current welfare measures and participation income

44
1 Current welfare measures and participation income: involvement in socially valuable activities and motivational issues. Abstract: This paper found that participation income can be considered a better policy than the current welfare system due to its ability to incentivize people to participate in socially valuable activities. First, this research argues participation income (PI) is the best alternative welfare measure available. Then, previous arguments made against the feasibility of PI are addressed through new technologies such as blockchain and new market development as the sharing economy. The new challenge identified for participation income is the definition of the right level of monetary compensation. To provide a quantitative answer to what the right level of compensation could be, a vignette survey was put in place. Results gave a significant negative effect of low monetary compensation level on individual’s willingness to participate. In the case of a high compensation, results are not significant. This can probably be explained by setting the level of the high compensation too low. Overall, this study pointed out that PI is a more sensible public policy than current welfare systems. It also contributed to stimulate and start a new discussion around a possible PI scheme. Rebecca Belochi - 11084499 Bsc Economics and Business Finance and Organizations University of Amsterdam Dhr. Dr. D.F. Damsma

Upload: others

Post on 17-Feb-2022

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Current welfare measures and participation income

1

Current welfare measures and participation income: involvement in socially valuable activities and motivational issues.

Abstract: This paper found that participation income can be considered a better policy than the current welfare system due to its ability to incentivize people to participate in socially valuable activities. First, this research argues participation income (PI) is the best alternative welfare measure available. Then, previous arguments made against the feasibility of PI are addressed through new technologies such as blockchain and new market development as the sharing economy. The new challenge identified for participation income is the definition of the right level of monetary compensation. To provide a quantitative answer to what the right level of compensation could be, a vignette survey was put in place. Results gave a significant negative effect of low monetary compensation level on individual’s willingness to participate. In the case of a high compensation, results are not significant. This can probably be explained by setting the level of the high compensation too low. Overall, this study pointed out that PI is a more sensible public policy than current welfare systems. It also contributed to stimulate and start a new discussion around a possible PI scheme.

Rebecca Belochi - 11084499 Bsc Economics and Business Finance and Organizations University of Amsterdam

Dhr. Dr. D.F. Damsma

Page 2: Current welfare measures and participation income

2

Statement of originality

This document is written by student Rebecca Belochi, who declares to take

full responsibility for the contents of this document.

I declare that the text and work presented in this document are original and that

no sources other than those mentioned in the text and its references have been

used in creating it.

The faculty of economics and business is responsible solely for the supervision

of completion of the work, not for the contents.

Page 3: Current welfare measures and participation income

3

Table of Contents

1. Introduction ................................................................................................................. 5

2. Ethical and political aspects on the idea of Participation Income .............................. 7 2.1. The dilemma of Participation Income, an ethically and politically superior idea considered unfeasible. ..................................................................................................................................... 7

2.2. Emergence of new trends offering viable solution to PI’s dilemma ..................................... 9

3. Economic aspect on the idea of Participation Income: incentives and motivational issues…. ............................................................................................................................. 10

3.1. The debate in academic literature surrounding motivation ................................................. 11 3.2. Understanding of the relationship between intrinsic and extrinsic motivation, and monetary incentives .................................................................................................................................... 12

4. Methodology ............................................................................................................... 14 4.1 Research design ................................................................................................................ 14

4.2 Vignette layout ................................................................................................................. 15

4.3. Scales and measurements.................................................................................................. 17 4.3.1. Scales ................................................................................................................................... 17 4.3.2. Control variables .................................................................................................................. 17 4.3.3. Data manipulation ................................................................................................................ 18

4.4. Data collection procedure. ................................................................................................ 18

4.5. Data analysis process. ....................................................................................................... 19

5. Results. ....................................................................................................................... 19 5.1. Descriptive Statistics ........................................................................................................ 20

5.1.1. Correlations .......................................................................................................................... 20 5.2. Testing of hypothesis ........................................................................................................ 21

5.2.1. Predictors. ............................................................................................................................ 21 5.2.2. Direct effect of low monetary compensation on willingness to participate............................... 22 5.2.3. Direct effect of high monetary compensation on willingness to participate ............................. 22 5.2.4. Effect sizes of extrinsic and intrinsic motivation in low monetary compensation setting. ......... 22 5.2.5. Effect sizes of extrinsic and intrinsic motivation in high monetary compensation setting ......... 23 5.2.6. Mediation effects in a low monetary compensation setting...................................................... 23 5.2.7. Mediation effects in a high monetary compensation setting .................................................... 23

6. Discussion ................................................................................................................... 26 6.1. Results summary .............................................................................................................. 26

6.1.1. Low monetary setting ............................................................................................................ 26 6.1.2. High monetary setting ........................................................................................................... 26

6.2. Discussion of the results and perspective on previous literature findings ........................... 27 6.2.1. Crowding out of intrinsic motivation. ..................................................................................... 27 6.2.2. Higher incentives, higher performance .................................................................................. 27

6.3. Contributions to theory and suggestions for future research .............................................. 28

6.4. Contribution to policy makers ........................................................................................... 29

6.5. Limitations. ...................................................................................................................... 29

7. Conclusion. ................................................................................................................. 30

Page 4: Current welfare measures and participation income

4

References ......................................................................................................................... 32

Appendix ........................................................................................................................... 37

Appendix 1A: no monetary compensation vignette ....................................................................... 37

Appendix 1B: low monetary compensation vignette ..................................................................... 38

Appendix 1C: high monetary compensation vignette .................................................................... 39

Appendix 2: Survey questionnaire ................................................................................................ 40

Appendix 3: overview of scales and original studies ..................................................................... 43

Tables overview.

Table 1: correlations overview for all variables................................................................................ 20

Table 2: output summary of mediation analysis in a low monetary compensation setting. ................ 24

Table 3: summary of direct and indirect effects of mediation analysis for a low monetary

compensation setting. ...................................................................................................................... 24

Table 4: output summary of mediation analysis in a high monetary compensation setting. ............... 25

Table 5: summary of direct and indirect effects of mediation analysis for a high monetary

compensation setting ....................................................................................................................... 25

Page 5: Current welfare measures and participation income

5

1. Introduction.

Current welfare systems are outdated. Our societies evolved and exposed individuals to new

dilemmas. In the 1930s, John Maynard Keynes predicted that per capita income level would rise,

allowing individuals to spend less time working to cover their basic needs and dedicate more time to

leisure (1933). However, Keynes was only partially right, income per capita did increase but working

hours remained unchanged. Robert and Edward Skidelsky (2012) argue one of the reason lies in

individuals’ insatiable nature. Another reason could also be the way society frames work. As Keynes

pledges in Economics possibilities for our grandchildren (1930), we need to evolve towards other

systems enabling individuals to find a sense of purpose in other activities than a traditional work setting.

Beyond this idealistic viewpoint, more grounded arguments also support the need for a new organisation

of societies. The growing applications of artificial intelligence and robotisation are expected to have

significant political and economic effects on societies all over the world. West (2018), underlines the

political turbulences inherent to the disruption caused by artificial intelligence, especially when thinking

of its impact on working activities. A McKinsey report published in 2017 expects the automatisation of

jobs to impact 375 million workers worldwide. Similarly, Frey and Osborne (2013) identified more than

54% of European Union’s jobs as being at risk of computerisation. Therefore, as applications of

artificial intelligence and robotisation increase, so does the range of individuals it might affect.

Consequently, it is reasonable to argue the State needs to actively reshape how societies are organised

in order to face the consequences of the development of such groundbreaking technology. The State

has to offer opportunities to individual to redirect their interests. An area mostly controlled by the State,

such as welfare, represents a good starting point. In that matter, the role of the State has to evolve and

cannot be restricted to health and workfare. The economist Atkinson already developed a theory along

this line of thought in 1996, Participation Income (PI). Individuals are monetarily compensated in return

for their participation in the overall activity of the country. Atkinson’s definition of the participation

requirement is broad, it can be interpreted as any activity that is benefiting to the society as a whole

such as “ people working as an employee, engaging in approved forms of education or training, caring

for young, elderly or disabled, and undertaking forms of voluntary work” (p.68-69). This paper

investigates whether Participation Income is the key to reforming welfare systems and if this change is

preferable to the current situation in terms of individual’s involvement in socially valuable activities.

The majority of the academic attention given to PI has been in comparison to Universal Basic

Income (UBI). UBI differs from PI in its unconditionality, justified by the inherent right of each

individual to freedom (Van Parijs, 2001). Until now, UBI was preferred to PI due to the simplicity of

its operationalisation. All individuals are entitled to receive UBI, which does not constrain individuals’

right to privacy in contrary to Participation Income where increased monitoring and administrative

overload burden the elaboration of a sensible scheme (Wispelaere and Stirton, 2007). However, the

arguments raised are now obsolete with the recent developments in technology such as blockchain,

Page 6: Current welfare measures and participation income

6

making PI relevant again. Blockchain is introduced as the discovery of the century (Higginson et al.,

2017). It consists of an open and decentralized database for transactions or information that are safely

encrypted and impossible to hack. Trust in this peer to peer interaction system without a third party or

official institution is build upon the infallible security system. Thus, Blockchain has the potential to

revolutionize many sectors of our society, in the case of the public sector it could efficiently reorganize

the way governments manage data (Cheng et al., 2017) while also enabling a better fraud prevention

and more transparency (Higginson et al., 2017). Its potential is best illustrated through the Estonian “e-

governance and digital society” e-Estonia initiative. During this process, blockchain was an essential

component to allow trust in the new system and its operationalization. Citizens can, with their digital

identity, access a variety of services from tax declarations, to health files and even vote (e-Estonia).

