context maps

Upload: irenek

Post on 31-May-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    1/24

    Context effects and context maps

    for positioning

    Minhi Hahn*Eugene Won**Hyunmo Kang*Yong J. Hyun**KAIST Graduate School of Management**Dongduk Womens University

    Received (in revised form): 29 September 2005

    Context effects refer to changes in consumer preference and choice responseswhen a new alternative is added to a choice set. This paper proposes a generalscheme for classifying various context effects using newly defined share-ratiomeasures (SRM) and share-change measures (SCM). With these measures, we canalso draw context maps and preference-substitutability maps that visualise thenature of context effects and positions of competing brands. These maps allow

    marketers to make positioning decisions that take advantage of positive contexteffects.

    Introduction

    A scene is shown of two truck drivers competing to see who will arrivefirst at a building. The brands on the trucks are shown as FedEx and UPS.

    They arrive at the building almost at the same time. The drivers rush intothe building only to find a DHL man coming out with a smile. This is arecent DHL commercial, comparing it with and differentiating it fromFedEx and UPS. By giving consumers the impression that FedEx and UPSare similar, DHL may have tried to distinguish its own service as unique.

    Market positioning is defined as arranging for a product to occupy aclear, distinctive, and desirable place relative to competing products in theminds of target consumers (Kotler & Armstrong 2004, p. 55). Similarly,product position means the way the product is defined by consumers onimportant attributes the place the product occupies in consumers mindsrelative to competing products (Kotler & Armstrong 2004, p. 259). Thus,

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    2/24

    unless competing products are clearly identified, market positioning isincomplete and a product position cannot be understood clearly.

    It is becoming more difficult nowadays to identify relevant competingproducts as more products are competing in goal-derived or needs-basedproduct markets. For example, a luxury car brand may have to competenot only with other luxury car brands but also with other non-caralternatives, such as stock options or money, as rewards packages forsenior executives. Also, the main market for a ladys skin cream productmay be the Christmas present market for husbands. Aside from suchunusual examples, it is not an easy task to identify those competitors thatcompete more directly with the firms brand even in the same product

    category. In this paper, we propose a new framework, called context maps,which can help marketing managers determine competing products forcomparison in making positioning decisions. The context maps showvisually how shares are gained or lost when each competing alternative isadded to consumers consideration sets.

    The framework is also useful for classifying context effects (i.e. theeffects of adding an alternative to or subtracting an alternative from achoice set on changes in consumer preference and choice responses). Manypopular models used for predicting market shares, including multinomial

    logit models, are based on the independence from irrelevant alternatives(IIA) principle (Luce 1959). This principle assumes that relative preferencebetween two options does not depend on the presence or absence of otheroptions. However, many consumer studies have shown the existence ofvarious context effects. For example, a new alternative product often takesdisproportionately greater share from similar than from dissimilarproducts (Debreu 1960). Tversky (1972) and Batsell and Polking (1985)are among the many who proposed choice models that incorporate suchsubstitutability effects among similar products. On the other hand, it was

    observed that a new alternative product can increase shares of similar butmore powerful products. Huber et al. (1982) called such context effectsattraction effects. Simonson (1989) observed compromise effects suchthat the addition of an extreme alternative increases shares of intermediateoptions. The addition of a new alternative similar to competing productsmay increase or decrease shares of the focal product. While Kahn et al.(1987) observed lone alternative effects, where the lone alternatives lostshare, Brenner et al. (1999) observed what we call uniqueness effects,where the unique alternative gained share. Our classification frameworkmakes clear how those independently observed context effects areinterrelated.

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    3/24

    We also present preference-substitutability maps. These maps show thecompetitive relationship between all pairs of brands in the market in terms

    of their relative preference and relative substitutability with each other. Ascontext maps, preference-substitutability maps are derived from the changein market share of the existing brands due to the introduction of a third brand.

    In the next section, we suggest a general scheme to classify various con-text effects when an alternative is added to a choice set. After key measuresto analyse context effects are proposed, we describe how context maps andpreference-substitutability maps can be drawn and analysed. Thenapplications are illustrated with real survey data for cell phones, digitalcameras, and movies in the Korean market. We conclude this paper with a

    discussion of the strengths and weaknesses of the proposed framework.

    Classifying context effects

    We first introduce the situation where there is no context effect. Accordingto Luce (1959), the independence from irrelevant alternatives (IIA) axiomholds if

    for i,j A T, where T= { 1 , 2 , , N} is a set ofNcompeting products,PA(i) is the probability of i being chosen when A is the set of availablealternatives. Popular choice models such as the multinominal logit (MNL)model (Guadagni & Little 1983; McFadden 1973) and ASSESSOR (Silk &Urban 1978), a new product forecasting model, are based on the IIAaxiom. When this assumption holds, the addition of a new alternative inthe choice set or the subtraction of an alternative from the choice set does

    not affect the preference of consumers. Therefore, there is no context effectwhen the IIA axiom holds.For simplicity of further discussions, we will suppose there are two

    alternatives, 1 and 2, in the choice set. Alternative 1 is our focal alterna-tive. Let the choice shares of alternative 1 and 2 be P(1) and P(2). Inaddition, suppose another alternative, 3, is added to the choice set. Let thechoice shares of 1 and 2 be P(1) and P(2) in the choice set with the threealternatives. With the simplified notations, IIA holds if

    (1) (1)

    (2) (2)

    P P

    P P

    =

    ( ) ( )

    ( ) ( )

    A T

    A T

    P i P i

    P j P j

    =

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    4/24

    Our classification scheme is based on the following definitions.

