customer concentration and managerial agency costs · 2019. 4. 24. · customer concentration and...

53
Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs * Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST) [email protected] Hyun-Dong Kim Sogang University [email protected] Kwangwoo Park Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST) [email protected] This version: February 15, 2019 * This research was supported by the Sogang University Research Grant of 2018 (201810007.01). Corresponding author: Professor of International Finance, Graduate School of International Studies, Sogang University; 35 Baekbeom-ro, Mapo-gu, Seoul 04107, South Korea; Tel: +82-2-705-8682; Email: [email protected]

Upload: others

Post on 07-Nov-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs*

Taeyeon Kim

Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST)

[email protected]

Hyun-Dong Kim†

Sogang University

[email protected]

Kwangwoo Park

Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology (KAIST)

[email protected]

This version: February 15, 2019

* This research was supported by the Sogang University Research Grant of 2018 (201810007.01).

† Corresponding author: Professor of International Finance, Graduate School of International Studies, Sogang

University; 35 Baekbeom-ro, Mapo-gu, Seoul 04107, South Korea; Tel: +82-2-705-8682; Email:

[email protected]

Page 2: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

1

Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs

Abstract

Using a sample of U.S. firms over the 1977-2016 period, we find that a higher level of

customer concentration is related to lower market value of suppliers’ excess cash. We

conjecture that managerial agency problems are aggravated in dependent suppliers with a few

large customers, resulting in investors’ lower assessment value to suppliers’ excess cash

reserves. Furthermore, we show that managers in supplier firms with higher customer

concentration receive greater compensation, engage in more value-destroying mergers, and

experience less forced turnover. Our results add an agency view to the prevailing risk-based

view of customer concentration in the existing literature.

JEL classifications: G30; G32; G34

Keywords: Customer concentration; managerial agency costs; value of cash; suppliers;

relationship-specific investments

Page 3: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

2

1. Introduction

The finance literature on a firm’s relationship with non-shareholder stakeholders—

including employees, suppliers, and customers—has grown dramatically over the past few

decades. Many existing studies on this area focus on the interaction between a firm and its

customers and suppliers, and examine how a firm’s supplier–customer relationship affects

corporate policy decisions.1 For example, Kale and Shahrur (2007) and Banerjee, Dasgupta

and Kim (2008) show that suppliers tend to maintain lower leverage when they depend on

major customers. Dhaliwal, Judd, Serfling and Shaikh (2016) and Campello and Gao (2017)

provide evidence that firms with a more concentrated customer base have a higher cost of

capital. Wang (2012) further find a negative relation between a supplier’s dependence on

supplier-customer relationships and its dividend payments.2

The existing studies, however, relate customer concentration to its business risks between

suppliers and stakeholders. Although the current literature improves our understanding on the

risk-based view on customer concentration, relativity little is known about agency issues that

stem from a firm’s supplier–customer relationship. In this paper, we fill this gap by

examining the relationship between customer concentration and the managerial agency

problem. Specifically, we focus on how a closer relationship with fewer and larger customers

induces and aggravates a supplier’s managerial agency problem.

When a firm’s business depends on a few major customers, the relationship with its

customers becomes more important as it affects the firm’s daily operation. These

1 “Customer concentration” is a commonly used concept in the supplier–customer relationship literature. A high

level of a supplier’s customer concentration indicates that the supplier depends on a small set of major

customers for a large portion of its sales. 2 Itzkowitz (2013) documents two recent trends in U.S. firms that relate to the increasing importance of

supplier–customer relationships. First, a decrease in diversification across industries and vertical integration has

been observed, creating new relationships between suppliers and customers. Second, shifting from selecting

customers based on price, many firms focus on a few major customers (partners) to create enduring business

relationships for better innovation, enhanced product quality, and more valuable teamwork.

Page 4: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

3

relationships include supply contracts and interactions between related people for managing

the transaction of goods and services (Crawford, Huang, Li, and Yang 2016). The extant

literature suggests that firms with concentrated customers are more beneficial because of

increased operational efficiencies (Patatoukas, 2011; Cen, Maydew, Zhang, and Zuo, 2017).

Moreover, by having a few key customers, suppliers may signal the market that their products

are of high quality (Cen, Dasgupta, Elkamhi, and Pungaliya, 2015).

There exists, however, a dark side of concentrated supplier-customer relationships.

Suppliers with a few major customers are less diversified, and are required to engage in

relationship-specific investments, which may have a very limited value outside the supplier-

customer relationship (Titman and Wessels, 1988; Allen and Phillips, 2000). Thus, customer-

dependent suppliers face a potential hold-up risk. The shocks threatening relationships with

concentrated customers can drive suppliers into a significant risk of financial distress,

reverberating throughout their supply chains (Kolay, Lemmon, and Tashjian, 2016; Intintoli,

Serfling, and Shaikh, 2017). Furthermore, given the long-lasting relationships with a few key

customers (Emshwiller, 1991), the suppliers have strong incentives to maintain their

relationships with such customers in the course of business (Raman and Shahrur, 2008).

Existing studies (e.g., Shleifer and Summers, 1988; Coates, 2001; Stout, 2002) suggest

that a firm needs to make a commitment not to act opportunistically to exploit its

counterparties’ quasi-rents.3 This idea is consistent with the view of Johnson, Karpoff, and Yi

(2015) that a supplier’s commitment is important for maintaining a supplier–customer

relationship. In the relationship between customer-dependent suppliers and major customers,

implicit contracts to engage in this type of firm commitment appear to be valuable in

3 Quasi-rents occur when a counterparty engages in a relationship-specific investment that may lose value if the

firm adjusts its policies and decisions (Johnson et al., 2015).

Page 5: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

4

resolving hold-up problems (Gillan, Hartzell, and Parrino, 2009; Johnson et al., 2015).4 Such

implicit contracts are informally implemented by managers’ personal connections and

reputations with their major counterparties (Klein and Leffler, 1981). Johnson et al. (2015)

note that CEOs’ personal connections and reputations at customer-dependent suppliers are

essential in retaining long-term relationships with customers.5

In line with this thought, managers of customer-dependent suppliers are hired for their

personal commitments to their customers (Shleifer and Summers, 1988; Intintoli et al., 2017).

Such connections and reputations make it possible that suppliers do not behave themselves

like opportunists to exploit their customers’ quasi-rents (Johnson et al., 2015). Accordingly,

personal commitments encourage customers to consistently engage in relationship-specific

investment. However, if the managers are removed, existing personal commitments are no

longer effective, and suppliers fail to retain their stable relationship with customers (Shleifer

and Summers, 1988). In a similar vein, Johnson et al. (2015) suggest that takeover defenses

become important in maintaining implicit commitments because they decrease the likelihood

of managerial replacement. Intintoli et al. (2017) further show that the replacement of

managers disrupting supplier–customer relationships has a negative effect on the financial

performance of suppliers. Taken together, incumbent CEOs of customer-dependent suppliers

who have personal connections and reputations are most likely to continue close relationships

with major customers. This implies that replacing these CEOs is costly to suppliers with

concentrated customers.

Since the seminal work by Jensen and Meckling (1976), extensive literature argues that

4 In the classical Fisher Body–General Motors example described in Klein, Crawford and Alchian (1978),

managers of Fisher Body (supplier) could promise not to increase prices to appropriate General Motors’

(customer) quasi-rents. See Klein et al. (1978), Johnson et al. (2015), and Gillan et al. (2009) for more detailed

descriptions of the Fisher Body–General Motors example. 5 Johnson et al. (2015) provide an example of the Pemstar–International Business Machines case in their study.

See Johnson et al. (2015) for more detailed descriptions on the case.

Page 6: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

5

an agency conflict between a principal (a shareholder) and an agency (a manager) occurs due

to an irreversible investment from their unique relationship (Williamson, 1975; Klein et al.,

1978; Grossman and Hart, 1986). In particular, Shleifer and Vishny (1989) model how

managers can entrench themselves by engaging in manager-specific investments. Managers

have an incentive to engage in businesses associated with their skills and expertise. Specially,

managers focus on investing in assets specific to their skills, and the value of such assets

would be higher than if they were controlled by alternative managers without the required set

of skills. Such investments will make themselves valuable to shareholders and they are less

likely to be replaced even after a poor performance. As a result, managers can be entrenched

and pursue perquisites by wasting free cash flow.

Returning to the issue of dependent suppliers on concentrated customers, we conjecture

that CEOs having implicit commitments with concentrated customers are more likely to make

manager-specific investments associated with supplier–customer relationships. So, replacing

CEOs of customer-dependent suppliers imposes a substantial cost to these firms. Hence,

CEOs with major customers can entrench themselves by engaging in excessive investments

in their own specific assets. In this regard, managerial agency problems resulting from

manager-specific investments appear to be significantly prevalent in suppliers with highly

concentrated customers.

As an example of agency costs in practice, extensive studies discuss that managers waste

corporate resources by using the resources to their own devices. To capture the inefficient

uses of corporate resources and the possible value destruction resulting from agency

problems, we focus on cash reserves.6 Firms should hold a certain amount of cash to pay out

6 Three reasons are suggested by extant literature for using cash reserves as a proxy for agency costs (e.g.,

Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith, 2007; Frésard and Salva, 2010; Faulkender and Wang, 2006). First, managers can

easily access cash reserves with little monitoring, and also have much discretion on their use. Thus, cash may

provide managers with resources to invest in non-positive net present value (NPV) projects, destroying

Page 7: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

6

funds for day-by-day operation, and to provide a buffer against unexpected events or the cost

of external financing for their investments. However, if cash reserves are held in excess of the

amount committed for operations and investments, they can be exploited as resources for

managers’ private benefits (Myers and Rajan, 1998). In this case, holding excessive cash may

harm firm value, suggesting that the market value of one dollar cash reserves may not be

equivalent to the value of a dollar. To justify this thought, Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007)

and Frésard and Salva (2010) examine how investors value excess cash holdings of a firm

with weak governance. When investors recognize that managers may use cash inefficiently,

the market value of those resources is discounted. We thus hypothesize that excess cash

holdings of suppliers with more concentrated customers will be valued lower by investors

because managerial agency problems are expected to be more severe for such suppliers.

Using a comprehensive sample of U.S. firms spanning 1977 to 2016, we examine the

relationship between suppliers’ customer concentration and their managerial agency costs.

We find that a higher level of customer concentration is related to a lower market value of

suppliers’ excess cash, implying that managerial agency problems are expected to be more

severe in suppliers with concentrated customers. Our baseline results may be subject to

endogeneity concerns related to measurement errors, omitted variable bias, and reverse

causality. Hence, we conduct various tests designed to mitigate potential endogeneity issues.

Our results are qualitatively similar when we employ alternative measures for the market

value of excess cash and also control for time-invariant omitted CEO and firm characteristics,

as well as corporate governance. Moreover, the results still hold when a propensity score

matching procedure and two-stage least square regressions are run.

shareholders’ wealth. Second, firms reserve substantial amounts of cash, and the value of cash holdings accounts

for a significant proportion of their wealth. Third, while a supplier–customer level is quite sticky, the degree of

cash holdings substantially varies over time. This variation in cash provides us with an optimal setting to test the

effect of customer concentration on the value of cash in suppliers.

Page 8: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

7

In addition, we investigate how customer concentration affects CEO compensation and

acquisition decisions to confirm the existence of agency problems. Our results show that

managers in suppliers with higher customer concentration receive greater compensation than

vice versa. Such suppliers also experience lower abnormal stock returns after a mergers and

acquisitions (M&A) announcement upon acquiring a target firm. Thus, when a business

relationship with customers is more important, managers extract higher benefits from

shareholders, in the form of receiving a higher compensation and investing in value-

destroying deals.

Next, we examine the possible channel through which higher customer concentration

leads to managerial agency costs of suppliers. Because supplier–customer relationships

become more important for suppliers who highly depend on a few major customers, these

suppliers are likely to hire managers who are better able to retain customer relationships.

Thus, supplier–customer relationships are most valuable under current managers and

replacing managers is very costly to suppliers with a highly concentrated customer base. As

expected, we find that customer-related CEOs are more prevalent in suppliers with higher,

than lower, customer concentration. Our finding also shows that such managers are less

forced out, allowing them greater job security.

