controlling the electricity demand surge in the greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the...

12
Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek islands with solar air-conditioning: A model of market penetration Paraskevas Gravouniotis Centre for Environmental Policy Imperial College London London SW7 2AZ [email protected] ABSTRACT This paper presents a non-linear model that simulates a future were solar assisted space cooling equipment increasingly takes a share of the market in a set of islands with autonomous power systems where tourism is the main economic activity but also the reason behind high energy costs. The key aim of the broader research is to assess whether the diffusion of energy efficient demand-side equipment can significantly reduce the rate of capacity expansion and related costs and comment on considerations for diffusion policy for new technology while ensuring the competitiveness of the tourism product of these islands. Albeit focussed on the Greek islands of the Mediterranean, the original research this paper stems from develops a framework to assess power-saving demand-side equipment in similar environments found across SIDS, an easy to grasp tool for policy appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands. Categories and Subject Descriptors General Terms Tourism and Economics Keywords Electricity, demand-side management, system dynamics, space cooling, simulation, learning rate, diffusion, energy policy. 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1 Islands, the environment and tourism Islands are sensitive both to environmental and economic conditions. In those islands where tourism has been replacing more traditional subsistence economies, the demands to service the visitors can further exacerbate the environmental fragility of the ecological and cultural systems that initially attract the visitors. Among the services residents and visitors are demanding in upward trend is those provided by electricity. The lack of or limited local resources means that imported fuels not only endanger environmental disaster but make power expensive when it exists. Demand side management and energy conservation needs to be increasingly put on the table. Tourism in islands has adverse effects on freshwater, energy, food, land use and waste management and it is responsible for much of the recorded deterioration in these resources [1]. Intense tourism exploitation can deteriorate the environment to a level where it has an adverse effect on tourism and the economy is weakened as a result. It is an economic opportunity but also a threat to further development if not properly managed [2]. It has been argued that stakeholders of emerging tourism destinations should ensure sustainable development initiatives are encouraged, to prevent deterioration of their resources and to safeguard continued availability of resources in the future [3]. 1.2 The power siuation in the Greek islands The energy systems on the grid unconnected (also referred to as autonomous) Greek islands of the Aegean Sea exemplify five main characteristics in varying scales across the archipelago. These characteristics also underlie their problematic behaviour: 1. High costs of electricity, most of which is generated by expensive stacked diesel and heavy fuel oil (HFO) units, which is subsequently sold at subsidised rates to end-users. 2. Predominantly mid-voltage (20kV) and distribution level local grids and limited interconnections to neighbouring islands that would allow load sharing. 3. A highly seasonal and energy-intensive tourism sector. 4. A growing residential consumption mainly attributed to rising incomes and growing numbers and usage of readily available electric appliances. Permission to make digital or hard copies of all or part of this work for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not made or distributed for profit or commercial advantage and that copies bear this notice and the full citation on the first page. To copy otherwise, or republish, to post on servers or to redistribute to lists, requires prior specific permission and/or a fee. Conference’04, Month 12, 2004, City, State, Country. Copyright 2004 ACM 1-58113-000-0/00/0004…$5.00.

Upload: others

Post on 07-Aug-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek

islands with solar air-conditioning:

A model of market penetration Paraskevas Gravouniotis

Centre for Environmental Policy Imperial College London London SW7 2AZ

[email protected]

ABSTRACT

This paper presents a non-linear model that simulates a future

were solar assisted space cooling equipment increasingly takes a

share of the market in a set of islands with autonomous power

systems where tourism is the main economic activity but also the

reason behind high energy costs. The key aim of the broader

research is to assess whether the diffusion of energy efficient

demand-side equipment can significantly reduce the rate of

capacity expansion and related costs and comment on

considerations for diffusion policy for new technology while

ensuring the competitiveness of the tourism product of these

islands.

Albeit focussed on the Greek islands of the Mediterranean, the

original research this paper stems from develops a framework to

assess power-saving demand-side equipment in similar

environments found across SIDS, an easy to grasp tool for policy

appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of

interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands.

Categories and Subject Descriptors

General Terms

Tourism and Economics

Keywords

Electricity, demand-side management, system dynamics, space

cooling, simulation, learning rate, diffusion, energy policy.

