classical growth theory-aftermarx

Upload: virus2009

Post on 06-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 Classical Growth Theory-AfterMarx

    1/5

    Classical Growth Theory

    After Marx:

    Structural Change and Steady States

    Marx's frightening vision did not carry over into Neoclassical theory.

    But then, it is hard to say the early Neoclassicals had a substantial

    theory of growth at all. The possible exception was Marshall, but

    even he improved little upon the Classical system (of Smith andRicardo, not Marx). That was only to be really developed in later

    years.

    Concern with growth was then largely confined to the German and

    English Historical Schools, although these thinkers did little more

    than improve the recording and collection of facts on economic

    history. They did explore, for instance, institutional and cultural

    roots of productivity and factor changes (especially regarding

    population growth and the social-cultural habits that induced capital

    accumulation), but the essence of their system were only footnotes

    to the Classical theory. The American Institutionalists also did little

    beyond this - except that their massive empirical efforts on business

    cycles and national incomes accounts might have spurred new

    interest into the phenomenon of growth. Simon Kuznets, in

    particular, was instrumental in this respect.

    However, in the 1920s and 1930s, three new sets of storiesemerged which improved upon the Classical theory substantially.

    They all drew, to a good extent, from Karl Marx's theoretical schema

    that had been channeled by a European tradition that ran through

    Tugan-Baranovsky, Spiethoffand Aftalion. Specifically, two themes

    ran through the new stories: firstly, that the economy should be

    considered explicitly in its disaggregated, multi-sectoral structure;

    secondly, the concept of a steady-state growth path is introduced as

    a a reference point for such an economy.

    1

    http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marshall.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/ricardian.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/historic.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/enghist.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/institut.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/kuznets.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/cycle/overinvestment.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/tugan.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/spiethoff.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/aftalion.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marshall.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/ricardian.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/historic.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/enghist.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/institut.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/kuznets.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/cycle/overinvestment.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/tugan.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/spiethoff.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/aftalion.htm
  • 8/3/2019 Classical Growth Theory-AfterMarx

    2/5

    The first of these "structural" theories was that developed by Joseph

    A. Schumpeter in his 1911 classic, Theory of Economic Development

    and then further explored later on in his Business Cycles (1939) and

    his Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy(1942). His system was,again, supply driven: the main secular engine of growth was the

    increase in factor supplies. The difference, however, was

    Schumpeter's resurrection ofSmith's concern with the entrepreneur

    as an innovator who improved growth by efficiently combining

    resources, adopting new technical improvements in machinery and

    conducting the division of labor.

    Schumpeter's starting point is the steady state, or rather, a

    smoothly expanding economy. Unlike Smith, his population growth

    was exogenous and his savings rate rather constant or, at best, a

    residual and not a driver of growth - he was not very much

    concerned with distribution. In Schumpeter's view, the driver of

    "development" (as opposed to boring "growth") were discontinuous

    punctuated changes in the economic environment. These, he

    claimed, were brought about by a variety of things (e.g. sudden

    discoveries of new factor supplies), but entrepreneurial innovation

    was the central one.

    The entrepreneur's innovations drive development but their motive,

    like Marx had argued, was "raw instinct" - profit-derived wealth

    being merely an "index" of that instinct. Innovation, again like Marx,

    was not wholly exogenous: quite the contrary, competition for small

    profits "induced" entrepreneurs to innovate, whereas uncompetitive

    periods with high profits were a brake on the rate of innovation.

    It only takes a few leaders. From a steady economy, a technical

    innovation by a single entrepeneur opens up new profitable avenues

    - therefore, more entrepreneurs are induced to innovate, thereby

    increasing the profits in the economy as a whole, thereby driving

    growth. But as as the "supply of entrepreneurs" in any generation is

    numerically exhausted, capitalists turn upon each other and

    compete away the existing profits. Profits begin to decline and the

    economy slows down. However, the decline in profits will eventually,

    again, induce those with entrepreneurial inclinations to once again

    2

    http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/schump.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/smith.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/schump.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/smith.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htm
  • 8/3/2019 Classical Growth Theory-AfterMarx

    3/5

    innovate.

    One may think of this as more of a cycle theory than a growth

    theory, but Schumpeter claimed that there were ratchet effects in

    innovation so that entrepreneurial-driven spurts of economic activity

    led to progressively higher levels of income. And there is no long

    run need to slow down: unlike Ricardo, Schumpeter claimed that

    there were no diminishing returns to innovation. The only reason

    one may be driven towards slower, steady-state is that all the

    entrepreurs in a generation might be already "used up".

    There are also institutional preconditions for innovation: a capitalist

    system (private ownership of property) was one, existence andavailability of plentiful credit is another. Like Wicksell, Schumpeter

    abandoned Say's Law and claimed that credit made present activity

    independent of past activity and thus enabled entrepreneurship.

    Hence, since entrepreneurial innovation could be arrested by lack of

    credit, then financial innovation was also an important factor for

    increasing growth.

    Although he did not have diminishing returns to innovation,

    Schumpeter did have long-run elements in his theory which induced

    a breakdown in growth. These are rooted in social-cultural changes:

    enterprise may grow to the point entrepreneurial function may be

    replaced by bureaucratic managers who are less apt to innovate;

    growth uncovers economies of scale and may lead to permanently

    high industrial concentration and high profits (which again, are a

    brake on innovation); also, entrepreneurial activity will be

    progressively viewed as "bad" because capitalism leads to the

    breakdown of social and family relations and alienates the

    bourgeoisie and, in particular, is despicable to intellectuals who are

    highly influential upon public attitudes; this negative view of

    rapacious entrepreneurship will then conspire, culturally speaking,

    to diminish the supply of entrepreneurs. (Also, that same breakdown

    in the family may also take away from the "dynastic" aspirations

    which often lies behind the "raw instincts" of entrepreneurs).

