early states synopsis

29
http://ccr.sagepub.com Cross-Cultural Research DOI: 10.1177/1069397102238924 2003; 37; 105 Cross-Cultural Research Dmitri M. Bondarenko and Andrey V. Korotayev "Early State" in Cross-Cultural Perspective: A Statistical Reanalysis of Henri J. M. Claessen’s Database http://ccr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/1/105 The online version of this article can be found at: Published by: http://www.sagepublications.com On behalf of: Society for Cross-Cultural Research can be found at: Cross-Cultural Research Additional services and information for http://ccr.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Email Alerts: http://ccr.sagepub.com/subscriptions Subscriptions: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.nav Reprints: http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav Permissions: © 2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.com Downloaded from

Upload: kostaslock

Post on 04-Oct-2015

13 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

DESCRIPTION

Early States Synopsis

TRANSCRIPT

  • http://ccr.sagepub.com

    Cross-Cultural Research

    DOI: 10.1177/1069397102238924 2003; 37; 105 Cross-Cultural Research

    Dmitri M. Bondarenko and Andrey V. Korotayev "Early State" in Cross-Cultural Perspective: A Statistical Reanalysis of Henri J. M. Claessens Database

    http://ccr.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/1/105 The online version of this article can be found at:

    Published by:

    http://www.sagepublications.com

    On behalf of: Society for Cross-Cultural Research

    can be found at:Cross-Cultural Research Additional services and information for

    http://ccr.sagepub.com/cgi/alerts Email Alerts:

    http://ccr.sagepub.com/subscriptions Subscriptions:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navReprints:

    http://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navPermissions:

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://www.sccr.orghttp://ccr.sagepub.com/cgi/alertshttp://ccr.sagepub.com/subscriptionshttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsReprints.navhttp://www.sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navhttp://ccr.sagepub.com

  • 10.1177/1069397102238924 ARTICLECross-Cultural Research / February 2003Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE

    Early State inCross-Cultural Perspective:A Statistical Reanalysis ofHenri J. M. Claessens Database

    Dmitri M. BondarenkoRussian Academy of Sciences

    Andrey V. KorotayevRussian State University for the Humanities

    The authors reanalyze Claessens data set on the Early States.

    Though Claessens Early State typology is largely justified, we sug-

    gest some corrections and amendments to his typologization and

    his model of Early State evolution. We show that the development of

    personal ownership of land correlates rather weakly with the politi-

    cal development of the Early State, and that political development

    might be accompanied by the strengthening of communal owner-

    ship. We also examine the correlation between Early State political

    development and ruler sacralization. Though this correlation is in-

    significant for the whole sample, its insignificance is accounted for

    by two distinct evolutionary patterns. The pattern observed in the

    axial age zone is characterized by a strong negative correlation be-

    tween political development and ruler sacralization, while the pat-

    tern observed throughout the rest of the world is characterized by a

    strong positive correlation between the two variables. The authors

    discuss possible causes of this difference.

    105

    Cross-Cultural Research, Vol. 37 No. 1, February 2003 105-132

    DOI: 10.1177/1069397102238924

    2003 Sage Publications

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Keywords: Early State; land ownership; ruler sacralization

    To many colleagues, the name of Hans Claessen has become almost

    synonymous with the Early State. Over the past decades, he suc-

    ceeded in making this topic into a major theme in anthropological

    and evolutionist discourse. Indeed, due to his inspiration, the topic

    attained truly global dimensions: a long series of seminars and con-

    ferences in all sorts of contexts, bringing together people from all

    parts of the globe; and an equally impressive stream of books, arti-

    cles and collections.

    P. Geschiere, 1995, p. 7

    The Early State (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978) is perhaps the most

    influential volume on the evolution of archaic states. The book was

    conceived in 1973, when Henri J. M. Claessen and Peter Skalnk

    met at a conference. By 1978, the project had been joined by more

    than 20 scholars from different countries, and The Early State vol-

    ume appeared. Since then, about 10 volumes of the series have

    been published, almost all edited by Claessen in cooperation with

    different colleagues (on the history of The Early State project, see

    Kradin, 1998; Kochakova, 1996, 1999; Oosten & van de Velde,

    1994). The Early State concept originated within the framework of

    neostructuralism. Its founding fathers, Claessen and Skalnk,

    were attempting to overcome the atemporality of classical

    structuralism by combining structuralism with elements of

    neoevolutionism. This intent, of course, departs from the essen-

    tially structuralist orientation still evident in the first volume of

    The Early State series (1978, pp. 533-596). As a historiographer of

    the concept and one of its most active supporters, Kochakova

    (1999) observed that the first volume of the series represented a

    static comparison of The Early States whereas the next three were

    devoted to their dynamic consideration (p. 6).

    In its evolutionary dimension, however, The Early State concept

    has unilinearity and directionality (see Bondarenko, 1998, pp. 18-

    106 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    Authors Note: We are most grateful to Henri Johannes Maria Claessen for

    his friendship and support of our studies. This article could not have been

    written without the materials he has been supplying us with for many

    years. The study was supported by grants from the Russian Foundation for

    the Humanities (RGNF no. 01-03-00332a) and from the Russian Founda-

    tion for Basic Research (RFBR/RFFI no. 01-06-80142).

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • 22; Carneiro, 1987, p. 757; Kradin, 1998, pp. 10-12). Consider the

    prevalent typology of The Early States. The inchoate, typical, and

    transitional Early States are distinguished by differing levels of

    development (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978, pp. 22, 589, 641). The

    multilinearity and nondirectionality within the concept are

    replaced by the possibility of movement along the staircase of

    social evolution (Claessen & Skalnk, 1981). Yet despite The Early

    State proponents sympathetic view of Marxism and, more gener-

    ally, the leftist nature of this anthropological trend (see

    Bondarenko,1998;Kubbel, 1988,pp.15-16;Webb,1984), its adher-

    ents still represent The Mature State1 as an exception to the gen-

    eral rule. The general rule is represented by The Early State

    (Claessen & Oosten,1996,p.9;Claessen & van de Velde,1987,p.20).

    In this article, we concentrate on the first volume of The Early

    State project (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978) for the following reasons.

    The whole project is definitely and consistently cross-cultural.

    However, the research is mainly qualitative rather than quantita-

    tive, though the editors of The Early State managed to obtain data

    on more than 200 variables for quite a representative worldwide

    sample of Early States. They also achieved a high level of data for-

    malization, allowing Claessen to conduct some preliminary statis-

    tical analyses. We believe that further statistical analysis of

    Claessens data set is possible. This article is only the beginning of

    that analysis.2

    We decided to start with a reanalysis of Claessens developmen-

    tal typology of Early States. He divided them into the following

    three groups: inchoate, typical, and transitional according to

    their closeness to the Mature State and remoteness from the

    prestate forms of sociopolitical organization. His division of the

    Early States was based on the following 10 criteria:

    1. The presence of markets and professional traders.

    2. The succession of general state functionaries through appointment

    rather than in a hereditary way.

    3. Special state functionaries through appointment rather than in a

    hereditary way.

    4. State functionaries through appointment rather than in a heredi-

    tary way.

    5. The presence of salaried functionaries.

    6. Codified law.

    7. Formal judges.

    8. Codified punishment.

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 107

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • 9. Personal property of land among aristocracy.

    10. Personal property of land among commoners.

    The inchoate Early State has none of these characteristics (at least

    explicitly); the transitional Early State has all of them. The typical

    Early State is somewhere in between.

    The respective data set Claessen used for his typologization

    (recoded by us for a further statistic reanalysis) is presented in the

    appendix. Claessen classified 21 states of his sample as shown in

    Table 1.

