demographics, redistribution, and optimal in⁄ation · 2017. 2. 25. · demographics,...

31
Demographics, Redistribution, and Optimal Ination James Bullard, FRB of St. Louis Carlos Garriga, FRB of St. Louis Christopher J. Waller, FRB of St. Louis 2012 BOJ-IMES Conference Demographic Changes and Macroeconomic Performance The views expressed herein do not necessarily reect those of the FOMC or the Federal Reserve System.

Upload: others

Post on 27-Jan-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Demographics, Redistribution, and OptimalInflation

    James Bullard, FRB of St. LouisCarlos Garriga, FRB of St. Louis

    Christopher J. Waller, FRB of St. Louis

    2012 BOJ-IMES ConferenceDemographic Changes and Macroeconomic Performance

    The views expressed herein do not necessarily reflect those ofthe FOMC or the Federal Reserve System.

  • Inflation and Demography

    I Can observed low inflation outcomes be related todemographic factors such as an aging population?

    I A basic “back-of-the-envelop” suggests NOI Consider an economy were capital and money are perfectsubstitutes

    r = δ+ n =1

    1+ π

    I The effect of a permanent increase in n′ > n increases thereturn of capital r ′ > r and inflation decreases to π′.

    I Countries with relatively young (old) populations would haverelatively low (high) inflation rates, all else equal.

  • Inflation and Demography: Japan

  • Inflation and Demography: USA

  • Objective

    I Understand the determination of central bank objectives whenpopulation aging shifts the social preferences for redistributionand its implications for inflation.

    I The intergenerational redistribution tension is intrinsic inlife-cycle models.

    I Young cohorts do not have any assets and wages are the mainsource of income.

    I Old generations cannot work and prefer a high rate of returnfrom their savings.

    I When the old have more (less) influence over redistributivepolicy, the rate of return of money is high (low).

  • Objective

    I Approach: Based on Bullard and Waller (2004) but withdynamics

    I Use a direct mechanism to decide the allocations. A babyboom corresponds to putting more weight on the young of aparticular generation relative to past and future generations.

    I This mechanism can replicate any steady state allocationarising from a political economy model with populationgrowth or decline.

  • Outline Presentation

    I Effi cient economy and intergenerational redistributionI Constrained effi ciency and redistributionI Optimal Wedges: Capital taxes=InflationI Numerical examples

    I Transitory demographicsI Persistent demographic changes

  • Model

  • Environment

    I Two-period OLG model with capital.I Discrete time t = ...,−2,−1, 0, 1, 2, ...I Population growth Nt = (1+ n)Nt−1 where N0 = 1I Preferences: U(c1,t , c2,t+1) = u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)I Neoclassical production F (Kt ,Nt ) and constant depreciation δI Per capital resource constraint

    c1,t +1

    1+ nc1,t−1 + (1+ n) kt+1 = f (kt ) + (1− δ) kt .

  • Social Preferences and Optimal Allocations

    I The objective function weights current and future generationsaccording to

    V (k0) = max{βλ−1u(c2,0) +∞

    ∑t=0

    λt [u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)]}.

    subject to the resource constraint.I Optimality conditions imply

    u′(c1,t )u′(c2,t )

    =λt−1λt

    β(1+ n)

    and

    (1+ n)u′(c1,t )u′(c1,t+1)

    =λt+1λt

    [1− δ+ f ′(kt+1)

    ].

  • Steady State

    I Effi cient production: the steady state stock of capital ks isdetermined by

    f ′(ks ) = (1+ n)λ−1 + δ− 1,

    For λ < 1, the economy is dynamically effi cient. When λ = 1,the economy satisfies the golden rule f ′(k∗) = n+ δ.

    I Effi cient consumption cs1 and cs2 solve

    u′(cs1 ) = β(1+ n)u′(cs2 )

    cs1 +cs21+ n

    + (δ+ n)ks = f (ks ).

  • Market Implementation: Intergenerational Redistribution

    I Consumers: Representative newborn solves

    max u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)

    s.t. c1,t + st = wt lt + T1,t ,

    c2,t+1 = (1− δ+ rt+1)st + T2,t+1.The optimality condition

    u′(wt lt − st +T1t ) = βu′ [(1− δ+ rt+1)st + T2,t+1] (1+ rt+1).

    I Intergenerational redistribution:

    T1,t +T2,t1+ n

    = 0.

