ciepr 2013 revisiting sovereign bankruptcy report

57
REVISITING SOVEREIGN BANKRUPTCY Committee on International Economic Policy and Reform Markus Brunnermeier Barry Eichengreen Mohamed El-Erian José De Gregorio Takatoshi Ito Philip Lane Eswar Prasad Hélène Rey Dani Rodrik Hyun Song Shin Andrés Velasco Yongding Yu OCTOBER 2013 Lee C. Buchheit Anna Gelpern Mitu Gulati Ugo Panizza Beatrice Weder di Mauro Jeromin Zettelmeyer LEAD AUTHORS OTHER COMMITTEE MEMBERS

Upload: bc-moon

Post on 19-Aug-2015

8 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

DESCRIPTION

CIEPR 2013 Revisiting Sovereign Bankruptcy Report

TRANSCRIPT

REVISITING SOVEREIGN BANKRUPTCYCommittee on International Economic Policy and Reform Markus BrunnermeierBarry EichengreenMohamed El-ErianJos De GregorioTakatoshi Ito Philip Lane Eswar PrasadHlne ReyDani RodrikHyun Song ShinAndrs VelascoYongding YuO C T O B E R2 0 13Lee C. BuchheitAnna GelpernMitu GulatiUgo PanizzaBeatrice Weder di MauroJeromin ZettelmeyerLEAD AUTHORSOTHER COMMITTEE MEMBERSREVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY IITABLE OF CONTENTSPreface and Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iiiExecutive Summary. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .ivChapter 1: Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1Chapter 2: Pathologies in Sovereign Debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5Chapter 3: Argentina and the Rebirth of the Holdout Problem. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15Chapter 4: Euro Area Issues. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21Chapter 5: Policy Proposals for the Euro Area and Beyond . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29References. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY IIIThe Committee on International Economic Pol-icy and Reform is a non-partisan, independent group of experts, comprised of academics and formergovernmentandcentralbankofcials.Its objective is to analyze global monetary and fnan-cialproblems,ofersystematicanalysis,andad-vancereformideas.TeCommitteeattemptsto identify areas in which the global economic archi-tectureshouldbestrengthenedandrecommend solutionsintendedtoreconcilenationalinterests with broader global interests. Trough its reports, it seeks to foster public understanding of key issues inglobaleconomicmanagementandeconomic governance. Each Committee report will focus on a specifc topic which will emphasize longer-term rather than conjunctural policy issues.TeCommitteeisgratefultotheAlfredP.Sloan Foundation*forprovidingfnancialsupportand totheBrookingsInstitutionforhostingthecom-mittee and facilitating its work. ContributionsbyElizabethBroomfeldandcom-mentsandsuggestionsbyRichardPortesare gratefullyacknowledged.QuynhTonnuprovided excellent administrative support.Committee MembersMarkus Brunnermeier, Princeton UniversityLee C. Buchheit, Cleary Gottlieb Steen & Hamilton LLPBarry Eichengreen, University of California, BerkeleyMohamed El-Erian, PIMCOAnna Gelpern, Georgetown UniversityMitu Gulati, Duke UniversityJos De Gregorio, University of ChileTakatoshi Ito, University of TokyoPhilip Lane, Trinity College DublinUgo Panizza, Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies, GenevaEswar Prasad, Cornell University and Brookings InstitutionHlne Rey, London Business School Dani Rodrik, Harvard UniversityHyun Song Shin, Princeton UniversityAndrs Velasco, Columbia UniversityBeatrice Weder di Mauro, University of MainzYongding Yu, Chinese Academy of Social SciencesJeromin Zettelmeyer, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development**** Due to his offcial position at EBRD, Mr. Zettelmeyer is an honorary advisor to the Committee.PREFACE AND ACKNOWLEDGMENTS*Brookings recognizes that the value it provides to any donor isinitsabsolutecommitmenttoquality,independenceand impact.Activitiessponsoredbyitsdonorsdonotrefectthis commitment and the research agenda, content, nor outcomes are infuenced by any donation.REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY IVSovereigndebtcrisesoccurregularlyandofen violently.TerecentdebtcrisisinGreeceal-most led to the collapse of the Euro. Yet there isnolegallyandpoliticallyrecognizedprocedure for restructuring the debt of bankrupt sovereigns. Procedures of this type have been periodically de-batedmostrecently,aboutadecadeago,when IMFmanagementproposedaglobalsovereign debt restructuring mechanism (SDRM). Tey have so far been rejected. Countries have been reluctant togiveuppowertosupranationalrulesorinsti-tutions. Creditors and debtors have felt that there weresufcientinstrumentsforaddressingdebt crisesathoc.Importantly,therewerealsofears that making debt easier to restructure would raise thecostsandreducetheamountsofsovereign borrowing in many countries. Tis was perceived to be against the interests of both the providers of both creditors and major borrowers.TisyearsCIEPRreportarguesthatboththe natureandourunderstandingofsovereigndebt problems have changed in ways that create a much stronger case for an orderly sovereign bankruptcy regime today than ten years ago.Pre-crisispolicymistakesandinpar-ticular,thetendencyofdomesticpolicy-makers to overborrow or pay too little at-tentiontoprivatedebtaccumulationthat might turn publicare now recognized to beamuchmoresevereproblemforbor-rowing countries than the costs or limited availabilityofprivatefnancing.Farfrom beingaproblem,proposalsthatwould limittheabilitytoborrowforcountries with poor policies are a good thing.Recent court rulingsparticularly a recent U.S.rulingthatgivesholdoutcreditors that decline a restructuring ofer the right to interfere with payments to the creditors that accept such an ofer. Tis will compli-cate eforts to resolve future debt crises on an ad hoc basis.Sovereigndebtcrisesarenolongerjusta probleminemergingmarkets,butacore concerninadvancedcountriesaswell particularlyintheEuroarea.IftheEuro istosurvive,thiswillrequirebothbetter waystoresolvedebtcrisesandstronger, market-based incentives that prevent debt problems from occurring in the frst place.Toaddresstheseproblems,thereportpresents policyproposalsattwolevels:fortheEuroarea, and globally. TeEuroareadifersfromotherintegratedre-gionsbothinthatitsmembershavefewerin-strumentstodealwithdebtcrisestheycannot devalueorinfateandbecauseacrisisinone membercanhavecatastrophicconsequencesfor others(bythreateningthecommoncurrency). Tisrequiresbothamechanismfortheorderly resolution of debt crises and stronger incentives to prevent them. Te current fnancial architecture in the Euro area is inadequate in this respect, because its main pillarthe European Stability Mechanism (ESM)isnotsetuptodealwithunsustainable debt.Ifitisusedevenwhentherearesignifcant concernsabouttheabilityofborrowerstorepay their debts, it will become source of transfers, rath-er than just crisis lending. Tese problems could be addressed via an amend-ment of the ESM treaty that encourages and legiti-mizesboth legally and politicallydebt restruc-turing in unsustainable debt cases. EXECUTIVE SUMMARYREVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY VFirst,assetsandrevenuesofcountries undertakingadebtrestructuringwould bedeemedimmunefromlegalactionby holdouts if a restructuring is approved by the ESM. Second, the treaty would require a debt re-structuring as a condition for ESM lending when national debts exceed a pre-set level. Tis should be higher than the Maastricht limit of 60 percent of GDP, but not so high as to render the constraint meaningless. In the Euro area, this may mean a level about 1 times the Maastricht limit. Te pres-ence of such a debt threshold would help diferentiateborrowingcostsinnormal timesbasedonthestrengthofeconomic policies.Atthesametime,itwouldpro-tect ESM resources and Euro area taxpay-ers,andpreventextremeadjustmentsof publicfnancesattheexpenseofcitizens whousuallyhavelittlecontroloverpoli-cy mistakes leading to excessive sovereign debt.Importantly,Euroareacountriesmustbegivena chance to deal with legacy debt before this regime isintroduced.Forcountriessignifcantlyabove thefutureupperdebtthreshold,thiswillrequire a judgment of whether debt can be reduced below thelimitwithinareasonabletimeframe.Where theanswerisno,theEuroareaneedstomakea choice between an upfront restructuring backed bytheESMandextrasupport,forexample,in the form of providing a joint and several guarantee onnewdebtissuanceaslongascountriesadhere to an agreed fscal consolidation path.At the global level, the relatively small size of the IMF,itsdefactopriorityanditstrackrecordin gettingrepaidmakeitlesslikelythatcrisislend-ingwillturnintotransfers.However,experience showsthatincentivesarestackedagainstthe timelyrecognitionandrestructuringofunsus-tainabledebts.Recentcourtrulingsencouraging holdouts,discouragingcreditorparticipationin debtexchangeofers,andbringingintoquestion theIMFsprioritystatus,willmakethisproblem worse. To address this without allowing sovereigns to frivolously repudiate their debts, two alternative mechanisms are proposed. Acoordinatedintroductionofastrong form of collective action clauses in sov-ereignbondcontract,namely,provisions that allow for the restructuring of bonded debt with the agreement of a supermajori-ty of creditors across all bonds. TecreationofaSovereignDebtAdjust-mentFacilitybytheInternationalMon-etaryFund,whichwouldcombineIMF lendingwithdebtrestructuring.Aset ofclearlydefnedexantecriteria,analo-gous to those used in the HIPC initiative, would need to be developed to steer high debtcountriestowardsthisfacility.An amendment of the IMF articles would en-sure that the assets of countries using this facilitywouldbeshieldedfromholdouts if a supermajority of creditors agrees to a restructuring. Te main diference between the two proposals is thatthesecondwoulddomoretocorrectbiases thatdelaynecessarydebtrestructuring.Further-more,whilebothwoulddealwiththeholdout problem in the long run, the IMF-based proposal would have immediate efects, while better collec-tiveactionclauseswouldbecomeefectiveonly gradually, as existing debt is replaced by newly is-sued debt.Teworldiscurrentlylessequippedtohandle problemsofunsustainabledebtthanatanytime sincethe1930s.Atthesametime,theextentof these problems has grown. Reform proposals that could address them have become more mature and more targeted, and arguments that led to the rejec-tion of analogous proposals 10 years ago no longer apply. It is time for policy makers to tackle the cen-tral problems head on. REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 1Sovereigndebtcrisestendtotriggercallsfor sovereignbankruptcy.Inthepostwarera,a frstroundofsuchcallscoincidedwiththe greatLatinAmericandebtcrisisofthe1980s.A secondroundaccompaniedthepost-Bradydebt crises, beginning with the 1995 Mexican crisis and particularlyRussias1998default,andleadingto theInternationalMonetaryFunds2001proposal foraSovereignDebtRestructuringMechanism (SDRM), which was intensely debated and fnally rejected by IMF shareholders in April 2003.1 Since 2010,callsforsomeformofinternationalsover-eignbankruptcyregimehavereturned.2Tese havebeenmotivatedpartlybyeventsinEurope, but also by difculties in restructuring stubbornly high debt levels in other parts of the world, such as the Caribbean Sea Basin, and by ongoing litigation that could make such restructurings even harder.Tis