This paper will not focus on the specificities of how the blockchain technology can support the creation

of a PI scheme by diminishing the practical problems associated to it. Nevertheless, it relies on that

argument to support the claim that PI is a viable solution for the public sector to consider today.

Alongside the fact that PI is relevant for society today, it is still necessary to determine whether

or not it is preferable to the current welfare situation. If one follows the standard neoclassical economic

reasoning, monetary incentives are expected to always have a positive impact on individual’s

motivation, no matter the level of compensation. On the other hand, research in the field of economics

and psychology found that monetary compensation does not always result in the increase of individual’s

motivation and performance (Gneezy and Rustichini, 2000). In certain cases, a monetary incentive

scheme can lead to worse results than one without any. This demonstrates the need for further research,

in the context of participation income, to be able to determine whether its implementation would be

beneficial for society or if current welfare systems are preferable.

The topic of Participation Income is broad. Current research is mainly qualitative and focused

on PI’s opposition to UBI. For this paper, the aim is to quantitatively take part in the discussion

surrounding PI in the hope to possibly contribute to the elaboration of a PI scheme. Whilst the

participation criterion of Atkinson is the type of broad definition necessary for the implementation of

PI, this paper will focus on socially benefitting activities that are not recognized by the State today. This

choice was made due to the fact that activities such as education programs or full time employment are

already part of public administrative structures. Therefore, it is expected to be easier to account for them

and should not represent a challenge for a future PI scheme. Moreover, the additional value of PI rests

in its ability to allow States to include until now unaccounted for, non-monetized, activities into the

economic activity. Those can take the form of voluntary work, taking care of elderly, etc. In this sense,

the goal is also to underline the importance of PI in enabling the State to take into account new types of

activities. Accordingly, this paper will attempt to answer the following question: Are individuals more

willing to engage in socially desirable activities not recognized by the State today in a Participation

Income setting or in the current welfare system? Is this willingness dependent on the level of

compensation?

Page 7: Current welfare measures and participation income

7

The paper will be structured as follows. First, an outline of the political and ethical questions

evolving around participation income is provided as well as an argumentation regarding the feasibility

of a participation income scheme. Thereafter, the key literature around the economic aspect of PI,

namely the opposition of intrinsic and extrinsic motivation, is discussed and leads to the elaboration of

this research’s hypothesises. Then, the research methodology is addressed. Finally, after the results are

analysed, they are put in perspective through a discussion and used to draw the conclusion.

2. Ethical and political aspects on the idea of Participation Income.

The concept of Participation Income is the result of Atkinson’s work to understand income

inequalities and his attempt to introduce realistic proposals to significantly reduce them (2015, p.304).

Current welfare systems in Europe fail to do so, mainly because of their dependence upon means-tested

benefits (Atkinson, 1996). Mean-tested benefits are the monetary compensations allocated by the state

to an individual or household under the condition that their “means”, i.e. level of income, is below a

certain level considered critical. This system induces the perverse incentive for other individuals in a

household to limit their employment to remain under the ceiling defined by policy makers that entitles

them to support. Following Atkinson’s argument, new welfare proposal have to be developed.

Participation Income provides individual monetary support independently of one’s working or familial

situation and level of income under the only condition of participation to activities considered beneficial

for society. The participation criterion is much more inclusive than the usual workfare requirement, it

includes socially valuable activities such as “engaging in approved forms of education or training,

caring for young, elderly or disabled, and undertaking forms of voluntary work…” (Atkinson, 1996,

p.3) as well as any other type of valuable activity no recognised through monetisation.

2.1. The dilemma of Participation Income, an ethically and politically superior idea

considered unfeasible.

Participation Income is not the only existing proposal with the intent of reforming the welfare

system. The main opposition to PI is formulated as the Universal Basic Income idea. UBI is an universal

compensation for all individuals, differentiated from PI by its unconditionality (Van Parijs, 2003).

UBI’s main advocate, Philippe Van Parijs, supports the need for an unconditional measure through the

external asset argument. Essentially, the argument rests on an egalitarian conception of justice and the

individual right to freedom; all individuals should be entitled to receive a proportion of the available

external wealth as a form of substantial basic income (Van Parijs, 1997). Whilst UBI’s concept is

Page 8: Current welfare measures and participation income

8

admirable for its purist interpretation of justice and equality, PI stands out as a stronger proposal both

ethically and in terms of ability to gather political support. First, academics and the public alike object

to UBI principles out of fear of free riding, making it politically weak. For example, a referendum

conducted in 2016 exploring public’s opinion on a potential basic income introduction in Switzerland

faced substantial opposition with 77% of citizens voting against the project (BBC, 2016). The

opposition can be understood through individual’s fear that a disconnect between money and work will

be harmful for society. Therefore, as Wispelaere and Stirton (2007) point out, PI would allow to more

significantly gather political support. It enables to reach common grounds between on one hand

workfare supporters that require a participation criterion and on the other hand universalists who can

come to terms with a broad and largely inclusive criterion. Additionally, PI also stands out as the most

ethical proposal when confronted to UBI. Academics have also debated the risk of a too loose

distribution of money associated with UBI. Brian Barry (2001), depicts this issue by analogy to a surfer

in Malibu. In the context of a universal basic income, society suspects that individuals receiving benefits

might use them to go surf on the beach instead of contributing in a meaningful way to society. This

argument rests on the reciprocity principle introduced by Stuart White. It is defined as: “Those who

willingly enjoy the economic benefits of social cooperation have a corresponding obligation to make a

productive contribution, if they are so able, to the cooperative community which provides these

benefits” (White, 1997, p. 317). However, as White underlines, the concept should not to be understood

in a capitalistic way, contributions do not have to be equal to the benefits received or of the same nature.

In this sense, a monetary compensation can be considered equivalent to a service, such as charity work

or help to elderly. This interpretation of White’s principal coincides with the goal of Participation

Income, incentivise individual to engage in socially valuable activities and offer an approach considered

fairer or more ethical as to how individuals are eligible to receive monetary compensation.

However, Participation Income’s advantages also come with potential drawbacks, two are

discussed here because they are considered to be the most substantial opposition to a PI scheme:

administrative overload and the risk of a too government steered definition of socially valuable

activities. The main point is addressed by Wispelaere and Stirton (2007), the risk of administrative

overload. PI’s administrative weakness derives from the broad definition of the participation criterion

which makes it difficult to enforce effectively and to monitor all individuals accordingly. The

significant costs imposed on the public administration confront PI supporters with a dilemma between

reducing the extent of the participation criterion to make it more easily enforceable, accept a weak

enforcement of the broad criterion, or impose the high costs on the administration said justified by PI

advantages for society. This challenge is introduced as the Trilemma of Participation Income

(Wispelaere and Stirton, 2007). This administrative weakness consequently leads to political weakness

since, in this situation, PI would not be the key to a political consensus. Additionally, another point of

critique of Participation Income is that, in practice, the socially desirable activities citizens can engage

in risk to be restricted to a centralised government steered definition. This would imply that the liberties

Page 9: Current welfare measures and participation income

9

of individuals to engage in activities they consider meaningful are limited. This is embodied by the idea

of Cristian Perez-Munoz (2015), a civic program designed by the State to help fulfil unmet social needs.

Such a program can become very restrictive and feel like a duty more than a meaningful participation

for individuals.

2.2. Emergence of new trends offering viable solution to PI’s dilemma.

The discussed drawbacks of participation income can be overcome today thank to the

innovations and developments that took place in recent years, and therefore can be considered outdated.

With regards to administrative overload, the blockchain technology represents a breakthrough to rethink

public policies, especially welfare. Moreover, facing the risk of an oppressing presence of the State in

defining socially beneficial activities, the recent developments of sharing platforms represent a viable

solution to allow a decentralisation of activities.

The solution to administrative overload and intrusion lies in the blockchain technology. It’s

applications are vast and, in the case of this research, very relevant for new public policies. For instance,

Estonia has proven that the blockchain technology can digitalise and administratively operate an entire

government (Arets, 2017). In fact, every Estonian citizen has a digital identity with which he or she can

perform all administrative procedures online such as tax declaration, vote or access health files.

Blockchain was a key element for this digitalised society to protect all the information processed and

register all activities in a non-intrusive manner. Moreover, the procedure allowed to significantly reduce

public expenditures by approximatively 2 percent of Estonia’s gross domestic product (Epstein and

Franklin, 2017). This compelling decrease in administrative costs allows to draw the conclusion that,

in the case of Participation Income, blockchain outdates the argument of its high administrative burden

and would represent a considerable improvement compared to current welfare systems.

The second main point of critique against PI lies in the risk of a too restrictive government

steered definition of socially valuable activities. In fact, the goal of Participation Income is to incentivise

individuals to do more for the community, engage in socially beneficial activities. However, if the

government restricts the definition of what a socially beneficial activity may be, thus reducing the

choice of individuals, it takes the risk that they will engage in the opposite behavior. However, a

growing trend over the last years has the potential to tackle this issue, the sharing economy. Sharing

platforms demonstrated their potential to efficiently match local demands and supply thanks to the

internet. It great potential value is best illustrated through the estimated 23 billion dollars of funding

directed towards sharing platforms between 2010 and 2017 (Wallenstein and Shelat, 2017). Benkler

(2004) defines the sharing economy as a potentially more efficient third organising entity of economic

production than the State and markets.