We further identify potential circumstances wherein customer concentration is more

closely associated with managerial agency problems. We find that the negative relationship

between customer concentration and the market value of excess cash is more pronounced in

suppliers that are dependent on major customers who can easily switch their suppliers. This

result shows that the negative market value of excess cash from customer concentration

occurs particularly under circumstances wherein the management of supplier–customer

relationships and the role of the supplier’s manager are more important.

Page 9: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

8

Our study contributes to the extant literature in numerous ways. First, to the best of our

knowledge, we are the first to directly examine managerial agency costs of suppliers that

result from their concentrated customer base. Prior studies investigate the governance role of

customers in suppliers, and postulate that major customers have incentives to monitor the

managers of suppliers (Wang, 2012; Johnson et al., 2015; Kang, Liu, Yi, and Zhang, 2015).

Shifting our attention from the literature on customers’ role in monitoring supplier managers,

we focus on managerial agency conflicts with shareholders in customer-dependent suppliers

and suggest a mechanism by which managerial agency problems occur.7 Second, our study

adds to the literature that investigates management entrenchment due to manager-specific

investments (e.g., Shleifer and Vishny, 1989). Our findings show that managers for suppliers

with major customers can entrench themselves by engaging in specific investments

associated with supplier–customer relationships. Third, our findings also contribute to the

existing literature on the value of cash holdings (e.g., Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith, 2007;

Faulkender and Wang, 2006). These extant studies mainly address how corporate governance

and corporate financial policy affect the value of cash. We further show that the marginal

value of excess cash declines with higher customer concentration.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the sample and variables

used in this study, and provides the descriptive statistics. Next, section 3 discusses the

empirical results of our paper. Finally, section 4 presents our conclusions.

7 The monitoring roles of customers can be different from those of general shareholders. Since customers are

concerned about their suppliers’ daily operations rather than growth or performance, their incentives to monitor

managers of suppliers depend largely on how effectively their implicit contracts are enforced (Wang, 2012;

Kang et al., 2015). On the other hand, shareholder incentives to monitor their managers vary with the size of

their financial claims (Shleifer and Vishny, 1986), implying that the interests of customers are different from

those of shareholders. These arguments suggest that agency conflicts between shareholders and managers still

exist in suppliers with a highly concentrated customer base, even though customers appropriately monitor their

suppliers’ managers.

Page 10: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

9

2. Data Description and Research Design

2.1 Sample Construction

We obtain supplier–customer data from the segment customer files provided by

Compustat. We also collect accounting and financial information from Compustat, and then

match it with supplier–customer data. We exclude firms with missing data and firms in

utilities (SIC 4900-4999) and financial industries (SIC 6000-6999) because their financial

decisions are heavily regulated by the government. Moreover, firms with negative excess

cash holdings are excluded since financial constraints are likely to be more important to

determine the market value of excess cash rather than managerial agency cost. Our final

sample contains 67,016 U.S. supplier-year observations from 1977 to 2016.

To conduct additional tests, we collect diverse information from several data sources. The

analyst forecasting and CEO-level variables are obtained from the Institutional Brokers’

Estimate System (I/B/E/S) and ExecuComp dataset, respectively. We retrieve a sample of

M&A deals from the Securities Data Company (SDC) Platinum database, and obtain stock

information from Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP). Moreover, information on

CEO forced turnover is hand-collected using Factiva, and corporate governance variables are

obtained from the Institutional Shareholder Services (ISS) database.

2.2 Customer Concentration Measures

We identify suppliers and their major customers from Compustat. Since 1976, the

Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 14 (SFAS 14) has required suppliers to

report their major customers that account for 10% or more of their total sales. Segment

customer files of Compustat provide the information on the SFAS 14 regulation, including

suppliers’ and names of their major customers, as well as suppliers’ sales to each major

Page 11: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

10

customer. Although suppliers are required to identify customers who represent at least 10% of

their sales, some suppliers voluntarily report accounting information of customers that

constitute less than 10% of their total sales. To reduce a potential selection bias, we exclude

this customer data when measuring relevant variables.

Following Dhaliwal et al. (2016), we construct three different variables to measure a

customer concentration level. First, we construct an indicator variable that is equal to one if a

supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for 10% or more of its sales and

zero otherwise. This variable is denoted as Major Customer for the remainder of this paper.

Second, based on Banerjee et al. (2008), we define Major Customer Sales as the fraction of

the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. Major Customer Sales is calculated

as follows:

𝑀𝑎𝑗𝑜𝑟 𝐶𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝑆𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠𝑖,𝑡 = ∑ 𝑆𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡𝜂𝑖,𝑡

𝑗=1 (1)

where 𝜂𝑖,𝑡 is the number of supplier 𝑖’s major customers in year 𝑡, and sales ratio is the

ratio of supplier 𝑖’s sales to major customer 𝑗 over supplier 𝑖’s total sales in year 𝑡. A high

level of Major Customer Sales indicates that a large fraction of a supplier’s sales is captured

by its major customers.

Following Patatoukas (2011), we also define the third measure of customer concentration,

Customer HHI, as a Herfindahl index of supplier’s sales to major customers, and calculate

this variable as below:

𝐶𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝐻𝐻𝐼𝑖,𝑡 = ∑ 𝑆𝑎𝑙𝑒𝑠 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑗,𝑡2𝜂𝑖,𝑡

𝑗=1 (2)

This measure considers both the number of major customers and the volume of a

supplier’s sales to each major customer. Higher Customer HHI means that a large proportion

of a supplier’s sales comes from a small number of major customers.

In addition, Major Customer Sales and Customer HHI take the value of zero if a supplier

Page 12: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

11

does not report any major customer, otherwise they take the value of one if a supplier

depends on only one major customer.

2.3 Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings

We use the market value of suppliers’ excess cash holdings to measure their managerial

agency cost. Excess cash, defined as the cash that is not required for firm operations or

investments, is measured as the cash reserved above a predicted normal level of cash by

following Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007). We estimate the amount of normal cash by

regressing suppliers’ cash holdings on variables that capture their various motives of cash

reserves as identified by the extant literature (Fama and French, 1998; Dittmar and Mahrt-

Smith, 2007; Frésard and Salva, 2010).8 In addition, we control for customer concentration

level in those regressions because suppliers with more concentrated customers tend to hold

more cash than those with less concentrated customers (Itzkowitz, 2013; Bae and Wang,

2015). Then, excess cash, denoted as Xcash, is calculated as the residuals from regressions on

normal cash. We only consider positive excess cash because negative excess cash concerns

financial constraints rather than agency issues.

To measure the market value of excess cash, we regress the market value of the firm on

excess cash holdings and other control variables based on Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007).

In this regression, the interaction term between customer concentration and excess cash, our

main variables of interest, is included to capture the effect of customer concentration on the

market value of excess cash. We also run the regression with a customer concentration

variable to control for customer concentration’s direct impacts on the market value of the

8 Firms’ motive to hold cash includes hedging needs, growth options, and financing restrictions. Our regression

model of excess cash estimation is fully described in Appendix B.

Page 13: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

12

firm. Our regression model is shown below:

𝑀𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡 𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽1𝐶𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽2𝑋𝑐𝑎𝑠ℎ𝑖,𝑡 +

𝛽3𝐶𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑐𝑒𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑖,𝑡 ∗ 𝑋𝑐𝑎𝑠ℎ𝑖,𝑡 +

𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑜𝑙 𝑉𝑎𝑟𝑖𝑎𝑏𝑙𝑒𝑠 + 𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟 𝐹𝑖𝑥𝑒𝑑 𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑠 +

𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑦 𝐹𝑖𝑥𝑒𝑑 𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑠 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 (3)

where Market Value/Assetsi,t is the market value of supplier i scaled by total assets at time t,

which is calculated as the sum of market value of equity and book value of short- and long-

term debt divided by total assets. Customer Concentrationi,t and Xcashi,t are supplier i’s

customer concentration and excess cash holdings in period t, respectively.

Following Fama and French (1998), we control for suppliers’ earnings, research and

development (R&D) expenditures, interest expenses, and dividend payouts. To control for

investors’ expectation, we also include two-year lagged (from year t-2 to year t) and forward

(from year t to year t+2) changes of these control variables, as well as two-year forward

changes in the market value of the firm. All controls are normalized by total assets, and year

and industry fixed effects are included in the regressions.

2.4 Descriptive Statistics

Panel A of Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics for our variables. The mean value of

Major Customer is 0.345, which indicates that 34.5% of suppliers in our sample have at least

one major customer. The average supplier’s sales to major customers account for 13.9% of

total sales, and the mean value of Customer HHI is 0.047. Suppliers with at least one major

customer sell 40.2% of their total sales to those customers on average, and the mean value of

their Customer HHI is 0.136. The mean excess cash held by suppliers is 0.867, and cash

reserves account for 19.8% of total assets on average. The mean total assets and net assets of

Page 14: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

13

suppliers are 2,261 and 1,975 million dollars, respectively. On average, the market value of

the firm to total assets is 1.159, and earnings ratio to total assets is 0.087. The average R&D

expenditure and interest expense amount to 3.8% and 2.7% of total assets, respectively.

Moreover, the mean value of dividend ratio is 0.010. To mitigate the outlier effect, all

continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level.

[Insert Table 1 here]

We conduct univariate tests to obtain preliminary insights on the relationship between

customer concentration and excess cash. In Panel B of Table 1, we split the sample into two

groups according to whether or not suppliers disclose at least one major customer. We

perform the difference-in-mean and difference-in-median tests between these two groups.

Suppliers with at least one major customer hold more excess cash than those without a major

customer. Specifically, the mean value of excess cash holdings is 0.899 for suppliers that

have at least one major customer, whereas it is 0.849 for those with no major customer. The

difference is statistically significant at the 1% confidence level. The results of the univariate

tests suggest that agency problems are more severe in suppliers with more concentrated

customers.9 In addition, suppliers with at least one major customer have smaller total assets

and net assets; higher cash, market value, and R&D expenditure; and lower interest expense

and dividend payouts.10 These results are consistent with the extant literature.11

9 Since suppliers with more concentrated customers are likely to face high risks (Itzkowitz, 2013; Bae and

Wang, 2015; Dhaliwal et al., 2016; Campello and Gao, 2017), they may hold more cash reserves. To focus on

the agency problem, rather than the precautionary purpose of cash holdings, we investigate the market value of

excess cash holdings using positive excess cash, as explained in section 2.3. 10 Campello and Gao (2017) find that higher customer concentration increases interest rate spreads since the

risk of firms with concentrated customers is higher than the risk for other firms. Such firms suffer from higher

costs of debt and may face difficulties in raising capital from debt financing, thus yielding lower leverage and

interest expense. 11 See Wang (2012), Itzkowitz (2013), Dhaliwal et al. (2016), Campello and Gao (2017), and Krolikowski and

Yuan (2017).

Page 15: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

14

3. Baseline Regression Analysis

To investigate the effect of customer concentration on the market value of excess cash

holdings, we estimate equation (3) by using ordinary least square (OLS) regressions. Table 2

presents our baseline results. In column (1), we use Major Customer as a customer

concentration measure, and the coefficient on excess cash (Xcash), -0.253, is significantly

negative at the 1% level. Given suppliers with positive excess cash are only used in our

analysis, negative coefficient on excess cash appears to be reasonable because investors may

be concerned about excessive cash reserves that can potentially result in an agency problem.

The coefficient on interaction term between customer concentration and excess cash (Major

Customer*Xcash here), our main variable of interest, is -0.116, with statistical significance at

the 1% level. This result suggests that the market value of excess cash is lower in suppliers

with at least one major customer than in those with no major customer. In the perspective of

economic significance, the market value of suppliers with at least one major customer

decreases by $ 0.369 (=0.253+0.116) as they hold an additional one dollar of excess cash,

whereas the market value of those with no major customer reduces by $0.253 with an

additional one dollar of excess cash.