report revisits the case for a sovereign bank-ruptcy regime, understood as a mix of national and international institutions that would, in some con-ditions, sanction a comprehensive modifcation of sovereign debt contracts, and extend legal protec-tionstothesovereignsandcreditorsinvolved.It formulatestheeconomictrade-ofsinvolvedwith creatingsucharegime,explainswhyandunder what conditions the regime could improve welfare, and presents options for implementing the regime. Itsmainconclusionisthattheintellectualcase forandfeasibilityofasovereigndebtworkout mechanism based on some combination of nation-al statutes and international treaty is much stron-ger now than it was 10 or 20 years ago. Tis is es-pecially true for the euro zone, where the case for such a regime is particularly strong and its imple-mentationasacomplementtotheexistingEuro-pean Stability Mechanism would be comparatively straightforward.As background for the logical structure of this re-port, it is useful to briefy recall the SDRM discus-sions of the early 2000s. Te main focus of this de-batewastheperceivedtrade-ofbetweenex-post andex-anteefciency.SDRMproponentsbased their proposal on ex-post inefciency, exemplifed bythesuccessesornear-missesofholdoutcred-itorsincasesagainstBrazilandPeru.3Teargu-mentwasthatifcreditorscouldexpectholdout strategiestopayof,freeridingwouldbecome 1 For a survey, see Rogof and Zettelmeyer (2002).2See, e.g., Gianviti et al (2010), Weder di Mauro and Zettelmeyer (2010); EEAG (2011); Bogdandy and Goldmann (2012); and Miller and Tomas (2013).3 Panizza, Sturzenegger, and Zettelmeyer (2009); Schumacher, Trebesch, and Enderlein (2012).CHAPTER 1: IntroductionREVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 2overwhelming, rendering orderly debt restructur-ings unfeasible. Conversely, SDRM critics focused on ex-ante efciency. Tey argued that since gov-ernmentscouldnotbeeasilyforcedtopaytheir debts,sovereigndebtwasfeasibleandafordable onlybecausesovereigndebtcriseswerecostly.A sovereigndebtrestructuringmechanismwhose express purpose was to lower the cost of debt crises might do more harm than good by lowering incen-tives to repay and sharply raising the cost of debt. Inprinciple,therewasawayofbalancingthe trade-ofbetweenex-postcostsandex-antein-centives: an SDRM involving a double triggernamely, the debtor country would be able to make arequestforassistance(analogoustoflingfor bankruptcyprotection),andabankruptcycourt-likeinstitutioncouldrejectfrivolousrequests. However,fromtheperspectiveofSDRMcritics, thissolutionhadtwoweaknesses.First,private creditorsmightnottrustthebankruptcycourtparticularly if it were the IMF, which was viewed as bothsusceptibletopoliticalpressureandsubject toconfictsofintereststhroughitsownroleasa large creditor. Second, perverse incentives created bylowercrisiscostsmightextendbeyondincen-tivestorepudiateencompassingabroadrange ofprecrisispoliciesthatinfuencedthechances ofgettingintodebt-servicingdifculties.Hence, tocreategoodincentivesfordebtorcountries,an international bankruptcy court would need to not only distinguish between an ability to pay and a willingnesstopaycrisisbutalsojudgewheth-eranabilitytopaycrisisweremainlythefault ofthecountryortheresultofbadluck.Tiswas viewedasatallorderforanyinstitutionpartic-ularlythosethatmightnotbefullyindependent, and that might be sympathetic to a countrys plight regardless of its causes.Te SDRM was rejected in 2003, in part because the UnitedStatesandlargeemergingmarketborrow-ers could not be convinced that its ex-post benefts outweigheditsex-anterisks,andpartlybecause theex-postcostsofthestatusquodidnotseem intractableatthetime;mostdebtcrisessincethe mid-1990s had been resolved fairly quickly without statutory bankruptcy, and did not lead to litigation by holdouts. Tose who worried about holdouts, in lieu of a treaty change, got market-wide contract re-form, whereby collective action clauses were intro-ducedinmostNewYorklawbondsissuedbegin-ning 2003. Tis was rationalized as a small step to-ward a more ex-post efcient resolution, which was unlikely to upset markets ex ante (and it did not).Since2003therehavebeenthreedevelopments thataddto,andmighthavechangedthebalance of,thesetofargumentsoutlinedabove.First,re-searchonsovereigndebtproblemshasevolved totakeabroaderandsomewhatdiferentview oftheex-anteproblem.Asanempiricalmatter, thetraditionalenforcementproblemseemstobe overshadowed by moral hazard problems of a dif-ferentkind.Debtorcountrieshavecontrolover keyfactorstheirdebtlevels,debtstructureand prospectsforeconomicgrowththatdetermine their ability to pay. Additional moral hazard prob-lems may be created at the expense of third parties. Tese problems can result in overborrowing, along with delays in seeking unavoidable sovereign debt restructurings. Te consensus seems to have shif-ed away from the fear that countries might restruc-tureopportunisticallytothefearthattheymight restructuretoolate,andthattheserestructurings might not be deep enough. Tis has fundamental implications for the debate on sovereign bankrupt-cy: If the main problem in sovereign debt is not re-pudiating debtors and overly tight borrowing con-straints, but rather overborrowing at the front end andprocrastinationatthebackend,thentheold trade-ofbetweenex-anteandex-postefciency no longer holds, at least within some range. Low-ering the costs of debt crises ex post might beneft efciency ex ante. Second,theholdoutproblemhasexperienceda rejuvenation.Oneoftheargumentsagainstthe SDRM was that it was a heavy-handed way of ad-dressing a problemcoordination failures in debt restructuringthatcouldbesolvedeasilyusing procedures and legal techniques that debtors could REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 3invoke unilaterally. For example, take-it-or-leave-it debt exchange ofers, backed by minimum partici-pation thresholds and exit consents, allowed debt-ors to strip holdouts of enforcement weapons with theagreementofasimplemajorityofbondhold-ers.However,recentcourtrulingsagainstArgen-tina in New York give creditors tools to overcome such tactics. At the same time, bond contracts have developed to require supermajorities for the most powerful exit amendments, which are no longer as potentasolutionastheywereintherestructur-ings of the early 2000s. Further, investors pursuing holdout strategies have become increasingly efec-tive, as a function of both their fnancing and their legal sophistication. As a result, successful debt re-structurings have become harder to achieve, even if they are in the interests of both the debtor and a large majority of creditors.Tird, the important special case of the euro area now looms large. Tis has characteristics that both aggravatetheex-anteproblemandincreasethe plausibilityofastatutorysolution.Tecloseeco-nomic,fnancialandpoliticallinkagesinsidethe eurozoneincluding,perhapsmostimportant, thethreatthatasovereigndefaultmighttrigger acostlyexitfromthesinglecurrencymakethe members of the common currency area much less willingtoriskafaileddebtrestructuringintheir midst. On top of this, the lack of monetary and ex-change rate instruments at the country level makes itharderforthesememberstoaddressgrowth andcompetitivenessproblemswithoutexternal support. For both reasons, the euro zone sufers a moreseveremoralhazardproblemthan,say,the potential moral hazard caused by IMF crisis lend-ing.Tismaycontributetomispricing,overbor-rowinganddelaysinneededsovereigndebtre-structuring,asoccurredinGreece.Atthesame time, because so many areas of economic policy in the European Union, and particularly in the euro area,arealreadygovernedbycommonstatute,a statutoryapproachtowardsovereignbankruptcy maystandabetterchanceintheeuroareathan elsewhere.Te remainder of this report follows the structure of these three arguments. We begin with a survey ofshifingviewsonthepathologiesinsovereign debt.Wenextdiscusstheimpactofrecentliti-gationandchangesinbondcontractsonadhoc debtrestructurings.Tisisfollowedbyachapter thatargueswhyamoresystematicapproachto sovereigndebtrestructuringmightbeparticular-ly needed in the euro area. Te fnal chapter pres-ents a number of proposals that could address the problem.Teseincludeaproposaltomodifythe 2012treatyestablishingtheEuropeanStability Mechanism (ESM) to require debt restructuring as aconditionofESMassistanceinpredefnedcir-cumstances,andtoimmunizetheassetsofthose countriesthathaveundergoneESM-sanctioned restructurings from attachments by holdout cred-itors. At the broader international level, the report presents and discusses three alternative optionstwothatwouldinvolvecontractualorstatutory changes in major borrowing jurisdictions, and one involving an IMF-based restructuring mechanism. Telatterenvisagesendorsementofasovereign debtorsrestructuringproposalbybothamajori-ty of creditors and the IMF. Following this double endorsement,thedebtorsassetswouldbecome immunefromattachmentinthejurisdictionsof IMF members.Te report does not discuss two important topics. First, because it focuses on sovereign debt, it does not deal with how to unwind or prevent excessive debts incurred in the private sector.4 However, the linksbetweentheseproblemsandsovereigndebt problemsarebriefydiscussedinthecontextof theeuroarea(chapter3).Teargumentisthat whiletheproposalsmadeinthisreportwillnot bythemselvessolveprivatesectordebtproblems, 4Some of these problems, particularly as pertaining to private debt accumulation fueled by international capital fows, were discussed in last years CIEPR report, Banks and Cross-Border Capital Flows: Policy Challenges and Regulatory Responses (CIEPR 2012).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 4theymayamelioratethem;marketswillbemore likelytopricesovereigndefaultrisksregardless of whether these originate from sovereign debt or socialized private debt. Tis should give incentives tosovereignstoworrymoreaboutcreditbooms that could give rise to quasi-fscal liabilities. While theproposalsinthisreportandplanstocreatea euro areabased Banking Union address diferent problems, these problems are linked, and the pro-posals should be viewed as complementary.Second, we do not discuss a class of ideas that have broadlysimilaraimsastheproposalsinthisre-port, namely, how to prevent sovereign debt crises throughdebtcontractswithequity-likefeatures, for example, by indexing repayments to gross do-mesticproduct(GDP)orcommodityprices.5Al-thoughwearesympathetictotheseideas,forthe purposes of the present report we take it as a given that in spite of periodic calls, bonds with these fea-tures do not play an important role in sovereign f-nance, and are unlikely to play such a role anytime soonin part for reasons analyzed in chapter 2. Te focus of this report is on mechanisms that are plausibletodaymechanismsthatwouldallow fortheswifrenegotiationofdebtundercertain conditions, in ways that not only make crises less costlybutalsoencouragesovereigndebtorsand creditors to act more responsibly in normal times.5 See, e.g., Mody (2013).