Page 10: Current welfare measures and participation income

10

To conclude, as a result of the facts given above the discussion around PI’s implementation

reopens. New innovations enable PI to be regarded as a relevant and legitimate alternative welfare

measure. Today, a viable PI scheme could take the form of a sharing platform, allowing individuals to

participate in a way that is significant to them, operated by blockchain for more efficiency, security and

independence. Howbeit, as participation income’s feasibility was the center of academic debates and

research in the last years, a critical aspect of its scheme-design has been neglected. Indeed, the ability

of PI to live up to its ideal essentially depends on the level of compensation. Neoclassic economic theory

suggests the only way to incentivise individuals to exert an effort is a monetary compensation (Gneezy

and Rustichini, 2000). It follows that any monetary compensation level should have a positive effect on

individuals’ willingness to engage in socially valuable activities. However, research in behavioural

economy and psychology has proven otherwise. In fact, monetary compensation might negatively affect

individuals’ willingness to exert an effort (Gneezy and Rustichini, 2000) i.e. in some cases, individuals

perform better without a monetary reward. Additionally, the effect of the monetary incentive also

depends on the initial motivation of the individual and the context. A person engaging in an activity for

other reasons than make a living will see his or hers motivation decrease with the offer of a monetary

reward (Heyman and Ariely, 2004). This opposition in the literature suggests the determination of

whether or not a monetary compensation is necessary and what its level should be are critical to the

success of a participation income scheme and thus this point is addressed in the next section.

3. Economic aspect on the idea of Participation Income: incentives and motivational issues.

Now that the ethical and political character of PI have been discussed and the idea of a PI scheme

made relevant again thanks to the development of today’s new technologies, it is important to

investigate what the next interrogation might be when thinking of Participation Income. The new

challenge that PI advocate face is the question of monetary compensation for individual’s participation.

In fact, the possible benefits of a Participation Scheme in comparison to the current welfare system can

only be maximised if the level of compensation is right. Literature in economics, social sciences, and

psychology reveals a complex discussion surrounding the effects of compensation on individual’s

motivation and performance.

Page 11: Current welfare measures and participation income

11

3.1. The debate in academic literature surrounding motivation.

The first intuition on the role of intrinsic motivation was officially formulated by Titmuss (1970),

he defended the idea that monetizing blood donations would decrease individual’s sense of duty and

lead to a decrease in willingness to donate. However, until now, economics have been almost entirely

relying on the relative price effect theory to explain changes in supply, production, motivation,

performance… (Frey and Jegen, 2001). This is expressed through three different views on motivation

in economics. One view sees an individual’s motivation as very hard to define and identify as intrinsic

or extrinsic. In this case, intrinsic motivation is deliberately discarded and defined as an endogenous

constant in economic models (Frey and Jegen, 2001). Another consideration is the one of the classical

economists, they recognize the value of intrinsic motivation but also acknowledge the complexity of its

inclusion in economic theories. In this line of thought, Adam Smith stressed the importance of morals

and sense of duty for individual’s action and the market place and how extrinsic rewards can distort

those values in Theory of Moral Sentiments (1822). Finally, another approach considers intrinsic

motivation to be completely irrelevant. Lazear (2000), for example, discredits the value of recognizing

intrinsic motivators whilst studying the effectiveness of pay-for-performance schemes in a monotonous

work setting; placing windshields on cars (p.1342).

Moreover, not only the sources of motivation are discussed throughout academic fields but also

the effects of different type of incentives on motivation. Ariely, Gneezy and Loewenstein (2009) point

out that high monetary incentives can lead to worse performance. They reveal that large monetary

incentives do not lead to higher performance in tasks requiring creativity, problem solving and

concentration. Empirical evidence on the effect of incentives has since then grown. Deci, Koestner and

Ryan (1999) define through the Cognitive Evaluation Theory the underlying motivators of intrinsic

motivation: the need of an individual for autonomy and competence. This leads to the conclusion that

monetary rewards have a negative effects on intrinsic motivation and, in a majority of cases, this is due

to the perceived controlling effect of the incentive. Heyman and Ariely (2004) also underline the

importance of the level of incentives. They show that low incentives crowd out intrinsic motivation and

that, in the case of extrinsically motivated behavior, higher incentives are more effective. Those results

have been taken in consideration in economics even though they cannot be completely explained. The

crowding out effect of intrinsic motivation remains one of the most substantial anomalies in economics

(Frey and Jegen, 2001). For the purpose of this research however, it is necessary to analyze the effect

of different levels of incentives on motivation or intention to participate to be able to analyze

Participation Income to its fullest potential. Hence, the new relevant challenge PI faces is how to frame

monetary compensation allocated to individuals to avoid crowding out intrinsic motivation and still

incentivize individuals to participate. Moreover, the question does not limit to whether or not

compensation is necessary but also what the right level of compensation should be.

Page 12: Current welfare measures and participation income

12

3.2. Understanding of the relationship between intrinsic and extrinsic motivation, and

monetary incentives.

First, the relationship between low monetary reward, no compensation at all, and individual’s

motivation is studied. Frey and Oberholzer-Gee (1997), linked the discussion on monetary incentives

to public policies’ elaboration. They stressed the importance of taking into account the possible negative

effect of monetary incentives in the case of public policies that target areas where involvement depends

on individual’s intrinsic motives. Also, Gneezy, Meier and Rey-Biel (2011) raise the point that

monetary incentives can be a source of misinterpretation, a signal, making the task of determining the

right level of compensation very delicate. For instance, offering a monetary incentive could be

understood as a lack of confidence in one’s intrinsic motivation to perform a task correctly.

Additionally, Gneezy and Rustichini (2000) defend the view that money destroys individuals’ sense of

duty and therefore often leads to less motivation and less willingness to exert an effort. Through an

experimental study in day-care centers in Israel, they investigated the relationship between monetary

incentives and behavior. A fine was appointed to parents that were late to pick up their children.

Surprisingly, imposing fines did not decrease the amount of late parents each day but lead to the

opposite behaviour. Parents perceived the fine as an opportunity to diminish the morals behind the duty

to be on time and avoid being late, and simply replaced it by monetary value. This case illustrates how

money can drive out intrinsic values. Another point they raise is the importance of the level of

compensation in the case a monetary reward is offered. They have quantitatively examined whether or

not higher incentives leads to better results and concluded that indeed, if a monetary compensation is

offered, the higher the compensation the better the performance. This entails that a low monetary

incentive would, in addition to having the possible drawback of crowding out intrinsic motivation, have

a lesser effect on performance than higher incentives if the effect is expected to be positive. Therefore,

it seems crucial to determine whether a small monetary compensation leads to better performance than

no monetary compensation at all and how it affects intrinsic and extrinsic motivation.

Secondly, the relationship between a high monetary compensation, no compensation and an

individual’s motivation is examined. Heyman and Ariely (2004) underlined that when increasing the

monetary incentive, performance or motivation similarly increase. Moreover, Reeson and Tisdell (2008)

have specifically studied the relationship of monetary incentives and individual’s contribution to public

goods. Those contributions are mainly motivated by intrinsic factors and therefore are very sensitive to

monetary incentives. They identify a dilemma for policy makers to strengthen one’s already existing

engagement by intrinsic motivation while providing a good extrinsic incentive to encourage other

participants. In this context, a low monetary compensation is not the solution since it would only crowd-

out individual’s intrinsic motivation. However, a high compensation could enable to not adversely affect

intrinsically motivated individuals whilst providing a good incentive for extrinsically inclined

individuals. This would result in a higher contribution to public good overall, both intrinsically and

Page 13: Current welfare measures and participation income

13

extrinsically motivated. Bowles and Polonia-Reyes (2010), identify another reason why in some cases

monetary incentives can enhance a pro-social behaviour: situational cues or how incentives are framed.

If a monetary incentive is perceived as fair (this entails a level of compensation that is not considered

too low and perceived as disrespectful) and complementing one’s social preferences, there is a high

chance it will lead to more willingness to participate. Therefore, the effect of a higher monetary

compensation should be analysed in more depth to be able to identify its effect on both intrinsic and

extrinsic motivation and the resulting effect on individual’s willingness to participate.

To conclude, as a result from the analysis of motivation literature and the relationship between

intrinsic and extrinsic motivators, several points can be made. First, two possible situations stand out

when thinking of the new challenge PI is facing: identifying the right level of monetary compensation.

It is clear that the relationship between monetary incentives and willingness to participate is not as

straightforward as it was initially assumed. This is mainly due to intrinsic and extrinsic motivation that

react differently to incentive levels. In the case of PI, contribution is mostly dependent on intrinsic

factors as the goal is to participate meaningfully to the country’s activity. However, extrinsic motivation

can also be relevant to increase the amount of participation. Therefore, the two settings that need further

investigation examine a low level of monetary compensation and a high level in relation to individual’s

willingness to participate. They are the basis for the hypothesis tested in this research, defined as

follows.

H1: A low monetary compensation setting will result in less willingness to participate than a setting with

no monetary compensation.

H2: A high monetary compensation setting will result in more willingness to participate than a setting

with no monetary compensation.

H3: Intrinsic motivation is a stronger driver of individual’s willingness to participate than extrinsic

motivation in a low monetary incentive scheme compared to no monetary compensation.

H4: Extrinsic motivation is a stronger driver of individual’s willingness to participate than intrinsic

motivation in a high monetary incentive scheme compared to no monetary compensation.

H5: The relationship between individuals’ willingness to participate in a low monetary setting

compared to no compensation setting is sequentially mediated by extrinsic and intrinsic motivations,

such that the presence of low compensation (vs. no compensation) is associated with higher (lower)

Page 14: Current welfare measures and participation income

14

extrinsic motivation and reduced (higher) intrinsic motivation, which leads to lower (higher)

intentions to participate.