[Insert Table 2 here]

Columns (2) and (3) of Table 2 present the regression results using Major Customer Sales

and Customer HHI as the measures of customer concentration, respectively. The coefficients

on Xcash and Customer Concentration*Xcash are significantly negative at the 1% level.

Given that the means of Major Customer Sales and Customer HHI are 0.139 and 0.047 in

Panel A of Table 1, respectively, the market value of an additional one dollar on excess cash

is -$ 0.298 (=-0.249-0.354*0.139) and -$0.300 (=-0.259-0.875*0.047), respectively. If Major

Customer Sales and Customer HHI increase by one standard deviation (0.379 for Major

Page 16: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

15

Customer Sales and 0.160 for Customer HHI in Panel A of Table 1), the market value of an

additional one dollar of excess cash is -$ 0.383 (=-0.249-0.354*0.379) and -$ 0.399 (=-0.259-

0.875*0.160), respectively. Accordingly, the results of columns (2) and (3) show that the one-

standard-deviation increases in Major Customer Sales and Customer HHI lead to around 30%

drop in the market value of excess cash. These results are qualitatively similar when we re-

estimate equation (3) using a subset of suppliers that report at least one major customer in

columns (4) and (5). Overall, our results of Table 2 show that the negative impact of customer

concentration on the market value of excess cash holdings is economically significant,

thereby providing empirical evidence on the presence of managerial agency problems in

suppliers with a concentrated customer base.

4. Endogeneity Issue

In section 3, we have shown a negative relationship between customer concentration and

the market value of excess cash holdings. However, our results might be subject to various

types of endogeneity problems, such as measurement error, omitted variable bias, and reverse

causality. Although we measure our main variables and control for other determinants by

following prior literature, a measurement error and an omitted variables bias can still

influence both customer concentration and the market value of excess cash holdings. Such

issues would make our observed relationship suspicious. Because exogenous variations in

customer concentration measures appear to be insufficient, reverse causality may also arise in

the baseline results. Thus, we perform additional tests to mitigate endogeneity concerns.

4.1 Alternative Measures for the Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings

In Table 3, we address issues on measurement errors by employing the market value of

Page 17: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

16

cash ratio and the forecasted market value of excess cash holdings, instead of the market

value of excess cash holdings. We re-estimate our baseline specification in Panel A of Table 3

using cash ratio. In columns (1)–(3), the coefficients on Cash Ratio are significantly positive.

Given that cash holdings can be used as buffers for new investments or against financial

constraints, the positive sign seems to be reasonable. Furthermore, the coefficients on the

interaction term between customer concentration and cash ratio are negative, with statistical

significance at the 1% level. These results are consistent with our baseline results in Table 2,

indicating that the market value of cash ratio is lower for suppliers with more concentrated

customers.

[Insert Table 3 here]

In our normal cash regressions used to calculate excess cash, we control for the market

value of assets normalized by total assets, but this variable is included again as a dependent

variable in equation (3). This measurement process may lead to endogeneity related to the

market value of assets. To address endogeneity, we use the forecasted market value of assets.

The market value of assets forecasted by analysts is measured as the sum of the forecasted

market value of equity and the book value of short- and long-term debt. In addition,

forecasted market value of equity is defined as the product of the common shares outstanding

and the average target price predicted by analysts. To calculate the average target stock price,

we use analysts’ prediction, whose forecast horizon is 12 months; the prediction is announced

within three months before and after the fiscal year end. Because analysts are more informed

than other types of investors, their predicted market value of excess cash would better reflect

governance issues, including agency problems.

In Panel B of Table 3, we re-run the regressions with the forecasted market value

normalized by total assets. The coefficients on the interaction term between customer

Page 18: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

17

concentration and excess cash remain significantly negative in all columns, suggesting that

analysts poorly evaluate excess cash holdings of suppliers that depend on a few major

customers. Taken together, our main results hold unaffected even when we use alternative

measures for the market value of excess cash holdings.

4.2 Propensity Score Matched Sample Analysis

We have so far controlled for various firm-level characteristics, but our estimation may

still suffer from omitted variables that correlate with both customer concentration and the

market value of excess cash holdings. To address any omitted variable bias, we employ a

propensity score matching procedure to enable a closer comparison between firms sharing

similar characteristics in all respects, with the only exception of customer concentration.

Using a logit regression model, we first regress Major Customer on our control variables

used in equation (3), and estimate the propensity score—that is, the probability that a supplier

has at least one major customer. Based on a nearest-neighbor propensity score matching

procedure, we match each supplier with at least one major customer to a supplier with no

major customer, but with the closest propensity score. Finally, we construct a smaller

subsample of suppliers with at least one major customer and matched suppliers with no major

customer. We then run our main regression again for this subsample in Table 4.

[Insert Table 4 here]

The results using a subsample obtained from propensity score matching are comparable to

our baseline result in Table 2. The coefficients on Xcash’s interaction terms with customer

concentration are significantly negative in columns (1)–(3). This is clear indication that our

earlier finding is not likely to be a by-product of omitted variable issues.

Page 19: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

18

4.3 CEO and Firm Fixed Effects Regressions

To additionally alleviate any omitted variable bias, we re-estimate baseline regressions

with CEO and fixed effects in Table 5. Columns (1)–(3) report the results including the CEO

fixed effects, and the other columns present those with firm fixed effects regression.12 All

coefficients on interaction terms between customer concentration and excess cash are

negative, with statistical significance at the 1% level. These results suggest that omitted

variables related to CEO or firm characteristics are not likely to drive our baseline finding.

[Insert Table 5 here]

4.4 Two-stage Least Squares Regressions

Furthermore, we run two-stage least squares (2SLS) regressions with instrumental

variables in order to mitigate primary endogeneity issues, including omitted variable bias and

reverse causality. Particularly, we address endogeneity concerns that may arise because the

exogenous variations in our customer concentration variables are not sufficient. An

instrumental variable used in our 2SLS regressions should capture a variation in customer

concentration (i.e., inclusion restriction), but be exogenous to the market value of assets (i.e.,

exclusion restriction). As in Campello and Gao (2017), we employ M&A activities in major

customers’ industries (horizontal M&A), denoted as Customer M&A, as an instrumental

variable. Extant studies (e.g., Fee and Thomas, 2004; Bhattacharyya and Nain, 2011;

Campello and Gao, 2017) show that suppliers tend to engage in business with more

concentrated customers after M&A waves in their customers’ industries because the number

of customers decreases by their horizontal M&A. Therefore, M&A activities in major

12 We use ExecuComp database to retrieve information on CEOs. Because ExecuComp database starts from

1993, our sample substantially decreases in the regressions with CEO fixed effects.

Page 20: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

19

customers’ industries are positively associated with the level of customer concentration,

which satisfies the inclusion restriction. On the other hand, Customer M&A appears to affect

suppliers’ market value of assets only through the supplier–customer link—that is, a shock of

customers’ industries is unlikely to directly influence supplier characteristics, which satisfies

the exclusion restriction.

For the M&A data, we focus on observations with the deals that are initiated and

completed by acquirers in the same two-digit SIC code as their targets. We use the deal value

of M&A normalized by the acquirer’s total sales as a proxy for acquisition activity. Then, the

extent of industry-level acquisition is defined as the average acquisition activities of firms in

a given industry over the past five years. The five-year window is used to prevent a few big

deals from driving the total deal value. Next, we manually match the reported major

customers’ name with the historical company name listed on the Compustat database.13,14

Finally, after matching major customers’ industries with industry-level acquisition activities,

we measure Customer M&A as the weighted sum of acquisition activities across industries in

which the supplier’s major customers operate.15 To meet the exclusion condition, we exclude

the observations that a supplier operates in the same industries with its customers.

Our main regressions include two potential endogenous variables, Customer

Concentration and Customer Concentration*Xcash. Thus, we run two first-stage regressions

with two instrumental variables, Customer M&A and Customer M&A*Xcash, following the

methodology of Benmelech and Frydman (2015). Our two instrumental variables are

included in each first-stage regression. In addition, suppliers that report their major customers

13 While the Compustat segment customer file provides suppliers’ identification number, customers’

identification numbers are not available. 14 Our sample significantly reduces because we use only suppliers whose major customers are matched with

Compustat’s historical company data. 15 Since a supplier may have major customers operating in different industries, we use the weight that is defined

as the supplier’s percentage sales to each major customer.

Page 21: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

20

are only useful because we should know the major customers’ names to measure Customer

M&A. Under this construction rule, a sample of Major Customer equal to one only remains,

making Major Customer useless in the 2SLS regression. We therefore employ Major

Customer Sales and Customer HHI as customer concentration variables. Table 6 reports the

results on 2SLS regressions.

[Insert Table 6 here]

Columns (1)–(4) present the results of first-stage regressions, and columns (5) and (6)

report those of the second-stage regressions. Major Customer Sales is used in columns (1),

(2), and (5), while Customer HHI is used in columns (3), (4), and (6). Major Customer Sales

and Customer HHI are included in the first-stage regression as dependent variables in

columns (1) and (3), respectively. In addition, Major Customer Sales*Xcash and Customer

HHI*Xcash are used as dependent variables in columns (2) and (4), respectively. On the other

hand, the market value of assets normalized by total assets is included in the second-stage

regressions as a dependent variable. The coefficients on Customer M&A (Customer

M&A*Xcash) in columns (1) and (3) (columns (2) and (4)) are significantly positive. The F-

statistics of the first-stage regressions are also sizable, exceeding the rule-of-thumb value of

10 for the weak instrument test. In the second-stage regressions, the coefficients on the

interaction terms between customer concentration and excess cash (Major Customer

Sales*Xcash and Customer HHI*Xcash) are negative, with statistical significance at the 1%

level. The results on the F-statistics obtained from the Wu–Hausman test also confirm that

our customer concentration measures are exogenous by themselves. In short, our main

finding, namely, the negative impact of customer concentration on managerial agency

problems, remains significant, suggesting that the result is not likely to be driven by

endogeneity issues

Page 22: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

21

5. Further Robustness Tests

5.1 Alternative Measures of Managerial Agency Costs

We have far argued that excess cash held by suppliers with more customer concentration

is poorly valued by the capital market because of the potential agency problem. In this

section, we perform additional robustness tests to confirm the presence of an agency problem

for suppliers with a concentrated customer base.

Following Masulis, Wang and Xie (2009) and Chen, Harford and Lin (2015), we first

focus on CEO compensation. Since CEO compensation can be the most direct way to shift

shareholders’ wealth to managers, a rich body of literature on corporate governance considers

a higher level of CEO compensation, relative to comparable firms, as a by-product of a

managerial agency problem (e.g., Bertrand and Mullainathan, 1999; Core, Holthausen, and

Larcker, 1999; Masulis et al., 2009; Chen et al., 2015). Thus, we expect that managers of

suppliers with a highly concentrated customer base will receive a higher level of

compensation customer concentration.

Panel A of Table 7 shows the regression results for the effect of customer concentration

on CEO compensation. We employ two different CEO compensation variables, ln(CEO Total

Compensation) and CEO Excess Compensation, as dependent variables. ln(CEO Total

Compensation) is the natural logarithm of total annual compensation of CEO, while CEO

Excess Compensation is the residuals from the regression of the natural logarithm of CEO

total compensation on the natural logarithm of total market value of the firm. Following

Masulis et al. (2009), firm size (ln(Assets)), Tobin’s q (Tobin’s Q), return on assets (ROA),

leverage(Leverage), excess stock return (Excess Stock Return), stock return volatility (Stock

Return Volatility), R&D expenses (R&D Expenses/Assets), capital expenditure

Page 23: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

22

(CAPEX/Assets), firm ages (ln(Firm Age)), and CEO tenure (ln(CEO Tenure)) are included as

control variables in the regressions.

[Insert Table 7 here]

In general, ln(CEO Total Compensation) and CEO Excess Compensation are positively

related to Customer Concentration, with statistical significance. Those results show that CEO

total and excess compensation increase with a more concentrated customer base, supporting

our conjecture that customer concentration appears to induce a managerial agency problem

for suppliers.