1. INTRODUCTION

1.1 Islands, the environment and tourism Islands are sensitive both to environmental and economic

conditions. In those islands where tourism has been replacing

more traditional subsistence economies, the demands to service

the visitors can further exacerbate the environmental fragility of

the ecological and cultural systems that initially attract the

visitors. Among the services residents and visitors are demanding

in upward trend is those provided by electricity. The lack of or

limited local resources means that imported fuels not only

endanger environmental disaster but make power expensive

when it exists. Demand side management and energy

conservation needs to be increasingly put on the table.

Tourism in islands has adverse effects on freshwater, energy,

food, land use and waste management and it is responsible for

much of the recorded deterioration in these resources [1]. Intense

tourism exploitation can deteriorate the environment to a level

where it has an adverse effect on tourism and the economy is

weakened as a result. It is an economic opportunity but also a

threat to further development if not properly managed [2]. It has

been argued that stakeholders of emerging tourism destinations

should ensure sustainable development initiatives are

encouraged, to prevent deterioration of their resources and to

safeguard continued availability of resources in the future [3].

1.2 The power siuation in the Greek islands The energy systems on the grid unconnected (also referred to as

autonomous) Greek islands of the Aegean Sea exemplify five

main characteristics in varying scales across the archipelago.

These characteristics also underlie their problematic behaviour:

1. High costs of electricity, most of which is generated by

expensive stacked diesel and heavy fuel oil (HFO) units,

which is subsequently sold at subsidised rates to end-users.

2. Predominantly mid-voltage (20kV) and distribution level

local grids and limited interconnections to neighbouring

islands that would allow load sharing.

3. A highly seasonal and energy-intensive tourism sector.

4. A growing residential consumption mainly attributed to

rising incomes and growing numbers and usage of readily

available electric appliances.

Permission to make digital or hard copies of all or part of this work for

personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are

not made or distributed for profit or commercial advantage and that copies

bear this notice and the full citation on the first page. To copy otherwise, or

republish, to post on servers or to redistribute to lists, requires prior specific

permission and/or a fee.

Conference’04, Month 1–2, 2004, City, State, Country.

Copyright 2004 ACM 1-58113-000-0/00/0004…$5.00.

Page 2: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

5. Limited use of renewable energy resources due to licensing,

planning, system balance and social acceptance bottlenecks

resulting in heavy reliance on imported fuel oil for the

generation of electricity and heat.

In the Greek islands and for the purposes of the simulation built

during the research, air-conditioning (A/C) for space cooling was

found to be the main driver behind a near exponential surge in

both power peaks and consumption of electricity, estimated at a

10% mean per annum growth (Figure 1 below).

Figure 1: Peak load evolution in medium-large islands of the

South Aegean islands, 1976-2004 [4]

There are 32 autonomous power stations (APS) which provide

the bulk of the electricity needed on the Greek unconnected

islands of the Aegean Archipelago [5]. The total installed

capacity of APS is approximately 800 MW, while their

generation in 2005 reached almost 2200 GWh [6]. Table 1

attempts a classification of the APS found on the islands.

The generating sets found in the islands APSs are mainly running

on heavy fuel oil (mazut) and diesel, while among the

unconnected islands there is a gas turbine only in Rhodes. In

total there are 220 operating, according to the PPC [5]. The

rating varies from 100 kW to 36 MW for Rhodes.

Table 1: Aegean islands classified according to the installed

capacity of their APS

Category

(scale)

APS installed

capacity (MW)

Islands

Small < 1 Agathonissi, Aghios Efstratios,

Anafi, Antikithira, Donousssa,

Othoni

Medium > 1 and < 9 Amorgos, Astipalea, Kythnos,

Serifos, Sifnos, Simi, Skyros

Medium

Large

> 9 and < 20 Ikaria, Ios, Karpathos, Milos,

Patmos

Large >20 and < 50 Andros, Lemnos, Mykonos,

Santorini, Syros

Very

Large

> 50 Chios, Kos-Kalimnos, Lesvos,

Paros, Rhodes, Samos

1.3 The threat of A/C and tourism According to Greece‟s most established market research

company, ICAP [7], there was a 350% increase in split A/C unit

sales between 1994 and 2000. After that period the market

dropped, albeit still maintaining Greece among the top three

countries of the A/C market [7]. As nearly 70% of the sales take

place once the summer heat actually affects the population,

milder summers in the two years after 2003 decreased demand

(Figure 2).

Figure 2: Sales of split A/C units [7]

Power demand in Greece correlates with ambient temperature.