    We decided to start by checking the validity of this classification

    using principal components factor analysis (and the study of the

    correlation matrix for Claessens typologization variables). The

    results are shown in Tables 2 and 3.

    The statistical analysis suggests that most of the Early State

    development indicators are indeed positively, significantly, and

    rather strongly correlated with one another. The factor loadings of

    all the variables for Factor 1 (with eigenvalue as high as 5.6,

    accounting for 56.1% of variance) are positive and generally rather

    high. Hence, it seems reasonable to consider factor scores for Fac-

    tor 1 as a sort of Early State Development Indexa measure of

    each states closeness to the Mature State. Let us consider how the

    early states are arranged along this axis (see Figure 1).

    Thus, in general, Claessens typologization of early states is sup-

    ported by our factor analysis. All the inchoate early states have

    lower Factor 1 scores than both typical and transitional ones,

    whereas most transitional early states have higher scores than the

    typical ones.

    But there are still a few problems here. The most evident prob-

    lem is constituted by three casesYoruba, Inca, and China. The

    Inca score is so close to Chinas that they should belong to one sub-

    type of the early state. In addition, the Yoruba state has a higher

    score than China, which suggests that either China should be

    regarded as a typical rather than a transitional early state, or

    Yoruba should be regarded as a transitional rather than typical

    early state.

    Note also that Norway, Volta, and Zande are much closer to the

    typical Early States than to their fellow inchoate statesHawaii,

    Tahiti, and Ankole. The impression is that these societies were

    characterized by a different type of sociopolitical organization than

    the rest of the sample societies. Thus, the conventional classifica-

    tion of Hawaii, Tahiti, and Ankole as complex chiefdoms (e.g.,

    108 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • TABLE 1

    Claessens Classification of Early States

    Inchoate States Typical States Transitional States

    Ankole (17th-19th centuries) Angkor (9th-13th centuries) Aztecs (15th-16th centuries)

    Hawaii (18th-early 19th centuries) Axum (1st-6th centuries) China (late 2nd-early 1st millennium B.C.)

    Norway (10th-11th centuries) Egypt (first half of 1st millennium B.C.) France (10th-11th centuries)

    Tahiti (18th century) Iberia (6th century B.C.-1st A.D.) Jimma (19th-20th centuries [until 1932])

    Volta (15th-19th centuries) Incas (15th-16th centuries) Kuba (19th century)

    Zande (18th-19th centuries) Kachari (17th-18th centuries) Maurya (4th-2nd centuries B.C.)

    Mongolia (13th-14th centuries)

    Scythia (6th-3rd centuries B.C.)

    Yoruba (19th century)

    109

    2003 SA

    GE

    Publications. A

    ll rights reserved. Not for com

    mercial use or unauthorized distribution.

    at EM

    OR

    Y U

    NIV

    on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.com

    Dow

    nloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • TABLE 2

    Correlation Matrix for Claessens Early States Development Indicators

    Mode of Mode of Personal Personal

    Succession Succession Property Property

    of General of Special Salaried Codified Formal Codified of Land of of Land of

    Markets Trade Functionaries Functionaries Functionaries Law Judges Punishment Aristocracy Commoners

    Markets .781 .609 .666 .728 .621 .518 .794 .261 .273

    (.000) (.006) (.005) (.002) (.003) (.012) (.000) (.148) (.137)

    Trade .781 .550 .500 .577 .458 .481 .730 .218 .284

    (.000) (.009) (.029) (.015) (.021) (.014) (.002) (.185) (.119)

    Mode of succession of .609 .550 .653 .731 .398 .563 .742 .412 .599

    general functionaries (.006) (.009) (.004) (.002) (.051) (.008) (.002) (.056) (.007)

    Mode of succession of .666 .500 .653 .767 .338 .558 .693 .354 .336

    special functionaries (.005) (.029) (.004) (.002) (.109) (.015) (.006) (.107) (.131)

    Salaried functionaries .728 .577 .731 .767 .714 .866 .837 .415 .415

    (.002) (.015) (.002) (.002) (.002) (.000) (.000) (.079) (.079)

    Codified law .621 .458 .398 .338 .714 .792 .720 .553 .433

    (.003) (.021) (.051) (.109) (.002) (.000) (.003) (.009) (.036)

    Formal judges .518 .481 .563 .558 .866 .792 .730 .263 .150

    (.012) (.014) (.008) (.015) (.000) (.000) (.002) (.139) (.271)

    Codified punishment .794 .730 .742 .693 .837 .720 .730 .141 .283

    (.000) (.002) (.002) (.006) (.000) (.003) (.002) (.323) (.175)

    Personal property of .261 .218 .412 .354 .415 .553 .263 .141 .645

    land of aristocracy (.148) (.185) (.056) (.107) (.079) (.009) (.139) (.323) (.002)

    Personal property of .273 .284 .599 .336 .415 .433 .150 .283 .645

    land of commoners (.137) (.119) (.007) (.131) (.079) (.036) (.271) (.175) (.002)

    NOTE:Numbers in bold indicate correlation is significant at the < .01 level (one-tailed).Numbers in italics indicate correlation is significant at the < .05 and > .01

    level (one-tailed).Numbers not in bold or in italics indicate correlation is not significant at the < .05 level (one-tailed).Numbers in parentheses are p values.

    110

    2003 SA

    GE

    Publications. A

    ll rights reserved. Not for com

    mercial use or unauthorized distribution.

    at EM

    OR

    Y U

    NIV

    on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.com

    Dow

    nloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Earle, 1978, 1997, pp. 33-46, pp. 200-203, 2000) is perhaps more

    reasonable than Claessens grouping them together with Early

    States. These are minor problems, however. The main problem is

    as follows.

    The academic community understands the state in two distinct

    ways. On one hand, the state is often understood as a certain type

    of society (e.g., Fried, 1967, who considered the state as the most

    recent type of society preceded by stratified, ranked, and egalitar-

    ian societies; see also, e.g., Carneiro, 2000, p. 186; Haas, 1982;

    Pugachjov & Solovjov, 2000, pp. 251-252), but it is just as often

    understood as a type of political organization. As a political organi-

    zation, the state is merely a subsystem within the social system: It

    is not identical with the society as a whole (Belkov, 1993, pp. 32-38,

    1995, pp. 171-175; Claessen, 1996, p. 1255; Godiner, 1991, p. 51;

    Grinin, 1997, p. 20; Jakobson, 1997, p. 6; Pugachjov & Solovjov,

    2000, pp. 251-252).

    Now, as a general rule, scholars can use whatever definitions

    they choose, provided that these definitions remain consistent

    throughout a single piece of research. The writers of The Early

    State did not follow this rule (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978). On one

    hand, Claessen and Skalnk (1978) proposed the following defini-

    tion of the Early State:

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 111

    TABLE 3

    Factor Analysis of Claessens

    Early States Development Data Set

    Factor Loadingsa

    Variable Factor 1 Factor 2 Factor 3

    Salaried functionaries .86 .10

    Professional traders .84 .23 .17

    Codified punishment .84 .32

    Markets .82 .27 .15

    Mode of succession of general functionaries .78 .14 .33

    Codified law .76 .17 .56

    Formal judges .76 .17 .50

    Mode of succession of special functionaries .73 .12 .31

    Personal property of land of aristocracy .50 .74 .11

    Personal property of land of commoners .50 .74 .24

    Eigenvalue 5.6 1.4 .9

    % of variance explained 56.1 14.3 9.1

    a. Cutoff point = .1.