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 5A key feature distinguishing sovereign debt con-tractsfromdebtowedbyprivatepartiesis weakercontractenforcement.Inasovereign default, the remedies at the disposal of creditorsparticularlyprivatecreditorsarelimitedbythe fact that most sovereign assets are located within a sovereigns jurisdiction and cannot be seized, even when creditors have won in court (see chapter 3). In spite of this fact, many sovereigns have histori-cally been able to borrow large amounts of funds.6 Howisthispossible?Whywouldprivatedebtors entrustsovereignswiththeirmoneywhenthey cannot enforce repayment?Inspiredbythispuzzle,themoderneconomic literatureonsovereigndebt,whichdevelopedin the 1980s, initially focused on understanding why sovereigndebtevergotrepaid.Itconcludedthat borrowers repay because defaults are economical-ly costly for the debtor country.7 Countries will be able to borrow up to the point in which the temp-tationtodefaultisbalancedbyitscosts.Instan-dard theories of sovereign debt, this level of debt is generally below the level at which countries would like to be able to borrow. Itfollowsthatattemptstoreducethecostsofde-fault could also reduce welfare because they would make sovereign debt more expensive and lower the maximum level of debt that a sovereign can accu-mulate.Conversely,attemptstoimproveenforce-mentcouldimprovewelfareeveniftheymake debt crises more painful and protracted. Tis logic hasledsomeresearcherstowarnthatproposals aimed at reducing the ex-post costs of debt crises could backfre.8 It is thus important to also exam-ine policy proposals in the area of crisis resolution from an ex-ante perspectivetaking into account their likely impact on the sovereign debt market in normaltimesratherthansimplyfromtheper-spective of whether they will reduce the costs of a crisisoncethishashappened.Tepresentreport takes this perspective throughout. Atthesametime,itisimportanttorealizethat inspiteoftheenforcementprobleminsovereign CHAPTER 2: Pathologies in Sovereign Debt6According to the IMFs World Economic Outlook (April 2013 edition), general government debt in 2012 stood at about 35 percent of GDP on average in emerging markets and developing countries and over 100 percent of GDP in advanced countries.7Te contributions include Eaton and Gersovitz (1981); Sachs and Cohen (1982); and Bulow and Rogof (1989a, 1989b). For surveys of the literature, see Panizza, Sturzenegger, and Zettelmeyer (2009); Wright (2011); Das, Papaioannou, and Trebesch (2012); Tomz and Wright (2013); and Aguiar and Amador (forthcoming). For evidence on the costs of default, see Mitchener and Weidenmier (2005); Tomz (2007); Borensztein and Panizza (2009); Sandleris (2012); Tomz and Wright (2013); and Cruces and Trebesch (2013).8 See Dooley (2000) and Shleifer (2003).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 6debt,itislogicallypossibletomakecrisisresolu-tion more efcient without making debtors coun-tries worse of in normal times. Tere are two rea-sons for this:Even if there is a trade-of between ex-ante incentives to repay and the ex-post costs of default, this does not mean that this trade-ofcannotbeameliorated.Inprinciple,it could be possible to improve contracts or institutions governing sovereign debt in a waythatreducescrisiscostswhilemain-taining incentives to repay.Furthermore,therecouldbeimportant casesinwhichthereisnotrade-ofbe-tweenreducingtheex-postcostsofcri-ses and improving ex-ante incentives. For example,thecostsofdefaultcouldbea resultofhistoricinstitutionsorcontracts thatarenotoptimalinthesenseofpro-vidingjusttherightamountofdeterrent to stop creditors from repudiating. Or the situationmightbecomplicatedbyincen-tive problems that go beyond the enforce-ment problem. Distorted incentives could drive a wedge between the maximum that asovereigncanborrowtheborrowing limitand what it should be borrowingthe socially optimal amount of borrowing. Ifthisweretobethecase,reducingthe costsofcrisesmightnothaveanysocial costexante.Infact,forcountriesthat overborrowinthesensethatactual borrowingisabovethesociallyoptimal amounttighterborrowingconstraints would improve welfare.Tefrstpointhasbeenunderstoodsinceatleast thelate1980s.9Supposethatitwerepossiblyto writecontracts(implicitlyorexplicitly)orcreate institutions so as to make sovereign defaults costly ifandonlyiftheycannotbeexcusedbyshocks tofundamentalsoutsidethecontrolofdebtor countries.Tatis,repudiationswouldbesevere-lypunished(andasaresult,wouldneveroccur), whileshockstodebtservicecapacitywouldlead to a corresponding adjustment in the debt burden withoutanypunishment.Insuchaworld,costly debt crises would never arise, in spite of the pres-ence of an enforcement problem. Intherealworld,however,debtcrisescannotbe neatlyseparatedintoexcusabledefaultsdriven byfundamentalsandinexcusablerepudiations. Yettheremaybeinstitutionalorcontractualim-provementsforexample,debtcontractsthatin-dexrepaymentstovariablessuchasinternational commoditypricesthatreducethefrequencyor costs of debt crises. Te main insight is that costly crises are never just a refection of the enforcement problem, but also refect a combination of the en-forcementproblemwithotherproblems,suchas imperfectinformationorincompletecontracts. As such, it may be possible to reduce the costs of crisesthroughinstitutionsorcontractsthatlegit-imizedebtrestructuringsincertaincircumstanc-es(whichwouldobviouslyexcludestrategicde-faults). Tis is the favor of some of the proposals made in the fnal chapter of this report.Te second point is less well understood, is poten-tiallymorecontroversial,andassuchisthemain focusofthischapter.Itrelatestotheexistenceof pathologies in sovereign debt that go beyond weak contractenforcement,andthepossibilitythat these additional pathologies may be more relevant as drivers of actual borrowing behavior. Tese pa-thologies include political failures, the moral haz-ardassociatedwiththepresenceofinternational bailouts, and a lack of seniority in sovereign debt contracts.Together,theycouldbeasourceof overborrowingandsuboptimalpublicdebtman-agement.Politicalconsiderationsandinefcient contractdesignmayalsoleadtoasituationin which,ratherthandefaultingtoomuchandtoo early,countriesdefaulttoolateandtoolittle.In this case, reducing the costs of default will be good not only ex postonce a crisis has occurredbut 9 See Grossman and Van Huyck (1988).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 7alsoexante,byreducinginefcientborrowingin normal times and making debt crises less likely.OverborrowingInstandardeconomictheoriesofsovereigndebt, sovereignsarecredit-constrainedbecausetheir ability to borrow is capped by a level that depends ondefaultcosts.Tetypicalsituationinthese models is underborrowing, in the sense that debt levels are suboptimally low from a social perspec-tive. Specifcally, debt levels are lower than what a countrywouldwanttoborrowinaworldwhere debt contracts could be enforced in the same way as, for example, corporate debt contracts.Tis view of sovereign debt is difcult to reconcile with actual borrowing behavior, both across coun-triesandovertime.Figure1shows2012general governmentdebtlevelsforthreegroupsofcoun-triesthatareroughlysimilar,withineachgroup, with respect to per capita income levels and (in the case of the two emerging market groups) geogra-phy and trading partners. Of the countries shown, onlytwo(GreeceandJamaica)donotcurrently haveaccesstointernationalcapitalmarkets.Of course, the fact that a country has access to capital marketsdoesnotmeanthatitsdebtmaynotbe primarily determined by its debt limit; these coun-tries may want to stay somewhat below their max-imum borrowing in order to have room to respond toeconomicshocks.Tequestioniswhetherthe data pattern observed in fgure 1 is consistent with this notion.Figure1showsthatadvancedeconomiestend tohavehigherdebtlevelsthanemergingmarket countries.10Tisisconsistentwiththeviewthat 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160GreeceItalyBelgiumFranceCanadaNetherlandsSwitzerlandSwedenAustraliaHungaryPolandSlovak RepublicUkraineRomaniaTurkeyBulgariaRussiaEstoniaJamaicaBrazilVenezuelaUruguayArgentinaMexicoColombiaPeruChileFIGURE 1. GENERAL GOVERNMENT DEBT IN THREE GROUPS OF COUNTRIES, 2012 (PERCENTAGE OF GDP)10Tis is true not only for the average of advanced countries and emerging markets selected in fgure 1 for illustrative purposes but also more generally.Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook database, April 2013.REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 8debt levels are determined by repayment prospects; advanced countries may be able to borrow in larg-er amounts because they are institutionally better able to commit to debt repayment, or because they are less likely to sufer shocks that would put their debtlevelsoverthelimitwheredebtrestructur-ingisoptimal.However,withinthethreegroups, variationsindebtlevels(evenignoringGreece andJamaica,thetwooutliers)aresolargeasto be irreconcilable with the view that most of these countriesareborrowingatorclosetotheirdebt limits.Itisimplausiblethatcountriesdiferences in commitment credibility, the location of their as-sets, their degree of international integration, their dependence on foreign capital or other factors that coulddrivediferencesintheirborrowinglimits couldalsoexplain,forexample,whyCanadian debt is at 86 percent of GDP while Australian debt isonly27percent,whyItalysdebtis127percent ofGDPwhilethatoftheNetherlandsisonly71 percent,whydebtisonly19percentofGDPin Perubut45percentinArgentinaand68percent in Brazil, or why debt stands at 19 percent of GDP in Bulgaria but 37 percent in Romania. Similarargumentsapplyovertime.Belgiumin-creaseditsdebtlevelfromabout75percentof GDPin1980toalmost140percentin1993and subsequentlyreduceditagainto87percentin 2007.Overthesameperiod,theFrenchgovern-mentsdebtmorethanquadrupledasashareof GDP, rising more or less continuously, from about 20percenttoabout90percent.Peruhalvedits governmentdebtbetween2000and2012.Sodid Sweden.Inallthesecases,itisdifculttoimag-inethattheseswingsweretheresultoftighteror laxersovereignborrowingconstraints.Itismore plausiblethatmostofthesecountrieswerefar fromtheirborrowinglimitsduringmostoftheir histories, and that debt levels changed as a result of policy choices and economic shocks, which afect-ed growth and determined the size of government defcits and debts. If one accepts the fact that for most advanced and emerging market economies debt levels are deter-minednotbythemaximumamountthatthese countries can borrow but instead by policy choices over time, it is possible, in principle, that countries may,fromasocialperspective,beoverborrowing rather than underborrowingthat is, they may be borrowingbeyondthepointatwhichthesocial cost of one additional unit of debt equals the social beneft of an additional unit of debt-fnanced gov-ernmentexpenditure.Overborrowingcouldarise from at least three distortions.First,policymakersofenhaveincentivestobor-rowmorethanwhatissociallyoptimal(forare-cent survey, see Eichengreen et al. 2011). Political failures can also lead to debt crises through subop-timaldebtmanagement.Contingentdebtinstru-ments with contractual obligations that are linked toacountrysabilitytopaycanhelpinensuring thatagovernmentmeetsitsfnancingneedsand paymentobligationsatthelowestpossiblecost consistentwithaprudentdegreeofrisk(Missale 1999).However,self-interestedpoliticianshave limited incentives to issue contingent debt instru-ments that have upfront costs but may yield bene-fts for their successors.11Second, overborrowing might be the result of mor-al hazard linked to the presence of an international lender of last resort. Because