dividing the spoils of power: how are the benefits of majority party

26
State Politics and Policy Quarterly, Vol. 9, No. 2 (Summer 2009): pp. 125–150 ©2009 by the Board of Trustees of the University of Illinois Dividing the Spoils of Power: How Are the Benefits of Majority Party Status Distributed in U.S. State Legislatures? Henry A. Kim, University of Arizona Justin H. Phillips, Columbia University abstract We assess the conditions under which majority status generates benefits for incum- bent legislators and how these benefits are distributed among members of the major- ity party. We argue that majority status is valuable only in procedurally partisan chambers; that is, when the majority party monopolizes chamber leadership positions and control of the legislative agenda. Contrary to the existing literature, we also posit that these rewards should be distributed broadly across the majority party. To test our expectations, we utilize 10 recent transitions in the partisan control of U.S. state legislatures and data on campaign contributions. Consistent with our expectations, majority status is valuable, but only in procedurally partisan chambers. Furthermore, the premium in campaign contributions enjoyed by the majority party is primarily distributed to backbenchers, although top party leaders also benefit. These results provide important insights into the distribution of power and influence in U.S. state legislatures. despite the large number of scholarly articles and books devoted to evaluating partisan theories of legislative organization, little attention has been paid to the implications of chamber-wide majority party advantage at the level of individual legislators. The existing literature has focused on whether the majority party collectively enjoys substantial advantages in the legislative process, not who in the majority party benefits (Cox and McCub- bins 1993; Cox, Kousser, and McCubbins 2005; Aldrich 1995). Do these ben- efits accrue exclusively to majority party leaders or to individual members outside of the party leadership? What are the relative magnitudes of these benefits? What conditions determine their distribution? This article addresses these questions in the setting of U.S. state legis- latures. In particular, we examine whether and how donors reallocate their campaign giving following an intra-chamber change in the identity of the

Upload: dinhdan

Post on 02-Jan-2017

217 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

State Politics and Policy Quarterly, Vol.9,No.2(Summer2009):pp.125–150

©2009bytheBoardofTrusteesoftheUniversityofIllinois

Dividing the Spoils of Power: How Are the Benefits of Majority Party Status Distributed in U.S. State Legislatures?

HenryA.Kim,University of ArizonaJustinH.Phillips,Columbia University

abstract

Weassesstheconditionsunderwhichmajoritystatusgeneratesbenefitsforincum-bentlegislatorsandhowthesebenefitsaredistributedamongmembersofthemajor-ityparty.Wearguethatmajoritystatusisvaluableonlyinprocedurallypartisanchambers;thatis,whenthemajoritypartymonopolizeschamberleadershippositionsandcontrolofthelegislativeagenda.Contrarytotheexistingliterature,wealsopositthattheserewardsshouldbedistributedbroadlyacrossthemajorityparty.Totestourexpectations,weutilize10recenttransitionsinthepartisancontrolofU.S.statelegislaturesanddataoncampaigncontributions.Consistentwithourexpectations,majoritystatusisvaluable,butonlyinprocedurallypartisanchambers.Furthermore,thepremiumincampaigncontributionsenjoyedbythemajoritypartyisprimarilydistributedtobackbenchers,althoughtoppartyleadersalsobenefit.TheseresultsprovideimportantinsightsintothedistributionofpowerandinfluenceinU.S.statelegislatures.

despite the large numberofscholarlyarticlesandbooksdevotedtoevaluatingpartisantheoriesoflegislativeorganization,littleattentionhasbeenpaidtotheimplicationsofchamber-widemajoritypartyadvantageatthelevelofindividuallegislators.Theexistingliteraturehasfocusedonwhetherthemajoritypartycollectively enjoyssubstantialadvantagesinthelegislativeprocess,notwhointhemajoritypartybenefits(CoxandMcCub-bins1993;Cox,Kousser,andMcCubbins2005;Aldrich1995).Dotheseben-efitsaccrueexclusivelytomajoritypartyleadersortoindividualmembersoutsideofthepartyleadership?Whataretherelativemagnitudesofthesebenefits?Whatconditionsdeterminetheirdistribution? ThisarticleaddressesthesequestionsinthesettingofU.S.statelegis-latures.Inparticular,weexaminewhetherandhowdonorsreallocatetheircampaigngivingfollowinganintra-chamberchangeintheidentityofthe

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 125 4/7/09 4:23:31 PM

majorityparty.WeemployamethodderivedfromtheinnovativestudybyCoxandMagar(1999)thatexaminesadjustmentsincontributionpatternsfollowingchangesinpartycontroloftheU.S.HouseofRepresentatives.Ouranalysis,however,goesbeyondthatofCoxandMagar,examininghowthatvalueisdistributedamongmajoritypartyleaders,committeechairs,andbackbenchers1whodonotenjoyanyprivilegedpositionsinthechamber. FollowingexistingstudiesofU.S.CongressbyDenzauandMunger(1986),GrierandMunger(1993),andRomerandSnyder(1994),weviewcampaigncontributionsasapaymentfor“legislativeservices”thatmembersofanassem-blycanprovideonbehalfofpotentialdonors.Inotherwords,campaigncon-tributionsareanindirectmeasureofalegislator’sinfluence.Thegreaterthevalueofservicesthatalegislatorcanprovide,themorecontributionsheorshecanraise,holdingallelseequal.Byexaminingthedistributionofcontributions,wecaninferthedistributionofpowerandinfluencewithinthechamber. Formalpowersandprivilegesarenotdistributeduniformlyinalegis-lature,evenwithinthemajorityparty.Researchatthestatelevelindicatesthatpartyleadersandcommitteechairsoftenhavemoreformalpowersandagreaterabilitytoinfluencelegislativeoutcomesthanmajoritypartyback-benchers(Francis1989;Rosenthal2004;SquireandHamm2005;Hamm,Hedlund,andMartorano2006).Asaresult,theexistingliteraturesuggeststhatthebenefitsofmajoritystatus,ifatallvaluable,willmostlyfalluponindividualsholdingthesepositions. Wearguetheopposite:Thefruitsofthemajoritystatusshouldbesharedbroadlywithintheparty.Sincedisloyalbackbencherscoulddefecttotheminorityanddeprivethemajoritypartyofproceduralcontrolinthecham-ber,assuringtheirlong-termallegianceisessentialtothemajority’scon-tinuedholdonpower.Thisrequiresthatbackbenchersbegivenastakeinmaintainingtheirparty’scollectiveadvantages.Suchastakeisfurnishedbyprovidingthemashareofinfluence,eventhoughtheylackformalpositionsinthelegislativeprocess.Oneoftheprincipallociinwhichbackbencherscanexertinfluenceisthepartycaucus,wheretheycanpartakeinintrapartybargainsandofferinputintothepolicymakingprocess. Nonetheless,wemustbeginbyconsideringwhetherandwhenmajoritypartystatusisvaluableinstatelegislatures.Unfortunately,nosystematicstudyexiststoestablishthisvalueintermsofcampaigncontributions.Thereislittlepointinexaminingthedistributionofbenefitswithinthemajoritypartyiftherearenobenefitstobedistributed.Importantly,therearereasonstoexpectthatthevalueofmajoritystatuswillsystematicallydifferacrosschambers.Statelegislaturesvarygreatlyintheextenttowhichthemajor-itypartymonopolizeschamberleadershippositions,committeechairman-

126 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 126 4/7/09 4:23:32 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 127

ships,orproceduralcontroloverthelegislativeagenda(JewellandWhicker1994;SquireandHamm2005).Weexpectthatthevalueofmajoritystatusdependsontheinternalorganizationofthechamber;undersomeinstitu-tionalarrangements,majoritystatusmightnotbevaluable. Wearguethattheprerequisiteofvaluablemajoritystatusiswhatweterm“proceduralpartisanship.”Wedefinethisascompletemonopolybythemajoritypartyofallagenda-settingauthorityinthechamber,includingthespeakershipandcontrolofallcommittees.Inthesechambers,themajorityparty’scontroloveralllegislativeoutcomesisanearcertainty.Othercham-bersmayfeatureminoritypartymembersincontrolofseveralpositionswithagenda-settingauthority,evenifmajoritypartymembersretaincontrolovermostofthem.Welabeltheseinstitutionalarrangements“procedurallybipartisan.”Controlofsuchpositionsbyminoritypartymemberssuggeststhatmajoritypartymembershipisneitheranecessarynorsufficientcondi-tionforinfluenceinthelegislativeprocess.Bargainscanbestruckwherebyevenminoritypartymembersaregivenaseatatthebargainingtableandaccrueapremiumincampaigncontributions,whilesomemajoritypartymembersarecutout. Totestourexpectations,wetakeadvantageof10recentinstancesofpar-tisanchangeinasampleofeightU.S.statelegislatures.First,wecomparethevalueofmajoritystatusacrosschambersthatareexclusivelyorganizedbythemajorityparty(i.e.,procedurallypartisanchambers)tothosethatarenot(i.e.,procedurallybipartisanchambers).Amongoursampleofstates,wefindthatthevalueofmajoritystatusisindeedtiedtotheexclusivityofproceduraladvantages:itisvaluableonlyifthemajoritypartymonopolizesallkeypostsandcontrolofthelegislativeagenda.Wheremajoritystatusisindeedvalu-able,wefindthatthemajoritypartypremiumrangesfromover$10,000inIndianatoapproximately$35,000inGeorgia.Inprocedurallynon-partisanlegislatures,thevalueofthemajoritystatusisstatisticallyzero. Toexaminethedistributionofmajoritypartypremiums,wepooldatafromthefivestateswherethemajoritystatusisshowntobevaluable.Weesti-matehowtheincreasedcontributionsthataccompanythechangeinmajoritystatusaredistributedamongmajoritypartyleaders,committeechairs,andbackbenchers.Wefindthatmuchofthemajoritypartypremiumgoestothebackbenchers;simplybeingamajoritypartymemberwithout holdinganyprivilegedpositionsconfersasignificantvalue.Thisfindingsupportsourargumentthatsuccessfulpartygovernmentprovidesitsbackbencherswithashareofinfluencesothattheycanbenefitfromtheirparty’sstatus. Inthenextsection,wedescribethelogicofourstudyandformulatehypothesesconcerningtheconditionsunderwhichmajoritystatusmay,

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 127 4/7/09 4:23:32 PM

andmaynot,bevaluableandhowthebenefitsofmajoritystatusshouldbedistributed.Wethenaccountforourselectionofcasesandhighlightsomeoftheimportantcross-sectionalvariationwithinoursample.Next,wedescribeourdata,statisticalmodel,andresults.Followingthediscussionoftheresults,weconsidertheirimplicationsforvarioustheoriesoflegislativeorganizationaswellasourunderstandingoflawmakinginstatehouses.

theoretical framework

When is Majority Status Valuable?