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • The Early State is a centralized socio-political organization for the

    regulation of social relations in a complex, stratified society divided

    into at least two basic strata, or emergent social classesviz. the

    rulers and the ruledwhose relations are characterized by political

    dominance of the former and tributary obligations of the latter, legit-

    imized by a common ideology of which reciprocity is the basic princi-

    ple. (p. 640)

    Thus, Claessen claimed that he understood the state not as a

    certain type of society but as a centralized socio-political organi-

    zation for the regulation of social relations in a complex, stratified

    society. However, in his list of the diagnostic characteristics of, say,

    the transitional Early State, he includes the presence of markets,

    professional traders, and personal land ownership by both aristoc-

    racy and commoners (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978). These are char-

    acteristics of a society regulated by a centralized sociopolitical

    112 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    1.5 Aztecs (1.45); Jimma (1.45) Transitional

    Maurya (1.22) Early

    1.0 France (1.04); Kuba (1.05) States

    Yoruba (.78) ??????????

    .5 Inca (.52); China (.57) ??????????

    Angkor (.15)

    .0 Kachari (.02); Iberia (.03) Typical

    Egypt (.07) Early

    Axum (.21) States

    Scythia (.36); Mongolia (.32)

    .5 Norway (.55)

    Volta (.70)

    Zande (.82) Inchoate

    1.0 Early

    1.5 States

    Hawaii (1.59)

    Ankole (1.71)

    Tahiti (1.93)

    2.0

    Figure 1: Ranking of Early States along the Axis of Early State Develop-

    ment Index (factor scores for Factor 1)

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • organization. Hence, one wonders what exactly is being

    typologized. If we are discussing the political organization of soci-

    ety, why should we consider characteristics of society as a whole?

    And if we are discussing the whole social system, why should we

    consider six characteristics of political organization and just four

    characteristics of other societal subsystems?

    Claessens typologization paints a unilineal picture of early

    states, proposing that they can be arranged along one line even if

    we consider not only the indexes of political development but also

    other characteristics of social and economic development.

    As mentioned above, most variables used by Claessen for his

    Early State typologization are characterized by strong and signifi-

    cant correlations between one another. But not all of them are so

    correlated. Note that neither characteristic of personal property

    development shows any significant correlation with the political

    development variables.

    Let us now consider more attentively Claessens hypothesis that

    political development in the direction of the Mature State is

    strongly correlated with the transition from communal to private/

    personal land ownership (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978). First, we

    must single out the dimension of purely political development. To

    do this, we will include in the analysis only the characteristics of

    political development: succession of general and special state func-

    tionaries through appointment versus a hereditary way, presence

    of salaried functionaries, codified law, formal judges, and codified

    punishment.Factor 1 scores for principal components factor analy-

    sis can in this case be considered as an index of political develop-

    ment (in the direction of Mature State).

    The results are shown in Table 3.

    Note that the factor analysis already suggests an interesting

    alternative to the political development of the Early State, which

    can be seen in the scattergram in Figure 2.

    The political development of the Early State could be accompa-

    nied by the elaboration of the system of appointed (and not heredi-

    tary) functionaries in the absence of codified law and formal judges

    (which in our sample is most clearly represented by Egypt, Iberia,

    and Yoruba). But it can also be accompanied by the legal formaliza-

    tion without a full transition to the functionaries succession by

    appointment (which in our sample is most clearly represented by

    Inca and Angkor).

    Now let us see how the political development of the Early State

    correlates with the development of personal ownership of land.

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 113

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Claessen contrasted personal ownership with collective/commu-

    nal ownership (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978, pp. 591, 645-646).

    Hence, we decided to make a factor analysis of six variables of the

    114 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    TABLE 4

    Factor Analysis of Claessens Early

    States Political Development Data Set

    Political Development

    Index (Equals

    Factor 1 scores

    for principal

    Early State component analysis) Factor 2 Scores

    Aztecs 1.42 0.08

    Jimma 1.42 0.08

    France 1.13 0.53

    Kuba 1.13 0.53

    Maurya 1.10 0.87

    Yoruba 1.00 1.50

    Inca 0.81 1.48

    China 0.13 0.64

    Angkor 0.10 1.68

    Iberia 0.06 1.52

    Egypt 0.12 1.61

    Norway 0.33 0.94

    Axum 0.44 0.66

    Zande 0.54 0.73

    Mongolia 0.61 0.90

    Scythia 0.64 0.30

    Volta 1.12 0.32

    Hawaii 1.32 0.04

    Ankole 1.73 1.24

    Tahiti 1.73 1.24

    Factor Loadings

    Variable Factor 1 Factor 2

    Formal judges .84 .376

    Codified law .75 .584

    Codified punishment .86

    Salaried functionaries .89

    Mode of succession of general functionaries .77 .345

    Mode of succession of special functionaries .75 .472

    Eigenvalue 3.95 .84

    % of variance explained 65.9 14.0

    NOTE: The cutoff point for factors is .3. The score for Kachari is entirely unrepresentative due to

    the absence of data on four out of six variables.

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • data collected by Claessen and colleagues on these subjects. In

    addition to personal ownership of land by aristocracy and personal

    ownership of land by commoners, we also analyzed the following

    variables: ownership of land by aristocrats through community

    membership, personal land ownership by sovereign, land owner-

    ship by sovereign through community membership, and land own-

    ership by commoners through community membership. We

    expected that Factor 1 of the principal component analysis would

    have positive loadings for personal property variables and nega-

    tive ones for communal property variables and, hence, it would be

    possible to use Factor 1 scores as an index of the development of

    personal ownership of land/decline of communal ownership. This

    expectation was confirmed (see Table 5).

    Now let us see how the Personal Ownership of Land Index corre-

    lates with the Political Development Index (see Figure 3).

    The development of the political system of the Early State corre-

    lates rather weakly with the development of personal ownership of

    land. As Figure 3 graphically demonstrates, an Early State could

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 115

    Legal Formalization vs. Appointed Functionaries (factor 2 score)

    2,01,51,0,50,0-,5-1,0-1,5-2,0

    Po

    litic

    al D

    eve

    lop

    men

    t In

    dex

    (fa

    cto

    r 1

    sco

    re)

    2,0

    1,5

    1,0

    ,5

    0,0

    -,5

    -1,0

    -1,5

    -2,0

    TahitiAnkole

    Hawaii

    Volta

    Scythia MongoliaZande

    AxumNorway

    EgyptIberiaAngkor China

    Inca

    YorubaMaurya Kuba

    France

    JimmaAztecs

    Figure 2: Early States Political Development Index Legal Formalization

    Versus Appointed Functionaries (scattergram)

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • reach a high level of political development without reaching a high

    level of personal ownership (and/or preserving strong communal

    ownership forms)Angkor, Inca, and Yoruba. On the other hand, a

    relatively high level of personal ownership (and/or disappearance

    of strong communal ownership forms) may not be accompanied by

    an equally high level of development in the direction of the Mature

    State. This is not surprising. Consider, for example, western

    Europe at the beginning of the 2nd millennium A.D., when a fast

    political development (which finally led to the formation of Mature

    States in this region and was accompanied by equally fast and rad-

    ical developments in all othertechnological, economical, cul-

    turalspheres of social life) occurred together with the develop-

    ment and strengthening of the communal ownership of land (e.g.,

    Alaev, 1999, pp. 100-101, 2000, p. 171; Bessmertnyj, 1969, pp. 163-

    166; Genicot, 1990).

    Finally, we decided to consider how the political development of

    the Early States correlates with their so-called ideological develop-

    ment. The data on these variables (published in The Early State)

    were available (without too many missing cases) for parameters

    connected with the position of the ruler. Their principal component

    factor analysis produced the results shown in Table 6.

