion, it is a much improved project, with an

    IRR of 4percent.

    In the final case, Project E, the situation for the government is made

    worse by requiring an upfront fee of $1,325 in Year 0, in addition to the

    transfer price of $4,800 in Year 4. Yet according to the IRR criterion, the

    arrangement is more attractive with an IRR of 20 percent.

    None of these situations are unusual. Such patterns in the case flow

    are common in project finance arrangements. However, the IRR is found

    to be a highly unreliable measure of the financial attractiveness of such

    arrangements when irregular cash flows are likely to exist.

    4.3.3 Benefit–Cost Ratio Criterion

    The BCR, sometimes referred to as the profitability index, is the ratio of

    the present value of the cash inflows (or benefits) to the present value of

    the cash outflows (or costs) using the opportunity cost of funds as the

    discount rate:

  • Using this criterion, in order for a project to be acceptable, the BCR

    must have a value greater than 1. Moreover, for choices between

    mutually exclusive projects, the rule would be to choose the alternative

    with the highest BCR.

    However, this criterion may produce an incorrect ranking of projects

    if the projects differ in size. Consider the following cases of mutually

    exclusive projects A, B, and C:

    Project A Project B Project C

    PV investment costs $1.0 million $8.0 million $1.5 million

    PV benefits $1.3 million $9.4 million $2.1 million

    NPV of net benefits $0.3 million $1.4 million $0.6 million

    BCR 1.3 1.175 1.4

    In this example, if the projects were ranked according to their BCRs,

    Project C would be chosen. However, since the NPV of Project C is less

    than the NPV of Project B, the ranking of the projects should result in

    Project B being selected; thus, the BCR criterion would lead to an

    incorrect investment decision.

    The second problem associated with the use of the BCR, and perhaps

    its most serious drawback, is that the BCR of a project is sensitive to the

    way in which costs are defined in setting out the cash flows. For example,

    if a good being sold is taxed at the manufacturer’s level, the cash flow

    item for receipts could be recorded either net or gross of sales taxes.

    In addition, costs can also be recorded in more than one way.

    Suppose that a project has the recurrent costs. In this case, the BCR will

    be altered by the way these costs are accounted for. All the costs and

    benefits are discounted by the cost of capital at 10 percent and expressed

    in dollars.

    Project D Project E

    PV investment costs $1,200 $100

    PV gross benefits $2,000 $2,000

    PV recurrent costs $500 $1,800

  • If the recurrent costs are netted out from cash inflows, Project E

    would be preferred to Project D according to the BCR because:

    BCRD = (2,000 − 500)/1,200 = 1.25 BCRE

    = (2,000 − 1,800)/100 = 2.00

    However, if the recurrent costs are instead added to the present value of

    cash outflows, Project D appears to be more attractive than Project E:

    BCRD = 2,000/(500 + 1,200) = 1.18

    BCRE = 2,000/(1,800 + 100) = 1.05

    Hence, the ranking of the two projects can be reversed depending on the

    treatment of recurrent costs in the calculation of the BCR. On the other

    hand, the NPV of a project is not sensitive to the way the costs are

    treated, and therefore, it is far more reliable than the BCR as a criterion

    for project selection.

    4.3.4 Pay-Out or Pay-Back Period

    The pay-out or pay-back period measures the number of years it will take

    for the net cash flows to repay the capital investment. Projects with the

    shortest pay-back period are preferred. This method is easy to use when

    making investment decisions. The criterion puts a large premium on

    projects that have a quick pay-back, and thus, it has been a popular

    criterion in making business investment choices.1 Unfortunately, it may

    provide the wrong results, especially in the case of investments with a

    long life, where future net benefits are known with a considerable degree

    of certainty.

    In its simplest form, the pay-out period measures the number of

    years it will take for the undiscounted net cash flows to repay the

    investment. A more sophisticated version of this rule compares the

    discounted benefits over a number of years from the beginning of the

    project with the discounted investment costs. An arbitrary limit may be

    set on the maximum number of years allowed, and only those

    investments that have enough benefits to offset all investment costs

    within this period will be acceptable.

    1 This criterion has similar characteristics to the loan life cover ratio (LLCR)

    used by bankers. This might explain its continued use in business

    decision-making.