Wedistinguishbetweenwhatweterm“procedurallypartisan”and“proce-durallybipartisan”statelegislatures.Theformer,suchastheU.S.HouseofRepresentatives,operatesontheprinciplethatthemajoritypartycompletelymonopolizesallprocedurallyimportantpositionsandtherebycontrolovertheagenda.Thelatter,suchastheTexasandVermonthouses,donotrequiremembershipinthemajoritypartyasaconditionforholdingkeylegislativepositionsanddonotallowthemajoritypartytoexerciseexclusivecontrolovertheagenda. Thevastmajorityofstatelegislativechambersareprocedurallypartisan.Inthesechambers,thepresidingofficer—usuallytheSpeaker—isselectedwithinthemajoritypartycaucus,whosemembersthenunitebehindtheirnomineeinballotingonthechamberfloor(JewellandPatterson1986).Themajoritypartyalsoenjoysamonopolyoverthechamber’scommit-teesystem.Thepartycaucus,inconjunctionwiththepresidingofficer,decidesuponthetotalnumberofcommitteesaswellastheirjurisdictions(Francis1989;Rosenthal2004).Thecaucusalsoclaimsforitsmember-shipallchairmanshipsandtherighttooccupyapreponderanceofseatsonallcommittees(JewellandWhicker1994).Throughtheseinstitutionaladvantages,themajoritypartycontrolstheflowoflegislation;i.e.,ithasthepowertoexpedite,delay,orstopthepassageofbills.Thesepowersareregularlyusedbypartyleaders,actingasagentsoftheircaucus,tobothmovethroughthechamberlegislationthatadvancestheinterestsofthepartyanditssupportersandtokilllegislationthatharmstheirpartisaninterests,dividesthecaucus,orisespeciallycontroversial(CoxandMcCub-bins1993;Rosenthal2004). Therefore,majoritypartymembersinaprocedurallypartisanchambershouldbeabletodomuchmoreforpotentialdonorsthancomparablysitu-atedmembersoftheminority.Ifsuchisthecase,majoritypartymembersshouldhavegreaterabilitytoraisecampaigncontributions.Thisleadstoourfirsthypothesis:

128 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 128 4/7/09 4:23:32 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 129

ThePartisanHypothesis(H1):Whenalegislatureisprocedurallypartisan,membersofthemajoritypartywillraisemoreincampaigncontributionsthanwilltheircounterpartsintheminority,ceteris paribus.

Ontheotherhand,majoritypartiesinprocedurallybipartisanchambersdonotmonopolizecommitteechairs,chamberleadershippositions,orthelegislativeagenda.Instead,thesepositionsandpowersareheldby,anddis-tributedto,membersacrosspartylines.Thispatternoflegislativeorganiza-tionismostcommonlyfoundinstatesthathavepreviousexperiencewithsingle-partydominanceorwhenablocwithinthemajoritypartydefects,forwhateverreason,fromitscaucusandagreestoorganizethechamberwiththeminority. Inprocedurallybipartisanlegislatures,thebenefitsofmajoritystatusshouldbesmall.First,minoritymemberswhoareservingascommitteechairsandchamberleaderscannotbeexpectedtowieldtheirauthorityinamannerthatbenefitsthemajoritypartyoritsmembers.Anyadditionalcampaigncontributionstheyaccruethroughtheexerciseoftheirinfluencedonotaddtothemajorityparty’spremium.Second,minoritycommitteechairsandchamberleadersholdtheirjobsinplaceofmajoritypartymem-bersandwiththecooperationandsupportfromotherchamberleaderswhoareoftenthemselvesmembersofthemajorityparty.Thissuggeststhatprocedurallybipartisanchambersareorganizedaroundsomeprinciplethatsupersedesloyaltytoone’sfellowpartisans. Inplaceofthemajorityparty,abipartisanagenda-settingstructureexiststhatspreadsbenefitstosomemembersonbothsidesofthepartyline.Thereareseveralpossibilitiesastowhatmightconstitutetheorganizingprincipleofabipartisanregime;itcouldbethespeaker’s“personal”cliqueoraregionalorideologicalgrouping.Whatevertheorganizingrationale,ittrumpsmerepartyaffiliationindeterminingwhogetsashareofinfluencenecessaryforrenderinglegislativeservices.Thisleadsustooursecondhypothesis:

TheBipartisanHypothesis(H2):Whenalegislatureisprocedurallybiparti-san,membersofthemajoritypartywillnotraisemoreincampaigncontri-butionsthantheircounterpartsintheminority,ceterisparibus.2

How Are the Benefits of Majority Status Distributed?

Apositiveaveragepremiumformajoritystatusdoesnotrevealmuchabouthowthesebenefitsaredistributedwithintheparty.Inanylegislature,themajoritypartyisacomplexorganizationwithmembersholdingdifferentrolesandwithdifferentformalpowersandprivilegesdistributedunevenlyamongtheseroles.Givensuchinternalcomplexity,thebenefitsofthemajor-itystatusmaynotaccrueuniformlyacrossallmembersoftheparty.

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 129 4/7/09 4:23:32 PM

ManycurrentstudiesofpartygovernmentinbothCongressandstatelegislatures(Aldrich1995;CoxandMcCubbins1993;JewellandWhicker1994;Clucas2001)emphasizetheroleofmajoritypartyleaders,ashasourdiscussionthusfar.Intheseanalyses,themajoritypartydetermines,asagroup,itsoverallgoalsand,toachievetheseaims,delegatesasetofpowerstotheleadership,includingthosetobeusedagainsttheirownmembersasnecessary.Inturn,thetoppartyleadersdelegatepowerfurthertoanotherrungofleadersbelow,suchascommitteechairs,tohelpimplementthepartyagenda.Littleremainsforthebackbencherstodointheparty’sday-to-dayoperation,otherthantorevokethedelegationcollectivelyiftheleadershiprunsafoulofthepartyasawholeandtosetforththedelegationanew. Inmostoftheexistingtheoreticalconceptionsofpartygovernment,indi-vidualbackbenchersareassignedrelativelylittlepower.Discussionoftheirrolesisgenerallylimitedtothatofsettingthepartygovernmentinmotionandtobringingittoaclose,ifnecessary,andonlybyactingasacollective.Allday-to-dayoperationsarerunbythepartyleaders,whoenjoymyriadformalpowersthroughoutthelegislativeprocess(CoxandMcCubbins1993).Thereislittleopportunityfortheindividualmajoritypartybackbencherstorenderlegislativeservicesonbehalfofparticularinterestgroups,manyofwhommightnotbeseekingbroadpolicychange.Giventhelargedisparityinpotentialinfluence,contributorsmaypreferdirectingdonationstoleaders.Thispossibilityisexpressedasourthirdhypothesis:

TheLeadershipHypothesis(H3):Thefinancialadvantagesofmajoritypartystatuswillbeenjoyedprincipallybypartyleadersandcommitteechairs,notbackbenchers.

Whiletheroleofleadersisclearlyimportant,wesuspectthattheiruseofformalpowerswillbedirected,inlargepart,atmaintainingthesupportofbackbenchers.Themajoritypartyleadershiprequiresthesupportoftheseindividualsfortworeasons.Mostimportantly,theleaders’ownjobsdependonthecontinuedsupportfromco-partisansintheircaucus.Second,thevotesofbackbenchersarenecessaryforupholdingtheleaders’agenda-settingwork.Majoritypartybillsneedtobeprotectedfromencroachment(i.e.,unfriendlyamendments)bothincommitteeandonthechamberfloor,andtheywillultimatelyneedtogarneramajorityofvotesforpassage.Supportfrombackbenchersinthesestepswillbemorelikelyiftheyhaveapersonalstakeinmaintainingthecohesionofthemajorityparty.Suchastakecanbegeneratedbypartyleadersthroughthesharingoftheirinfluencewiththeirco-partisansandbyadvancingtheinterestsofindividualbackbenchersintheday-to-dayoperationsofthelegislature.Suchhelpfromanattendantleadershipkeepsupthevalueofpartymembership.Ineffect,mostmajority

130 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 130 4/7/09 4:23:33 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 131

partymembers,eventhoselackinginformalpowers,shouldbegrantedashareofthecollectiveadvantagethattheirpartyenjoysandthussomestakeworthdefendinginthemajoritystatusitself. Wepositthatanimportantmechanismfordistributingthebenefitsofthemajoritystatustobackbenchersisthepartycaucus.3Thecaucusprovidesaforumforcommunicationbetweentheleadershipandbackbenchersandfordealmakingwhereaccessisrestrictedtomembersofthesameparty.Theseactivitiespermitincorporationoftheneedsoftheindividualmembersintotheparty’soverallagendaandallowforresolutionofinternaldisputesthroughdeliberationandbargaining(Rosenthal2004).Thebargainsstruckinthecourseofthecaucusprocessmayevengenerateanintrapartyconsen-susthatmightnotnaturallyexist.Oncebargainsarestruckinthecaucus,themajoritycanhonorthedealsitsmembershavereached,thankstoitsproceduralandnumericaladvantages.Theproceduraladvantagesensurethatthedealswillbeprotectedfrominterferenceandbebroughtupforcon-siderationonthefloor.Thenumericaladvantage—steeledbytheintrapartybargains—assuresthattheyhavesufficientvotestoguaranteepassage. Inthisconceptionofpartygovernment,majoritystatusbringswide-spreadbenefitsthroughouttheparty,fortheleaderswithformalpowersandbackbencherswithout.Thisleadstothefollowinghypothesis:

