country reviews - anpec - associação nacional dos ... · web viewwe also take a...

31
Brazil after the Great Recession: Searching for a Coherent Developmental Strategy 40° Encontro Nacional de Economia - Área 5 - Crescimento, Desenvolvimento Econômico e Instituições Philip Arestis, University of Cambridge, UK; and University of the Basque Country, Spain. Email: [email protected] André Moreira Cunha, UFRGS, and Research Fellow at CNPq, Brazil. Email: [email protected] Fernando Ferrari-Filho, UFRGS and Research Fellow at CNPq, Brazil. Email: [email protected] Julimar da Silva Bichara, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Spain. Email: [email protected] Abstract: This paper analyzes the Brazilian economy in terms of its recent performance, considering the major transformations of the global order posed by the global financial crisis and, moreover, by China´s rise. We review some historical and theoretical aspects of macroeconomic management in a developmentalist perspective. We then analyze the policy efforts to overcome the impact of the ‘Great Recession’ and to sustain the dynamism of the economy. We also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil. Our evidence and analysis suggest that development policies will only deliver consistent and positive results if the previous flaws of the policy framework, inherited from the neoliberal period, are reversed. Key Words: Great Recession, Brazil, macroeconomic and development policies, structural change. JEL: O2; O11; O54 Resumo: O presente trabalho analisa o desempenho recente da economia brasileira a partir das transformações na ordem internacional derivadas da crise financeira global e, principalmente, da ascensão da China. Parte-se de uma revisão teórica e histórica da gestão macroeconômica em uma perspectiva desenvolvimentista. Na sequência são analisados os esforços de política econômica empregados para enfrentar a “grande recessão” e sustentar o dinamismo da economia. São apresentadas evidências empíricas de que o Brasil experimenta um

Upload: trantu

Post on 09-Mar-2018

226 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Brazil after the Great Recession: Searching for a Coherent Developmental Strategy40° Encontro Nacional de Economia - Área 5 - Crescimento, Desenvolvimento Econômico e Instituições

Philip Arestis, University of Cambridge, UK; and University of the Basque Country, Spain. Email: [email protected]é Moreira Cunha, UFRGS, and Research Fellow at CNPq, Brazil. Email: [email protected] Ferrari-Filho, UFRGS and Research Fellow at CNPq, Brazil. Email: [email protected] da Silva Bichara, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid, Spain. Email: [email protected]

Abstract: This paper analyzes the Brazilian economy in terms of its recent performance, considering the major transformations of the global order posed by the global financial crisis and, moreover, by China´s rise. We review some historical and theoretical aspects of macroeconomic management in a developmentalist perspective. We then analyze the policy efforts to overcome the impact of the ‘Great Recession’ and to sustain the dynamism of the economy. We also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil. Our evidence and analysis suggest that development policies will only deliver consistent and positive results if the previous flaws of the policy framework, inherited from the neoliberal period, are reversed.

Key Words: Great Recession, Brazil, macroeconomic and development policies, structural change.

JEL: O2; O11; O54

Resumo: O presente trabalho analisa o desempenho recente da economia brasileira a partir das transformações na ordem internacional derivadas da crise financeira global e, principalmente, da ascensão da China. Parte-se de uma revisão teórica e histórica da gestão macroeconômica em uma perspectiva desenvolvimentista. Na sequência são analisados os esforços de política econômica empregados para enfrentar a “grande recessão” e sustentar o dinamismo da economia. São apresentadas evidências empíricas de que o Brasil experimenta um padrão regressivo de mudança estrutural, o que nos leva a concluir que políticas desenvolvimentistas só serão capazes de produzir resultados robustos se houver uma reversão do arcabouço de políticas herdado do período neoliberal.

Palavra-Chave: Grande Recessão, Brasil, Políticas macroeconômicas e desenvolvimentistas, Mudança estrutural

Page 2: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Brazil after the Great Recession: Searching for a Coherent Developmental Strategy

1. Introduction

Since the late 1990s conventional economic wisdom has been challenged by the increasing instability of the financial markets and the emergence of new economic powers that have not been strictly following the so-called Washington Consensus, particularly China and India. In this context, the global financial crisis, which began in August 2007, and induced the ‘Great Recession’ (GR), has substantially altered the dynamic process of the international economy. Governments of advanced and emerging countries have responded to the GR with massive fiscal and monetary stimulus, by rescuing financial and non-financial corporations and by reintroducing a more hands on approach to deal with the economic problems (Griffith-Jones, Ocampo and Stiglitz, 2010; Arestis, Sobreira and Oreiro, 2011). Brazil is not an exception. Alongside the countercyclical policies aimed at smoothing the negative impacts of the external environment, the central government has been trying to implement more active developmental policies.

This paper discusses and analyses this new landscape. Our main contribution is to discuss the recent economic performance of Brazil, the country involved with major transformation of the global order. We argue that Brazil has to face at least three interconnected major issues: firstly, it must re-orient its macroeconomic policy in line with the new global environment of higher financial instability and less buoyant markets; secondly, it has to establish a new development strategy to cope with the challenges posed by China´s rise as a global power; and, thirdly, this development strategy must inform the government´s other policies, including macroeconomic policies, in order to avoid the lack of coherence and strength that have characterized previous efforts to push the Brazilian economy on a sustainable path of economic growth.

We proceed as follows: after this Introduction we review some historical and theoretical aspects of macroeconomic management from a developmentalist perspective; we then analyze the Brazilian economic performance and the policy efforts to overcome the impact of the GR and to sustain the dynamism of the economy; we take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive patter of structural change in Brazil; the final section summarises and concludes.

2. Historical and Theoretical BackgroundWe argue in this section that the heterodox traditions – from Keynes (1964) to the Developmental

State paradigm (Khan and Christiansen, 2010) – offer a better rationality and way to the reconstruction of a coherent set of policies designed to develop an emerging country such as Brazil. There are historical and theoretical arguments that support this position.

Between the 1820s and 1930s, Latin American countries followed an outward development model, based on production and trade specialisation in agriculture and mining. As showed by Unctad (2003), the export-led model based on agriculture and mining did not deliver stability, self-sustained growth and the modernization of the institutions and the economy.1 During this period the region experienced fiscal and external imbalances, which had to be financed by volatile capital flows, thanks to the fact that the export sector, mainly dependent on commodities, was incapable of generating enough hard currency to finance the merchandise imports demand and other financial commitments. Capital flow reversals were frequent, and government used to be pressured by creditors to promote deflationary adjustments in domestic income and absorption.

As stressed by Prebisch (1984) and Furtado (1964), between the second half of the nineteenth century and the first decades of the twentieth century, the business cycles of Latin American peripheral

1 According to the Unctad (2003): “During the first 100 years of its independence, Latin America sought rapid and close integration into the world economy, pursuing a policy of what is now called outward-oriented development in conditions of highly volatile capital flows and periodic financial crises ... Despite success in expanding exports, trade was unable to act as an engine of industrialization and growth within the region because the export sector in most countries was not sufficiently large ... Even those countries that were relatively successful in expanding the industrial sector could not translate these gains into growth of manufactured exports” (p. 129).

2

Page 3: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

countries were tightly correlated with the core countries business cycles, led by Great Britain, the then hegemonic power. Industrialisation and urbanisation at the core increased the demand for natural resources at the periphery, which helped to improve the terms of trade. In such a context commodities price cycles and financial cycles, both exogenously determined, have always been essential for the internal economic dynamics in Latin America.

The interwar crisis opened the room for a radical change. The breakdown of the global trading system, the collapse of the gold standard, the outbreak of the Second War, and the hegemonic transition from Great Britain to the United States brought to an end the export-oriented model. Latin American countries started to manufacture goods previously imported from the ‘centre’, in a process lately named ‘import substitution’. The ‘development from within’, led by the State, generated reasonable results until its crisis in 1980s.

This historical background informs many contemporary commentators, who have been arguing that in order to recover its capacity to grow in a sustainable way, Brazil and other emerging countries should adopt a new developmental approach, where the State would resume an activist role (Sicsú et al., 2005; Cimoli et al., 2009; Peres and Primi, 2009; Khan and Christiansen, 2010; Carneiro, 2010; Bresser-Pereira, 2011; De Paula, 2011). There is no consensus on how to name this new strategy or about how far should the State go to manage the economy.2 In common these analysts share a critical perspective on economic orthodoxy and inherit the insights of heterodox traditions rotted in the works of Keynes (1964), Schumpeter (1961), Prebisch (1984) and Kaldor (1967), among others, and, also, in the more recent Development State paradigm (Khan and Christiansen, 2010). Therefore, they are all critics of the Washington Consensus and its corollary, the so called New Consensus Macroeconomic (NCM), which, prior to the global financial crisis, was considered by orthodoxy as the only set of macroeconomic policies to be adopted by advanced and emerging countries (Arestis and Sawyer, 2010).

