Transcript
Page 1: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

sustainability

Article

Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid WasteDisposal PPP Projects in China

Xueguo Xu, Tingting Xu * and Meizeng Gui *

School of Management, Shanghai University, Shanghai 200444, China; [email protected]* Correspondence: [email protected] (T.X.); [email protected] (M.G.)

Received: 18 August 2020; Accepted: 9 September 2020; Published: 17 September 2020�����������������

Abstract: In municipal solid waste disposal public–private-partnership (PPP) projects, economicbenefits, as well as social and ecological benefits, are critical in sustaining sustainability development.However, private investors may make more efforts for economic benefits than for social and ecologicalbenefits out of self-interest. Because the government does not have the same information that theinvestors have, information asymmetry leads to opportunistic behavior. To solve these problems,principal–agent models were established to analyze the incentive mechanism for encouraginginvestors to adopt a positive attitude toward both economic benefits and social and ecological benefits,inhibiting investors’ opportunistic behavior. In particular, numerical simulation was carried outto analyze the relationships between related parameters (c1, c2, ct, a, β, k,λ, p). The results show thatthe investors with higher comprehensive abilities are more willing to make efforts for social andecological benefits. An increase in incentive and governance intensity would help to encourageinvestors to make more efforts for project benefits and to lower the level of opportunistic behavioradopted by investors. The complexity of the task and the fuzziness of the perception of effort inputresults aggravate the uncertainty and risk of the projects due to information asymmetry. Therefore,real-time and positive incentives are important. In order to ensure the social and ecological benefitsof a project, performance standards should be set according to the actual situation; investors preferfixed compensation with lower risk, but fixed compensation does not have incentive effect, and theproportion should not be too high.

Keywords: PPP; municipal solid waste disposal; principal–agent; incentive and governance; China

1. Introduction

With rapid economic development and urbanization, the disposal and management of municipalsolid waste have become a serious problem in China. Because of the large population and thebackward municipal solid waste (MSW) disposal technology, the image of Chinese cities and thephysical and mental health of the inhabitants have been severely damaged and threatened by theharmful effects of mortifying wastes [1–3]. By the end of 2018, China’s urbanization level had reached59.58%, the quantity of MSW produced by 200 large and medium cities had reached 211.473 milliontons, and the daily output of MSW per capita exceeded 1 kg. “Garbage siege” has become a majorproblem of urban governance in China. MSW is growing at an average annual rate of 5%, more thanin any other Asian country [4]. With the continuous promotion of the new urbanization strategy,it can be predicted that the urban population will continue to grow steadily in the future, and a largenumber of people will produce a large amount of MSW. With the increasing MSW, the social andecological impacts of MSW have also increased, and now its disposal is a growing social concern [5].A sustainable development strategy based on protecting natural resources and the environment,stimulating economic development, and aiming at improving our lives is the blueprint to achieve abetter and more sustainable future for all of us. China has a large population, relatively insufficient

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686; doi:10.3390/su12187686 www.mdpi.com/journal/sustainability

Page 2: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 2 of 16

per capita resources, great employment pressure, and a prominent ecological environment. Therefore,the issue of sustainable development is important. Because the garbage siege has caused seriousenvironmental pollution and has seriously harmed people’s health, sustainability increasingly receivesattention in the field of MSW management. Therefore, it is urgent to adopt appropriate methodsto solve the MSW problem to achieve sustainable development. Junhan Huang et al. proposedthree planning scenarios for MSW disposal to enhance its sustainability, i.e., anaerobic digestion,incineration, and landfilling [6]. Landfilling and incineration can be used to deal with MSW disposal.In China, the landfill is the main MSW disposal method due to the its low cost and the advantageof its simple operation. The use of landfills is the simplest, cheapest, and most common way ofmanaging disposal of MSW. However, it is the least environmentally friendly means of MSW disposal;the use of landfills reduces the efficiency of waste disposal and even causes serious problems, such asgroundwater contamination and air pollution with the release of harmful gases from landfill andsoil contamination [7]. Incineration can generate electricity, but micro-pollutants emitted from thecombustion process are also a concern [8]. In recent years, due to the low efficiency of waste disposaland the above problems, landfills have rarely been used. Waste incineration has become more andmore popular thanks to its large amount of MSW disposal, high disposal rate, significant reduction ofthe volume of waste, the economic benefits brought by electricity generation, etc. However, the processof incineration can produce bottom ash and fly ash, which are harmful to human health. Because of thebackward technology, poor regulation, and heavy financial burden, the government cannot supportthe responsibility of MSW disposal services [9]. Thus, it is necessary to search for a new way to provideMSW disposal services [3], and increasing emphasis should be placed on enhancing efficacy of selectiveMSW collection in the place of MSW generation to improve the efficiency of waste disposal [10].

MSW disposal involves numerous public infrastructural items, such as landfills, incinerationplants, and compost plants. Moreover, this treatment requires high professional quality. For a longtime, MSW disposal has been handled by the government. However, with the continuous increase ofMSW, efficiency is difficult to guarantee if still completely depending on the government; the financialburden for infrastructure development often tends to exceed what most governments can afford.To address these problems, the public–private-partnership (PPP) model provides a new channel tosolve the financial burden and efficiency problems caused by MSW [11]. PPP, firstly proposed bythe UK government in 1982, refers to the cooperative relationship established by the governmentand private organizations through franchise agreements. The government grants private enterpriseslong-term franchise rights and income rights in exchange for infrastructure, and provides certainpublic goods and services [12,13]. PPP is sometimes regarded as a potential vehicle for sustainability,as a long-term contract bundled with various functions could make the interests of private partnersconsider the life cycle costs [14]. In recent years, the Chinese government has also been promotingthe PPP model [15–17]; as there is an urgent need to deal with MSW, China has to apply the PPPmodel in environment treatment projects, such as MSW disposal [18–20]. According to the governmentand Social Capital Cooperation Center (PPP Project Library) of the Ministry of Finance of China,nearly 20 PPP projects for MSW disposal have been put into the PPP database. The number of PPPprojects for MSW disposal that have entered the preliminary consultation stage of the project is alsocontinuously increasing.

However, MSW disposal PPP projects have encountered some problems. The government playsthe role of the principal, and private investors act as the agent in PPP projects. Principal–agent theoryis an essential part of contract theory in institutional economics. Its central task is to analyze how todesign the optimal contract incentive agent under information asymmetry and conflicts of interest.In MSW disposal PPP projects, the government has minimal information and can neither completelyknow the efforts of private investors nor precisely grasp their information. Sustainability is oftenconsidered as a three-dimensional concept that includes social, ecological, and economic perspectives.Azapagic and Perdan indicated that sustainable development must be considered economically,socially, and ecologically [21]. Therefore, the profits of MSW disposal PPP projects mainly include

Page 3: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 3 of 16

economic benefits (EB) and social and ecological benefits (SEB). EB are mostly obtained by collectingMSW disposal fees and MSW power generation. SEB refers to the benefits brought by protecting theenvironment, improving urban living conditions, and enhancing the overall image and competitivenessof a city. The government wants to maximize the comprehensive benefits of the project, while privateinvestors only focus on their profits. Interests conflicts and asymmetric information may lead to moralhazards [22]. Private investors are more likely to maximize their profits through opportunistic behavior,which will seriously damage the interests of the public. Then, public resistance could occur due topublic severe concerns [23]. Therefore, specific governance instruments and incentives are needed toencourage investors to adopt positive attitudes toward cooperation [24,25]. Complementary regulatorystrategies should also be adopted to safeguard the interests of all parties [26].