    Definition 1

    There is a context effectif

    Definition 2

    The context effect ispositive for alternative 1 if

    The context effect is negative for alternative 1 if

    Definition 3

    Suppose the context effect is positive. The positive context effect is definedto be strong ifP(1) > P(1). The positive context effect is defined to beweak otherwise.

    Table 1 shows our classification scheme. The context effect is defined to bepositive if the focal alternative gets a greater share than expected from the

    IIA principle (i.e. when there is no context effect). The context effect isdefined to be strongly positive if the share of the focal alternative isincreased as the third alternative is included in the choice set. Note that theregularity assumption in choice states that choice shares cannot increasewhen a new alternative is added to the choice set. Thus, the situation withthe strong context effect is the one that violates the regularity assumption.Table 1 also relates each category to previously studied context effects.Also, there are context effects newly defined in this paper.

    When the added alternative (alternative 3) takes away more share fromthe focal alternative 1 than from 2, we define that this is a negative contexteffect for alternative 1. If alternative 3 is more similar to alternative 1, it is

    (1) (1)

    (2) (2)

    P P

    P P

    (1) (1)

    (2) (2)

    P P

    P P

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    5/24

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

    Tab

    le

    1

    Choiceoutcomesandconte

    xteffects

    *

    Classification

    [P(1)/P(1)]*

    Remark

    Nocontexteffect

    Equa

    ltoone

    Lessthanorequaltoone

    Independencefromi

    rrelevantalternatives(IIA)(Luce1959)

    Neg

    ativecontexteffect

    Lessthanone

    Substitutability(similarity)effect(negative)(Debreu1960;

    Tversky1972)

    Lonealternative

    effect(Kahnetal.1987)

    Weakpositivecontexteffect

    Greaterthanone

    Weakattraction

    effect**

    Weakcompromiseeffect**

    Weakuniquenesseffect**

    Substitutabilityeffect(positive)

    Stro

    ngpositivecontexteffect

    Greaterthano

    ne

    Attractioneffect(Huberetal.1982)

    Compromiseeff

    ect(Simonson1989)

    Uniquenesseffe

    ct**

    *P(1)andP(2)arechoiceshareswithonly1and2inthechoiceset.P(1)andP(2)arechoiceshareswith1,2andth

    eaddedoptioninthechoiceset.

    **N

    ewlydefined.

    1

    2

    1

    2

    [

    (

    )/

    (

    )]

    [

    (

    )/

    (

    )]

    P

    P

    P

    P

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    6/24

    the substitutability effect (Debreu 1960). For example, suppose there aretwo animation movies in a choice set for viewing at the regular price (i.e.

    The Incredibles and Shrek II). Also, suppose a new option is added ofviewing Shrek IIwith a $1 discount. The additional option is likely to takeaway most of the share from viewing Shrek IIat its regular price but notmuch from viewing The Incredibles. If alternative 3 is more similar toalternative 2, it is consistent with the lone alternative effect. Kahn et al.(1987) suggested that lone alternatives can be in a disadvantageousposition when competing with a group of alternatives that are similar toone another. If the addition of alternative 3 enhances the attractiveness ofthe category characterised by alternatives 2 and 3, it can reduce the share

    of alternative 1 more than expected under the IIA condition.When the added alternative takes away more share from the competing

    alternative 2 than 1, there is positive context effect for alternative 1. At thesame time, if the share of alternative 1 is increased, there is a strongpositive context effect. The attraction effect (Huber et al. 1982) andcompromise effect (Simonson 1989) are in this category. Also, theadvantage of a unique alternative over a group of similar alternatives,observed by Brenner et al. (1999), is consistent with the strong positivecontext effect. Simonson and Nowlis (2000) suggest that consumers need

    for uniqueness enhances the choice of unique alternatives. We will call ituniqueness effect if alternative 1 shows a strong positive context effectwhen a third alternative (3) is added that is more similar to alternative 2.

    With the addition of alternative 3, the market share of alternative 1 maybecome lower than its original share but it may still achieve a greater sharethan expected under the IIA condition. Such weak positive context effectswere not discussed in previous studies of consumer choices. If there is apositive context effect, but not strong enough to be classified as theattraction effect, compromise effect or uniqueness effect, because the

    market share is not increased with the addition of the third alternative, wewill call it weak attraction effect, weak compromise effect and weakuniqueness effect, respectively. Weak positive context effects can arisefrom the substitutability effect as well. When the added alternative is moresubstitutable with alternative 2 than 1, it may take a disproportionatelygreater share from alternative 2.