TheCaucusHypothesis(H4):Thefinancialadvantagesofmajoritypartystatuswillbewidelydispersedamongmembersofthemajoritypartycaucus,includingbackbenchers.

sample of legislatures

ToassessthemonetaryvalueofmajoritystatusinU.S.statelegislatures,weassembleasampleoflegislativechambersthatexperiencedaswitchintheidentityofthemajoritypartyandforwhichthereisreadilyaccessiblecam-paignfinancedata.Unfortunately,dataconcerningthecontributionsmadetostatelegislativecandidateshavenotbecomesystematicallyavailableuntilthepastdecade.4Additionally,manystateshavenotexperiencedarecentchangeinthepartisancontroloftheirlegislature.Thesetwoconsiderationslimitthestatesfromwhichwecanculloursample. Withtheserestrictionsinmind,wehaveidentified10instancesofpartisanchangeinlowerlegislativechambers:Colorado(2004),Georgia(2004),Indiana(1994,1996,and2004),Illinois(1996),NewJersey(2001),Oklahoma(2004),Texas(2002),andVermont(2000).5Fourofthesecases—Colorado,Indiana(1996),Illinois,andNewJersey—aretransitionsfromRepublicantoDemo-craticcontrol,whiletheremainingarechangesintheoppositedirection.

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 131 4/7/09 4:23:33 PM

Thissampleincludesbothprocedurallypartisanandbipartisanlegisla-tures.ThechambersinGeorgia,Illinois,Indiana,NewJersey,andOklahomarepresenttheformercategory.EachofthesecloselyresemblestheU.S.HouseofRepresentativesinthatthemajoritypartymaintainsmonopolycontrolovertheleversofpower.Membersofthemajorityconsistentlyholdallofthechamber’sleadershippositions,chairallmajorcommittees,andcontrolthelegislativeagenda.6Themajoritypartyineachalsohasastronglegislativecaucuswithawell-developedleadershipstructure. TheTexasandVermontHouses,ontheotherhand,areprocedurallybipartisan.Themajoritypartyintheformerdoesnotplayaroleinorga-nizingthechamber.Instead,thistaskishandledexclusivelybythespeakerandhisbipartisanleadershipteam(Jones,Micozzi,andVonnahme2006;MaxwellandCrain2006).Teamstatus,whichusuallytranslatesintovariousprestigiouspositions,isbasedonamember’spersonalrelationshipwiththespeakerorideologyratherthanhisorherpartisanaffiliation(HammandHarmel1991;Kraemer,Newell,andPrindle2003).Asaconsequence,severalprizecommitteesineachlegislativesessionarechairedbymembersoftheminorityparty.Forinstance,aftertheRepublicanswoncontrolfromDemocratsfollowingthe2002elections,Democraticlawmakerscontinuedtochairsixcommittees,includingseveraldesirablecommittees,includ-ingtheEnvironmentalandNaturalResourcesCommitteeandtheRulesCommittee.Beyondthespeakership,theTexasHousehasnoformalpartyorganization. Similarly,privilegedpositionsintheVermontHousearesharedacrosspartylines.Thespeaker,regardlessofhisorherpartisanaffiliation,routinelyappointsDemocrats,Republicans,andmembersofthirdpartiestochaircom-mittees.Approximately20percentofchairmanshipsineachlegislativesessionareheldbynon-majoritylawmakers,includingsuchchoiceassignmentsasthetransportationandagriculturecommittees.Moreover,thechamberhasahistoryofelectingminoritypartymembersasspeaker,somethingthatisrarelyobservedinotherlegislatures.ArecentexampleisRalphC.Wright,aDemocratwhoservedasspeakerforsixyears(1985though1991)withaRepublicanmajority(Wright2005).Thissuggeststhat,asinTexas,privilegedpositionsareoftendistributedbasedonpersonalrelationshipsandideologywithpartyaffiliationasasecondaryconsideration. TheColoradoHouseisanintermediatecase.Althoughthemajoritypartyorganizesthechamberandmonopolizesallleadershippositionsandcom-mitteechairs,controloftheseinstitutionsdoesnotallowittocontrolthelegislativeagenda.Theagenda-settingpowersofthemajoritypartyareseverelylimitedbythestateconstitution.InNovemberof1988,voterspassedaballot

132 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 132 4/7/09 4:23:33 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 133

measureentitled,“GiveAVotetoEveryLegislator(GAVEL),”requiringthatallproposedbillsbegivenavoteincommitteeand,ifpassed,beconsideredonthechamberfloor(Straayer2000).Thisrequirementdeprivesthespeakerandcommitteechairstheabilitytounilaterallyblocklegislation,andittrans-formedColorado’slegislaturefromatextbookcaseofmajoritycontroltoadecentralizedbody(Cox,Kousser,andMcCubbins2005,14).Keypostswithinthelegislatureweredeprivedoftheauthoritytosustainadecidedlypartisanagendaandthepowerneededbypartyleaderstobenefittheirbackbencherswasdecidedlyweakened. Oursamplealsoaccountsfortwoadditional,andpotentiallyrelevant,variationsinstatepoliticalinstitutions.Thefirstoftheseislegislativepro-fessionalization,thefullspectrumofwhichiscapturedbyourstates.ThelegislaturesinIllinoisandNewJerseyareconsideredprofessional;membersservefull-timeinnearlyyear-roundsessionswithlargesalariesandstaffs.Incontrast,thechambersinGeorgia,Indiana,andVermontaretypicallycategorizedas“citizenlegislatures.”Intheseassemblies,lawmakersmeetinshortsessions,withonlyasmallsalaryandperdiemandsupportfromveryfewstaff.Finally,theTexasandOklahomachambersareclassifiedashybridlegislatures(Kurtz1990;HammandMoncrief2004). Similarly,oursampleencompassesadiversityofcampaignfinanceregimes.Ononeextreme,wehaveseveralstateswithverypermissivelaws.TheseincludeTexas,Illinois,andIndiana,whichallowforunlimitedgivinginstatelegisla-tiveracesbyindividualsandpoliticalactioncommittees(PACs).AttheotherendofthespectrumisthestateofVermont,whichhasadoptedoneofthenation’smoststringentsetofcontributionlimits,permittingPACs,individu-als,corporations,andunionstogivenomorethan$200tocandidates.Whilewedonotanticipatethatourresultswillvaryasafunctionoflegislativepro-fessionalizationorastate’scampaignfinancelaws,byutilizingasampleoflegislaturesthatvaryonthesedimensions,wecanseeifourresultsarerobusttothesedifferences.7

empirical analysis

Data and Statistical Model

FollowingtheapproachusedbyRomerandSnyder(1994)andCoxandMagar(1999),weestimatethevalueofmajoritypartystatuslongitudinallyinsteadofcross-sectionally.Specifically,weexaminechangesinthecam-paigncontributionsmadetoindividualincumbentlegislatorsacrosstwoelectoralcycles,thefirstofwhichresultedinapartisanchange.Thisallowsustoholdconstantmostmember-specificdeterminantsofcontributions,

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 133 4/7/09 4:23:33 PM

animportantconsiderationgiventhelimiteddataavailableregardingindi-viduallegislators. Unlikeexistingstudies,foreachstateinoursample,wealsoutilizedatafromtwoconsecutiveelectioncycles(chosenatrandom)acrosswhichtheidentityofthemajoritypartyremainsunchanged.Doingsoallowsustoestablishabetterbaselinefornormalsession-to-sessionvariationsincam-paigncontributions.Also,itpermitsamoreaccurateexaminationofthechangesinlegislatorstatusthattakeplaceintheabsenceofpartisanchange.Changesinleadershippositions,committeechairmanships,andcommitteeassignmentstakeplaceevenwhenthesamepartyremainsincontrolofthechamber.Asweareinterestedinnotjustthevalueofthemajoritystatusalonebutalsothedistributionofthebenefitswithinthemajorityparty,anexaminationoftheeffectsfromthechangesinkeypositionsthatdonotaccompanyachamber-widepartisanchangeisdesirable.TheidentityofallthestatesandelectionyearsusedinthisanalysisaredisplayedinTable1.

Table 1. StatesandElectionCyclesUsedinEmpiricalAnalysis

Mean Mean Election Election Partisan Contributions ContributionsState Cycle1 Cycle2 Change Cycle1 Cycle2

Colorado 2004 2006 R→D $33,291 $41,027 1998 2000 Control 20,517 28,442Georgia 2004 2006 D→R 57,082 58,875 1998 2000 Control 39,468 37,412Illinois 1998 2000 Control 213,550 234,454 1996 1998 R→D 255,169 216,092Indiana 2004 2006 D→R 76,891 56,369 2002 2004 Control 65,031 74,667 1996 1998 R→D 57,041 50,945 1994 1996 D→R 39,089 52,967NewJersey 2001 2003 R→D 119,420 153,826 1999 2001 Control 120,670 113,598Oklahoma 2004 2006 D→R 59,438 62,079 2000 2002 Control 41,793 33,437Texas 2002 2004 D→R 168,796 187,638 1998 2000 Control 125,296 147,157Vermont 2000 2002 D→R 2,651 1,776 1998 2000 Control 1,432 2,683

Notes:Thefirstcolumnidentifiesthestatesincludedinouranalysis.Thefollowingtwocolumnslisttheelectioncyclesusedforeach.ThefourthcolumnindicateswhetherthechambertransitionedfromRepublicantoDemo-craticcontrol(R→D),DemocratictoRepublicancontrol(D→R),orisusedasacontrolcase(meaningtherewasnopartisanchange).Theremainingcolumnsidentifymeantotalcontributionsbystateforeachelectioncycle.Meantotalcontributionsaretheaverageamountofmoneyraisedperelectioncyclebyincumbentlegislators(minusfundsreceivedfrompartycommitteesandfundsdonatedbylegislatorstotheirowncampaigns).