    We decided to concentrate on Factor 1, which we interpreted as a

    Rulers Sacralization Index. Note that the negative loading for the

    variable Tours by Sovereign (Gafol) (Gafol is defined as inspections

    during which the ruler with his retinue traveled around his posses-

    sions, collecting assessments, executing judgement, etc.) fits this

    interpretation very wella totally sacralized ruler would hardly

    run the defilement risk inherent in any extensive visits to the pro-

    fane zones of his realm.Such a negative correlation looks quite nat-

    ural because the main means of sacralizing the ruler is imposing

    taboos on him. All those taboos are aimed at limiting the rulers

    opportunities to communicate freely with his subjects (the taboo

    that directly prohibits him to appear in their presence except in

    very rare ritual occasions is also frequent) (e.g., Bondarenko, 1995,

    pp. 203-231; Claessen, 1986, pp. 116-119, pp. 124-125, 1987, pp. 206-

    207, pp. 219-220, 234, 2000, pp. 178-186, p. 194; Claessen & Oosten,

    1996; Claessen & Skalnk, 1978, pp. 511-530, pp. 533-596, 1981, pp.

    1-13, pp. 59-86, pp. 239-250; Frazer, 1922; Freud, 1923; Heusch,

    1987; Ldtke, 1991; Tokarev, 1990, pp. 320-330).

    Now let us see how the Rulers Sacralization Index correlates

    with the Political Development Index (see Figure 4).

    116 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Of course, the initial impression is that the two variables do not

    correlate at all. However, a closer inspection of the scattergram

    reveals that this impression is quite misleading.The lack of signifi-

    cant correlation is in fact a result of the so-called Galton effect.

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 117

    TABLE 5

    Factor Analysis of Claessens Land Ownership Variables

    Political Development

    Index (Equals

    Factor 1 scores

    for principal

    Early State component analysis) Factor 2 Scores

    Aztecs 0.26 0.80

    Jimma 2.03 1.47

    France 0.82 1.48

    Kuba 0.92 2.91

    Maurya 1.37 0.47

    Yoruba 0.91 0.34

    Inca 0.91 0.34

    Kachari 0.91 0.34

    China 0.88 0.43

    Angkor 1.25 0.05

    Iberia 0.80 1.32

    Egypt 0.02 0.15

    Norway 1.25 0.05

    Axum 0.31 0.12

    Zande 0.45 1.23

    Mongolia 0.91 0.34

    Scythia 1.25 0.05

    Volta 1.06 0.91

    Hawaii 0.11 0.64

    Ankole 0.23 1.08

    Tahiti 1.25 0.05

    Factor Loadings

    Variable Factor 1 Factor 2

    Communal ownership of land by aristocrats .85 .20

    Personal ownership of land by commoners .79 .21

    Personal ownership of land by aristocracy .72 .44

    Communal ownership of land by commoners .70 .58

    Private ownership of land by sovereign .53 .70

    Communal ownership of land by sovereign .40 .14

    Eigenvalue 2.8 1.13

    % of variance explained 46.7 18.9

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Those dealing with the Galton problem normally worry about cor-

    relations being inflated as a result of diffusion effects. However, as

    Carol Ember and Melvin Ember argued, the Galton problem could

    well produce the opposite effects: duplication may weaken results,

    because a set of historically related cases may be exceptional to a

    cross-cultural generalization rather than consistent with it

    (Ember, 1971; Ember & Ember, 1998, p. 679). We seem to confront

    precisely such a case here. In the 1980s, many suggested that we

    treat the Galton problem as a network autocorrelation problem

    (e.g., Burton & White, 1987, p. 147, 1991; Dow, Burton, & White,

    1981, 1982; Dow, Burton, White, & Reitz, 1984; White, Burton, &

    Dow, 1981). This suggestion implies that Galton effects may result

    from the influence of historical networks. We could not help but

    notice that all the cultures in the upper left quarter of the scatter-

    gram belonged to one large historical network that emerged in a

    more or less full-fledged form during the Axial Age (e.g.,

    Eisenstadt, 1982, 1986; Gellner, 1988; Jaspers, 1953) but whose

    origins seem to go back to a much earlier time (Chase-Dunn & Hall,

    118 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    Private Ownership of Land Index

    2,52,01,51,0,50,0-,5-1,0-1,5

    Polit

    ical D

    evelo

    pm

    ent In

    dex

    2,0

    1,5

    1,0

    ,5

    0,0

    -,5

    -1,0

    -1,5

    -2,0

    TahitiAnkole

    Hawaii

    Volta

    ScythiaMongoliaZande

    AxumNorw ay

    Egypt IberiaAngkor China

    Inca

    YorubaMauryaKuba

    France

    JimmaAztecs

    Figure 3: Early States Political Development Index Personal Owner-

    ship of Land Index (scattergram)

    NOTE: = .4, p = .035 (one-tailed).

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • 1997). In the figure below, this historical network will be called

    Axial. The Axial zone roughly corresponds to the Middle Old

    World region singled out by Burton, Moore, Whiting, and Romney

    (1996) on the basis of a correspondence analysis of Murdocks

    Ethnographic Atlas database (1967).

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 119

    TABLE 6

    Factor Analysis of Claessens Ruler Sacralization Variables

    Early State Factor 1 Scores Factor 2 Scores

    Aztecs 1.68 0.91

    Jimma 1.05 2.46

    France 1.41 0.39

    Kuba 1.83 0.25

    Maurya 1.11 0.32

    Yoruba 1.94 1.28

    Inca 0.27 0.34

    Kachari 0.37 0.33

    China 0.60 0.27

    Angkor 0.87 0.05

    Iberia 1.13 0.32

    Egypt 1.16 0.16

    Norway 1.39 0.29

    Axum 0.47 0.18

    Zande 0.70 0.20

    Mongolia 0.17 0.25

    Scythia 0.27 0.34

    Volta 0.75 0.25

    Hawaii 0.24 2.45

    Ankole 0.21 0.09

    Tahiti 0.64 2.52

    Factor Loadings

    Variable Factor 1 Factor 2

    The sovereign or close kinsman is high priest .882

    Ruler is high priest .804 .337

    Human sacrifices at rulers funerals .701 .431

    Acquisition of sacral status .172 .926

    Tours by sovereign .524 .566

    Ritual anarchy on rulers death .139 .434

    Eigenvalue 2.24 1.67

    % of variance explained 37.3 27.8

    NOTE: The cutoff point for factors is .1.

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Let us see how the correlation between the Political Develop-

    ment Index and the Ruler Sacralization Index looks for the Axial

    Historical Network Zone (see Figure 5).

    For this zone, the correlation is negative and significant.Now let

    us see how this correlation looks for the rest of the world (see Fig-

    ure 6).

    For the rest of the world, the correlation is positive and margin-

    ally significant. The immediate impression is that the Early States

    of the Axial Historical Network and the rest of the world followed

    rather different patterns of sociopolitical development. The pres-

    ence in the overall sample of a roughly similar number of cases

    from both subsamples destroyed the correlation, producing a sta-

    tistically insignificant result.

    What could account for this difference? We believe that what

    really needs an explanation is the peculiarity of the sociopolitical

    development of the Axial Historical Network societies. It is not sur-

    prising that in the rest of the world, the growth of the political

    power of the state and its ruler was accompanied by the growth of

    120 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    Ruler Sacralization Index

    2,52,01,51,0,50,0-,5-1,0-1,5-2,0

    Po

    litic

    al D

    eve

    lop

    men

    t In

    de

    x

    2,0

    1,5

    1,0

    ,5

    0,0

    -,5

    -1,0

    -1,5

    -2,0

    TahitiAnkole

    Hawaii

    Volta

    ScythiaMongoliaZande

    AxumNorway

    EgyptIberia

    AngkorChina

    Inca

    YorubaMaurya Kuba

    France

    JimmaAztecs

    Figure 4: Early States Political Development Index Ruler Sacralization

    Index (scattergram with regression line)

    NOTE: = .01, p = .48 (one-tailed).