    Context maps

    Previous studies on context effects suggest that IIA situations are quiteideal and do not often occur. Consumer preferences for the focal product

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    7/24

    depend on the competitors considered in the choice set. Marketers maystrategically influence consumers in selecting potential competitors

    compared in the choice set. The context maps discussed in the followingenable marketers to visually investigate the context effects originated fromthe existence of competitors considered in the choice set.

    We suggest two key measures for the analysis of context effects based onTable 1. The first of these is the share-ratio measure (SRM), defined as:

    SRM(1, 2|3)

    = and

    SRM(1, 2|None)

    =

    where 1, 2 and 3 denote that alternative 3 is added in the choice set of 1and 2, and None means there is no additional alternative other thanalternatives 1 and 2 in the choice set. SRM(1, 2) can be understood simply

    as a measure of relative preference between alternatives 1 and 2. Logtransformation is applied to make the SRM value zero when the shares arethe same for alternatives 1 and 2.

    Comparing the value of SRM(1, 2|3) with that of SRM(1, 2|None), wecan identify whether there is any context effect caused by alternative 3 ornot and, if there is, whether the context effect is positive or negative. If thevalue of SRM(1, 2|3) is greater than SRM(1, 2|None), the context effect ispositive, meaning that the share of alternative 1 is at least greater than thatunder the IIA situation when alternative 3 is included in the choice set. If

    the value of SRM(1, 2|3) is less than SRM(1, 2|None), the context effect isnegative, meaning that the share of alternative is smaller than that underthe IIA situation. If SRM(1, 2|3) = SRM(1, 2|None), the IIA conditionholds, implying that there is no context effect.

    The second measure is the share-change measure (SCM) defined as:

    SCM(1, 2|3)

    = and

    SCM(1, 2|None) = 0

    (1)log

    (1)

    P

    P

    (1)log

    (2)

    P

    P

    (1)log

    (2)

    P

    P

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    8/24

    where 3 denotes that alternative 3 is included in the choice set. SCMsimply represents the change of the focal brands market share after the

    introduction of alternative 3. Again, log transformation is applied to makethe value of SCM(1, 2|3) zero when there is no change in the share ofalternative 1 even if alternative 3 is included in the choice set. We defineSCM(1, 2|None) = 0 to denote that there is no change in share when noalternative is added to the choice set. From Table 1, we see that, assumingSRM(1, 2|3) > 0, the positive context effect is strong if SCM(1, 2|3) > 0.Otherwise, it is weak.

    Using the two measures, SRM as the x-axis and SCM as the y-axis, wecan draw a context map for any pair of brands in the market, as in

    Figure 1. Any point in the map has the coordinate of (SRM, SCM).Suppose we have collected data from consumers asking their choiceintentions in various choice sets with two alternatives (e.g. alternative 1and 2) or with three alternatives (e.g. alternatives 1, 2 and one otheralternative). We can easily identify what kind of context effect is occurringin each situation by calculating values of SRM and SCM for each of thecases when a third alternative is added and then drawing context maps likethat shown in Figure 1. All the points, {SRM(1, 2|k), SCM(1, 2|k)}, aredirected by the arrows starting from the point {SRM(1, 2|None),

    SCM(1, 2|None)} which is {log (P(1)/P(2)), 0}. The directions of the arrowsshow the types of context effect that arise from the introduction of a thirdbrand, k, into the choice set {1,2}.

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

    Figure 1 Identifying the types of context effect with context maps

    SRM(1,2|k)= log [P(1)/P(2)]

    SCM(1,2|k)= log [P(1)/P(1)]

    Case 3

    Case 2

    Case 1

    Case 4

    Case 5

    (Log [P(1)/P(2)], 0)

    Weakpositivecontexteffect

    Negativecontexteffect

    No contexteffect (IIA)

    Strongpositivecontexteffect

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    9/24

    From context maps, we can identify the nature of context effects,observing the direction of the arrows. In Figure 1, context effects are

    positive for product 1 in cases 1, 2 and 3. The arrows are directed to theright from the point of {SRM(1, 2|None), SCM(1, 2|None)}. In such cases,the market share for product 1 is at least more than expected under the IIAcondition. Case 1 is the most desirable situation, showing a strong positivecontext effect. Case 2 is a special example of a weak positive context effectsuch that market share of product 1 stays constant after the addition of thethird alternative. In Case 3, the context is positive but weak. The additionof an alternative decreases the share, but not more than expected under theIIA condition. The added alternative takes a disproportionately greater

    share from alternative 2 than 1. Case 4 is the situation where IIA holds.The added alternative draws proportionally equal shares from alternatives1 and 2. In Case 5, addition of an alternative not only decreases the shareof the product but also damages the focal product more than its directcompetitor.

    The illustration shows that we can analyse the advantages anddisadvantages of including an additional alternative in the choice set bydrawing context maps. Typically, the context map is drawn from theperspective of a focal product. With a fixed main competitor always in the

    choice set, it shows the effect of adding a different product in the choiceset as the third alternative. Of course, for further analysis, marketers canchange the main competitor or even the focal product, and can analyse theeffects of changing the product. If we use similarity-among-alternativesdata in addition to context maps, we can identify the exact nature of thecontext effects described in Table 1.