The Hellenic Transmission System Operator (HTSO), in its 2008

report about the future of the electricity grid, makes the case that

air-conditioning has been the major cause of this new

phenomenon over the past decade [8]. Figure 3 below compiles

the data into a diagram that illustrates this observation.

Correlation of temperature and peak demand

0

2000

4000

6000

8000

10000

12000

Janu

ary

Febur

ary

Mar

chApr

il

May

June

July

Augus

t

Septe

mbe

r

Octob

er

Nov

embe

r

Dec

embe

r

Peak d

em

an

d (

MW

)

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

Tem

pera

ture

(C

)

2005 MW 2006 MW 2007 MW

2005 0C 2006 0C 2007 0C

Figure 3: Correlation of temperature and peak demand in

Greece [8]

The main driver behind the rising energy demand in the islands

is the A/C load of hotels and „rooms to let‟. Tourism,

international and internal, has a great impact on an island‟s

seasonal population (Figure 4). This consequently stresses

capacity levels in the effort to meet base and peak loads that are

physically impossible to meet without a power output increase on

the island. There are rare and limited interconnections among

islands that would allow extended load management options.

There has been no restriction on the efficiency range of electric

appliances or substantial demand-side management (DSM)

policy so far by the government [9,10,11,12].

Obtaining a higher power output instantaneously to meet summer

peak loads has an immediate impact on the costs of the generated

power, as either the gensets need to run close to or above rated

output, or the operator has to utilise older stand-by and

inefficient engines [13]. This adds immediately to the running

costs of the operator. When investments in new permanent

capacity take place, the fixed cost takes many more years to pay

back due to low utilisation factors. In addition, the cost of the

Un

it s

ales

(th

ou

san

ds)

Page 3: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

outages and the lost revenue of foregone sales should be included

in the evaluation of the cost of not meeting the load, i.e. the

value of lost load. That figure then provides the basis for

comparing alternative interventions.

Figure 4: Tourist arrivals against permanent population in

the Aegean [4]

1.4 The financial bottleneck The Public Power Corporation (PPC) solely operates the

autonomous power systems (APS) of the Greek unconnected

islands through its Island Directorate. The total cost of

generating one kWh of electricity on the islands ranges from

€0.11 to €1.20 [14,15]; Kaldellis, who has extensively researched

and written on the energy situation of the islands for more than a

decade now, estimated mean electricity production of medium

and medium large islands at €0.15 to €0.40 per kWh [4].

The retail price for the household sector is about €0.08/kWh (the

standard household tariff is uniform across the country, for social

equity purposes). This price-cost difference amasses each year to

an unavoidable gap in the finances of the corporation. For 2001 it

was estimated to stand at €340 million and rising [14] while the

PPC itself estimates it at €442 for 2007, in a paper presented by

the Regulatory Authority for Energy (RAE) at a recent conference

[16]. This figure represents a 5% debt increase rate per annum.

2. A QUICK MODEL OVERVIEW

2.1 Considerations for the design A number of key observations were drawn in the design of the

simulation model as summarised below.

Mean year-on year demand increase is 10% in the

unconnected islands.

Demand peaks occur for short periods of time in the summer.

Tourism is the main cause of the demand surge seasonally and

historically.

Air-conditioning stands out as the technology that most affects

demand peaks.

The Public Power Corporation (PPC) is effectively in practice

and legally the sole supplier of power.

The income of households has been rising due to tourism, and

so has population, since touristic islands can support extended

local economies. As a result, demand for electricity services

through newly introduced appliances has been also increasing.

Peak and consumption curves of electricity since the 1970s

appear parabolic if not exponential.

The PPC‟s forecasting methods create a reinforcing loop of

capacity expansion beyond the carrying capacity of the

islands‟ resources.

The PPC‟s mandate does not include any form of

institutionalised DSM intervention. The unwritten underlying

assumption is an ever expanding supply-side that by nature

has very limited options.

The simulation should develop over a 50 year period to

capture the dynamics since electrification and to assess

policies for the critical 20 years ahead, as the current

paradigm is not sustainable even in the short-term, due to the

accumulating financial losses.

The management of the utilities is complex, as on the one

hand the utilisation of the installed capacity is very low

because of lengthy off-season periods, while one the other

hand in the short summer frenzy the reserve margin is on

many occasions insufficient.

Generating engines are outdated or worked in conditions that

they are not supposed to and as a result running costs are even

higher. On the other hand, fixed costs take a long time to pay

back, again creating conflicting objectives for a proper

capacity expansion policy.