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • ruler sacralization. But what could account for the opposite pat-

    tern found within the Axial Historical Network?

    It was not by chance that we called this network Axial: the Axial

    Age revolutions are quite relevant here. Eisenstadt (1982), for

    example, considered as one of the most important features of the

    Axial Age revolutions the development of highly autonomous reli-

    gious-intellectual elites (clerics) claiming independent sacral-

    religious authority. This authority was institutionalized within all

    the world (universal) religionsBuddhism, Christianity, Islam.

    In the premodern world (by, say, the 17th century A.D.), the Axial

    Historical Network zone was roughly identical with the Universal

    Religions zone.

    As we stated above, the roots of the Axial Historical Network

    seem to go much deeper than the Axial Age itself. The peculiar

    social evolution pattern occurring within the Axial Zone appears to

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 121

    Ruler Sacralization Index

    1,51,0,50,0-,5-1,0-1,5-2,0

    Po

    litic

    al

    De

    ve

    lop

    me

    nt

    Ind

    ex

    2,0

    1,5

    1,0

    ,5

    0,0

    -,5

    -1,0

    ScythiaMongolia

    AxumNorway

    Egypt

    Iberia

    AngkorChina

    MauryaFrance

    Jimma

    Figure 5: Early States Political Development Index Ruler Sacralization

    Index (scattergram, for the Axial Historical Network only)

    NOTE: = .57, p = .03.

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • be rooted in the zones pre-Axial cultural heritage. Note that three

    (Greece, Iran, India) out of the five (Palestine and China are the

    others) main Axial revolution centers are associated with the Indo-

    Europeans. On the other hand, the basic principles of the social

    organization of the proto-Indo-Europeans, as they have been

    reconstructed by a wide range of sources (textual [e.g., Rigveda],

    linguistic, archaeological, ethnographic, and so forth [Dumzil,

    1958; Kullanda, 1995; Wikander, 1938]), must have served as a

    sound basis for the Axial sociopolitical development pattern. The

    sociopolitical organization of pastoral proto-Indo-Europeans

    appears to have been characterized by a developed age-class sys-

    tem.Within it, the sacral religious functions were performed by the

    age-class of elders. Productive functions (animal husbandry and

    agriculture) were performed by the age-class of mature married

    122 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    Ruler Sacralization Index

    2,52,01,51,0,50,0-,5-1,0

    Po

    liti

    ca

    l D

    eve

    lop

    me

    nt

    Ind

    ex

    2,0

    1,5

    1,0

    ,5

    0,0

    -,5

    -1,0

    -1,5

    -2,0

    TahitiAnkole

    Hawaii

    Volta

    Zande

    Inca

    YorubaKuba

    Aztecs

    Figure 6: Early States Political Development Index Ruler Sacralization

    Index (scattergram, for the rest of the world)

    NOTE: = .55, p = .66.

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • men, whereas the military functions (on the basis of which the

    political leadership functions were also developed) belonged to the

    age-class of initiated youngsters.

    With the formation of stratified societies among the Indo-Euro-

    peans, the age-class stratification tended to transform into a social

    stratification system. Within this process, the age-class of initiated

    youngsters transformed into an estate/varna of warriors/political

    leaders (Indian kshatryas or, say, the noble estate of medieval west-

    ern Europe). The age-class of elders transformed into an estate/

    varna of priestsIndian brahmans or the priestly estate of medi-

    eval western Europe. The age-class of mature married men trans-

    formed into an estate/varna of peasantsIndian vayshyas or the

    European third estate. Within this pattern, so-called political and

    sacral/religious authorities were rather sharply divided (Claessen

    & Oosten,1996,pp.272-274,438).This division, of course,provided

    good backgrounds for both the Axial Age transformations and the

    Axial Historical Network sociopolitical development pattern.

    At first glance, a tight cluster in the upper left of Figure 5, con-

    sisting of such apparently diverse cultures as early medieval

    France, ancient (Mauryan) India, and the Jimma Abba Jafar state

    of the 19th and 20th centuries A.D. in southwest Ethiopia, looks like

    a perfect illustration of the postmodernist conviction that stan-

    dard statistical procedures can produce extremely wild results and

    thus cannot serve as a sound basis for any generalizations. How-

    ever, there are better grounds for viewing this cluster as evidence

    of the reliability of standard statistical procedures.

    All the three states were, first of all, strongly influenced by the

    Axial Age world religionsChristianity in the case of France, Bud-

    dhism in the case of Mauryan India (at least at the age of Asoka),

    and Islam in the case of Jimma.3 France and Mauryan India are

    further united by their common Indo-European heritage, with its

    original three-function system implying the separation of the

    sacral-religious function and the political-military one. The

    Jimma, surprisingly, share something in common with them in

    this respect: the pastoral backgrounds of the Galla were also char-

    acterized by a developed age-class system within which the politi-

    cal-military and sacral-religious functions were performed by dif-

    ferent age-classes and, hence, rather sharply separated.4

    But the pre-Axial influences on the Axial Age sociopolitical

    development are not merely Indo-European. As Berezkin (1994,

    1995a, 1995b, 1997, 2000) noticed, the sociopolitical evolution

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 123

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • pattern of the most ancient agricultural centers in western Asia

    (associated, most likely, with the Aufrasians/Semito-Hamites

    [e.g., Militarjov & Shnirelman, 1984]) seems to have been charac-

    terized by the growth of cultural complexity through functional

    differentiation rather than social stratification. From the very

    beginning, this pattern appears to have differed significantly from

    the one observed in the pre-Columbian Americas, tropical Africa,

    or Oceania. Although, according to Berezkin, development in the

    Near East was interrupted between the 4th (Mesopotamia) and

    late 3rd (south Turkmenistan) millennia B.C.,5 its cultural-political

    heritage might have contributed to the development of the civil-

    temple communities in eastern Mediterrania. Those communities

    also seem to have formed a sound basis for the Axial Age transfor-

    mations (Diakonoff, Neronova, & Sventsitskaja, 1989).

    METHODOLOGICAL CONCLUSION

    Our research, we believe, shows that there is no impenetrable

    gap between so-called orthodox quantitative, worldwide, cross-cul-

    tural research, and qualitative comparative studies. The Early

    State project constituted an important step toward bridging the

    gap between the two types of cross-cultural research. Claessens

    data set is extremely valuable, and we think further statistical

    analysis of it will bring new and interesting results.

    The Early State remains, in many respects,an incomparable vol-

    ume. It looks like a miniature copy of the HRAF. It contains loads of

    fully formalized data, but you can also find details about the values

    of virtually any variable in question (using the subject index,

    which serves in this case as an analogue of the Outline of Cultural

    Materials [e.g., Murdock et al., 1987]). The recipe for such an

    impressive result was very simple. Claessen and Skalnk distrib-

    uted among The Early State contributors a well-designed question-

    naire and insisted on the contributors answering all the questions

    clearly and completely. Another important precondition for The

    Early State success was, naturally, a very well-designed, truly

    worldwide cross-cultural sample.

    It is unfortunate that, to our knowledge, The Early State algo-

    rithm has not been repeated. There is a pressing need for new

    worldwide, cross-cultural projects based on similar algorithms.