    Preference-substitutability maps

    In this section, measures of relative preference and substitutability aresuggested through the application of the measures developed in previoussections. Relative preference, in a binary choice case, can be representedsimply by the share-ratio of two compared alternatives. Suppose our focalproduct is alternative 1. We define the relative-preference measure (RPM)of alternative 1 with respect to alternative j as:

    RPM (1,j) = SRM(1,j|None)=(1)

    log( )

    P

    P j

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    10/24

    wherej is the main competitor selected in the two-alternative choice set.The RPM(i,j) value can be calculated assuming each brand i in the market

    is the focal alternative. The overall score of RPM at the industry level isobtained by getting the average of RPM(i,j) values across all thecompeting products for i:

    Overall RPM(i) =

    where Nis the total number of alternatives considered including i. Notethat the average ofRPM(i) values is always zero.

    Substitutability of the focal firm 1 to a competitor, k, is conceptualised

    as the degree of shares alternative k takes away from 1 when k is added asthe third alternative in the choice set. Assuming that there are Ncompetingproducts in total, we have (N 2) number of two-alternative choice setsthat include 1 and one of its competitors except k. The substitutabilitymeasure for alternative 1 with respect to k is the average of the propor-tions of the shares that k takes away from 1 in the (N 2) choice sets. Wedefine the relative-substitutability measure (RSM) of alternative 1 withrespect to k as:

    wherej is the main competitor selected for the two-alternative choice setand N is the total number of alternatives considered including 1 and k.The greater share alternative k takes away from 1 rather than its

    competitors, on average, the higher the value ofRSM(1, k). Thus, higherscores imply that 1 is more substitutable for k.RSM(i, k) values can be calculated, assuming each brand i in the market

    is the focal alternative. The overall score of RSM at the industry level is

    Note that the average value of all the notations RSM(i, k) is always zeroand the average value of overall notations RSM(k) is zero as well. Thismeans that the proposed substitutability measure shows the relative

    1,

    1( ) ( , )

    1

    N

    k k i

    Overall RSM i RSM i kN =

    =

    1,

    1,

    1(1, ) { ( ,1 | ) ( ,1 | )}2

    1 ( ) ( )log log

    2 (1) (1)

    N

    j k

    N

    j k

    RSM k SRM j k SRM j NoneN

    P j P j

    N P P

    =

    =

    1,

    1( , )

    1

    N

    j j i

    RPM i jN =

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    11/24

    substitutability of a pair compared to other pairs in the considered market.RSM has a value greater than zero if the pair has a substitutability greater

    than the average of the market and less than zero in the other case.Utilising the proposed measures, we can drawpreference-substitutability

    maps either from a focal firms perspective or from the overall industryperspective. Using the values of RPM(1, k) and RSM(1, k) as twocoordinates for each competitor k, preference-substitutability maps fromthe perspective of brand 1 can be drawn. The firm-level preference-substitutability map plots all the (N 1) competitors of the focal firms interms of their relative preference to and substitutability with the focalbrand. Also, with the overall RPM(i) and RSM(k) as the coordinate

    {RPM(i), RSM(k)}, industry-level preference-substitutability maps can bedrawn. The industry-level preference-substitutability map plots all Nfirmsin the market according to their overall preference and relativesubstitutability values. With these maps, marketers can visually observeoverall positions of competitors with respect to the substitutability andpreference as conceptualised in this paper.

    Application of context maps and preference-substitutability maps

    Design and data collection

    We collected choice data for cell phones, digital cameras and movies. Forthis study, five leading brands were selected from cell phones (LG,Motorola, Pantech, Samsung and SK Teletech) and digital cameras(Canon, Nikon, Olympus, Samsung and Sony). Also, five recently releasedmovies (Clean, DMZ, Notebook, Pretty and Taxi) were selected asalternatives in the movie category. These movies were all released on thesame day. Among the movies, DMZ and Pretty are Korean while the

    others are not. The most important target segments for the three productsare young consumers in their twenties. We collected data from 86 collegestudents. Among the respondents, 47 (54.7%) were male and 39 (45.3%)female; the mean age was 22.7 years; 85 (98.8%) possessed cell phonesand 37 (43.0%) had digital cameras.

    Subjects were asked to choose one alternative from each of ten two-alternative choice sets for one product category and each of ten three-alternative choice sets for another product category. There were threetypes of questionnaire. Two-alternative choice sets for cell phones wereincluded in Type A, for digital cameras in Type B and for movies in Type C.On the other hand, three-alternative choice sets for movies were included

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    12/24

    in Type A, for cell phones in Type B and for digital cameras for Type C.Thus, no subjects answered the two-alternative questions and the three-

    alternative questions for the same products. Between the two-alternativequestions and three-alternative questions, subjects answered questions ondemographics and possession of the products. The three questionnairetypes were randomly assigned to subjects. Questions on perceivedsimilarity among alternatives were presented in the final part.

    Subjects were told that all the cell phones had been launched recently.They were told that all the phones featured a one-megapixel digitalcamera, an MP3 player and a video messaging function. Thus, the fivealternatives differed only in brand name and price. For digital cameras,

    information regarding megapixels, size of memory and price was given foreach alternative. In the case of the movies, short introductions regardingthe genre and synopsis were presented to the subjects. We present the datafor the cellular phone category in Table 2.