  • The use of the pay-back period as an investment criterion by the

    private sector is often a reflection of a high level of risk, especially

    political risk. Suppose a private venture is expected to receive a subsidy

    or be allowed to operate only as long as the current government is in

    power. In such circumstances, in order for a private investor to go ahead

    with this project, it is critical that the pay-back period of the project is

    shorter than the expected tenure of the government.

    The implicit assumption of the pay-out period criterion is that

    benefits accruing beyond the time set as the pay-out period are so

    uncertain that they should be disregarded. It also ignores any investment

    costs that might occur beyond that date, such as the landscaping and

    replanting costs arising from the closure of a strip mine. While the future

    is undoubtedly more uncertain than the present, it is unrealistic to assume

    that beyond a certain date, the net benefits are 0. This is particularly true

    for long-term investments such as bridges, roads, and dams. There is no

    reason to expect that all quick-yielding projects are superior to long-term

    investments.

    As an example, two projects are illustrated in Figure 4.3. Both are

    assumed to have identical capital costs (i.e., Ca = C

    b). However, the

    benefit profiles of the two projects are such that Project A has greater

    benefits than Project B in each period until Period t*. From Period t

    * to tb,

    Project A yields 0 net benefits, but Project B yields positive benefits, as

    shown in the shaded area.

    With a pay-out period of t* years, Project A will be preferred to

    Project B because for the same costs, it yields greater benefits earlier.

    However, in terms of the NPV of the overall project, it is very likely that

    Project B, with its greater benefits in later years, will be significantly

    superior. In such a situation, the pay-back period criterion would give the

    wrong recommendation for the choice between investments.

    Figure 4.3: Comparison of Two Projects with Differing Lives using

    Pay-out Period

  • 4.3.5 Debt Service Coverage Ratios

    The debt service coverage ratio is a key factor in determining the ability

    of a project to pay its operating expenses and to meet its debt servicing

    obligations. It is used by bankers who want to know the annual debt

    service capacity ratio (ADSCR) of a project on a year-to-year basis, and

    to obtain a summary ratio of the loan life cover ratio (LLCR) (Yescombe,

    2002).

    The ADSCR is the ratio of the annual net cash flow of the project

    over the amount of debt repayment due. It is calculated on a year-to-year

    basis as follows:

    ADSCRt = [ANCFt / (Annual Debt Repaymentt)]

    where ANCFt is annual net cash flow of the project before financing for

    Period t and Annual Debt Repaymentt is annual interest expenses and

    principal repayment due in the specific period t of the loan repayment

    period.

    The overall project’s LLCR is calculated as the present value of net

    cash flows divided by the present value of loan repayments from the

    current period t to the end period of loan repayment:

    LLCRt = PV(ANCFt to end year of debt) /

    PV(Annual Debt Repaymentt to end year of debt)

    where PV(ANCFt to end year of debt) and PV(Annual Debt Repaymentt to end year of

  • debt) are the sum of the present values of annual net cash flows and annual

    debt repayments, respectively, over the current period t to the end of loan

    repayment. The discount rates used are the same as the interest rate being

    paid on the loan financing. The LLCR tells the banker whether there is

    enough cash from the project to make bridge financing in one or more

    specific periods when there is inadequate cash flow to service the debt.

    Table 4.3 illustrates the example of an investment of $2 million

    being undertaken with a proposal for financing that includes a loan of

    $1 million bearing a nominal interest rate of 15percent, with a

    repayment period of five years (with an equal repayment) beginning one

    year after the loan is given. The required rate of return on equity is

    assumed at 20 percent.

    Table 4.3 shows the annual cash flows net of operating expenses,

    along with the annual debt service obligations. The project is not

    attractive to the banker since the ADSCRs are low, at only 1.07 in Years

    1 and 2, with no single years giving a debt service ratio of more than

    1.47. This means that there could be a cash shortfall and an inability to

    pay the lenders the principal repayment and interest that is due.