In China, there are many incentive and governance methods for PPP projects. Reputation incentiveshelp to improve the social image of investors by giving spiritual recognition to high-quality privateinvestors operations that actively avoid opportunism. Policy incentives are that the governmentgives priority to supporting PPP projects. Policy incentives can bring in social capital throughinvestment subsidies, fund injections, guarantee subsidies, loan interest discounts, and tax preferences.Subsidies incentives mean that the government attracts private investors by providing fixed andvariable subsidies. Government guarantee incentives often use to provide guarantee mechanism for theoperation of the whole life cycle in PPP projects. The government becomes the shareholder of a specialpurpose vehicle (SPV) through direct investment and shares risks and benefits with private investors.Access governance means that investors with relevant management experience, professional ability,financing ability, and good credit status are selected as partners through open bidding, inviting bidding,and competitive negotiation. Process governance refers to strengthening the whole-process governanceof project quality and operation standards during the implementation of the project. Further, it carriesout a comprehensive evaluation on the quantity, quality, and capital use efficiency of public productsand services. The evaluation results shall serve as the basis for financial subsidies, price standards,and cooperation period. Credit ratings deal with the establishment of government credit restraintmechanisms, credit rating, blacklist system, and outstanding performance of investors in the nextfranchise to give priority. External governance means that the public gives feedback to conductimpartial governance, assessment, and evaluation on the construction and operation of projects.Performance governance links government payment and user payment with performance assessments,and takes performance evaluation results as an essential basis for price adjustments, positive incentives,and adverse penalties.

In the past decade, lots of researchers have studied the incentive mechanisms in PPP projects.However, relevant researches have focused on EB, SEB, and opportunistic behavior of private investorsin MSW disposal. Thus, PPP projects remain rare and little attention is paid to the impact ofopportunistic behavior on benefits distribution and the significance of SEB. Indeed, economic benefitsare as critical as social and ecological benefits in MSW disposal PPP projects. The primary objectives ofMSW disposal PPP projects are to rebuild the overall image and improve the living environment of thecity. Therefore, social and ecological benefits need to take them seriously. The total output of a projectnot only depends on the efforts of the investors but also are affected by external uncertainties. Investorsmay engage in opportunistic and self-interested behavior. The present study aims to fill this gapby establishing an incentive and governance model of multi-task principal-agent under informationasymmetry to encourage investors to adopt a positive attitude toward both economic benefits, social andecological benefits, and inhibit investors’ opportunistic behavior. The objective of this paper is toaddress two problems from the perspective of sustainable development. First, we consider how toeffectively encourage investors to make more effort for achieving the sustainable development goalsof EB and SEB in MSW disposal PPP projects. Second, we consider how to avoid moral hazardssuch as opportunistic behavior by investors through effective governance and penalty mechanism.The main methods of this paper were the construction of an incentive and governance model throughprincipal-agent theory, which helps to formulate the basis for decision-making between government

Page 4: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 4 of 16

and investors. Numerical simulation was also carried out for demonstrating the application of theprincipal-agent models. Compared with the previous study, this paper separately considered EB andSEB of MSW disposal PPP projects, set the optimal proportion of economic benefits allocated to privateinvestors, basic standard, and incentive coefficients for social and ecological benefits. Multi-taskprincipal-agent incentive models were established considering the impacts of investors’ opportunisticbehavior during information asymmetry. The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The followingsection provides a comprehensive review of the MSW disposal PPP project and incentive mechanism.The third section introduces the parameters and hypotheses of research models. Then, principal-agentmodels were constructed to analyze the incentive and governance mechanism for MSW disposal PPPprojects, followed by discussions of the models. A numerical example is presented in the fifth sectionto enhance a better understanding. Finally, summary findings and conclusions are offered.

2. Literature Review

PPP refers to cooperation between the government and private investors, which has become aneffective way to solve the dilemma of “garbage siege” in many countries in the field of municipalsolid waste disposal. The rights and obligations of the two parties is determined by contracts.Moreover, private investors can earn reasonable profits by providing high-quality facilities andservices to the public [27,28]. The PPP model applied in MSW problems can alleviate the pressureof the local government and improve the efficiency of disposal services. At the same time, it canreduce the secondary pollution caused during the process [3]. Many kinds of research focused onthe implementation and operation of MSW disposal PPP projects had been proposed previously.Mohan et al. [29] considered the PPP model as a useful mode for domestic garbage treatment.Wu et al. [30] established a risk assessment framework for garbage incineration power generationand evaluated the risks of such projects. Arbulú et al. [31] pointed out that the use of PPP models tosolve MSW problems in tourist attractions can effectively save costs and improve efficiency. The keyto forming a partnership between government and investors lies in the common goal of providinghigh-quality products and services at the least cost for specific projects. Based on realizing commongoals, the government can maximize comprehensive benefits and improve the efficiency of publicservices. In contrast, private investors can maximize their interests to achieve a win-win situation.However, the government and investors have different targets in MSW projects. The governmentis committed to maximizing the EB and SEB of the project to achieve its sustainable development.Private investors are inevitably profit-driven and may reduce the service quality of the project orneglect the investment in ecological protection and social responsibility [22]. Based on principal-agenttheory, differences in interest demands of both parties and information asymmetry also give rise toopportunistic behaviors, thus resulting in moral hazards [32]. Opportunistic behavior adopted byprivate investors seriously harms public interests and affects the success of the project [33]. At the sametime, it affects the health and sustainability of partnerships between the government and investors [34].Therefore, scientific and reasonable incentive contracts need to be established to maximize the totalprofits of MSW PPP disposal projects.

Lots of countries have applied PPP models in multiple fields. The Ministry of Finance of Chinaissued a document to promote the PPP model in 2014, which set off a PPP upsurge in China. To promotehealthy and sustainable development of the projects, encouraging private investors to work hard andinhibiting their opportunistic behavior are essential. The sustainability of public–private partnershipshas been widely covered in the relevant research [35–37]. From an incentive perspective, analyses onPPP projects in different fields have been proposed. Baron et al. [38] developed a two-stage incentivemechanism for studying how to observe the real information of private investors and solve the problemof information asymmetry. Tsai et al. [39] analyzed the government’s incentive to PPP projects byadopting a case study model, which clarified the problem of the government implementing incentivemeasures for private investors in sewage treatment and recycling waste goods. Ho et al. [40] analyzedthe intensity and influencing factors of government rescue PPP projects through the game theory

Page 5: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 5 of 16

model, offering a framework and methodology to understand the behavioral dynamics of the partiesin PPP. Schmidt et al. [41] considered the relationships between public and private investors to bepromoted and formed by exchanging information and setting incentives mechanism, thus improvingthe utilization efficiency of resources to accomplish the project’s construction. Shi et al. [42] pointed outthat a flexible incentive mechanism should be adopted according to the conflicts of interest and externaluncertainties to improve the smooth implementation of the project. Lohmann et al. [43] analyzed theopportunistic behavior of private investors in the PPP project negotiation stage. Liu et al. [44] built aprincipal-agent model with opportunism tendency by analyzing the private investors’ speculation inPPP projects. Li et al. [45] discussed the behavior of private investors under the incentive mechanism.Wang et al. [46] added reciprocity preference theory to the traditional principal-agent model andestablished an incentive mechanism based on the optimal government share ratio. Peng Li et al.proposed a dynamic decision- making method to evaluate the performance of enterprises in PPPprojects [47].