    124 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • APPENDIX

    Data Set Used by Claessen for Typologization of Early States (recoded for a statistic reanalysis)

    Mode of Mode of Personal Personal

    Succession Succession Property Property

    Professional of General of Special Codified Formal Codified of Land by of Land by

    Description Markets Traders Functionaries Functionaries Salaries Law Judges Punishment Aristocracy Commoners

    Angkor 3present 3present 2intermediate 2intermediate 0absent 1present 1present , 0absent 0absent

    Ankole 2limited 1absent 1hereditary 1hereditary 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent

    Axum 3present 3present 2intermediate 2intermediate , 0absent 0absent , 0absent 0absent

    Aztecs 3present 3present 3appointment 3appointment 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present

    China 3present 3present 2intermediate 2intermediate , 1present 0absent 1present 1present 1present

    Egypt , , 2intermediate 3appointment , 0absent 0absent , , ,

    France 3present 3present 2intermediate 3appointment 1present 1present 1present 1present 0absent 1present

    Hawaii 1absent 1absent 1hereditary , 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent , 0absent

    Iberia , , 3appointment , , 0absent 0absent , 0absent 1present

    Inca 3present , 2intermediate 2intermediate 1present 1present 1present 1present 0absent 0absent

    Jimma 3present 3present 3appointment 3appointment 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present

    Kachari 2limited , , , , , 1present 1present 0absent 0absent

    Kuba 3present 3present 2intermediate 3appointment 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present 0absent

    Maurya 3present 3present 3appointment 2intermediate 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present 1present

    Mongolia 3present 3present , , 0absent 0absent 0absent , 0absent 0absent

    Norway 2limited 2limited , , , 0absent 0absent , 0absent 0absent

    Scythia 3present 3present 1hereditary , , 0absent 0absent , 0absent 0absent

    Tahiti 1absent 1absent 1hereditary 1hereditary 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent

    Volta 2limited 2limited 2intermediate 2intermediate 0absent 0absent 0absent 0absent 1present 1present

    Yoruba 3present 3present 3appointment 3appointment 1present 0absent 1present 1present 0absent 0absent

    Zande 2limited 1absent 2intermediate 2intermediate 0absent 0absent 0absent 1present 0absent ,

    SOURCE: This appendix used as a basis Claessen and Skalnk (1978, p. 592, table XX ).

    125

    2003 SA

    GE

    Publications. A

    ll rights reserved. Not for com

    mercial use or unauthorized distribution.

    at EM

    OR

    Y U

    NIV

    on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.com

    Dow

    nloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Notes

    1. There is no explicit definition of the Mature State in The Early State

    (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978). However, the differences between the Early

    State and the Mature State are explained in Early State Dynamics

    (Claessen & van de Velde, 1987):

    The restriction of the definition (of the Early StateD.B., A.K.) to tributary

    relations instead of taxation (i.e., haphazard instead of regular contributions

    to supply the needs of the government), and to a class division that is only in-

    cipient makes it possible to draw a line between the Early State and more

    mature types of state (cf. Claessen, 1984; Shifferd, 1987). The level of the Ma-

    ture State is reached when a different type of legitimacy and a managerial,

    bureaucratic type of organization replace the earlier forms (cf. Bargatzky,

    1987); Shifferd (1987) adds to these factors the development of a legal system

    that transcends specific office holders, even the ruler, as well as the forma-

    tion of a permanent police force. These latter points are similar to Vitkins re-

    quirements of an extensive and qualitative broadening of the sphere of con-

    trol, the emergence of a bureaucratic apparatus and the development of a

    money economy that freed the sovereign from the necessity of allotting them

    (the office holders) land, together with corresponding economic rights of

    dominance (Vitkin, 1981, p. 450; cf. Smith, 1985, who distinguishes between

    Dominion and Bureaucracy). (pp. 4-5)

    2. Of course, the data represented in the volume were gathered in the

    1970s. Claessen himself recognized that in places corrections, or addi-

    tions might have been possible in the light of the knowledge we have now

    (personal communication, September 13, 2000). On the other hand,

    Claessen still believes (in our opinions, with complete justification) that

    the data are based on a series of case studies that are for the greater part

    still valuable (personal communication, September 13, 2000).

    3. Of course, both Christianity and Islam formed well after the Axial

    Age.However,both of them originated within the Abrahamic religious tra-

    dition that acquired its distinctly Axial Age shape during the Axial Age

    (including rather sharp separation of sacral religious and mundane politi-

    cal authorities [Diakonoff, Neronova, & Sventsitskaja, 1989]), which

    makes it possible to treat both these religions as the Axial ones (Jaspers,

    1953).

    4. Note that the role of the Galla prestate backgrounds in the astonish-

    ingly fast development of the Jimma in the direction of a Mature State was

    already quite clearly spelled out by Lewis, who contributed his description

    of Jimma Abba Jafar to The Early State project (Claessen & Skalnk, 1978,

    pp. 321-338).

    5. However, the polities developing squarely within this pattern appear

    to have continued to exist in some parts of south Arabia up to the end of the

    1st millennium B.C. (Frantsouzoff, 1995, 1997, 2000).

    126 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • References

    Alaev, L. B. (1999). Chastnaja sobstvennost na zemlju v drevnej isrednevekovoj Indii [Private ownership of land in ancient and medievalIndia]. In L. S. Vasilev (Ed.), Chastnaja sobstvennost na Vostoke (pp.94-119). Moskva, Russia: Institut ekonomicheskikh problemperekhodnogo perioda.

    Alaev, L. B. (2000). Problema selskoj obshchiny v klassovyhobshchestvakh [Village community in class societies]. In O. V. Volkova(Ed.), L. B. Alaev: obshchina v ego zhizni (pp. 168-181). Moskva, Russia:Vostochnaja literatura.

    Bargatzky, T. (1987). Upward evolution, suprasystem dominance, and theMature State. In H. J. M. Claessen & P. van de Velde (Eds.), Early statedynamics (pp. 24-38). Leiden, the Netherlands: Brill

    Belkov, P. L. (1993). Problema genezisa gosudarstva: pererastaet livozhdestvo v gosudarstvo? [The problem of state origin: Does chiefdomtransform into state?] In I. V. Sledzevski (Ed.), TsivilizatsiiTropicheskoj Afriki: obshchestva, kultury, jazyki (pp. 29-40). Moskva,Russia: Institut Afriki.

    Belkov, P. L. (1995). Rannee gosudarstvo, predgosudarstvo,protogosudarstvo: igra v terminy? [Early state, prastate, protostate: Anotions game?] In V. A. Popov (Ed.), Rannie formy politicheskojorganizatsii: ot pervobytnosti k gosudarstvennosti (pp. 165-187).Moskva, Russia: Vostochnaja literatura.

    Berezkin, Yu. E. (1994). Apatani i drevneyshiy Vostok: alternativnajamodel slozhnogo obshchestva [Apa Tanis and the ancient near east: Al-ternative model of complex society]. Kunstkamera: etnograficheskietetradi, 4, 5-19.

    Berezkin,Yu.E. (1995a).Alternative models of middle range society. Indi-vidualistic Asia vs. collectivistic America? In N. N. Kradin & V. A.Lynsha (Eds.), Alternative pathways to early state (pp. 75-83).Vladivostok, Russia: Dalnauka.

    Berezkin, Yu. E. (1995b). Vozhdestva i akefalnye sloznye obshchestva:arkheologicheskie dannye i ethnografichestke paralleli [Chiefdomsand acephalic complex societies: archaeological data and ethnographicparallels]. In V. A. Popov (Ed.), Rannie formy politicheskoj organizatsii:ot pervobytnosti k gosudarstvennosti (pp. 62-78). Moskva, Russia:Vostochnaja literatura.

