economic and institutional determinants in fiscal pressure: an application to the european case

20
Agustin Molina-Morales, Ignacio Amate-Fortes and Almudena Guarnido-Rueda are professors of Applied Economics at the University of Almeria, Spain. The authors thank two anonymous reviewers for suggestions that have improved the quality of this paper. Any remaining mistakes are the responsibility of the authors. A preliminary version of this paper was presented at the XIII Meeting of Applied Economics, Sevilla, May 2010. 573 ©2011, Journal of Economic Issues / Association for Evolutionary Economics JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES Vol. XLV No. 3 September 2011 DOI 10.2753/JEI0021-3624450303 Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure: An Application to the European Case Agustin Molina-Morales, Ignacio Amate-Fortes and Almudena Guarnido-Rueda Abstract: The objective of this study has been to undertake an analysis of the economic and institutional determining factors of fiscal pressure in a group of European countries with different levels of economic development, recent history, or level of cooperation and integration among them. We have used a panel of data from 40 countries and a time period of eleven years. Apart from the variables generally used, we have introduced additional ones such as governing party ideology, rate of economic freedom of Euro-area countries, together with another set of institutional variables. Results obtained show that the purely economic model improves when institutional and geopolitical variables are included and, in this way, it is possible to see which countries governed by the left, belonging to the Euro-area or having been members of the Soviet block, and with economic freedom, are more liable to increase fiscal pressure. Keywords: fiscal pressure, institutions, public expenditure JEL Classification Codes: B15, F5, H11, H20 Studying the causes for the increase in size of the public sector has traditionally been related to evolution in expenditure. Different theories have been developed and contrasted analyzing the issue both from the demand and from the supply (Albi, González-Páramo and Zubiri 2004). Indeed, after the approach presented by Adolf Wagner in the last quarter of the nineteenth century, several criteria have been proposed to explain said growth, of course, taking into account, in a more or less explicit manner, that the difficulty for increasing taxes is a limiting factor in the expansion of expenditure. Outstanding among the theories that explicitly refer to this

Upload: almudena

Post on 10-Dec-2016

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Agustin Molina-Morales, Ignacio Amate-Fortes and Almudena Guarnido-Rueda are professors of Applied Economics at the University of Almeria, Spain. The authors thank two anonymous reviewers for suggestions that have improved the quality of this paper. Any remaining mistakes are the responsibility of the authors. A preliminary version of this paper was presented at the XIII Meeting of Applied Economics, Sevilla, May 2010.

573 ©2011, Journal of Economic Issues / Association for Evolutionary Economics

JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES Vol. XLV No. 3 September 2011 DOI 10.2753/JEI0021-3624450303

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure: An Application to the European Case

Agustin Molina-Morales, Ignacio Amate-Fortes

and Almudena Guarnido-Rueda

Abstract: The objective of this study has been to undertake an analysis of the economic and institutional determining factors of fiscal pressure in a group of European countries with different levels of economic development, recent history, or level of cooperation and integration among them. We have used a panel of data from 40 countries and a time period of eleven years. Apart from the variables generally used, we have introduced additional ones such as governing party ideology, rate of economic freedom of Euro-area countries, together with another set of institutional variables. Results obtained show that the purely economic model improves when institutional and geopolitical variables are included and, in this way, it is possible to see which countries governed by the left, belonging to the Euro-area or having been members of the Soviet block, and with economic freedom, are more liable to increase fiscal pressure. Keywords: fiscal pressure, institutions, public expenditure JEL Classification Codes: B15, F5, H11, H20

Studying the causes for the increase in size of the public sector has traditionally been related to evolution in expenditure. Different theories have been developed and contrasted analyzing the issue both from the demand and from the supply (Albi, González-Páramo and Zubiri 2004). Indeed, after the approach presented by Adolf Wagner in the last quarter of the nineteenth century, several criteria have been proposed to explain said growth, of course, taking into account, in a more or less explicit manner, that the difficulty for increasing taxes is a limiting factor in the expansion of expenditure. Outstanding among the theories that explicitly refer to this