This historical summary is important to our argument for at least two main reasons. Firstly, the first generation of development economists produced their theories under the influence of the crisis on the liberal order and the new belief in State activism. Macroeconomic and development policies at both centre and peripheral countries were set to overcome what was then perceived as structural flaws of free markets. It took at least two generations until the hegemonic return of neoliberal arguments and policies. Secondly, some structural features of the outward oriented model pursued by Latin American countries, particularly the overdependence on production and export of natural resources, returned in the early twenty-first century. Differently from the previous period, countries like Brazil are not fighting to industrialize their economies, but, instead, they are trying to avoid re-primarization of their exports and deindustrialization.3

Contemporary policymakers must deal with a crucial task of coordinating the short-term requirements of stabilisation policies with the long-term requirements of the development process, in a context of globalisation and instability. Economic orthodoxy used to offer simple answers to very complex problems. Therefore, growth would be achieved by market forces, and governments should only guarantee sound money and ‘good governance’ (Arestis and Sawyer, 2010). In short, one should follow the Washington Consensus and its corollary, the NCM. Unfortunately, policymakers in peripheral countries, despite their ideological commitment with orthodoxy, face more blurred and complex realities.

There is, of course, the Keynesian framework, which provides better anchors for policymakers who want to promote stability and growth.4 The reconciliation between short – and long – run policy

2 Bresser-Pereira (2011) argues that the ‘new developmentalism’ would be an alternative strategy to both conventional orthodoxy and the old-style Latin American national developmentalism.3 It refers to the composition of exports, where raw materials share on total exports surpass manufacturing products share, particularly technology-intensive products. Therefore,‘re-primarization’ cum deindustrialization represents a perverse structural change which tends to reduce the income elasticity of exports and to increase the income elasticity of imports (Bresser-Pereira, 2009 and 2010; Oreiro and Feijó, 2010). 4 See, among others: King (2003; 2008); Harcourt (2008); and Davidson (2011). King (2008) summarizes the origins of the Post Keynesian view as follows “The origins of Post Keynesian economics may be traced back to the publication of the General Theory in 1936, since Keynes's masterpiece was open from the outset to alternative interpretations ... One of them, the

3

Page 4: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

goals could be attained because Keynesian tradition has been developed to deal with two majors issues: (i) in the short run, macroeconomic policies should stabilize demand levels in order to guarantee full employment; and (ii) in the long run, development policies must create a social and economic environment, where private wealth creation is compatible with a reasonable pattern of income distribution. Therefore, Keynesian policies go far beyond short-term stabilization policies, encompassing a developmental perspective with a strong moral reasoning: economic growth must be considered as a mean to an ultimate end, which is to promote an affluent (and less unequal) society.5

Harcourt (2008), Dutt (2010), Taylor (2004 and 2011), among others, emphasize that Keynesian growth theory has evolved from the original insights of Keynes (1964).6 Accordingly, a capitalist economy is a monetary economy where aggregate demand plays a crucial role in determining the levels of output and employment. Such an economy is characterized, inter alia, by the fact that the decision-making behaviour of individuals occur in an uncertain environment. Therefore, decisions are affected by psychological factors.7 Unemployment is not necessarily a temporary phenomenon and employment is determined in production markets rather than in labour markets. Fearing the future individuals can increase they demand for money or highly liquid assets and, as a consequence, private demand for consumer goods and investment goods might not be sufficient to guarantee full employment. In an uncertain environment money is not neutral and macroeconomic policies can affect the levels of income and employment, both in the short and the long term. Keynesian growth models share at least one main feature: aggregate demand is a key determinant of the long-term pace of economic growth (Dutt, 2010, p. 42). Other traditions, classical and neoclassical, are supply-driven and consider that economic growth is explained by the accumulation of factors of production – capital and labour – and the efficiency (or productivity) in their use.

Keynesian economic policy, in both conception and practice, is intended to maintain levels of effective demand for the purpose of mitigating involuntary unemployment by stabilizing business peoples’ state of confidence.8 The focus of Keynes (1964; see, also, Skidelsky, 2009) proposal was the power that the State should hold to steer the economic system, given that, if left to the free workings of market, the economic system and economic policies themselves – unless there was coordination among them – would contribute not to solving, but to enlarging the main problems of monetary production economies.

On this particular issue, Keynesian economic policies are structured so as to make it possible to manage endogenous features in monetary, fiscal and exchange rate policies (Arestis and Sawyer, 2010;

IS–LM model developed by J. R. Hicks, James Meade and others, subsequently formed the core of the neoclassical synthesis model of output and employment in the short run. However, the Cambridge (UK) Post Keynesians, including Richard Kahn, Nicholas Kaldor, Joan Robinson and Piero Sraffa, directed their early criticisms against the long-run component of the neoclassical synthesis, the Solow growth model, in which full employment was ensured by capital–labour substitution along a well-behaved aggregate production function. The ‘Cambridge capital controversies’ of the late 1950s and early 1960s demonstrated the analytical failure of neoclassical growth theory, and were an important episode in the emergence of the Post Keynesian school... Subsequently Robinson, Kaldor and the American Sidney Weintraub attacked the monetarist theory of inflation, emphasizing the causal role of the rate of change of money wages and arguing that monetary growth was the effect of inflation, not its cause. Kaldor, Weintraub and another American, Paul Davidson, were early advocates of the theory of endogenous money.” (pp. 2-3). Harcourt (2008) argues that “Post-Keynesianism is an extremely broad church. The overlaps of each end of a long spectrum of view are marginal (sic), often reflecting a little more than a shared hostility towards mainstream neoclassical economics and methodology ...” (p. 2).5 For a detailed analysis of the Keynesian framework see Keynes (1964), Minsky (1986), Davidson (2011), Harcourt (2008), and Arestis and Sawyer (2010). Extensions and contributions from convergent traditions, particularly the Latin American structuralism, can be obtained in Prebisch (1984), Furtado (1964), Peres and Primi (2009), Tregenna (2009) and Palma (2007, 2011).6 Nevertheless, as Dutt (2010) points out: “... Keynes´s theory had much in common with the earlier dynamic theories of economists like Malthus and Marx, and, indeed, with some of his contemporaries, most notably Kalecki” (p. 41).7 Taylor (2011) suggests that “Fundamental uncertainty, the absence of Say´s Law, and the presence of tensions between collective social actors characterized Keynesian economics” (p. 215).8 Keynes (1964) proposed a new social philosophy in order to address the fact that “[t]he outstanding faults of the economic society in which we live are its failure to provide for full employment and its arbitrary and inequitable distribution of wealth and incomes” (p. 372).

4

Page 5: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Taylor, 2004, 2010; Davidson, 2011). Nowadays, the globalization process tends to disrupt not only domestic markets but also whole countries, especially emerging countries, by establishing a kind of extended financial casino; the current international financial crisis is a good example to the nature and problems of the globalization process.9

In a Keynesian perspective, the achievement of full employment must be considered a major goal for economic policy.10 For that purpose, Keynes (1964, chapter 24), after identifying the main faults of the entrepreneur economies, that are “its failure to provide for full employment and its arbitrary and inequitable distribution of wealth and incomes” (p.372), suggests fiscal policy to be used, which through the multiplier effect, and the community’ propensity to consume, as well as low interest rates to stimulate investment and to promote “the euthanasia of the rentier” (p.376), and “a (…) comprehensive socialisation of investment” (p. 378) should assure full employment. Going in this direction, de Carvalho (1992) argues that, in a Keynesian perspective, “[f]ull employment policies should be implemented by the combination of (…) fiscal policies, income policies and monetary policies.11 Fiscal policy should be designed to obtain global long-term employment stability; income policies should obtain price stability; Monetary policy would then have the role (…) of preventing changes in the state of liquidity preference (…)’ (p. 212). Thus, the macroeconomic policy of national economies should be coordinated in such a way as to (i) operationalize fiscal policies designed to expand effective demand and reduce social inequalities; (ii) make for more flexible monetary policy so as to galvanize levels of consumption and investment; and (iii) coordinate and regulate financial and foreign exchange markets in order to stabilize capital flows and exchange rates. In short, taking up the idea of Minsky (1986), there is a need for State intervention and regulation through Big Government and Big Bank.