Fuel consumption rises as engines are run on their stand-by

ratings to serve mid-load. The capacity margin is by rule of

thumb aimed to equal the largest unit of the APS.

Because of the forecasting function and the planning

procedure, investment occurs in large steps that overshoot the

real needs and as a result some islands get more than they

need while others risk power shortages.

The delay from approval of investment to actual installation

might be anything from 3 to 8 years. However, as mobile

generating sets are in use across the Aegean Sea, the

realisation of a capacity expansion need may also delay as the

capacity needs to be persistent.

The generating engines of the APSs for the islands concerned

are in the 200 – 4,000 kW range.

Researching on the quantitative expressions of these observations

the non-linear simulation model was built, tested and calibrated.

2.2 Main components The model adopted the principles and methodology of System

Dynamics (SD). It is a computer-aided approach to policy

analysis and design. It applies to dynamic problems arising in

complex social, managerial, economic, or ecological systems,

literally any dynamic systems characterised by interdependence,

mutual interaction, information feedback, and circular causality.

It was originally developed at MIT by Prof. J.W. Forrester in the

1960s borrowing heavily from control theory.

Page 4: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

One of the tools to consider, comprehend and demonstrate the

dynamic behaviour of simulation exercise in SD is the Causal

Loop Diagram (CLD). It is a story-telling notation that is then

translated to model structure and equations. A simple structure

from the model to serve as an example is Figure 5. Choosing any

element to start from, installed capacity in this case, the reader

assumes an upward trend in that variable and then examines the

effects on the following variable based on the polarity on the

arrow. When there is a plus the trend at the start of the arrow is

retained, when there is a minus sign the trend is reversed. For

example, a decrease in the capacity margin causes the margin

gap to increase against its target value and thus initiates a

increase in planned capacity. The ║ symbol indicates a

significant delay in the system, i.e. building and commissioning

new plant. Thus, the installed capacity also increases causing a

balancing effect on the original agitation of the capacity margin

which is now set to increase as new capacity comes in. Thus this

loop is called a balancing loop in CLD notation, indicated by the

“B” in its centre.

Capacity

Margin

Target Capacity

Margin

Margin Gap

InstalledCapacity

+

+-

Planned Capacity

Expansion

+

+

B

Figure 5: A simple balancing loop

In the actual simulation this balancing loop is part of the utility

expansion heauristics that along with other soft and hard

variables determine the need to invest in capacity and the time to

invest.

The other basic building-block loop in CLD is the reinforcing

loop as in Figure 6 borrowed as an example from actual model

design once again. It represents the main dynamic behaviour of

the diffusion of the new technology, the SolaR assisted Air-

Conditiong (SRAC) equipment, as it replaces the current variant,

the ELectric Air-Conditioning units (ELAC)

Cost of SRAC

relevant to ELAC

Fraction of SRAC

adoption

Learning

+

+

-

R Attractiveness of the

dominant (ELAC)

-

Figure 6: A simple reinforcing loop

Assume the fraction of the SRAC market share increases. As this

is an emerging technology the learning potential is high and is

also pushed up leading to overall cost improvements relative to

the ELAC as scales of manufacture, installation and perhaps

marketing grow. Consequently, ELAC is loosing part of its

attractivess and thus more SRAC is adopted. Therefore, in this

case the original agitation has further strengthened the initial

variable, thus a reinforcing loop.

In the actual model, the attractivess and relevant cost ratio as

well as the learning ratios are extensively researched and

mathematically described. For details, the reader can refer to two

paper by the author at the System Dynamics conference or get in

touch for unpublished papers and advice [17.18].

The complete narrative of the simulation exercise with its final

behavioural modes, feedbacks and cause and effect assumptions

is found overleaf in Figure 7. It can be read by following the

same method as for the simple CLDs before. Segment I is the

main utility component commanding the capacity and its

expansion as well as generating its financial figures.Segment II is

the sub-model of tourism and destination competitiveness and,

finally, segment III is the learning and diffusion sub-model. The

narrative mainly postulates that tourism is an external seasonal

agitator that rules the dynamics. On the one hand, it distorts the

forecasting data and amplifies the response, i.e. greater one-off

capacity investments. On the other hand, it initiates peaks of

random nature, duration and timing that can cause extremely

demanding fuel consuming operating conditions and outages.