574

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

limitation is the displacement effect of Peacock and Wiseman (1961), which considers that social commotions lead to an acceptance of the increase in taxes, and the theory of Fiscal Illusion (Puviani 1903), which suggests that tax load is perceived to be lower than it actually is. In any case, there is an imbalance between the approaches from the side of expenditures and revenues. It isn’t a single case in studies of the evolution of public finances, since the same has occurred, for example, in the case of incidence analysis: the reference to taxes has a long history and relative to expenditure only began to generalize in the 1970s.1

This study is intended to contribute to the study of the behavior and evolution of fiscal pressure, from the knowledge already established by theory and its empirical contrast introducing, apart from the purely economic factors, those institutional parameters that could be determinant for explaining the evolution in fiscal pressure.

For this purpose, a model using panel data from 40 countries in the European continent has been applied over a period of time between 1996 and 2006. The use of such a heterogeneous sample is a relevant and new aspect in the analysis of fiscal pressure as it includes countries with different levels of economic development that have undergone different historical processes of integration. Empirical studies in this field using institutional variables focus on studying developing countries; studies on developed and least developed countries (Piancastelli 2001) seldom use institutional variables. Using the model we developed, we analyzed the economic and institutional determining factors of fiscal pressure, separating them in order to distinguish the influence of both types of variables, which is the main objective of this study. For this purpose we have introduced a set of variables, which we understand are a novelty in this type of empirical study. These variables include: the index of economic freedom, the quality index of institutional infrastructure, ideology of the dominant party, Euro-area membership, prior membership of the Soviet block, and other geographic variables like the fiscal behavior in Northern countries and Mediterranean countries. The results of this model lead us to conclude that the evolution in fiscal pressure is substantially better explained when the entire set of institutional and geopolitical variables is introduced.

The study is structured as follows: following this introduction, the next section reviews the different explanatory theories for the evolution of income tax. The third portion presents an analysis of the determining factors in fiscal pressure, differentiating and assessing economic and institutional factors. In the fourth part, a panel data model that includes 40 countries, is applied to determine the influence of the different variables on fiscal pressure. The final section presents the conclusions.

Explanatory Theories for the Evolution of and the

Determining Factors in Fiscal Income Hinrichs (1966) presented an autonomous theory about change in tax structure during economic development. This study considers that traditional societies obtain government revenues primarily from non-fiscal sources or from traditional direct taxes. In the transition to modern society, these sources gradually decrease, and when

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

575

the change starts, indirect taxing increases in importance, particularly in external trade. In time, the internal indirect taxes increase to higher levels than the external ones. With respect to direct taxing, the old taxes decrease as income grows and the modern taxes gradually take their place. The flexibility of the structure of the increased taxes can be analyzed bearing in mind the differences in cultural styles in Northern and Latin countries. It should be noted that this theory incorporates several terms of institutional content: traditional societies, transition to modern society, change, external versus internal trade, and cultural style.

From here, and as already noted, few studies have been performed. For expository reasons we have chosen to separate the two sets of variables that are used. Traditionally, empirical analyses of fiscal pressure have usually placed emphasis on the determining economic factors. More recently, studies have started to analyze the relevance of the institutional factors, which may help to explain fiscal pressure. In our model we pay special attention to this set of institutional variables. In fact, through our work we try to explain the effect of institutional variables commonly used in conjunction with economic and geopolitical variables, applied to a sample that includes countries with different levels of development. Economic Factors

The analysis of factors determining the level of income tax in countries has a long tradition dating back to the studies of Bahl (1971), Bird (1976), Chelliah, Bass and Kelly (1975), Lotz and Morss (1970), Musgrave (1969) and Tait, Gratz and Eichengreen (1979). Among these studies there is a wide consensus about the fact that specific realities in the countries imply different economic, social and even institutional factors that vary according to their level of development. Among the traditional variables indicated by these authors, we may quote the economic size of the country, its level of income per capita, commercial openness and specialization, productive structure, level of urbanization, illiteracy rate, level of formality in the financial system, or openness level of the economy. The structure of existing taxes (Feenberg and Rosen 1987) and the ability of the government to collect taxes (Eshag 1983) are other factors that have been considered for explaining fiscal pressure.

Tanzi (1992) adds public debt as a factor, which tends to increase the level of taxes. Wallace and Bahl (2005) also add demographic features to the analysis and they conclude that in countries with the highest demographic growth rates there is a tendency to collect less as it is more difficult to register new contributors.

Easterly and Rebelo (1993) describe the empirical relations among the fiscal policy variables, level of development and rate of growth, concluding that there is a strong relation between level of growth and fiscal structure. In the same line as Hinrichs, they argue that poor countries are fundamentally based on taxes on international trade, while taxes on income are important in developed economies. They consider that Wagner’s “law” applies from the side of income, as they find that the government income/GDP ratio increases as the consumer price index (CPI) grows, both in the cross-sectional and longitudinal analyses. It is observed that as

576

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

income increases, taxes on international trade decrease as a percentage of the public income, while the rate of income tax increases. As population increases, the rate of taxes on consumption decreases with respect to public income. They consider that “in general, democracies and non-democracies implement different policies.” The character of the political system is not important, however, in terms of the fiscal policy once income is controlled. The effects of the income level and the population level on the type of fiscal system are surely related to the administrative costs and those for undertaking taxation.

Lammert (2004) considers how the scale economies that may be produced should be taken into account, among other factors, to determine the level of taxation. For this author, religion is important in the fiscal regimes structure. Capacity for payment is the dominant principle in Protestant countries, and benefit is the dominant principle in Catholic countries. Apart from these, there are other influences such as political parties, level of corporatism, density of unions and frequency of strikes, percentage of retired contributors, and the higher or lower level of economic growth.2

In this brief analysis of the economic literature, we shall finally underscore the study of Tavares (2004) whose probit model concluded that right-wing governments favor the reductions in expenses and the left-wing ones prefer increases in income tax.

Institutional Variables

The most widespread current in new institutionalism3 is the so-called “Law and

Economics,” which analyzes transaction costs and ownership rights. The best known names in Law and Economics are Armen Alchian, Ronald Coase, Harold Demsetz, Richard Posner and Oliver Williamson. Another important current is known as “Constitutional Political Economy,” by James Buchanan from the Public Choice School. The “New Economic History” of Fogel and North also sees history as a process of evolution of institutions. The “Theory of Human Capital” by Schultz should also be taken into consideration, or Gary Becker’s “Economic Analysis of Institutions and of Family and Marriage Functions.”

Following the classification offered by Aixalá and Fabro (2007) we identify seven groups of institutional factors:

1. Civil Liberties, which include a whole set of rights like freedom of press, freedom

of expression, religious freedom, freedom for meeting, and impartial legal procedures.

2. Political Rights, which measure the liberty of citizens to participate in the political process in an equitable manner, the sufficient competence in the political sphere and the holding of free and impartial elections.

3. Economic Freedom, which includes the security of legally acquired property rights and the liberty to undertake voluntary transactions both within and outside the frontiers of the nation (Gwartney and Lawson 2003).

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

577

4. Corruption, which refers to using a public office for personal benefit, including bribes, extortion and other criminal offenses like fraud and fund embezzlement (Mauro 1995).

5. Social Capital, which includes institutions, relations and norms that comprise the quality and quantity of social interactions in a society, such as general confidence indicators and civic norms (Putnam 1993).

6. Political Instability, which includes, on one hand, indexes that combine variables related to phenomena of social discomfort, such as revolts, murders and coups, and on the other hand, rate measures for the renewal of the executive, interpreted as an indicator of its instability or failure (Alesina and Perotti 1994).