H6: The relationship between individuals’ willingness to participate in a high monetary setting

compared to no compensation setting is sequentially mediated by extrinsic and intrinsic

motivations, such that the presence of high compensation (vs. no compensation) is associated with

higher (lower) extrinsic motivation and reduced (higher) intrinsic motivation, which leads to

higher (lower) intentions to participate.

As previous critics of Participation Income have been answered, PI established as an ethically and

politically superior idea to other welfare measures, and the new relevant challenge for PI identified, the

next step to take is the quantitative process of this research to provide an answer to the research question.

4. Methodology.

The methodology this paper follows is described here. First, the choice of research design is

defended. Then, the set up of the research is clarified through the elaboration of the vignettes and scales.

This is followed by a description of the data collection procedure. Finally, the data analysis process is

laid-out.

4.1 Research design.

To offer a quantitative answer to the question this paper raises, a vignette survey design was

chosen. Also known as factorial study, it consists of a vignette experiment associated with a standard

survey questionnaire. The added value of such a research design is discussed here.

An experimental vignette study, as defined by Aguinis and Bradley (2014), “consists of

presenting participants with carefully constructed and realistic scenarios to assess dependent variables

including intentions, attitudes and behaviours”. More specifically, a vignette, “a short carefully

constructed scenario” (Atzmuller and Steiner, p.128, 2010) is presented to participants before they

answer a standard survey questionnaire. The added value of the vignette survey thus lies in the

possibility for researchers to randomly present different scenarios to participants and control the causal

relationship between variables. A vignette study therefore enables to simultaneously reinforce the

internal and external validity of a study, which has been one of researcher’s most prominent dilemma

when studying causal relationships so far (Aguinis and Bradley, 2014). Traditionally, the use of an

experiment yields to high internal validity due to the controlled setting but low external validity since

Page 15: Current welfare measures and participation income

15

findings cannot be generalised. On the other hand, a non-experimental setting such as a survey leads

to a low internal validity due to the unclear relationship between variables whilst external validity

remains good (Atzmuller and Steiner, 2010). In the case of a vignette experiment, internal validity is

strong due to the controlled scenario participants are presented whilst it remains representative of reality

and therefore strengthen external validity as well.

When thinking of Participation Income and the best investigation method to evaluate if it is a

better welfare measure, two points stand out. First, it is essential to realise that participants need to face

a realistic context to make sure they answers are representative so that internal validity is strong. A big

scale real-life experiment would be very complex to set up and costly. Moreover, it is also important to

be able to control precisely for certain variables when trying to measure intention to participate in a PI

scheme, since as it was discussed before it can already be dependent on two factors: intrinsic and

extrinsic motivation. The survey questionnaire added to the vignette experiment allow to present

individuals a controlled realistic setting whilst remaining an accessible method and therefore is the best

option for this research.

4.2 Vignette layout.

A realistic description of a possible participation scheme had to be elaborated to provide

participants with a credible scenario. The construction of the vignette is essential since it is the key

element to participant’s answer to the survey questionnaire. If the vignette is not believable,

respondents’ answers will not be representative. Therefore, it is essential to clearly layout the details

participants received.

For this research, three vignettes were created. Each one was developed with the objective to

provide an answer to the developed hypothesis. Essentially, all three vignettes are completely similar

except for the level of compensation individuals receive. This means that all three vignette present the

same set of survey questions to the participants and the description of the PI scheme is also similar. For

the first vignette, no monetary compensation is offered. Individuals engage in socially valuable

activities because they enjoy helping others. For the second and third scenarios, individuals are

respectively offered a low and a high monetary compensation. Consequently, this setting allows to

control the dependent variable: intention to participate, given the level of compensation by randomly

assigning participants to one out of the three vignettes. The decision on the level of low and high

monetary compensation was made based on the level of the minimal hourly wage in the Netherlands,

which is 9.96 euros an hour for an individual working full time (Rijksoverheid, 2018). In the high

monetary setting, a participants is compensated at the value of 10 euros an hour, free of tax. Therefore,

if he decides to dedicate the equivalent amount of time of a full time job, he shall be able to subsist to

his or hers basic needs and thus should be entitled to at least the minimum wage. In this setting,

Page 16: Current welfare measures and participation income

16

participants can earn up to 1600 euros free of tax. In the low monetary compensation setting, individuals

are offered 5 euros an hour. Here, even if individuals decide to invest all their time in the project, they

will not receive enough money to subsist, as the maximum represents 800 euros a month, free of tax.

In this case, PI is seen as a way to help others next to one’s primary activity to make a living.

The project described in all three vignettes is a government developed online platform and app

independently operated by blockchain called “Live better together”. The idea is simple, individuals are

put in contact to help each other out, providing or offering help at a local level. There are no restrictions

as to which activities individuals wish to engage in. The community consists of individuals but also

local governmental agencies and non-profit organisations. Any one of them can post requests for help

but also answer them. Possible requests on the platform could take many forms. For example, it could

be a neighbour needing help with administrative work, supervision and academic tutoring for his or her

children, etc. But it could also be a post from the municipality asking help cleaning up the forest or a

post from the shelter asking for help walking dogs. The goal of the platform is therefore to incentivise

individuals to engage in many diverse socially beneficial activities by offering a wide range of them.

Individuals can dedicate up to 40 hours from their time per week to socially valuable activities. Hence,

it is important to note that this is a crucial aspect in how PI represents an alternative to current welfare

systems. If one considers the high monetary compensation scenario, individuals by participating 40

hours a week can earn the equivalent of the minimum wage and therefore all individuals looking to

work and participate in the country’s activity are able to do so. An overview of the three vignettes as

well as the survey questionnaire can be found in appendices 1 and 2.

It is also important to note that blockchain holds a crucial role in the execution of all

administrative work and supervision. The first step in which blockchain is essential is individual’s

registration. To make the registration process as quick and non-intrusive as possible, citizens only have

to enter basic information such as name, age, familial situation, address and the blockchain will cross-

reference it with the data base of the government. Additionally, activities individuals which to engage

in have to be described in a couple of keywords that will also enable the blockchain to analyse the goal

intended with the activity and verify it is beneficial for society. Moreover, blockchain also has a central

role to register individual’s activity, this is done through a double-rating system. Both parties engaged

in an activity have to provide some references such as the date, the duration and their level of

satisfaction; if the provided information match on both sides the blockchain registers the activity as

completed and approved. Finally, blockchain is also key to the distribution of the monetary

compensation offered by the government. This is done through the elaboration of smart contracts, self-

initiating contracts, that are registered with the blockchain. In the case of this project, payment is

initiated if the activity registered by the blockchain on the platform meets the requirements set by the

government.

Page 17: Current welfare measures and participation income

17

4.3. Scales and measurements.

As it has been previously established, individual’s intention to participate depends on more than

one factor. Indeed, extrinsic and intrinsic motivation seem to react differently to levels of monetary

incentives from previous academic researches. Moreover, one could also reasonably assume that an

individual’s intention to participate is dependent on age, working situation, etc. The scales and different

measurements used in this research in an attempt to clarify which factors significantly affect

individual’s willingness to participate are described here.

4.3.1. Scales

To insure that the internal validity of the experiment is strong, all the scales were adapted from

previous peer-reviewed and published researches targeting the same variable. Additionally, to reinforce

the reliability of the intended measurements, one scale always comprised at least three items. They were

arranged in an specific order, to diminish the chance of participants realising two questions intended to

measure the same intention. Finally, all questions were associated to a seven point scale when possible.

The scales used in this research include individual’s intention to participate, extrinsic

motivation, and intrinsic motivation. Individual’s intention to participate was measured through scales

developed by Pavlou and Gefen (2004) as well as White et al. (2012) and Hamari et al. (2015). Pavlou

and Gefen investigated how to enhance individual’s trust in online market places and encourage online

transactions. White et al. researched the link between one’s intention to purchase a product and its

ethical nature. Finally, Hamari et al. investigated individuals’ motivation for engaging in collaborative

consumption also known as sharing economy. All three studies developed questions on respectively

transaction intentions, purchase intentions and intention to participate. Intrinsic motivation scales were

developed by adapting questions from the research of Paul et al. (2009) which focused on the source of

individual’s repeating purchase behaviour to improve customer relationship. Measurements for

extrinsic motivation were taken from the research of Hamari et al. (2015). In this case, involvement in

the sharing economy was analysed under the angle of monetary motives. The adapted questions for this

study are exhibited in appendix 3.

4.3.2. Control variables

Other measurements relate to participants’ personal information, relevant for this research.

They include participant’s age, working situation, residency, level of income, gender, education, as well

as their involvement in volunteering activities. Bucher et al. (2016) determined previous involvement

in the volunteering activities usually positively affects individual’s willingness to participate in the

sharing economy. Böcker and Meelen (2017), identified that education also has an effect on

Page 18: Current welfare measures and participation income

18

participation in collaborative consumption. Additionally, Ranzini et al. (2017) showed that millennial,

and thus younger citizens with lover income levels and less stable employment opportunities, are more

sensible to the new trend of the sharing economy. Finally, residency is considered to be a relevant

criterion for this research as participants range from different countries across the European Union and

a pattern of support for a PI scheme could be identified depending on the existing national welfare

policies.

4.3.3. Data manipulation

The data was first analysed in terms of complete data sets. All incomplete participations were

deleted. In total, 120 complete responses were collected and downloaded in SPSS.