This pattern has been repeated over the years, leading to the

exponential growth of power consumption and peak demand

observed in the islands.

How might the system be put under control and dampen the

impact of tourism? The answer points to innovative demand-side

management policies exercising control of the energy system

before peak growth manifests as urgent capacity installations.

Left to business as usual, the demand will always rise due to the

intricate concurrent dynamics of the island economies (increasing

volumes of tourism, seasonality, population increase and rising

standards of living) and the delays of the planning process.

+

Page 5: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

I

II

III

Household

consumption

Load

Factor

-

Tourism

consumption

Peak demand

Capacity

Margin

Target Capacity

MarginMargin Gap

InstalledCapacity

-

+

+-

Planned Capacity

Expansion

+

+

B1

-

R2

Total consumption

+

+

+

Competitiveness

Local cooling

coverage

Regional cooling

coverage

Gap

-+

A/C Installations

Cost of SRAC

relevant to ELAC

Fraction of SRAC

adoption

Learning

+

+

+

-

R5Tourism carrying

capacity

-

+

+

Attractiveness of the

dominant (ELAC)

Arrivals

+

-

+

+

A/C Efficiency

+

-+

B2

R4

Running Costs

+

Fixed Costs

Debt

+

+

Support

-

-

CapacityExpansion

Delay+ -

-

R1

R3

R6 R7

Figure 7: The complete model story-telling CLD

Page 6: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

Page 1

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

3:

3:

3:

4:

4:

4:

0

2620

5240

1: tourism carry ing cap… 2: potential adopters 3: ELAC adopters 4: SRAC adopters

1

1

1

1

1

2

22

2

2

3

33 3 3

4

4

4

4

4

Page 2

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

2880

41262

79645

1: ELAC 5y r cost 2: SRAC 5y r cost

1 1 1 1 1

2

22 2 2

Page 2

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

0

1500

3000

total adopters: 1 - 2 -

1

11 1

1

2

2

2

2

2

Page 4

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

0

200

400

capacity per tourist: 1 - 2 -

1

1

11 1

2

22 2 2

A. C.

D. B.

Figure 8: Observing the competition of equipment

Page 7: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

Page 1

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

3:

3:

3:

4:

4:

4:

0

2620

5240

1: tourism carry ing cap… 2: potential adopters 3: ELAC adopters 4: SRAC adopters

1

1

1

1

1

2

2

2

2

2

33

33

3

4 4 4 4 4

Page 1

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

3:

3:

3:

4:

4:

4:

0

2620

5240

1: tourism carry ing cap… 2: potential adopters 3: ELAC adopters 4: SRAC adopters

1

1

1

1

1

2

2

2

2

2

33

33

3

4 4 4 4 4

Page 1

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

3:

3:

3:

4:

4:

4:

0

2620

5240

1: tourism carry ing cap… 2: potential adopters 3: ELAC adopters 4: SRAC adopters

1

1

1

1

1

2

22

2

2

3

33 3 34

4

4

4

4

Page 1

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

2:

2:

2:

3:

3:

3:

4:

4:

4:

0

2620

5240

1: tourism carry ing cap… 2: potential adopters 3: ELAC adopters 4: SRAC adopters

1

1

1

1

1

2

22

2

2

3

3

3 3 34

4

4

4

4

B.

A.

C.

D.

3. DEMONSTRATION OF DIFFUSION

DYNAMICS AND MODEL INQUIRIES

3.1 Diffusion schemes and the system Graph A in Figure 8 illustrates the dynamics of replacement

between the two equipment variants in Line 3 and Line 4.

Initially, there is only the early power-consuming variant (Line

3). At some point around the course of the 7th year a scheme is

introduced that sees the installation of 200 efficient units. The

size of the scheme is such that it causes the cost of the new

equipment over five years (purchase and operation) to drop

below that of the conventional technology, as observed in graph

B. As soon as installations commence, SRAC is the favourable

choice, therefore we see its rapid growth (Graph A / Line 4) and

the parallel decline of the ELAC stock.

What is the impact on the system, however? Graph C (sensitivity

type graph) compares the scenario with (Line 2) and without

(Line 1) the introduction of the efficient variant. The number of

total adopters, i.e. visitors who enjoy the cooling service, has

increased dramatically in the former case. The improvement in

coverage is achieved in line with the competition requirement of

the regional cooling capacity per person (estimated at 200W by

research), as can be confirmed in Graph D (sensitivity) between

the two scenarios.

3.2 Exploring causality The model was designed to explore a range of policy question.

What is the best promotion strategy for new equipment? How do

policy-makers know which alternative scheme will work? The

sub-model gives the ability to design a promotional policy and

dynamically study such issues. It is not intended to provide the

answers which would have been a superficial claim but rather

helps to map and comprehend complex issues as well as provide

a common shared vision of the issues at hand when the

modelling and testing exercise are shared. Here is a

demonstration of the sort of value and issues such a systemic

approach can provide and the sort of causality analysis that can

be performed.

The demands of a diffusion programme can be observed through

the graphs in Figure 9. Despite attempting the introduction of the

new equipment in Graph B, as denoted by Line 4, there is

practically no impact compared to the reference case represented

in Graph A. The technology fails to break into the market, as the

cost impacts are not significant enough to establish the viability

of the new equipment variant, although the planned installations

are set to 25% of the dominant variant at the time. However,

raising the installations to roughly 28% puts the appropriate

learning effects in motion and the new technology has a startling

development, as shown in Graph C.

The final graph (D) in Figure 9 depicts an alternative policy

design. Instead of a single large-scale demonstration scheme, the

policy-makers decide on an annual small-scale installation

scheme as low as 6% of the installed variant in the first year.

The consideration behind this is the smaller budget required and

a fractional approach that would allow closer monitoring of the

procedure. The choice between the two and a number of other

potential schemes will depend on conditions of available funds,

institutional organisation and commitment, and the financial

profile of the commercial actors involved.

Figure 9: Assesing promotion schemes

Page 8: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

The choice will also depend on the rapidness of substitution

desired, as demonstrated in the sensitivity graph of Figure 10,

where lines 1 to 4 represent each of the cases from (A) to (D) in

Figure 9 this time comparing their service coverage. Line 1 is the

reference case of (A) and Line 2 is (B) in the previous. Line 3

and Line 4 correspond to graphs (C) and (D) respectively.

Although these last two succesful scenarios balance at similar

percentages of coverage, their path is different due to the

modular approach of the latter. This shows that a possible saving

in funds for the modular scheme has to be balanced against the

time taken to achieve the result.

In the following, the impacts of three diffusion scenarios on

selected system parameters will be elaborated.

4. SIMULATION FOR POLICY MAKING The diffusion scheme scenarios examined are:

Twenty units installed every year (referred to as Sc.20/12)

One hundred and twenty units every three years (Sc.120/36)

Two hundred units in a single year (referred to as Sc.200/0)

From top to bottom these scenarios are graphically represented in

the same order in Figure 11 below.

Figure 11: Diffusion scenarios studied

Page 5

1.00 120.80 240.60 360.40 480.20 600.00

Months

1:

1:

1:

0

25

50

serv ice cov erage: 1 - 2 - 3 - 4 -

1

1

1

11

2

22 2 2

33

3 3 3

4

4

4 44

Figure 10: Sensitivity of system response to promotional schemes

Sc.20/12

Sc.120/36

Sc.200/0

Page 9: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

4.1 The impact on capacity expansion The most likely set of graphs to look into where and how the

savings for the utility occur is that of installed capacity in Figure

12. The obvious effect of the intervention in all cases is less

installed capacity compared to BAU. The graphs include the

annualised growth of peak power demand and consumption for

each scenario. It can be observed that fewer expansions are

needed: in all three scenarios one can count five instead of the

six expansions under BAU. In addition, in all cases the added

capacity is found to occur in smaller steps than BAU indicating a

better managed system. The second observation, as a

consequence of the previous, is the delay in installing capacity.

Thus a better managed system perhaps points to improved

running costs, whereas investment deferral affects capital costs.

Figure 12: Installed capacity of scenarios vs. BAU

4.2 The impact on competitiveness The common sense developed in the simulation model suggests

that when the local space cooling capacity per visitor is below the

regional average, the competitiveness of the island as a

destination is marginally diminished. To mitigate this, a range of

switches and converters make sure potential adopters move from

their adopter stock to either the Elecrtic A/C (ELAC) or the

SolaR assisted A/A (SRAC) stock, depending on conditions of

costs and learning, causing a rise in the space cooling capacity

per adopter.

Any movement of that index though should be cross examined

with the coverage of the service. A rise in the capacity per visitor

could be also observed using more inefficient equipment, which

means covering fewer people with more power while trying to

keep close to the regional average, not a desirable situation. In

the case of Figure 13 below, there is a different story though.