Furthermore, we explore managerial decisions on mergers in suppliers with a

concentrated customer base to identify the positive relationship between customer

concentration and the agency problem in suppliers. The literature suggests that an acquisition

can be used to pursue managers’ private benefit at the expense of shareholders (e.g., Jensen

and Ruback, 1983; Masulis, Wang, and Xie, 2007). Since agency-driven managers want to

construct their own empire building by increasing firm size and scope, they have incentive to

engage in value-destroying merges. Masulis et al. (2009) and Chen et al. (2015) show that

firms that suffer from an agency problem experience negative announcement abnormal

returns on their M&A decisions. In a similar vein, we investigate whether there are negative

announcement returns on the acquisitions initiated by suppliers with a high customer

concentration.

For our M&A data, we require that acquisitions are completed, and acquirers have stock

return during 210 trading days before the announcement data. Then, we compute the five-day

cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) over the (-2, +2) window around the announcement

date of mergers, which is denoted as CAR(-2, +2).16 We additionally construct Negative

16 We calculate abnormal returns using the residuals from a market model. Its parameters are estimated over the

Page 24: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

23

CAR(-2, +2) Dummy, which is an indicator variable that is equal to one if CAR(-2, +2) is

negative and zero otherwise. Based on M&A literature (e.g., Masulis et al., 2007 and Masulis

et al., 2009), we control for various firm and deal characteristics that can affect

announcement stock returns on mergers. For firm controls, ln(Assets), Tobin’s Q, ROA, and

Leverage are used in our analysis; the deal characteristics include Relative Deal Size, High-

tech, Diversifying Acquisition, Public Target, Private Target, Subsidiary Target, Stock Deal,

and All Cash Deal. Detailed definitions for each variable are available in Appendix A.

Panel B of Table 7 presents the results for the regressions of announcement abnormal

stock returns on customer concentration. CAR(-2, +2) and Negative CAR(-2, +2) Dummy are

used as dependent variables in columns (1)–(3) and (4)–(6), respectively. The coefficients on

Customer Concentration are significantly negative in columns (1)–(3), showing that suppliers

with more concentrated customers experience lower abnormal returns after their acquisition

announcement. Moreover, Customer Concentration is positively and significantly related to

Negative CAR(-2, +2) Dummy in columns (4)–(6). This result indicates that, as suppliers

become more dependent on a few major concentrated customers, they tend to engage more in

value-destroying deals. Overall, our findings from Table 7 suggest that managerial agency

problems are aggravated in suppliers with more concentrated customers.

5.2 Possible Channel

We have argued that the role of CEOs in managing customers is more important in

suppliers with a highly concentrated customer base. Thus, replacing the managers is very

costly to such suppliers, and these managers can be entrenched. In this section, we examine

the importance of a supplier’s CEO for maintaining customer relationships in order to

(-210, -11) window and market returns are measured as the value-weighted return of CRSP.

Page 25: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

24

identify a potential channel through which customer concentration may affect managerial

agency costs of suppliers.

First, we investigate whether CEOs who are better able to manage supplier–customer

relationships are more likely to be appointed by suppliers with a higher customer

concentration. We consider a CEO who formerly served major customers as a competent

CEO in managing customer relations. To construct this variable, information on the CEO’s

work experience is obtained from the ISS database. The variable Customer-related CEO is

defined as an indicator variable equal to one if the supplier’s CEO previously served as a

senior manager or board member for one or more major customers, and zero otherwise. Then,

we analyze whether suppliers with more concentrated customers more frequently hire CEOs

who previously worked for major customers.

Table 8 reports the results of univariate comparisons and multivariate regressions to

examine the relationship between customer concentration and customer-related CEO. In

Panel A, we split the sample into two groups according to whether or not the supplier has a

higher level of customer concentration than the median of the total sample’s customer

concentration level. We then test the difference in mean between these two groups. We find

that a customer-related CEO is more likely present in the sample with a higher, than lower,

customer concentration, suggesting that CEOs who better manage customer relations are

more likely to serve suppliers with more concentrated customers. Panel B of Table 8 presents

the results from logit regressions of the customer-related CEO on customer concentration. All

coefficients on Customer Concentration are significantly positive, indicating that CEOs who

have former work experience with major customers tend to serve suppliers with a highly

concentrated customer base. Thus, the results in Table 8 imply that CEOs who are better able

to manage supplier–customer relationships are more frequently appointed by suppliers for

Page 26: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

25

whom retaining relationships with customers is more important.

[Insert Table 8 here]

Second, we examine the relationship between CEO forced turnover and customer

concentration. It would be more difficult for suppliers with higher customer concentration to

dismiss their CEOs because the role of CEOs in managing relationships with customers may

be more valuable in such suppliers.

To measure the forced CEO turnover, we initially collect information on CEO departure

from the ExecuComp database. Next, we manually identify reasons for CEO departure using

the Factiva search engine, and classify CEO departure into forced turnover and voluntary

leave. Following Parrino (1997) and Campbell, Gallmeyer, Johnson, Rutherford and Stanley

(2011), we define CEO departure as forced turnover if related news satisfies the following

criteria: (1) The CEO turnover is not announced over at least six months prior to this event.

(2) The departing CEO does not leave due to reasons of health problem, death, or the

acceptance of another position elsewhere. (3) The departing CEO is under the age of 60 - that

is, unlikely to be retired. (4) The departing CEO does not sit on the board of directors after

leaving the CEO position. Finally, we construct Forced CEO Turnover, which is equal to one

if the CEO is forced out and zero otherwise.

Panel A of Table 9 presents the results from the logit and Cox regressions of forced CEO

turnover on customer concentration. Following Campbell et al. (2011), we control for various

firm- and CEO-level characteristics, including firm size (ln(Assets)), industry adjusted ROA

(Industry Adjusted ROA), excess stock return (Excess Stock Return), stock return volatility

(Stock Return Volatility), firm ages (ln(Firm Age)), CEO tenure (ln(CEO Tenure)), CEO total

compensation (ln(CEO Total Compensation)), and CEO ownership (CEO Ownership). The

detailed definitions for all variables are provided in Appendix A. All coefficients on Customer

Page 27: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

26

Concentration are significantly negative, indicating that the likelihood of CEOs being forced

out decreases for suppliers with higher customer concentration.

[Insert Table 9 here]

We next explore the effect of CEO tenure on the relationship between CEO forced

turnover and customer concentration. We expect that a negative relationship between CEO

forced turnover and customer concentration strengthens in suppliers with longer CEO tenure

because long-tenured CEOs may build closer personal connections with primary customers.

In Panel B of Table 9, we decompose the sample into two groups depending on whether or

not the supplier’s CEO tenure is longer than the median of the total sample firms’ CEO

tenure. We then re-run the logit regressions of Panel A for each subsample to compare the

effect of customer concentration on CEO forced turnover between the two groups. We find

that the coefficients on Customer Concentration are more significant and smaller for

suppliers with a longer-tenured CEO than those with a shorter-tenured CEO.

5.3 Customer Switching Costs

We now turn our attention to a potential circumstance wherein customer concentration

can induce managerial agency problems manifested within suppliers. Particularly, we focus

on customer switching costs. Managing supplier–customer relationships is more valuable to

suppliers when their customers can easily replace them. Under this corporate environment,

the role of managers in keeping this relationship increases. Thus, we expect customer

concentration’s negative influence on agency problems to be more pronounced for suppliers

whose customers have lower switching costs, which are fixed costs incurred by customers

when changing suppliers. Following the extant literature (e.g., Inderst and Wey, 2007; Hui,

Klasa, and Yeung, 2012; Dhaliwal et al., 2016), we construct two customer switching cost

Page 28: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

27

variables, namely Supplier Market Share and Fraction of Customer COGS. When a supplier’s

market share is low, its customers may readily find alternative suppliers in the market. Based

on this thought, the suppliers’ market share is used to measure customer switching costs.

Supplier Market Share is a supplier’s sales divided by total sales of the supplier’s industry. As

an additional measurement of customer switching costs, we employ Fraction of Customer

COGS, which is the weighted sum of each major customer’s purchases from the supplier

divided by each customer’s cost of goods sold (COGS). The weight is the supplier’s

percentage sales to each major customer. As a fraction of the supplier’s sales over a

customer’s COGS is smaller, the customer becomes less dependent on the supplier, which

lowers the cost of changing the supplier. Using these two variables on customer switching

costs, we split the supplier sample into two subsamples according to whether or not major

customers have lower switching costs than the median of the total sample’s switching costs.

We conjecture that the negative relationship between customer concentration and the market

value of excess cash is likely to strengthen when the market share of the supplier is low, and

when the supplier’s sales account for a lower proportion of the customer’s COGS.

Table 10 presents the results of the subsample analysis based on customer switching

costs. In Panel A, we use Supplier Market Share to measure customer switching costs. The

coefficients on Customer Concentration*Excess Cash are more significant and smaller for

suppliers with low market shares than for suppliers with high market shares. Those results

suggest that the negative association between customer concentration and market value of

excess cash is prominent when customers can switch their suppliers at low costs.

[Insert Table 10 here]

In Panel B, we conduct the subsample analysis using Fraction of Customer COGS.17 We

17 Since customer information is required to measure Fraction of Customer COGS, suppliers whose major

Page 29: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

28

find that the negative effect of customer concentration on the market value of excess cash is

magnified for suppliers with low Fraction of Customer COGS, compared with those who

have high Fraction of Customer COGS. This result is consistent with our prediction on

customer switching costs.

5.4 Corporate Governance

For robustness, we investigate whether our observed relationship between customer

concentration and the market value of excess cash holdings is influenced by corporate

governance. Because corporate governance is closely associated with the market value of

excess cash holdings (Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith, 2007), the suppliers’ governance may affect

our results. To alleviate this concern, we try to control for corporate governance in our

regressions. To proxy corporate governance, we use the entrenchment index (E-index)

constructed by Bebchuk, Cohen, and Ferrell (2009), which is based on six antitakeover

provisions.18 In general, high E-index indicates weak governance in that anti-takeover

provisions enable managers to be more entrenched, thus aggravating agency problems. Table

11 presents the results on regressions that include E-index. These results indicate that our

main findings still remain unchanged when we control for corporate governance.

[Insert Table 11 here]

4. Conclusion

In this paper, we focus on analyzing the effect of customer concentration on managerial

agency costs in suppliers. To test this, we investigate how the extent of suppliers’ customer

customers are available in Compustat are only included in our analysis. Thus, our sample in Panel B of Table 10

substantially reduces. 18 The E-index is constructed using the ISS database. See Appendix A for a detailed definition of the E-index.

Page 30: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

29

concentration influences the market value of their excess cash holdings. We conjecture that

excess cash holdings in suppliers with higher concentrated customers will be valued lower in

the capital market because managerial agency problems are expected to be more severe in

such suppliers. Consistent with this conjecture, our empirical results show that customer

concentration is negatively related to the market value of suppliers’ excess cash reserves. The

results persist when we address endogeneity issues and conduct additional robustness tests.

To the best of our knowledge, this study is the first to directly explore managerial agency

costs of suppliers that may stem from their concentrated customer base. The extant literature

largely examines the role of customers in suppliers’ governance, finding that major customers

have incentives to monitor managers of suppliers. However, monitoring incentives of

customers are different from those of shareholders, and thus agency conflicts between

managers and shareholders still exist within customer-dependent suppliers in spite of

monitoring of suppliers’ managers by customers. Along this line of thought, we turn our

attention to managerial agency costs of suppliers with higher customer concentration. We

suggest a mechanism through which managerial agency problems arise for such suppliers.

Moreover, our study adds to the literature that examines management entrenchment related to

investments in manager-specific assets. We also contribute to the existing studies on the value

of cash holdings by providing evidence on how the extent of customer concentration affects

the market value of suppliers’ excess cash.

Page 31: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

30

References

Allen, J.W., Phillips, G.M., 2000. Corporate equity ownership, strategic alliances, and

product market relationships. Journal of Finance 55, 2791-2815.

Bae, K.-H., Wang, J., 2015. Why do firms in customer–supplier relationships hold more

cash? International Review of Finance 15, 489-520.