Afterwards, an investigation for outliers in the data set was conducted. Anomalies in the data

were found in how individuals value the compensation they were offered. Five participants in the low

compensation setting perceived their hourly compensation as high, whereas six participants in the high

compensation setting saw their compensation as low. As individual’s perception of their compensation

is a key element in predicting their intention to participate, since it is assumed it can affect both intrinsic

and extrinsic motivation, those 11 participants were categorised as outliers and deleted from the data

set.

4.4. Data collection procedure.

Here, the process of data collection is described. The goal was to gather as many answers as

possible from diverse backgrounds. The main mean of distribution was social media. Respondents

principally represented the Netherlands, Germany and France. Additionally, potential participants were

approached individually and asked for their email addresses to complete the survey in public places; for

the majority at the university of Amsterdam. The survey was developed in English. However, to make

participation of French individuals easier, the survey was also translated and available in French. To

make results statistically significant, a goal of about forty participants per scenario was fixed,

corresponding to a total of 120 complete data sets.

Page 19: Current welfare measures and participation income

19

4.5. Data analysis process.

Overall, the data set is composed of 62 female and 46 male participants, represented by a mean

age of 34.9 and individuals ranging from 15 to 68 years old. The majority of them are divided amongst

three nationalities, namely Dutch, French, and German representing respectively 56%, 21%, and 11%

of the pool of nationalities. A majority of participants, 36%, are also students as opposed to individuals

working full time, 27%, and self-employed 19%. The mean salary of the sample is situated somewhere

between zero and 1,550 euros a month after tax, probably due to the high number of students in the

sample. There is also a good distribution of higher incomes ranging above 3,500 euros a month, 30%,

and incomes between 1,550 and 3,500 euros a month representing 16%. Finally, of all the participants,

35% claim to already have been involved in volunteering activities.

All non-continuous variables were transformed into dummy variables. This resulted in

dummies for nationality, salary, gender, age, and previous involvement in volunteering activities (see

appendix 4). Also, one new variable was created for each measurement namely intrinsic motivation,

extrinsic motivation and intention to participate. The correlation of the items composing the new

variable was checked, to make sure they all measure the same intention, through Cronbach’s alpha. This

step was taken to ensure the internal validity of the study remains strong and measures what it intends

to investigate.

Finally, once all these operations were executed, the following tests were applied to the data

set. To begin, a correlation table is set up to allow comparison of all variables and their effects on each

other. Afterwards, the relationship between intention to participate and the monetary compensation

level is studied thanks to a PROCESS test. The Hayes PROCESS test is a regression based technique

that enables to control for the mediating effect of certain variables (Hayes, 2011). In the context of this

study, as it is attempted to show the effect of intrinsic and extrinsic motivation on intention to

participate, the two-mediator model six is used to test both hypothesis.

5. Results.

In this section, the results of the analysis described in the previous section are presented. First,

the correlation table is discussed as it clarifies the relationship between variables to allow for further

investigation. Thereafter, the mediating effects of intrinsic and extrinsic motivation on intention to

participate are presented.

Page 20: Current welfare measures and participation income

20

5.1. Descriptive Statistics.

5.1.1. Correlations.

To begin with, a simple correlation analysis was used to identify whether the variables did have

a basic linear relationship with one another, overall results can be found in table 1. Most importantly,

extrinsic motivation (r = .38, p < .01) and intrinsic motivation (r = .77, p < .01) were both associated

with higher intention to participate which is in line with the reviewed literature. This was a crucial point

for the elaboration of a double mediation analysis since both variables are expected to mediate

individual’s intention to participate. Both variables also seem to be connected since extrinsic motivation

is positively associated to intrinsic motivation (r = .32, p < .01). Additionally, extrinsic motivation

appears to be positively associated with a low monetary compensation setting (r = .23, p < .05) as well

as with a high monetary compensation setting (r = .24, p < .05). However, intrinsic motivation does not

show any significant result associated to either low (r = -.08, p = .389) or high (r = -.001, p = .989)

compensation even though the implied negative relationship is in accordance with the literature. Thus,

even though results are not significant, it is argued the relationship is still worth investigating further in

a mediation setting.

Table 1: correlations overview for all variables.

Note: N=109. * p< .05; ** p<.01

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

1. LowCom

2. HighCom -.51**

3. Part_T -.16 .07

4. Intr_T -.08 .00 .77**

5. Ext_T .23* .24* .38** .32**

6. Age -.06 .12 .12 .04 -.12

7. French -.06 -.11 .01 .01 -.18 .08

8. Other_N -.04 .06 .12 .07 .03 .10 -.28**

9. INCOME_M -.02 .07 -.03 -.14 -.17 .15 .19 -.16

10. INCOME_H -.09 .09 .04 .16 -.15 .57** .17 .08 -.23*

11. FEMALE -.02 .00 -.01 .03 -.05 .12 -.07 .01 .08 .00

12. VOLUN_Y -.11 .24* .05 -.01 .01 .07 .03 .19* .15 -.04 .05

Page 21: Current welfare measures and participation income

21

5.2. Testing of hypothesis.

All hypothesis are tested through Hayes’ serial multiple mediator model number six. The steps

taken follow his recommendations as given in his book (Hayes, 2013, pp. 143-163). How results are

reported and what paths are tested can be seen in figure 1. The model was run with the consistent

heteroscedasticity consistent standard error option of Hubert and White, as recommended by Hayes and

Cai (2007), to allow for a stronger validity and power of the tests performed. Moreover, the tests were

run whilst also controlling for age, gender, nationality, and level of income. The results can be found in

tables 2, 3, 4, and 5.

Figure 1: model 6, double mediation.

Note: taken from Hayes, A. F. (2013). Introduction to mediation, moderation, and conditional process

analysis: A regression-based approach. Guilford Publications.

5.2.1. Predictors.

When running the analysis, certain control variables were found as predictors of the two

mediators and the dependent variables in both monetary settings. They will be presented here before

addressing hypothesis testing.

Two control variables significantly associate to the dependent variable willingness to participate.

First, it is found that age is positively associated to intention to participate (B = .013, SE = .004, p =

.002). This implies that the older an individual is, the more likely he is to participate in the proposed

participation income scheme. Additionally, high income appears to be negatively related to an

Page 22: Current welfare measures and participation income

22

individual’s willingness to participate (B = -.358, SE = .151, p = .019). This can be interpreted as the

idea that individual’s with higher incomes will be less willing to engage in a participation scheme.

Moreover, categories of incomes also seem to have effects on both mediators. First, high income

is perceived as positively paired with intrinsic motivation (B = .497, SE = .209, p = .019). This can be

understood as individuals earning higher incomes to be more sensitive to intrinsic motivation. Also,

medium income negatively affects extrinsic motivation (B = -.860, SE = .337, p = .012). This implies

that individuals earning between 1,550 and 3,500 euros a month are adversely affected by extrinsic

motivation.

5.2.2. Direct effect of low monetary compensation on willingness to participate.

Hypothesis one predicted that a low monetary compensation setting will result in less intention

to participate than a setting with no monetary compensation. The total effect c is negative and significant

(c = -.413, SE = .200, p = .042) which means that a low monetary compensation setting versus no

monetary compensation is negatively associated with individuals’ willingness to participate (see table

3). Therefore, hypothesis one is supported.

5.2.3. Direct effect of high monetary compensation on willingness to participate.

Hypothesis two speculated that a high monetary incentive scheme will result in more willingness

to participate than no monetary incentives at all. This can be tested through the total effect of the

compensation scheme on intention to participate. The total effect (c = -.099, SE = -.210, p = .639) is not

significant (see table 5), thus hypothesis two rejected. There is no strong statistical support for the idea

that a higher level of compensation results in more willingness to participate. However, the latest

discussions on mediation methods (Hayes, 2009) argue that scholars should continue to test for

mediation in the absence of direct effect.1 Thus, this paper will proceed with the mediation analysis.

5.2.4. Effect sizes of extrinsic and intrinsic motivation in low monetary compensation setting.

Hypothesis three assumed intrinsic motivation is a stronger driver of intention to participate than

extrinsic motivation in a low monetary incentive setting. By comparing partially standardised indirect

effects, one can see that indeed intrinsic motivation has a bigger effect (Ind2= -.502, SE = 175, CI: -.840

to -.157) on intention to participate than extrinsic motivation does (Ind1 = .251, SE = .112, CI: .075 to

.499) as it can be seen in table three. Hence, hypothesis three is supported.

1 “ If a mediator is a variable, M, that is causally between X and Y and that accounts at least in part for the association between X and Y, then by definition X and Y must be associated in order for M to be a mediator of that effect” (p.8).

Page 23: Current welfare measures and participation income

23

5.2.5. Effect sizes of extrinsic and intrinsic motivation in high monetary compensation setting.

Hypothesis four tested that in the case of a high monetary compensation setting, extrinsic

motivation would be a stronger driver of intention to participate than intrinsic motivation. Partially

standardized indirect effects allow to provide an answer. However, extrinsic motivation appears to have

less of an effect (Ind1 = .277, SE = .117, CI: .082 to .534) on willingness to participate than intrinsic

motivation (Ind2 = -.460, SE = .180, CI: -.837 to -.117). Therefore, even though the magnitude of the

negative effect of intrinsic motivate does decrease (from -.502 to -.460), as it can be seen by comparing

tables three and five, it also remains larger than the effect of extrinsic motivation and accordingly,

hypothesis four is rejected.

5.2.6. Mediation effects in a low monetary compensation setting.

Hypothesis five predicted that intrinsic and extrinsic motivation would sequentially mediate the

relationship between a low monetary compensation and individual’s willingness to participate.