Figure 13: Capacity per tourist for Sc.120-36

The capacity per visitor drops but it does not trigger mitigative

action because the uptake of the more efficient variant, especially

after commercialisation, actually achieves more with less. The

actual total number of adopters grows significantly higher than

the BAU case, as Figure 14 illustrates.

Figure 14: Total adopters Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

This is the effect of a virtuous cycle of efficiency that was

predicted in the Causal Loop Diagram. As the efficiency uptake

grows, the capacity per visitor, which is a weighted average of

visitors on the ELAC and SRAC adopter stocks, drops. This

triggers a competitive gap that drives more potential adopters to

either of the two A/C adopter stocks. As this happens, the system

Sc.20/12

Peak annualised growth: 8.36% Consumption annualised growth: 7.31%

Sc.120/36

Sc.200/0

Peak annualised growth: 8.31% Consumption annualised growth: 7.51%

Peak annualised growth: 8.44% Consumption annualised growth: 7.88%

Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

Sc.120/36

Page 10: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

becomes ever more efficient as SRAC commercialises and

becomes the dominant option. As a result the island can afford to

expand the service to all potential adopters and still spend less

per visitor compared to the BAU case (Figure 15).

Figure 15: Service coverage Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

There is a key insight to be revealed here. In the background

modelling decisions it is assumed that the regional space cooling

average, treated as the “competition”, stays constant at 400

W/person, i.e. it has not advanced technologically (nor degraded

in quality for that matter). What effectively the simulated island

did is exactly the opposite, to innovate. And it paid off by

expanding the service to more of its visitors at the same or even

lower cost of cooling. The impact of such a strategy during a

recession in tourism arrivals is studied in the original research

but not presented in this paper.

Figure 16: Financial result of utility 120/36 vs. BAU

At the same time, the utility itself improves its finances (Figure

16 in terms of running accumulation year on year, not discounted

to any basis year). Still, as it stands in the Greek islands, it is a

reduction in financial loss rather than increase of profits that the

utility can achieve. Nonetheless, this saving could be passed to

consumers who would still need to be heavily subsidised for their

power as Figure 17 attests. The marginal cost of kWh consumed

remains well above the average electricity tariff of €0.08.

Figure 17: Total cost of kWh consumed 120/36 vs. BAU

Next, the effect of the demand side intervention on the tourism

industry and most importantly the utility‟s financial performance

is presented.

4.3 The impact on tourism & utility finances Continuing the view into the positive impacts of the diffusion

intervention, the potential benefits to the tourism industry are

briefly looked into although a fully fledged CBA is not

undertaken. Figure 18 compares the average monthly

consumption of electricity per tourist between the BAU and

Sc.120/36 as an example. At month 241, roughly eleven years

after the scheme‟s introduction (eight after completion), the

saving to the industry due to the drop of the average electricity

consumption is estimated at about €70,000 a year. This comes to

about €12 per visitor a month or £3 per visitor a week. It seems

like a small amount but if a one-week package holiday to the

island is to cost a random €50 less per visitor per week than

offered by a comparable competing destination, the electricity

saving would represent 6% of that discount. For a family of four

on a two-week package, the total saving would be a significant

€400 of which 6% is already sizeable enough considering it is

only concerning power efficiency of the A/C service in the basket

of services holiday-makers are receiving. Further elaboration into

pricing strategy for tourism is far from the paper‟s immediate

aims.

As the industry is becoming more competitive, less consumption

means fewer sales for the utility operator, a possible fear of

policy-makers in introducing energy efficiency. And it might be.

However, the specific socio-economic conditions where such

measures are applied should be considered.

Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

Page 11: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

Figure 18: Tourist average consumption Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

Figure 19: Household average consumption Sc.120/36 vs.

BAU

For example, the nature of households‟ power consumption

behaviour, as well as the population and income dynamics

described actually cause a rise in the monthly consumption

(Figure 19) when DSM schemes to the commercial sector are

introduced. Still, the effect of efficiency is definite as in Figure

20. In Figure 21, indeed sales drop (top graph) but costs even

more so (bottom graph).

Figure 20: Consumed power Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

Figure 21: Utility sales & costs Sc.120/36 vs. BAU

The original research of this paper looked into more impacts of

the diffusion scenarios on the system such as the savings

achieved and the break even point of the programmes, the utility

cost components and the cost of SRAC a.o. It also performed a

series of what-if tests to assess behaviour under extreme events.