Banerjee, S., Dasgupta, S., Kim, Y., 2008. Buyer–supplier relationships and the stakeholder

theory of capital structure. Journal of Finance 63, 2507-2552.

Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., Ferrell, A., 2009. What matters in corporate governance? Review of

Financial Studies 22, 783-827.

Benmelech, E., Frydman, C., 2015. Military CEOs. Journal of Financial Economics 117, 43-

59.

Bertrand, M., Mullainathan, S., 1999. Corporate governance and executive pay: evidence

from takeover legislation. Working paper. University of Chicago and Harvard

University.

Bhattacharyya, S., Nain, A., 2011. Horizontal acquisitions and buying power: A product

market analysis. Journal of Financial Economics 99, 97-115.

Campbell, T.C., Gallmeyer, M., Johnson, S.A., Rutherford, J., Stanley, B.W., 2011. CEO

optimism and forced turnover. Journal of Financial Economics 101, 695-712.

Campello, M., Gao, J., 2017. Customer concentration and loan contract terms. Journal of

Financial Economics 123, 108-136.

Cen, L., Dasgupta, S., Elkamhi, R., Pungaliya, R.S., 2015. Reputation and loan contract

terms: the role of principal customers. Review of Finance 20, 501-533.

Cen, L., Maydew, E.L., Zhang, L., Zuo, L., 2017. Customer–supplier relationships and

corporate tax avoidance. Journal of Financial Economics 123, 377-394.

Chen, T., Harford, J., Lin, C., 2015. Do analysts matter for governance? Evidence from

natural experiments. Journal of Financial Economics 115, 383-410.

Coates, J., 2001. Explaining variation in takeover defenses: Blame the lawyers. California

Law Review 89, 1301-1422.

Core, J.E., Holthausen, R.W., Larcker, D.F., 1999. Corporate governance, chief executive

officer compensation, and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics 51, 371-

406.

Crawford, S., Huang, Y., Li, N., Yang, Z.C., 2016. Customer concentration and public

disclosure: evidence from management earnings forecasts. Working paper. University

of Houston and Texas at Austin.

Dhaliwal, D., Judd, J.S., Serfling, M., Shaikh, S., 2016. Customer concentration risk and the

cost of equity capital. Journal of Accounting and Economics 61, 23-48.

Dittmar, A., Mahrt-Smith, J., 2007. Corporate governance and the value of cash holdings.

Journal of Financial Economics 83, 599-634.

Emshwiller, J.R., 1991. Suppliers struggle to improve quality as big firms slash their vendor

rolls. Wall Street Journal 16, B1-B2.

Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 1998. Taxes, financing decisions, and firm value. Journal of

Finance 53, 819-843.

Faulkender, M., Wang, R., 2006. Corporate financial policy and the value of cash. Journal of

Finance 61, 1957-1990.

Page 32: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

31

Fee, C.E., Thomas, S., 2004. Sources of gains in horizontal mergers: evidence from customer,

supplier, and rival firms. Journal of Financial Economics 74, 423-460.

Frésard, L., Salva, C., 2010. The value of excess cash and corporate governance: evidence

from us cross-listings. Journal of Financial Economics 98, 359-384.

Gillan, S.L., Hartzell, J.C., Parrino, R., 2009. Explicit versus implicit contracts: evidence

from CEO employment agreements. Journal of Finance 64, 1629-1655.

Grossman, S.J., Hart, O.D., 1986. The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical

and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy 94, 691-719.

Hui, K.W., Klasa, S., Yeung, P.E., 2012. Corporate suppliers and customers and accounting

conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics 53, 115-135.

Inderst, R., Wey, C., 2007. Buyer power and supplier incentives. European Economic Review

51, 647-667.

Intintoli, V.J., Serfling, M., Shaikh, S., 2017. CEO turnovers and disruptions in customer–

supplier relationships. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 52, 2565-2610.

Itzkowitz, J., 2013. Customers and cash: How relationships affect suppliers' cash holdings.

Journal of Corporate Finance 19, 159-180.

Jensen, M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1976. Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs

and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.

Jensen, M.C., Ruback, R.S., 1983. The market for corporate control: the scientific evidence.

Journal of Financial Economics 11, 5-50.

Johnson, W.C., Karpoff, J.M., Yi, S., 2015. The bonding hypothesis of takeover defenses:

evidence from IPO firms. Journal of Financial Economics 117, 307-332.

Kale, J.R., Shahrur, H., 2007. Corporate capital structure and the characteristics of suppliers

and customers. Journal of Financial Economics 83, 321-365.

Kang, J.-K., Liu, W.-L., Yi, S., Zhang, L., 2015. Monitoring role of customer firms in

suppliers and its effect on supplier value: evidence from block acquisitions of

suppliers by customer firms. Journal of Financial Intermediation 24, 537-563.

Klein, B., Crawford, R.G., Alchian, A.A., 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and

the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics 21, 297-326.

Klein, B., Leffler, K.B., 1981. The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance.

Journal of Political Economy 89, 615-641.

Kolay, M., Lemmon, M., Tashjian, E., 2016. Spreading the misery? Sources of bankruptcy

spillover in the supply chain. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 51, 1955-

1990.

Krolikowski, M., Yuan, X., 2017. Friend or foe: customer-supplier relationships and

innovation. Journal of Business Research 78, 53-68.

Loughran, T., Ritter, J., 2004. Why has IPO underpricing changed over time? Financial

Management 33, 5-37.

Masulis, R.W., Wang, C., Xie, F., 2007. Corporate governance and acquirer returns. Journal

of Finance 62, 1851-1889.

Masulis, R.W., Wang, C., Xie, F.E.I., 2009. Agency problems at dual-class companies.

Journal of Finance 64, 1697-1727.

Myers, S.C., Rajan, R.G., 1998. The paradox of liquidity. Quarterly Journal of Economics

113, 733-771.

Parrino, R., 1997. CEO turnover and outside succession a cross-sectional analysis. Journal of

Page 33: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

32

Financial Economics 46, 165-197.

Patatoukas, P.N., 2011. Customer-base concentration: implications for firm performance and

capital markets. Accounting Review 87, 363-392.

Raman, K., Shahrur, H., 2008. Relationship-specific investments and earnings management:

evidence on corporate suppliers and customers. Accounting Review 83, 1041-1081.

Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H., 1988. Breach of trust in hostile takeovers. In: Corporate

Takeovers: Causes and Consequences. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp. 33-

68.

Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1986. Large shareholders and corporate control. Journal of

Political Economy 94, 461-488.

Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1989. Management entrenchment: the case of manager-specific

investments. Journal of Financial Economics 25, 123-139.

Smith, A., 1937. The Wealth of Nations. Modern library, Random House, New York.

Stout, L.A., 2002. Do antitakeover defenses decrease shareholder wealth? The ex post/ex ante

valuation problem. Stanford Law Review 55, 845-861.

Titman, S., Wessels, R., 1988. The determinants of capital structure choice. Journal of

Finance 43, 1-19.

Wang, J., 2012. Do firms' relationships with principal customers/suppliers affect shareholders'

income? Journal of Corporate Finance 18, 860-878.

Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. New York: The Free Press.

Page 34: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

33

Appendix A. Variable Definitions

Variable Definition

Customer Concentration Measures

Major Customer An indicator variable equal to one if the supplier reports at least one

corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero

otherwise

Major Customer Sales Fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers

Customer HHI Sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer

over its total sales

Cash Measures

Xcash Excess cash holdings, calculated as the residuals from the normal cash

regression in column (6) of Table A1

Cash Ratio Ratio of cash holdings to total assets

Firm Characteristics

Assets Total assets

Net Assets Total assets minus cash holdings

Market Value Sum of the market value of equity and the book value of short- and

long-term debt

Forecasted Market Value Sum of the forecasted market value of equity and the book value of

short- and long-term debt; the forecasted market value of equity is

defined as the product of the common shares outstanding and the

average target price predicted by analysts

Earnings Net income before interests and extraordinary items

R&D Expense Research and development expenses, which are set to zero if missing

Interest Expense Interest expenses

Dividends Amount of dividend paid to common shares

ROA Ratio of operating income before depreciation to total assets

Leverage Sum of short- and long-term debt divided by total assets

Industry Adjusted ROA ROA minus industry median ROA

Excess Stock Return Buy-and-hold stock returns minus value-weighted market returns over

the given year

Stock Return Volatility Standard deviation of monthly stock returns over the given year

Firm Age Ages of the firm based on the years listed on Compustat

Tobin’s Q Ratio of the market value of assets to the book value of assets

CAPEX Capital expenditures

Advertising Expense Advertising expenses

CF Cash flow, calculated as earnings before interests and taxes

Std. Industry CF Industry median of cash flow’s standard deviation over the past ten

years

NWC Net working capital, calculated as current assets minus current liabilities

and cash holdings

Market-to-Book Ratio Ratio of the market value of equity to the book value of equity

Instrumental Variables

Customer M&A Weighted sum of acquisition activities across industries in which the

supplier’s major customers operate; the weight is the supplier’s

percentage sales to each major customer; industry-level acquisition

activities are calculated as the average acquisitions of firms in the

industry over the past five years; deal values scaled by acquirer’s total

sales are used as a proxy for each firm’s acquisition level

3-year Lagged Sales Growth Three-year lagged compound sales growth

CEO Characteristics

ustomer-related CEO An indicator variable equal to one if the supplier’s CEO previously

Page 35: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

34

served as a senior manager or board member at one or more major

customers and zero otherwise

Forced CEO Turnover An indicator variable equal to one if the CEO is forced out and zero

otherwise

CEO Tenure CEO tenure in the given year

CEO Total Compensation Total annual compensation of CEO

CEO Excess Compensation Residuals from the regression of the natural logarithm of CEO total

compensation on the natural logarithm of total market value of firm

CEO Ownership Percentage of the firm’s equity owned by the CEO

Deal Characteristics

CAR(-2, +2) Five-day cumulative abnormal returns over the (-2, +2) window around

the announcement date of mergers

Negative CAR(-2, +2) Dummy An indicator variable equal to one if CAR(-2, +2) is negative and zero

otherwise

Relative Deal Size A deal value scaled by acquirer’s market value of assets

High-tech An indicator variable equal to one if both acquirer and target operate in

the high-tech industries defined by Loughran and Ritter (2004) and zero

otherwise

Diversifying Merger An indicator variable equal to one if the acquirer and target have

different first two-digit SIC code and zero otherwise

Public Target An indicator variable equal to one if the target is a public target and zero

otherwise

Private Target An indicator variable equal to one if the target is a private target and

zero otherwise

Subsidiary Target An indicator variable equal to one if the target is a subsidiary target and

zero otherwise

Stock Deal An indicator variable equal to one if the deal is at least partially financed

by stocks and zero otherwise

All Cash Deal An indicator variable equal to one if the deal is only financed by cash

and zero otherwise

Switching Cost Measures

Supplier Market Share Supplier’s sales divided by total sales of its industry

Fraction of Customer COGS The weighted sum of each major customer’s purchases from the supplier

divided by each customer’s cost of goods sold (COGS); the weight is the

supplier’s percentage sales to each major customer

Corporate Governance Measure

E-index Bebchuk et al.’s (2009) entrenchment index; this index is calculated as

the number of antitakeover provisions held by the firm among its six

provisions: staggered boards, limits to shareholder by-law amendments,

supermajority requirements for mergers, supermajority requirements for

charter amendments, poison pills, and golden parachutes.