The State is the social entity capable of gathering together the greatest amount of the information available in society and, at the same time, it is the social legislator with legal competence to safeguard institutions’ ongoing existence and to alter them as required by the evolution of the different social systems. It is, thus, up to the State, for the collective good and not for private interest, to coordinate economic activity. In an uncertain world, where agents risk their power of command over social wealth in order to gain more such power in the future, economic policy should be the greatest source of solidity for private enterprise. It should guarantee the dynamics of increasing wealth which, consequently, maintains and expands the society’s inclination to consume, thus enhancing investors’ prospects.12

Sharing convergent insights and stimulated by the major historical transformation of the first half of the twenty century, the first generation of development economists used to think in terms of structural problems. This means some characteristics of a country that undermines its potential to advance in the same supposed ‘natural path of development’ once followed by the rich countries. In this context, Keynesians and other heterodox economists13 assumed that investment is a key determinant of income expansion. Moreover, for Keynesians the economic growth process is not sector-indifferent or linear and stable. That is, manufacturing matters and governments must have an active role to support structural transformations (Palma, 2007; Tregenna, 2009). The so-called Kaldor’s laws (Kaldor, 1967; Thirlwall, 2011) express how import the manufacturing sector is. Accordingly, this sector has special growth-enhancing characteristics, where it would be possible to identify a strong connection between the rate of growth in manufacturing and the total income growth, which is the Kaldor’s (1967) first growth law. The second law, known as Verdoorn’s law (Verdoon, 1949), suggests that because of static – thanks to

9 For a more detailed discussion of the globalization process and the global financial crisis, see: Griffith-Jones, Ocampo and Stiglitz (2010) and Arestis, Sobreira and Oreiro (2011).10 “The achievement of full employment is a widely accepted major policy objective for Post Keynesian economists, and policies and institutional arrangements supportive of high levels of demand are advocated” Sawyer (2008, p. 101). See, also, King (2003; 2008); Arestis and Sawyer (2011, chapter 3); and Davidson (2011).11 For a recent assessment of Keynesian income policies see, among others, Sawyer (2008); and Davidson (2011, chapters 10, 17 and 18).12 On this point, Minsky (1986) argues that “[i]f the market mechanism is to function well, we must arrange to constrain the uncertainty due to business cycles so that the expectations that guide investment can reflect a vision of tranquil progress”. (p. 6)13 Particularly in Keynesian, Kaldorian and Latin American Structuralist traditions (see, among others, Palma, 2007; Tregenna, 2009; and Thirlwall (2011).

5

Page 6: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

economies of scale – and dynamic economic returns derived from capital accumulation, technological progress and learning by doing, the productivity of the manufacturing sector is positively related the growth of the manufacturing sector. The third law claims that there is a positive relationship between the productivity of the non-manufacturing sector and the growth of the manufacturing sector (Kaldor, 1967; Thirlwall, 2011).

Emphasizing this point, the higher the growth of the manufacturing sector and its productivity, the higher will be the growth of the whole economy and the productivity of other economic sectors. Further arguments are relevant: Hirschman (1958), who claims that manufacturing leads economic growth thanks to its backward and forward linkages to other sectors; Kaldor (1967), Robinson (1962) and Schumpeter (1961) who stress that technological progress has, at least in a certain extent, an endogenous dynamics associated with the capital accumulation led by the manufacturing sector; and by Prebisch-Singer14 and Kaldor-Thirwall15, who link income-elasticity differences in manufacturing products and natural resource-intensive products to balance of payments constraints to economic growth. The latter is in a context where primary-product prices tend to decline in relation to manufacture product prices in the long run. It is also possible to argue that in order to achieve growth-cum-stability, governments must prioritize the industrialization process or to avoid the de-industrialization one.

Based on these historical and theoretical arguments we analyze the recent performance of the Brazilian economy in the next two sections.

3. The Recent Performance of the Brazilian Economy After three decades of rapid economic growth and modernization, between 1950s and 1980s,

Brazil experienced a quarter of a century of semi-stagnation and instability. Hoping to overcome macroeconomic imbalances, governments abandoned the developmental strategies outlined in section 2 and adopted market-friendly structural reforms inspired by the Washington Consensus. Despite the success in controlling high inflation, the expectations of development were not fully fulfilled (Arestis and Saad-Filho, 2008; De Paula, 2010).

Table 1 explores the main characteristics of recent Brazilian governments (Fernando Henrique Cardoso, Lula da Silva and Dilma Rousseff). It shows a non-exhaustive recollection of policies and indicators. Due to lack of space we focus on the coherence, or lack of it, between macroeconomic and development policies, instead of a detailed analysis of each policy.16

Table 1. Main Policies and Outcomes – Brazil, 1995-2011

14 See Prebisch (1984) and Thirlwall (2011).15 See Thirlwall (2011).16 For details see, among others: Arestis, De Paula and Ferrari-Filho (2007); Arestis and Saad Filho (2008); Bresser-Pereira (2009 and 2010); Carneiro (2010); De Paula (2010).

6

Page 7: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Presidency Policies Economic Performance Fernando Henrique Cardoso

Main characteristic: coherence

between macroeconomic and development policies, both

mainly following the Washington Consensus Paradigm

1995-1998

Real Plan (1994/1995); Financial Crises – Mexico (1995), Asia

(1998), Russia and LTCM (1998) 1999-2002

Inflation Target Regime (1999); Financial Crises (2000-2002) –

Argentina, Dotcom Bubble, 9/11.

Macroeconomic Policy: mainly orthodox (new consensus macroeconomic). Focus on monetary stabilization (Real Plan) thorough exchange rate based strategy (1995-1998) and the introduction of inflation target regime (1999 – present). Fiscal surpluses and free floating exchange rate regime (from 1999 onwards). IMF stabilization plans: 1998-2002. Procyclical policies during financial crises

Main outcomes 1995-2002 GDP growth average: 2.3% Real Interest Rates*, Average (%): 58% Inflation rate average (IPCA): 9.2% Credit/GDP (Average): 23% General government net debt/GDP (2002): 60.6% General government net lending/borrowing (Average, % of GDP): -4.9% Current Account/GDP average: -3.3% Exports (US$ billion): 1995: 46 2002: 60 Gini Index 2002: 0.589 P&D/GDP (1996-2002 Average): 0.9% Poverty line in 2002: 26.7% Health expenditure, public (% of GDP - average): 3.0% Public spending on education, total (% of GDP): 4.1%

Development Policy: Washington Consensus type of structural reforms: privatization, deregulation, financial sector reform, capital account liberalization, administrative reform, private sector pension reform, fiscal responsibility law, etc.

Luiz Ignácio Lula da Silva Main characteristic: lack of

coherence between macroeconomic and development policies

2003-2006

Buoyant international markets (2003-2008); China´s rise

2007-2010

Global Financial Crisis

Macroeconomic Policy: mainly orthodox (new macroeconomic consensus). Inflation target regime, fiscal surpluses, free floating regime. From 2006 onwards, particularly after the global financial crisis, pragmatism and countercyclical policies.

Main outcomes 2003-2011 GDP growth average: 3.9% Real Interest Rates*, Average (%): 40% Inflation rate average (IPCA): 5.9% Credit/GDP (Average): 36% General government net debt/GDP (2011): 36.4% General government net lending/borrowing (Average, % of GDP): -3.1% Current Account/GDP (average): -0.2% Exports (US$ billion): 2003: 73 2011: 256 Gini Index 2011: 0.541 P&D/GDP (2003-2008 Average): 1% Poverty line 2011: 12.8% Health expenditure, public (% of GDP - average): 3.5% Public spending on education, total (% of GDP): 4.8%

Development Policies: income distribution (“Bolsa Família”, real increase in minimum wage, job creation); recovery in public investments (PAC and Minha Casa, Minha Vida); proactive external policy; credit expansion, particularly through state owned banks (BNDES, BB and CEF).

Dilma Rousseff 2011 – Present

Main Characteristics: in search for coherence between macroeconomic and development policies

Macroeconomic policy: Coordination between monetary and fiscal policy; pragmatism within the police framework inherited from Cardoso and Lula da Silva´s governments. Macroprudential regulation and mild capital controls. Development policy: More activism. Widening and deepening of Lula´s policies; industrial, innovative and trade policies (“Plano Brasil Maior”).

Source: Author´s elaboration based on: (i) Ministry of Finance (2012a; 2012b); (ii) Brazilian Central Bank (www.bcb.gov.br); (iii) IPEADATA (www.ipeadata.gov.br); (iv) World Bank (http://data.worldbank.org/); and (v) IMF Word Economic Outlook Database, April 2012 (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/index.aspx). Access on 25/04/ 2012. Note: (*) Real interest rate is the lending interest rate adjusted for inflation as measured by the GDP deflator.

We observe that Fernando Henrique Cardoso´s two terms were broadly coherent, pursuing a Washington Consensus type of strategy. The first Lula da Silva’s term mainly followed Cardoso in macroeconomic policies, while his second term introduced more ambitious development policies.17 That is to say, Lula da Silva´s kept the macroeconomic framework based on the inflation targeting regime, the

17 See, among others: Paulani (2008); Carvalho (2008); Bresser-Pereira (2009); and Serrano and Summa (2011).

7

Page 8: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

target for primary budget surplus and the flexible exchange rate in a context of free capital mobility. Nevertheless, his government reinforced income distribution policies.18

The orthodox macroeconomic policies followed by Fernando Henrique Cardoso and Lula da Silva resembled the New Consensus Macroeconomics. Monetary policy had a deflationary bias, where rising interest rates to control domestic demand was the main way to keep inflation under control. The consequences of high interest rates were: (i) a serious constraint on economic growth, through the price of credit and entrepreneurs’ poor expectations and; (ii) it increased public debt, which was formed mainly by indexed bonds or short-term fixed rate bonds, and currency overvaluation. Dominated by the goal of obtaining an average primary surplus of 3.25% of GDP in order to maintain some fiscal balance and to stabilize the public debt, fiscal policy did not really pursue austerity. In fact, in all the years that the government set targets for primary surpluses, it was not saving anything, but it was substituting payments for rentiers with public investment and social programs. The modus operandi of the inflation targeting regime plus the adoption of a floating exchange rate regime, under the conditions of full liberalisation of the capital account, resulted in volatility of the nominal exchange rate and the appreciation of the real exchange rate.