    Table 4.3: Calculation of Annual Debt Service Capacity Ratio

    (dollars)

    Year 0 1 2 3 4 5

    Net cash flow −2,000,000

    320,00

    0 320,0

    00 360,0

    00 440,0

    00 380,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 0 298,31

    6 298,3

    16 298,3

    16 298,3

    16 298,3

    16

    ADSCR 1.07 1.07 1.21 1.47 1.27

    Year 6 7 8 9 10

    Net cash flow 100,000 200,000

    480,0

    00 540,0

    00 640,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment

    ADSCR

  • The question now is how the ADSCRs can be improved. There are

    fundamentally only three alternatives:

    decrease the interest rate on the loan;

    decrease the amount of debt financing; or

    increase the duration of the loan repayment.

    a) Decrease the Interest Rate on the Loan

    If the terms of the loan can be restructured so that the ADSCRs look

    better, it may be attractive to the banker to provide financing. Table 4.4

    shows the effect of obtaining a concessional interest rate or interest rate

    subsidy for the loan. In this case it is assumed that a 1 percent interest

    rate can be obtained for the full five-year period that the loan is

    outstanding. The ADSCRs are much larger now, never becoming less

    than 1.55; however, such a financing subsidy might be very difficult to

    obtain.

    Table 4.4: Decrease the Interest Rate on the Loan (dollars)

    Year 0 1 2 3 4 5

    Net cash flow −2,000,000

    320,00

    0 320,0

    00 360,0

    00 440,0

    00 380,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 0 206,04

    0 206,0

    40 206,0

    40 206,0

    40 206,0

    40

    ADSCR 1.55 1.55 1.75 2.14 1.84

    Year 6 7 8 9 10

    Net cash flow 100,000 200,000

    480,0

    00 540,0

    00 640,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment

    ADSCR

    b) Decrease the Amount of Debt Financing

  • Table 4.5 shows a case in which the amount of the loan is reduced from

    $1 million to $600,000. Here, the ADSCRs are found to increase greatly,

    so that they now never fall below a value of 1.79. Since the amount of

    the annual repayment of that loan becomes smaller (equity financing is

    increased), the ability of the project to service the debt becomes much

    more certain.

    Table 4.5: Decrease the Amount of Borrowing by Increasing

    Equity to $1.4 Million (dollars)

    Year 0 1 2 3 4 5

    Net cash flow −2,000,000

    320,00

    0 320,0

    00 360,0

    00 440,0

    00 380,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 0 178,98

    9 178,9

    89 178,9

    89 178,9

    89 178,9

    89

    ADSCR 1.79 1.79 2.01 2.46 2.12

    Year 6 7 8 9 10

    Net cash flow 100,000 200,000

    480,0

    00 540,0

    00 640,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment

    ADSCR

    c) Increase the Duration of the Loan Repayment

    Table 4.6 shows the case in which the duration of the loan is increased

    from five to ten years. If a financial institution is able to extend a loan for

    such a long period, the annual debt service obligations will fall greatly.

    The result is that except for Years 6 and 7, the annual debt service

    obligation never falls below 1.61. In Years 6 and 7, the ADSCRs are

    projected to be only 0.50 and 1.00, respectively. This is due to a

    projected fall in the net cash flows that might arise because of the need to

    make reinvestments or heavy maintenance expenditures in those years.

  • Table 4.6: Increase the Duration of Loan Repayment (dollars)

    Year 0 1 2 3 4 5

    Net cash flow −2,000,000

    320,00

    0 320,0

    00 360,0

    00 440,0

    00 380,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 0 199,25

    2 199,2

    52 199,2

    52 199,2

    52 199,2

    52

    ADSCR 1.61 1.61 1.81 2.21 1.91

    Year 6 7 8 9 10

    Net cash flow 100,000 200,000

    480,0

    00 540,0

    00 640,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 199,252 199,25

    2 199,2

    52 199,2

    52 199,2

    52

    ADSCR 0.50 1.00 2.41 2.71 3.21

    The question now is whether the project has sufficiently strong net

    cash flows in the years following Years 6 and 7 to warrant the financial

    institution providing the project bridge financing for these two years.

    This additional new loan would be repaid from the surplus net cash flows

    in later years. In addressing this question, the LLCR is the appropriate

    criterion to determine whether the project should qualify for bridge

    financing. The present value of the net cash flows remaining until the

    end of the debt repayment period, discounted at the loan interest rate, is

    divided by the present value of the debt repayments for the remaining

    duration of the loan. It is also discounted at the loan interest rate. These

    estimations are presented in Table 4.7.

    The LLCRs for Years 6 and 7 are 1.77 and 2.21, respectively. This

    indicates that there are likely to be more than adequate net cash flows

    from the project to safely repay the bridge financing that is needed to

    cover the likely shortfalls in cash during Years 6 and 7.