Page 36: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

35

Appendix B. Measuring Excess Cash

In this appendix, we explain our methodology to measure excess cash. Following Dittmar

and Mahrt-Smith (2007), excess cash is defined as the difference between actual cash and the

predicted normal level of cash. The regression model for predicting the normal level of cash

is shown below

ln (𝐶𝑎𝑠ℎ 𝑅𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜)𝑖,𝑡 = 𝛼 + 𝛽1 𝑀𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡 𝑉𝑙𝑎𝑢𝑒/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽2ln (𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠)𝑖,𝑡 +

𝛽3𝐶𝐹/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽4𝑆𝑡𝑑. 𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑦 𝐶𝐹/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 +

𝛽5𝑁𝑊𝐶/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽6𝑅&𝐷 𝐸𝑥𝑝𝑒𝑛𝑠𝑒𝑠/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 +

𝛽7𝐶𝐴𝑃𝐸𝑋/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽8𝐿𝑒𝑣𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖,𝑡 + 𝛽9𝐷𝑖𝑣𝑖𝑑𝑒𝑛𝑑/𝐴𝑠𝑠𝑒𝑡𝑠𝑖,𝑡 +

𝛽10𝑀𝑎𝑗𝑜𝑟 𝐶𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑜𝑚𝑒𝑟𝑖,𝑡 + 𝑌𝑒𝑎𝑟 𝐹𝑖𝑥𝑒𝑑 𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑠 +

𝐼𝑛𝑑𝑢𝑠𝑡𝑟𝑦 𝐹𝑖𝑥𝑒𝑑 𝐸𝑓𝑓𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑠 + 𝜀𝑖,𝑡 (B.1)

where Cash Ratio is the ratio of cash holdings to total assets; Market Value is the sum of the

market value of equity and the book value of short-term and long-term debt; Assets is total

assets; CF is cash flow, calculated as earnings before interests and taxes. Moreover, Std.

Industry CF is the industry median of cash flow’s standard deviation over the past 10 years;

NWC is net working capital, which is calculated as current assets minus current liabilities and

cash holdings; R&D Expense is research and development expenses, which are set to zero if

missing. Finally, CAPEX is capital expenditures; Leverage is the sum of short-term and long-

term debt divided by total assets; Dividend is the amount of dividend paid to common shares;

Major Customer is an indicator variable equal to one if the supplier reports at least one

corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero otherwise.

In our normal cash model, we include Major Customer to control for customer

concentration because recent studies suggest a positive relationship between customer

Page 37: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

36

concentration and cash holdings.19 We also use 2SLS regressions with three-year lagged

sales growth (3-year Lagged Sales Growth) as an instrumental variable for Market

Value/Assets by following Dittmar and Mahrt-Smith (2007) and Frésard and Salva (2010).

Since the proxy for investment opportunities (Market Value/Assets) in equation (B.1) is

simultaneously used as the dependent variable for market value in our main model (equation

(3)), we introduce a 2SLS estimation to mitigate endogeneity issues. 3-year Lagged Sales

Growth appears to satisfy two requirements to make the instrumental variable valid. First, a

positive relationship between past sales growth and market-to-book ratio is likely to exist

because these variables are generally used to proxy a firm’s investment opportunities.

Second, 3-year Lagged Sales Growth may be exogenous to corporate decisions on cash

holdings—that is, current cash holdings are not able to affect past sales growth.

Table A1 reports the results on regressions that estimate equation (4). OLS regression and

2SLS regression results are present in columns (1)–(2) and columns (3)–(6), respectively. The

coefficients on Major Customer Sales in columns (2) and (6) are significantly positive,

confirming that we need to control for a customer concentration. Furthermore, the

coefficients on 3-year Lagged Sales Growth are significantly positive in columns (3) and (4).

The F-statistics obtained from the Wu–Hausman test indicate that we should treat the

endogeneity concern. The F-statistics in the first-stage regressions also reject that the

instrument is weak. Finally, excess cash holdings used in our main regressions are the

residual obtained from the regression in column (6).20

[Insert Table B1 here]

19 See Itzkowitz (2013) and Bae and Wang (2015). 20 Our main results remain unchanged even when we measure excess cash holdings as the residuals of

regressions in columns (2) and (5).

Page 38: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

37

Table 1. Summary Statistics and Univariate Test

This table presents summary statistics and the results on univariate tests. Panel A reports the number of observations,

25th percentile, mean, median, 75th percentile and standard deviations for customer concentration measures, cash holding

measures, and various firm characteristics. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Variable definitions

are provided in Appendix A. Panel B presents mean and median comparison test results of cash holding measures and

firm characteristics between two groups. The sample is split into two subsamples according to whether the supplier

reports at least one major customer. t-tests and Willcoxon-Mann-Whitney tests are conducted for the comparison test in

the means and medians, respectively. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Panel A. Summary Statistics

Obs. 25% Mean Median 75% Std.

Customer concentration measures

Major Customer 67,016 0.000 0.345 0.000 1.000 0.475

Major Customer Sales 67,016 0.000 0.139 0.000 0.202 0.240

Customer HHI 67,016 0.000 0.047 0.000 0.033 0.113

Customer concentration measures for suppliers with at least one major customer

Major Customer Sales 23,121 0.187 0.402 0.346 0.571 0.247

Customer HHI 23,121 0.029 0.136 0.073 0.176 0.157

Cash holding measures

Xcash 67,016 0.396 0.867 0.776 1.233 0.588

Cash Ratio 67,016 0.070 0.198 0.135 0.259 0.182

Firm characteristics

Assets (in millions) 67,016 24.148 2,260.833 133.896 816.207 7,437.480

Net Assets (in millions) 67,016 17.543 1,974.522 102.595 683.874 6,614.770

Market Value/Assets 67,016 0.653 1.159 0.941 1.426 0.855

Earnings/Assets 67,016 0.050 0.087 0.080 0.113 0.054

R&D Expense/Assets 67,016 0.000 0.038 0.000 0.037 0.083

Interest Expense/Assets 67,016 0.005 0.027 0.017 0.035 0.035

Dividends/Assets 67,016 0.000 0.010 0.000 0.013 0.019

Panel B. Univariate Tests

Suppliers with at least

one major customer

(Obs. = 23,122)

Suppliers with no

major customers

(Obs. = 43,894) Test of difference

Mean Median Mean Median Mean Median

Xcash 0.899 0.824 0.849 0.752 0.050*** 0.072***

Cash Ratio 0.234 0.169 0.178 0.122 0.056*** 0.047***

Assets (in millions) 1010.119 77.566 2919.671 181.154 -1909.552*** -103.588***

Net Assets (in millions) 841.884 53.477 2571.161 146.904 -1729.277*** -93.427***

Market Value/Assets 1.266 1.013 1.103 0.907 0.163*** 0.106***

Earnings/Assets 0.087 0.077 0.087 0.080 0.000 -0.003

R&D Expense/Assets 0.057 0.007 0.028 0.000 0.029*** 0.007***

Interest Expense/Assets 0.025 0.014 0.028 0.019 -0.003*** -0.005***

Dividends/Assets 0.007 0.000 0.011 0.000 -0.004*** -0.000***

Page 39: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

38

Table 2. Customer Concentration and Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings

This table presents the results of baseline regressions of market value of excess cash on customer concentration. Market

Value/Assets is calculated as the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of short-term and long-term debt,

divided by total assets. Xcash is excess cash holdings, which are defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression

in column (6) of Table A1. Three customer concentration variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator variable

that is equal to one if the supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales,

and zero otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers.

(3) Customer HHI is the squared sum of ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. ∆L2

and ∆2 indicate the change in a relevant variable from year t-2 to year t and from year t and t+2, respectively. Variable

definitions are provided in Appendix A. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC

codes. All continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm

level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

All suppliers

Suppliers with at least

one major customer

Major

Customer

Major

Customer Sales Customer HHI

Major

Customer Sales Customer HHI

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Customer Concentration 0.149*** 0.468*** 1.050*** 0.582*** 0.931***

(7.76) (10.34) (10.41) (8.44) (7.86)

Xcash -0.253*** -0.249*** -0.259*** -0.213*** -0.288***

(-24.79) (-25.44) (-27.62) (-8.82) (-16.25)

Customer Concentration*Xcash -0.116*** -0.354*** -0.875*** -0.442*** -0.761***

(-7.28) (-9.26) (-9.02) (-7.26) (-6.50)

Earnings/Assets -0.914*** -0.909*** -0.901*** -0.937*** -0.929***

(-15.88) (-15.84) (-15.72) (-11.43) (-11.35)

∆L2 Earnings/Assets 0.315*** 0.312*** 0.311*** 0.275*** 0.273***

(10.17) (10.10) (10.05) (7.24) (7.20)

∆2 Earnings/Assets -0.185*** -0.180*** -0.175*** -0.181*** -0.176***

(-5.19) (-5.07) (-4.95) (-3.72) (-3.60)

∆L2 Net Assets/Assets 0.234*** 0.235*** 0.235*** 0.271*** 0.269***

(15.56) (15.66) (15.64) (11.25) (11.19)

∆2 Net Assets/Assets 0.242*** 0.241*** 0.241*** 0.239*** 0.240***

(17.51) (17.47) (17.49) (12.19) (12.22)

R&D Expense/Assets 2.181*** 2.146*** 2.144*** 1.942*** 1.943***

(18.85) (18.60) (18.65) (12.95) (12.99)

∆L2 R&D Expense/Assets 1.003*** 1.004*** 1.003*** 0.910*** 0.910***

(6.90) (6.94) (6.95) (4.97) (4.99)

∆2 R&D Expense/Assets 2.271*** 2.245*** 2.254*** 2.268*** 2.287***

(14.79) (14.74) (14.82) (11.60) (11.71)

Interest Expense/Assets 5.690*** 5.703*** 5.700*** 5.883*** 5.887***

(19.68) (19.77) (19.82) (13.92) (13.97)

∆L2 Interest Expense/Assets -0.958*** -0.950*** -0.943*** -0.914** -0.894**

(-3.74) (-3.72) (-3.70) (-2.49) (-2.44)

∆2 Interest Expense/Assets 0.643*** 0.637*** 0.643*** 0.631 0.647

Page 40: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

39

(2.69) (2.66) (2.69) (1.54) (1.58)

Dividends/Assets 8.191*** 8.247*** 8.187*** 8.686*** 8.626***

(19.69) (19.88) (19.76) (13.49) (13.45)

∆L2 Dividends/Assets 1.986*** 1.952*** 1.985*** 1.153* 1.180*

(5.08) (5.01) (5.10) (1.75) (1.78)

∆2 Dividends/Assets 6.032*** 6.043*** 6.011*** 5.402*** 5.365***

(16.96) (17.00) (16.97) (9.50) (9.45)

∆2 Market Value/Assets -0.039*** -0.039*** -0.039*** -0.048*** -0.048***

(-8.34) (-8.30) (-8.33) (-7.61) (-7.64)

Observations 67,016 67,016 67,016 23,121 23,121

Adjusted R-squared 0.350 0.352 0.352 0.385 0.385

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 41: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

40

Table 3. Customer Concentration and Alternative Measures of Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings: Market

Value of Cash Ratio and Forecasted Market Value of Cash Holdings

This table presents the results of regressions using alternative measures of the market value of excess cash holdings to

examine the effect of customer concentration on market value of excess cash holdings. Market Value/Assets is defined

as the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of short- and long-term debt, divided by total assets.