  • No Intergenerational Redistribution (Ramsey)

    I In the absence of intergenerational redistribution

    V (k0) = max{βλ−1u(c2,0) +∞

    ∑t=0

    λt [u(c1,t ) + βu(c2,t+1)]}

    s.t. c1,t = fl (kt ) l − (1+ n)kt+1,c2,t = [1− δ+ fk (kt )] kt ,

    I Optimality conditions (endogenous multipliers γ1,t ,γ2,t)

    u′(c1,t )u′(c2,t )

    =λt−1λt

    β(1+ n)γ1,tγ2,t

  • Markets Redistribute: Capital taxes/inflationI The intergenerational decision of savings (capital) is morecomplicated:

    (1+ n) u′(c1,t )︸ ︷︷ ︸↑savings

    =λt+1λt

    u′(c1,t+1)fl ,kl

    1+ n︸ ︷︷ ︸↑wage rate

    +βu′(c2,t+1)[1− δ+ fk + fk ,kst1+ n︸ ︷︷ ︸]

    ↓return all savings

    I Effi cient wedges

    u′(c1,t )βu′(c2,t+1)

    =

    [1− δ+ fk

    ( st−11+n

    )(1+ φkt+1)

    ](1+ φλt+1)

    .

    where

    φk =kfk ,kfk

    < 1; φλt+1 = λu′(c1,t+1)u′(c1,t )

    fk ,k

    (st−11+ n

    )l

    1+ n< 1

  • Money and Capital

    I The optimal intergenerational redistribution determines theequilibrium interest rate.

    I These parameters determine inflation when capital and moneyare perfect substitutes.

    I Per capita money growth rate evolves

    Mt+1 (1+ n) = (1+ zt )Mt

    I Arbritrage then implies that

    fk (kt ) =1

    1+ πt=1+ n1+ zt

    .

    I Money is priced as an asset that is held in zero net supply(Woodford’s (2003) “cashless” economy).

  • Quantitative Illustration

  • Functional Forms

    I Preferences:

    U(c1,t , c2,t+1) =c1−σ1,t1− σ + β

    c1−σ2,t+11− σ ,

    I Technology:f (k) = Akα

  • Parameterization

    Parameter Valueα 0.35A 10

    l = δ 1σ 2n 0.99630

    β 0.97930

  • Steady State

  • Capital Stock

    0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.50.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6

    1.8

    2

    2.2

    2.4

    Intergenerational Discounting(λ)

    Cap

    ital S

    tock

    E fficientConstrained

  • Consumption Young

    0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5

    0.45

    0.5

    0.55

    0.6

    0.65

    Intergenerational Discounting ( λ)

    Con

    sum

    ptio

    n Yo

    ung(

    %)

    EfficientConstrained

  • Inflation (n

  • Inflation (n=0)

    0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5

    -0.015

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    Intergenerational Discounting( λ)

    Infla

    tion

    EfficientConstrained

  • Transitional Dynamics:Demographics and Inflation

  • Intergenerational Redistribution: Transitory

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 900.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6In

    terg

    ener

    atio

    nal D

    isco

    untin

    g ( λ

    )

  • Inflation and Demographics: Transitory

    10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

    -0.01

    -0.005

    0

    0.005

    0.01

    0.015In

    flatio

    n (A

    nnua

    lized

    ) EfficientConstrained

  • Interest Rates and Demographics: Transitory

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-0.5

    -0.4

    -0.3

    -0.2

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2In

    tere

    st R

    ates

    (% C

    hang

    e)

    EfficientConstrained

  • Intergenerational Redistribution: Permanent

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 900.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1

    1.2

    1.4

    1.6In

    terg

    ener

    atio

    nal D

    isco

    untin

    g ( λ

    )

  • Inflation and Demographics: Permanent

    10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    x 10-3In

    flatio

    n (A

    nnua

    lized

    )EfficientConstrained

  • Interest Rates and Demographics: Permanent

    0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100-0.5

    -0.4

    -0.3

    -0.2

    -0.1

    0

    0.1

    0.2In

    tere

    st R

    ates

    (% C

    hang

    e)

    EfficientConstrained

  • Conclusions

    I Study the interaction between population demographics, thedesire for redistribution in the economy, and the optimalinflation rate.

    I The intergenerational redistribution tension is intrinsic inlife-cycle models.

    I Young cohorts do not have any assets and wages are the mainsource of income.

    I Old generations cannot work and prefer a high rate of returnfrom their savings.

    I When the old have more (less) influence over redistributivepolicy, the rate of return of money is high (high).