countries tend to re-paywhattheyborrowfromofciallenders,there is limited empirical evidence for debtor moral haz-ard at the expenses of global taxpayers. Creditors, however, may have incentives to behave recklessly and lend without adequate regard to risk because ofcial bailout packages may allow for repayments thataretoohighwithrespecttothesocialop-timum.Tebillisnotfootedbyglobaltaxpayers but by local taxpayers who end up repaying, even whenitwouldhavebeenbettertorestructure (Jeanne and Zettelmeyer 2001). Although, in prin-ciple, moral hazard can be mitigated by designing 11While political failures limit the supply of contingent debt instruments, market failures associated with coordination problems limit the demand for such instruments. REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 9ofcial rescue packages that bail-in private cred-itors, such bail-ins may not be optimal ex post, and it may be difcult for ofcial lenders to commit to them ex ante. Ofcial packages can also delay the moment when a country decides to restructure its debts (more is given on this below), making cred-itors willing to provide short-term fnance to risky creditorsinthehopeofbeingabletocollectbe-fore the country defaults or starts the restructuring process.Tird,overborrowingcouldresultfromthefact that, in the absence of seniority rules, new lending tohigh-riskcountriesdilutestheclaimsofexist-ingcreditors.Debtdilutioncanleadtoexcessive debtaccumulationbecausethemarginalinterest ratedoesnotrefecttheincreaseinriskbrought about the issuance of new debt (Bolton and Jeanne 2007).Countrieswithprudentfscalpoliciesface theoppositeproblembecausethepossibilityof dilutingthedebtincreasestheriskoflendingto these countries. Debt dilution has also an adverse efect on debt composition because, in the attempt to hold debt that is difcult to dilute, lenders will bereluctanttobuylong-termsecuritiesorlo-calcurrencydebtinstruments(Borenszteinetal. 2005).12Overborrowingrequirescreditorsintheprivate or ofcial sector that agree to provide the needed fnancing.Overborrowingisofenfacilitatedby herding behavior, which leads creditors to take on too much risk during periods of global optimism.13 Tough most theoretical models of sovereign debt suggestthatcountriesshouldborrowabroad duringrecessionsandrepayduringgoodtimes, thereisevidencethatnetlendingtoemerging marketanddevelopingcountriesispro-cyclical, withlargecapitalinfowsduringperiodsofhigh growth and outfows during recessions (see Paniz-za,Sturzenegger,andZettelmeyer2009,table2). Tis is also true for cross-border, bank-intermedi-ated private credit fows (CIEPR 2012). Inthestereotypicalcaseofoverborrowingsyn-drome,economicreformsandfnancialliberal-izationarefollowedbyrapidandunsustainable capitalinfowschanneledtotheprivatesectorby domestic banks and fueled by excessive optimism among residents, foreign investors and policymak-ers (McKinnon and Pill 1996). A global shock, or the realization that the infows are not sustainable, isofenfollowedbyasuddenstop(Calvo2005), economiccollapseandfnancialcrisis.Atthis point,privatesectorliabilitiesaretransferredto thesovereign,exacerbatingtheimpactofpublic overborrowing during the preceding upswing.Assuggestedbyfgure1,intheadvancedecon-omies,thecreditconstraintsassociatedwithen-forcementproblemsareunlikelytobebindingat levels that are sufciently low to rule out overbor-rowing. Many advanced economies have been able to accumulate large public debts, and, until recent-ly,therewasnostrongrelationshipbetweendebt levels and the borrowing costs faced by this group ofcountries.Tisremainstruefortheadvanced economies that do not belong to the euro area (see chapter 4).14In emerging market countries, debt ratios tend to belower,andthecorrelationbetweenborrowing costsandfundamentalsistighterthaninthead-vanced economies. Low debt ratios are consistent withthepresenceofcreditconstraintsassociat-edwithlimitedenforcement.However,alimited ability and willingness to borrow may also be due tothefactthatemergingmarketcountrieshave weakerinstitutions(Reinhart,Rogof,andSavas-tano2003),haveriskierdebtstructures(Eichen-green et al. 2005), and face larger external fnancial shocks (Calvo 2005). 12 Dilution accounts for more than 80 percent of the default risk in the baseline calibrated model of Hatchondo, Martinez, and Sosa Padilla (2012).13In the presence of rational herding, investors disregard fundamentals and stand ready to either lend at will when everybody else is lending or to liquidate good credits when everybody else is also selling (see Allen, Morris, and Shin 2006).14 For an econometric analysis, see DellErba, Hausmann, and Panizza (2013). REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 10Althoughemergingmarketcountriesdoface precariousaccesstocredit,thepresenceofgen-eralizedcapitalfowsbonanzasandsuddenstops suggeststhatglobalfactorsmaybeamoreim-portantdeterminantofcreditconstraintsthan country-specifcconsiderationslinkedtocapaci-tyandwillingnesstopay(Calvo,Leiderman,and Reinhart 1993; Gonzlez-Rozada and Levy Yeyati 2008). For instance, in a context of historically low interestrates,investorshavebeenwillingtotake greaterriskstoachievereturns.Tissearchfor yield allowed low-rated frontier markets to issue internationalbondswithlowspreadscompared with higher-rated instruments issued by tradition-al borrowers (table 1). Restructuring Too LateTereisevidencethatpolicymakersareofenre-luctant to restructure their debts and suboptimally postponeunavoidabledefaults(e.g.,Borensztein andPanizza2009;LevyYeyatiandPanizza2010; IMF2013).Delayeddefaultscanleadtothede-struction of value because a prolonged predefault crisis may reduce a countrys capacity and willing-ness to pay. Its capacity to pay is reduced because procrastination prolongs the climate of uncertain-ty, high interest rates and restrictive fscal policies that are inefective in avoiding default but amplify outputcontractions.Delayeddefaultsreduceits willingnesstopaybecauseelectorsthathavesuf-feredlongperiodsofeconomicausterityareless likelytosupportacreditor-friendlydebtrestruc-turing. Becausepolicymakersareofenreplacedafera debtdefault(fgure2),laterestructuringsmaybe causedbyself-interestedagentsthathaveincen-tives to gamble for redemption, even when delays entaileconomiccostsforsocietyasawhole.My-opicpolicymakerswhodonottakeintoaccount the long-run costs of excessive debt accumulation may also decide to delay a default in order to have continuous access to external resources. Short po-liticalhorizonsmayalsocreateincentivestoun-dertakepoliciesthatincreasethevulnerabilityof thefnancialsectortogovernmentdefault.Tis generatesshort-termbeneftsintermsofahigh-er capacity to borrow, but at the expense of higher future default costs if the accumulated debt turns out to be unsustainable (Acharya and Rajan 2013). TABLE 1. SELECTED BOND ISSUANCES IN FRONTIER MARKETSCountry DateAmount(millions of dollars) CurrencyYield(basis points)Maturity (years)Rating (S&Pa)Angola 08/2012 1,000 dollar 700 7 BB-Bolivia 10/2012 500 dollar 490 10 BBHonduras 04/2013 500 dollar 750 10 B+Mongolia 11/2012 1,000 dollar 512 10 BBMongolia 11/2012 500 dollar 412 5 BBParaguay 01/2013 500 dollar 460 10 BBRwanda 04/2013 400 euro 660 10 BTanzania 02/2013 600 dollar LIBORb + 600 7 NRZambia 10/2012 750 dollar 560 10 B+Memo:Investment-gradeU.S. corporatesc201113 dollar 450 1015aStandard & Poors.bLondon Interbank Ofered Rate.cBofA Merrill Lynch U.S. corporate 1015 year efective yield.REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 11FIGURE 2. THE PROBABILITY OF REPLACING THE MINISTER OF FINANCE GIVEN VARIOUS EVENTS0%5%10%15%20%25%30%35%40%45%Tranquil years After BankLoan DefaultsAfter BondDefaultsSource: Borensztein and Panizza (2009, table 11).Alternatively, policymakers who believe that stra-tegicdefaultscanhavelargereputationalcosts but that unavoidable defaults carry limited costs intermsofreputationmaydecidetopostponea neededdefaultinordertosignalthatthedefault isindeedunavoidable.Finally,policymakersmay delaynecessarydefaultsbecause,intheabsence of a clear mechanism to manage the restructuring process, they overstate the actual costs of default.TeIMF(2013)describesseveralepisodesin which a country decided to initiate a restructuring processyearsaferIMFstafhadjudgedthedebt situationtobeunsustainable.Inthemajorityof thesecases,thecountriesdecidedtorestructure andapproachtheInternationalMonetaryFund only when they lost market access. Tere are, how-ever,alsocasesinwhichdelayswerefacilitated byofcialsectorfnancingtocountriesthathad lostmarketaccessandwerefacingunsustainable debtsituations.15Awillingnesstoprovideofcial fnancingtocountriesthatfaceanunsustainable situation is sometimes driven by private creditors lobbying, especially if the restructuring could lead to large losses for banks located in ofcial lenders countries,orduetothefearthatarestructuring would trigger global market turmoil (IMF 2013). Restructuring Too LittleInthelate1990s,itwasfearedthattheprocessof debtsecuritizationsparkedbytheBradyexchang-es would amplify creditors coordination problems and lead to long and litigious negotiations. Howev-er, by and large (Argentinas 2005 restructuring is a notable exception; see the next section), these fears didnotmaterialize.Tedurationoftheaverage defaultepisodesisnowmuchshorterthaninthe 1980s(Inter-AmericanDevelopmentBank2006; Bi, Chamon, and Zettelmeyer 2011; Trebesch 2013). Quickdebtrestructuringswithattractiveofers, however,canleadtoinsufcientdebtreduction andmaynotrestoredebtsustainability.Tecur-rentsystemmaythusgeneratetwo,equallybad, equilibria(Powell2011).Inthefrstequilibrium, countriesimplementquickandcreditor-friend-lyrestructuringsbutdonotsolvetheirdebt-sus-tainabilityproblem.Tesecondequilibriumcan deliver larger debt relief at the cost of long negoti-ations and protracted litigation. Evidence showing apositiverelationshipbetweenhaircuts(i.e.,the lossesfacedbybondholdersduringdebtrestruc-turing episodes) and the duration of restructuring episodes (fgure 3) and the bimodal distribution of haircuts(fgure4)isconsistentwithsuchaview (Powell 2012). 15Greece is an example. According to the IMFs (2013, 20) own assessment: Te case of Greece is also illustrative of the difculty of introducing early debt restructuring. Even in the face of a sustained loss of market access, debt restructuring could be delayed because of the ample availability of ofcial fnancing and the authorities stated willingness to entertain an unprecedented program of fscal adjustment. Even under these supportive conditions, however, it was not possible to establish that there was a high probability of debt sustainability as required by the exceptional access policy. Te chosen course was therefore to amend the policy to create an exception to the requirement of high probability in circumstances where there is a high risk of international systemic spillovers. Eventually, the planned adjustment proved unfeasible and, despite additional ofcial sector fnancing on supportive terms, private debt restructuring became unavoidable and was launched in February 2012. Tere have been, however, also cases in which ofcial fnancing and adjustments have been successful in restoring debt sustainability while avoiding a full-fedged debt restructuring. Turkey in the early 2000s is an example of a situation in which ofcial fnancing was successful in addressing a nearly unsustainable debt situation (IMF 2013).