Due to the economic policy strategy based on inflation targeting, an increased primary surplus target and flexible exchange rate, Brazil’s GDP performance was poor: from 2003 to 2006, the average growth rate of Brazil was, approximately, 3.5% per year. Moreover, the inflation rate was maintained at high level in relation to other inflation targeting countries, averaging 6.4% per year. In 2007, at the start of Lula de Silva’s second mandate, economic policy – and particularly fiscal policy – underwent a slight change. At that time, however, the Brazilian Central Bank (BCB) continued to operate monetary policy in such a way as to meet inflation targets; fiscal policy was directed at supporting the implementation of the Growth Acceleration Programme (PAC).19 In addition, Brazil and most other emerging countries benefited from higher commodity prices, which contributed both to their achieving significant current account surpluses and accumulating international reserves.

Lula da Silva’s response to the global financial crisis (GFC) represented an important shift from previous episodes of crises, where central government pursued procyclical policies, usually within the framework of the IMF stabilization programs. The central government responded to the contagion effect with a broad variety of counter-cyclical economic measures.20 The Brazilian Central Bank (BCB) eased monetary policy by lowering the policy rate and by increasing liquidity in the interbank market. State-owned banks – Brazilian Development Bank (BNDES), Banco do Brasil (BB) and Caixa Econômica Federal (CEF) – were oriented to supply credit to the economy, in a context where private banks (national and foreign) became reluctant to expand credit facilities to consumers and corporations. Fiscal policy was expansionary, aiming at boosting aggregate demand and mitigating the negative impact of the crisis on the level of economic activity through three major channels: additional government spending, tax cuts and subsidies. The rise in government spending covered, among other things: (i) an expansion of the Growth Acceleration Programme (PAC); (ii) the start up of a programme of government incentives and subsidies for housing construction, called Minha Casa, Minha Vida (‘My House, My Life’), targeted at low and middle-income households; (iii) budget transfers to municipalities; (iv) extension of unemployment insurance benefits; and (v) real increase in minimum wage. Beyond the stimulus package, the Brazilian government also adopted other counter-cyclical macroeconomic policies, as well as labour policies and sector specific measures.

18 For example: (i) minimum wage increased 66% in real terms from 2002-2012, reaching the highest level in four decades;(ii) income transfers to families, including ‘Bolsa Família’, reached an amount of 8.6% of GDP in 2011; it was 6.8% of GDP in 2002. In terms of the composition of central government spending, the Ministry of Finance (2012a) states that “From 2002 to 2011, primary spending rose from 15.7% of GDP to 17.5% of GDP. The increase is mainly explained by income transfers, which increased 1.8 pp in the period ... Investment and education spending also grew respectively by 0.2 pp and 0.3 pp of GDP since 2002. On the other hand, payroll costs and other expenses have been reduced.” (p.83). Moreover, since 2003 the economy has created more than 17.3 million formal jobs” (p. 34).19 PAC had three main objectives: stimulate private investment; increase government investment in infrastructure; and remove the main obstacles to economic growth (bureaucracy, inadequate norms and regulation). 20 See, Cunha et al. (2011) and Ministry of Finance (2012a, 2012b).

8

Page 9: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

As a result of the economic policy ‘flexibility’, as well as the policy response to the international financial crisis in 2009, the Brazilian average growth rate increased over the period 2007-2010 by 4.5% per year.21 Regarding the inflation rate over the same period, it, surprisingly, decreased to an average rate of 5.1% per year. Domestic demand sustained economic growth, while inflation behaviour was mainly influenced by the sharp fall in the commodity prices in the second half of 2008, by the deceleration of the domestic economy in 2008 (last quarter) and 2009 and by the domestic currency appreciation in 2009 and 2010.22

It is important to stress that, on the one hand, Brazil’s reaction to the international financial crisis, although rather delayed, was successful because Brazil did not have a high level of external debt (it is currently a net creditor to the international markets), the composition of its public debt improved,23

enabling the BCB to build up foreign exchange reserves. On the other hand, although Brazil’s economic recovery restored flows of international capital once again, it posed long-standing problems associated more with the period of prosperity. These include the tendency for the real to appreciate, affecting industry and the balance of trade,24 and, until 2010, the BCB’s predisposition to subordinate fiscal policy to the primacy of monetary policy.

In late 2010 and in 2011, the first year of Dilma Rouseff’s term, the central government faced the dilemma of going for moderate economic growth to face inflationary pressures. At the same time, the volatility in financial markets due to the euro area crisis, the competitive pressures from other countries in domestic and external markets, the lack of strength in manufacturing sector – industrial production grew only 0.3% in 2011 – the appreciation of domestic currency, the major deficiencies in infrastructure and the poor quality of public services and institutions, among other factors, have raised doubts about the prospects of the Brazilian economy. Monetary and fiscal policies were reverted to previous conventional lines and, in 2011, the Brazilian economy went through a process of growth slowdown: the GDP increased 2.7%, a modest rate and below the regional average (Ministry of Finance, 2012b).

The BCB introduced several macroprudential measures to deal with the financial markets instability, particularly the potential disruptive effects of an excessive absorption of private capital flows (Ministry of Finance, 2012b). Moreover, in order to face the development challenge, Dilma Rousseff launched her own programmes, which apparently were set to deepen Lula da Silva’s previous efforts, such as ‘PAC phase 2’25 and the Brasil Maior Plan, the new industrial policy.

It is reasonable to argue that one main feature of the period post-2006 is the lack of coherence between macroeconomic and development policies, because the latter has become more ambitious and developmentalist in nature, while the former has mainly been routed in an orthodox framework. In other words, the Brazilian economic policy is still based on monetary regime dominance (it means, inflation

21 The Ministry of Finance (2012a) summarizes the official perspective as follows: “After two decades of low economic dynamism, the progress of the Brazilian economy has been considerable in recent years. The economy entered a period of robust expansion, based on a development model focused on domestic market strengthening, with job creation and income distribution, promoting investment and expanding credit market, with inflation under control, and outstanding sound fiscal and financial systems. Thus, Brazil has reached high levels of growth, combined—in an unprecedented manner—with justice and social development. Far different from the former financial and currency crises, Brazil has vigorously faced one of the most serious and profound ongoing global crises. In the past, same magnitude crises have driven the economy into imbalances in the balance of payments, public debt increases and higher country risk perception, inhibiting new investments and damaging economic growth. Nowadays, the macroeconomic results are worthy to be recorded. From 2002 to 2012, average inflation has fallen from 15% to less than 5% per year, public debt to GDP ratio has declined by almost half, exports have risen by more than five times, poverty has shrunk by more than 50%, and the country grows twice as much as experienced in previous decades” (p. 136). Giambiagi and Pinheiro (2012) offer a critical assessment from a conventional perspective; for a heterodox view see Carneiro (2010) and Serrano and Summa (2011).22 See Banco Central do Brasil, ‘Inflation Reports’ (several issues). Available at: http://www.bcb.gov.br/?INFLAREPORT. Access on 20/06/2012. See, also, Ministry of Finance (2012a; 2012b).23 In the late 1990s and early 2000s, a considerable portion of the public debt was indexed to the exchange rate, while at present nearly all public debt is indexed to the real.24 Further details can be found in Bresser-Pereira (2010).25 The PAC 2 will invest R$ 1 trillion within 2011-2014 in infrastructure projects, where nearly 50% of the total will be directed to the energy sector and 30% housing (Minha Casa, Minha Vida). In 2011, the amounts committed to PAC reached R$ 35.4 billion, which represents a 20% increase when compared to 2010, and a 121.3% expansion between 2007 and 2011. In 2012 it is expected to reach R$ 42.6 billion. (Ministry of Finance, 2012a and 2012b).

9

Page 10: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

targeting regime). This explains why in 2010 and 2011 the BCB increased the interest rate to keep inflation under control, the government decided to increase primary surplus target and the Brazilian currency has continued its appreciation process.

It must be recognized that the economic policy introduced by the monetary authorities since the early 2011 is different from those adopted during the Lula da Silva government. The new government has tried to coordinate fiscal and monetary policy to increase the pace of interest rate reduction. It has also used State-owned banks more aggressively to boost competition in credit markets and, therefore, to reduce interest rates to consumers and corporations. The monetary authorities have adopted broader strategic capital controls to avoid the appreciation of the real.26 Finally, the new industrial policy seems to be more ambitious and reliable.27 Nevertheless, it is still not clear if Dilma Rousseff’s government will be able to deal with the contradictions of pursuing a developmentalist strategy without major changes in the underlying macroeconomic policy framework.

4. Brazil in a Sino-Centred Global Economy: Back to the Past?Brazil is a nation under construction. Recent improvements barely overcome the burden of a

quarter of a century of semi-stagnation and of centuries of a pattern of development unable to include all segments of the population (Furtado, 1992). Moreover, growth acceleration and macroeconomic performance have been associated with a regressive pattern of specialization in production and trade. These facts have raised concerns about the pattern of the relationship with China and other peripheral countries. In a context where experts have suggested that global economy would increasingly be Asian-centred in the decades to come,28 there are those who fear that Brazil and other Latin American countries will become merely satellites, trapped in a typical ‘South position’ as suppliers of natural resources and importers of manufactured products.29 This section provides some evidence in that direction.