Lots of researchers have conducted detailed studies on the incentive problems of PPP projectsfrom different perspectives, but most of them only considered a single project goal. However, in MSWdisposal PPP projects, both EB and SEB need to be considered. EB targets must set SEB targets toachieve sustainable development of PPP projects [25]. The effective incentive mechanism for somesingle benefits targets may become ineffective and it is vital to design PPP model optimal incentivecontracts based on a multi-task principal-agent. Holmstrom et al. [48,49] proposed a multi-taskprincipal-agent model based on the linear principal-agent model previously proposed and studiedby the optimal contract design under the multi-task principal-agent relationships. Baker et al. [50,51]analyzed the impact of performance evaluation in the multi-task principal-agent incentive mechanism.However, most of these studies ignored the influence of investors’ opportunistic behavior on theproject and did not establish the governance and penalty mechanism related to investors’ opportunisticbehavior. Opportunism is a common phenomenon in social and economic activities due to informationasymmetry and different interests [52,53]. Opportunistic behavior refers to the behavior that investorsare motivated to pursue their interests by deceit to achieve gains [54,55]. Lan et al. [34] pointed out thatpreventing opportunistic behavior can effectively ensure the health and sustainability of cooperation.However, information asymmetry between the two parties leads to the opportunistic behavior ofthose who hold more information when dealing with both parties [32,56]. You et al. [57] argued thatthere is a positive correlation between external uncertainties and opportunistic behaviors of investors.However, the correlation could weaken contract control and adjustment. Wang et al. found thatthe opportunistic behavior of investors influenced by public engagement, government reputation,incentive mechanism, discovery probability of opportunistic behavior, and penalty measures [58].Since opportunistic behavior is not conducive to the healthy and sustainable partnership of both partiesin MSW disposal PPP projects, effective governance mechanisms, such as contracts, are needed togovern investors’ opportunistic behavior [59].

According to the above literature review, we can conclude that much of the research on theincentive mechanism of PPP projects do not focus on the issue of multi-task benefits incentive,nor consider the influence of opportunistic behavior on investors. Based on this, the current studyrefers to the research model of incentive and governance, and establishes the incentive and governancemodel of a multi-task principal-agent under the condition of information asymmetry.

3. Model Development

The performance in MSW disposal PPP projects includes EB and SEB, which depend on theoperation and management of private investors. Generally, the government attempts to get investorsto put as much effort as possible to maximize comprehensive project benefits, while private investorsfocus on their own economic profits. Incentives are considered as one of the most effective measuresto eliminate conflicts of interest and achieve a win-win situation for the two parties [16]. Moreover,because private investors have more information than the government, the government cannot fully

Page 6: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 6 of 16

observe the efforts of private investors in projects. Asymmetric information may lead to moral hazards.Private investors may adopt opportunistic behaviors to obtain more benefits, such as minimizingconstruction, operation and management costs, and increasing fees, which may lead to low projectquality, as well as capacity and financial burden for the government [60]. Therefore, governance andpenalty mechanisms are needed to guide investor’s behavior in projects.

The following hypothesis must be formulated to analyze the incentive model:

Hypothesis 1 (H1). π1 is set as economic benefits (EB) and π2 denotes the social and ecological benefits(SEB). The EB and SEB are determined by the effort level e1 and e2, respectively. According to Holmstrom [61],the output of EB and SEB in MSW disposal PPP projects can be expressed as follows:

π1 = ae1 + ε1 (1)

π2 = ae2 + ε2 (2)

where a represents the own capabilities and resources of private investors, a > 0, and εi(i = 0, 1) are randomvariables, which obey normal distribution with means of zero and variances of σ2

i (i = 0, 1): εi ∼ N(0, σ2

i

),

i = 0, 1.

Hypothesis 2 (H2). C(e1, e2) is the cost of private investors in making efforts to purchase EB and SEB. c1, c2.(c1, c2 > 0) are the cost coefficients, respectively. For the same level of benefits efforts, the higher the value of thecost coefficient would lead to higher cost. The cost function of EB and SEB can be expressed as followed:

C(e1, e2) =12(c1e2

1 + c2e22) (3)

Hypothesis 3 (H3). et is the efforts of private investors in adopting opportunistic behavior. e1 + e2 + et = 1.The output obtained by the investors’ opportunistic behavior is M, which can be expressed as follows:

M(et) = Tet = T(1− e1 − e2) (4)

where T represents the output coefficient of the investors’ opportunistic behavior, T ≥ 0. The following is the costfunction of opportunistic behavior:

C(et) =12

cte2t =

12

ct(1− e1 − e2)2 (5)

ct > 0 is the cost coefficient in taking opportunistic behavior [44].

Hypothesis 4 (H4). The government would govern investors’ behavior throughout the project to regulatethe behavior of investors. The probability that the government finds the investor’s opportunistic behavior is P,which also represents the level of government governance. Once the investor’s opportunistic behavior is observedby the governance mechanism, there are penalties from the government. The function can be expressed as follows:

F(et) = λ[pet + (1− p)δ] = λ[p(1− e1 − e2) + (1− p)δ] (6)

where λ is coefficient of the penalty, λ > 0. δ is a random variable that obeys normal distribution with mean ofzero and variances of σ2

3, i.e., δ ∼ N(0, σ2

3

), δ and ε are mutually independent [62]. The cost of government

governance can be instructed as follows:

C(p) =12

c jp2 (7)

where c j > 0 is the cost coefficient of government [63].

Page 7: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 7 of 16

Hypothesis 5 (H5). The government cannot observe the investment level of investors’ efforts. Thus,the incentives for investors consist of two parts: one is the fixed subsidy or income promised in the contracts α;the other is the incentive income provided according to the project benefits that can be observed by government.The total incentive benefits of private investors in municipal solid waste disposal PPP projects can be instructedas follows:

S = α+ βπ1 + k(π2 −π0) (8)

where π0 is the basic standard of SEB. The basic purpose of MSW disposal PPP projects is rebuilding the overallimage of the city and improving the living environment of the city. Therefore, minimum SEB targets shall beset for the project [48]. β is the proportion of EB allocated to the private investors, which also denotes the EBincentive coefficient. k is the incentive coefficient for SEB.

Hypothesis 6 (H6). The government is risk-neutral, while investors are risk averse. ρ is the risk evasioncoefficient [64].

In the MSW disposal PPP projects, the government attempts to maximize the total output benefits,including EB and SEB. The total income of government can be expressed as follows:

ϕg = (1− β)π1 + π2 + F(et) − α− k(π2 −π0) −C(p) (9)

The expected utility of the government is:

E(ϕg) = E[(1− β)π1 + π2 + F(et) − α− k(π2 −π0) −C(p)]= (1− β)ae1 + ae2 + λp(1− e1 − e2) − α− k(ae2 −π0) +

12 c jp2 (10)

Investors are inevitably profit-seeking and the purpose of the project is to maximize its ownprofits. The total income of private investors ϕs can be expressed as follows:

ϕs = α+ βπ1 + Tet −C(et) −C(e1, e2) − F(et) (11)

The expected net income of investors can be expressed as:

E(ϕs) =E[α+ βπ1 + Tet −C(et) −C(e1, e2) − F(et)]

= α+ βae1 + k(ae2 −π0) + T(1− e1 − e2) − λp(1− e1 − e2)

−12

[c1e2

1 + c2e22 + ct(1− e1 − e2)

2] (12)

The variance of the net income of investors can be expressed as follows:

Var(ϕs) = (ϕs − E(ϕs)2 =

[β2σ2

1 + k2σ22 + λ2(1− p)2σ2

3

](13)

Since the private investors is risk averse, the certainty utility (CE) can be expressed as follows:

CE = E(ϕs) −12ρ[β2σ2

1 + k2σ22 + λ2(1− p)2σ2

3

](14)

Therefore, incentives of private investors in the MSW disposal PPP projects can be expressed asconstrained programming problems, and ω0 is the minimum utility that the private investors wouldreserve. The constrained programming problems can be expressed as follows:

max(1− β)ae1 + ae2 + λp(1− e1 − e2) − α− k(ae2 −π0) +12

c jp2 (15)

Page 8: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 8 of 16

(IR)α+ βae1 + k(ae2 −π0) + T(1− e1 − e2) − λp(1− e1 − e2)

−12

[c1e2

1 + c2e22 + ct(1− e1 − e2)

2]−

12ρ

[β2σ2

1 + k2σ22 + λ2(1− p)2σ2

3

]≥ ω0

(IC)(e1, e2) ∈ argmaxα+ βae1 + k(ae2 −π0) + T(1− e1 − e2) − λp(1− e1 − e2)

−12

[c1e2

1 + c2e22 + ct(1− e1 − e2)

2]−

12ρ

[β2σ2

1 + k2σ22 + λ2(1− p)2σ2

3

](16)

According to the former analysis, private investors determine their efforts level (e∗1, e∗2) based onthe maximization of their own profits. According to the first-order optimal solutions to Equations (15)and (16), the optimal solutions to the constrained programming problems can be instructed as follows:

e1 =c2ct − Tc2 + aβ(c2 + ct) + λpc2 − akct

c1c2 + c1ct + c2ct(17)

e2 =c1ct − Tc1 + ak(c1 + ct) + λpc1 − aβct

c1c2 + c1ct + c2ct(18)

et =c1c2 + (c1 + c2)(T − λp) − a(βc2 + kc1)

c1c2 + c1ct + c2ct(19)

β∗ =a(ac2 + akct − λpc2)

a2(c2 + ct) + ρσ21(c1c2 + c1ct + c2ct)

(20)

k∗ =a(ac1 + aβct − λpc1)

a2(c1 + ct) + ρσ22(c1c2 + c1ct + c2ct)

(21)

λ∗ =ap(c1 + c2 − βc2 − kc1)

p2(c1 + c2) + ρσ23(1− p)2(c1c2 + c1ct + c2ct)

(22)

α∗ = ω0 − βae1 − k(ae2 −π0) − T(1− e1 − e2) + λp(1− e1 − e2)

+ 12

[c1e2

1 + c2e22 + ct(1− e1 − e2)

2]+ 1

2ρ[β2σ2

1 + k2σ22 + λ2(1− p)2σ2

3

] (23)

4. Model Analysis and Discussion

Equations (17)–(19) show that private investors’ efforts and opportunistic behavior towardsprojects determine by multiple factors that divided into two parts. One is the level of private investors’own capabilities and resources (a), the output coefficient of the investors’ opportunistic behavior (T),and the cost coefficient of investors efforts (c1, c2, ct). All of these are determined by private investors.The other is the incentive coefficient of SEB (β) and the incentive coefficient of EB (k), penalty coefficientfor investors’ opportunistic behavior (λ), and the intensity of government supervision (p), which arecontrolled by the government. Since incentives need to be designed from the perspective of thegovernment, it is necessary to consider what the government can control. The level of private investors’efforts to economic benefits is positively correlated with the proportion of economic benefit allocation(β) in the incentive contract and negatively correlated with the incentive coefficient of social andecological benefits (k). On the contrary, the efforts of social and ecological benefits are negatively relatedto the proportion of economic benefit allocation (β) and positively associated with the incentives forsocial and ecological benefits (k). The higher the penalty for opportunistic behaviors of investors (λ),the more investors will reduce opportunistic behaviors and increase their efforts in project economicand social and ecological benefits. The related equations can be expressed as follows:

∂e1

∂β> 0,

∂e1

∂k< 0,

∂e1

∂λ> 0,

∂e2

∂β< 0,

∂e2

∂k> 0,

∂e2

∂λ> 0,

∂et

∂β< 0,

∂et

∂k< 0,

∂et

∂λ< 0 (24)

Page 9: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 9 of 16

According to the above analysis, the following conclusions can be drawn:The investor’s efforts and resources are limited. The government cannot observe the real ability

and efforts of investors due to information asymmetry. In principal-agent contracts, the governmentcan only observe EB and SEB of PPP projects, and discover the opportunistic behavior of investorsby setting up a governance mechanism. According to the above analysis, the investor’s efforts andopportunistic behavior are affected by the government’s incentives and penalty in principal-agentcontracts. Therefore, the government needs to design incentive contracts in a targeted manner accordingto the characteristics and expected benefits of different MSW disposal PPP projects to control the levelof effort and inhibit the opportunistic behavior of investors.

According to Equations (17)–(19), investors’ efforts in economic, social, and ecological benefitsare positively correlated with government governance, while investors’ investment in opportunisticbehavior is negatively correlated with government governance. The related equations can be expressedas follows:

∂e1∂p = λc2

c1c2+c1ct+c2ct> 0

∂e2∂p = λc1

c1c2+c1ct+c2ct> 0

∂et∂p = −

λ(c1+c2)c1c2+c1ct+c2ct

< 0

(25)

This shows that the higher the governance of the government, the higher the efforts level ofinvestors in MSW disposal PPP projects, and the lower the investment in opportunistic behaviorof private. In addition, Equation (25) shows that the governance mechanism also has an incentiveeffect, where the existence of penalty will strengthen the incentive effect, which is λ ↑, ∂e1

∂p , ∂e2∂p ↑,

∂et∂p ↓ .

The existence of governance makes investors’ investments transparent. The higher the level ofgovernance, the more transparent of private investors. Information asymmetry can also be alleviated.In addition, penalties force investors to reduce opportunistic behavior and turn to achieve economicbenefits and social and ecological benefits. When p = 1, governance intensity reaches 100% and theinformation is completely symmetric, which achieve the Pareto optimal effort level. Equations (20)

and (21) show that(∂β∗

∂p , ∂k∗∂p

)< 0 and λ ↑, ∂β

∂p ↓,∂k∗∂p ↓ , which indicate that when there is only incentive

mechanism in the principal-agent relationship. The government can only predict the efforts of investorsby observing the economic, ecological, and social benefits of the project due to information asymmetry.When there is a governance mechanism, the government can base on the observed project economic,ecological, and social benefits and the results of governance. The information value of EB andSEB observed by the government has declined, so the incentive intensity of benefits needs to bereduced accordingly.

The governance mechanism in MSW disposal PPP projects can encourage investors to makemore efforts and effectively inhibit the opportunistic behavior of investors. Increasing penaltiesof opportunistic behavior helps strengthen motivation. Incentive and governance mechanisms arecomplementary and the existence of the penalty enhances complementarity.

Equations (17)–(19) demonstrate that the basic social and ecological benefit standard π0 of MSWdisposal PPP projects is not directly related to the investment efforts and opportunistic behavior ofprivate investors, but it is necessary to set this basic standard. ∂α∗

∂π0< 0 means that the improvement

of basic standards for social and ecological benefits help increase investors’ efforts to ensure π2 > π0,which ensures excess social and ecological benefits of proportion k. As the proportion of allocation ofthe benefits increases, the proportion of the fixed subsidy promised in the contracts needs be lowered.The corresponding basic standard of social and ecological benefits should be set according to the actualsituation of the PPP project. High standards are hard to achieve and encourage investors to adoptopportunistic behaviors. However, when the basic standards are too low, they do not meet actualdemand. Based on the above analysis, the following conclusions can be obtained:

Page 10: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 10 of 16

In MSW disposal PPP projects, the government can set a basic standard for investors to ensurethe social and ecological benefits of projects. Excess rewards will be received when investors meetbasic standards.

According to Equations (20)–(22),(∂β∗

∂ρ , ∂k∗∂ρ , ∂λ

∂ρ

)< 0,

(∂β∗

∂σ21, ∂k∗∂σ2

2, ∂λ

∂σ23

)< 0. The optimal incentives are

negatively correlated with the risk evasion coefficient, so the principal-agent contracts need to be moreflexible according to investors’ attitudes towards risks. Risk-averse investors prefer a fixed subsidyor income. If private investors are risk-averse, incentive compensation for project benefits should bereduced. However, investors with a low degree of risk aversion and individual risk tolerance can takestrong incentives. Optimal incentives are negatively correlated with the random variables indicates thatthe incentives should set in combination with the external environment situation. The more uncertainthe external environment of projects, the more the output of projects is affected by external randomvariables. In other words, better performing projects may be due to a favorable external environmentrather than the efforts and abilities of the investors. On the contrary, poor project performance is notnecessarily caused by investors’ lack of effort or opportunistic behavior. Therefore, the incentives needto be adjusted accordingly under the high uncertainty of the external environment.

Investors with high risk aversion prefer fixed income rather than incentive income. The greaterthe external environment uncertainty, the higher the proportion of fixed income is required for private

investors. Since(∂α∗

∂ρ , ∂α∗

∂σ21, ∂α

∂σ22, ∂α

∂σ23

)> 0, fixed income is zero risk and has a certain protective effect for

investors. In addition, according to Equations (20)–(22), there is no direct correlation between investor’sefforts and fixed income. Therefore, fixed subsidies have no incentive effect and the proportion shouldnot be too high when designing principal-agent contracts.

5. Numerical Example

In this section, a numerical simulation was carried out to further analyze the application ofthe models and the relationships between related parameters. Ideally, the government could judgeinvestors’ attitude to risk based on their previous participation in PPP projects and calibrate the riskevasion coefficient value ρ, the cost coefficient of efforts (c1, c2), and the cost coefficient of privateinvestors when pursuing opportunistic behavior (ct) based on the judgment results. The value ofinvestors’ own resources (a) can be inferred from the amount of collective investment between thegovernment and investors. The output coefficient of the investors’ opportunistic behavior (T) canbe obtained from certain economic indicators, such as the return of investment (ROI). Meanwhile,the intensity of governance (p) and penalty coefficient (λ) for investors based on previous experience inPPP projects are determined by the government. Finally, the variance of normally distributed randomvariables σ2

1, σ22, and σ2

3 are difficult to measure, and can be derived using simulations.For investors, suppose the cost coefficient of EB (c1) and the cost coefficient of SEB (c2) are 10;

moreover, assume the cost coefficient of private investors in pursuing opportunistic behavior (ct)is 5. The risk evasion coefficient value (ρ) of investors is 0.8 and the level of the investors’ ownresources (a) is 0.4. The output coefficient of the investors’ opportunistic behavior (T) is 0.3. For thegovernment, suppose the intensity of governance (p) is 0.5 and the coefficient of penalty (λ) is 2.Assume σ2

1 = σ22 = σ2

3= 0.5 for simplifying the calculations. The results of numerical simulation aredisplayed as follows.

As depicted in Figures 1–3, the investors’ efforts and opportunistic behavior are related to the costcoefficient and investment level of the investors’ own resources. The improvement of investors’ ownresources helps convert the efforts invested in the project into output benefits and increases governmentincentives. Therefore, private investors increase output efforts to achieve output benefits rather thanengaging in opportunistic behavior. When the cost coefficients (c1, c2, ct) increases, more costs arenegatively correlated with private investors’ behavior. Since the cost coefficient and resource levelis the investor’s own information that cannot be collected by the government due to informationasymmetry, the efforts level of output benefits and opportunistic behavior by private investors cannot

Page 11: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 11 of 16

be observed by the government either. Therefore, the government can only setup incentive mechanismsto encourage investors based on project benefits and governance mechanisms to regulate investors’opportunistic behavior.Sustainability 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 12 of 18

Figure 1. Efforts of economic benefits.

Figure 2. Efforts of social and ecological benefits.

Figure 3. Efforts of opportunistic behavior.

Figure 1. Efforts of economic benefits.

Sustainability 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 12 of 18

Figure 1. Efforts of economic benefits.

Figure 2. Efforts of social and ecological benefits.

Figure 3. Efforts of opportunistic behavior.

Figure 2. Efforts of social and ecological benefits.

Sustainability 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 12 of 18

Figure 1. Efforts of economic benefits.

Figure 2. Efforts of social and ecological benefits.

Figure 3. Efforts of opportunistic behavior.

Figure 3. Efforts of opportunistic behavior.

Page 12: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 12 of 16

Figures 4–6 show that the incentive intensity for economic benefits increases the incentive incomeof economic benefits obtained from the government and enhances the investment level of economicefforts. Moreover, as the efforts of investors are limited, the level of social and ecological benefitsdecreases as the level of economic efforts increases. The incentives and governance in MSW disposalPPP projects effectively inhibit the opportunistic behavior of investors. Because of the rise in incentives,the income obtained by investors through efforts increase and, due to the existence of governancemechanisms, investors’ opportunistic behavior will be punished once observed by the government.The selection of incentive coefficients for multi-benefits indirectly reflects the importance of benefitsto projects and the government. For municipal waste disposal PPP projects, social and ecologicalbenefits largely determine the success or failure of the project. Further, the incentive coefficient (k) isincredibly important.

Sustainability 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 13 of 18

Figures 4–6 show that the incentive intensity for economic benefits increases the incentive income of economic benefits obtained from the government and enhances the investment level of economic efforts. Moreover, as the efforts of investors are limited, the level of social and ecological benefits decreases as the level of economic efforts increases. The incentives and governance in MSW disposal PPP projects effectively inhibit the opportunistic behavior of investors. Because of the rise in incentives, the income obtained by investors through efforts increase and, due to the existence of governance mechanisms, investors’ opportunistic behavior will be punished once observed by the government. The selection of incentive coefficients for multi-benefits indirectly reflects the importance of benefits to projects and the government. For municipal waste disposal PPP projects, social and ecological benefits largely determine the success or failure of the project. Further, the

incentive coefficient ( k ) is incredibly important.

Figure 4. Relationship between incentives and efforts of economic benefits.

Figure 5. Relationship between incentives and efforts of social ecological benefits.

Figure 4. Relationship between incentives and efforts of economic benefits.

Sustainability 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 13 of 18

Figures 4–6 show that the incentive intensity for economic benefits increases the incentive income of economic benefits obtained from the government and enhances the investment level of economic efforts. Moreover, as the efforts of investors are limited, the level of social and ecological benefits decreases as the level of economic efforts increases. The incentives and governance in MSW disposal PPP projects effectively inhibit the opportunistic behavior of investors. Because of the rise in incentives, the income obtained by investors through efforts increase and, due to the existence of governance mechanisms, investors’ opportunistic behavior will be punished once observed by the government. The selection of incentive coefficients for multi-benefits indirectly reflects the importance of benefits to projects and the government. For municipal waste disposal PPP projects, social and ecological benefits largely determine the success or failure of the project. Further, the

incentive coefficient ( k ) is incredibly important.

Figure 4. Relationship between incentives and efforts of economic benefits.

Figure 5. Relationship between incentives and efforts of social ecological benefits.

Figure 5. Relationship between incentives and efforts of social ecological benefits.

Page 13: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 13 of 16Sustainability 2020, 12, x FOR PEER REVIEW 14 of 18

Figure 6. Relationship between incentives and efforts of opportunistic behavior.

6. Conclusions

In MSW disposal PPP projects, there are a series of contractual relationships and principal-agent relationships between the government and investors. This paper analyzes the incentive mechanisms of the government and constructs the principal-agent models in the presence of incentives and governance. The results suggest that incentives and supervision are complementary, and the existence of the penalty will enhance that complementarity. To ensure the sustainable development of projects and inhibit the opportunistic behavior of investors, the government must design supervision and punishment mechanisms to encourage investors to improve their investment level of efforts. Combining performance incentives with process governance, and make reasonable assessment payment according to the completion progress of the project. Investors ensure the quality and quantity of projects completion. Taking governance measures, opportunistic behavior will be punished. Third parties can be introduced to conduct governance and establish particular governance institutions for PPP projects of MSW disposal, online media is combined with public governance. To ensure the coordinated and sustainable development of economy, society, and environment for the PPP projects of MSW disposal, and to prevent investors from blindly pursuing economic benefits, the basic social and ecological benefit standards must be set for the PPP project. Although this standard has no incentive, it will have an indirect impact on investors through the influence of fixed income. Investors are risk-averse and prefer a risk-free fixed income. The greater the external uncertainty, the higher the demand for a fixed income. However, the proportion of fixed income, which has no incentive effect, should not be too high when designing principal-agent contracts. The ability and resources of the investors are limited; information asymmetry makes it impossible for the government to know the actual ability level and efforts of the investors. Therefore, the government needs to select qualified partners by access governance and value for money evaluation in the preparation stage of the project. The uncertainty of the external environment and the degree of risk aversion of investors affects the behavior of investors. When designing principal-agent contracts, the government needs to investigate the attitude of the private sector towards risks and the degree of uncertainty of the external environment and develop different incentives and governance mechanisms for different types of investors. For investors in the growth stage with low-risk aversion, the government should increase the incentive strength, and at the same time, governance intensity can appropriately lower. Investors in the mature stage with high-risk aversion should be given lower incentive strength to improve intensity. When the external environment is uncertain, the government should strengthen governance to select whether the benefit of the project come from the efforts of investors or the external market environment, and determine the incentive strength for investors based on this. The results also show the importance of governance mechanism, which can enhance

Figure 6. Relationship between incentives and efforts of opportunistic behavior.

6. Conclusions

In MSW disposal PPP projects, there are a series of contractual relationships and principal-agentrelationships between the government and investors. This paper analyzes the incentive mechanisms ofthe government and constructs the principal-agent models in the presence of incentives and governance.The results suggest that incentives and supervision are complementary, and the existence of the penaltywill enhance that complementarity. To ensure the sustainable development of projects and inhibitthe opportunistic behavior of investors, the government must design supervision and punishmentmechanisms to encourage investors to improve their investment level of efforts. Combining performanceincentives with process governance, and make reasonable assessment payment according to thecompletion progress of the project. Investors ensure the quality and quantity of projects completion.Taking governance measures, opportunistic behavior will be punished. Third parties can be introducedto conduct governance and establish particular governance institutions for PPP projects of MSWdisposal, online media is combined with public governance. To ensure the coordinated and sustainabledevelopment of economy, society, and environment for the PPP projects of MSW disposal, and toprevent investors from blindly pursuing economic benefits, the basic social and ecological benefitstandards must be set for the PPP project. Although this standard has no incentive, it will have anindirect impact on investors through the influence of fixed income. Investors are risk-averse andprefer a risk-free fixed income. The greater the external uncertainty, the higher the demand for afixed income. However, the proportion of fixed income, which has no incentive effect, should notbe too high when designing principal-agent contracts. The ability and resources of the investors arelimited; information asymmetry makes it impossible for the government to know the actual abilitylevel and efforts of the investors. Therefore, the government needs to select qualified partners by accessgovernance and value for money evaluation in the preparation stage of the project. The uncertainty ofthe external environment and the degree of risk aversion of investors affects the behavior of investors.When designing principal-agent contracts, the government needs to investigate the attitude of theprivate sector towards risks and the degree of uncertainty of the external environment and developdifferent incentives and governance mechanisms for different types of investors. For investors in thegrowth stage with low-risk aversion, the government should increase the incentive strength, and atthe same time, governance intensity can appropriately lower. Investors in the mature stage withhigh-risk aversion should be given lower incentive strength to improve intensity. When the externalenvironment is uncertain, the government should strengthen governance to select whether the benefitof the project come from the efforts of investors or the external market environment, and determine theincentive strength for investors based on this. The results also show the importance of governancemechanism, which can enhance the incentive effect, alleviate the “incentive failure”, and help prevent

Page 14: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 14 of 16

investors’ moral hazards. In the process of incentive governance, the government payment methodand proportion can be made transparent to attract more social capital to participate in the PPP projectsof MSW disposal and reduce the uncertainty of projects.

Author Contributions: The author X.X. designed the study and drafted the manuscript; T.X. and M.G. contributedto the research methodology and research model. All authors have read and approved the final version ofthe manuscript.

Funding: This research and the APC were funded by a Special Project of High-Quality Integrated Development atthe Yangtze River Delta.

Acknowledgments: Thank you for the efforts of anonymous reviewers and editors.

Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

1. Chong, Y.T.; Teo, K.M.; Tang, L.C. A lifecycle-based sustainability indicator framework for waste-to-energysystems and a proposed metric of sustainability. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2016, 56, 797–809. [CrossRef]

2. Wang, Y.; Zhang, X.; Liao, W.; Wu, J.; Yang, X.; Shui, W.; Deng, S.; Zhang, Y.; Lin, L.; Xiao, Y.; et al. Investigatingimpact of waste reuse on the sustainability of municipal solid waste (MSW) incineration industry usingemergy approach: A case study from Sichuan province, China. Waste Manag. 2018, 77, 252–267. [CrossRef][PubMed]

3. Wang, L.; Yan, D.; Xiong, Y.; Zhou, L. A review of the challenges and application of public–private partnershipmodel in Chinese garbage disposal industry. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 230, 219–229. [CrossRef]

4. Mian, M.M.; Zeng, X.; Nasry, A.A.N.B.; Al-Hamadani, S.M.Z.F. Municipal solid waste management in China:A comparative analysis. J. Mater. Cycles Waste Manag. 2017, 19, 1127–1135. [CrossRef]

5. Xue, W.; Cao, K.; Li, W. Municipal solid waste collection optimization in Singapore. Appl. Geogr.2015, 62, 182–190. [CrossRef]

6. Huang, J.; Zhao, R.; Huang, T.; Wang, X.; Tseng, M.-L. Sustainable municipal solid waste disposal in the beltand road initiative: A preliminary proposal for Chengdu city. Sustainability 2018, 10, 1147. [CrossRef]

7. Alwaeli, M. An overview of municipal solid waste management in Poland. The current situation, problemsand challenges. Environ. Prot. Eng. 2015, 41. [CrossRef]

8. Sofi, M.; Sabri, Y.; Zhou, Z.; Mendis, P. Transforming Municipal Solid Waste into Construction Materials.Sustainability 2019, 11, 2661. [CrossRef]

9. Chang, M.; Memon, M.A.; Imura, H. International experience of public–private partnerships for urbanenvironmental infrastructure, and its application to China. Int. Rev. Environ. Strateg. 2003, 4, 223–248.

10. Alwaeli, M. A glance at the world: Recycling of packaging waste in Poland. Waste Manag. 2009, 29, 3054–3055. [CrossRef]11. Cheng, Z.; Ke, Y.; Lin, J.; Yang, Z.; Cai, J. Spatio-temporal dynamics of public private partnership projects in

China. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2016, 34, 1242–1251. [CrossRef]12. Grimsey, D.; Lewis, M.K. Evaluating the risks of public private partnerships for infrastructure projects. Int. J.

Proj. Manag. 2002, 20, 107–118. [CrossRef]13. Gao, L.; Zhao, Z.-Y. System dynamics analysis of evolutionary game strategies between the government and

investors based on new energy power construction public–private-partnership (PPP) project. Sustainability2018, 10, 2533. [CrossRef]

14. Lenferink, S.; Tillema, T.; Arts, J. Towards sustainable infrastructure development through integrated contracts:Experiences with inclusiveness in Dutch infrastructure projects. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2013, 31, 615–627.[CrossRef]

15. Xiong, W.; Chen, B.; Wang, H.; Zhu, D. Public–private partnerships as a governance response to sustainableurbanization: Lessons from China. Habitat Int. 2020, 95, 102095. [CrossRef]

16. Wu, Y.; Li, L.; Xu, R.; Chen, K.; Hu, Y.; Lin, X. Risk assessment in straw-based power generation public–privatepartnership projects in China: A fuzzy synthetic evaluation analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 161, 977–990.[CrossRef]

17. Cong, X.; Ma, L. Performance evaluation of public–private partnership projects from the perspectiveof Efficiency, Economic, Effectiveness, and Equity: A study of residential renovation projects in China.Sustainability 2018, 10, 1951. [CrossRef]

Page 15: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 15 of 16

18. Shahbaz, M.; Raghutla, C.; Song, M.; Zameer, H.; Jiao, Z. Public–private partnerships investment in energyas new determinant of CO2 emissions: The role of technological innovations in China. Energy Econ.2020, 86, 104664. [CrossRef]

19. Liang, Q.; Hu, H.; Wang, Z.; Hou, F. A game theory approach for the renegotiation of Public–privatePartnership projects in Chinese environmental and urban governance industry. J. Clean. Prod.2019, 238, 117952. [CrossRef]

20. An, X.; Li, H.; Wang, L.; Wang, Z.; Ding, J.; Cao, Y. Compensation mechanism for urban water environmenttreatment PPP project in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 201, 246–253. [CrossRef]

21. Azapagic, A.; Perdan, S. Indicators of Sustainable Development for Industry: A General Framework.Process. Saf. Environ. Prot. 2000, 78, 243–261. [CrossRef]

22. Wang, G.W.Y.; Pallis, A.A. Incentive approaches to overcome moral hazard in port concession agreements.Transp. Res. Part. E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2014, 67, 162–174. [CrossRef]

23. Zheng, X.; Yuan, J.; Guo, J.; Skibniewski, M.J.; Zhao, S. Influence of Relational Norms on User Interests inPPP Projects: Mediating Effect of Project Performance. Sustainability 2018, 10, 2027. [CrossRef]

24. Hueskes, M.; Verhoest, K.; Block, T. Governing public–private partnerships for sustainability: An analysis of procurementand governance practices of PPP infrastructure projects. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2017, 35, 1184–1195. [CrossRef]

25. Rangel, T.; Vassallo, J.M.; Arenas, B. Effectiveness of safety-based incentives in Public Private Partnerships:Evidence from the case of Spain. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2012, 46, 1166–1176. [CrossRef]

26. Gao, L.; Zhao, Z.-Y. The Evolutionary Game of Stakeholders’ Coordination Mechanism of New EnergyPower Construction PPP Project: A China Case. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1045. [CrossRef]

27. Cumming, D. Government policy towards entrepreneurial finance: Innovation investment funds.J. Bus. Ventur. 2007, 22, 193–235. [CrossRef]

28. Ke, Y.; Wang, S.; Chan, A.P.C. Risk allocation in public–private partnership infrastructure projects:Comparative study. J. Infrastruct. Syst. 2010, 16, 343–351. [CrossRef]

29. Mohan, G.; Sinha, U.K.; Lal, M. Managing of Solid Waste through Public Private Partnership Model.Procedia Environ. Sci. 2016, 35, 158–168. [CrossRef]

30. Wu, Y.; Xu, C.; Li, L.; Wang, Y.; Chen, K.; Xu, R. A risk assessment framework of PPP waste-to-energy incinerationprojects in China under 2-dimension linguistic environment. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 183, 602–617. [CrossRef]

31. Arbulú, I.; Lozano, J.; Rey-Maquieira, J. The challenges of municipal solid waste management systemsprovided by public–private partnerships in mature tourist destinations: The case of Mallorca. Waste Manag.2016, 51, 252–258. [CrossRef] [PubMed]

32. Xiong, W.; Li, T. Evolutionary game analysis on opportunistic behavior of purchasing alliance with oversightmechanism. In Proceedings of the Chinese Control Conference, Xi’an, China, 26–28 July 2013; pp. 8000–8005.

33. Xiong, W.; Li, T. Evolutionary game analysis on opportunistic behavior of purchasing alliance with Con tract mechanism. In Proceedings of the 10th World Congress on Intelligent Control and Automation, Beijing,China, 6–8 July 2012; pp. 468–473.

34. Lan, G.; Liu, W.; Sun, J. Analysis and Precaution Research of the Opportunistic Behaviors in PurchasingAlliances. In Proceedings of the 2013 International Conference on Psychology, Management and SocialScience(PMSS 2013), Shenzhen, China, 23–24 January 2013; p. 318.

35. Bjärstig, T. Does collaboration lead to sustainability? a study of public–private partnerships in the Swedishmountains. Sustainability 2017, 9, 1685. [CrossRef]

36. Bai, L.; Li, Y.; Du, Q.; Xu, Y. A fuzzy comprehensive evaluation model for sustainability risk evaluation ofPPP projects. Sustainability 2017, 9, 1890. [CrossRef]

37. Du, J.; Wu, H.; Zhao, X. Critical factors on the capital structure of public–private partnership projects:A sustainability perspective. Sustainability 2018, 10, 2066. [CrossRef]

38. Baron, D.P.; Besanko, D. Regulation and information in a continuing relationship. Inf. Econ. Policy1984, 1, 267–302. [CrossRef]

39. Tsai, W.T.; Chou, Y.H. Government policies for encouraging industrial waste reuse and pollution preventionin Taiwan. J. Clean. Prod. 2004, 12, 725–736. [CrossRef]

40. Ho, S.P. Model for financial renegotiation in public–private partnership projects and its policy implications:Game theoretic view. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2006, 132, 678–688. [CrossRef]

41. Schmidt, E.K. Research management and policy: Incentives and obstacles to a better public–private interaction.Int. J. Public Sect. Manag. 2008, 21, 623–636. [CrossRef]

Page 16: Incentive Mechanism for Municipal Solid Waste Disposal PPP

Sustainability 2020, 12, 7686 16 of 16

42. Shi, S.; Yang, M. Internal contract governance incentives and flexible incentive mechanism in urbaninfrastructure PPP projects. J. Cent. South. Univ. 2011, 17, 155–160.

43. Lohmann, C.; Rötzel, P.G. Opportunistic Behavior in Renegotiations Between Public–private Partnershipsand Government Institutions: Data on Public–private Partnerships of the German Armed Forces. Int. PublicManag. J. 2014, 17, 387–410. [CrossRef]

44. Liu, J.; Gao, R.; Cheah, C.Y.J.; Luo, J. Incentive mechanism for inhibiting investors’ opportunistic behavior inPPP projects. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2016, 34, 1102–1111. [CrossRef]

45. Li, S.; Cai, H. Government incentive impacts on private investment behaviors under demand uncertainty.Transp. Res. Part. E: Logist. Transp. Rev. 2017, 101, 115–129. [CrossRef]

46. Wang, Y.; Cui, P.; Liu, J. Analysis of the risk-sharing ratio in PPP projects based on government minimumrevenue guarantees. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2018, 36, 899–909. [CrossRef]

47. Li, P.; Liu, J.; Wei, C. A Dynamic Decision Making Method Based on GM (1, 1) Model with PythagoreanFuzzy Numbers for Selecting Waste Disposal Enterprises. Sustainability 2019, 11, 5557. [CrossRef]

48. Holmstrom, B.; Milgrom, P. Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives.Econom. J. Econom. Soc. 1987, 55, 303–328. [CrossRef]

49. Holmstrom, B.; Milgrom, P. Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and jobdesign. JL Econ. Org. 1991, 7, 24. [CrossRef]

50. Baker, G.P. Incentive Contracts and Performance Measurement. J. Political Econ. 1992, 100, 598–614. [CrossRef]51. Baker, G.; Gibbons, R.; Murphy, K.J. Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts.

Q. J. Econ. 1994, 109, 1125–1156. [CrossRef]52. Mohamed, K.A.; Khoury, S.S.; Hafez, S.M. Contractor’s decision for bid profit reduction within opportunistic

bidding behavior of claims recovery. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2011, 29, 93–107. [CrossRef]53. Church, B.K.; Lynn Hannan, R.; Kuang, X. Information Acquisition and Opportunistic Behavior in Managerial

Reporting. Contemp. Account. Res. 2014, 31, 398–419. [CrossRef]54. Das, T.K.; Rahman, N. Determinants of Partner Opportunism in Strategic Alliances: A Conceptual Framework.

J. Bus. Psychol. 2010, 25, 55–74. [CrossRef]55. Lu, W.; Liang, W.; Zhang, L.; Liu, W. A novel noise reduction method applied in negative pressure wave for

pipeline leakage localization. Process. Saf. Environ. Prot. 2016, 104, 142–149. [CrossRef]56. Ahola, T.; Ruuska, I.; Artto, K.; Kujala, J. What is project governance and what are its origins?

Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2014, 32, 1321–1332. [CrossRef]57. You, J.; Chen, Y.; Wang, W.; Shi, C. Uncertainty, opportunistic behavior, and governance in construction

projects: The efficacy of contracts. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2018, 36, 795–807. [CrossRef]58. Wang, G.; Xue, Y.; Skibniewski, M.J.; Song, J.; Lu, H. Analysis of private investors conduct strategies

by governments supervising public–private partnership projects in the new media era. Sustainability2018, 10, 4723. [CrossRef]

59. Lu, P.; Guo, S.; Qian, L.; He, P.; Xu, X. The effectiveness of contractual and relational governances inconstruction projects in China. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2015, 33, 212–222. [CrossRef]

60. Feng, Z.; Zhang, S.-B.; Gao, Y. Modeling the impact of government guarantees on toll charge, road quality andcapacity for Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT) road projects. Transp. Res. Part A-Policy Pract. 2015, 78, 54–67. [CrossRef]

61. Holmström, B. Managerial incentive problems: A dynamic perspective. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1999, 66, 169–182. [CrossRef]62. Xiang, P.; Wang, J. Research on Preventing Moral Hazard of Construction Project Based on Information

Asymmetries. Open Constr. Build. Technol. J. 2014, 8, 468–475. [CrossRef]63. Ren, M.; Liu, C. A Supervision Contract Design of Electronic Products Manufacturers Controlling E-waste

Pollution at Source under the Government and Consumers Supervising. Int. J. U-E-Serv. Sci. Technol.2013, 6, 27–40.

64. Wang, X.; Li, S.; Yang, H.; Shen, Y. Study on dynamic incentive contracts in telecom business innovation withwin-win consideration. J. Syst. Eng. 2011, 26, 671–678.

© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open accessarticle distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution(CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).


Top Related