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 12Politicaldistortionscanamplifytheseproblems. Myopic policymakers who want to quickly access the international capital market and do not inter-nalizethecostsoffuturedefaultsmaydecideto advocatetheimplementationofquickandcredi-tor-friendlyrestructurings.Equallymyopicpol-icymakerswhodonotneedaccesstotheinter-nationalcapitalmarketmayinsteaddecidetobe excessively tough with their creditors and hurt the countrys international reputation.Teofcialsectorsometimesservestoexacerbate theproblemthroughsomebiasstemmingfrom myopia or overoptimism. Some of the restructuring episodesdescribedbytheIMF(2013)werebased onoveroptimisticdebtsustainabilityassessments, with relatively small face-value haircuts that did not restore debt sustainability, required prolonged of-cial support and led to additional restructurings.16Problems associated with suboptimal haircuts are amplifedbythefactthathaircutsanddebtrelief are diferent concepts. Haircuts are usually calcu-latedbycomparingthepresentvalueofoldand newdebtsobtainedbydiscountingfuturepay-ments with the exit yield (i.e., the interest rate faced bythecountrywhenitcompletestherestructur-ingprocess).17However,countriesshouldevalu-ate their debts by using the interest rate that they expecttoprevailinnoncrisistimes.Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer (2007) apply this idea to a series of debt restructuring episodes that took place be-tween1998and2003andshowthatthedebtre-lief of these restructuring episodes is signifcantly smaller than the losses sufered by investors. 0 5 10 15 20 25 30020406080100120Delay (years)Haircut (%)HIPC Donor Funded HIPC Donor Funded Brady Deals OtherFIGURE 3. THE LONGER THE RESTRUCTURING NEGOTIATIONS, THE HEAVIER THE HAIRCUT16However, there are also a few cases in which restructurings exercised that were deemed to be too timid ended up being successful in restoring debt sustainability. One example is Uruguays 2003 debt restructuring that, according to a 2006 assessment, was deemed to have lef signifcant debt vulnerabilities (IMF 2006). 17 Formally: Hsz= 1 Present Value New Debt (r) / Present Value Old Debt (r), where r is the exit yield.Note: HIPC = Heavily Indebted Poor Countries initiative.Sources: Powell, Sandleris, and Tavella (2013); Tavella (2013).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 11FIGURE 2. THE PROBABILITY OF REPLACING THE MINISTER OF FINANCE GIVEN VARIOUS EVENTS0%5%10%15%20%25%30%35%40%45%Tranquil years After BankLoan DefaultsAfter BondDefaultsSource: Borensztein and Panizza (2009, table 11).Alternatively, policymakers who believe that stra-tegicdefaultscanhavelargereputationalcosts but that unavoidable defaults carry limited costs intermsofreputationmaydecidetopostponea neededdefaultinordertosignalthatthedefault isindeedunavoidable.Finally,policymakersmay delaynecessarydefaultsbecause,intheabsence of a clear mechanism to manage the restructuring process, they overstate the actual costs of default.TeIMF(2013)describesseveralepisodesin which a country decided to initiate a restructuring processyearsaferIMFstafhadjudgedthedebt situationtobeunsustainable.Inthemajorityof thesecases,thecountriesdecidedtorestructure andapproachtheInternationalMonetaryFund only when they lost market access. Tere are, how-ever,alsocasesinwhichdelayswerefacilitated byofcialsectorfnancingtocountriesthathad lostmarketaccessandwerefacingunsustainable debtsituations.15Awillingnesstoprovideofcial fnancingtocountriesthatfaceanunsustainable situation is sometimes driven by private creditors lobbying, especially if the restructuring could lead to large losses for banks located in ofcial lenders countries,orduetothefearthatarestructuring would trigger global market turmoil (IMF 2013). Restructuring Too LittleInthelate1990s,itwasfearedthattheprocessof debtsecuritizationsparkedbytheBradyexchang-es would amplify creditors coordination problems and lead to long and litigious negotiations. Howev-er, by and large (Argentinas 2005 restructuring is a notable exception; see the next section), these fears didnotmaterialize.Tedurationoftheaverage defaultepisodesisnowmuchshorterthaninthe 1980s(Inter-AmericanDevelopmentBank2006; Bi, Chamon, and Zettelmeyer 2011; Trebesch 2013). Quickdebtrestructuringswithattractiveofers, however,canleadtoinsufcientdebtreduction andmaynotrestoredebtsustainability.Tecur-rentsystemmaythusgeneratetwo,equallybad, equilibria(Powell2011).Inthefrstequilibrium, countriesimplementquickandcreditor-friend-lyrestructuringsbutdonotsolvetheirdebt-sus-tainabilityproblem.Tesecondequilibriumcan deliver larger debt relief at the cost of long negoti-ations and protracted litigation. Evidence showing apositiverelationshipbetweenhaircuts(i.e.,the lossesfacedbybondholdersduringdebtrestruc-turing episodes) and the duration of restructuring episodes (fgure 3) and the bimodal distribution of haircuts(fgure4)isconsistentwithsuchaview (Powell 2012). 15Greece is an example. According to the IMFs (2013, 20) own assessment: Te case of Greece is also illustrative of the difculty of introducing early debt restructuring. Even in the face of a sustained loss of market access, debt restructuring could be delayed because of the ample availability of ofcial fnancing and the authorities stated willingness to entertain an unprecedented program of fscal adjustment. Even under these supportive conditions, however, it was not possible to establish that there was a high probability of debt sustainability as required by the exceptional access policy. Te chosen course was therefore to amend the policy to create an exception to the requirement of high probability in circumstances where there is a high risk of international systemic spillovers. Eventually, the planned adjustment proved unfeasible and, despite additional ofcial sector fnancing on supportive terms, private debt restructuring became unavoidable and was launched in February 2012. Tere have been, however, also cases in which ofcial fnancing and adjustments have been successful in restoring debt sustainability while avoiding a full-fedged debt restructuring. Turkey in the early 2000s is an example of a situation in which ofcial fnancing was successful in addressing a nearly unsustainable debt situation (IMF 2013).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 13ProphylaxisIfthepathologiesdescribedabovedominatethe classicenforcementproblem,areformthatfacil-itatesthedebtrestructuringprocess,strengthens incentivesforevaluatingcreditrisk,andreduces procrastination could be efcient both ex post and ex ante: Ifeasierdebtrestructuringbolstersin-centivestocarefullyassesscountryrisk, areforminthisdirectionwillincrease borrowing costs for countries with unsus-tainable policies and reduce their ability to accumulate excessive debts. Conversely, a smootherdebtrestructuringprocessmay beneft(oratleastnotharm)countries thatdonotoverborrowbecause,inthe caseofalargenegativeshock,investors are likely to obtain higher recovery values (Rogof 2003).18Asystemthatguaranteesspeedyand transparentdebtrestructuringscanalso reduce the overborrowing associated with creditormoralhazardbecauseitallows theinternationalfnancialinstitutionsto resistpressuretolendtocountriesthat facesustainabilityproblems.Tiswillbe particularlytrueiftherestructuringpro-cessiscombinedwithaclearsetofrules thatallowsforexceptionalfnancingto countries that face liquidity problems but preventofciallendersfromproviding funds to countries that face an unsustain-able debt situation. Asovereigndebtrestructuringframework could also have positive efects on debt com-position. Reforms that reduce moral hazard andleadtomorecarefulcountry-specifc riskassessmentmayprovidepolicymakers withincentivestoissuesaferfromthe 18A possible caveat is that, in the presence of uncertainty (or other market imperfections), creditors may reduce lending fows to countries with a fully sustainable debt situation.0.0160.0140.0120.010.0080.0060.0040.0020-20% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120%DensityHaircut FIGURE 4. HAIRCUTS SEEM TO HAVE A BIMODAL DISTRIBUTIONSource: Powell (2012).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 14pointofviewoftheissuerdebtinstru-ments. Enforceable seniority rules that ad-dressdebtdilutionproblemsmayreduce overborrowingandincreaseinvestors willingness to hold such instruments.Althoughmarginalimprovementstothedebt workout process are unlikely to result in inefcien-ciesexante,19itispossiblethatreformdesigned tofacilitatesovereigndebtrestructuringcould overshoot and, by reducing a countrys willingness to pay, raise the borrowing costs of solvent sover-eigns.However,thechancesthatthismighthap-penarecontainedbythefactthatwillingnessto pay is sustained by the economic costs of default, which are not directly afected by the debt restruc-turing regime. Besides the political costs of default mentionedabove,alargeliteraturesuggeststhat defaultsinfictbroadcollateraldamageonthe debtorcountry.Defaultsmayhaveanegativeef-fect on the countrys overall reputation (not just its reputation vis--vis its creditors) and increase the costsofallitstransactionsandagreements(eco-nomicandpolitical,domesticandinternational) thatrequireasubstantialamountoftrustamong thecounterparties(ColeandKehoe1998).20If such reputational costs are large enough, the coun-trys willingness to pay will be maintained even in the presence of an (ex-post) efcient debt restruc-turing mechanism. Indeed, a sovereign debt court abletoassessabilitytopaycouldcreatewilling-ness to pay by increasing the reputational costs of strategic defaults and mitigate the delayed default problems by reducing the reputational costs of un-avoidable defaults.Toconclude,therearemultipleex-anteproblems associatedwithsovereigndebt,andtheseprob-lems in principle could be reduced through a sov-ereign bankruptcy procedure, without necessarily exacerbatingtheenforcementproblem.Tissaid, thedesignofcomplexmechanismsthatcandeal with several inefciencies at once is rife with dif-cultiesandwouldrequiresignifcantinformation and commitment capacity. Te last chapter of this report discusses whether such mechanisms might be legally and politically feasible. 19For evidence showing that collective action clauses do not signifcantly increase borrowing costs for most issuers, see Eichengreen and Portes (1995); Eichengreen and Mody (2000); and Bradley and Gulati (2012).20An alternative class of models suggests that sovereign defaults may have large economic costs because they reveal negative information on the underlying structure of the economy (Sandleris 2008; Cato, Fostel, and Kapur 2007).