Figure 1 illustrates that, despite the recent growth acceleration, GDP growth during the globalization era has been disappointing. As a consequence, Brazil´s share in world income has been falling since 1980. In this context, the 2004-2011 boom can be interpreted, simply, as an incipient recovery. The same is true if we look to merchandise trade. Figure 2 shows that despite the five-fold increase in nominal exports from 2001 to 2011, Brazil´s share has been basically the same since 1980. In fact, and early 1980s, Brazil, Mexico, China and Korea had similar shares in world trade. Three decades later, Brazil has basically the same share, while the others have increased their shares markedly, particularly China.

Figure 1 – Brazil’s Gross Domestic Product”: Growth and Share of the World Total

26 According to the Ministry of Finance (2012b): “Due to the great volume of capital coming into the country, the Brazilian Government decided to take some macroprudential measures in order to mitigate the effects of the strong inflows of short-term capital. The main instrument used was the Financial Transaction Tax (IOF) for some capital categories, such as investments in equities, fixed income and directs loans, depending on the term of the transaction” (p. 119).27 It comprises: (i) taxation measures, such as payroll tax benefits for specific sectors, tax (IPI) reduction and payment postponement (PIS-Cofins); (ii) government procurement for machinery and health sectors; (iii) foreign trade finance; (iv) trade defense to avoid fraud and circumvention; (v) incentives to information technology and communications sectors; (vi) the new Automotive Regime (2013-2017) with incentives to research, development and innovation; (vi) credit facilities to fund production, investment and innovation. The details can be found in Ministry of Finance (2012b).28 See: Goldman Sachs (2007) and CEPAL (2001).29 Jenkins (2010) and Phillips (2011) review the recent debate.

10

Page 11: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

1910

1914

1918

1922

1926

1930

1934

1938

1942

1946

1950

1954

1958

1962

1966

1970

1974

1978

1982

1986

1990

1994

1998

2002

2006

2010

(A) GDP growth, 1910-2011 - 10 Years Moving Average (%)

Globalisation(1980� s onwards)

National Developmentalism(1950� s to 1980� s)

2,50

2,70

2,90

3,10

3,30

3,50

3,70

3,90

4,10

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

(B) GDP based on purchasing-power-parity, 1980 - 2011 (share of world total, %)

Source: Author´s calculations based on IMF World Economic Outlook Database, April 2012. Available at: (http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2012/01/weodata/index.aspx (obtained on 25/04/2012).

Figure 2 – Merchandise Exports in Selected Economies, 1980-2010

0

50

100

150

200

250

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

(A) Exports Value - US$ Billion

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

Brazil China Korea, Republic of Mexico

(B) Share of World Total (Average, %)

1980-1985 1986-2000 2001-2010

Source: Author´s calculations based on the WTO Database. Available at: (http://stat.wto.org/StatisticalProgram/WSDBStatProgramHome.aspx?Language=E (obtained on 25/04/2012).

Contributors from different theoretical backgrounds,30 converge to the diagnosis that the lack of a robust long-term recovery in investment and productivity seem to undermine the overall performance of the economy.31 Figure 3 presents the evidences. Brazil used to be a catching-up country during its developmentalist era (1950-1980), when the level and the growth of productivity were superior to those observed in other emerging markets. Nevertheless, during the globalization era all indicators of efficiency (labour productivity and total factor productivity) and capital accumulation were disappointing.

In 2011, for instance, Gross Fixed Capital Formation reached only 19.6% of GDP, which is higher than the 16% to 17% of GDP average obtained from 2002 to 2009. Central government investment has fluctuated around 1% of GDP (Ministry of Finance, 2012a), while the empirical literature suggests that public sector should invest 5% do 7% of GDP (Spence, 2012). This relative recovery has not been enough to reach previous levels of investment – around 25% of GDP – that seems to be necessary to boost

30 Differences emerge when contributors try to explain why the country has experienced negative performance in investment and efficiency. For the sake of simplicity we should divide explanations into two groups: (i) conventional wisdom, based on neoclassical arguments, that argued sustained State intervention during the developmental era distorted the fundamental prices and the institutional environment, which reduced saving and discouraged the entrepreneurs to invest (Bacha and Bonelli, 2004; Bonelli and Pessoa, 2010; Fishlow and Bacha, 2010); (ii) alternative interpretations, mainly heterodox, argued that Brazil took the wrong policy pack since the late 1980´s, where the Washington Consensus type of reforms and policies, particularly the financial openness, introduced excessive macroeconomic volatility and weakened the State capacity to sustain investments and to stabilize the overall economy (Arestis, De Paula and Ferrari-Filho, 2007; Arestis and Saad-Filho, 2008; Bresser-Pereira, 2009; Carneiro, 2010; see, also, Palma, 2007 and 2010; Rodrik and Mcmillan, 2011).31 This should not be surprising simply because as Taylor (2011) suggests: “Economists use two key variables to analyze growth of real output per capita. One is investment, or gross fixed capital formation; the other is the rate of growth of labor productivity. Investment adds to the existing capital stock and serves as vehicle for new technologies to boost productivity” (p. 173). Moreover, Taylor (2011, pp. 177-179) shows that it is possible to generate growth accounting equations similar to those derived from Solow-Swan model based only on national income and production account numbers, where output growth is decomposed into three components: growth rates of labour, capital and a surplus. Neoclassical models use the Solovian total factor productivity growth (TFPG) as a proxy of this general surplus. Therefore “The macroeconomy can get alone without a neoclassical aggregate production function” (p. 177). Taylor (2011) also argues that “It seems moderately more enlightening to think in terms of separate rates of labor and capital productivity increase rather than bundle them up into TFGP, but mainstream economists analyzing sources of growth invariably do the latter” (p. 179).

11

Page 12: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

productive capacity in the country. In fact, Spence (op. cit.) reports that empirical literature states that investment ratio of 25% to 35% of GDP would be necessary to sustain high levels of economic growth.

The higher levels of economic growth (Figure 1) and productivity (Figure 3) observed during the period of industrialization and urbanization led by the State (the national-developmentalist era) fits in with the Kaldor´s growth laws, in the sense that the manufacturing sector dynamism spilled over to the rest of the economy (Bresser-Pereira, 2010; Carneiro, 2010). As argued by Rodrik and McMillan (2011), echoing Kaldor (1967), diversification of production and international trade structures is at the core growth of the acceleration processes. Therefore, it is not surprising that the lack of economic strength has coincided with an anaemic and unstable performance of the manufacturing sector, coupled with the ‘re-primarization’ of exports and the structural problems, such as lack of a modern infrastructure, widespread informality and so on (Rodrik and McMillan, 2011).

Figure 3 – Productivity Indicators and Investments in Selected Economies, 1960-2011

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

1950

1952

1954

1956

1958

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

(C) Labour Productivity Growth Emerging Economies (Log scale)

Brazil South Korea India China Mexico

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

1950

1952

1954

1956

1958

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

(D) Labour Productivity GrowthAdvanced Economies (Log scale)

Germany United States Japan

116 109

163

141

93

158

9889

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

Germany United States

China India Japan South Korea Brazil Mexico

(E) Total Factor Productivity - Cumulative Growth, 1990- 2009 (1990=100)

6.148 4.451 1.998 1.120

12.696 14.914

29.874

7.992 13.690

45.158

8.939 14.196

19.725

43.275

68.155

40.953

-10.000 20.000 30.000 40.000 50.000 60.000 70.000 80.000

Braz

il

Sout

h K

orea Indi

a

Chin

a

Mex

ico

Ger

man

y

Uni

ted

Stat

es

Japa

n

(A) Labour Productivity, 1960-2011 (GDP per Person Employed, in 1990 GK $)

1960 2011

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

Brazil South Korea

India China Mexico Germany Japan

(B) Labour Productivity Catching-up (United States = 100)

1950-1980 1981-2000 2001-2011

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

1982

1984

1986

1988

1990

1992

1994

1996

1998

2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

(F) Gross capital formation, 1960-2010 (% of GDP)

East Asia & Pacific (developing only) High income: OECD

Latin America & Caribbean Brazil

Source: Author´s calculation based on: (i) Productivity indicators: The Conference Board Total Economy Database™, January 2012. Available at: http://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/ (obtained on 25/04/ 2012); and (ii) Gross Capital Formation – World Bank. Available at: http://data.worldbank.org/ (obtained on 25/04/ 2012).