7. Institutional Infrastructure, which is a series of indicators that collect assessments of several aspects related to the above points, such as property rights security, government policies predictability, legal system reliability, legislative system efficiency, bureaucracy efficiency, corruption, the Rule of Law, expropriation risk, and several categories of political instability.

Aixalá and Fabro (2007) indicate that although the empirical studies include

civil liberties and political rights in a single variable, it is more convenient to separate these concepts given the existence of indicators that emphasize one more than the other.

There are two problems presented by the institutional variables. First, the low time coverage of many indicators, which hinders the adequate use of panel data. And second, the differences in the coverage of countries that condition the researcher when deciding the group of countries to analyze. Even so, the interest for this type of variables among researchers is making them become more complete as to the time period under consideration and the number of countries analyzed.

The inclusion of institutional variables in empirical studies of fiscal pressure is relatively recent, the majority of which focus on the analysis of developing countries. Even so, some researchers already ascribed to institutions a very important role in the elaboration of tax systems before the neoinstitutionalism boom. In this way, Kaldor (1963) said that political institutions are fundamental for the success of any tax reform. In this same sense, Bird (1989) underlined the importance of the dimension of tax administration in obtaining an efficient tax system in transitional and developing countries.

Cheibub’s (1998) analysis determines the extent to which the political regime affects the capacity for collecting tax, and reaches the conclusion that the effect is nonexistent, so political instability in democratic regimes is irrelevant for obtaining higher or lower tax collection. Torgler (2005), however, demonstrates that in the most democratic countries, contributors are more willing to pay taxes. Benhabib and Przeworski (2006), however, maintain that although a more democratic regime leads to the application of more redistributive policies, this is not maintained in societies with high levels of inequality, as the elites do not accept extreme redistributive policies. In addition, Bird, Martínez-Vázquez and Torgler (2004) analyze the factors that determine the tax effort of a series of developing countries, using traditional and

578

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

institutional variables, reaching the conclusion that the latter are relevant for analyzing fiscal pressure in this set of countries.

The Model

The model we use to try to explain the fiscal pressure throughout economic, institutional and geopolitical variables is a lineal model. The sample introduces novelties in scope, as we analyze the case of 40 European countries, grouping them by five different levels of development: 1) those in transit from a dictatorial to a democratic regime, 2) capitalist countries and those in a process of economic liberalization, 3) countries sharing a common currency, 4) countries that had been members of the Soviet block, and 5) those with totally different religions (Table 1).

The period of time considered was limited to the availability of data, especially that of the institutional variables. Even so, we have managed to generate a panel data model for an 11-year period from 1996 to 2006. In this sense, the use of panel data to study the economic and institutional determinants of fiscal pressure is also novel because the majority of empirical studies use cross-section data, as the institutional indexes were created relatively recently, and a series of more than 10 years has not

Table 1. Sample Used

Countries in the Economic and

Monetary Union in 2006

Other EU Countries in

2006 Other European

Countries

Austria Belgium Finland France Germany Greece Holland Ireland Italy Luxembourg Portugal Spain

Czech Republic Cyprus Denmark Estonia Hungary Latvia Lithuania Malta Poland Slovakia Slovenia Sweden United Kingdom

Albania Byelorussia Bosnia and

Herzegovina Bulgaria Croatia Iceland Macedonia Moldavia Norway Romania Russia Serbia and

Montenegro Sweden Turkey Ukraine

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

579

been available for some of these indicators. In this way we have been able to analyze 440 observations for each of the variables used, because we have used a sample of 40 countries over an 11-year period. Data

The variables used are summarized in Table 2.

The Model

We estimated a linear model by using two estimators: Feasible Generalized Least Squares (FGLS) and Panel Corrected Standard Errors (PCSE). The Wooldridge test that was performed determined that the model presents a problem of autocorrelation. Also, the modified Wald test shows that the model is also heteroscedastic. To fix this, the two best estimators were FGLS and PCSE.4

We used a panel of data to jointly assess all the institutional variables used. Using panel data instead of cross-section analysis allows us to control the individual heterogeneity, produce data with a higher degree of variability and a lower level of collinearity among the regressors, study dynamic adjustment processes, identify and measure effects that are not detectable with pure cross-section or time series data, and build and contrast models of more complex behavior than would be possible using simpler data.

We have undertaken ten different estimates. In the first two estimates we used a model with only economic variables. The model is the following:

PFt = α + β1Yi,t-1 + β2GPit + β3AGRit + ηi + δt + μit (1)

where PF is fiscal pressure, Y is per capita income measured by GDP, GP is public expenditure with respect to GDP, AGR is the influence the agricultural sector has on GDP, ηi registers the individual unnoticed effects in each country that are not constant in time, and δt measures the unnoticed time effects that vary in time but do not differ from one country to another.

Subsequently, we have added to the original model the institutional and geopolitical variables used. In this case, the estimated model is the following:

PFt = α + β1Yi,t-1 + β2GPit + β3AGRit + γ1ILCit + γ2IDPit + γ3ILEit + γ4IPCit + γ5ICIIit + λ1PARTYit + λ2EUROit + λ3PECOSi+ λ4RELIGIONit+ λ5MEDITERRANEANi + λ6NORDICi + ηi + δt + μit (2) where ILC is the index of civil liberties, IDP is the index of political liberties, ILE is the index of economic liberties, whether prepared by the Fraser Institute or by the Heritage Foundation, IPC is the corruption perception index, ICII is the index measuring the quality of institutional infrastructure, PARTY is the dummy variable whose value is one if the governing party is left wing, EURO is the dummy variable

580

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

Table 2. Taxonomy of Modelized Variables

continued

NATURE NAME DESCRIPTION

Economic

Tax Pressure

Defined as income tax (taxes and contributions to Social Security) in relation to GDP. Source: Governments Finance Statistics, FMI.

Public Expenditure

Defined as all non-financial expenditures made by the public sector in relation to GDP. We consider this variable very important as a determining factor in tax pressure. In fact, more than a century ago, Wicksell (1896) said that the decisions of assigning public resources are always efficient provided they are efficiently financed. Besides, many of the countries we are analyzing here acquired the commitment of maintaining sound public finances, so income taxes are closely related to public expenditure. Source: Governments Finance Statistics, FMI.

Public Deficit

Defined as the Government's capacity or need for lending and borrowing. The reason that has lead us to use this variable is the same as the one used for public expenditure. The commitment of most of these countries to the consolidation of public finances makes a higher public deficit lead to a higher tax pressure. Source: Governments Finance Statistics, FMI.

GDP Per Capita

Measured in American Dollars, it is a proxy variable for the development level of a country. A direct relation to tax pressure is expected (Bahl 1971; Chelliah 1971). In contrast with other studies, this variable has been used with a delay, as direct taxes encumber the income obtained the previous year. Source: Governments Finance Statistics, FMI.

Importance of the

Agricultural Sector in

GDP

Following the main studies undertaken in this field, we have decided to use this variable to verify the inverse ratio that exists between tax pressure and the importance of the agricultural sector within economy, as public expenditure is concentrated in towns, and in many countries agriculture is exempt from tax (Bahl 2003). Source: World Bank.

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

581

continued

NATURE NAME DESCRIPTION

Institutional

Civil Liberties

Civil Liberties Index: It is an index prepared by the NGO Freedom House, which includes assessments on religious and press freedom, Rule of Law, economic, human and association rights. It is a very widely used index in empirical studies.