After running the analysis, the direct effect of low monetary compensation on willingness to

participate remained significant (c’ = -.531, SE = -.145, p = .001) but the value of the total effect is

smaller (c = -.444, SE = .200, p = .042). From this, we can infer there is an associated effect with at

least one of the mediators.

The mediational path running from low monetary compensation, to intrinsic motivation until

intention to participate is significant and negative (Ind2= -.502, SE = 175, CI: -.840 to -.157). Also, the

mediational path from low monetary setting to extrinsic motivation on behavioural intentions is

significant and positive (Ind1 = .251, SE = .112, CI: .075 to .499).

Finally, this study finds evidence of sequential mediation. In this case, extrinsic motivation

positively mediates the path from intrinsic motivation to intention to participate (Ind3 = .338, SE = .108,

CI: .153 to .570). However, against expectation this effect is positive and thus does not support

hypothesis five which is rejected.

5.2.7. Mediation effects in a high monetary compensation setting.

Finally, hypothesis six predicted whether the relationship between a high monetary compensation

and intention to participate is sequentially mediated by intrinsic and extrinsic motivation.

First, there is a clear mediating effect of intrinsic and extrinsic motivation on intention to

participate. The direct effect when testing for all the path simultaneously is not significant (c’ = -.298,

SE = .159, CI: -.594 to .039), this evidence supports the claim that intrinsic and extrinsic motivation

fully mediate the relationship between X and Y.

Moreover, the mediational path from a high monetary compensation setting to intrinsic

motivation until individual’s willingness to participate is significant and negative (Ind2 = -.460, SE =

.180, CI: -.837 to -.117). Similarly, the path running from high monetary compensation to extrinsic

Page 24: Current welfare measures and participation income

24

motivation until intention to participate is positive and significant (Ind1 = .277, SE = .117, CI: .082 to

.534).

Finally, this study proves sequential mediation. Whilst the mediational path testing for both

intrinsic and extrinsic motivation is significant (Ind3 = .374, SE = .110, CI: .167 to .602) it is positive.

Therefore, evidence goes against the hypothesis of this research that extrinsic motivation negatively

relates to intrinsic motivation and hypothesis six is rejected.

Table 2: output summary of mediation analysis in a low monetary compensation setting. Consequent

M1 (extrinsic) M2 (intrinsic) Y (intention to participate)

Antecedent Coeff. SE p Coeff. SE p Coeff. SE p

X (low vs no) 𝑎1 1.292 .243 p < .001 a2 -.668 .234 p = .005 c' -.494 .145 p = .001

M1 (extrinsic) - - - d21 .348 .072 p < .001 b1 .180 .053 p = .001

M2 (intrinsic) - - - - - - b2 .699 .068 p < .001

constant iM1 3.138 .361 p < .001 iM2 4.675 .338 p < .001 iY .506 .155 p = .205

Control variables

Age - - - - - - .013 .004 p = .002

High Income - - - .497 .209 .019 -.358 .151 p = .019

Medium Income -.860 .337 p = .012 - - - - - -

R2 = .295 R2 = .240 R2 = .684

F(8,96) = 7.936, p < .001. F(9,95) = 4.275, p < .001. F(10,94) =31.737, p < .001.

Table 3: summary of direct and indirect effects of mediation analysis for a low monetary compensation setting.

Effect Effect_ps* SE p LLCI ULCI

Direct effect c' -.494 -.531 -.145 p = .001 -.781 -.206

Total effect c -.413 -.444 .200 p = .042 -.811 -.015

BOOT

SE

BOOT

LLCI

BOOT

ULCI

Indirect effect 1_ps* a1,b1 .251

.112

.075 .499

Indirect effect 2_ps* a2,b2 -.502

.175

-.840 -.157

Indirect effect 3_ps* a1,d21,b2 .338

.108

.153 .570

Total indirect effect_ps* .087 .219 -.327 .534

* partially standardized results

Page 25: Current welfare measures and participation income

25

Table 4: output summary of mediation analysis in a high monetary compensation setting.

Consequent

M1 (extrinsic) M2 (intrinsic) Y (intention to participate)

Antecedent Coeff. SE p Coeff. SE p Coeff. SE p

X (high vs no) 𝑎1 1.429 .269 p < .001 a2 -.612 .228 p < .001 c' -.277 .159 p = .085

M1 (extrinsic) - - - d21 .348 .085 p < .001 b1 .180 .059 p = .003

M2 (intrinsic) - - - - - - b2 .699 .062 p < .001

constant iM1 3.138 .361 p < .001 iM2 4.675 .339 p < .001 iY .506 .397 p = .205

Control variables

Age - - - - - - .013 .004 p = .002

High Income - - - .497 .209 p = .019 -.358 .151 p = .019

Medium Income -.860 .337 p = .012 - - - - - -

R2 = .295 R2 = .240 R2 = .684

F(8,96) = 5.023, p < .001. F(9,95) = 3.337, p = .001 F(10,94) = 20.335, p < .001.

Table 5: summary of direct and indirect effects of mediation analysis for a high monetary compensation setting

Effect Effect_ps* SE p LLCI ULCI

Direct effect c' -.277 -.298 .159 p = .085 -.594 .039

Total effect c -.099 -.107 -.210 p = .639 -.517 .318

BOOT SE BOOT LLCI BOOT ULCI

Indirect effect 1_ps* a1,b1 .277

.117

.082 .534

Indirect effect 2_ps* a2,b2 -.460

.180

-.837 -.117

Indirect effect 3_ps* a1,d21,b2 .374

.110

.167 .602

Total indirect effect_ps* .192 .226 -.243 .640

* partially standardized results

Page 26: Current welfare measures and participation income

26

6. Discussion.

This section addresses the outcomes of hypothesis testing. First, a summary of the results will be

provided. Thereafter, results will be comprehended in perspective of the academic literature reviewed

in section three. Finally, the limitations of this research layout will be discussed.

6.1. Results summary.

6.1.1. Low monetary setting.

In the case of a low monetary compensation setting, results show that it has, as expected, a direct

negative effect on intention to participate. Additionally, extrinsic and intrinsic motivation are related,

which leads to partial mediation of the relationship between low monetary compensation and intention

to participate. All three indirect effects were significant. The path testing for both extrinsic and intrinsic

motivation lead to positive effect on intention to participate. Extrinsic motivation based on a low

monetary compensation positively affected willingness to participate. However, intrinsic motivation in

a low monetary setting lead to less willingness to participate. This supported the conjecture that intrinsic

motivation has a stronger negative effect on intention to participate than the positive effect of extrinsic

motivation on intention to participate. Therefore, from the results above, it can be concluded that

extrinsic and intrinsic motivation both partially mediate the relationship between low monetary rewards

and intention to participate even though there is no negative sequential mediation. This implies that they

both are mediators of the relationship but independently of one another.

6.1.2. High monetary setting.

In contrast to expectations, no direct relationship was found between a high monetary incentive

scheme and individual’s willingness to participate. Consequently, the main hypothesis that higher

compensation leads to more willingness to participate was rejected. However, significant indirect

effects stand out and are still relevant for interpretation following Hayes’ argument (2009). The indirect

effect of extrinsic motivation based on high compensation had a positive influence on intention to

participate, whilst the path testing for intrinsic motivation based on high compensation remained

negative for intention to participate contrary to expectations. However, the difference in size between

the effect of intrinsic and extrinsic motivation on intention to participate decreased in the high

compensation setting in comparison to the low compensation setting. This implies that a higher

monetary incentive did have an influence on the both mediators and individual’s intention to participate.

Additionally, there was evidence of sequential mediation for intrinsic and extrinsic motivation even

though the negative effect was not proven. Therefore, it can be concluded that they both mediate the

relationship independently of one another. In conclusion, there is thus no statistically supported

Page 27: Current welfare measures and participation income

27

argument that a higher compensation level leads to more willingness to participate whilst intrinsic and

extrinsic motivation do mediate that relationship.

6.2. Discussion of the results and perspective on previous literature findings.

6.2.1. Crowding out of intrinsic motivation.

One could say that Titmuss’ intuition was right (1970). As Gneezy and Rustichini (2000), and

many others, have proven low monetary incentives have a negative effect on intrinsic motivation. This

study is another addition to the literature supporting the theory that low monetary incentives crowd out

individual’s intrinsic motivation. In low monetary setting, individuals were more sensitive to intrinsic

factors than extrinsic and the introduction of a low monetary reward negatively affected their intrinsic

motives which resulted in less willingness to participate. It is however important to note that the effect

on extrinsic motivation was positive. Thus, the resulting decrease in intention to participate has to be

interpreted as a simple sum, intrinsic motivation’s effect was larger than the one of extrinsic motivation

and lead to less willingness to participate.

The implications for a participation income scheme are the following. Intrinsic motivation

seems to clearly dominate individuals’ motives of participation. Therefore, it appears as important to

frame participation accordingly and ensure individuals understand their participation is meaningful to

society and not only a mean to receive monetary compensation. This is a point that Bowles and Polonia-

Reyes (2012) underlined as crucial to enhance the effectiveness of monetary incentives. Additionally,

it is clear that a PI scheme should not be elaborated on the basis of low monetary rewards or the intended

effect will not be reached and participation will be lower than if no compensation at all would have

been offered.

6.2.2. Higher incentives, higher performance.

The testing of the effectiveness of higher incentives on intention to participate is more

mitigated. There is no evidence that higher monetary incentives lead to more willingness to participate.