    Our raw data show that predicting market share based on the IIAassumption can be quite misleading. For example, SK Teletech andPantech have market share of 64% and 36% respectively in a pairedcomparison case. When LG Cyon is introduced into the choice set, it takesan overall share of 7%. According to the IIA principle, the shares for SK

    Teletech and Pantech should be 60% and 33% after the new brandintroduction. However, the data show that market share for SK Teletechand Pantech is 82% and 11% respectively after the introduction. There isa 22.4% deviation from what the IIA assumption predicts. The data verifythe importance of analysing the context effects.

    Analysis of key measures

    From the choice data shown in Table 2, values of the share ratio measure

    (SRM) and share change measure (SCM) were calculated. Table 3 showsthe SRM and SCM scores for the cellular phone category. Note that agreater value of SRM(focal, 2nd brand|3rd brand) than SRM(focal, 2ndbrand|None) means the focal brand shows a positive context effect whenthe third brand is included in the choice set, and vice versa. A positivevalue of SCM stands for an increase in share of the focal brand when thethird brand is added in the choice set. It is very difficult to interpret theSRM and SCM values directly from Table 3. The context maps allowmarketers to easily identify the context effects.

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    13/24

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

    Tab

    le

    2

    Sharesofcellphones

    Two

    -andthree-alternativechoiceset

    s

    Set1

    Set2

    Set3

    Set4

    Set5

    Set6

    Set7

    Set8

    Set9

    Set10

    i

    LG

    Pantech

    Samsung

    Motorola

    Samsu

    ng

    SKTeletech

    SKTeletech

    LG

    Pantech

    Motorola

    j

    SKTeletech

    Samsung

    M

    otorola

    Pantech

    LG

    Pantech

    Samsung

    Motorola

    LG

    SKT

    eletech

    k

    Samsung

    LG

    Pantech

    SKTeletech

    Motorola

    LG

    Pantech

    SKTeletech

    Motorola

    Sam

    sung

    Sha

    resintwo-andthree-alternativechoicesets(%)

    Two-alternativech

    oicesets

    Three-alternativechoicesets

    i

    j

    i

    j

    k

    Set

    1

    14.3

    85.7

    10.7

    35.7

    53.6

    Set

    2

    35.7

    64.3

    10.7

    75.0

    14.3

    Set

    3

    89.3

    10.7

    60.7

    21.4

    17.9

    Set

    4

    21.4

    78.6

    07.1

    14.3

    78.6

    Set

    5

    89.3

    10.7

    71.4

    10.7

    17.9

    Set

    6

    64.3

    35.7

    82.1

    10.7

    07.1

    Set

    7

    50.0

    50.0

    32.1

    60.7

    07.1

    Set

    8

    50.0

    50.0

    3.6

    21.4

    75.0

    Set

    9

    67.9

    32.1

    32.1

    32.1

    35.7

    Set

    10

    32.1

    67.9

    07.1

    39.3

    53.6

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    14/24

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

    Table 3 SRM and SCM values for cell phones

    Focal brand 2nd brand Added brand SRM SCM

    Samsung SK Teletech Pantech 0.636 0.194LG 0.405 0.069

    Motorola 0.310 0.069

    Pantech SK Teletech 2.140 0.057LG 1.946 0.154

    Motorola 1.224 0.057

    LG SK Teletech 1.609 0.511Pantech 1.658 0.174

    Motorola 1.897 0.223

    Motorola SK Teletech 2.015 0.511

    Pantech 1.041 0.386LG 1.386 0.223

    SK Teletech Samsung Pantech 0.636 0.442LG 0.405 0.336

    Motorola 0.310 0.241

    Pantech Samsung 1.504 0.693LG 2.037 0.245

    Motorola 1.705 0.201

    LG Samsung 1.204 0.875Pantech 2.442 0.043

    Motorola 3.045 0.134

    Motorola Samsung 1.705 0.547Pantech 2.398 0.147

    LG 1.253 0.100

    Pantech Samsung SK Teletech 2.140 1.609

    LG 1.946 1.204Motorola 1.224 0.693

    SK Teletech Samsung 1.504 1.609

    LG 2.037 1.204Motorola 1.705 0.916

    LG Samsung 0.288 1.846

    SK Teletech 0.405 1.846Motorola 0.000 0.747

    Motorola Samsung 0.182 1.482

    SK Teletech 0.693 1.705LG 0.105 0.894

    LG Samsung SK Teletech 1.609 0.000

    Pantech 1.658 0.288Motorola 1.897 0.000

    SK Teletech Samsung 1.204 0.288

    Pantech 2.442 0.693Motorola 3.045 1.386

    (continued)

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    15/24

    Table 4 shows the values of the relative preference measure (RPM) aswell as the average of RPM across all the competitors (i.e. the overallrelative preference measure). Note that a positive value means the focalbrand is preferred more than the comparison brand. Naturally, the greaterthe overall RPM, the stronger the overall preference of the brand. Amongcell phones, Samsung and SK Teletech are the top two in terms ofpreference. It is interesting that Samsung and SK Teletech are equallypreferred when compared directly. However, when they are compared toLG or Motorola, Samsung is preferred much more than SK Teletech. As

    expected, we found Canon and Sony to be the top two brands in the digitalcamera category. Among the movies, Notebook and Taxi were the mostpopular.