Forecasted Market Value/Assets is defined as the sum of the forecasted market value of equity and the book value of

short- and long-term debt. Cash Ratio is the ratio of cash holdings to total assets. Xcash is excess cash holdings, which

are defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression in column (6) of Table A1. To measure a level of customer

concentration, three different variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator variable that is equal to one if the

supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero otherwise. (2)

Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (3) Customer HHI is

the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. Variable definitions are

provided in Appendix A. The estimation results of other controls are omitted for brevity. All regressions include year

and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard

errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1%

is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Panel A. Customer Concentration and the Market Value of Cash Ratio

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

Major Customer Major Customer Sales Customer HHI

(1) (2) (3)

Customer Concentration 0.008 0.078* 0.387***

(0.42) (1.69) (3.47)

Cash Ratio 1.904*** 1.941*** 1.919***

(19.24) (20.77) (21.47)

Customer Concentration*Cash Ratio -0.269** -0.808*** -2.167***

(-2.31) (-3.75) (-4.24)

Observations 123,639 123,639 123,639

Adjusted R-squared 0.453 0.453 0.453

Control Variables Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Panel B. Customer Concentration and Forecasted Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings

Dependent variable = Forecasted Market Value/Assets

Major Customer Major Customer Sales Customer HHI

(1) (2) (3)

Customer Concentration 0.523 0.913 3.127

(0.93) (0.65) (0.91)

Xcash -0.139 -0.307 -0.468

(-0.29) (-0.68) (-1.20)

Customer Concentration*Xcash -2.132*** -3.808** -7.410**

(-2.83) (-2.30) (-2.16)

Observations 15,843 15,843 15,843

Adjusted R-squared 0.210 0.210 0.210

Control Variables Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Page 42: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

41

Table 4. Customer Concentration and Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings: Propensity Score Matching

Analysis

This table presents the results of regressions using the propensity score matched sample to examine the effect of

customer concentration on market value of excess cash holdings. Dependent variable is Market Value/Assets, which is

calculated as the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of short- and long-term debt divided by total

assets. Xcash is excess cash holdings, which are defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression in column (6)

of Table A1. To measure a level of customer concentration, three different variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an

indicator variable that is equal to one if the supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than

10% of its sales and zero otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by

major customers. (3) Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over

its total sales. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix A. Control variables are identical to controls in Table 2,

whose estimates are omitted for brevity. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC

codes. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level.

t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

Major Customer Major Customer Sales Customer HHI

(1) (2) (3)

Customer Concentration 0.064** 0.341*** 0.815***

(2.55) (6.56) (7.56)

Xcash -0.338*** -0.317*** -0.325***

(-18.07) (-19.15) (-21.76)

Customer Concentration*Xcash -0.042* -0.238*** -0.642***

(-1.94) (-5.25) (-6.07)

Observations 46,244 46,244 46,244

Adjusted R-squared 0.378 0.380 0.380

Control Variables Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Page 43: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

42

Table 5. Customer Concentration and Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings: CEO and Firm Fixed Effects

This table presents the results of regressions with CEO and firm fixed effects to examine the effect of customer

concentration on market value of excess cash holdings. Dependent variable is Market Value/Assets, which is calculated

as the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of short- and long-term debt divided by total assets. Xcash

is excess cash holdings, which are defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression in column (6) of Table A1.

To measure a level of customer concentration, three different variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator

variable that is equal to one if the supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of

its sales and zero otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major

customers. (3) Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total

sales. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix A. Control variables are identical to controls in Table 2, whose

estimates are omitted for brevity. All regressions include year fixed effects. Continuous variables are winsorized at the

1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the

10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

CEO fixed effects Firm fixed effects

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Customer Concentration 0.136*** 0.325*** 0.664*** 0.104*** 0.327*** 0.695***

(4.54) (4.46) (3.88) (5.90) (7.33) (7.00)

Xcash -0.335*** -0.337*** -0.349*** -0.324*** -0.320*** -0.331***

(-12.76) (-13.28) (-14.22) (-26.07) (-26.99) (-29.30)

Customer Concentration*Xcash -0.140*** -0.348*** -0.855*** -0.108*** -0.307*** -0.722***

(-4.37) (-4.40) (-4.49) (-6.85) (-7.94) (-7.39)

Observations 10,683 10,683 10,683 65,245 65,245 65,245

Adjusted R-squared 0.789 0.790 0.789 0.639 0.640 0.640

Control Variables Included Included Included Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

CEO Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes No No No

Firm Fixed Effects No No No Yes Yes Yes

Page 44: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

43

Table 6. Customer Concentration and Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings: 2SLS Regressions

This table presents the results of two stage least squares (2SLS) regressions of market value of excess cash on customer

concentration. Customer M&A, defined as the weighted sum of acquisition activities across industries in which the

supplier’s major customers operate, is employed as an instrument variable for customer concentration. To measure a

level of customer concentration, two different variables are used: (1) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the

supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (2) Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s

sales to each major customer over its total sales. Market Value/Assets is calculated as the sum of the market value of

equity and the book value of short- and long-term debt divided by total assets. Xcash is excess cash holdings, which are

defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression in column (6) of Table A1. Variable definitions are provided in

Appendix A. Control variables are identical to controls in Table 2, whose estimates are omitted for brevity. All

regressions include year and industry fixed effects, defined based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous variables are

winsorized at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in parentheses.

Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

1st stage 2nd stage

Dependent Variable Dependent Variable

Major

Customer Sales

Major Customer

Sales*Xcash

Customer

HHI

Customer

HHI*Xcash

Market Value

/Assets

Market Value

/Assets

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Major Customer Sales 1.795***

(3.09)

Major Customer Sales*Xcash -1.418***

(-3.79)

Customer HHI 3.441***

(3.26)

Customer HHI*Xcash -3.130***

(-3.71)

Customer M&A 0.039*** -0.051*** 0.025*** -0.019***

(4.05) (-4.65) (3.36) (-2.82)

Customer M&A*Xcash 0.018 0.140*** 0.017* 0.072***

(1.47) (7.77) (1.90) (6.59)

Xcash 0.047*** 0.519*** 0.020*** 0.153*** 0.268 0.028

(4.54) (35.24) (3.54) (21.11) (1.46) (0.22)

First Stage F-statistics 38.923*** 38.731*** 34.506*** 33.151*** N/A N/A

Wu-Hausman F-statistics N/A N/A N/A N/A 5.961*** 6.395***

Observations 7,152 7,152 7,152 7,152 7,152 7,152

Adjusted R-squared 0.138 0.550 0.118 0.327 0.320 0.320

Control Variables Included Included Included Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 45: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

44

Table 7. Customer Concentration and Alternative Measures of Agency Costs: Suppliers’ CEO Compensation and

Acquisition Decisions

This table presents the results of regressions of suppliers’ CEO compensation and acquisition decisions on customer

concentration. ln(CEO Total Compensation) is the natural logarithm of total annual compensation of CEO. CEO Excess

Compensation is the residuals from the regression of the natural logarithm of CEO total compensation on the natural

logarithm of total market value of firm. CAR(-2, +2) is defined as five-day cumulative abnormal returns over the (-2,

+2) window around the announcement date of mergers. Negative CAR(-2, +2) Dummy is an indicator variable that is

equal to one if CAR(-2, +2) is negative and zero otherwise. To measure a level of customer concentration, three different

variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator variable that is equal to one if the supplier reports at least one

corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the

fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (3) Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of

the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix A. All

independent variables are lagged by one year. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit

SIC codes. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm

level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Panel A. Suppliers’ CEO Compensation

Dependent variable =

ln(CEO Total Compensation)

Dependent variable =

CEO Excess Compensation

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Customer Concentration 0.095** 0.171* 0.493** 0.079** 0.146 0.457**

(2.49) (1.91) (2.15) (2.11) (1.64) (2.03)

ln(Assets) 0.453*** 0.453*** 0.453*** 0.045*** 0.045*** 0.045***

(24.26) (24.30) (24.26) (2.73) (2.75) (2.75)

Tobin’s Q 0.045** 0.045** 0.045** -0.086*** -0.086*** -0.086***

(2.28) (2.27) (2.26) (-4.46) (-4.46) (-4.45)

ROA 0.839*** 0.843*** 0.847*** 0.315 0.318 0.321

(4.04) (4.06) (4.07) (1.58) (1.59) (1.61)

Leverage -0.086 -0.083 -0.081 0.024 0.027 0.028

(-0.97) (-0.93) (-0.91) (0.28) (0.31) (0.32)

Excess Stock Return 0.215*** 0.214*** 0.214*** 0.161*** 0.160*** 0.160***

(9.11) (9.05) (9.04) (7.10) (7.05) (7.04)

Stock Return Volatility -0.149 -0.149 -0.154 0.395* 0.396* 0.389*

(-0.65) (-0.64) (-0.67) (1.74) (1.74) (1.71)

R&D Expense/Assets 1.216** 1.221** 1.249** 0.882* 0.884* 0.902*

(2.31) (2.30) (2.37) (1.70) (1.68) (1.73)

CAPEX/Assets -0.453 -0.459 -0.469 -0.567 -0.571 -0.576*

(-1.25) (-1.26) (-1.30) (-1.63) (-1.64) (-1.65)

Advertising Expense/Assets 0.180 0.188 0.192 0.269 0.275 0.280

(0.45) (0.46) (0.47) (0.69) (0.70) (0.71)

ln(Firm Age) 0.016 0.014 0.013 0.038 0.037 0.036

(0.59) (0.53) (0.50) (1.52) (1.46) (1.45)

ln(CEO Tenure) -0.054*** -0.054*** -0.054*** -0.063*** -0.063*** -0.063***

(-2.60) (-2.59) (-2.58) (-3.02) (-3.01) (-3.00)

Observations 10,144 10,144 10,144 10,144 10,144 10,144

Adjusted R-squared 0.533 0.532 0.532 0.062 0.062 0.062

Page 46: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

45

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Panel B. Suppliers’ Acquisition Decisions

Dependent variable = CAR(-2, +2) Dependent variable =

Negative CAR(-2, +2) Dummy

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Customer Concentration -0.005* -0.012* -0.044* 0.114* 0.296** 1.119**

(-1.80) (-1.87) (-1.69) (1.84) (2.21) (2.13)

ln(Assets) -0.005*** -0.005*** -0.005*** 0.071*** 0.072*** 0.071***

(-7.46) (-7.55) (-7.52) (4.49) (4.57) (4.54)

Tobin’s Q -0.004*** -0.004*** -0.004*** 0.088*** 0.087*** 0.087***

(-4.36) (-4.32) (-4.33) (4.00) (3.96) (3.96)

ROA 0.006 0.005 0.005 -0.501** -0.478** -0.475**

(0.49) (0.41) (0.41) (-2.25) (-2.14) (-2.13)

Leverage 0.013* 0.013* 0.013* -0.185 -0.187 -0.187

(1.78) (1.79) (1.79) (-1.27) (-1.28) (-1.28)

Relative Deal Size 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.052 0.050 0.050

(1.32) (1.34) (1.34) (0.89) (0.86) (0.85)

High-tech 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.089 0.087 0.088

(0.49) (0.50) (0.49) (1.02) (1.01) (1.01)

High-tech*Relative Deal Size -0.044*** -0.044*** -0.044*** 0.329* 0.334* 0.335*

(-3.89) (-3.90) (-3.90) (1.74) (1.77) (1.77)

Diversifying Merger -0.010*** -0.010*** -0.010*** 0.274*** 0.277*** 0.277***

(-4.31) (-4.36) (-4.35) (4.69) (4.74) (4.73)

Public Target*Stock Deal -0.031*** -0.031*** -0.031*** 0.482*** 0.480*** 0.478***

(-8.99) (-8.97) (-8.95) (6.12) (6.10) (6.08)

Public Target*All Cash Deal 0.002 0.002 0.002 -0.193*** -0.194*** -0.195***

(0.78) (0.80) (0.81) (-2.60) (-2.62) (-2.63)

Private Target*Stock Deal 0.005 0.005 0.005 -0.062 -0.061 -0.059

(0.50) (0.50) (0.49) (-0.30) (-0.29) (-0.29)

Private Target*All Cash Deal 0.012 0.012 0.012 -0.133 -0.135 -0.136

(1.21) (1.22) (1.23) (-0.51) (-0.52) (-0.53)

Subsidiary Target*All Cash Deal 0.002 0.002 0.002 -0.348* -0.352* -0.354*

(0.28) (0.31) (0.32) (-1.75) (-1.77) (-1.79)

Observations 7,029 7,029 7,029 7,025 7,025 7,025

Adjusted R-squared 0.069 0.069 0.069 N/A N/A N/A

Pseudo R-squared N/A N/A N/A 0.046 0.046 0.046

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 47: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

46

Table 8. Customer Concentration and Customer-related CEO

This table presents the results of univariate comparisons and multivariate regressions to examine the relation between

customer concentration and customer-related CEO. Customer-related CEO is an indicator variable equal to one if the

supplier’s CEO previously served as a senior manager or board member at one or more major customers and zero

otherwise. To measure a level of customer concentration, two different variables are used: (1) Major Customer Sales is

the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (2) Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios

of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix A. All

regressions include year and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous variables are winsorized

at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance

at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Panel A: Univariate Comparisons

High Major Customer Sales

(N = 3,315)

Low Major Customer Sales

(N = 3,317)

Mean Difference

Customer-related CEO 0.044 0.035 0.009**

High Customer HHI

(N = 407)

Low Customer HHI

(N = 6,225)

Mean Difference

Customer-related CEO 0.081cu 0.037 0.044***

Panel B: Multivariate Tests

Dependent variable = Customer-related CEO

Major Customer Sales Customer HHI

(1) (2)

Customer Concentration 0.785* 1.725***

(1.72) (2.80)

ln(Assets) 0.180*** 0.203***

(2.72) (2.93)

Market-to-book Ratio -0.062 -0.071

(-0.72) (-0.82)

Observations 6,016 6,016

Pseudo R-squared 0.109 0.115

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Page 48: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

47

Table 9. Customer Concentration and Forced CEO Turnover

This table presents the results of logit and Cox hazard regressions of forced CEO turnover on customer concentration.