12

Page 13: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Figure 4 reveals that the manufacturing sector has reduced its relative share on GDP32 and on total employment (Figure 4). As stressed by Palma (2007; 2011) Brazil had apparently suffered from a premature deindustrialisation. In 1980 Brazil had the largest manufacturing sector among developing countries, ranked in the eighth position with a 2.6% percent of the world total production. To put it in perspective, China ranked twelfth, with 1.7%, and South Korea ranked twentieth-eighth with 0.6%. In 2010, Brazil ranked eleventh, behind China, South Korea, India and Mexico.33

Table 2 suggests that the exports structure also changed. Between 1997 and 2010, primary products and natural-resource-intensive manufactures increased their share in total exports from 52% to 66%, while labour and scale-intensive manufactures experienced a share reduction from 33% to 20%. These sectors have been subjected to intense competitive pressures from China and other Asian economies, both home and abroad, particularly in Latin American markets. Moreover, according to the exports concentration index, Brazilian exports have concentrated, particularly in markets located in Africa, Asia and Europe (Lélis, Cunha and Lima, 2012).

Figure 4 – Evolution of the Manufacturing Sector in Brazil 1950-2010*

Sources: United Nations Statistics Division - National Accounts; Groningen Growth and Development Centre 10-sector database, June 2007. Available at: http://www.ggdc.net (obtained on 25/04/ 2012). Note: (*) Panel A – Manufacturing Sector (% of GDP); Panel B – Manufacturing sector value added as a share of total value added; and manufacturing employment as a share of total employment.

Table 2 - Brazil´s Technological Intensity of Exports and Imports, 1997-2010 (Pavitt Taxonomy*)

1997 2010 1997 2010Primary Products 22,5% 42,6% 13,5% 14,0%Manufactures - Natural Resources-Intensive 29,3% 23,9% 19,9% 20,6%Manufactures - Labor-Intensive 10,6% 5,7% 10,3% 9,2%Manufactures - Scale-Intensive 22,0% 14,1% 17,9% 20,1%Manufactures - Specialized Suppliers 9,7% 7,0% 21,8% 19,6%Manufactures - Science-based 4,4% 4,9% 16,6% 16,4%Non Classified 1,5% 1,9% 0,0% 0,0%Total 100,0% 100,0% 100,0% 100,0%

Exports Imports

51,8% 66,5%

32,6% 19,8%

Source: Author´s estimation using Pavitt (1984) taxonomy and data from Global Trade Information Services (GTIS).

Figure 5 reveals that the manufacturing sector had an increasing external deficit between 2008 and 2011, while primary products performed a massive surplus. It vividly shows the contradictions of the recent economic recovery: global, particularly Chinese, demand stimulates natural resources trade surplus, while Chinese and other Asian countries competition both at home and abroad, in a context of

32 At current US dollars prices. Source: United Nations Statistics Division - National Accounts. Available at: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/snaama/Introduction.asp (obtained on 05/05/2012).33 See Palma (2007, 2011), but predominantly United Nations Statistics Division - National Accounts. Available at: http://unstats.un.org/unsd/snaama/Introduction.asp (obtained on 05/05/2012).

13

Page 14: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

buoyant internal markets and currency overvaluation in Brazil, has been pointed out as a source of the manufacturing sector trade deficit and de-industrialisation pressures (Bresser-Pereira, 2010; IEDI, 2011, 2012). Conventional arguments, inspired by Ricardian and neoclassical trade models,34 suggest that Brazil will be better off in this ‘re-orientation’ of its production and international trade (Bonelli and Pessoa, 2010; Fishlow and Bacha, 2010). Rich in natural resources, the country’s destiny would be to supply food, minerals and oil to old and new global powers. The heterodox perspective highlighted in section 2 argues that in order to guarantee a stable long-term development path, Brazil should not abandon the post-1930 national industrialization project. On the contrary, this should be renewed and adapted to current circumstances and challenges (Peres and Primi, 2009; Bresser-Pereira, 2010).

Figure 5 – Brazil: Trade Balance in Selected Sectors, 1989-2011 (US$ billions)78,5

-48,7

29,8

-60,0

-40,0

-20,0

0,0

20,0

40,0

60,0

80,0

100,019

89

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

2011

Natural Resources and Other Manuf. Total

Source: IEDI (2011; 2012).

Recent data suggests that Brazil in not an exception. Many Latin American countries have experienced similar trends. For instance, in 2010, primary products represented 54% of total exports in the whole region.35 Trade with Asia is particularly characterized by a North-South pattern, where Latin American countries export natural resources-intensive products and import manufactured products. Except from intra-regional trade and the Mexico-United States trade, the North-South pattern is dominant (Cepal, 2011).

Calderón (2008), Cepal (2011), Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2011), ADB (2012), among others, provide evidence for Latin American countries, including Brazil, which shows increasing links with the new emerging global power, China. As we argued in section 2, the outward oriented model followed by Brazil and most of peripheral countries until 1930s, was characterized, among other things, by the close business cycles synchronization with the core economies, particularly UK, the then hegemonic power. Urbanization and industrialization at the centre created a huge demand for food and raw materials. These economies also needed markets and investment alternatives. Both dimensions interacted in a way that amplified the reflexive and dependent nature of peripheral economies.

The following empirical exercise suggests that this might be happening again. In order to assess if Brazilian business cycle synchronization with its main trade partners is associated with the trade intensity, we use the empirical strategy pioneered by Frankel and Rose (1998) and expanded by Calderón (2008), among others. Firstly, we calculate the business cycles synchronization between Brazil and its main trade partners,36 between 1975 and 2010, measured trough the 15 year-window rolling correlations of real output fluctuations using Hodrick-Prescott and Baster-King filters.37 Secondly, we construct the bilateral trade intensity between countries i and j, in time t, using two proxies, also proposal by Frenkel and Rose (1998):

34 For full references see Thirlwall (2011).35 See ECLAC's Statistical Yearbook 2011. Available at: www.eclac.cl (obtained on 20/04/2012).36 Argentina, Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador, Paraguay, Peru, Venezuela, Uruguay, Canada, Mexico, United States, Germany, France, Holland, Italy, Spain, Angola, Algeria, Egypt, Nigeria, South Africa, Saudi Arabia, United Arab Emirates, India, Indonesia, Japan, South Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, Thailand, Philippines, Vietnam, Turkey, and Russia. They represented 63% of Brazilian total exports in 2011.37 The data of trade are of IMF, of Direction of Trade Statistics, and the GDP are of WDI-World Bank.

14

Page 15: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

I. ITT (Trade Intensity weighted by the total trade): ITTijt = (Xijt + Mijt) / (Xit + Xjt + Mit + Mjt),

Where: Xijt represents the total export of country i to country j, at time t; Xit and Mit represent the total export and import of the country i, respectively.

II. ITY (Trade Intensity weighted by GDP, represented by Y): ITYijt = (Xijt + Mijt) / (Yit + Yjt)

We further estimate equation (1), as per below, proposed by Frankel and Rose (1998), that is:

Corr (v, s)ijt = α + β ITijt + εijt (1)

Where: Corr (v, s)ijt denotes the correlation of business cycles between country i and j, at time t; IT refers to the intensity of trade, proxied by ITT or ITY; α and β are the regression coefficients to be estimated.

Figure 6 reports that the country business cycles have been much more correlated with China and other Asian economies than with the United States, Brazil´s former main trade partner. Business cycles synchronization can be explained by trade channels. Calderón (2008) found similar results considering Latin American countries in their relation to China and India. Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2011) also showed that the long-term impact of a China GDP shock on the typical Latin American economy has tripled since the mid-1990s, while the long-term impact of a US GDP shock has halved. In a recent report, the Inter-American Development Bank (IADB, 2012) assumes that the evolution of Chinese economy has become increasingly important to the region.

Figure 6 – Business Cycles Synchronization between Brazil and Its Main Trade Partners, 1975-2010*

-1

-0,8

-0,6

-0,4

-0,2

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

1

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980

1981

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Chile Japão China Venezuela Coreia do Sul

-1

-0,8

-0,6

-0,4

-0,2

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

1

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

Itá lia Alemanha GB Rússia Holanda

-1

-0,8

-0,6

-0,4

-0,2

0

0,2

0,4

0,6

0,8

1

1975

1977

1979

1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

1991

1993

1995

1997

1999

2001

2003

2005

2007

2009

Argentina França Espanha EUA

Source: Authors´ calculations based on the ‘World Development Indicators’. Available at: http://data.worldbank.org (obtained on 10/01/2012. Note: (*) 15 Year-Window Rolling Correlations of real output fluctuations using Hodrick-Prescott filter.

Table 3 reports the results of our regressions: β was statically significant in our four estimations. We use two filters (Baster-King and Hodrick-Prescott) and two different proxies for trade intensity (ITT and ITY). According to the underlying literature, a positive β suggests that higher trade intensity reinforce business cycles synchronization. Considering this piece of evidence and previous trade performance indicators, it should be the case that in the Brazilian case there is a specialization trend typical of the North-South pattern, more precisely exporting natural-resources and importing manufactured products. Our results confirm previous ones, particularly Calderón (2008). It also reinforces the perception that Brazil and other Latin American countries have been much more connected to China (Cepal, 2011; Cesa-Bianchi et al., 2011; IADB, 2012; Jenkins and Barbosa, 2012).

Table 3 – Effects of Trade Intensity on Business Cycles Synchronization, Brazil, 1975-2010

15

Page 16: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

FilterITT ITY

GDP 14,099*** 86,779***(-2,461) (-15,1)

19,572*** 117,826***(-2,983) (-18,353)

* p<0.05, ** p<0.01, *** p<0.001 Standard Deviation in parenthesis

ITT - trade intensity weighted by total trade; ITY - trade intensity weighted by GDP

To estimate the equation we used trade intensity (IT) as Instrumental Variable (IV) to solve the homogeneity between trade and GDP.

The IT was estimated through a traditional gravitational model, i.e., using Language, Frontier and Distance as instruments.

After that we estimate the equation using a Panel Data model. The Hausman test shows that Two-Stages Least Squares (2SLS) is efficient

and the Sargan Test support the null hypothesis that the all the instruments (IV Model) were valid.

Trade Intensity

GDP Hodrick Prescott

Baster King

In short, recent literature and our own results suggest that robust growth in China in recent years has created some externalities for Latin American countries. In natural-resource-rich countries the Chinese demand for agricultural and mineral commodities has resulted in trade surpluses, which contributed to a virtuous cycle of growth with less external and fiscal vulnerabilities. Countries already characterized by a high degree of specialization in commodities production and exports have reinforced their pattern of international integration. At the same time, countries with larger manufacturing sectors, such as Brazil, have concentrated their exports on commodities. As a result, manufacturing sector experiences massive trade deficits, and there is a renewed stimulus to the previous process of de-industrialization.38

In this section we have showed that the recent economic growth acceleration was not strong and sustained enough to overcome the quarter of century of semi-stagnation experienced after the 1980s debt external crisis. Brazil´s infrastructure, technological capabilities, social institutions, particularly in education, housing and health care, and business environment should be markedly improved to attain the requirements of a modern and affluent society.39, 40, 41 To overcome recent and historical structural weakness, the country needs coherence and strength in its policies. Indeed, it needs an alternative development strategy based on the heterodox tradition, which we explored in section 2. We strengthen this conclusion further in what follows in our ‘final remarks’ as in section 5.

5. Final Remarks: In Search for Coherence and Robustness

During the 1990s and early 2000s Brazil followed macroeconomic and development policies characterized by their coherent and faithful adherence to the Washington Consensus. Instead of growth and stability that economic orthodoxy would suggest, the country experienced semi-stagnation and macroeconomic instability. However, since 2004 a positive combination of growth acceleration,

38 Previous studies provided evidence that China´s exports have been dislocating other countries exports and, therefore, Chinese competence in manufacturing has stimulated deindustrialization among developing and advanced countries. See, among others, Greenway, Mahabir, Milner (2008), Giovannetti and Sanfilippo (2009), Wood and Mayer (2010), Giovannetti, Sanfilippo and Velucchi (2011), Lélis, Cunha and Lima (2012) and Jenkins and Barbosa (2012).39 According to the ‘World Competitiveness Report 2011-2012’, Brazil ranks 53 in a group of 141 countries. See http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GCR_CountryProfilHighlights_2011-12.pdf (obtained on 27/04/2012). OECD states that “Brazil under-invested in infrastructure for over three decades, and infrastructure investment rates have come up only slowly since 2007. Infrastructure needs are sizeable in almost all sectors” (http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/economics/promoting-infrastructure-development-in-brazil_5kg3krfnclr4-en; obtained on 27/04/2012).40 The ‘Global Information Technology Report 2010-2011’ ranks Brazil in the 56 position among 138 countries (http://www3.weforum.org/docs/WEF_GITR_Report_2011.pdf; obtained on 27/04/2012). This report states that Brazil is a contradictory country where the ‘modern business’ segments can rapidly and efficiently incorporate new technologies, while the more deep social capabilities and infrastructure are very deficient.41 The World Bank ranks 127 in a list of 183 countries, where 1 is the best business environment for small and medium enterprises, and 183, the worst. Brazil´s performance is far worse than the regional average. It is also worse than most of its main competitors among emerging markets. See “Doing Business 2012”. Available at: http://www.doingbusiness.org/~/media/fpdkm/doing%20business/documents/profiles/country/BRA.pdf (obtained on 27/04/2012).

16

Page 17: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

macroeconomic resilience, income redistribution and poverty reduction has created a new socio-political environment.

The presidencies of Lula da Silva (2003-2010) and Dilma Rousseff (2010 - today) have been pushing more ambitious development goals. Nevertheless, their economic policies have been associated with contradictions. On the one hand, macroeconomic policies have mainly been conventionally framed, while pragmatically managed after the global financial crisis. On the other hand, development policies have been based on a more hands-on and State-led approaches. In view of this contradiction macroeconomic variables, such as exchange rates, interest rates, taxes and so on, which can be influenced by policymakers, have not contributed to the developmental effort. From a historical and theoretical perspective (section 2) we assume that the Keynesian tradition, enlarged by other heterodox contributions, provides a better framework to pursue coherence and strength between macroeconomic and development policies.

We have also argued that it is far from clear how strong and sustainable the recent economic recovery will be, particularly if we consider the domestic economic and institutional flaws and the external challenges (section 3). Agriculture and mining, despite its importance and competitiveness, cannot provide enough jobs, income, taxes and dynamic efficiency gains to sustain a country with the dimensions and complexities of Brazil. Therefore, the deindustrialisation process and the ‘re-primasization’ of exports must be taken as serious threats.

Thus, the challenge of the Brazilian government is to keep its developmental agenda and economic policies not only in response to international financial crises, but, mainly, in normal times. The search for coherence and strength in this heterodox perspective leads to the necessity to overcome the conservative trap created by the New Consensus Macroeconomic framework. In other words, economic policy should be reoriented towards enhancing employment and economic activity. The Brazilian exchange rate should be administrated by the BCB, an efficient anti-speculation mechanism to control (or regulate) capital movements should be created in an attempt to prevent financial and exchange rate crises and avoid exchange rate appreciation as well as balance the balance of payments; also to introduce structural economic initiatives to improve income distribution and to reduce the social gaps and infrastructure bottlenecks.

Development policies will only deliver consistent results if the government is able to face the task of avoiding previous flaws of the policy framework inherited from the neoliberal period, such as: (i) to reduce deflationary impacts of monetary policy; (ii) to use fiscal policy to stimulate income growth and distribution, which means to promote investment in public utilities, to adopt progressive taxation42 and to implement social programmes aimed to reduce inequality; (iii) to manage capital flows, exchange rate and financial sector prudential regulation in order to limit currency overvaluation pressures and boom and bust credit cycles; and (iv) to pursue industrial, innovation and trade policies to improve competitive capabilities of the manufacturing sector.

Finally, and as we suggested in section 4, China´s rise represents an additional challenge, in the sense that it tends to reinforce the problems associated with the so-called ‘natural resources curse’ and the deindustrialization. To overcome these problems, macroeconomic and development policies must be coherent and strong enough to complete the Brazilian modernization process in the context of a globalized and unstable world.

References

42 The Brazilian tax system has historically been contributing to increased inequality. There are few progressive taxes – those aimed toward the rich – such as personal income tax (IRPF) and property tax (IPTU). Indirect taxation prevails. These are the cases of the federal sales tax (IPI), the contribution to welfare financing (COFINS) and the state tax on goods and services (ICMS), which are added to the overall cost of products. They are collected by businesses and therefore included in the prices paid by consumers. Therefore, the poorest deciles of the population pay 32.8% of their income in taxes, while the richest deciles pay only 27.7% (Pochmann, 2008, Oliveira, 2010).

17

Page 18: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Arestis, P.; De Paula, L. F.; Ferrari-Filho, F. 2007. Assessing the Economic Policies of President Lula da Silva in Brazil: has fear defeated hope? In: Arestis, P.; Sawyer, M. (Eds.). Political Economy of Latin America: recent economic performance. Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.

Arestis, P.; Saad-Filho, A. (Eds.). 2008. Political Economy of Brazil: recent economic performance. Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan.

Arestis, P.; Sawyer, M. 2010. (Editors). 21st Keynesian Economics. Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.Arestis, P.; Sobreira, R.; Oreiro, J. L. 2011. The Financial Crisis – Origins and Implications.

Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.Bacha, E.; Bonelli, R. 2004. Accounting for Brazil Growth Experience: 1940-2002. Working Paper nº1,

IEPE/CdG. Rio de Janeiro: IEPE/CdG (Available at: http://iepecdg.com.br/?acao=textos&page=3, Access on 20/04/2012).

Bonelli, R.; Pessoa, S. A. 2010. Desindustrialização no Brasil: um resumo da evidência. Rio de Janeiro, IBRE/Fundação Getúlio Vargas, Texto para Discussão nº 7, May.

Bresser-Pereira, L. C. (Editor). 2010. Doença holandesa e Indústria. Rio de Janeiro, Editora FGV. Bresser-Pereira, L. C., 2011. From old to new developmentalism in Latin America. In. OCAMPO, J. A.;

ROS, J. (Editors). Handbook of Latin America Economics. Oxford, Oxford University Press.Cardim de Carvalho, F. J. 1992. Mr Keynes and the Post Keynesians: principles of macroeconomics for a

monetary production economy. Aldershot, Edward Elgar. Carneiro, R. M. 2010. ‘O Desenvolvimento Brasileiro Pós-Crise Financeira: oportunidades e riscos’.