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 15A Fundamental TensionFromalegalperspective,therearetwonotewor-thydistinctionsbetweencorporateandsovereign debt. First, as already discussed, sovereign debt is mostlyunenforceable.Tisisbecausesovereign immunityshieldsmostpublicassetsfromcredi-tors, even if they win a judgment against a default-inggovernment.21Tedebtorspropertyiseither inside its own national borders (where the courts areloathtosidewithcreditorsagainsttheirown government), or enjoys the special protections that areprovidedforembassies,centralbankfunds, militaryinstallationsandthelike.Propertyused forcommercialactivityismoreaccessible,but sincethewaveofprivatizationsinthelate20th century,fewgovernmentshaveconductedmuch commercial business in their own name. Although sovereigns ofen waive immunities when they bor-rowabroad,courtssometimesinterpretgeneral waivers narrowly or even ignore them. Where the legal scope for enforcement is so limited, political pressures play an outsize role, adding to uncertain-ty about the outcome of any given case. Second,althoughsovereigndebtcontractsare hardtoenforce,theyalsolastforever.Without bankruptcy,sovereigndebtcannotbedischarged togivethecountryafreshstart.Inmostcases,a determinedcreditorinsistingonfullrepayment cannotbeforcedtorestructureitsbonds.Atthe sametime,thecombinationofimmunityand transactionaltechniquethatshieldsdebtorsfrom enforcementisimperfect.Itreliesondiversena-tionallawsandcontractprovisions.Whencredi-torstrytoattachexternalpaymentfows,theef-fectivenessofimmunityasashielddependson individual sovereigns capacity to litigate and sur-vivethelossofmarketaccessforpotentiallylong stretchesoftime.Tisimpliesthatcreditorswith the time, will and resources to pursue a country to the ends of the Earth can try to make life difcult for it in perpetuity, throwing obstacles in the way of its international trade and fnancial activity. Arguably,thebalancebetweenthesefundamen-tal characteristics of sovereign debtthe fact that enforcementisdifcultandunpredictable,but not absent altogether; and the fact that sovereigns cannotgetafreshstarthasmadeorderlydebt restructuringspossibleintheneweraofbonded debt.Facedwiththealternativesofacceptinga reasonabletake-it-or-leave-itdebtexchangeofer or the hard work and uncertainty of enforcement, CHAPTER 3:Argentina and the Rebirth of the Holdout Problem21 E.g., see Weidemaier (forthcoming).REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 16mostcreditorswillaccepttheofer,particularly when the litigation prospects and secondary mar-ketvaluesofdefaultedinstrumentsarefurther erodedbyrestructuringtechniques(Bi,Chamon, and Zettelmeyer 2011). Tis calculus may not ap-plytospecializeddistresseddebtfundsexpert litigatorsthathavethepatience,skillanddeep pocketstoexploittheloopholesinsovereignim-munityprovidedthesovereignsoveralldebt stockisreducedtomakesidepaymentspossible. Sovereigns,inturn,willunderstandthatinthe presenceoftheseloopholes,andgiventhenon-dischargeability of debt, holdouts can be a perma-nentsourceofirritationanddisruption.Asare-sult, they will typically settle, and sometimes repay holdouts in full. Since the revival of the sovereign bond market in the1990s,thefundamentaltensionbetweenthe lackofenforcementandthelackofafreshstart hasproducedaregimewherefewcreditorshold out.Tosethatdoholdoutdonotfundamental-lydisrupttherestructuringprocess.Withvery fewexceptionsmostnotablyArgentina,where the authorities took a confrontational stance with creditors, largely for reasons of domestic political economyalldebtexchangessincethereturnof theemergingmarketssovereignbondmarketin the early 1990s have conformed to this pattern. As wearguedintheprevioussection,someofthese debtexchangesdidnotgofarenoughinreduc-ingdebtburdens.Buttheycertainlyconstituted atechnologyfordebtrestructuringthatmini-mized litigation and exclusion from sovereign debt markets. The Return of the HoldoutTosecreditorsthatrefusedArgentinasrestruc-turing ofers have been chasing it around the globe since 2001, using tactics that range from the exotic to the cartoonish. However, recent rulings in New York may give creditors the frst broadly replicable remedy against sovereign debtors since the days of gunboatdiplomacyacenturyago(box1).Rely-ing on the pari passu clause in Argentinas fscal agency agreement, a group of holdouts secured an order that bars Argentina from making payments onitsrestructureddebtunlessitpaysholdouts proportionately(ratably).Undercourtorders, ifthenewbondholdersgetpaidinfullunderthe restructured contracts, holdouts are entitled to full payment under their original contracts.Because versions of the pari passu clause are pres-entinallsovereignbonds,theratablepayment order in New York has given creditors a way to in-terceptfowsfromawiderangeofsovereignsto frms and ofcial institutions. For the frst time in decades,sovereigndebtenforcementlookslikea much more realistic prospect in a major fnancial jurisdiction. Tis is because cross-border payment fowsremainubiquitousandessentialformost sovereigns. Te pari passu remedy operates by in-fictingcollateraldamage;thatis,thosecreditors under performing debt contracts are blocked from receiving their payments, and payment and clear-ing systems and trustees are threatened with con-tempt of court if they help the debtor pay its per-forming bonds.22 Tis forces the debtor to choose betweenrepayingholdoutsinfullanddefaulting oncreditorswithinthereachofU.S.courts.Te latter, in turn, would imply a loss of access to large segmentsoftheinternationalmarket,alongwith possibly interfering with trade-related payments.Inaworldofwell-coordinatedcreditors,giving creditorsapowerfulnewenforcementtoolmight improve welfare. Creditors would enforce debt re-payment when it is in their collective interest to do so. Tis would rule out rogue debtor behaviorthatis,instanceswhencountriesrepudiatetheir 22Although the creditors said that they were not trying to block payments to the IMF, the terms of the court orders appear to cover private and ofcial payments in equal measure.REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 17BOX 1. NML CAPITAL, LTD. V. ARGENTINAArgentina defaulted on more than $80 billion in foreign bonds in 2001. Two debt exchanges and over a decade later, it has restructured 93 percent of this total. NML Capital, Ltd., is among the creditors that rejected Argentinas ofers and sued for full payment. NML is an afliate of Elliott Associates, which specializes in distressed sovereign debt litigation. Elliotts successful lawsuit against Peru a decade ear-lier, on the same theory it has since used against Argentina, was prominently cited to support SDRM.UnlikePeru,Argentinahasrefusedtosettlewiththeholdouts,andithaschoseninsteadtopaythe costofmovingitsassetsbeyonditscreditorsreachandtoavoidnewborrowingabroad,forfearof attachment. By 2012, both the creditors and the courts were ready to escalate debt enforcement. In February, the U.S. federal judge in New York, who has presided over Argentinas debt litigation all these years, ruled that it had violated the pari passu clause in its old bonds with its protracted failure to pay, by enacting laws that impede settlement, and by making ofcial statements of defanceamong other things. Te court required Argentina to pay both its old and new bonds ratably. Te court later elaborated that ratablepaymentsmeantthatArgentinamustpayNMLanditsco-plaintifsfullprincipalandpast-due interest (now $1.4 billion) whenever it makes the periodic coupon payment on the restructured bonds. Te judge prohibited Argentina from rerouting payments on the new bonds, and threatened to sanction third parties that might help Argentina pay this debt but not NML. Te threat covers trust-ees,clearinghousesandpaymentsystems,evennamingsomelocatedinBelgium,Luxembourgand the United Kingdom. Te court efectively gave Argentina only two ways to comply: pay everyone, or default on everyone.InOctober2012,theU.S.FederalAppealsCourtfortheSecondCircuitagreedthatArgentinahad violated the pari passu clause and must make ratable payments. It dismissed the U.S. executive branchs objectionstothelowercourtscontractinterpretation,itswarningsthattheremedywouldimpede future restructurings, and its claim that the court had violated the U.S. Foreign Sovereign Immunities Act by telling Argentina how to spend its treasury funds anywhere in the world.In August 2013, the Second Circuit also afrmed the lower courts formula for ratable payment, and refused to limit up front the injunctions territorial reach, or its potential impact on third parties. Te court was unpersuaded by the many submissions from the exchange bondholders and fnancial insti-tutions potentially subject to sanctions. However, the injunction remains stayed (suspended) for now, to allow appeals to the U.S. Supreme Court. Te stay may be at risk in the wake of Argentinas recent announcementthatitwouldofertoswapitsrestructuredNewYorkbondsfordomesticdebtwith payment streams beyond the reach of U.S. courts.Argentina appealed to the U.S. Supreme Court in June 2013, asking it to review the holding that it may not service its new bonds unless it pays the plaintifs ratably. France has fled a friend-of-the-court brief urging review, and stressing the consequences for debt restructuring and the Paris Club. In light of the August 2013 court decision, Argentina and other countries are likely to make other submissions to the Supreme Court. Te Court is also likely to ask the U.S. government for its views.REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 18debtsorofercreditorsadebtrestructuringwell belowtheircapacitytopay.Tesehavebeenrare in sovereign debt since World War II, much rarer than the opposite problem of overindebted coun-triesthatrestructuretoolittletoolate,asargued in the previous chapter; however, ruling out rogue behavior entirely surely would be good news, par-ticularlyfromtheperspectiveofnewborrowers withshorttrackrecords.If,conversely,adebtor is genuinely unable to payor debt is inefciently high, creating a debt overhang problem that weighs ongrowthandfuturecapacitytopaycreditors couldcollectivelyagreetorenegotiatedebtcon-tracts.Debtorswouldbedischargedofpastdebt obligations through a change in the contract terms of each and every existing debt obligation.Intheabsenceofefectivecreditorcoordination, however,theNewYorkdecisionscouldturnout tobeabigproblem.Tisisbecausetheyarelike-ly to upset the delicate balance between imperfect enforcementandthenondischargeabilityofdebt thathasmadeadhocdebtexchangesreasonably smooth in the past. Tough sovereign debt remains nondischargeable,potentialholdoutshavebeen handed a much better enforcement technique than they had in the past: third party enforcement di-rected not at the sovereign itself but at those private parties on which the sovereign depends. Tis will make successful debt exchanges harder to coordinate, even when they are in the joint interests of the debtor country and the creditors collective-ly. On one hand, the bargaining power of potential holdouts will be higher, making holdout strategies a more attractive proposition. One the other hand, creditors considering an exchange ofer must weigh not only the proposed haircut but also the prospect ofdefendingalawsuitor,ataminimum,having their reduced payments interrupted by future hold-outs. Tis means that even where litigation is unat-tractive to most creditors, participation is likely to become much less attractive. Asaresult,exchangeoferscouldfailforlackof participationevenwhentheywerecollectively optimal, or they could result in much lighter hair-cuts than would be needed to restore debt sustain-ability. Te country and most of its creditors, and perhapsevenitsneighborsandothervictimsof spillovers, could risk getting permanently stuck in debt purgatory.No Easy Way OutTe opinions of the U.S. Court of Appeals mistak-enly suggest that the court follows on the heels of a majorshifinsovereigndebtcontractsthatfacili-tates restructuringthe