Source:InstituteonMoneyinStatePolitics

134 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 134 4/7/09 4:23:34 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 135

Totestourfirsttwohypotheses,weestimatethefollowingmodel:

ΔContributions=b1+b2ΔMajorityStatus+b3ΔPartyLeadershipStatus+b4ΔChairStatus+b5ΔLaggedElectoralSafety+b6ΔValuableCommittee

Ourdependentvariableisthechangeintotalcontributionsraisedbyindividualincumbentlegislatorsacrosstwoelectioncycles.CampaignfinancedatacomefromtheInstituteonMoneyinStatePolitics,anonpartisan,nonprofitorgani-zationthatcompilescampaigncontributioninformationoneverystate-levelcandidateandmajorpoliticalpartycommitteeinthecountry.TheInstitutegathersitsdatafromthestatedisclosureagencieswithwhichcandidatesmustfiletheircampaignfinancereports.Unfortunately,thedatadonotdistinguishgivingbypoliticalactioncommitteesfromdirectgivingbyindividualsandeconomicentities.ThereisnowaytoisolatePACcontributionsinaconsis-tentfashionacrossmultiplestatesduetodifferencesinthedefinitionofwhatconstitutesaPAC.Thus,weexaminechangesintotalcontributions,ratherthanPACcontributionsasperCoxandMagar.Inclusionofindividuals’con-tributions,whichmaynotbestrictlymotivatedbyconsiderationsofpolicyinfluence,certainlyintroducesadditionalnoiseintothedata(Thompson,Cassie,andJewell1994).Ifanything,thisbiasesagainstfindingsthatstatisticallyconfirmourhypotheses.Additionally,sinceweareonlyinterestedinmoneyraiseddirectlybylegislators,wesubtractfromtotalcontributionsanymoneydonatedbyacandidatetohisorherowncampaign,orgivenbyapoliticalparty,orfromchamberleadership.Allcontributionsdataaremeasuredinconstant(2000)dollars. Changeinmajoritystatusisoperationalizedasatrichotomousvariablewith1denotingmemberswhogainedmajoritystatusfromoneelectiontothenext,–1denotingmemberswholostmajoritystatus,and0denotingnochange.Incumbentswhoscore0usuallyswitchedpartiesfollowingapartisanchange,aremembersofathirdparty,orcomefromacontrolcase.Thechangeinpartyleadershipandcommitteechairstatusarealsoopera-tionalizedtrichotomously.Here,alegislatorisassignedavalueof1ifheorshebecameapartyleader(chair),–1ifheorshelostherleadershipposition(chairmanship),and0iftherewasnochangeinherstatus(orlackthereof).Weconsiderpartyleadershippositionstoincludethespeakerandmajorityandminorityleaders.Theidentitiesofpartyleadersandcommitteechairswereobtainedthroughcontactswithlegislativestaffsandvariousissuesofstatelegislativebluebooksandjournals.Theexistingliteraturesuggestsmemberswhogainacommitteechairorwhoareelectedtoatopleadershippostwillseebiggerincreasesincampaigncontributions,allelsebeingequal(Francis1989;CoxandMagar1999).

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 135 4/7/09 4:23:34 PM

Previousresearchsuggestsanumberofadditionalvariableslikelytobepertinentindeterminingtheamountofcampaigncontributionsraisedbyindividualincumbentlegislators.Inordertotestourhypotheses,weneedtocontrolforthesefactors.Amongothers,largercampaigncontributionsareknowntobelinkedtolegislatorpreferences,favorablecommitteeassign-ments,andelectoralsafety(JonesandBorris1985;GrierandMunger1993;ThielemannandDixon1994). Dataavailabilityprecludestheinclusionoflegislatorpreferences.Asofyet,preferencemeasuresofstatelegislators(cf.DW-Nominatescores)arenotreadilyavailablefortheyearsincludedinourstudy.Givenouruseofalongitudinalmodel,however,itisunlikelythattheabsenceofsuchameasurewouldsystematicallybiasourresultssincethereisnoreasontoexpectthatlegislatorpreferenceschangemuchoveraspanofjusttwoelectioncycles. Wedoincludemeasuresforservingondesirablecommittees.Scholarsandobserversofstatelegislaturesgenerallyagreethataseatonakeypolicyorcontrolcommitteequalifiesassuchanassignment.Themostwidelycitedexamplesofeachtypearefiscalandrulescommittees(Francis1989;Rosen-thal2004;Wright2005).Fiscalcommitteesshapepublicpolicybydecidingwhichgovernmentprogramsreceivefundingandhowthecostsofthoseprogramsaretobedistributed.Membersofthesecommitteesarealsowellsituatedtosupplytargetedbenefits,suchasindustry-specifictaxbreaks.Rulescommitteeshelpthechamberleadershipcontrolthelegislativeagendabydeterminingwhichbillsandamendmentsareallowedonthechamberfloor.Bothtypesofcommitteesreceiveagreatdealofattentionfromlobbyistsandaffordmembersexcellentopportunitiestoprovidelegislativeservicestoorganizedinterests. Beyondfiscalcommittees,however,littlesystematicstudyisavailableatthestatelevelonthedesirabilityofotherpolicycommittees(JewellandWhicker1994).Inlightofthis,weemploywhatwebelievetobeadefensiblemethodofsystematicallyidentifyingthosecommitteesthatmightaffordmemberssomeofthebestopportunitiestoprovidevaluablelegislativeser-vices.WedothisusingreportsfromtheInstituteonMoneyinStatePoli-tics.Accordingtothese,theeconomicsectorswithlargestcontributionstostatelegislativecampaignsaretheFIRE(finance,insurance,andrealestate)andhealthcaresectors(O’Connell2004;Weiss2006).Thus,weconsideralegislatorservingononeofthesecommitteestoalsobeonanimportantpolicymakingcommittee. Foreachstateinoursample,wehaveidentifiedthefiscalandrulescom-mitteesaswellasthosethathavejurisdictionovertheFIREandhealthcaresectors.Tocapturechangingmembershiponthesecommittees,wehave

136 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 136 4/7/09 4:23:34 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 137

createdfourvariables.Eachisoperationalizedtrichotomouslyinthesamemannerasthevariablesdiscussedabove.Avalueof1denotesamemberwhogainedanassignmentonacommittee,–1denotesalegislatorwholostoneoftheseassignments,and0denotesnochange.TheonlymodificationmadetothisapproachisintheanalysisoftheTexasHouse.Inthiscase,themodelincludesavariabletocapturemembershiponthecommitteeresponsibleforregulatingtheoilandnaturalgasindustries.TheenergysectorinTexasisalsoalargedonortostatelegislativeraces,makingserviceonthiscommit-teeaplumassignment.Legislatorswhojoinavaluablecommitteemightseelargerincreasesincampaigncontributionsthanthosewhodonot. Lastly,weincludealaggedmeasureofelectoralvulnerability.Tocalcu-latethismeasure,wetakethedifferenceofacandidate’sloggedvotesharesfromthepriortwoelections.8Thedatausedtocreatethismeasureweregenerouslyprovidedbyvarioussecretariesofstate.Existingresearchinstatepolitics(c.f.,JonesandBorris1985)hasshownthatorganizedinterestsinstatelegislativeelectionstendtotargettheirdonationstoincumbentswhoarelikelytoretaintheirseats,suggestingthatelectoralsafetyshouldleadtohigherdonations,especiallyoncepartycontributionshavebeenremoved.

results

Webeginbytestingthepartisanandbipartisanhypotheses.Todoso,weestimateourmodelseparatelyforeachstateinoursample.Thefirstsetsoffindings—theeffectsofachangeinmajoritystatusonthetotalcontributionsraised—arereportedinTable2andTable3.Thedependentvariableisthechangeintheamountofcampaigncontributionsinconstantdollarsraisedbyagivenincumbentlegislatoracrosstwoconsecutiveelectioncycles.Theindependentvariablesarechangesinthestatusofthelegislatorthattakeplaceovertheperiodexamined,includinggainorlossofmajoritystatus,partyleadershippositions,committeechairmanships,andmembershipsonpotentiallyimportantpolicycommittees. Table2reportstheresultsfortheprocedurallypartisanchambersinoursample:Georgia,Illinois,Indiana,NewJersey,andOklahoma.9Ineachestima-tion,thecoefficienton∆MajorityStatus,whichcapturesthevalueofservinginthemajorityinsteadoftheminorityparty,ispositiveandsignificantatthe95or90percentlevel(usingaone-tailedtest).10Theseresultsareconsistentwiththepartisanhypothesis.Thegainofmajoritystatusbyalegislatorinaprocedurallypartisanchamberleadstoastatisticallysignificantincreaseinthereceiptsofcampaigncontributions.Theestimatedvalueofservinginthe

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 137 4/7/09 4:23:35 PM

majoritypartyinoneofthesechambersrangesfromwellover$10,000inIndianatoalmost$35,000inGeorgia,withtheaveragevalueacrossallfivestatesequaling$20,622. Surprisingly,almostnoneoftheremainingexplanatoryvariablesroutinelyexhibitastatisticallymeaningfuleffectoncontributions.Thevariablecaptur-ingchangeinpartyleadershiphasapositiveandlargecoefficientinallbutonecase,butitonlyobtainsstatisticalsignificanceintheGeorgiaHousewherealeadershippositionisworthover$150,000inadditionalcampaigncontribu-tions.Thesignsontheremainingtermsareinconsistentacrosschambersandrarelystatisticallysignificant.Manyofthesecoefficientsshould,however,betreatedwithcaution.Rarelydochangesintheoccupantsofformalpositionsoccuracrosstwoelectionscycles,particularlyinthecaseoftoppartyleaders,whichmakesaccurateestimationofeffectsdifficultandincreasesthelikeli-

Table 2. ChangeinTotalContributionstoIncumbentLegislators:ProcedurallyParti-sanChambers

New Georgia Illinois Indiana Jersey Oklahoma Pooled

ΔMajorityStatus 34,794* 26,597* 10,578* 12,649# 18,494* 0.26* (9,274) (17,987) (3,605) (8,699) (9,112) (0.05)ΔPartyLeader 154,930* 18,225 12,897 -103,901 74,056 0.16 (81,130) (15,801) (15,896) (6,880) (82,686) (0.46)ΔCommitteeChair 7,058 –3,445 –92 10,546 –7,275 –0.01 (9,837) (17,987) (4,389) (12,627) (8,729) (0.06)ΔFiscalCommittee –13,877 –441 –5,708 13,683 –621 –0.08 (8,134) (6,434) (4,254) (17,568) (5,692) (0.06)ΔRulesCommittee 890 22,219 –3,337 9,468 43,559* 0.05 (12,267) (24,120) (4,870) (7,857) (21,006) (0.10)ΔFIRECommittee 2,364 –20,468 –507 5,515 –12,303 –0.05 (8,816) (19,212) (3,765) (17,479) (9,312) (0.06)ΔHealthcareCommittee 12,769 –3,965 –3,207 –1,634 –3,575 0.02 (16,374) (7,521) (6,289) (16,572) (19,993) (0.12)ΔLaggedVote 12,056 37,955 7,262 –14,308 42,997* 0.31* (15,014) (39,757) (5,997) (28,448) (13,325) (0.13)Constant –362 –18,827 14,517 5,588 –8,310 0.13 (4,289) (8,212) (4,035) (5,186) (4,472) (0.07)N 243 178 298 105 106 932R2 0.28 0.05 0.14 0.29 0.32 0.07FStatistic 6.91 0.89 4.68 412.31 3.51 5.41

*p<0.05;#p<0.10;one-tailedtestNotes:Thedependentvariableisthechangeintotalcontributionsraisedbyindividualincumbentlegislatorsacross

twoelectioncycles.AllmodelsareestimatedusingOLSandrobuststandarderrors.Electioncycledummiesareincludedbutnotreportedhere.Thepooledmodelutilizesdatafromallstateswithprocedurallypartisanlegislaturesandincludesbothelectionyearandstatedummyvariables.Thedependentvariableinthepooledmodelisthechangeintotalstandardizedcampaigncontributions.

138 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 138 4/7/09 4:23:35 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 139

hoodthattheresultsaredrivenbytheidiosyncraticcharacteristicsofthelegislatorswhoexperiencedthestatuschange.11

Toaddressthispossibility,weestimateamodelinwhichthedataforallprocedurallypartisanstatesarepooled.Bycombiningdataforallofthesechambers,wecanlimittheinfluenceofidiosyncraticfactorsandpotentiallyobtainmoreaccuratecoefficientestimates.Therearealsotheoreticalreasonstobelievethatpoolingisappropriate.Intheprecedingsection,wearguethatallprocedurallypartisanchambersaredrivenbythesameorganizingprinciple,eveniftheymightdifferinsignificantwaysfromprocedurallybipartisanchambers.ThisissupportedbythefindingspresentedinTable2thatsuggestthatthedeterminantsofcampaigncontributionsacrossoursam-pleofprocedurallypartisanchambersarequitesimilar.Inordertoanalyzethepooleddata,westandardizethedependentvariable.Foreachchamber-electioncycle,wesubtractmeantotalcontributionsfromeachlegislator’stotalanddividebythesamplestandarddeviation.Asaresult,contributionsforeachchamber-electioncycle,canbeconsidereddrawnfromthestandardnormaldistributionandcanbecomparedacrosscases.12Thecoefficientsontheexplanatoryvariablesnowindicatethechangeinstandardizedcampaigncontributionsthataccompanyastatuschange.Forexample,acoefficientofonemeansthataone-unitchangeintheexplanatoryvariableleadstoaonestandarddeviationincreaseincampaigncontributions. TheresultsofthisnewestimationarereportedinthelastcolumnofTable2.Onceagain,wefindstrongsupportforthepartisanhypothesis.ThecoefficientonΔMajorityStatusispositiveandsignificantatp=0.95.Themagnitudeofthecoefficientindicatesthatgainingmajoritystatusresultsina.26standarddeviationincreaseintotalcontributions,ceterisparibus.13Theimportanceofthemajoritystatusinprocedurallypartisanchambersisfurtherillustratedbystandardizedregressioncoefficients(notreportedhere).Theserevealthatmajoritystatushas,byfar,thelargestrelativeimpactonchangesincampaigncontributions. Table3displaystheresultsofourestimationsfortheproceduralbipar-tisancases,TexasandVermont,andtheintermediatecase,Colorado.Thelasttwocolumnsshowpooledestimations.SinceColoradodoesnothavearulescommittee,werunthepooledmodeltwice,onceincludingchangeinmembershiponarulescommittee(andwithoutColorado)andonceexclud-ingthisvariable(andincludingColorado).Allofthesenewestimationsareconsistentwiththebipartisanhypothesis.Thegainofmajoritystatusinthesechambersleadstonostatisticallysignificantincreaseincontributions.Ineachofthesechambers(andinthepooledmodel),thecoefficientonΔMajority

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 139 4/7/09 4:23:35 PM

Statusissmallandnegative.Combinedwithourearlierresults,thesefindingssuggestthatproceduralpartisanshipisnecessaryforensuringthevalueofmajoritystatus. Unlikeintheprocedurallypartisanchambers,manyofthecontrolvari-ablesareimportantpredictorsofcontributions.Inallthreechambers,lead-ershipstatusisquitevaluable,reachingoveronemilliondollarsintheTexasHouse.14Additionally,inColoradoandTexas,gainingmembershiponkeycommitteesresultsinasignificantincreaseincampaigncontributions.ThevaluablecommitteesinColoradoappeartobethefiscalandFIREcommit-tees,whileinTexastheyarethosethataddressthehealthcareandtheenergysectors.Texaslegislatorsalsoseeasignificantincreaseincontributionsupongainingacommitteechairmanship.Inbothpooledmodels,however,onlythevariablesfortoppartyleaders,committeechairs,andelectoralsafetyhave

Table 3. ChangeinTotalContributionstoIncumbentLegislators:ProcedurallyBipar-tisanChambers

Colorado Texas Vermont Pooled Pooled

ΔMajorityStatus –2,498 –209 –204 –0.09 –0.07 (2,477) (11,363) (184) (0.06) (0.07)ΔPartyLeader 6,656# 1,077,719* 1,304* 0.99* 1.49* (4,411) (252,942) (373) (0.41 (0.55)ΔCommitteeChair –1,243 25,239* –153 0.14# 0.13# (4,500) (14,859) (383) (0.08 (0.09)ΔFiscalCommittee 4,112# –15,187 –665 –0.04 –0.13 (3,066) (14,533) (357) (0.08) (0.08)ΔRulesCommittee __ 2,609 –412 __ –0.21 (14,833) (586) (0.16)ΔFIRECommittee 5,884* 16,146 –156 0.12 –0.13 (2,770) (19,569) (786) (0.18) (0.25)ΔHealthcareCommittee –4,081 35,524# –473 0.14 –0.01 (1,952) (24,519) (982) (0.16) (0.16)ΔOilCommittee __ 23,668# __ __ __ (14,833)ΔLaggedVote 5,140 13,666 900* 0.60 0.56* (5,834) (30,707) (445) (0.17) (0.18)Constant 9,772 19,977 1,201 –0.02 –0.01 (3,041) (6,810) (202) (0.19) (0.02)N 46 224 140 410 364R2 0.25 0.57 0.31 0.08 0.09FStatistic 5.03 3.39 19.43 3.25 2.96

*p<0.05;#p<0.10;one-tailedtestsNotes:Thedependentvariableisthechangeintotalcontributionsraisedbyindividualincumbentlegislatorsacross

twoelectioncycles.AllmodelsareestimatedusingOLSandrobuststandarderrors.Electioncycledummiesareincludedbutnotreportedhere.Thepooledmodelsutilizedatafromallstateswithprocedurallybipartisanlegislaturesandincludebothelectionyearandstatedummyvariables.Thedependentvariableinthepooledmodelisthechangeintotalstandardizedcampaigncontributions.