Observatório da Economia Global, nº 4, Campinas, Instituto de Economia.Carvalho, F. C. 2008. Lula's Government in Brazil: A New Left or the Old Populism? In: Arestis, P.;

Saad-Filho, A. (Eds.). Political Economy of Brazil: recent economic performance. Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan.

Cepal. 2011. La República Popular China y América Latina y el Caribe. Hacia una nueva fase en el vín-culo económico y comercial, Junio. Santiago de Chile, CEPAL.

Cimoli, M.; Dosi, G.; Stiglitz, J. (Eds.). 2009. Industrial Policy and Development: the political economy of capabilities accumulation. Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Cunha, A. M.; Prates, D. M.; Ferrari-Filho, F. 2011. Brazil Responses to the International Financial Crisis: a successful example of keynesian policies? Panoeconomicus, v. 5, pp. 693-714.

Davidson, P. 2011. Post Keynesian Macroeconomic Theory: a foundation for successful economic policies for the twenty-first century, Second Edition. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

De Paula, L. F. 2010. Financial Liberalization and Economic Performance: Brazil at the Crossroads. London, Routledge.

Dutt, A. K. Keynesian Growth Theory in the 21st Century. In: Arestis, P.; Sawyer, M. 2010. (Editors). 21st

Keynesian Economics. Basingstoke, Palgrave MacMillan.Fishlow, A.; Bacha. E. 2010. Recent commodity price boom and Latin American growth: more than new

bottles for an old wine? In: Ocampo, J.A.; Ros, J. (Eds.). Handbook of Latin American Economics. Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Furtado, C. 1964. Development and Underdevelopment. Los Angeles, University of California Press.Furtado, C.1992. Brasil, a construção interrompida. São Paulo, Paz e Terra.Giambiagi, F.; Pinheiro, A. C. 2012. Além da Euforia – riscos e lacunas do modelo. São Paulo: Campus.

Giovannetti, G.; Sanfilippo, M. 2009. Do Chinese Exports Crowd-out African Goods? An Econometric Analysis by Country and Sector. European Journal of Development Research, vol. 21, nº 4, pp. 506-530.

Giovannetti, G.; Sanfilippo, M.; Velucchi M. 2011. The “China effect” on EU Exports to OECD markets – A focus on Italy. Working Paper nº17, December. Universita' degli Studi di Firenze.

Goldman Sachs. 2007. BRICs and Beyond. The Goldman Sachs Group/Global Economics Department.Greenaway, D.; Mahabir, A.; Milner, C. 2008. Has China displaced other Asian countries' exports? China

Economic Review, vol. 19, Issue 2, June, pp.152–169.

18

Page 19: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Griffith-Jones; Ocampo, J. A.; Stiglitz, J. E. 2010. Time for a visible hand: lessons from the 2008 World Financial Crisis. New York, Oxford University Press.

Harcourt, G. C. 2008. The Structure of Post-Keynesian Economics: the core contributions of the pioneers. Cambridge University Press.

Hirschman, A. O. 1958. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University Press.Iadb. 2012. The World of Forking Paths: Latin America and the Caribbean facing global economic risks.

Washington, DC, IADB.Iedi. 2011. A Indústria de Transformação por Intensidade Tecnológica: o desafio de crescer sem

deteriorar ainda mais o saldo comercial. Carta IEDI, nº 4541, São Paulo, IEDI.Iedi. 2012. O Comércio Exterior Brasileiro em 2011. Análise IEDI, 20/1/2012.Jenkins, R. 2010. China’s Global Expansion and Latin America. Journal of Latin American Studies, vol.

42, Part 4, Nov., pp. 809–837.Jenkins, R., Barbosa, A. F. 2012. Fear for Manufacturing? China and the Future of Industry in Brazil and

Latin America. The China Quarterly, vol. 209, pp 59-81.Kaldor, N. 1977. Strategic Factors in Economic Development. New York, Ithaca.Keynes, J. M. 1964. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York, HBJ Book.Khan, S. R.; Christiansen, J. (Eds). 2010. Towards New Developmentalism: Market as Means rather than

Master. London, Routledge.King, J. E. (Editor). 2003. The Elgar Companion to Post Keynesian Economics. Cheltenham, Edward

Elgar Publishing Limited.King, J. E. 2008. ‘Post Keynesian economics’. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Second

Edition. Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. Palgrave Macmillan, 2008. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. 13 June 2012 <http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_P000135>

Lélis, M. T.; Cunha, A. M.; Lima, M. G. 2012. El desempeño de las exportaciones de China y el Brasil hacia América Latina, 1994-2009. Revista de la Cepal, nº 106, pp. 57-77.

Ministry of Finance. 2012a. Brazilian Economic Outlook, nº 14, February. Brasília, DF: Ministry of Finance.

Ministry of Finance. 2012b. Brazilian Economic Outlook, nº 15, April. Brasília, DF: Ministry of Finance.Minsky, H. 1986. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Heaven, Twentieth Century Fund Report.Ocampo, J. 2000. Developing countries’ anti-ciclycal policies in a globalized world. Santiago de Chile,

CEPAL.Oliveira, F.A. 2010. A Evolução da Estrutura Tributária e do Fisco Brasileiro: 1889-2009. Texto para

Discussão IPEA n. 1469. Brasília, IPEA.Oreiro, J. L.; Feijó, C. Desindustrialização: conceituação, causas, efeitos e o caso brasileiro. Revista de

Economia Política, São Paulo, vol.30, vol. 118, n. 2, pp.219-232.Palma, G. 2007.Four Sources of ‘De-industrialisation and a New Concept of the ‘Dutch Disease’. HSRC

EGDI Roundtable, May. Palma, G. 2011. Why has productivity growth stagnated in most Latin American countries since the neo-

liberal reforms? Cambridge Working Papers in Economics (CWPE) 1030, July, 2011.Paulani, L. M. 2008. The Real Meaning of the Economic Policy of Lula's Government. In: Arestis, P.;

Saad-Filho, A. (Eds.). Political Economy of Brazil: recent economic performance. Basingstoke, Pal-grave Macmillan.

Pavitt, K. 1984. Sectoral patterns of technical change: towards a taxonomy and a theory. Research Policy, vol. 13, n. 19, pp. 343-373.

Peres, W.; Primi, A. 2009. Theory and Practice of Industrial Policy. Evidence from the Latin American Experience. Serie Desarrollo Productivo, nº137, February. Santiago de Chile, CEPAL.

Phillips, N. 2011. Re-Ordering the Region? China, Latin America and the Western Hemisphere. European Review of Latin American and European Studies, n. 90, pp. 89-99.

Pochmann, M. 2008. Desigualdade e Justiça Tributária. Brasília, IPEA.

19

Page 20: Country Reviews - ANPEC - Associação Nacional dos ... · Web viewWe also take a fresh look at the empirical evidence concerning the regressive pattern of structural changes in Brazil

Prebisch, R. 1984. Five Stages in My Thinking on Development. In: MEIER, G.M.: SEERS, D. (Eds.). Pioneers in Development. Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Robinson, J. 1962. Essays in the Theory of Economic Growth. London: MacMillan.Rodrik, D., Mcmillan, M. 2011. Globalization, Structural Change, and Productivity Growth. NBER

Working Paper No. 17143, June.Sawyer, M. 2003. Economic Policy. In King, J. E. (Editor). The Elgar Companion to Post Keynesian

Economics. Cheltenham, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.Schumpeter, J. 1961. The Theory of Economic Development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit,

interest, and the business cycle. New York: Oxford University Press.Serrano, F., Summa, R. 2011. Política Macroeconômica, Crescimento e Distribuição de Renda na

Economia Brasileira nos Anos 2000. Textos Avulsos – no. 6 – Março – Observatório da Economia Global: Campinas, SP: Instituto de Economia.

Sicsú, J.; De Paula, L. F.; Michel, R. 2005. Novo-Desenvolvimentismo: um projeto nacional de desenvolvimento com equidade social. Barueri, Manole.

Skidelsky, R. 2009. Keynes: the return of the master. New York, Public Affairs.Spence, M. Growth in Postcrisis World. In Blanchard et al. (Eds). 2012. In the Wake of the Crisis: leading

economists reassess economic policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Taylor, L. 2004. Reconstructing Macroeconomics: structuralist proposals and critiques of the mainstream.

Harvard University Press.Taylor, L. 2011. Maynard's Revenge: the collapse of free market macroeconomics. Harvard University

Press.Tregenna, F. 2009. Characterising Deindustrialisation: an analysis of changes in manufacturing

employment and output internationally. Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 33, nº 3, pp.433–466.Thirlwall, A. P. 2011. Economics of Development. Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan.Unctad. 2003. Trade and Development Report 2003. Geneva, United Nations Trade and Development

Commission.Verdoorn, P. J. 1949. Fattori che Regolano lo Sviluppo della Produttivita del Lavoro. L'Industria , vol.

nº 1, pp. 3–10.

20