However, one can argue that there is an underlying effect of increasing the level of compensation. As

it was mentioned in section 6.1.2., the difference in effect size between intrinsic and extrinsic motivation

on intention to participate decreased in the high compensation level compared to the low. This can be

interpreted as a first sign that the effect of a higher compensation is relevant but smaller than expected.

Thus, a higher increase in monetary reward would be necessary to lead to significant results. Heyman

and Ariely (2004) hypothesized that a higher monetary reward would lead to higher performance, an

assumption that is not significantly supported through this study even though there is strong evidence

for it. The main contribution of this study would then be the to illustrate the dilemma described by

Reeson and Tisdell (2008). They argue that policy makers are faced with a dilemma when trying to

Page 28: Current welfare measures and participation income

28

incentivize contribution to public good. On one hand not to decrease intrinsic motivation with monetary

rewards while still attracting extrinsically motivated individuals through them. They give a high

monetary reward as a solution to avoid adversely affecting intrinsic motives, however in the case of this

study, the compensation still negatively affected intention to participate for intrinsic motivation.

6.3. Contributions to theory and suggestions for future research.

This research contributed to discussions addressed in the academic field. First, it sheds a new

light on participation income and its potential. By addressing PI’s previous limitations and identifying

the new ones, this paper contributed to restart the debate surrounding PI and make it a relevant welfare

measure. The proposed use of blockchain technology and recent trend of the sharing economy provide

new insights in how the public sector can be restructured. Indeed, changes ahead induced by

technological progress will represent a challenge for every country and this proposal represents the first

step towards actively addressing the issue. There are many more aspects open to investigation such as

the overall effectiveness of a complete PI scheme also including “traditional” activities such as full time

work or studying. It is hoped this first study will induce many more discussion amongst scholars on the

new future for participation income and its elaboration.

Moreover, this paper offers additional evidence of the negative effect of low monetary

compensation on intrinsic motivation, and thus supports crowding out theory. Whilst the direct positive

effect of higher monetary rewards could not be proven, a clear link between the monetary compensation

setting and intention to participate was established as well as the mediating role of intrinsic and extrinsic

motivation in that relationship. In line with these results, as the effect of higher monetary rewards could

not significantly be proven, several choices can be made. Future researchers can attempt to tackle this

limitation by investigating the effect of a higher incentive on motivation, or research whether the same

incentive on a specific target group has a different effect. This point will also be discussed in the next

section.

To conclude, with the argued new relevance of a participation scheme, many questions remain

unanswered and offer material for future research. Another possibility is to tackle this research’s

limitation, mentioned in the next paragraph, in order to achieve more significant results.

Page 29: Current welfare measures and participation income

29

6.4. Contribution to policy makers.

Another way to interpret this paper’s results is from the viewpoint of policy makers. From the

beginning, the position this research defended is that current welfare measures are outdated. If one

considered the academic literature on alternative welfare measures, universal basic income and

participation income stood out. Given the results of this study, as monetary compensation harms

intrinsic motivation, one could argue that they support the defense of a UBI scheme. However, as it was

previously established, it must not be forgotten that UBI is a measure that does not convince a majority

of individuals and fails to secure political support as opposed to participation income. Moreover, results

certainly do not reject the overall relevance of PI, simply that there is more research needed to set the

right level of compensation which mostly depends on the expectations of policy makers.

Accordingly, the weaker effect of extrinsic motivation given by the results in a high monetary

compensation setting has to be analysed with the intentions of policy makers in mind . If policy makers

envision a future PI scheme intended for the whole population, the level of compensation needs to be

reconsidered. As a final PI scheme should also incorporate “traditional” activities such as studying or

full time employment, a compensation set a the level of minimum income can appear insufficient for a

majority of individuals. Thus, it is still necessary to determine how much higher the compensation level

should be set to allow for higher intrinsic motivation whilst also not harming individual’s intrinsic

motives. On the other hand, if policy makers seek to develop a PI scheme intended for individuals

currently without occupation, a scheme closer to workfare, while further investigation is required, the

compensation level set in this study might be sufficient to extrinsically motivate individuals.

6.5. Limitations.

Understandably, several limitations were faced during the elaboration of this research. Even

though the validity and significance of all results are supported and defended in this paper, the reader

should also keep the following limitations in mind.

First, the hypothetical nature of all vignette experiments represents a limitation to the

interpretation of individual’s willingness to participate. There always is a difference between a real and

a hypothetical situation, no matter how strong internal and external validity are. In the case of this

experiment, it is possible individuals were more willing to participate because they knew they would

not have to actually commit to this project. It is also possible that the level of monetary reward was not

as relevant as expected compared to intrinsic motives because individuals knew they would never

receive that monetary reward. Neil et al. (1994) investigated this effect on hypothetical payments

showing they were consistently higher than real payments, thus proving that individuals commitments

in theoretical settings is sometimes overestimated compared to their actual willingness. Such

Page 30: Current welfare measures and participation income

30

discrepancies are inherent to a study construct like a vignette experiment and thus inevitable, it is

however still important to underline them.

Another possible point of critique for this research would be the composition as well as the size

of the sample. Even though it was attempted to create an as diverse as possible sample population, most

of the respondents were students and two major subgroups of a representative population sample were

missing: retired individuals and individuals looking for employment. Thus, it cannot be argued that this

sample is representative of a country’s population. Moreover, the data set gathered in total 120

respondents, whilst it is a sufficient amount of participants to have a statistically significant result, a

larger group would have been preferred.

This point leads to another limitation of this study, namely time and financial resources. If more

time was available for this research, it probably would have been possible to gather a larger data set or

even consider to elaborate a more complex and demanding real-life experiment.

Finally, a last point that could be considered for future research would be the determination of

a high level of compensation. From the results, a high compensation equal to the minimum wage is not

enough to extrinsically motivate individuals and lead to more willingness to participate. With more

time, it would have been possible to pre-test for such considerations, asking individuals what a high

compensation would represent for them and thus better investigate its effects. Therefore, it is suggested

that for further research, one considers to test for different levels of high and low compensation and

investigate how intention to participate varies accordingly.

7. Conclusion.

In today’s fast changing world, individuals have to face new challenges and the role of the State

has to be redefined, especially when thinking of welfare measures. Previous debates in academic

literature discussed which proposals represented a better alternative to the current welfare system. This

paper argued that participation income is the best alternative to current welfare system. Afterwards, it

answered the following research question: Are individuals more willing to engage in socially desirable

activities not recognized by the State today in a Participation Income setting or in the current welfare

system? Is this willingness dependent on the level of compensation?

First, this paper argued that participation income represents and ethically and politically

superior idea to other welfare proposals and would induce more participation in socially valuable

activities than the current welfare system. Moreover, the outdated arguments made against PI such as

its administrative overload and risk of government steered definition of participation were addressed

and solved with the new revolutionizing blockchain technology and the recent trend of the sharing

economy.

Page 31: Current welfare measures and participation income

31

After addressing PI’s outdated unfeasibility, this paper identified the new relevant challenge

that PI is facing, finding the right level of compensation. As literature in behavioral economics and

psychology suggests, individual’s intention to participate or performance is not defined by a clear and

straight forward relationship with the level of compensation. On the contrary, it was found that low

levels of compensation carry a risk of crowding out intrinsic motivation whilst higher level of

compensation do not always lead to a higher level of performance. Therefore, this research identified

a need to investigate the relationship of individual’s willingness to participate in a PI setting depending

on the level of compensation.

To provide an answer as to whether intention to participate is contingent on the level of

compensation, a vignette study was developed. Three vignette scenarios were created, all three

representing the same PI project with the only difference being the level of compensation offered to

individuals in return for their participation. One scenario offered no compensation at all, while the others

respectively offered a low (5 euros) and a high (10 euros) per hour compensation for engaging in

socially valuable activities. Through adapted scales developed from previous peer-reviewed studies, the

survey questionnaire measured how monetary compensation affected participant’s willingness to

participate in a possible PI scheme through intrinsic and extrinsic motivation.

Results were found by running a double mediation model through the PROCESS method of

Andrew F. Hayes (2013). They allow to formulate an answer to the second part of the research question.

Individual’s intention to participate is dependent on the level of compensation offered. Results indicated

a low monetary compensation leads to less intention to participate, supporting crowding out theory. The

experiment for higher compensation gives somewhat more mitigated results. No significant relationship

is found on how a high compensation affects willingness to participate, even though it still appears that

the higher the compensation the less intrinsic motivation is negatively affected by it.

Page 32: Current welfare measures and participation income

32

References.

Aguinis, H., & Bradley, K. J. (2014). Best practice recommendations for designing and implementing

experimental vignette methodology studies. Organizational Research Methods, 17(4), 351-371.

Ajzen, I. (1991). The theory of planned behavior. Organizational behavior and human decision

processes, 50(2), 179-211.

Arets, M. (2017, January 22). How Estonia became the most digital country in the world [Web log

post]. Retrieved April, 2018, from http://www.martijnarets.com/how-estonia-became-the-most-

digital-country-the-world/.

Ariely, D., Gneezy, U., Loewenstein, G., & Mazar, N. (2009). Large stakes and big mistakes. The

Review of Economic Studies, 76(2), 451-469.

Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What Can Be Done?.

Atkinson, A. B. (1996). The case for a participation income. The Political Quarterly, 67(1), 67-70.

Atzmüller, C., & Steiner, P. M. (2010). Experimental vignette studies in survey research. Methodology:

European Journal of Research Methods for the Behavioral and Social Sciences, 6(3), 128.

Barry, B. (1999). Basic Income and the Work Ethic. Reciprocity and the Guaranteed Income, 101.