140 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 140 4/7/09 4:23:35 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 141

astatisticallymeaningfuleffect.Standardizedregressioncoefficientsforthepooledmodels(notreportedhere)indicatethatthelargestrelativeimpactoncampaigncontributionscomesfromchangesinchamberleadershippositions(andchangesinelectoralsafety),whiletheeffectfromthechangeinmajoritystatusisnegligible.Overall,thedissimilaritybetweentheresultsinTables2and3stronglysuggeststhatchambergovernanceinprocedurallypartisanchambersisverydifferentfromthosethatarenot.15Indeed,thelargepre-miumsthataccompanybothchamberleadershipandcommitteechairmanstatusunderscoretheirimportanceintheprocedurallybipartisanlegislaturesandsuggestthatthesechambersoperateinatop-downmanner. Whiletheresultspresentedthusfarindicatethatthemajoritypartypre-miumsaremuchlargerinprocedurallypartisanchambersthanthosethatarenot,theresultsdonotindicatewhethertheseobserveddifferencesacrosschambertypesarestatisticallymeaningful.Totestforthispossibility,weconductstatisticaltestsacrossourestimations.Specifically,wecomparethecoefficientonΔMajorityStatusfromeachofthechambersthatisprocedur-allybipartisan(thestatesinTable2)tothecoefficientfromeachchamberthatisprocedurallypartisan(thestatesinTable3). Duetospacelimitations,wedonotreportthespecificsofthesetestshere.Nonetheless,theyprovidefurthersupportforourfirsttwohypotheses.Wefindthatthevalueofmajoritystatusinalloftheprocedurallypartisanchambersissignificantlygreater(atp=0.95or0.90usingaone-tailedtest)thanitisinColoradoandVermont.WealsofindthatthevalueofmajoritystatusintheGeorgia,Oklahoma,Illinois,andIndianaHousesisstatisticallylargerthanintheTexasHouse,althoughthedifferencebetweenthevalueintheNewJerseyandTexasHousesfallsshortofstatisticalsignificance. Aretheseresultsdrivenbyvariationsinlegislativeprofessionalizationandcampaignfinanceregimes?Itdoesnotseemtobethecase.Thevalueofmajoritystatusisnotcorrelatedwithprofessionalization.Wefindevidenceofamajoritypartypremiuminprofessional(IllinoisandNewJersey),semi-pro-fessional(Oklahoma),andcitizenlegislatures(IndianaandGeorgia).Therealsoappearstobenoconsistentrelationshipwithstatecampaignfinanceregimes.Wefindmajoritystatustobevaluableinstateswithverypermissivecampaignfinancelaws(IllinoisandIndiana),aswellasinthosewithmorestringentregulations(NewJerseyandGeorgia). Overall,thesefindingssuggesttwodistinctmodesoflegislativegovernancestructures,dependingonwhetherthemajoritypartymonopolizeschamberleadershippositionsandtheagenda.Theprocedurallypartisanformgeneratesapositivevalueformajoritypartymembership.Theprocedurallybipartisanformdoesnotgenerateapositivevaluemerelyformajoritypartymembership,

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 141 4/7/09 4:23:36 PM

althoughitdoesappeartoenhancethevalueofcertainprivilegedpositionsalongthelegislativeprocess. Havingestablishedthatmajoritystatusisvaluableinprocedurallypar-tisanlegislatures,weinvestigatehowthisvalueisdistributedamongmajor-itypartymembers.Dopartyleadersandchairmenreceivethebulkofthebenefits,assuggestedbytheleadershiphypothesis,orarebenefitssharedbroadlythroughouttheparty,asperthecaucushypothesis? Toevaluatetheleadershipandcaucushypothesesfully,weneedtointeractourvariablethatcapturesachangeinmajoritystatuswithtermsthatindicatealegislator’sotherpositionswithinthechamber.Forinstance,ifwewanttocomparehowpartyleadersbenefitfromachangeinmajoritystatusrelativetotheirco-partisanswhoserveonafiscalcommittee,weneedtointeractdummyvariablesindicatingpartyleadershipstatusandserviceonarevenueorexpenditurescommitteewithΔMajorityStatus. Inthenextestimationofourmodel,weagainpoolthedataforalloftheprocedurallypartisanchambers,butnowweinteractΔMajorityStatuswithdummiesindicatingwhetheralegislatorisapartyleader,servesonafiscal,FIRE,rules,orhealthcarecommittee,andwiththevariableΔCommitteeChair.Wealsoincludethenecessarybaseterms.Thenewinteractionsmeanthatthecoefficientonthestand-aloneindicatorforchangeinmajoritystatusnowmeasurestheaveragepremiumreceivedbymajority-partybackbencherswhoarenotonanyimportantpolicyorcontrolcommittees,ratherthanthepremiumenjoyedcollectivelybyallmajoritypartymembers.Theremaininginteractiontermsthenallowustoestimateseparatelythemajoritypremiumsenjoyedbytoppartyleaders,committeechairs,andbackbenchersservingonkeycommittees. TheresultsofthisnewestimationarereportedinTable4.16Toproperlyinterpretthecoefficientsonthenewinteractiontermsandtocomparethesetoourbaselinecategory,wecalculatemarginaleffectsasrecommendedbyBrambor,Clark,andGolder(2006).TheresultsarereportedinTable5.Thesecondcolumnofthetableshows,byformalposition,theincreaseincontri-butionsformembersofthenewmajorityparty.17Thethirdcolumnreportsthedifferencesbetweenthechangesincontributionsreceivedbybackbench-ersnotservingonakeycommitteeandlegislatorswithvariousprivilegedpositionsandwhetherthesedifferencesarestatisticallysignificant. ThefirstrowofTable5showsthatbackbenchersnotservingonafiscal,rules,FIRE,orhealthcarecommitteeenjoy,onaverage,a.11standarddevia-tionincreaseintotalcampaigncontributions.Thisincreasefallsjustshortofreachingstatisticalsignificanceusingatwo-tailedtest,althoughitissignifi-cant(atp=0.90)usingaone-tailedtest.Importantly,itsuggeststhatthevalue

142 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 142 4/7/09 4:23:36 PM

Table 4. ChangeinTotalContributionstoIncumbentLegislators:ProcedurallyPartisanChambers(PooledData)

ΔMajorityStatus 0.11 (0.07)ΔPartyLeader –0.70 (0.53)PartyLeader 0.78# (0.46)PartyLeader*ΔMajorityStatus 0.59 (0.39)ΔCommitteeChair 0.02 (0.06)ΔCommitteeChair*ΔMajorityStatus 0.06 (0.07)ΔFiscalCommittee –0.13# (0.07)FiscalCommittee 0.11# (0.06)FiscalCommittee*ΔMajorityStatus 0.15# (0.08)ΔRulesCommittee 0.01 (0.10)RulesCommittee 0.02 (0.11)RulesCommittee*ΔMajorityStatus 0.24* (0.12)ΔFIRECommittee –0.07 (0.08)FIRECommittee 0.03 (0.07)FIRECommittee*ΔMajorityStatus 0.16* (0.08)ΔHealthcareCommittee 0.05 (0.12)HealthcareCommittee 0.01 (0.08)HealthcareCommittee*ΔMajorityStatus –0.12 (0.11)ΔLaggedVote 0.34* (0.12)Constant –0.07 (0.11)N 932R2 0.11FStatistic 4.70

*p<0.05;#p<0.10;two-tailedtestsNotes:Thedependentvariableisthechangeintotalstandardizedcampaigncontribu-

tionsraisedbyanincumbentlegislator.ThemodelisestimatedusingOLSandrobuststandarderrors.Electioncycleandstatedummiesareincludedbutnotreportedhere.

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 143 4/7/09 4:23:36 PM

ofmajoritystatusiswidelydistributedwithinthepartyandnotnecessarilycontingentuponholdingaprivilegedpositioninthelegislativechamber. Theresultsinthebottomfourrowssuggestasimilarconclusion.Back-benchersservingonkeypolicyandcontrolcommitteesconsistentlyseetheircampaigncontributionsincreasebymeaningfulamountsupongainingmajoritystatus.Backbencherswithaseatonarulescommitteeseea.38standarddeviationincreaseintotalcontributions,whilethoseservingonafiscalorFIREcommitteereceiveincreasesof.37and.31,respectively.Alltheseincreasesarestatisticallysignificantatp=0.95usingatwo-tailedtest.Intheprocedurallypartisanchambersincludedinouranalysis,many,ifnotmost,membersofthemajoritycaucusserveonatleastoneofthesethreetypesofcommittees.Forexample,intheGeorgiaHouse,approximately40percentofmajoritypartymembersserveononeofthechamber’stwofiscalcommittees.Whileserviceonakeypolicymakingcommitteeclearlyenhancesthevalueofmajoritystatus,thisenhancementissharedbroadlywithinthepartyanddoesnotfallexclusivelytocommitteechairsasthelead-ershiphypothesissuggests.Equallyasimportant,thecoefficientsonchange

Table 5. AverageIncreaseinContributionsFollowingaGainofMajorityStatus:ProcedurallyPartisanChambers(PooledData)

IncreaseRelative toBackbenchers Increasein whoGained Contributions MajorityStatus

Gainmajoritystatus(backbenchers) 0.11## __ (0.08)Gainmajoritystatuswhileservingasatoppartyleader 1.49* 1.38* (0.61) (0.61)GainMajorityStatus&GainChairmanship 0.20* 0.08 (0.08) (0.11)GainMajorityStatuswhileservingonrulescommittee 0.38* 0.27 (0.16) (0.16)GainMajorityStatuswhileservingonfiscalcommittee 0.37* 0.26* (0.08) (0.10)GainMajorityStatuswhileservingonFIREcommittee 0.31* 0.20# (0.14) (0.12)GainMajorityStatuswhileservingonHealthcarecommittee –0.01 –0.12 (0.14) (0.14)

*p<0.05;#p<0.10;two-tailedtests##p<0.10usingaone-tailedtestNotes:Thesecondcolumnshowsthestandarddeviationincreaseincampaigncontributions,byformalpositioninthe

legislature,followingagaininmajoritystatus.Thefinalcolumnshowswhetherthisvalueissignificantlydifferentfromthechangeexperiencedbybackbencherswithoutassignmentsonkeypolicyorcontrolcommittees.Forinstance,thefourthrowshowsthatlegislatorswhogainmajoritystatuswhileservingonarulescommitteeenjoya.38standarddeviationincreaseintotalcontributions.Standarderrorsarereportedinparentheses.

144 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 144 4/7/09 4:23:37 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 145

incommitteeassignmentandonourstand-alonemeasuresofcommitteemembership(seeTable4)arealmostalwaysstatisticallyinsignificant.Thisfindingindicatesthatservingonanimportantpolicyorcontrolcommitteewithoutbeinginthemajoritymightnotbeparticularlyvaluable.Inotherwords,committeemembershipismuchmorevaluableformajoritypartymembersthanfortheminority. TheresultspresentedinTable5alsoshowthatthemajoritypartypremiumisdistributedtolawmakerswhooccupyprivilegedpositionsinthechamber.Toppartyleadersseetheircampaigncontributionsrisebyawhopping1.49standarddeviationswhentheirpartygainsmajoritystatus.Thisincreaseismuchlargerthanthatenjoyedbythetypicalbackbencher.Lawmakerswhogainbothachairmanshipandmajoritystatusseetheircontributionsriseby.20standarddeviation.Whilethisincreaseissignificant,itisnotstatisticallylargerthanthepremiumincontributionsenjoyedbybackbenchers—eitherthosewithorwithoutanassignmentonakeypolicyorcontrolcommittee.18Interestingly,thepremiumenjoyedbythosewhogainachairmanshipinconjunctionwithmajoritystatusis,onaverage,smallerthanthatenjoyedbybackbenchersonafiscal,rules,orFIREcommittee,althoughthesedifferencesarenotstatisticallymeaningful. Overall,theresultsreportedinTable5providestrongsupportforthecaucushypothesis.Thepremiumincampaigncontributionsenjoyedbythemajoritypartyisnotdistributedprincipallyamongthosewithprivilegedpositionsinthelegislature,butratherissharedwidelyamongthemajoritypartymembership.Backbenchers(thosewithandwithoutkeyassignments),toppartyleaders,andcommitteechairsallbenefit.Nevertheless,importantcaveatsdoemerge.First,whilebenefitsaredistributedwidely,toppartylead-ersseethelargesttotalincreaseintotalcampaigncontributions.Second,thevalueofbackbencherstatuswithinthemajoritypartyvariessubstantiallyasafunctionofalawmaker’scommitteeassignments.Changeinthemajoritystatusbyitself,withoutmembershiponakeypolicyorcontrolcommittee,confersarelativelysmallandstatisticallyinconsistentincreaseincampaigncontributions.Serviceonapowerfulcommittee,inconjunctionwithmajor-itystatus,offersmuchlargerandmorerobustincreases.Thelargesizeofthemajoritypartycontingentsonsuchcommittees,however,meansthatthesecommittee-basedpremiumsaresharedbroadlythroughouttheparty. Beforeconcluding,weshouldnotethatthenatureofourresearchdesignlimitsoursampletolegislativechamberswhereboththeDemocraticandRepublicanpartiesarecompetitive.Forsomereaders,thismayimplythatthenecessaryconditionsforvaluablemajoritypartystatusincludenotonlyproceduralpartisanship,butalsoacompetitivetwopartysystem.Wedonot

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 145 4/7/09 4:23:37 PM

believethistobethecase.AsThompson,Cassie,andJewell(1994)note,legisla-tivepartiesseektomaximizetheirchamberseatshare.Asaresult,itisunlikelythatevenapartythatenjoysaverysizablemajoritywouldstoprewardingtheloyaltyoftheirbackbenchers.Notonlyaredefectionstotheminoritypartyembarrassing,butgiventheunpredictablenatureofpolitics,thereisnoreasonforthecurrentmajoritynottozealouslyguardeachseat.

implications

Inthisarticle,wehavedevelopedatheoryofwhatdetermineswhethermajor-itystatusisvaluableinalegislatureandhowthatvalueisdistributedwithinthemajorityparty.Wefindthatthevalueofmajoritystatusinstatelegisla-turesissensitivetotheparticularsofchamberorganization.Servinginthemajorityisvaluableonlyifthechamberisprocedurallypartisan.Thatis,itisvaluableifeverypathforabillthroughthelegislativeprocessandeverypathforindividuallegislatorstoadvancethroughthechamber’sleadershiphierarchyisconstrainedtoliewithinthemajorityparty.Ontheotherhand,ifthelegislatureisorganizedinaprocedurallybipartisanfashion,themajoritypartyceasestobe“theonlygameintown,”andthevalueofmajoritystatusfallsstatisticallytozero.Inthesechambers,themembersoftheorganizingcoalitionarescatteredacrosspartylinesandthebenefitstheyaccruedonotcoincidewithserviceinanyparticularpoliticalparty. Inthosechamberswheremajoritystatusisvaluable,alargeproportionofthisvaluefallstobackbenchers.Beingamajoritypartybackbencherissufficienttoconferapremiumincampaigncontributions,althoughthedistributionofthesebenefitsfavorsbackbenchersonimportantpolicyorcontrolcommittees.Nonetheless,occupyingaleadershippositioninthelegislativehierarchyisnoguaranteeofanadditionalpremium.Someposts,suchastoppartyleadership,conferalargebonuswhileothers,suchascommitteechairmanships,donot.Thissuggestsaredistributivemechanismisatworkwithinthemajorityparty,throughwhichtheleadersareworkingnotonlyforthemselvesbutalsofortheirfellowco-partisanswithlessformalpowersandprivileges.Wespeculatethatthisinternalcooperationisengenderedandfacilitatedbythecaucuspro-cess,whichprovidesavenueforintra-partycommunicationandbargaining,makingiteasiertoarrangePareto-improvingtradeswithinthemajorityparty.Theconsequentboostinthevalueofmajoritystatushelpsundergirdpartygovernmentinprocedurallypartisanlegislatures. Thefindingspresentedherehaveimportantimplicationsforourunder-standingofpolicymakinginstatelegislatures.Theysuggestthat,inpro-cedurallypartisanassemblies(i.e.,thevastmajorityofstatelegislatures),

146 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 146 4/7/09 4:23:37 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 147

majoritypartybackbenchersexertsubstantialinformalinfluenceonthepolicymakingprocessandderivesubstantialbenefits—intermsofcam-paigncontributions—evenwithlimitedformalpowers.Insuchchambers,wesuspectabottom-upprocessprevails,perhapsthroughthemajoritypartycaucus,andresultingpolicyoutcomesshouldbroadlyreflecttheinterestsofmajoritypartymembers.Thesamecannotbesaidforprocedur-allybipartisanlegislatures.Inthese,thelociofkeypolicydecisionsappeartolieoutsidethemajoritypartycaucusandinthehandsoftopleadersandcommitteechairswhomaybeagentsofacross-partygoverningcoalition.Policymakinginthesechambersisnotlikelytoreflectthatoftheentiremajorityparty. Whymightsomestatesadoptandmaintainaproceduralbipartisanstruc-tureoverthepartisanvariant?Basedonourunderstandingofthecasesweexamine,theredoesnotappeartobeasingle,simpleanswertothispuzzle.Potentialanswersmightincludepasthistoryaswellasvarioushistorical“acci-dents”ofleadershipandothereventsthatmarkinstitutionaldevelopmentsinthesestates.Forexample,VermontandTexasshareahistoryoflongperiodsofsinglepartydominance,coupledwithperiodsofhighlypersonalisticleg-islativeleadership.Regardless,theexactrolesplayedbypasteventsinshapingtheinstitutionsinthesechambersremainbeyondthescopeofthisarticle,butcertainlywarrantfurtherstudy. Ourfindingssuggestthatsustainablepartygovernmentinstatelegislaturesdependsontheinteractionbetweentheformalrulesandinstitutionsandtheinformaldistributionofbenefits.Maintainingformalmechanismsofmajoritypartyinfluenceispredicatedonspreadingitsfruitswidelyamongitsmem-bers,eveniftheydonotholdformalpowers.Putdifferently,successfulpartygovernmentrestsoncreatingpositivevalueforthebackbenchers,notsimplymonopolizingallagenda-settingpowerinthehandsofthemajorityparty.

endnotes

Fortheirhelpfulcomments,wewouldliketothankGaryCox,AndrewGelman,GaryJacobson,andGeraldWright.Forinvaluableassistancegatheringdata,wealsothankRachelWeissoftheNationalInstituteonMoneyinStatePolitics,numerousstatelegisla-tiveaides,andourresearchassistantBrittanyBrewer.

1.Forthesakeofsimplicity,weusetheterm“backbencher”torefertolawmakerswhodonotoccupyformalleadershippositionsinthelegislativehierarchy. 2.Membersofthecross-partygoverningcoalitioninprocedurallybipartisanchambersmayraisemoreincampaigncontributionsthanthenon-members.Determiningthemem-bershipofsuchcoalitionsis,however,difficultandbeyondthescopeofthisarticle. 3.Informalmechanismsmightalsoexist,suchasthosebasedonapersonalrelation-