    Berezkin, Yu. E. (1997). Amerika i Blizhniy Vostok: formy sotsio-politicheskoi organizatsii v dogosudarstvennuiu epokhu [America andthe Middle East. Forms of sociopolitical organization in the pre-stateperiod]. Vestnik drevnej istorii, 2, 3-24.

    Berezkin, Yu. E. (2000). Once again on horizontal and vertical links instructure of the middle range societies. In N. N. Kradin, A. V. Korotayev,D. M. Bondarenko, V. de Munck, & P. K. Wason (Eds.), Alternatives of so-cial evolution (pp.220-224).Vladivostok,Russia:Far Eastern Branch ofthe Russian Academy of Sciences.

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 127

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Bessmertnyj,Ju.L. (1969).Feofalnaja derevnja i rynok v Zapadnoj Evropev XII-XIII vekakh [Feudal village and market in western Europe in the12th and 13th centuries]. Moskva, Russia: Nauka.

    Bondarenko, D. M. (1995). Benin nakanune pervykh kontaktov sevropejtsami: Chelovek. Obshchestvo. Vlast [Benin on the eve of thefirst contacts with Europeans: Man. Society. Authority]. Moskva, Rus-sia: Institut Afriki.

    Bondarenko, D. M. (1998). Kontseptsija rannego gosudarstva: osnovnyepolozhenija i popytka ikh otsenki [The early state concept: Basic ten-ets and an attempt of their assessment]. In I. V. Sledzevski & D. M.Bondarenko (Eds.), Afrika: obshchestva, kultury, jazyki (pp. 16-26).Moskva, Russia: Institut Afriki.

    Burton, M. L., Moore, C. C., Whiting, J. W. M., & Romney, A. K. (1996). Re-gions based on social structure. Current Anthropology, 37, 87-123.

    Burton, M. L., & White, D. R. (1987). Cross-cultural surveys today. AnnualReview of Anthropology, 16, 143-160.

    Burton, M. L., & White, D. R. (1991). Regional comparisons, replications,and historical network analysis. Behavioral Science Research, 25, 55-78.

    Carneiro, R. L. (1987). Cross-currents in the theory of state formation.American Ethnologist, 14, 756-770.

    Carneiro, R. L. (2000). The muse of history and the science of culture. NewYork: Kluwer Academic.

    Chase-Dunn, C., & Hall, T. D. (1997). Rise and demise. Comparing world-systems. Boulder, CO: Westview.

    Claessen,H.J.M. (1984).The internal dynamics of the early state. CurrentAnthropology, 25, 365-370.

    Claessen, H. J. M. (1986). Kingship in the early state. Bijdragen tot detaal-, land-, en volkenkunde. Antropologica, 142(28), 113-127.

    Claessen,H.J.M. (1987).Kings, chiefs and officials:The political organiza-tion of Dahomey and Buganda compared. Journal of Legal Pluralismand Unofficial Law, 25(26), 203-241.

    Claessen, H. J. M. (1996). State. In D. Levinson & M. Ember (Eds.), Ency-clopedia of cultural anthropology (Vol. 4, pp. 1253-1257). New York:Holt, Rinehart & Winston.

    Claessen, H. J. M. (2000). Structural change. Evolution and evolutionismin cultural anthropology.Leiden, the Netherlands:Universiteit Leiden.

    Claessen, H. J. M., & Oosten, J. G. (Eds.). (1996). Ideology and the forma-tion of early states. Leiden, the Netherlands: Brill.

    Claessen, H. J. M., & Skalnk, P. (Eds.). (1978). The early state. The Hague,the Netherlands: Mouton.

    Claessen, H. J. M., & Skalnk, P. (Eds.). (1981). The study of the state. TheHague, the Netherlands: Mouton.

    Claessen, H. J. M., & van de Velde, P. (Eds.). (1987). Early state dynamics.Leiden, the Netherlands: Brill.

    Diakonoff, I. M., Neronova, V. D., & Sventsitskaja, V. A. (Eds.). (1989).Istorija drevnego mira [Ancient history] (Vol. 2). Moscow, Russia:Nauka.

    128 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Dow, M. M., Burton, M. L., & White, D. R. (1981). Multivariate modelingwith interdependent network data. Behavioral Science Research, 17,216-245.

    Dow, M. M., Burton, M. L., & White, D. R. (1982). Network autocorrelation.Social Networks, 4, 169-200.

    Dow, M. M., Burton, M. L., White, D. R., & Reitz, K. (1984). Galtons prob-lem as network autocorrelation. American Ethnologist, 11, 754-770.

    Dumzil, G. (1958). Lidologie tripartite des Indo-Europens (Vol. 31).Brussels, Belgium: Collection Latomus.

    Earle, T. K. (1978). Economic and social organization of a complexchiefdom: The Halelea district, Kauai, Hawaii. Ann Arbor: MichiganUniversity Press.

    Earle, T. K. (1997). How chiefs come to power. The political economy in pre-history. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Earle, T. K. (2000). Hawaii (800-1824). In D. M. Bondarenko & A. V.Korotayev (Eds.), Civilizational models of politogenesis (pp. 73-86).Moscow, Russia: Institute for African Studies.

    Eisenstadt, S. N. (1982). The Axial Age: The emergence of transcendentalvisions and the rise of clerics. Archives Europennes de Sociologie, 2,294-314.

    Eisenstadt, S. N. (Ed.). (1986). The origins and diversity of Axial Age civili-zations. Albany: State University of New York Press.

    Ember, C. R., & Ember, M. (1998). Cross-cultural research. In H. R. Bernard(Ed.), Handbook of methods in cultural anthropology (pp. 647-690).Walnut Creek, CA: AltaMira.

    Ember, M. (1971). An empirical test of Galtons problem. Ethnology, 10, 98-106.

    Frantsouzoff, S. A. (1995). The inscriptions from the temples of DhatHimyam at Raybun (tables I-II). Proceedings of the Seminar for Ara-bian Studies, 25, 15-27.

    Frantsouzoff, S. A. (1997). Regulation of conjugal relations in AncientRaybun. Proceedings of the Seminar for Arabian Studies, 27, 47-62.

    Frantsouzoff, S. A. (2000). The society of Rayburn. In N. N. Kradin, A. V.Korotayev, D. M. Bondarenko, V. de Munck, & P. K. Wason (Eds.), Alter-natives of social evolution (pp. 220-224). Vladivostok: Far EasternBranch of the Russian Academy of Sciences.

    Frazer, J. G. (1922). The golden bough (Vol. 1, abridged ed.). New York:Macmillan.

    Freud, S. (1923). Totem i tabu [Totem and taboo]. Petrograd, Russia.Fried, M. (1967). The evolution of political society: An essay in political an-

    thropology. New York: Random House.Gellner, E. (1988). Plough, sword and book. London: Collins Harvill.Genicot, L. (1990). Rural communities in the medieval west. London: Har-

    vard University Press.Geschiere, P. (1995). The complex interaction of state and society in post-

    colonial Africa. In M. A. van Bakel & J. G. Oosten (Eds.), The dynamicsof the early state paradigm (pp.7-22).Utrecht, the Netherlands: ISOR.

    Godiner, E. S. (1991). Politicheskaja antropologija o proiskhozhdeniigosudarstva [Political anthropology on the origin of the state]. In S. Ja.

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 129

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Kozlov & P. I. Puchkov (Eds.), Etnologicheskaja nauka za rubezhom:problemy, poiski, reshenija (pp. 51-77). Moscow, Russia: Nauka.

    Grinin, L. E. (1997). Formatsii i tsivilizatsii. Glava 4. Sotsialno-politicheskie, etnicheskie i dukhovnye aspekty sotsiologii istorii [For-mations and civilizations. Chapter 4. Socio-political, ethnic, and spiri-tual aspects of sociology of history]. Filosofija i obshchestvo, 5, 5-64.