    If for some reason the banks were not comfortable providing the

    bridge financing needed to cover the cash flow shortfalls during Years 6

    and 7, they might instead require the firm to build up a debt service

  • reserve account during the first five years of the loan’s life from the cash

    that is over and above the requirements for servicing the debt.

    Alternatively, the banker may require the debt service reserve account to

    be immediately financed out of the proceeds of the loan and equity

    financing. This debt service reserve account would be invested in

    short-term liquid assets that could be drawn down to meet the financing

    requirements during Years 6 and 7.

    Table 4.7: Is Bridge Financing an Option? (dollars)

    Year 0 1 2 3 4 5

    Net cash

    flow −2,000,0

    00 320,00

    0 320,0

    00 360,0

    00 440,0

    00 380,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 0 199,25

    2 199,2

    52 199,2

    52 199,2

    52 199,2

    52

    ADSCR 1.61 1.61 1.81 2.21 1.91

    NPV of NCF 2,052,134

    1,991,

    954 1,922,

    747 1,797,

    159 1,560,

    733

    PV of debt

    repayments 1,150,

    000 1,093,

    360 1,028,

    224 953,3

    18 867,1

    76

    LLCR

    1.78 1.82 1.87 1.89 1.80

    Year 6 7 8 9 10

    Net cash

    flow 100,000 200,00

    0 480,0

    00 540,0

    00 640,0

    00

    Debt

    repayment 199,252 199,25

    2 199,2

    52 199,2

    52 199,2

    52

    ADSCR 0.50 1.00 2.41 2.71 3.21

    NPV of NCF 1,357,843

    1,446,

    519 1,433,

    497 1,096,

    522 640,0

    00

    PV of debt

    repayments 768,112 654,18

    9 523,1

    78 372,5

    15 199,2

    52

    LLCR 1.77 2.21 2.74 2.94 3.21

    It is sometimes the case that the financial institutions servicing the

  • loan will stipulate that if the ADSCR ever falls below a certain

    benchmark, say 1.8, it must stop paying dividends to the owners of the

    equity until a sinking fund of a specified size is created or a certain

    amount of the loan is repaid. In this way, the lenders are protected from

    what might become an even more precarious situation in the future.

    The actual benchmark requirements for the ADSCRs and the overall

    project’s LLCRs will depend on the business and financial risk

    associated with a particular sector and the specific enterprise. The

    sensitivity of the net cash flows from the project to movements in the

    economy’s business cycle will be an important determinant of what the

    adequate ratios for any specific project are. The existence of creditable

    government guarantees for the repayment of interest and principal will

    also serve to lower the benchmark values of the debt service coverage

    ratios for a project.

    4.3.6 Cost–Effectiveness Analysis2

    This is an appraisal technique primarily used in social projects and

    programs, and sometimes in infrastructure projects, where it is difficult

    to quantify benefits in monetary terms. For instance, when there are two

    or more alternative approaches to improving the nutrition levels among

    children in a community, the selection criterion could simply be to select

    the alternative that has the least cost. A similar case occurs when there

    are two alternatives for providing irrigation facilities to farmers in a

    certain region, for example, a canal system and a tube well network, and

    they cover the same area and provide the same volume of water in a year.

    The benefits in such cases are treated as identical, and, therefore, it is not

    necessary to quantify them or to place a monetary value on them if the

    problem is to select the project that will produce these benefits at the

    lowest possible cost.

    This approach is also useful for choosing between different

    technologies for providing the same services, for example, when there

    are two alternative technologies related to the supply of drinking water or

    the generation of electricity. When the same quantity and quality of

    water per annum can be delivered using pipes of different diameters, and

    2 See Curry and Weiss (1993) and Gittinger (1994) for discussion

    of cost–effectiveness analysis.

  • the smaller pipe involves greater pumping costs but has lower capital

    costs, a cost–effectiveness analysis may be used for making a choice. A

    similar situation occurs when there are two alternative ways of

    generating electricity, one with a lower investment cost but higher

    operating expenses (single-cycle versus combined-cycle technologies).

    Again, if the decision has been made to provide this service, there is no

    need to calculate the benefit in monetary terms. The cost–effectiveness

    analysis may be used in all such cases for selecting the best project or the

    best technology.

    If the amount of benefits of the alternative projects differ, and if the

    benefits cannot be measured in monetary terms but can be physically

    quantified, the pure cost–effectiveness of a project can be calculated by

    dividing the present value of total costs of the project by the present

    value of a non-monetary quantitative measure of the benefits it generates.