advent of collective action clauses (CACs)which creates the space for more robust enforcement. In this view, the rise of CACs getsthedebtorclosertoafreshstartandjustifes rebalancinginthedirectionofenforcement. However,whereasCACscanbehelpful,theydo notatleastinthevarietythatismostcommon in sovereign debt contracts todayeliminate hold-outs in sovereign debt restructuring so as to make the pari passu remedy unimportant. Under the pre-vailing model of CACs, a supermajority of creditors in a single bond series may vote to amend the terms and bind the dissenting minority. However, credi-tors can and do target small series trading at a deep discount,wheretheycanbuyablockingposition with relative ease, hold out, and threaten to sue. For instance, more than half of all foreign-law bonds in the Greek debt restructuring failed to get the need-ed votes to amend the terms. Tese bonds are still being serviced according to the original terms. Couldexitconsentsoferasolution?SinceEcua-dors2000restructuring,thishasbeenapopular techniquetodeterholdoutsinsovereignrestruc-turing.Whenparticipatingcreditorsexchange theiroldbondsfornewones,theyareaskedto votetoamendcertainnonfnancialtermsofthe bond that may be altered by simple majority, with theresultbindingonall.Intheearlydaysofthe tactic, it could be used to strip out a bonds terms concerning negative pledge, pari passu, listing, im-munityandjurisdiction.Nonparticipantsrisked stayingbehindwithanilliquidandpotentially REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 19BOX 2. THE ASSENAGON CASE CACs and exit consents both rely on majority rule. When a technique empowers a majority of bond-holders to impose restructuring terms on dissenters, it raises the possibility of unfair treatment. Such fairness concerns have featured most prominently in U.K. court cases about the oppression of bond-holder minorities. Taken to the extreme, this line of reasoning can block or severely limit the use of CACs and exit consents, and breathe new life into holdout strategies.Te High Court decision in Assenagon Asset Management S.A. and Irish Bank Resolution Corporation Limited (Formerly Anglo Irish Bank Corporation Limited) involved the use of exit consents in an Irish banks restructuring and recapitalization exercise. Holders of Anglo-Irish bank bonds were invited to exchange their holdings for new ones at 20 cents on the euro. At the same time, they were asked to vote to give the Irish Bank Restructuring Corporation, which had taken over the bank, the right to redeem nonparticipating bonds at 1 cent on 1,000, efectively wiping out their value. Te High Court deemed this oppressive and ruled for the fund challenging the transaction. Te judge appeared amenable to a sofer version of exit consents, whereby nonparticipants are given value equivalent to that received by the participants. However, when the worst possible outcome for nonparticipation is getting the same terms as everyone else, the urgency of signing up for an exchange goes away.worthlessinstrument.However,sincetheadvent of CACs on a mass scale in 2003, important non-fnancial terms in sovereign bonds have generally migrated to the list of reserve matters that require supermajorityamendment,alongwithfnancial terms.Tismeansthatblockingtheremovalof aparipassuclausethroughexitconsentsisnow just as easy as blocking the change in the payment terms itself. In addition, a U.K. courts decision in 2012potentiallylimitstheuseofexitconsentsin distressed exchanges (box 2). Tisseemstoleaveonlyoneapproachtoadhoc debt restructuring that could avoid the new threat of third-part enforcement, albeit at a much higher risk of litigation by mainstream creditors. Rather than ofering a debt exchange that would create in-centives to hold out, debtors could simply default ratablyonallcreditorsatonce.Forexample,a debtorcouldannounceanewpaymentstream equivalenttothatwhichitwouldhaveoferedin theformofanewdebtprecedingtheNewYork decisions.Bytreatingallcreditorsthesame,this approach would sidestep the possibility of enforce-ment. But this comes at a high price, given that the debtorwouldplungeintoatorrentoflitigation and likely forgo any hope of a fresh start. Pari Passu Is Not AllEvenintheabsenceoflegalandinstitutionalre-forms along the lines proposed in this report, the pari passu problem may well recede over the next decade or so (though only very gradually, given the typical maturities of sovereign bonds). Sovereigns and their creditors, including major trade associa-tions,haveadaptedtheircontractsinresponseto litigationandotherrestructuringdevelopments. Tereissomeevidencethatthisadaptationpro-cesshasalreadybeguninresponsetoNewYork court rulings. Hence, although recent legal devel-opmentsarelikelytoposeproblemsfordebtre-structuring in the short and medium terms, their efect is likely to diminish over time. REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 20However,thisfactobscuresamoresignifcant structuralproblem,ofwhichtheparipassusaga is a symptom. With no clear path to enforcement orafreshstart,bothsidesinthesovereigndebt restructuring game try to leverage contract provi-sions to win a given round. As the pari passu clause is gradually replaced, another technique will likely surfaceasaplatformforrecovery.Allitwilltake is for one adventurous (or frustrated) court to in-terpret a contract term in an unconventional way for a brief period of time. In the next round, sover-eigns might respond with more aggressive restruc-turing techniques. Te same contractual fexibility thatproducesingeniousrestructuringtechniques lendsitselftoingeniousenforcementtechniques, and so on. Putdiferently,contractsasinterpretedbyjudges have proven inadequate to mediate the tension be-tween the lack of enforcement and the impossibili-ty of discharge in sovereign debt. To the extent that contractsimproveovertimeandleavelessroom forinterpretation,thisproblemmayrecede.Tat said, experience suggests that this is at best an un-certain process that will take several decadesad-aptationisalongandwindingroadlitteredwith institutionalproblems,andisnotatallcertainto address interpretive shocks or result in more per-fectcontracts(GulatiandScott2013).Hence,a solution that is both durable and takes efects rea-sonably quickly will require policy actionwheth-er to improve contracts in a more radical and co-ordinated fashion than adaptation would produce on its own, or to create statutory solutions that can complement existing contracts. REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 21Euro PathologiesAlthoughsomeofthepathologiesrelatedto overborrowinganddelayedrestructuringthat were described in chapter 2 can be illustrated us-ing euro area experiences (particularly the case of Greece),theyhavebeenwellknowninemerging market settings for some time. Tis said, the euro areadoesappeartobespecialinwaysimplying thatthegeneralcaseforanoverhauloftherules governingdebtrestructuringandparticularly foratreaty-basedmechanismmayapplywith specialforce.Inparticular,theeuroareaembod-ies two structural features that exacerbate both the ex-ante pathologies described in chapter 2 and the difculties of managing debt crises ex post, partic-ularly in combination.First, a debt crisis aficting one country in the euro area constitutes a common problem for the entire currency area, to a degree that dwarfs crisis-related spillovers anywhere else in the world. Tis is partly theresultofclosetradeandfnanciallinkagesincludingthroughholdingsofsovereigndebtby bankinggroupsandotherinstitutionalinvestors withcross-borderpresence.However,economic linkages are also very highfor example, between the U.S. and Canada, between the U.K. and some euroareacountries,andbetweenGermanyand Switzerlandwithouttyingthesecountriesto-getherinquitethesamewayaswithintheeuro area.Apartfromasharedandofendifculthis-tory that rarely leaves room for indiference, what sets the euro area apart from other highly integrat-edareasisthatthecommoncurrencyitselfcon-stitutesapowerfulchannelthatlinkseconomic outcomesamongitsmembers.Tisispartlybe-causethepoliciesoftheEuropeanCentralBank (ECB) afect the entire currency area, but most of all because of the threat of a collapse of the com-mon currency, and the associated disruptions that this would create across the currency area. As a re-sult, a disorderly default in one part of the curren-cyunioncouldhavemassiveimplicationsforits othermembersevenmemberswhosedirectex-posures to the aficted country are not very high.Second, euro area countries have fewer policy in-struments for dealing with high debt. In particular, unless the euro area as a whole has a debt problem thatissymmetricalacrossmostmembersofthe currency union, the areas member countries can-not count on devaluation or accommodative mon-etarypolicytoofsetthecontractionaryimpact offscaladjustment.Asaresult,debtreduction efortsareeconomicallyandsociallymorecostly for given debt and defcit levels, and debt sustain-abilityproblemsariseatlowerlevelsofdebtthan in comparable countries with their own monetary authorities.CHAPTER 4: Euro Area IssuesREVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 22Note that the second problema lack of monetary policyinstrumentstohelpdealwithhighdebtis bynomeansuniquetotheeuroarea.Itis,infact, almostidenticaltothestandardproblemarising fromforeigncurrencyborrowingthathasaficted emerging market economies for many decades. Just as in the euro area, the presence of foreign currency debt renders standard monetary policy instruments essentially useless in a crisis, and implies that crises can be self-fulflling.23 What is special about the euro area, however, is the combination of a lack of instru-mentstodealwithdebtcrisesinindividualcoun-triesandthefactthat,ifthesedebtcrisesspinout of control, there could be dire consequences for the entire common currency area. As a result, the need bothforaregimethatpreventstheemergenceof debt problems and for additional policy instruments to handle debt crises when they do occur has been much more urgent in the euro area than elsewhere.Sofar,theseadditionalpolicyinstrumentshave consistedmainlyinthecombinationoffscalad-justmentandlarge-scale,conditionalofcialsup-port(eitherthroughtheEuropeanFinancialSta-bility Facility / ESM or the ECBs Outright Mone-tary Transactions program). Tough these forms of support can stop self-fulflling debt crises when debt is in principle sustainable, by defnition they donotworkinunsustainabledebtcases.Butbe-cause ofcial support and fscal adjustment are the only instruments on the table, the existing regime createsanincentivetomisdiagnosedebtprob-lemsdeclaringtheunsustainablesustainableandtostigmatizethosethatdisagree.Beforethe Greek debt restructuring fnally became the ofcial policyoftheEuropeanUnioninthesecondhalf of 2011, even the discussion of debt restructuring inEuropewasefectivelybrandedasun-Europe-anbyinfuentialpolicymakers.24Inturn,thiscan result in adjustment burdens that ultimately prove unfeasible, but usually not until they have caused great social and political harm. Atthesametime,large-scalecrisislendingcan give rise to moral hazard, at two levels: at the ex-penseoftheEuropeantaxpayerifofcialloans themselveshavetobewrittendownasseems likelywhenlendingoccursinunsustainabledebt casesbut also at the expense of the domestic tax-payer,whoisrequiredtorepayofcialloansthat arebeingusedtoservicedebtstoprivatecredi-tors.Teconsequencesareunderpricingofdebt and overborrowing, particularly in countries with weakerinstitutionsandpoliticalsystemsthatare not fully responsive to taxpayer interests.Fortunately, the euro area is special not only with respect to its problems in preventing and contain-ing debt crises but also in its potential to establish common institutions or legal frameworks to create newsolutions.Euroareamembersareofcourse also members of the EU, which has had a long, and for the most part successful, record of cooperating through supranational legal frameworks and insti-tutions.Furthermore,theeuroareahasonepar-ticularspecifcinstitutiontheESM,createdby treaty in 2012that could be easily adapted to em-bed a treaty-based debt restructuring regime. Te nextchapterhenceexploresthepossibilityofan amendment of the ESM treaty that would attempt toimpartincentivesforbetterdebtmanagement exante,bestowlegitimacyondebtrestructuring when this is in the common interest, and deal with the legal obstacles to debt restructurings posed by holdouts.Beforegoingdownthisroute,however,itisnec-essarytoaddressfourpossibleobjections,allof which are specifc to the euro area context: First, does the diagnosis change if one takes into account the nexus between public and privatedebtincludingoverlendingby banks?Inlightofthisnexus,mightthe creationofaeuroareabasedBanking 23 See Jeanne and Zettelmeyer (2003), and the references therein. 