    Table 5 shows the values of the substitutability measures RSM andoverall RSM. A positive number means the added brand takes away moreshare from the focal brand than its competitors, on average. The overallrelative substitutability measure is the average of the RSM scores. Amongthe cell phones, SK Teletech is the least substitutable and Pantech is themost substitutable overall. LG is highly substitutable with SK Teletech.Motorola is highly substitutable with Pantech. In the following sections,we interpret maps drawn from the values in Tables 3, 4 and 5.

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

    Table 3 SRM and SCM values for cell phones (continued)

    Focal brand 2nd brand Added brand SRM SCM

    LG (continued) Pantech Samsung 0.288 0.811SK Teletech 0.405 1.504

    Motorola 0.000 0.000

    Motorola Samsung 0.511 1.540SK Teletech 1.792 2.639

    Pantech 0.105 0.442

    Motorola Samsung SK Teletech 2.015 0.405Pantech 1.386 0.511

    LG 1.041 0.693

    SK Teletech Samsung 1.705 1.504

    Pantech 1.253 0.405LG 2.398 1.504

    Pantech Samsung 0.511 1.030SK Teletech 1.792 0.847

    LG 0.105 0.336

    LG Samsung 0.182 0.000SK Teletech 0.693 1.099

    Pantech 0.105 0.511

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    16/24

    Analysis of preference-substitutability maps

    Figure 2 shows the industry-level preference-substitutability maps for thethree product categories. Every point in the map has the coordinate of{RSM(i), RPM(i)}. Among the cell phones, the Samsung brand is the most

    preferred. However, it is more vulnerable in terms of substitutability thanSK Teletech. Pantech is in a highly substitutable position. In terms ofpreference, it is not among the weak brands. However, whenever a thirdbrand is considered in the choice set, Pantech is the brand that loses sharessubstantially. Nikon among the digital cameras and Clean among themovies are in similar positions to Pantech in that they are highlyvulnerable in terms of substitutability. On the other hand, DMZ in themovie category is the least substitutable movie although it is not amongthe most preferred. Apparently, those who prefer DMZ do not changetheir preferences when a third movie is presented as an option in the choiceset.

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

    Table 4 Relative preference and overall relative preference values

    Cell phones

    Comparison brand

    Focal brand Samsung SK Teletech Pantech LG Motorola Overall

    Samsung 0.000 0.588 2.120 2.120 1.207

    SK Teletech 0.000 0.588 1.792 0.747 0.782

    Pantech 0.588 0.588 0.747 1.299 0.218

    LG 2.120 1.792 0.747 0.000 1.165

    Motorola 2.120 0.747 1.299 0.000 1.042

    Table 5 Relative substitutability and overall relative substitutability values

    Cell phones

    Comparison brand

    Focal brand Samsung SK Teletech Pantech LG Motorola Overall

    Samsung 0.312 0.302 0.343 0.241 0.149

    SK Teletech 0.429 0.555 0.516 0.687 0.547

    Pantech 1.144 0.833 1.404 0.833 1.054

    LG 0.371 0.313 0.098 0.094 0.034

    Motorola 0.345 0.834 0.156 0.544 0.392

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    17/24

    Selected preference-substitutability maps from a firms perspective arepresented in Figure 3. In the preference-substitutability map for brand i,every competitor, k, is plotted as the point with the coordinate {(RSM(i, k),RPM(i, k)}. The first three are maps from the perspective of Samsung cellphone, Canon digital camera and the movie Notebook. Each is considered

    to be the leader in its respective product category. As they are the mostpreferred brands in their categories, there are no competitors in the thirdand fourth quadrants. When compared directly, SK Teletech is equallypreferred to Samsung in the cell phone category and Nikon is equallypreferred to Canon in the digital camera category. Note that Samsung issubstitutable to Pantech, implying that Pantech, not SK Teletech, could bethe most serious competitor. Similarly, for Canon, Nikon could be themost serious competitor. The movie Notebook seems to be in a stableposition. It is the most preferred and the second least substitutable movie.

    Some interesting results are found for other competitors, too. Thebottom three maps are preference-substitutability maps drawn from theperspective of SK Teletech, Pantech and LG, which are active competitorsin the cell phone category. SK Teletech is as strong a brand as Samsung inthis category. Although it is less preferred to Samsung overall, it is strongerin terms of the substitutability with other brands.