BBC, Switzerland's voters reject basic income plan. (2016, June). Retrieved April, 2018, from

http://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-36454060.

Benkler, Y. (2004). Sharing nicely: On shareable goods and the emergence of sharing as a modality of

economic production. Yale LJ, 114, 273.

Böcker, L., & Meelen, T. (2017). Sharing for people, planet or profit? Analysing motivations for

intended sharing economy participation. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 23,

28-39.

Bowles, S., & Polania-Reyes, S. (2012). Economic incentives and social preferences: substitutes or

complements?. Journal of Economic Literature, 50(2), 368-425.

Page 33: Current welfare measures and participation income

33

Bucher, E., Fieseler, C., & Lutz, C. (2016). What's mine is yours (for a nominal fee)–Exploring the

spectrum of utilitarian to altruistic motives for Internet-mediated sharing. Computers in Human

Behavior, 62, 316-326.

Casaló, L. V., Flavián, C., & Guinalíu, M. (2010). Determinants of the intention to participate in firm-

hosted online travel communities and effects on consumer behavioral intentions. Tourism

management, 31(6), 898-911.

Cheng, S., Daub, M., Domeyer, A., & Lundqvist, M. (2017, February). Using blockchain to improve

data management in the public sector. McKinsey Global Institute. Retrieved April, 2018, from

https://www.mckinsey.com/business-functions/digital-mckinsey/our-insights/using-blockchain-to-

improve-data-management-in-the-public-sector.

Epstein, J., & Franklin, S. (2017, January 5). How Estonia can save the Western Civilization. THE

HILL. Retrieved April, 2018, from http://thehill.com/blogs/pundits-blog/international/312937-

how-estonia-can-save-western-civilization.

Finch, J. (1987). The vignette technique in survey research. Sociology, 21(1), 105-114.

Frey, B. S., & Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). The cost of price incentives: An empirical analysis of

motivation crowding-out. The American economic review, 87(4), 746-755.

Frey, B. S., & Jegen, R. (2001). Motivation crowding theory. Journal of economic surveys, 15(5), 589-

611.

Frey, C. B., & Osborne, M. A. (2017). The future of employment: how susceptible are jobs to

computerisation?. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 114, 254-280

Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). Pay enough or don't pay at all. The Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 115(3), 791-810.

Gneezy, U., & Rustichini, A. (2000). A fine is a price. The Journal of Legal Studies, 29(1), 1-17.

Gneezy, U., Meier, S., & Rey-Biel, P. (2011). When and why incentives (don't) work to modify

behavior. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(4), 191-210.

Page 34: Current welfare measures and participation income

34

Hamari, J., Sjöklint, M., & Ukkonen, A. (2016). The sharing economy: Why people participate in

collaborative consumption. Journal of the Association for Information Science and

Technology, 67(9), 2047-2059.

Hartl, B., Hofmann, E., & Kirchler, E. (2016). Do we need rules for “what's mine is yours”?

Governance in collaborative consumption communities. Journal of Business Research, 69(8), 2756-

2763.

Hayes, A. F. (2013). Introduction to mediation, moderation, and conditional process analysis: A

regression-based approach. Guilford Publications.

Hayes, A. F. (2009). Beyond Baron and Kenny: Statistical mediation analysis in the new

millennium. Communication monographs, 76(4), 408-420.

Hayes, A. F., & Cai, L. (2007). Using heteroskedasticity-consistent standard error estimators in OLS

regression: An introduction and software implementation. Behavior research methods, 39(4), 709-

722.

Heyman, J., & Ariely, D. (2004). Effort for payment: A tale of two markets. Psychological

science, 15(11), 787-793.

Higginson, M., Lorenz, J., Münstermann, B., & Olesen, P. B. (2017, March). The promise of

blockchain. McKinsey Global Institute.

Skidelsky, E., & Skidelsky, R. (2012). How much is enough?: money and the good life. Penguin UK.

Keynes, J. M. (1933). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren. Essays in persuasion, 358-73.

Lazear, E. P. (2000). Performance pay and productivity. American Economic Review, 90(5), 1346-

1361.

Manyika, J., Lund, S., Chui, M., Bughin, J., Woetzel, J., Batra, P., ... & Sanghvi, S. (2017). Jobs lost,

jobs gained: Workforce transitions in a time of automation. McKinsey Global Institute.

Neill, H. R., Cummings, R. G., Ganderton, P. T., Harrison, G. W., & McGuckin, T. (1994). Hypothetical

surveys and real economic commitments. Land economics, 145-154.

Page 35: Current welfare measures and participation income

35

Paul, M., Hennig-Thurau, T., Gremler, D. D., Gwinner, K. P., & Wiertz, C. (2009). Toward a theory of

repeat purchase drivers for consumer services. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 37(2),

215-237.

Pavlou, P. A., & Gefen, D. (2004). Building effective online marketplaces with institution-based

trust. Information systems research, 15(1), 37-59.

Ranzini, G., Newlands, G., Anselmi, G., Andreotti, A., Eichhorn, T., Etter, M., ... & Lutz, C. (2017).

Millennials and the Sharing Economy: European Perspectives.

Reeson, Andrew F., & John G. Tisdell. 2008. “Institutions, Motivations and Public Goods: An

Experimental Test of Motivational Crowding.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization,

68 (1): 273–81.Pérez-Muñoz, C. (2016). A defence of participation income. Journal of Public Policy,

36(2), 169-193.

Smith, A. (1822). The theory of moral sentiments (Vol. 1). J. Richardson.

Titmuss, R. M. (1970). The gift relationship. From human blood to social policy. The gift relationship.

Social policy.

Van Parijs, P. (2001). Basic Income: A simple and powerful idea for the 21st century. Redesigning

Distribution, 4.

Van Parijs, P. (1997). Real freedom for all: What (if anything) can justify capitalism?. OUP Catalogue.

Wallenstein, J., & Shelat, U. (2017, August 22). Hopping Aboard the Sharing Economy. Retrieved

April, 2018, from https://www.bcg.com/publications/2017/strategy-accelerating-growth-consumer-

products-hopping-aboard-sharing-economy.aspx.

West, D. M. (2018, April). Will robots and AI take your job? The economic and political

consequences of automation. Brookings publications. Retrieved from

https://www.brookings.edu/blog/techtank/2018/04/18/will-robots-and-ai-take-your-job-the-

economic-and-political-consequences-of-automation/

We have built a digital society and so can you. (n.d.). Retrieved April, 2018, from https://e-estonia.com/.

Page 36: Current welfare measures and participation income

36

Widerquist, K., Noguera, J. A., Vanderborght, Y., & De Wispelaere, J. (2013). Basic income: an

anthology of contemporary research.

White, S. (1997). Liberal equality, exploitation, and the case for an unconditional basic

income. Political studies, 45(2), 312-326.

White, K., MacDonnell, R., & Ellard, J. H. (2012). Belief in a just world: Consumer intentions and

behaviors toward ethical products. Journal of Marketing, 76(1), 103-118.

Wispelaere, J. D., & Stirton, L. (2007). The public administration case against participation income.

Social Service Review, 81(3), 523-549.

Yli-Huumo, J., Ko, D., Choi, S., Park, S., & Smolander, K. (2016). Where is current research on

blockchain technology?—a systematic review. PloS one, 11(10), e0163477.

Page 37: Current welfare measures and participation income

37

Appendix. Appendix 1A: no monetary compensation vignette.

Page 38: Current welfare measures and participation income

38

Appendix 1B: low monetary compensation vignette.

Page 39: Current welfare measures and participation income

39

Appendix 1C: high monetary compensation vignette.

Page 40: Current welfare measures and participation income

40

Appendix 2: Survey questionnaire.

Page 41: Current welfare measures and participation income

41

Page 42: Current welfare measures and participation income

42

Page 43: Current welfare measures and participation income

43

Appendix 3: overview of scales and original studies.

SCALE Study Questions

INTENTION TO PARTICIPATE

Hamari, J., Sjöklint, M., & Ukkonen, A. (2016).

• I can see myself engaging in “Live better together” in the future.

INTENTION TO PARTICIPATE

White, K., MacDonnell, R., & Ellard, J. H. (2012).

• I expect to exert a great deal of effort to participate in this community.

INTENTION TO PARTICIPATE

Pavlou, P. A., & Gefen, D. (2004). • Given the chance, I predict that I will consider participating in “Live better together”.

• It is likely that I would participate if “Live better together” takes place in the near future.

INTRINSIC MOTIVATION Paul, M., Hennig-Thurau, T., Gremler, D. D., Gwinner, K. P., & Wiertz, C. (2009).

• I would participate in “Living better together” because it helps to ensure that I can live in a thriving local community.

• I would participate in “Living better together” because it allows me to do something good for others.

• I would participate in “Living better together” because it allows me to have enjoyable interactions with others.

EXTRINSIC MOTIVATION Hamari, J., Sjöklint, M., & Ukkonen, A. (2016).

• My participation in “Live better together” will benefit me financially.

• My participation in “Live better together” could improve my economic situation.

• My Participation in “Live better together” will save me time.

VOLUNTEERING Bucher, E., Fieseler, C., & Lutz, C. (2016).

• I do volunteer work to help needy people. • I work with a group to solve a problem in

the community where I live.

Page 44: Current welfare measures and participation income

44

Appendix 4: overview of dummies. Categorical variables Dummy variables

Gender 0 = Men

1 = Female French nationality 0 = Others

1 = French Other nationalities (dutch, german, others) 0 = French

1 = Others High income level 0 = Else

1 = High Medium income level Else = 0 Medium = 1