    The ratio is an estimate of the amount of costs incurred to achieve a unit

    of the benefit from a program. For example, in a health project, what are

    the costs, expressed in dollars, incurred in saving a person’s life?

    Presumably, there are alternative ways to save a life; what are their costs?

    The analysis does not evaluate benefits in monetized terms, but is an

    attempt to find the least-cost option to achieve a desired quantitative

    outcome.

    In applying the cost–effectiveness approach, the present values of

    costs need to be computed. While using the cost–effectiveness analysis,

    it is important to include all external costs – such as waiting time, coping

    costs, enforcement costs, regulatory costs, and compliance costs in the

    case of health care, offset by the salvage values at the end of the projects

    – and to choose the discount rate carefully. The preferred outcome will

    often change with a change in the discount rate.

    Pure cost–effectiveness analysis can be extended to more

    sophisticated and meaningful ways of measuring benefits. A quantitative

    measure can be made by constructing a composite index of two or more

    benefit categories, including quantity and quality. For example, the cost

    utility analysis in health care uses quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) as

    a measure of benefits. The QALY measure integrates two dimensions of

    health improvement, namely the additional years of life (reduction in

    mortality) and the quality of life (morbidity) during these years. On the

    basis of the costs incurred, expressed in dollars, the decision-maker

    would still choose the option with the least cost per QALY achieved by

    the project or the program (see, e.g., Garber and Phelps, 1997).

  • Cost–utility analysis attempts to include some of the benefits excluded

    from a pure cost–effective analysis, hence moving it a step closer to a

    full cost–benefit analysis.

    One should be aware of some of the shortcomings inherent in the

    cost–effectiveness approach. It is a poor measure of consumers’

    willingness to pay in principle because there is no monetary value placed

    on the benefits. Furthermore, in the calculation of the cost–effectiveness

    ratio, the numerator does not take into account the scale of alternative

    options. Nevertheless, this ratio is still a very useful criterion for

    selection of alternative options when the benefits cannot be monetized.

    4.4 Conclusion

    This chapter first described the concept of time value of money and the

    proper use of the discount rate in project appraisal. It reviewed six

    important criteria used by various analysts for judging the expected

    performance of investment projects. While each one may have its own

    merit in specific circumstances, the NPV criterion is the most reliable

    and satisfactory one for both the financial and the economic evaluation.

    For bankers and other financial lending institutions, measurements of

    the ADSCR and LLCR are the key factors that enable them to determine

    whether a project can generate enough cash to meet the debt service

    obligations before financing of the project should be approved.

    The chapter has also discussed the situation in which the benefits of

    a project or a program cannot be expressed in monetary values in a

    meaningful way; in such a case, a cost–effectiveness analysis should be

    carried out to assist in making welfare-improving investment decisions.

    References Boardman, A.E., D.H. Greenberg, A.R. Vining, and D.L. Weimer. 2001.

    Cost-Benefit Analysis: Concepts and Practice, 2nd

    edition. Englewood Cliffs,

    NJ: Prentice Hall.

    Curry, S. and J. Weiss. 1993. Project Analysis in Developing Countries. New

    York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Garber, A.M. and C.E. Phelps. 1997. “Economic Foundations of

    Cost-Effectiveness Analysis”, Journal of Health Economics 16(1), 1–31.

  • Gitman, L.J. 2009. Principles of Managerial Finance, 12th

    edition. Boston:

    Pearson Prentice Hall.

    Gittinger J.P. 1994. Economic Analysis of Agricultural Projects. Baltimore, MD:

    Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Gramlich, E.M. 1997. A Guide to Cost-Benefit Analysis. Englewood Cliffs, NJ:

    Prentice Hall.

    Ley, E. 2007. “Cost-Benefit Analysis: Evaluation Criteria (Or: ‘Stay away from

    the IRR’)”, paper prepared for the World Bank (November).

    Pohl, G. and M. Dubravko. 1992. “Project Evaluation and Uncertainty in

    Practice: A Statistical Analysis of Rate-of-Return Divergences of 1,015

    World Bank Projects”, The World Bank Economic Review 6(2), 255–277. Walker, C. and A.J. Smith. 1996. Privatized Infrastructure: The Build Operate

    Transfer Approach. London: Thomas Telford Publications.

    Yescombe, E.R. 2002. Principles of Project Finance. London: Academic Press.