Political Rights

Index of Political Rights: It is an index prepared by the NGO Freedom House, which includes assessments on free and impartial elections, multiple political parties, a significant opposition, military domination and self-determination of minority groups. The rate of use of this index is high in empirical studies.a

Economic Freedom

Index of Economic Freedom: It is an index prepared by the Heritage Foundation Research Institute/Wall Street Journal which includes assessments on commercial policy, Government tax load, Government intervention on economy, monetary policy, foreign investment and capital flow, foreign activity, financial activity, salary and price control, property rights, and black market regulation and activity. This indicator is not frequently used in empirical studies.

Index of Economic Freedom in the world: It is an index prepared by the non-profit research Fraser Institute including assessments about government size, legal structure and security of property rights, monetary policy and inflation, freedom of trade and regulation of credit, work and business. It is the most widely used indicator of this group by researchers.b

Corruption

Index of perception of corruption: It is an index prepared by the NGO Transparency International including perceptions of businessmen, academics and analysts about the level of corruption in civil servants and politicians. It is the most widely used indicator of this group of indexes as it includes assessments of 150 countries. We cannot use the rest of indicators due to the sample problems mentioned above.

582

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

Table 2. Taxonomy of Modelized Variables (continued)

continued

NATURE NAME DESCRIPTION

Institutional (continued)

Social Capitalc

Due to the lack of availability of data, we have not been able to use variables to measure the social capital, nor indicators to quantify the political instability. Even so, for the latter, there is an index prepared by the World Bank which measures the perception of the probability for the government to be subject to destabilization, which although immersed in a set of variables that measure the quality of institutional infrastructure, we use it in a third assessment as an indicator of political instability. This lack of data also often prevents us from using more than one variable within one group of institutional variables, which would have allowed us to evaluate the solidity of the model in a higher measure.

Political Instability

Index of Political Instability: It is an index prepared by the World Bank belonging to a group of indicators called Worldwide Governance Research Indicators. Although this index is used together with the rest of indexes to measure the quality of institutional infrastructure, as we have mentioned above, we use this index separately in a third assessment to analyse how the tax pressure is affected by a higher or lower political stability. In particular, this indicator quantifies the perception of the probability for the government to be subject to actions of destabilization or to be overthrown by unconstitutional or violent means, including terrorism.

Institutional Infrastructure

Governance Aggregate Indicators: These are six indicators prepared by the World Bank for measuring the quality of institutional infrastructure. These indexes are the following:

Voice and Responsibility, which measures the level to which the citizens of a country can participate in the election of their government, as well as the freedom of expression, freedom of association and press freedom.

Political Instability, already defined above.

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

583

continued

NATURE NAME DESCRIPTION

Institutional (continued)

Institutional Infrastructure

(continued)

Government Efficiency, measuring the quality of public service, quality of public administration and the level to which it is independent from political pressures, quality of the formulation and implementation of policies, and credibility of the government commitment with those policies.

Regulatory Quality, measuring the capacity of the government to formulate and apply appropriate policies and regulations allowing for and promoting private sector development.

Rule of Law, measuring the level to which the agents trust and obey social rules and, particularly, to which they trust and obey the police and the courts, they trust contracts, as well as the probability of crimes and violent acts to be committed.

Control of Corruption, which measures the level to which public power is used for private benefit, as well as small and large scale corruption, and the control of the State by select minorities and private interests.d

Instrumental

Governing Political Party

Its value is one if the government is left wing or left-centre, otherwise it is zero. With this variable we want to verify whether left-wing governments are more inclined to increase tax pressure.

Euro-Area Membership

Its value is one if the country belongs to the Euro area, otherwise it is zero. Again we try to quantify the effect that creation of the single currency has had on tax pressure.

Mediterranean Countries

Its value is one if the country has a Mediterranean coast, otherwise it is zero. With this variable we try to analyze tax behavior in the Mediterranean countries.

Northern Countries

Its value is one it the country is Northern (Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Iceland, Norway and Sweden), otherwise it is zero. With this we want to quantify the choice for a higher tax pressure in these countries.