24Nicolas Sarkozy, We Will Show Tat Europeans Pay Teir Debts, International Financing Review, December 10, 2011. Similar statements were made by ECB ofcials, particularly Lorenzo Bini Smaghi; see Private Sector Involvement: From (Good) Teory to (Bad) Practice, Berlin, June 6, 2011, http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2011/html/sp110606.en.html. REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 23Unionwith a common fscal backstopbesufcienttodealwithsovereigndebt problems in Europe?Second,wastheGreekdebtrestructur-ingagame-changerinthesensethatit demonstratedthefeasibilityoforderly debtrestructuringintheeuroarea?In light of this success, does the euro area still need a more formal restructuring regime? Or does the Greek restructuring solve the problem both ex ante, by sending a warn-ingtofuturerecklesssovereignborrow-ersandlenders,andexpost,bycreating a template for future restructurings in the euro area, should they become necessary?Tird, could the problem be solved by the aggregated collective action clauses that, sinceearly2013,havebeguntobeincor-poratedintothenewlyissuedsovereign bonds of all euro area members? Do these CACsalreadyconstitutearestructuring regime of sorts that might obviate the need for a more heavy-handed alternative?Fourthandfnally,couldtherecentre-formsoftheEuropeanfscalframework makeadebtrestructuringregimere-dundant?Shouldnotthenewrulesand strengthenedoversightsufcetoensure fscal discipline and to curb moral hazard? Also,ESMfundingisalreadyconditional onfulfllingthefscaltargets,sowhyis there a need to go any further?Banking Union and the Nexus between Private and Public DebtIt has ofen been pointed out that the euro area crisis was primarily caused by capital fows and bank credit directed mainly at private rather than public borrow-ers, together with the higher risk premia and break-down in interbank lending triggered by the subprime crisisintheUnitedStates.25Withfewexceptionschiefy,theproblemsofGreecesovereigndebt problems in the euro area have been a consequence, rather than the cause, of this broader crisis. Inthecontextofthediscussionsofar,thisraises severalquestions.IfthemainprobleminEurope was (and to some extent still is) privately held debt, does the emphasis on sovereign debt restructuring missthepoint?Evenworse,mightasovereign debtrestructuringregimeberenderedinefectual by the tight link between private and public debt? And to the extent that this link is at the core of the sovereign debt problem in Europe, would it not be addressedbytheBankingUnionthatEuropehas begun to build, obviating the need for a sovereign restructuring regime? Te frst and most obvious answer to these points is that although public and private debt are related fortheusualreasonsbecauseprivateoverbor-rowing can become public in a banking crisis, and but also because public overborrowing can crowd outprivateborrowingtheyarestillseparate problems in the sense that they are driven by dis-tinct moral hazard problems, each of which would continuetoposeathreatiftheotherwereelim-inated.Inparticular,evenifnewfnancialsector institutionsandmacroprudentialpolicieswereto eliminateanychanceofunsalutaryprivatecredit boomsinEurope,apotentialpublicoverborrow-ingproblemwouldremain,forthereasonsde-scribedinchapter2,andwouldbeparticularly important to address in the euro area. For the rea-sons described earlier in this chapterthe lack of country-level monetary policy instruments, larger mutualcostsofdebtcrises,andmoralhazardprudent sovereign debt levels in a currency union ofcloselyintegratedeconomiesshouldprobably be lower than elsewhere. Tis may require a supra-national debt restructuring framework to both set 25See, e.g., Lane (2012); Lane and Pels (2012); Shambaugh (2012); Sinn and Wollmershuser (2012); and Hughes Hallett and Martinez Oliva (2013). REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 24the right incentives and deal with large accidents. Tepresenceofsuchaframeworkdoesnot,of course, obviate the need to also improve fnancial sector supervision and resolution, both because of the disruptiveness of crises caused by private cred-it booms and to prevent private debt from becom-ing a public liability. Second,whilesovereignbankruptcyshouldobvi-ouslynotbethefrstlineofdefenseagainstbank-ing crises, it can help, even with private borrowing problems. Ex post, it would provide a framework for therestructuringofpublicliabilitiesregardlessof their origin. To the extent that debt markets believe thatprivateliabilitiescouldatsomepointbecome public, this should create additional incentivesvia thenationaltreasurytopreventoverborrowing. In a country with rapidly rising private debt and a strong chance that this debt will become public, but without any chance of sovereign debt restructuring, sovereign borrowing will remain cheap. In the same worldwithachanceofdebtrestructuring,unsus-tainable private borrowing should at some point be-gin to afect sovereign risk premia, even if sovereign debt remains low. Because it gives the fscal author-ities a wake-up call, this is a good thing. Tird,euroarea-basedBankingUnion,afscal backstopandasovereigndebtrestructuringre-gimeshouldbeviewedasindeed,asovereign debtrestructuringregimeislikelynecessaryfor the proper function of the Banking Union. Based on the arguments that were made at the beginning ofthischapter,onecaninprincipleimaginetwo alternative,internallyconsistentinstitutionalar-rangementsfortheeuroareathatrecognizethe linksbetweenpublicandprivatedebt.First,one inwhichbothsupervisionandresolutionremain national responsibilities, and in which a sovereign debt restructuring regime deals with national debt shocksregardlessofwhethertheiroriginliesin the public or private sector. Second, one in which bothsupervisionandresolutionarejoint,and there is both a common backstop and a sovereign debt restructuring regime. In a fnancial area with cross-border banking, the latter is preferable because it internalizes the mul-ticountry efects both of banking in normal times and of bank resolutions. But it will work only if the authoritieswhosedecisionsultimatelyinfuence the quality of bank assets have the right incentives. With major decision areasfor example, infuenc-inghousingmarketsremainingatthenational leveleveninaperfectBankingUnion,thisre-quires that national authorities retain skin in the game, in the sense that national fscal backstops, if required in the resolution process, are tapped be-forecommoneuroarealevelbackstops.Tis,in turn,requiresthatmeaningfulfscalbufersexist at the level of all euro area countries, which in turn require creating incentives against overborrowing through standard fscal channelsone of the pur-posesoforderlysovereignrestructuring.Atthe same time, because signifcant decisionmaking au-thorityintheBankingUnionwillbecentralized, the possibility of sovereign restructuring does not obviate the need for a common fscal backstop. If decisionmakingauthorityovernationalfnancial systemsisexplicitlyorimplicitlyshared,so,too, must fscal responsibility.27The Greek Debt Restructuringa Template?Notwithstanding its restructuring-unfriendly con-ditions, the euro area recently pulled of the larg-estdebtrestructuringinhistory:the2012Greek bond exchange, which was successful in the sense 26While it is beyond the scope of this report to propose how these mutual responsibilities should be calibrated, the general principle is clear: Tere must be a relation between national responsibility for preventing fnancial sector accidents and the contribution toward the resolution of a fnancial sector crisis that would be covered from national fscal sources before use of ESM resources. Te latter could be set as a share of national GDP (e.g., 20 percent, set uniformly across euro zone members on the assumption that national fnancial sector responsibilities comprise similar functions in all countries). Should this exceed national fscal capacity, sovereign and banking system assets would have to be restructured jointly.REVI SI TI NGSOVEREI GNBANKRUPTCY 25of being orderly; in achieving high creditor partic-ipation (97 percent); and in resulting in large debt relief, on the order of 50 percent of GDP.27 Was the Greekrestructuringagame-changerthatitcould byitselfusherinanerawhenunsustainabledebt cases in Europe are dealt with through orderly re-structuring? Even ignoring the fact that European policymakershaveconsistentlyemphasizedthat theGreekcasewouldremainuniqueandnotset any precedent for the handling of other high-debt cases, there are reasons to doubt this.First, the Greek debt restructuring was quick and achieved high creditor participation for mainly one reason: 93 percent of Greek bonds were governed by local (Greek) law. Tis permitted the Greek Par-liament to retroft a collective action mechanism on the local law debt stock that operated to sweep potentialholdoutsintothedeal,andalsogave Greecescopetoofercreditorsextraincentives thatreducedtheappealofholdingout,namely, anupgradeingoverninglaw.However,notevery euroareacountryenjoysthelocallawadvantage thatGreecedid.Tisappliesparticularlytosome of the smaller euro area countries and borrowings by subsovereign entities. Cyprus is a case in point. Duringitsrecentbail-inofinvestors,itimposed the bulk of the pain on its bank depositors, while holders of its foreign-law-governed bonds (a sub-stantial portion of its debt stock) have been paid in full and on time.Second,theGreekapproachtorestructuringre-quiredlargevolumesofofcialfnancing,asthe exchange ofer included an exceptionally high cash sweetener to incentivize participation.28 Tis is un-likelytoberepeated.Rescuemoneyisbecoming scarce in the euro area, both because of public and politicaloppositiontofurtherbailoutsandbe-cause the pool of available resources is shrinking, as demand continues to increase and the potential roles of the European Financial Stability Facility / E