    On the other hand, Pantech and LG are vulnerable brands, being highlysubstitutable with other competitors. For these brands, it is best toinfluence consumers to consider only one of the competitors along withtheir brands, if possible. In particular, this may be a highly reasonablestrategy for Pantech because it shows a 35.7% share against the strongest

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

    Figure 2 Preference-substitutability maps at the industry level

    Cell phones Digital cameras Movies

    Preference

    Substitutability

    SK Teletech

    Samsung

    Pantech

    LGMotorola

    1 0 1 2

    2

    1

    0

    1

    2

    Preference

    Substitutability

    DMZ

    Notebook

    Taxi

    Clean

    Pretty

    1 0 1 2

    2

    1

    0

    1

    2

    Preference

    Substitutability

    Sony

    Canon

    Nikon

    Olympus

    Samsung

    1 0 1 2

    2

    1

    0

    1

    2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    18/24

    brands like Samsung or SK Teletech when compared directly in the two-alternative choice sets (Table 2). Whenever a third competitor isconsidered, the added brand takes away substantial share from Pantech.LG is in a very difficult position, which requires dramatic changes in termsof both preference and substitutability.

    Analysis of context maps

    Context maps let marketers visually identify types of context effect whendifferent competitors are added to their consumers choice sets. Figure 4shows selected context maps.

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

    Figure 3 Selected preference-substitutability maps from a firms perspective

    Cell phones(for Samsung)

    Digital cameras(for Canon)

    Movies(forNotebook)

    Preference

    Substitutability

    SK Teletech

    Pantech

    LG

    Motorola

    1 0 1

    1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    Preference

    Substitutability

    DMZTaxi

    CleanPretty

    2 1 0 1

    1

    0

    1

    2

    Preference

    Substitutability

    Sony

    Nikon

    Olympus

    Samsung

    1 0 1

    1

    0

    1

    2

    Cell phones(for SK Teletech)

    Cell phones(for Pantech)

    Cell phones(for LG)

    Preference

    Substitutability

    Samsung

    SK Teletech

    SK Teletech

    Samsung Samsung

    Pantech

    Pantech

    LG

    LG

    Motorola

    MotorolaMotorola

    1 0 1

    1

    0

    1

    2

    Preference

    Substitutability

    1 0 1

    3

    2

    1

    0

    1

    Preference

    Substitutability

    1 0 1 2

    1

    0

    1

    2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    19/24

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

    Figure 4 Selected context maps

    Motorola

    LG

    Pantech

    SCM

    SRM0.0 0.3 0.6 0.9

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    Product: cell phoneFocal brand: SamsungSecond brand: SK Teletech

    Motorola

    Pantech

    SCM

    SRM

    0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5

    0.6

    0.4

    0.2

    0.0

    0.2

    Product: cell phoneFocal brand: SamsungSecond brand: LG

    Motorola SK TeletechSK Teletech

    LG

    SCM

    SRM

    0 1 2 3

    0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    Product: cell phoneFocal brand: SamsungSecond brand: Pantech

    Motorola

    SKTeletech

    Pantech

    Pantech

    SCM

    SRM

    2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.00.0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    Product: cell phoneFocal brand: LGSecond brand: Samsung

    Motorola

    SCM

    SRM

    0.9 0.6 0.3 0.0 0.3 0.6

    2.0

    1.5

    1.0

    0.5

    0.0

    Product: cell phoneFocal brand: LGSecond brand: Pantech

    Motorola

    Samsung Samsung

    SK TeletechSCM

    SRM

    3.5 2.5 1.5 0.5 0.5

    1.5

    1.0

    0.5

    0.0

    Product: cell phoneFocal brand: LGSecond brand: SK Teletech

    Sony

    Samsung

    Samsung

    Nikon Clean

    Pretty

    Taxi

    Olympus

    Olympus

    SCM

    SRM

    0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0

    0.2

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    Product: digital cameraFocal brand: CanonSecond brand: Nikon

    SCM

    SRM

    0.6 0.3 0.0

    0.2

    0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    0.2

    Product: Korean moviesFocal brand: DMZSecond brand: Notebook

    SCM

    SRM

    0.6 0.3 0.0 0.3

    0.2

    0.1

    0.0

    0.1

    Product: digital cameraFocal brand: SonySecond brand: Canon

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    20/24

    The focal brand of the first three context maps (the upper row) isSamsung in the cell phone category. The first map assumes that Samsung

    and SK Teletech are in the choice set. It is natural to consider SK Teletechas the main competitor for Samsung because it is almost equally preferredin the cell phone market. The context map clearly shows that it is to theadvantage of Samsung to influence consumers who have the two brands intheir choice sets to include another competitor. Strong positive contexteffects can be expected when a third alternative is included. The mapimplies that the biggest increase in share for Samsung is expected whenPantech is included in the choice set as a third alternative. The second mapshows the context effects when Samsung and Pantech are in the choice set.