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 147 4/7/09 4:23:37 PM

shipbetweentheleadersandbackbenchers.Thekeyremainsthattheserelationshipsareinternaltothemajorityparty. 4.Formoststates,thisdataisnotsystematicallyavailableuntilthemid-orlate-1990s. 5.Oursampleconstitutesanearlyexhaustivesetofstatelowerhousesthatunderwentoneormorechangesinpartisancontrolbetween1994and2004forwhichcampaignfinancedataanddataforourcontrolvariableswerereadilyavailable.Ahandfulofstates,includingWashington(1994),Michigan(1996),andMissouri(2002),wereexcludedbecausetherecentpartisanchangesintheselegislaturescoincidedwiththeeffectivedateoftermlimitlaws,leavingtoofewincumbentsforameaningfulanalysis. 6.Forthepurposesofthisarticle,weexpresslyrequirethataprocedurallypartisanchamberfeature:(1)majoritypartymonopolyofthespeakership;(2)majoritypartymonopolyofthechairmanshipsofallstandingcommitteesotherthanethics;and(3)thatthemajoritypartyoccupyamajorityoftheseatsonallstandingcommitteesotherthanethics.Formostlegislatures,theseconditionssufficetogivethemajoritypartymonopolycontrolofthelegislativeagenda.Usingthesecriteria,thechambersexaminedinthisarticlefallneatlyintotwodistinctgroups,withoneexception.IntheColoradoHouse,themajorityparty,despitecontrollingallformalleversofpower,isunabletomonopolizethelegislativeagendaduetoaconstitutionalamendment.Informationusedtocategorizestateswasobtainedthroughanexaminationoftheexistingliterature,legislativejournalsandrules,andconsultationswithlegislativestaff. 7.Thesechambersalsovarysubstantiallyintermsofspeakerandcommitteepowers(c.f.,Clucas2001;Hamm,Hedlund,andMartorano2006).Variationsinthevalueofmajoritystatusdonotappeartodependonthesefactors. 8.ΔLaggedElectoralSafety=log(Percentt–2)–log(Percentt–1),wherePercenttistheshareofthevoteobtainedbytheincumbentinanelectionyeart.Therearetwoinstanceswhenaredistrictingyearintervenesbetweentheelectionsusedtocreateourmeasure(thesubstantivecaseinTexasandacontrolcaseinIndiana,bothfollowingthe2000census).Unfortunately,thiscannotberectifiedduetodataunavailability.Wedonotbelievethatthishasameaningfuleffectonourresults.Estimationsthatexcludethelaggedelectoralsafetyvariableyieldcomparableresults. 9.TheestimationforIndianausesthreeinstancesofpartisanchangeandacontrolcase.Ifestimatedseparately,changeinmajoritystatusisstatisticallysignificantineachinstance. 10.Becausewemakedirectionalpredictionsforeachofourexplanatoryvariables,weemployone-tailedtestsofstatisticalsignificance.However,thevalueofmajoritystatusissignificantusingatwo-tailedtestinallprocedurallypartisanstatesexceptNewJersey.Observethatnocoefficientonavariableofinterestcanbenegativeandsignificantbecauseallofourdirectionalpredictionsarepositive. 11.Forinstance,thelargenegativecoefficientonthechangeinpartyleadershipstatusinNewJerseyisattributabletoAlbioSires.AssemblymanSireswentfromDemocraticbackbenchertospeakerbetweenthe2000–01and2002–03sessions.Forthe2001elec-tion,heraisedwellover$265,000,butforthe2003election,heraisedonly$83,000.NewJerseyalsofeaturesanegativecoefficientonthelaggedelectoralsafetyvariable.Thisrepresentstheonlynegativecoefficientonthisvariableamongallourcases,butitfailstoevenapproachstatisticalsignificance. 12.Thestandardizedcontributionisthus

(cij – μij )

ρijkij=

148 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 148 4/7/09 4:23:38 PM

summer 2009 / state politics and policy quarterly 149

andkij~N(0,1),wheremijisthesamplemeanandrijisthesamplestandarddeviation,forchamberiandelectioncyclej. 13.Surprisingly,severalcoefficientsonthevariablescapturingchangesinassignmentstokeycommitteesarenegative.Wesuspectthatthismighthavetodowithpoliticsofcommitteeassignment,specifically,whichlegislatorslosemembershipinthesecommitteeswhenapartylosesmajoritystatusandwhichgainnewseatsonthesecommitteeswhenapartywinsthemajority.Suchquestions,however,arebeyondthescopeofthisarticle. 14.SincetheonlypartyleaderintheTexasHouseofRepresentativesisthespeaker,ΔPartyLeaderreducestoameasureofmovementintoandoutofthespeakership. 15.OurresultsforTexasareconsistentwiththoseinThielemannandDixon’s(1994)studyofcampaigncontributionsintheTexasHouseinthe1988–89period.Theyfindthatbeinginthemajoritypartygeneratednoadditionalcontributions,butmembers’institutionalpositionsdid. 16.Weuseatwo-tailedtestforthissectionbecausetheleadershipandcaucushypoth-esesyieldpotentiallyconflictingpredictions. 17.Theseestimatesarecalculatedbysimplyaddingthecoefficientsonanyrelevantterms.Forexample,tocalculatetheincreaseincontributionsenjoyedbymemberswhogainmajoritystatuswhileservingonafiscalcommittee,weaddΔMajorityStatus(.11)toFiscalCommittee(.11)andΔMajorityStatus*FiscalCommittee(.15). 18.Thelackofbenefitsaccompanyingcommitteechairmanshipsdoesraiseaninterestingquestion:Whydolegislatorsseekchairmanships?Itmaybethattheyaremotivatedbydesireforgoodpublicpolicyorthattheypossessexpertiseinapolicyarea.Also,byrenderingservicetotheirco-partisans,committeechairsmayaccumulatetherespectandprestigeneededtorisetothetoppartyleadership,whichwedofindtobehighlyvaluable.

references

Aldrich,JohnH.1995.Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America.Chicago,IL: UniversityofChicagoPress.

Brambor,Thomas,WilliamRobertsClark,andMattGolder.2006.“UnderstandingInter-actionModels:ImprovingEmpiricalAnalyses.”Political Analysis14:63–82.

Clucas,RichardA.2001.“Principal-AgentTheoryandthePowerofStateHouseSpeak-ers.”Legislative Studies Quarterly26:319–38.

Cox,GaryW.,ThadKousser,andMathewD.McCubbins.2005.“WhatPolarizesParties?PreferencesandAgendaControlinAmericanStateLegislatures.”PresentedattheannualmeetingoftheAmericanPoliticalScienceAssociation,Washington,DC.

Cox,GaryW.,andEricMagar.1999.“HowMuchisMajorityStatusintheU.S.CongressWorth?”American Political Science Review93:299–310.

Cox,GaryW.,andMathewD.McCubbins.1993.Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley,CA:UniversityofCaliforniaPress.

Denzau,Arthur,andMichaelMunger.1986.“LegislatorsandInterestGroups:HowUnor-ganizedInterestsGetRepresented.”American Political Science Review 80:89–106.

Francis,Wayne.1989.Legislative Committee Game. Columbus,OH:OhioStateUniversityPress.

Grier,Kevin,andMichaelMunger.1993.“ComparingInterestGroupPACContributionstoHouseandSenateIncumbents,1980–1986.”The Journal of Politics55:615–43.

Hamm,KeithE.,andGaryF.Moncrief.2004.“LegislativePoliticsintheStates.”InPoli-

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 149 4/7/09 4:23:38 PM

tics in the American States,eds.VirginiaGrayandRussellL.Hanson.WashingtonDC:CongressionalQuarterlyPress.

Hamm,KeithE.,andRobertHarmel.1991.“LegislativePartyDevelopmentandtheSpeakerSystem:TheCaseoftheTexasHouse.”The Journal of Politics 55:1140–51.

Hamm,KeithE.,RonaldHedlund,andNancyMartorano.2006.“MeasuringStateLegisla-tiveCommitteePower:ChangeandChamberDifferencesinthe20thCentury.”State Politics and Policy Quarterly 6:88–111.

Jewell,MalcolmE.,andMarciaL.Whicker.1994.Legislative Leadership in the American States. AnnArbor,MI:UniversityofMichiganPress.

Jewell,MalcolmE.,andSamuelC.Patterson.1986.The Legislative Process in the United States, 4thed.NewYork,NY:RandomHouse.

Jones,Mark,JuanPabloMicozzi,andGregVonnahme.2006.“TheEvolutionofPartyPoliticsinTexas,1973–2006:TracingtheEmergenceofaPartisanLegislature.”CenteronInstitutionsandGovernance,UniversityofCalifornia,Berkley.WorkingpaperNo.23.

Jones,RuthS.,andThomasBorris.1985.“StrategicContributinginLegislativeCam-paigns:TheCaseofMinnesota.”Legislative Studies Quarterly10:89–105.

Kraemer,RichardH.,CharldeanNewell,andDavidF.Prindle.2003.Essentials of Texas Politics,7thed.Belmont,CA:Wadsworth.

Kurtz,CarlT.1990.“TheChangingStateLegislature(LobbyistsBeware).”InLeverag-ing State Government Relations,ed.WesleyPederson.Washington,DC:PublicAffairsCouncil.

Maxwell,William,andErnestCrain(withEdwinDavis,ElizabethFlores,JosephIgnagni,CynthiaOpheim,andChristopherWlezien).2006.Texas Politics Today,12thed.Bel-mont,CA:ThomsonWadsworth.

O’Connell,Sue.2004.State Election Overview 2004.Helena,MT:InstituteonMoneyinStatePolitics.

Romer,Thomas,andJamesSnyder.1994.“AnEmpiricalInvestigationoftheDynamicsofPACContributions.”American Journal of Political Science38:745–69.

Rosenthal,Alan.2004.Heavy Lifting: The Job of the American Legislature.Washington,DC:CongressionalQuarterlyPress.

Squire,Peverill,andKeithE.Hamm.2005.101 Chambers: Congress, State Legislatures, and the Future of Legislative Studies.Columbus,OH:TheUniversityofOhioPress.

Straayer,John.2000.The Colorado General Assembly. Boulder,CO:TheUniversityPressofColorado.

Thielemann,GregoryS.,andDonaldR.Dixon.1994.“ExplainingContributions:RationalContributorsandtheElectionsforthe71stTexasHouse.”Legislative Studies Quarterly19:495–506.

Thompson,Joel,WilliamCassie,andMalcolmE.Jewell.1994.“ASacredCoworJustaLotofBull?PartyandPACMoneyinStateLegislativeElections.”Political Research Quarterly47:223–37.

Weiss,Rachel.2006.State Election Overview 2006.Helena,MT:InstituteonMoneyinStatePolitics.

Wright,Ralph.2005.Inside the Statehouse: Lessons from the Speaker.Washington,DC:CongressionalQuarterlyPress.

150 kim and phillips

SPPQ 9_2 text.indd 150 4/7/09 4:23:38 PM