comments on “counterparty risk in financial contracts: should the insured worry about the...

12
Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th Annual Bank Research Conference September 18, 2008

Upload: kellie-caldwell

Post on 03-Jan-2016

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Comments on“Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts:

Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?”

Erik HeitfieldFederal Reserve Board

FDIC/JFSR 8th AnnualBank Research Conference

September 18, 2008

Page 2: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Paper touches on 3 vital issues

1. Credit risk transfer and counterparty risk

2. Liquidity risk management

3. Overlapping asymmetric information problems

Page 3: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Counterparty risk

• Bank seeks to transfer credit risk to an insurer• Insurer manages its own liquidity position given beliefs

about the risk of its contingent liabilities• Outcomes

– If no credit event occurs, the bank receives principal and interest on its exposure and the insurer receives guarantee fee income

• Bank , Insurer – If a credit event occurs and insurer is liquid, bank receives

principal and interest and insurer bears credit loss• Bank , Insurer

– If a credit event occurs and the insurer is illiquid, insurer defaults and bank bears credit loss

• Bank , Insurer

Page 4: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Liquidity management

• Insurer has a liquid asset endowment A• Invests premium income in a liquid asset L or an illiquid asset I

– Illiquid asset pays higher return: I > L– But it is not available to pay claims

• Insurer has a contingent liability C– Endowment is insufficient to pay claim: A < C– Liquid portfolio is sufficient to pay claim: A + L > C

• Insurer believes claim will occur with probability b

Insurer Payoffs

State

Claim (b) No Claim (1-b)

InsurerInvestment

Liquid A+L-C A+L

Illiquid 0 A+I

I L

bA I C

• Insurer invests premium in I iff:

Page 5: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Overlappingasymmetric information problems

• Adverse selection– Bank has better information about the risk of its credit

exposure than the insurer– A bank with a risky exposure has an incentive to lie

about the exposure’s credit quality

• Moral hazard– Insurer determines its liquidity position after the

insurance contract is negotiated– Insurer has in incentive to invest in less liquid, higher

return assets even though this increases the chances that it will not be able to pay claims

Page 6: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Equilibrium is not what you’d expect

• Traditional asymmetric information story– Insurer cannot distinguish between safe and risky

exposures, so insurance premiums do not reflect underlying risk

– Likewise, insurer liquidity management is not risk sensitive

• The paper’s result– The bank truthfully reports the risk of its credit

exposure and the insurer believes it– The insurer invests in more liquid assets if the bank’s

credit exposure is high risk

Page 7: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Intuition

• Counterparty risk depends on insurer’s beliefs– If the insurer believes that a credit event is likely, it has reason to invest in liquid

assets – If the insurer believes that a credit event is unlikely, it can increase profits at low

risk by investing in illiquid assets

• The bank’s cost of bearing counterparty risk depends on the likelihood of a credit event

– A bank with a safer insured exposure is less concerned about counterparty risk because the likelihood of a credit event is lower

– A bank with a riskier insured exposure is more concerned about counterparty risk because the likelihood of a credit event is higher

• Result: It is more costly for a bank with a risky exposure to report that its exposure is safe

– A bank with a riskier exposure truthfully reports this information, and the insurer believes it

– A bank with a riskier exposure pays higher premiums but bears less counterparty risk

Page 8: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Problematic Assumption #1Insurer has unlimited liability

Insurer Asset Value

Insurer Obligations

Investment PayoffDefault Point

Standard Model: limited shareholder liability

Current Model: bankruptcy costs borne by shareholders with unlimited liability

Page 9: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Problematic Assumption #2:No coordination problem among banks

• According to the basic model– Insurer endowed with an initial portfolio of assets and liabilities– A single credit guarantee contract affects insurer balance sheet in two

ways• Insurer receives up-front fee income held as an asset• Insurer holds a new contingent liability whose ex ante valuation depends

on the insurer’s beliefs about the likelihood of a credit event– After the contract is negotiated, the only decision available to the

insurer is whether to invest the contract fee income in a liquid/low-yield asset or an illiquid/high-yield asset

• Implication: – Insurer’s beliefs about a single contingent liability determines its

liquidity management– The bank is the only source new information about this liability– The bank has a strong incentive and ability to influence insurer beliefs

Page 10: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Extension to N banks

• Insurer has a liquid asset endowment A• Invests premium income in a liquid asset L or an illiquid asset I

– Illiquid asset pays higher return: I > L– But it is not available to pay claims

• Insurer has N contingent liabilities of (C/N) from N banks– Endowment is insufficient to pay all claims: A < C– Liquid portfolio is sufficient to pay all claim: A + L > C

• Insurer believes claim i will occur with probability bi

Insurer payoffs

Insurer Investment

Liquid

Illiquid

n

A L CN

nmax A I C , 0

N

Page 11: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Investment equilibrium with N banks

• Number of claims n, is a random variable whose probability distribution depends on the insurer’s belief vector (b1…bN)

• Insurer invests in illiquid asset iff:

• When N is large, changing bi alone will have a negligible affect on insurer liquidity decision

– As N∞, no separating equilibrium in idiosyncratic information possible (Lemma 7)

• Separating equilibrium only preserved if a bank can reveal information about the risk of other banks’ credit exposures (Lemma 8)– Assumes systematic shock affects all banks and– Each bank knows the magnitude of the systematic shock

C|EIA

C|EELIPr

CA

Nn

Nn

CA

Nn

Nn

Nn

CA

Nn

Page 12: Comments on “Counterparty Risk in Financial Contracts: Should the Insured Worry about the Insurer?” Erik Heitfield Federal Reserve Board FDIC/JFSR 8 th

Conclusions

• Should the insured care about the insurer?– YES, YES, YES!

• Does signaling by insured affectinsurer behavior?– Unlikely

• Insured exposure must be very large relative to other contingent liabilities of the insurer, or

• Insured must have access to information about insurer contingent liabilities not available to the insurer