These can be found on past and forthcoming publications by the

author.

5. Conclusions The paper elaborated on the key causes of the demand peaks on a

set of autonomous islands and found that summer tourism

demand is to blame for most of the financial burden. It establish

an understanding of the link between cooling comfort, visitor

arrivals and utility finances, explored causality and studied

appropriate energy policy design for technology diffusion.

Examining the CLD, destination competitiveness is introduced as

an exogenous factor. While the model could examine the impact

of policy intervention on a variety of energy services, the

research‟s aim is to explore and establish the validity of the

approach and the development and application of a methodology

rather than delivering an optimisation. Thus, the research

focussed on a single service, i.e. cooling comfort. Expanding the

ensuing methodology to more energy services and/or

environmental impacts as well as applying the methodology to

other islands or sets of islands and SIDS is a suggestion to

further research.

Sc.120/36

Sc.120/36

Sc.120/36

Sc.120/36

Sc.120/36

Page 12: Controlling the electricity demand surge in the Greek ... · appraisal and a potential tool for the economic assessments of interventions in the energy-environment systems of islands

6. REFERENCES [1] PIFS "Conclusions and recommendations from the Workshop

on Sustainable Energy Policies and Strategies for Pacific Island

Developing States", Pacific Islands Forum Secretariat, ed., Suva,

Fiji, 4-5 February 2002

[2] WTO & Todd, G. 2003, WTO background paper on climate

change and tourism, World Trade Organisation, Spain

[3] Chandra, R. Planning for sustainable development on the

Pacific Islands. www.geic.or.jp/islands/docs/rajesh.html . 2009.

Global Environment Information Centre

[4] Kaldellis, J K and Zafirakis, D (2007) 'Present situation and

future prospects of electricity generation in Aegean Archipelago

islands' Energy Policy. Vol.35(9), pp.4623-4639

[5] PPC 2006, Annual review programme of the island

autonomous power plants (2005) Athens

[6] RAE. www.rae.gr . 9/2007. Regulatory Authority for Energy

[7] ICAP 2008, Sectoral Review: Air-Conditioning Units, ICAP,

Athens

[8] HTSO 2008, Draft Development Plan for the Electric Grid

2008-2012, Hellenic Transmission System Operator, Athens

[9] Balaras, C. A., Santamouris, M., Asimakopoulos, D. N.,

Argiriou, A. A., Paparsenos, G., & Gaglia, A. G. 1999, "Energy

policy and an option plan for renewable energy sources (RES) for

the Hellenic islands of the North Aegean region", Energy, vol.

24, no. 1999, pp. 335-350

[10] Daskalaki, E., Balaras, C. A., & Tsagrasoulis, A. 2003,

"Cooling, Refrigeration & Air-Conditioning," in Analysis of

Energy Systems, 5 ed, C. A. Balaras, ed., Technical Institute of

Piraeus

[11] Energy Work Group 2003, Greek Technology Foresight

Programme: Energy - First Report, General Secretariat for R&D,

Athens, October 2003

[12] Mihalakakou, G., Santamouris, M., & Kovras, H. 2001,

"Energy design investigation for the Greek area of the North

Aegean Sea", Renewable Energy, vol. 24, no. 2001, pp. 171-183

[13] Bakos, G. C. 2002, "Feasibility study of a hybrid wind/hydro

power-system for low-cost electricity production", Applied

Energy, vol. 72, no. 2002, pp. 599-608

[14] Betzios, G. 2003a, "Integrated energy supply systems for

Green Islands towards 100% RES penetration", EREC, Crete,

Greece, pp. 45-52

[15] PPC 2002, Annual review programme of the island

autonomous power plants (2001), PPC, Athens

[16] IENE 2008, "Conference on the Energy Problem of the

Cyclades: Critical Questions & Options. Summary of

Conclusions.", Institute of Energy for South-East Europe, Athens

[17] Gravouniotis, P. “A system dynamics view of energy

demand and supply in small islands”. Proceedings of the 21st

International Conference of the System Dynamics Society. New

York, 2003.

[18] Gravouniotis, P. and B. Ausilio. “Energy Equipment

Diffusion & Touristic Competitiveness: Building of an SD Model

for the Greek Islands” Proceedings of the 26th International

Conference of the System Dynamics Society. 2008.