    The concept of "steady-state" was still primitive in Schumpeter. It

    3

    http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/cycle/overinvestment.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/ricardo.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/wicksell.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/cycle/overinvestment.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/ricardo.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/wicksell.htm
  • 8/3/2019 Classical Growth Theory-AfterMarx

    4/5

    was given more precision in the second set of theories we consider,

    namely the "steady-state" multi-sectoral growth theories of Gustav

    Cassel (1918) and John von Neumann (1937). Both Cassel and von

    Neumann presented growth models which are akin to Marx'sreproduction scheme in many respects but differed essentially in

    the absence of "crisis". One can argue that it was probably more

    inspired by the general equilibrium theory of Ln Walras (1874),

    who also referred to the concept of steady state growth in his theory

    of capital.

    John von Neumann, in particular, followed the Classical idea that

    surplus is the determinant of growth but, contrary to the Classicals,

    did not concern himself with any falling rates of profit. John von

    Neumann's concern was in the formalization ofsteady-state growth,

    but without reference to any Classical constraints that might bring

    the surplus down and bring the economy to a stationary state

    without growth. To some extent, this was due to the fact that, as a

    mathematician, von Neumann abstracted much from the "social

    considerations" that often went into the Classical theories, i.e. he

    did not concern himself with possible resource constraints presented

    by land, or changes in fertility, or "entrepreneurial" behavior or anyother such concepts. His exercise was a thoroughly mathematical

    one -- foreshadowing the later formalization of the Classical theory

    by Sraffa and Leontiefin many ways.

    As a result, the dynamic models of Gustav Cassel and John von

    Neumann have a perpetual multi-sectoral, steady-state growth rate

    which they saw as perpetual and constant. They identified the rate

    of growth to be identical to the rate of profit - the "Golden Rule"

    already implicit in the Classicals, Schumpeter and Walras. For more

    on all this, see our reviews of the Walras-Cassel model and the von

    Neumann system.

    The final set of growth theories that emerged in the 1920s and

    1930s are the "structural" theories of growth developed by the

    Soviet economist Grigory Fel'dman (1928) and the Kiel School (e.g.

    Adolph Lowe (1926, 1954, 1976), Fritz Burchardt (1928, 1931),

    Alfred K ler (1933), Emil Lederer (1931), Hans Neisser (1933, 1942

    4

    http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/cassel.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/neumann.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/walras.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/capital/walcapit.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/capital/walcapit.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/ricardian.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/sraffa.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/leontief.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/growth/optimal.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/get/walcass.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/growth/vonsystem/vonsys.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/growth/vonsystem/vonsys.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/soviet.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/marxian.htm#feldmanhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lowe.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htm#burchardthttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htm#kahlerhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htm#kahlerhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htm#kahlerhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lederer.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/neisser.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/cassel.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/neumann.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/walras.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/capital/walcapit.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/capital/walcapit.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/ricardian.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/sraffa.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/leontief.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/growth/optimal.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/get/walcass.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/growth/vonsystem/vonsys.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/growth/vonsystem/vonsys.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/soviet.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/marxian.htm#feldmanhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lowe.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htm#burchardthttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/schools/kiel.htm#kahlerhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lederer.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/neisser.htm
  • 8/3/2019 Classical Growth Theory-AfterMarx

    5/5

    ), Wassily Leontief(1941)). They effectively take the story up where

    Cassel-von Neumann drop off. They are more explicitly indebted to

    Marx's theory, particularly his schema of extened reproduction and

    his recognition of technological unemployment.

    The Kiel School was particularly interested in what happens offthe

    steady-state path. They focus on technological change as the big

    crucial variable that is constantly leading to increases in the rate of

    return on capital and thus higher investment. The difference is that

    the resulting growth is not steady, but rather "disproportionate".

    For instance, after technical progress, investment goods sector

    output increases while that of consumer goods industries lags

    behind, leading thereby to changes in relative prices during the

    process of adjustment. These changes in relative prices can lead to

    technological unemployment in certain industries (e.g. consumer

    goods) while growth proceeds at bursting speed in others. There is,

    as Neisser expressed it, "a race" betwen technical displacement of

    labor in some sectors and the rate of absorption of labor in other

    sectors from capital accumulation. Notice that "traditional" recipes

    for curing unemployment, e.g. lowering wages or stimulating

    demand, will not affect the technological unemployment problem asthese are aggregate measures, not designed for the specific

    sectoral problems. As they Lederer noted:

    "The primitive conception that, wheneverunemployment exists one

    could always restore equilibrium by a reduction in wages belongs

    into the junk-room of theory" (E. Lederer, 1931: p.32)

    Several aspects of the structural theories of growth of the Kiel

    School were absorbed by dynamic input-output models (e.g.

    Leontief, 1953; Samuelson and Solow, 1953; Morishima, 1964,

    1973). They were more directly influential on the development of

    Friedrich von Hayek's (1928, 1931) theory ofmacrofluctuations and

    John Hicks's (1973) theory of the disequilibrium growth "traverse".

    5

    http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/leontief.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/neisser.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lederer.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/leontief.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/samuelson.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/solow.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/morish.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hayek.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hayek.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/cycle/moneycycle.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hicks.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/leontief.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/marx.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/neisser.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/lederer.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/leontief.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/samuelson.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/solow.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/morish.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hayek.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/cycle/moneycycle.htmhttp://cepa.newschool.edu/het/profiles/hicks.htm