584

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

Table 2. Taxonomy of Modelized Variables (continued)

Notes:

a Both indexes (index of civil liberties and index of political liberties) are usually used by means of an indicator of democracy or political liberty. However, as mentioned by Aixalá and Fabro (2007), both variables should be used separately, as they refer to different concepts and, therefore, they lead to different implications for tax pressure.

b Assessment of both indexes is undertaken alternately, allowing us to verify the solidity of our model. c We have followed the classification, mentioned above, done by Aixalá and Fabro (2007). d As we have explained above, we have constructed a global indicator which allows us to quantify

the effects of the quality of institutional infrastructure on tax pressure. Another indicator is the average value of these six indicators. Later, in an alternative assessment, we will obtain from this global indicator the index which measures the political stability and use it individually to measure its effect on the dependent variable. Using two different measures for the quality of institutional infrastructure also allows us to verify again the solidity of the model.

NATURE NAME DESCRIPTION

Ex-Communist Countries

Its value is one if the country belonged to the group of countries with communist regimes, strongly related to the USSR or belonging to the USSR itself, otherwise it is zero. With this variable we try to analyze whether this historical fact has generated a pattern of behavior with respect to taxation in these countries.

Instrumental (continued)

Majority Religion

It measures the rate of Catholic Christians with respect to the rest of the population. This allows us to verify whether religion has an influence on paying tax.

whose value is one if the country belongs to the Euro area, PECOS is the dummy variable whose value is one if the country has been a satellite country of or has belonged to the USSR, RELIGION measures the percentage of Catholics over the entire population of the country, MEDITERRANEAN is the dummy variable that identifies those countries on the Mediterranean coast and NORDIC is the dummy variable whose value is one if is a Nordic country.

Finally, the third estimated model adopts the following form:

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

585

PFt = α + β1Yi,t-1 + β2GPit + β3AGRit + γ1ILCit + γ2IDPit + γ3ILEit + γ4IPCit + γ5ICIIit + γ6IEPit+ λ1PARTYit + λ2EUROit + λ3PECOSi + λ4RELIGIONit + λ5MEDITERRANEANi + λ6NORDICi + ηi + δt + μit (3) where the only difference with respect to the previous model is the inclusion of the variable IEP that measures the political stability and is not part of the calculation to obtain ICII (institutional infrastructure quality index). Results

After estimating the model explained by FGLS and PCSE, and verifying the global significance of the models used, we obtained the results presented in Tables 3, 4 and 5.

Table 3. Results of the Assessment of the Model Using Exclusively Economic Variables

Tax Pressure

GDP Per Capita (One Delay) 6.00

(0.26)

Public Deficit 0.34***

(6.22)

Public Expenditure 0.75***

(29.78)

Agriculture -0.39***

(-6.15)

Constant 6.35***

(4.86)

R2 0.878

* 10% significant. ** 5% significant. *** 1% significant.

586

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

Table 4. Results of the Assessment of Model 1 Using Economic, Institutional and Instrumental Variables

* significant 10%; ** significant 5%; *** significant 1%.

Tax Pressure

GDP Per Capita (One Delay) 0.00005**

(1.83) 0.00005**

(1.87) Public Deficit 0.42***

(7.42) 0.33***

(6.03) Public Expenditure 0.84***

(34.33) 0.79***

(31.37) Agriculture -0.29***

(-5.42) -0.32***

(-4.98) Civil Liberties 0.51*

(1.45) 0.77**

(2.07) Political Rights 1.67***

(4.02) 1.30***

(2.96) Economic Freedom (Heritage Foundation) 0.12***

(3.25)

Economic Freedom in the World (Fraser Institute)

1.32***

(3.88) Perception of Corruption -0.13

(-0.51) -0.19

(-0.67) Quality of Institutional Infrastructure 0.04

(1.02) 0.06*

(1.44) Political Party 0.43*

(1.22) 0.19

(0.53) Euro Area 0.79**

(1.64) 0.79*

(1.59) Ex-Communist Countries 2.59***

(3.05) 3.16***

(3.14) Northern Countries 1.28*

(1.50) 1.69*

(1.59) Mediterranean Countries 1.73***

(2.90) 2.05***

(2.79) Religion -0.0005

(-0.06) -0.005 (-0.54)

Constant -14.11***

(-4.07) -14.45***

(-3.86)

R2 0.915 0.913

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

587

Table 5. Results of Assessment of Model 2 with Economic, Institutional and Instrumental Variables

* significant 10%; ** significant 5%; *** significant 1%.