    For Samsung, it is best to include LG as the third alternative in the choiceset as a substantial increase in share is expected. Because consumers tendto perceive LG and Pantech to be similar, Samsung may be easilydifferentiated from the two competitors. When Motorola or SK Teletech isincluded as the third alternative, Samsung can expect positive contexteffects, but not an increase in market share. The third map shows thecontext effects when Samsung and LG are included in the choice set. In thiscase, Samsung should try not to include any third alternatives in the choiceset. When a third alternative is included, Samsung will observe a negative

    context effect. It is likely to face a substitution effect or a lone alternativeeffect.The three context maps in the second row are drawn from the

    perspective of LG, which is one of the weakest brands in the cell phonemarket. The left context map implies that LG will be better off by addinganother competitor for consumers who have LG and Samsung in thechoice sets. In fact, LG can expect an increase in market share if Pantechis included in the choice sets. The addition of Motorola or SK Teletech tothe choice set will not change the share of LG. For those consumers who

    have LG and SK Teletech or LG and Pantech in their choice sets, theaddition of a third alternative will not increase LGs share.The first two maps in the third row are selected from the digital camera

    category. In this market, Canon is the leader, with Sony following closebehind. The first map shows the context map of Canon for consumers whohave Canon and Nikon in their choice sets. For these consumers, ifSamsung or Olympus is added to the choice set, strong positive contexteffects for Canon arise. As consumers tend to perceive Olympus orSamsung to be more similar to Nikon, Canon is likely to enjoy theuniqueness effect, easily differentiating it from other competitors. AddingSony shows the weak positive context effect. Canons market share will be

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    21/24

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    22/24

    can be visualised at the industry level with respect to preference andsubstitutability.

    If the maps are analysed along with the perceived similarity data amongcompetitors, types of context effect can be identified. For example, if wehave detailed similarity data among competing products we can identifywhether it is the attraction effect, uniqueness effect or compromise effectwhen a strong positive context effect is observed. If marketers want tofurther investigate the implications of context effects, they can rely onanalysing models that incorporate context effects (Kivetz et al. 2004).

    Of course, the value of analysing such maps depends on the quality ofthe data. The subjects surveyed should be representative of target segments

    of the focal brand. Also, the context effects need to be compared withbasic cases where two alternatives are in the choice sets. Context effects letmarketers know how shares change from basic cases when a thirdcompetitor is included in the choice sets. The context effects should not beinterpreted beyond the basic cases on which the observed effects are based.

    Our framework is developed mainly for situations where a single optionis chosen. When consumers choose more than one option, we may applyour framework repeatedly by sequentially eliminating the option that hasalready been chosen. Unless consumers choose more than one option at

    the same time, our framework can still be a useful tool. For situationswhere consumers choose more than one option at the same time, we needto define alternatives as potential product mix options consumers mayselect.

    There may be several directions for further research. One is studyingconditions that enhance the consistency of context effects over time.Analysing context maps will be all the more useful if the observed effectsare stable over a long period of time (Drolet 2002). Identifyingheterogeneity among consumers regarding context effects is also

    important. The more homogeneous the consumer choice set in the targetmarket, the more useful will be the analysis of context maps. Studies onfurther applications of the measures may also be directed towardsmeasuring brand equity. Substitutability could be a key concept for adefensive strategy, whereas preference could be a key concept for anoffensive strategy as well as for defending brand power.

    References

    Batsell, R.R. & Polking, J.C. (1985) A new class of market share models. Marketing

    Science, 4, Summer, pp. 177198.

    Context effects and context maps for positioning

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    23/24

    Brenner, L., Rottenstreich, Y. & Sood, S. (1999) Comparison, grouping, andpreference. Psychological Science, 10, May, pp. 225229.

    Debreu, G. (1960) A review of individual choice behavior: a theoretical analysis.American Economic Review, 50, December, pp. 186188.

    Drolet, A. (2002) Inherent rule variability in consumer choice: changing rules forchanges sake.Journal of Consumer Research, 29, December, pp. 293305.

    Guadagni, P. & Little, J.D.C. (1983) A logit model of brand choice calibrated onscanner data. Marketing Science, 2, Summer, pp. 203238.

    Huber, J., Payne, J.W. & Puto, C. (1982) Adding asymmetrically dominatedalternatives: violation of regularity and similarity hypothesis.Journal of ConsumerResearch, 9, June, pp. 9098.

    Kahn, B., Moore, W.L. & Glazer, R. (1987) Experiments in constrained choice.Journal of Consumer Research, 14, June, pp. 96114.

    Kivetz, R., Netzer, O. & Srinivasan, V. (2004) Alternative models for capturing thecompromise effect.Journal of Marketing Research, 41, August, pp. 237257.

    Kotler, P. & Armstrong, G. (2004) Principles of Marketing(10th edn). New Jersey:Prentice Hall.

    Luce, R.D. (1959) Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis. New York:John Wiley & Sons.

    McFadden, D. (1973) Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior, inZarembka, P. (ed.) Frontiers in Econometrics. New York: Academic Press,pp. 105142.

    Silk, A.J. & Urban, G. (1978) Pretest market evaluation of new packaged goods:a model and measurement methodology.Journal of Marketing Research, 15, May,

    pp. 171191.Simonson, I. (1989) Choice based on reasons: the case of attraction and compromise

    effects.Journal of Consumer Research, 16, December, pp. 158174.Simonson, I. & Nowlis, S.M. (2000) The role of explanations and need for

    uniqueness in consumer decision making: unconventional choices based onreasons.Journal of Consumer Research, 27, June, pp. 4968.

    Tversky, A. (1972) Elimination by aspects: a theory of choice. Psychological Review,79, 4, pp. 281299.

    International Journal of Market Research Vol. 48 Issue 2

  • 8/14/2019 Context Maps

    24/24