Forced CEO Turnover is an indicator variable equal to one if the CEO is forced out and zero otherwise. To measure a

level of customer concentration, three different variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator variable that is

equal to one if the supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero

otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (3)

Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. Variable

definitions are provided in Appendix A. All independent variables are lagged by one year. All regressions include year

and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard

errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1%

is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Panel A. Full Sample Analysis

Dependent variable = Forced CEO Turnover

Logit Regressions Cox Regressions

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Customer Concentration -0.424* -1.692*** -6.363*** -0.426** -1.674*** -6.282**

(-1.96) (-2.72) (-2.58) (-2.02) (-2.74) (-2.57)

ln(Assets) 0.203** 0.195** 0.193** 0.185** 0.177* 0.175*

(2.19) (2.10) (2.09) (2.04) (1.96) (1.94)

Industry Adjusted ROA -2.146** -2.253** -2.315** -2.057** -2.162** -2.220**

(-2.17) (-2.26) (-2.32) (-2.15) (-2.25) (-2.30)

Excess Stock Return -0.823*** -0.822*** -0.817*** -0.794*** -0.791*** -0.784***

(-3.48) (-3.47) (-3.46) (-3.48) (-3.47) (-3.46)

Stock Return Volatility 1.316 1.391 1.325 1.381 1.454 1.390

(0.80) (0.85) (0.81) (0.87) (0.92) (0.88)

ln(Firm Age) -0.018 -0.033 -0.030 -0.028 -0.042 -0.038

(-0.13) (-0.24) (-0.21) (-0.20) (-0.31) (-0.29)

ln(CEO Tenure) -0.295*** -0.291*** -0.291*** -0.331** -0.330** -0.332**

(-3.15) (-3.12) (-3.12) (-2.55) (-2.53) (-2.55)

ln(CEO Total Compensation) 0.077 0.080 0.079 0.088 0.090 0.088

(0.65) (0.67) (0.66) (0.76) (0.79) (0.77)

CEO Ownership -0.006* -0.006* -0.006* -0.006 -0.006 -0.006

(-1.69) (-1.70) (-1.70) (-1.62) (-1.63) (-1.63)

Observations 10,029 10,029 10,029 10,840 10,840 10,840

Pseudo R-squared 0.0946 0.0972 0.0981 0.0728 0.0746 0.0751

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Panel B. Subsample Analysis

Dependent variable = Forced CEO Turnover

Long CEO Tenure Short CEO Tenure

Page 49: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

48

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Customer Concentration -0.569* -1.985** -6.427** -0.272 -1.285 -5.738*

(-1.65) (-2.16) (-1.98) (-0.94) (-1.50) (-1.67)

Observations 5,223 5,223 5,223 3,580 3,580 3,580

Pseudo R-squared 0.104 0.107 0.107 0.122 0.124 0.126

Control Variables Included Included Included Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 50: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

49

Table 10. Customer Concentration and Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings: Low vs. High Customer

Switching Costs

This table reports the results of regressions of market value of excess cash on customer concentration according to

subsample analysis of customer switching costs. We use two customers switching cost variables, Supplier Market Share

and Fraction of Customer COGS. Supplier Market Share is defined as a supplier’s sales divided by total sales of the

supplier’s industry. Fraction of Customer COGS is defined as the weighted sum of each major customer’s purchases

from the supplier divided by each customer’s cost of goods sold (COGS). Market Value/Assets is calculated as the sum

of the market value of equity and the book value of short- and long-term debt divided by total assets. Xcash is excess

cash holdings, which are defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression in column (6) of Table A1. To measure

a level of customer concentration, three different variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator variable that is

equal to one if the supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero

otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (3)

Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. Variable

definitions are provided in Appendix A. Chi-squared test statistics test for the equality of coefficient estimates on

Customer Concentration*Xcash between low and high Supplier Market Share subsamples and also between low and

high Fraction of Customer COGS subsamples. Control variables are identical to controls in Table 2, whose estimates

are omitted for brevity. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous

variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in

parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Panel A. Supplier Market Share

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

Low Supplier Market Share High Supplier Market Share

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Major

Customer

Major Customer

Sales

Customer

HHI

Customer Concentration 0.116*** 0.466*** 0.978*** 0.066*** 0.139** 0.431**

(4.28) (8.03) (8.29) (2.82) (2.32) (2.34)

Xcash -0.346*** -0.332*** -0.348*** -0.155*** -0.155*** -0.153***

(-21.57) (-22.13) (-24.73) (-13.48) (-13.97) (-14.26)

Customer Concentration*Xcash -0.108*** -0.365*** -0.831*** -0.029 -0.093* -0.419**

(-5.00) (-7.63) (-7.37) (-1.37) (-1.73) (-2.40)

Chi-squared Test Statistics N/A N/A N/A 7.03*** 14.76*** 3.96**

Observations 35,445 35,445 35,445 31,569 31,569 31,569

Adjusted R-squared 0.386 0.388 0.389 0.348 0.347 0.347

Control Variables Included Included Included Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Panel B. Fraction of Customer Cost of Goods Sold

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

Low Fraction of Customer COGS High Fraction of Customer COGS

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Major Customer Sales Customer

HHI

Major Customer Sales Customer HHI

Customer Concentration 0.547*** 1.303*** 0.219 0.553**

(4.09) (3.86) (1.36) (2.48)

Xcash -0.176*** -0.242*** -0.355*** -0.352***

(-3.96) (-6.72) (-4.50) (-7.55)

Page 51: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

50

Customer Concentration*Xcash -0.408*** -0.926*** -0.128 -0.367*

(-3.41) (-3.21) (-0.92) (-1.81)

Chi-squared Test Statistics N/A N/A 2.51 2.71*

Observations 4,466 4,466 4,465 4,465

Adjusted R-squared 0.403 0.404 0.392 0.394

Control Variables Included Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Page 52: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

51

Table 11. Customer Concentration and Market Value of Excess Cash Holdings: Controlling for Corporate

Governance

This table reports the results of regressions of market value of excess cash on customer concentration controlling for the

supplier’s governance. E-index is Bebchuk, Cohen, and Ferrell (2009) index of 6-antitakeover provisions with higher

values indicating weaker governance. Dependent variable is Market Value/Assets, which is calculated as the sum of the

market value of equity and the book value of short-term and long-term debt divided by total assets. Xcash is excess cash

holdings, which are defined as the residuals from the normal cash regression in column (6) of Table A1. To measure a

level of customer concentration, three different variables are used: (1) Major Customer is an indicator variable that is

equal to one if the supplier reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales, and zero

otherwise. (2) Major Customer Sales is the fraction of the supplier’s total sales generated by major customers. (3)

Customer HHI is the sum of squares for ratios of the supplier’s sales to each major customer over its total sales. Variable

definitions are provided in appendix A. Control variables are identical to controls in Table 2, whose estimates are omitted

for brevity. All regressions include year and industry fixed effects, defined based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous

variables are winsorized at the 1% level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in

parentheses. Significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

Dependent variable = Market Value/Assets

(1) (2) (3)

Major Customer Major Customer Sales Customer HHI

Customer Concentration 0.072** 0.191** 0.479**

(1.99) (2.32) (2.25)

Xcash -0.277*** -0.265*** -0.271***

(-11.38) (-11.24) (-11.97)

Customer Concentration*Xcash -0.105* -0.241** -0.682**

(-1.81) (-2.27) (-2.51)

E-index -0.045*** -0.045*** -0.045***

(-4.10) (-4.06) (-4.06)

Observations 13,910 13,910 13,910

Adjusted R-squared 0.495 0.496 0.495

Control Variables Included Included Included

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Page 53: Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs · 2019. 4. 24. · Customer Concentration and Managerial Agency Costs* Taeyeon Kim Korea Advanced Institute of Science and Technology

52

Table B1. The Estimation of the Normal Cash Level

This table presents the normal cash regression results to measure excess cash holdings. Ordinary least squares (OLS)

regressions are used in columns (1) and (2), while two stage least squares (2SLS) regression is employed columns (3)

to (6). We employ 3-year Lagged Sales Growth, which is 3-year lagged compounding sales growth of suppliers, as an

instrument for the market-to-book ratio. Major Customer, which is an indicator variable equal to one if the supplier

reports at least one corporate customer that accounts for more than 10% of its sales and zero otherwise, is included as a

control variable in columns (2), (4) and (6). Cash Ratio is the ratio of cash holdings to total assets. Market Value/Assets

is defined as the market value divided by total assets. Variable definitions are provided in Appendix A. All regressions

include year and industry fixed effects, based on two-digit SIC codes. Continuous variables are winsorized at the 1%

level. Standard errors are corrected for clustering at the firm level. t-statistics are in parentheses. Significance at the 10%,

5% and 1% is indicated by *, ** and ***, respectively.

OLS 2SLS – 1st stage 2SLS – 2nd stage

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

ln(Cash

Ratio)

ln(Cash

Ratio)

Market Value

/Assets

Market Value

/Assets

ln(Cash

Ratio)

ln(Cash

Ratio)

Market Value/Assets 0.089*** 0.089*** 0.491*** 0.489***

(23.56) (23.60) (9.78) (9.78)

3-year Lagged Sales Growth 0.032*** 0.032***

(13.89) (13.92)

ln(Assets) 0.033*** 0.034*** -0.015*** -0.017*** 0.039*** 0.041***

(7.96) (7.96) (-3.10) (-3.43) (8.54) (8.66)

CF/Assets 0.482*** 0.480*** -1.482*** -1.475*** 1.084*** 1.078***

(17.11) (17.02) (-24.62) (-24.53) (12.75) (12.74)

Std. Industry CF/Assets 0.017*** 0.017*** -0.008 -0.008 0.020*** 0.020***

(3.77) (3.79) (-1.38) (-1.41) (3.89) (3.92)

NWC/Assets 1.314*** 1.314*** 0.682*** 0.682*** 1.039*** 1.040***

(67.19) (67.20) (27.31) (27.33) (26.02) (26.08)

R&D Expense/Assets 1.500*** 1.496*** 2.341*** 2.357*** 0.542*** 0.536***

(18.73) (18.69) (13.03) (13.11) (3.34) (3.30)

CAPEX/Assets -0.410*** -0.413*** 3.452*** 3.464*** -1.841*** -1.844***

(-3.84) (-3.88) (28.08) (28.24) (-8.67) (-8.69)

Leverage -1.647*** -1.647*** 0.449*** 0.449*** -1.825*** -1.824***

(-56.46) (-56.45) (10.87) (10.88) (-46.48) (-46.54)

Dividends/Assets -0.321 -0.312 11.740*** 11.701*** -4.895*** -4.857***

(-0.79) (-0.76) (20.56) (20.56) (-6.62) (-6.59)

Major Customer 0.010* -0.045*** 0.028*

(1.69) (-2.75) (1.72)

First Stage F-statistics N/A N/A 192.955*** 193.804*** N/A N/A

Wu-Hausman F-statistics N/A N/A N/A N/A 103.412*** 103.023***

Observations 161,183 161,183 161,183 161,183 161,183 161,183

Adjusted R-squared 0.392 0.392 0.344 0.345 0.238 0.239

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Industry Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes