drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in italy -...

25
1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 1 Luigi Cembalo, Francesco Caracciolo, Eugenio Pomarici 2 Department of Agricultural Economics and Policy - University of Naples Federico II, Italy 3 Corresponding author: Luigi Cembalo 4 Via Università 96, 5 80055 Portici (Naples), Italy 6 e-mail: [email protected] 7 Tel. +39 081 2539065 8 Fax. +39 081 7755143 9 10 Abstract. The wine market has evolved dramatically over the last three decades. The premium wine 11 segment has expanded significantly to the detriment of basic wines. Nevertheless, in traditional 12 wine producing and consuming countries, inexpensive wines still account for a large market share, 13 both in volume and value. Marketing strategies for such wines are changing in an attempt to tap this 14 increasingly crowded market segment. Despite its importance, the basic wine segment has not been 15 studied in depth, and is often assumed to have no product differentiation. This paper tried to 16 ascertain the existence of a possible degree of heterogeneity within non-premium wines and to 17 measure, by means of elasticity computation, the relationships among categories of wines 18 aggregated with criteria that go beyond price. A demand system (censored QAIDS) was estimated, 19 using a statistically representative panel of 6,773 Italian households, to see to what extent, if any, 20 substitution occurs in home consumption of basic wines, which is the main channel of distribution 21 of inexpensive wines in Italy. Although price is an important lever in supply policies, our results 22 also suggest the importance of packaging, such as carton as an alternative to glass. 23 24 Keywords: censored demand system; elasticity computation; Italian wine sector; basic wine; 25 QAIDS. 26 JEL: Q13; D12; C34 27

Upload: others

Post on 25-Oct-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

1  

Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 1 

Luigi Cembalo, Francesco Caracciolo, Eugenio Pomarici 2 

Department of Agricultural Economics and Policy - University of Naples Federico II, Italy 3 

Corresponding author: Luigi Cembalo 4 

Via Università 96, 5 

80055 Portici (Naples), Italy 6 

e-mail: [email protected]

Tel. +39 081 2539065 8 

Fax. +39 081 7755143 9 

10 

Abstract. The wine market has evolved dramatically over the last three decades. The premium wine 11 

segment has expanded significantly to the detriment of basic wines. Nevertheless, in traditional 12 

wine producing and consuming countries, inexpensive wines still account for a large market share, 13 

both in volume and value. Marketing strategies for such wines are changing in an attempt to tap this 14 

increasingly crowded market segment. Despite its importance, the basic wine segment has not been 15 

studied in depth, and is often assumed to have no product differentiation. This paper tried to 16 

ascertain the existence of a possible degree of heterogeneity within non-premium wines and to 17 

measure, by means of elasticity computation, the relationships among categories of wines 18 

aggregated with criteria that go beyond price. A demand system (censored QAIDS) was estimated, 19 

using a statistically representative panel of 6,773 Italian households, to see to what extent, if any, 20 

substitution occurs in home consumption of basic wines, which is the main channel of distribution 21 

of inexpensive wines in Italy. Although price is an important lever in supply policies, our results 22 

also suggest the importance of packaging, such as carton as an alternative to glass. 23 

24 

Keywords: censored demand system; elasticity computation; Italian wine sector; basic wine; 25 

QAIDS. 26 

JEL: Q13; D12; C34 27 

Page 2: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

2  

28 

1. Introduction 29 

In the past three decades or so, the world wine market has experienced dramatic upheavals. One 30 

of the major changes has involved the structure of wine demand (Labys & Cohen, 2006; Hannin et 31 

al., 2010; Anderson and Nelgen, 2011). In the larger traditional producing and consuming countries, 32 

Italy and France, the annual per capita consumption of wine was, until the 1970s, higher than 100 33 

litres (Corsi et al., 2004) while, in the last three decades, it has declined to between 50 and 40 litres 34 

(OIV, 2012). During the same time span in the United States the increase in the number of wine 35 

drinkers, combined with a higher per capita consumption, has pushed the aggregate national wine 36 

consumption to the same level as Italy and France. Indeed, while during the ’70s wine consumed in 37 

France and Italy accounted for 40% of world consumption, nowadays the two countries account for 38 

about 25% (Anderson & Nelgen, 2011). 39 

In traditional producing and consuming countries the dramatic change in wine quantity consumed 40 

has been accompanied by major changes in consumption habits: from a necessary component in the 41 

daily diet to non-essential to a meal (Mäkelä et al., 2006). Consumption habits in traditional and 42 

new consuming countries are converging. Expensive wines have gained a considerable market 43 

share, becoming an accessible good no longer confined to a restricted elite of consumers (Ritchie, 44 

2009). At the same time, less expensive wines are reaching a place in the market similar to that of 45 

other Fast-Moving Consumer Goods. 46 

In order to have a clearer overview of the wine market, its characteristic high price range also 47 

deserves mention. This peculiarity has called for the development of commercial terminology to 48 

define different product categories based on specific price ranges. In the wine trade it is common to 49 

distinguish wines into two broad classes according to price category: non-premium, less expensive 50 

wines with basic quality characteristics; and premium, more expensive wines with complex quality 51 

characteristics and a high-value image (Anderson & Nelgen, 2011). In light of the absolute increase 52 

and relative importance of more expensive wines, a more detailed classification has been made in 53 

Page 3: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

3  

the wine business, dividing premium wines into sub categoriesi (Ernst and Young Entrepreneurs, 54 

1999; Rabobank, 2003; Costanigro et al., 2007). Nevertheless, a pan-national segmentation of the 55 

wine market is complex and any estimation of the market share in each category, in aggregate terms 56 

or per country, is no trivial task (Steenkamp & Ter Hofstede, 2002). However, estimation has been 57 

attempted according to a three-category classification of wine supply for 2009: non-premium, 58 

commercial premium and superpremium (Anderson & Nelgen, 2011)ii. Non-premium wines 59 

account for only one-seventh of the global wine trade in value (US$7 billion) but almost half in 60 

volume terms. It seems evident that non-premium winesiii represent a sizeable part in the world 61 

wine market. Together with the search for increasing value for products, this is one of the main 62 

reasons why suppliers are still hugely interested in the market for non-premium wines (Ritchie, 63 

2009). 64 

Despite the importance of non-premium wines, very few studies have specifically investigated this 65 

segment (Torrisi et al., 2006). One possible reason explaining this lack of coverage could be the 66 

presumption that, in a wine category with a narrow price range, there is almost perfect homogeneity 67 

due to wines with simple intrinsic attributes, little quality complexity, and hence not much 68 

differentiation. However, observation of the current supply shows a wide variety of products and 69 

various supplier’s marketing styles. Therefore, in-depth investigation of basic wine is of paramount 70 

importance to better understand how key parameters combine. A study is thus called for to explore 71 

the needs and motivations sustaining the demand for non-premium wines. Beside a large number of 72 

studies concerning the demand side on premium wines, or alcohol in general (Gallet, 2007; Davis et 73 

al., 2008; Gil & Molina, 2009; Panzone, 2012), the literature on demand for basic wines appears to 74 

be almost completely lacking. In this perspective, the objective of this paper is to ascertain the 75 

existence of a possible degree of heterogeneity within non-premium wines and to measure, by 76 

means of elasticity computation, the relationships among categories of wines aggregated with 77 

criteria that go beyond price. 78 

Page 4: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

4  

Studies of non-expensive wines have to be country-specific for two reasons. First, markets for non-79 

premium wines have average selling prices that differ because of different import tariffs and 80 

consumer taxes (Anderson & Nelgen, 2011); second, consumer product perception varies on a 81 

country by country basis (Mäkelä et al., 2006). The focus of this study was Italyiv. Together with 82 

France, Italy has the largest traditional wine consumption market, and the variety of strategies 83 

adopted by suppliers is one of the widest: suppliers seek to capture customer interests by looking at 84 

all intrinsic and extrinsic product attributes and working on communication and distribution 85 

(Bernetti et al., 2006). Although all these aspects of supply are important (Fraser, 2005; Amadieu & 86 

Viviani, 2011), pricing in a market with very small margins assumes great importance and the 87 

availability of appropriate information to support price fine-tuning is therefore crucial. 88 

The empirical strategy adopted was based on two steps. The first consisted in collecting information 89 

directly interviewing key informants to delineate the driving factors of supply on Italian retail 90 

shelves. Such factors allowed us to classify wines within the non-premium category using wine 91 

business driven criteria (e.g. labelling, types of packaging, and price). The second step was to 92 

estimate a demand system on a statistically representative sample of Italian households provided by 93 

AC-Nielsen. Demand system estimates based on micro data may suffer several biases. The main 94 

risks come from the violation of theoretical regularity restrictions (Barnett & Serletis, 2008) and 95 

from sample selection bias due to only a fraction of the population that has nonzero consumption 96 

for the items under study. Our model explicitly avoids the latter drawback, estimating a two-step 97 

censored demand system (Shonkwiler & Yen, 1999) based on the quadratic AIDS (Banks et al., 98 

1997). 99 

100 

2. The wine market in Italy 101 

2.1 Essential data for the Italian wine sector 102 

In order to illustrate the economic relevance of the overall Italian wine sector, a few essential 103 

figures are provided. Total Italian wine output has a value of nearly 8.2 billion euros: as a producer, 104 

Page 5: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

5  

exporter and consumer, Italy is top of the world ranking. In 2011, Italian wine production was 44 105 

million hectolitres, about 23 million of which was exported, for a value of 4.5 billion euros. Imports 106 

are rather small: in 2011 Italy imported about 2.3 million hectolitres, for a value of 300 million 107 

euros (Mediobanca, 2012)v. 108 

Italian wine production represents about 15% of world supply in volume and 13% in value. 109 

Italian wine exports represent 24% of world exports in volume and 18% in value (Anderson & 110 

Nelgen, 2011; OIV, 2012). Considering only non-premium wines Italy contributes, in value terms, 111 

about 18% to global supply and 16% to world export; such percentages demonstrate to what extent 112 

the Italian wine industry has invested in the non-premium wine business. 113 

Domestic consumption accounts for about 23 million hectolitres consumed by a substantial 114 

wine-drinking population, representing 54% of Italy’s total population (ISTAT, 2011; OIV, 2012). 115 

Wine purchased for at-home drinking (WAH) accounts for the largest slice of the wine market: 116 

about 70% of the total consumption in volume, and 30% in expenditure. WAH is supplied by many 117 

channels but the most important, in terms of volume, are the supermarket chains which sell about 118 

70% of wine (Mediobanca, 2011; Pomarici et al., 2012). The remaining percentage is purchased in 119 

neighbourhood grocery stores and wine shops, while direct purchase at wineries occurs especially in 120 

rural areas. The difference between the consumption figures in volume (70%) and in value (30%) 121 

highlights the extent to which cheap wine consumption is concentrated at home. 122 

123 

2.2 Data description and categorization of WAH consumption of wine in Italy 124 

Wine for at-home drinking can be investigated using scanner data from consumer panels. The 125 

data used in this study were provided by the AC-Nielsen home scan, a statistically representative 126 

panel of Italian households. Households involved in the Nielsen panel regularly record their 127 

purchases through a scanner (ConsumerScan). The data analysed thus consist of household wine 128 

expenditure at grocery stores (including neighbourhood and specialized grocery stores, convenience 129 

stores, small and large retail outlets), and are representative of Italian consumption of WAHvi. The 130 

Page 6: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

6  

information collected concerns value (euro), volume (litres) and the main extrinsic attributes of 131 

WAH purchases made by 6,773 Italian households (for a total of 71,760 purchases of 6,251 132 

different types of wines from 956 wine producers) during 2010 (from January to December). The 133 

6,251 types of wines recorded in the AC-Nielsen database need to be aggregated in fewer 134 

categories. However, any aggregation of wines belonging to the non-premium wines needs the 135 

criteria to be identified as objectively as possible. This applies even more if one considers that this 136 

segment is of great complexity due, for example, to a broad variety of brands, packaging, 137 

production areas, possible origin labels and grape variety certifications. Nevertheless, the literature 138 

contains no indication on non-premium wine categorization. Our study attempts to identify criteria 139 

for aggregating non-premium wines which allow homogeneous categories to be obtained. The 140 

empirical approach used was to proceed according to the same principles with which the supply of 141 

more economical wines is structured on the shelves of large retailers, which is the main site of 142 

purchase of packaged economical wines. Interviews were carried out with wine marketing experts. 143 

The sales director of Gruppo Italiano Vini S.p.A. (top Italian group by sales) and the director of 144 

commercial relations with large retailers at Marchesi dè Frescobaldi (one of the top 15 companies 145 

in Italy by turnover) were involved in an in-depth semi-structured interview in autumn 2011. The 146 

interviews, carried out individually with each of the two interviewees, were preceded by sending 147 

out the subject of the interview. On the basis of the interview results we developed an aggregation 148 

scheme of the single non-premium products sold in Italy. The results of this scheme were submitted 149 

to a third expert for final verification, director of the Gruppo CEVICO of relations with large 150 

distributors (Cevico is one of the top 15 Italian companies by turnover). The results can be 151 

summarized as follows. Key informants indicated the threshold that defines non-premium wines as 152 

3 euro/litrevii. Starting from this information, the distribution of WAH consumption by price, 153 

divided into non-premium and premium, from AC-Nielsen home scan data, is shown in table 1. 154 

Wine sold under 3 euro/litre represents nearly 60% of the total value and about two-thirds of the 155 

total volumeviii. 156 

Page 7: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

7  

Table 1. Premium and non-premium Italian distribution of wines 157 

Price classes (€/litre)

Share on

expenditure (%)

Share on

volume (%)

Non-premium wines (<3 euro) 58 67

Premium wines (>3 euro) 42 33

Total 100 100

Source: authors’ calculations based on data from A.C Nielsen (2010) 158 

In addition, the key informants all agreed that the critical factors behind the diversification of the 159 

supply of non-premium wines on the shelves are as follows: (i) packaging; (ii) branding; (iii) price. 160 

Packaging is currently an element of supply diversification as it is the field where many producers 161 

have explored the way to add value to wine with significant innovations able to improve the service 162 

delivered to the client and, at times, perception of sustainability. Such innovations have concerned 163 

the material of containers, mainly introducing the carton, as an alternative to glass bottles. As for 164 

the branding criterion, the key informants all agreed that a shelf must contain the market leader and 165 

the private labels, together with a set of wines with only locally recognizable brands. Concerning 166 

the third criterion, the shelf is formed to cover all price ranges in order to give any consumer the 167 

possibility of choosing a product based on his/her own preferences/budget. In particular, the range 168 

has to contain wines with a unit price ranging from 2 to 3 euro/litre, with characteristics that 169 

emulate premium wines, and wines with a unit price below 2 euro/litre, which typically have the 170 

profile of convenience products. The supply of non-premium wines on the shelves also appears 171 

diversified for other elements such as wine colour and certification category (e.g. Denomination of 172 

Controlled Origin or DOC, and Typical Geographic Indication or IGT). However, these elements 173 

were not indicated by the experts as being major factors in forming the assortment of winesix. 174 

The categorization scheme potentially yields 18 categories of wines: 2 packaging types (glass and 175 

carton); 3 levels of branding (market leader, private label, and others); 3 price levels (below 2 176 

€/litre, between 2 and 3 €/litre, above 3 €/litre). However, the information gathered by the experts 177 

Page 8: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

8  

has to be matched with, or confirmed by, the actual consumption data available in the AC-Nielsen 178 

dataset. Among the set of types/levels, the one that has to be explicitly identified in the AC-Nielsen 179 

dataset is the market leader. According to the market share in volume, Caviro can doubtless be 180 

considered the market leader with the highest market share in volume terms (12.5%); all other 181 

competitors show a market share lower than 1.51% (Table 2). Caviro mainly promotes two brands, 182 

Tavernello and Castellino, both sold in cartons, with an intense pull strategy, using TV and media 183 

advertising extensively. The main theme in advertising is the integrity and safety of the wine as a 184 

result of strict controls over every link in the supply chain, from vineyard management and 185 

winemaking through packaging and marketing, ensuring consistent quality throughout the entire 186 

process. 187 

188 

Table 2. Top four firms of the Italian wine-at-home market 189 

Wine brand Market share

in volume (%)

Mean

price

(€/litre)

Caviro 12.48 1.42

Conad 1.51 1.39

Soldo 1.41 1.48

San Matteo 1.32 1.58

Source: authors’ calculations based on data from A.C Nielsen (2010) 190 

191 

Private labels are those supplied by using the names of big distribution chains. The number of 192 

private labels available in the Nielsen database is 30, and the brands with the highest market share 193 

are Conad, Carrefour, COOP, GS, and LD. The 30 private labelled wines account for 7.89% in 194 

terms of market share (in volume terms) and are sold at an average price of 0.98 euro/litre, mainly 195 

in carton packaging. A summary of statistics from the AC-Nielsen dataset, organized by criteria 196 

Page 9: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

9  

suggested by experts, is shown in table 3. Some categories of wines are represented in small 197 

percentages. The criterion used to aggregate products was to consider, as a single category, those 198 

products represented in at least 2% in terms of market share (in volume terms). Those categories 199 

below that threshold were aggregated into the neighbouring category. 200 

201 

Tab. 3 - Summary statistics of wines organized by experts’ 202 

suggested criteria (volume %) 203 

Price categories (€/litre)

< 2 2 < . < 3 > 3

CARTON

Caviro* 11.79 - -

Private Label 6.08 - -

Other 14.86 0.02 0.02

GLASS

Caviro* 0.69 - -

Private Label 1.81 0.20 0.60

Other 24.10 12.64 27.19

Total 59.33 12.86 27.81

Source: authors’ calculations based on data from AC-Nielsen (2010) 204 

* Caviro is the market leader that sells wines almost exclusively in carton packaging 205 

206 

From the merging of information collected from experts and the Nielsen data we aggregated the 207 

products into categories. The outcome is an ex-ante categorization of the non-premium wine 208 

market. The whole set of wines contained in the AC-Nielsen dataset was therefore subdivided into 209 

six categories. Thus the WAH market becomes divided into the following categories: 210 

wines sold in carton at an average price below 2 euro/litre: 211 

Page 10: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

10  

- Market Leader (ML): Caviro wines; 212 

- Private Labels (PL): private label brand wines; 213 

- Other wines in Cartons (OC): wines with no specific or recognisable brand; 214 

wines sold in glass (bottle of 0.75 litre), one for each of the price categories: 215 

- Other wines below 2 euro/litre (BG: Basic Glass); 216 

- Other wines between 2 and 3 euro/litre (TB: Top Basic); 217 

- Other wines over 3 euro/litre (PW: Premium wines). 218 

This categorization permits analysis of brand-specific relationships among basic wines while jointly 219 

evaluating the role of packaging and price. Table 4 provides volumes (litres) and expenditure (euro) 220 

of wine as grouped according to the above market categorization. 221 

Table 4. Consumption, expenditure share and purchase frequency by wine category 222 

Mean

expenditure (%)

Household

purch (%)

Mean litre

consumption (%)

Market Leader (ML) 12 32 14

Private Label (PL) 6 22 8

Other wines carton (OC) 12 35 15

Other wines glass below 2 € (BG) 16 41 18

Other wines glass between 2 and 3 € (TB) 12 40 12

Premium wines over 3 € (PW) 42 61 33

Total 100

Source: authors’ calculations based on data from A.C Nielsen (2010) 223 

224 

3. Empirical model specification 225 

In this section we present the empirical model adopted to estimate the demand system. A 226 

Quadratic Almost Ideal Demand System (QAIDS) was implemented. The use of a model allowing a 227 

more general Engel curve shape than the popular Almost Ideal Demand System (AIDS) of Deaton 228 

& Muellbauer (1980) was required. The reasons are well rooted in the literature. In particular, 229 

Page 11: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

11  

Banks et al. (1997) show that the demand for some goods, particularly alcohol and clothing, has a 230 

quadratic relationship with the logarithm of total expenditure at higher income levels. For the above 231 

reason, they propose a quadratic logarithmic expenditure share system (QUAIDS), directly derived 232 

from the AIDS. This specification is spreading rapidly and was used, for example, by Moro and 233 

Sckokai (2000) to estimate food expenditure in Italy, and by Blundell and Robin (1999) and Fisher 234 

et al. (2001) to estimate food consumption in, respectively, the UK and USA. 235 

The QUAIDS stochastic representation of the system of equations for the budget share wi of the ith 236 

good (wine) is as follows: 237 

∑=

+⎭⎬⎫

⎩⎨⎧

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡++=

J

ji

iijijii u

am

bamPw

1

2

* )(ln

)()(lnln

pppλ

βγα { Ii ,,1K=∀ 238 

where *ia is the intercept of the model expressed as a linear function of some socio-economic and 239 

demographic attributes (residence, age, income class). It serves to assess the potential differences in 240 

household preferences and behaviour (Deaton and Muellbauer, 1980): 241 

∑=

+=K

kkikii Daa

1* δ { Ii ,,1K=∀ 242 

(2) 243 

where δi,k represents the contribution of the k-th characteristics of the households on the intercept of 244 

the i-th equation representing a category of wine. 245 

γij are the parameters to be estimated of prices Pj related to the j-th good (wine). βi are the total 246 

expenditure (m) parameters to be estimated, while λi represent the quadratic terms of expenditure. 247 

ln a(p) has the translog form: 248 

∑∑∑= ==

++=n

ij

n

jiij

I

iii PPPa

1 11*0 lnln

21ln)(ln γααp

(3) 249 

b(p) is the Cobb-Douglas price aggregator: 250 

∏=

=n

ii

iPb1

)( βp

(4) 251 

Page 12: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

12  

Finally, ui are the error terms. 252 

Information on prices paid by each household for the i-th wine is provided through unit values 253 

(€/litre) in order to generate a volume-weighted average of the category price. As suggested by 254 

Deaton and Zaidi (2002), the unavailable prices due to household non-consumption of the listed 255 

category were imputed by the median of the reported price by the purchasers, differentiating the 256 

value per region of residence and the household’s income class. 257 

Due to incomplete information of household consumption and budget allocation in the data 258 

generating process (DGP), a consumer multi-stage budgeting process was considered. It implies 259 

home consumption of wine as strictly separable from the demand for other goods. This hypothesis 260 

justifies the exclusion of expenditure on other goods for which data are not fully available. The 261 

assumption is reasonable if the estimation objectives are restricted to understanding consumption 262 

substitutability in the same food category: in this case it is non-premium wines. 263 

From an empirical point of view, according to the established consensus, demand system estimates 264 

based on household cross-sectional data can be cumbersome on several grounds. One of these is 265 

that household consumption variables are censored at zero. In demand studies using cross-sectional 266 

micro-data the zero-food consumption problem is a frequent issue; only a subset of households 267 

shows a positive consumption for the i-th good (wine) during the selected observation period. In the 268 

investigated wine demand system, percentages of zero-food consumption (censoring) are 269 

substantial: Private Label wines are consumed by 22% of households, Other Wines over 3 €/litre by 270 

61%. Since the seminal work of Heien and Wessels (1990), several empirical procedures for 271 

censored data have been developed such as those suggested by Perali and Chavas (2000), Golan et 272 

al. (2001) and Shonkwiler and Yen (1999). The latter approach is that commonly used in the 273 

literature (Akbay et al., 2007). Shonkwiler and Yen (1999) modelled zero-food consumption for a 274 

demand system of I equations as below: 275 

276 

Page 13: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

13  

iiiiiiiii emww ++Φ= )()();,(* zθzθΓp φτ { Ii ,,1K=∀ (5) 277 

and 278 

( )

⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡ −+

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎠⎞⎜

⎝⎛−+=

)ˆ()(

ˆ);,(

iiiii

iiiiiii ΦΦmwue

θzzθ

θzzθΓp

φφτ { Ii ,,1K=∀ (6) 279 

where Γi is a vector containing system demand parameters, z is a vector of exogenous variables, θi 280 

is a conformable vector of parameters, )ˆ( ii θzφ and )ˆ( ii θzΦ are the probability density function 281 

(PDF) and the cumulative distribution function (CDF), respectively. Estimation of equation 5 can 282 

be performed in two steps, where in the first step the maximum-likelihood probit estimates of 283 

)ˆ( ii θzφ and )ˆ( ii θzΦ are obtained using equation 7: 284 

y*=(zθi +νi) { Ii ,,1K=∀ (7) 285 

with νi the random errors and 286 

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

>=

00

01*

*

i

ii yif

yify { Ii ,,1K=∀ (8) 287 

and then estimating Γi and τi in the augmented system where 288 

wi*=yi wi

{ Ii ,,1K=∀ . (9) 289 

Equation 1 therefore becomes: 290 

( ) iiiiii

J

j

iijijiii e

am

bamPwy ++Φ

⎪⎪⎭

⎪⎪⎬

⎪⎪⎩

⎪⎪⎨

⎪⎭

⎪⎬⎫

⎪⎩

⎪⎨⎧

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡+

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡++= ∑

=

)()(

ln)()(

lnln1

2

* zθzθppp

φτλβγα { Ii ,,1K=∀

(10)

291 

To estimate the above system of I equations, a non-linear Feasible Generalized Least Square 292 

(FGLS) (Davidson & MacKinnon, 2004) estimating technique was followed, following the 293 

recommendations of Tauchmann (2005): it efficiently manages the heteroskedasticity introduced in 294 

the model estimate by the error term when using Shonkwiler and Yen’s (1999) approach. For the 295 

Page 14: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

14  

same reason, as in the single-equation case due to the downward bias of the population variance, 296 

standard errors were calculated by using the bootstrap method. Only socio-economic and 297 

demographic characteristics were included among the explanatory variables z in the selection 298 

equations (eq. 7), as suggested by Yen and Lin (2006). 299 

The economic theory provides a set of restrictions that are known as homogeneity, adding-up and 300 

symmetry. The symmetry and homogeneity conditions are respectively imposed by: 301 

γij= γji ∀ i,j= 1,…, I; (11) 302 

and 303 

∑ =j

ij 0γ ∀ i,j= 1,…, I. (12) 304 

Using the above specifications, the maximum-likelihood estimation of variance-covariance matrix 305 

of the residuals is not singular (determinant not equal to zero). Therefore the adding-up condition is 306 

not a-priori imposed by the share format of demand systems as usually happens. Estimation of the 307 

complete system (without the deletion of an equation) was performed (Drichoutis et al., 2008). 308 

309 

4. Empirical results 310 

The complete list of explanatory variables included in the demand system is reported in table 5. The 311 

average prices of wine categories have a limited variability (SD), expecting a considerable degree 312 

of substitutability or complementarity among wines of different categories, except for the Other 313 

Wines category insofar as it contains wines at over 3 euros/litre. The presence of the latter category 314 

in the model, though lying outside the specific objectives in this paper, ensures a higher degree of 315 

completeness in representing the demand system. In the model the purchasers are characterised by 316 

means of some socioeconomic variables (δi,k:1to9) directly obtained from information contained in 317 

the database used (income classes, age classes, place of residence) and behavioural variables 318 

constructed ad hoc (tendency to purchase in discount stores and to purchase red wines, wines from 319 

the region of residency and certification of origin wines). These are important elements that directly 320 

Page 15: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

15  

or indirectly reflect different consumption habits. Their introduction in the model thus allows the 321 

heterogeneity of wine purchasers to be represented in the analysis. 322 

323 

Table 5. Description of variables used in the food demand system 324 

Parameters Variables Mean SD

γi,j:ML Price of Market Leader (ML) 1.42 0.14

γi,j:PL Price of Private Label (PL) 0.98 0.16

γi,j:OC Price of Other Wines Carton (OC) 1.03 0.27

γi,j:BG Price of Other Wines basic glass (BG) 1.59 0.40

γi,j:TB Price of Other Wines top basic glass (TB) 2.47 0.36

γi,j:PW Price of Premium Wines over €3 (PW) 5.22 2.00

βi Total wine expenditure of the household (€/year) 67.36 112.36

δi,k:1 Share of household purchases in “discount” stores 0.10 0.25

δi,k:2 Share of household purchases for local wine 0.25 0.32

δi,k:3 Income class (1 low – 4 high) 2.51 0.98

δi,k:4 Age class of the household head (1 young – 5 old) 3.09 1.21

δi,k:5 1 if the household lives in North-East Italy 0.19 0.39

δi,k:6 1 if the household lives in Southern Italy 0.28 0.45

δi,k:7 1 if the household lives in North-West Italy 0.30 0.46

δi,k:8 Share of household purchases for “red wine” 0.50 0.37

δi,k:9 Share of household purchases for certificated wine 0.36 0.36

325 

The demand model estimation results are shown in Table 6. Starting from the bottom of the table, 326 

coefficients τi and λi are respectively the probability density function estimated parameter and 327 

quadratic component of equation (10) estimated parameter. 328 

329 

Page 16: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

16  

Table 6. Demand system parameter estimation and t-ratios 330 

Market

Leader

Private

Label

Other Wines

Carton

Other wines

Basic Glass

Other wines

Top B. Glass

Premium

wines over

3€

i,j: ML t-stat PL t-stat OC t-stat BG t-stat TB t-stat PW t-stat

αi 0.872 9.80 0.058 0.62 -1.784 -8.44 0.177 1.58 -0.388 -2.04 0.689 28.73

γi,j:ML -1.352 -4.99

γi,j:PL 0.231 2.87 -0.069 -3.75

γi,j:OC 0.338 12.36 -0.154 -5.11 0.038 1.72

γi,j:BG 0.369 2.81 0.127 8.00 -0.007 -0.41 -1.023 -1.13

γi,j:TB 0.588 4.59 0.017 0.81 -0.247 -9.71 0.046 2.26 -0.361 5.31

γi,j:PW -0.175 -25.89 -0.152 -1.72 0.032 -10.29 0.488 -3.85 -0.043 -4.01 -0.149 25.72

βi -0.028 -1.65 0.099 7.98 -0.222 -7.54 0.076 5.33 0.006 0.56 0.022 3.14

δi,k:1 -0.102 -1.81 0.101 2.37 -0.093 -1.93 -0.202 -2.47 0.176 4.26 -0.127 -5.98

δi,k:2 0.142 4.48 0.028 1.11 -1.176 -14.43 -0.088 -1.76 0.105 3.37 -0.063 -5.24

δi,k:3 0.030 3.18 -0.028 -3.35 -0.078 -5.69 -0.012 -1.37 -0.007 -1.00 0.003 0.79

δi,k:4 -0.044 -6.27 0.010 1.34 0.062 5.27 0.008 0.94 0.025 3.19 -0.010 -3.45

δi,k:5 0.151 5.10 -0.030 -0.95 -0.048 -1.29 0.115 4.43 -0.109 -3.32 0.061 6.53

δi,k:6 0.125 4.53 0.056 3.06 0.065 2.07 0.068 1.93 0.008 0.37 0.009 0.86

δi,k:7 -0.002 -0.11 -0.003 -0.17 -0.049 -1.51 0.075 3.34 -0.002 -0.14 0.008 0.95

δi,k:8 -0.101 -3.55 0.104 2.65 -0.170 -4.75 -0.219 -7.07 0.200 3.36 -0.085 -7.41

δi,k:9 0.223 2.28 -0.278 -8.14 -1.858 -12.22 -0.862 -8.32 0.120 2.70 0.139 8.25

λi 0.002 0.61 -0.013 -5.42 0.044 8.11 -0.017 -6.26 -0.002 -1.14 -0.003 -2.09

τi -0.081 -1.11 0.068 1.45 0.000 0.01 -0.216 -4.00 0.02 0.71 -0.019 -0.46

331 

Page 17: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

17  

As for the latter, the statistical significance of the coefficient in five equations over six implemented 332 

confirms the appropriateness of a quadratic form of the demand system. Coefficients δi,k represent 333 

socio-demographic characteristics. They show the major importance of socio-demographics proved 334 

by the level of significance reached for the most part. From the sign of the estimated parameters we 335 

may also make an initial inference on the average consumer profile for each category of wine 336 

analysed. As regards the Market Leader wine (coefficients δML,k:1to9 reported in the first column to 337 

the left in table 6), it may be inferred that the typical consumer in this wine category is someone 338 

who has a low purchasing share at discount stores (δML,k:1 -0.102), who prefers regional wines (δML,k:2 339 

0.142), who tends to be in a higher income class (δML,k:3 0.030), is younger (δML,k:4 -0.044), resides in 340 

north-east or southern Italy (δML,k:5 0.151 and δML,k:6 0.125), who prefers white wine (δML,k:8 -0.101), 341 

and who prefers certified wines (δML,k:9 0.223). It is also worth pointing out the estimated 342 

coefficients of the variables “income class” (δi,k:3) and “age class of the household head” (δi,k:4) for 343 

the categories “Market Leader (ML)” and “Premium Wines over 3€ (PW)”. As regards the former 344 

(δi,k:3) the sign is positive (δML,k:3=0.030 and δPW,k:3=0.003x) while it is negative for all the other wine 345 

categories. For the latter (δi,k:4) the sign is negative (respectively δML,k:4=-0.044 and δPW,k:4=-0.010) 346 

while it is positive for all the other categories. This allows us to state that the market leader 347 

(Caviro), which invests significantly in marketing, and wines with a higher price than 3 euro/litre 348 

(PW) attract the same consumer type, who can be depicted as younger with a higher disposable 349 

income, geared to the purchase also of wines in a higher price bracket. 350 

The effect of prices will be discussed after calculation of elasticities. From estimating the 351 

parameters of prices (γi,j) and expenditure (βi) of equation (10) we obtained Marshallian elasticity 352 

values for prices (direct ηi,i and cross ηi,j) using the procedure suggested by Yen et al. (2002): 353 

(13) 354 

355 

ηi,i =∂wi

∂Pi

Φi zθ̂i( ) / wi −1

Page 18: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

18  

(14) 356 

357 

The elasticities thus calculated are reported in table 7, where along the row we may read the effect 358 

on the quantity consumed of the i-th wine category of the change in price of the j-th wine 359 

represented in the column. The directly estimated elasticities reported along the main diagonal of 360 

the table show that demand for each of the six product categories considered in the analysis reacts 361 

to price variations in a different way, albeit within a limited range for all categories varying from -362 

1.18 to -1.50. The only exception is the “Other Wines Carton (OC)”, a category which, with a value 363 

of -3.04, describes a particularly elastic behaviour of demand. At the same time, one product 364 

category –Market Leader– has a fairly low elasticity. 365 

These differences show the effectiveness of being a market leader, which ensures a lower degree of 366 

vulnerability to price variations. The marketing implemented by Caviro is also effective with regard 367 

to basic wines sold in glass bottles (both BG and TB), although the latter benefit from a higher 368 

degree of market penetration (Tab. 4). The cross elasticities, in turn, show a very complex picture of 369 

substitution trends with rare cases of reciprocity. Brand cartons (Market Leader and Private Label) 370 

and non-brand cartons (Other Wine Cartons, OC) show a fairly differentiated demand behaviour in 371 

terms of substitution. Brand cartons are substituted by wine in glass: the Market Leader is 372 

substituted by more costly wines (PW), even if the opposite does not hold at the same magnitude; 373 

Private Label wines tend to be substituted mainly by top basic glass bottles (TB), also in this case 374 

without reciprocity. Other Wine Cartons (OC), whose demand is very price-sensitive, have various 375 

(fairly high) coefficients of cross elasticity, although the most frequent substitution is with Private 376 

Label wines. Basic Wines in glass bottles (BG) tend to be substituted mainly by Private Label wines 377 

(PL) - in this case one of the few cases of reciprocity occurs – or by more costly wines in glass 378 

bottles (PW). 379 

380 

ηi, j =∂wi

∂Pj

Φi zθ̂i( ) / wi

Page 19: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

19  

Table 7. Price elasticities 381 

ML

PL

OC

BG

TB

PW

Market Leader (ML) -1.18** -0.05** -0.24*** 0.10* -0.29* 0.60**

Private Label (PL) -0.27** -1.44*** 0.18*** 0.31*** 0.94 -0.41

Other W. Carton (OC) 0.54*** 1.92*** -3.04* 0.79 1.78 -2.13***

Other W. Basic Glass (BG) 0.13* 0.30** -0.06 -1.38* -0.20*** 0.34***

Other W. Top Basic Glass (TB) 0.33* 0.04 0.39 0.18 -1.50** -0.57*

Premium Wines over 3€ (PW) 0.13*** 0.29* 0.02*** 0.05*** -0.06*** -1.37***

The elasticities in the jth column indicate the change in the demand for all i goods as the jth good's price changes. 382 

Bootstrap estimate of the significance level: * p<0.10; **p<0.05; ***p<0.01 383 

384 

Top basic glass (TB) wines tend to be substituted by Market Leader (ML) or by non-brand cartons 385 

(OC), there being another example of reciprocity. Lastly, Premium wines (PW) show a moderate 386 

tendency to be substituted by all the other cheaper wines, with the exception of TB. Moreover, such 387 

wines tend to substitute only two product categories and are overall a rather isolated category. 388 

389 

5. Concluding remarks 390 

The aim of this paper was to investigate the domestic consumption of wine, with the focus on 391 

non-premium wines. In order to do so, a censored demand system (QAIDS) was estimated using 392 

AC-Nielsen homescan data, statistically representative of Italian households in year 2010. 393 

Moreover, categorization of non-premium wines was necessary in order to synthesize a wide range 394 

of wines in fewer categories. It emerged that the market for non-premium wines, apparently 395 

showing thousands of products, can be aggregated into five categories. The results show a complex 396 

picture in which there emerge important specific details in the demand behaviour towards the 397 

various categories considered. Hence, some important considerations may also be inferred on the 398 

strategies to be implemented with a view to consolidating demand-supply relations and on the 399 

Page 20: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

20  

possible evolution of the market for basic wines. Another result of our analysis worth noting 400 

concerns the categorization of basic wines proposed. As argued in section two, there is no single 401 

categorization of non-premium wines available. 402 

Our empirical strategy was to interview some key informants of the Italian wine sector who 403 

described how the supply of wines takes place in the Italy’s big retail chains. Consumption data 404 

provided by AC-Nielsen was managed to fit that picture on the consumption side. The statistically 405 

significant level of almost all coefficients estimated by means of the demand system confirms that 406 

the categorization implemented seems to capture the key elements of that particular market side. 407 

We may thus confirm what was stated in the first part of the paper: the market for cheaper wines is 408 

complex and products, categorized as proposed, show a significant degree of heterogeneity. 409 

Besides confirming our underlying hypothesis, the results obtained show a complex picture of the 410 

relations between the categories used in the analysis. Particular elements may be found which allow 411 

hypotheses to be postulated on the functioning of the market in the period in question and on its 412 

possible evolution. The most salient elements are low elasticities for carton wine of the market 413 

leader (ML) and high elasticity of non-brand wine in cartons (OC). Albeit with the necessary 414 

caution, on the basis of the results it may be stated that, also in the segment of more economical 415 

wines, brand is an effective instrument of diversification. The brand effect, though to a lesser 416 

extent, is also recognised in private label carton wines which, proposed with a similar price to that 417 

of carton wines without a recognisable brand, have a much lower elasticity than the latter. The high 418 

elasticity of products in cartons without a recognisable brand not only sustains the hypothesis of 419 

brand importance but also envisages the evolutionary dynamics of the market for non-premium 420 

wines which could be most accentuated, with a reduction in unbranded products and expansion of 421 

the weight and number of branded products. Examination of the cross elasticities allows further 422 

reflection on carton wine of the market leader and that with private label. The data show that as the 423 

price of the market leader grows, purchase of this product declines in favour of the premium wine; 424 

Page 21: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

21  

as the price of private label wine, purchases are shifted towards other basic products, except for the 425 

market leader carton. The two branded wines in the carton are not substitutable. 426 

Hypothesising on the evolution of the market size for more economical wines, it may be noted that 427 

only for two categories, the carton wine of the market leader and basic wine in glass, is a tendency 428 

shown to shift purchases towards premium wines. Indeed, most of the substitutions of purchases 429 

seem to remain within the circle of non-premium wines. Taken together, the results of our 430 

investigation clearly indicate that the market for non-premium wines is complex. Although non-431 

premium wines may be considered convenience products, their supply shows well-defined 432 

structuring. This encourages the launching of further studies, including those on the demand 433 

structure, in line with that presented in this paper. New studies will require that the categorisation of 434 

non-premium wines implemented herein be verified. In this sense, the experience of professionals 435 

operating in the supply chain of non-premium wines is undoubtedly essential. This approach could, 436 

however, be supplemented by surveys of consumers in order to analyse directly how the great 437 

variety of the supply of non-premium wines is viewed and perceived. 438 

439 

References 440 

Akbay, C., Boz, I. and Chern, W.S. (2007). Household food consumption in Turkey, European 441 

Review of Agricultural Economics, 34, 209-231. 442 

Amadieu, P. and Viviani, J.L. (2011). Intangible expenses: a solution to increase the French wine 443 

industry performance?, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 38, 237-258. 444 

Anderson, K. and Nelgen, S. (2011). Global wine markets, 1961 to 2009: a statistical compendium. 445 

The University of Adelaide press, Adelaide. 446 

Banks, J., Blundell, R. and Lewbel, A. (1997). Quadratic Engel curves and consumer demand, 447 

Review of Economics and Statistics, 79, 527-539. 448 

Barnett, W.A. and Serletis, A. (2008). Consumer preferences and demand systems, Journal of 449 

Econometrics, 147, 210-224. 450 

Page 22: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

22  

Bernetti, I., Casini, L., and Marinelli, N. (2006). Wine and globalisation: changes in the 451 

international market structure and the position of Italy, British Food Journal, 108, 306–315. 452 

Blundell, R. and Robin, J.M. (1990). Estimation in Large and Disaggregated Demand Systems: An 453 

Estimator for Conditionally Linear Systems, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 14, 209-232. 454 

Corsi, A., Pomarici, E. and Sardone, R. (2004). Italy, in K. Anderson (ed.), The World’s Wine 455 

Markets: Globalization at work, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, London. 456 

Costanigro, M., McCluskey, J. J. and Mittelhammer, R.C. (2007). Segmenting the Wine Market 457 

Based on Price: Hedonic Regression When Different Prices Mean Different Products, Journal 458 

of Agricultural Economics, 58, 454-466. 459 

Davidson, R. and MacKinnon, J.G. (2004). Econometric Theory and Methods, Oxford University 460 

Press, New York. 461 

Davis, T.R., Ahmadi-Esfahani, F.Z. and Iranzo, S. (2008), Demand under product differentiation: 462 

an empirical analysis of the US wine market. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource 463 

Economics, 52, 401–417. 464 

Deaton, A. and Muellbauer, J. (1980). An almost ideal demand system, The American Economic 465 

Review, 70, 312-326. 466 

Deaton, A. and Zaidi, S. (2002). Guidelines for Constructing Consumption Aggregates for Welfare 467 

Analysis, LSMS Working Paper No. 135, World Bank, Washington. 468 

Drichoutis, A.C., Klonaris, S., Lazaridis, P. and Nayga Jr, R.M. (2008). Household food 469 

consumption in Turkey: a comment, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 35, 93-98. 470 

Einav, L., Ephraim L., and Aviv, N. (2008). On the Accuracy of Nielsen Homescan Data, ERR-69, 471 

U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, Econ. Res. Serv. December, USA. 472 

Ernst and Young Entrepreneurs Etude des Filières et des Stratégies de Développement des Pays 473 

Producteurs de Vins dans le Monde: Analyse de la Filière Viticole Australienne, ONIVINS, 474 

Office National Interprofessionnel des Vins, Paris. 475 

Page 23: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

23  

Fisher, D., Fleissig, A.R. and Serletis, A. (2001). An Empirical Comparison of Flexible Demand 476 

System Functional Forms, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16, 59-80. 477 

Fogarty, J.J. (2010). The demand for beer, wine and spirits: a survey of the literature, Journal of 478 

Economic Surveys, 24, 428-478. 479 

Fraser, I. (2005). Microeconometric analysis of wine grape supply contracts in Australia, Australian 480 

Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 49, 23–46. 481 

Gallet, C.A. (2007). The demand for alcohol: a meta-analysis of elasticities, Australian Journal of 482 

Agricultural and Resource Economics, 51, 121-136. 483 

Gil, A. and Molina, J. (2009). Alcohol demand among young people in Spain: an addictive 484 

QUAIDS, Empirical Economics, 36, 515-530. 485 

Golan, A., Perloff, J.M. and Shen, E.Z. (2001). Estimating a demand system with non-negativity 486 

constraints: Mexican meat demand, Review of Economics and Statistics, 83, 541-550. 487 

Hannin, H., Couderc, J-P., d’Hauteville, F. and Montaigne, É. (2010). La vigne et le vin, La 488 

documentation Française, Paris. 489 

Heien, D. and Wessells, C.R. (1990). Demand Systems Estimation with Microdata: A Censored 490 

Regression Approach, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 8, 365-371. 491 

ISTAT, Italian National Institute of Statistics (2011), Consumption pattern of Italian population, 492 

available at http://www.istat.it/en/ 493 

Labys, W.C. and Cohen, B.C. (2006). Trends versus cycles in global wine export shares, Australian 494 

Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 50, 527–537. 495 

Mäkelä, P., Gmel, G., Grittner, U., Kuendig, H., Kuntsche, S., Bloomfield, K. and Room, R. (2006). 496 

Drinking Patterns and Their Gender Differences in Europe, Alcohol and Alcoholism, 41, 8-18. 497 

Mediobanca (2011). Indagine sul settore vinicolo, MBRES – Ufficio studi Mediobanca, Milano. 498 

Moro, D. and Sckokai, P. (2000). Heterogeneous preferences in household food consumption in 499 

Italy, European Review of Agricultural Economics, 27, 305-323. 500 

Page 24: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

24  

OIV: Organisation Internationale de la Vigne et du Vin (2012). Report of the Director General of 501 

the OIV on the world vitiviniculture situation in 2011, International Organisation of Vine and 502 

Wine, Paris, available at http://www.oiv.int/oiv/info/enconjoncture?lang=en 503 

Panzone, L.A. (2012). Alcohol Tax, Price–Quality Proxy and Discounting: A Reason Why Alcohol 504 

Taxes May Rebound, Journal of Agricultural Economics, 63, 715-736. 505 

Perali, F. and Chavas, J.P. (2000). Estimation of Censored Demand Equations from Large Cross-506 

Section Data, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 82, 1022-1037. 507 

Pomarici E., Boccia F., and Catapano D. (2012). The Wine Distribution Systems Over the World: 508 

An Explorative Survey, New Medit, 4, 23-38. 509 

Rabobank Wine is Business (Rabobank, Utrecht, 2003). 510 

Reg. (EC) 607/2009, 14 July (2009) L193/60, available at http://eur-511 

lex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:L:2009:193:0060:0139:EN:PDF. 512 

Ritchie, C. (2009). The culture of wine buying in the UK off trade, International Journal of Wine 513 

Business Research, 21 194-211. 514 

Shonkwiler, J.S. and Yen, S.T. (1999). Two-step estimation of a censored system of equations, 515 

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 81, 972-982. 516 

Steenkamp, J-B. and Ter Hofstede, F. (2002). International market segmentation: issues and 517 

perspectives, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 19, 185-213. 518 

Tauchmann, H. (2005). Efficiency of two-step estimators for censored systems of equations: 519 

Shonkwiler and Yen reconsidered, Applied Economics, 37, 367-374. 520 

Torrisi, F., Stefani, G. and Seghieri, C. (2006). Use of Scanner Data to Analyze the Table Wine 521 

Demand in the Italian Major Retailing Trade, Agribusiness, 3, 391-404. 522 

Yen, S.T., Kan, K. and Su, S. (2002). Household demand for fats and oils: two-step estimation of a 523 

censored demand system, Applied Economics, 34, 1799-1806. 524 

Yen, S.T. and Lin, B.H. (2006). A sample selection approach to censored demand systems, 525 

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 88, 742-749. 526 

Page 25: Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy - unina.itwpage.unina.it/francesco.caracciolo/AJARE_Full.pdf1 1 Drinking cheaply: the demand for basic wine in Italy 2 Luigi Cembalo,

25  

                                                            i Rabobank (2003), for instance, considers basic wines those sold at a price lower than 3 euro per standard 0.75 litre

bottle. Rabobank also proposes to classify premium wines into four sub-categories according to the price of a standard 0.75 litre bottle: popular premium (price between 3 and 5 euro); premium (price between 5 and 7 euro); super premium (price between 7 and 14 euro); ultra premium (price between 14 and 150 euro); icon (higher than 150 euro).  

ii Such estimation considers wines subdivided into three categories using prices measured as wholesale pre-tax prices per litre at the national border: non-premium, lower than US$2.5; commercial premium, US$2.5 – US$7.5; superpremium, higher than US$7.5 

iii From now on in this paper the authors have taken the liberty to use non-premium, less expensive and basic wines as synonymous. 

iv  The consumption and production pattern followed by Italy could be observed in all those wine producing and consuming countries showing the same structural characteristics. 

v Data about import and export come from the Global Trade Information Services Database vi Nielsen ConsumerScan data have been questioned in terms of accuracy. For a complete reference see Einav et al.

(2008). vii The cut-off price between non-premium (basic) and premium wines confirms the Rabobank classification which is

substantially equivalent to that proposed by Anderson and Nelgen (2011). viii It is worth noting that the data reported refer to the distribution within WAH consumption of wines in Italy, which is

estimated to be 70% in volume and 30% in value terms by Anderson and Nelgen (2011) ix No categorization was implemented based on “red – white” since, as experts pointed out, criteria that make consumers

choose between red or white wines are the same within each of these categories. Put differently, consumers make a choice between red and white based on variables, or attributes, that is beyond the choice set of attributes available in a store shelf. As for legal category, this criterion is relevant to consumer choices almost exclusively for premium wines. 

x Although the level of significance of this coefficient is estimated at 5%, it is worth holding it in due consideration for the purpose of describing purchasing behaviour.