    Haas, J. (1982). The evolution of the prehistoric state. New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press.

    Heusch, L. de. (1987). Ecrits sur la royaut sacre. Bruxelles, Belgium: Edi-tions de lUniversit de Bruxelles.

    Jakobson, V. A. (1997). Gosudarstvo kak sotsialnaja organizatsija(teoreticheskie problemy) [State as social organization (theoretical as-pects)]. Vostok/Oriens, 1, 5-15.

    Jaspers, K. (1953). The origin and goal of history. New Haven, CT: YaleUniversity Press.

    Kochakova, N. B. (1996). Dvadtsatiletie issledovatelskogo proektaRannee gosudarstvo [The twentieth anniversary of the early statescholarly project]. Vostok/Oriens, 4, 191-199.

    Kochakova, N. B. (1999). Rannee gosudarstvo i Afrika (analiticheskij obzorpublikatsij Mezhdunarodnogo issledovatelskogo proekta Ranneegosudarstvo) [The early state and Africa (an analytic review of publi-cations of the early state international scholarly project)]. Moscow,Russia: Institut Afriki.

    Kradin, N. N. (1998). Rannee gosudarstvo: kljuchevye aspekty kont-septsii i nekotorye momenty ejo istorii [The early state:Key aspects ofthe concept and some episodes of its history]. In I.V.Sledzevski & D.M.Bondarenko (Eds.), Afrika: obshchestva, kultury, jazyki (pp. 4-15). Mos-cow, Russia: Institut Afriki.

    Kubbel,L.E. (1988).Ocherki potestarno-politicheskoj etnografii [Essays ofpotestal and political ethnography]. Moscow, Russia: Nauka.

    Kullanda, S. (2002). Indo-European kinship terms revisited. Or does his-tory begin where linguistics ends? Current Anthropology,43,103-104.

    Kullanda, S. V. (1995). Tsar bogov Indra: junosha - voin - vozhd [Indra, thetsar of gods: Youth - warrior - chief]. In V. A. Popov (Ed.), Rannie formypoliticheskoj organizatsii: ot pervobytnosti k gosudarstvennosti (pp.104-125). Moscow, Russia: Vostochnaja literatura.

    Ldtke A. (Ed.). (1991). Herrschaft als soziale Praxis (Historische undsozialanthropologische Studien) [Dominance as social practice (Histor-ical and social anthropological studies)]. Gttingen, Germany:Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht.

    Militarjov, A. Ju., & Shnirelman, V. A. (1984). K probleme lokalizatsiidrevnejshikh afrazijtsev (opyt lingvo-arkheologicheskojrekonstruktsii) [Localization of the most ancient Afrasians (A linguis-tic-archaeological reconstruction)]. In I. F. Vardul, V. A. Dybo, P. M.Kozhin, A. Ju. Militarjov, & S. A. Starostin (Eds.), Lingvisticheskajareconstruktsija i drevnejshaja istorija Vostoka (Vol. 2, pp. 35-53).Moskva, Russia: Nauka.

    Murdock, G. P. (1967). Ethnographic atlas: A summary. Pittsburgh: Uni-versity of Pittsburgh Press.

    130 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Murdock, G. P., Ford, C. S., Hudson, A. E., Kennedy, R., Simmons, L. W., &Whiting, J. W. M. (1987). Outline of cultural materials. New Haven, CT:HRAF.

    Oosten, J. G., & van de Velde, P. (1994). Constructing the early state: Therise of a research programme. In M. van Bakel, R. Hagesteijn, & P. vande Velde (Eds.),Pivot politics.Changing cultural identities in early stateformation processes (pp. 7-21). Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis.

    Pugachjov, V. P., & Solovjov, A. I. (2000). Vvedenie v politologiju [Introduc-tion to political science]. Moskva, Russia: Aspekt.

    Shifferd, P. A. (1987). Aztecs and Africans: Political processes in twenty-two early states. In H. J. M. Claessen & P. van de Velde (Eds.), Earlystate dynamics (pp. 39-53). Leiden, the Netherlands: Brill.

    Smith, M. E. (1985). An aspectual analysis of polity formations. In H. J. M.Claessen, P. van de Velde, & M. E. Smith (Eds.), Development and de-cline. The evolution of sociopolitical organization (pp. 97-125). SouthHadley, MA: Bergin & Garvey.

    Tokarev, S. A. (1990). Rannie formy religii [Early forms of religion].Moskva, Russia: Politizdat.

    Vitkin, M. A. (1981). Marx and Weber on the primary state. In H. J. M.Claessen & P. Skalnk (Eds.), The study of the state (pp. 443-454). TheHague, the Netherlands: Mouton.

    Webb, M. C. (1984). The state of the art on state origins? Reviews in An-thropology, 11, 270-281.

    White,D.R.,Burton,M.L.,& Dow,M. (1981).Sexual division of labor in Af-rican agriculture. American Anthropologist, 83, 824-849.

    Wikander, S. (1938). Der arische Mnnerbund. Studien zur Indo-Iranischen Sprach- und Religionsgeschichte [Arian men secret society.Studies of Indo-Iranian linguistic and religious history].Lund,Sweden:Hkan Ohlssons Buchdruckerei.

    Dmitri M. Bondarenko is a senior research fellow and head of the Sector of

    Cultural Anthropology at the Center for Civilizational and Regional

    Studies, and senior research fellow of the Institute for African Studies, both

    of the Russian Academy of Sciences, and a professor at the Center of Social

    Anthropology at the Russian State University for the Humanities in Mos-

    cow. He received a Ph.D. and a Doctor of Science degree from Institute for

    African Studies of the Russian Academy of Sciences. He is the author of

    more than 120 publications, including three monographs (Benin on the

    Eve of the First Contacts with Europeans:Person.Society.Authority, 1995,

    Civilizations Theory and the Dynamics of Historical Process in

    Precolonial Tropical Africa, 1997, and Pre-Imperial Benin: Formation and

    Evolution of the Socio-Political Institutions System, 2001) and 16 edited

    volumes.He is a member of the Society for Cross-Cultural Research, the Eu-

    ropean Association of Social Anthropologists, and World Archaeological

    Congress. His spheres of interest include the formation and evolution of

    complex societies, the civilizations theory, and cultural anthropology of

    tropical Africa.

    Bondarenko, Korotayev / CLAESSENS DATABASE 131

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com

  • Andrey V. Korotayev is a professor in and head of the program in Anthro-

    pology of the East at the School of History, Political Science and Law at the

    Russian State University for the Humanities, and in the sociology faculty

    at the State University Higher School of Economics in Moscow. He is a se-

    nior research fellow of the Oriental Institute and of the Center for

    Civilizational and Regional Studies, Russian Academy of Sciences. He re-

    ceived a Ph.D. from Manchester University and a doctor of science degree

    from the Oriental Institute of the Russian Academy of Sciences. He has

    done field research in Yemen and Libya. He is the author of more than 130

    publications, including four monographs (Ancient Yemen, 1995; Factors of

    Social Evolution, 1997; Sabaean Studies: Some General Trends and Fac-

    tors of Evolution of the Sabaean Civilization, 1997; and Chiefdoms and

    Tribes of the Land of Hashid and Bakil, 1998). His research focuses on so-

    cial evolution, cross-cultural research, and Arabian anthropology.

    132 Cross-Cultural Research / February 2003

    2003 SAGE Publications. All rights reserved. Not for commercial use or unauthorized distribution. at EMORY UNIV on January 6, 2008 http://ccr.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://ccr.sagepub.com