Tax Pressure

GDP Per Capita (One Delay) 0.00005**

(1.78) 0.00005**

(1.95)

Public Deficit 0.42***

(7.35)0.34***

(6.14)Public Expenditure 0.84***

(33.74) 0.80***

(31.97) Agriculture -0.30***

(-5.40) -0.31***

(-4.93) Civil Liberties 0.51*

(1.43) 0.78**

(2.08) Political Rights 1.71***

(4.02) 1.32***

(2.99) Economic Freedom (Heritage Foundation) 0.11***

(3.02)

Economic Freedom in the World (Fraser Institute)

1.33***

(3.94) Perception of Corruption -0.12

(-0.47) -0.19

(-0.68) Quality of Institutional Infrastructure

(excluding political stability) 0.04

(1.12) 0.05*

(1.25) Political Stability -0.0006

(-0.03) 0.005 (0.26)

Political Party 0.44*

(1.23) 0.20

(0.56) Euro Area 0.77*

(1.59) 0.80*

(1.61) Ex-Communist Countries 2.71***

(3.05) 3.15***

(3.18) Northern Countries 1.32*

(1.51) 1.70**

(1.66) Mediterranean Countries 1.71***

(2.75) 1.96***

(2.73) Religion -0.0001

(-0.01) -0.004 (-0.41)

Constant -14.11***

(-4.02) -14.73***

(-3.95) R2 0.915 0.914

588

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

The first conclusion is that the model improves when we introduce institutional and geopolitical variables in the purely economic model. In fact, the adjustment quality, measured by the R2, changes from 0.77 to over 0.80. On the other hand, the different estimates according to the estimator used and the variables used do not differ substantially, so the model is robust.

As for the values obtained, most cases coincide with what is expected a priori. The most surprising result may be the parameter assessed for GDP per capita, because although it is significant and positive, its importance in determining fiscal pressure is very low. In fact, the estimated parameter value for this variable is around zero. Even so, this result coincides with other empirical studies such as the one by Bird, Martínez-Vázquez and Torgler (2004), in which the sign of the parameter for the GDP per capita varies depending on the specification of the model assessed, and the value is also usually quite low.

Public expenditure, which we have introduced in the analysis offers the expected results; there is a positive and very significant effect for public expenditure on fiscal pressure in these countries.

As for the productive specialization of the European countries, the agricultural sector has a clearly negative effect on fiscal pressure, which proves the difficulty to encumber economic activity in this sector. Besides, if we take for granted that in most developed countries the importance of agriculture on the economy is lowest, we can conclude that fiscal pressure grows as economic development increases.

As to the effect of both the index of civil liberties and the index of political rights on fiscal pressure, it is remarkable. European countries with higher freedom of 1) expression and belief, and 2) association and legal security, as well as the most democratic regimes, have the lowest fiscal pressure. Furthermore, the level of significance of these two variables is small. This result agrees with the conclusions of Cheibub (1998) that the political regime has no effect on the capacity for raising taxes.

As to the impact of economic freedom on fiscal pressure, the result varies with the index used. In the case of the indicator prepared by the Heritage Foundation, the estimated parameter changes signs depending on the estimator used and also has little significance. By contrast, the index generated by the Fraser Institute has a positive and significant effect. This result shows a positive relation between economic freedom and fiscal pressure, so the protection of property rights, a lower level of corruption, and solidity in tax policy have a positive effect on fiscal pressure.

The regressor sign of the corruption level in European economies changes depending on the variables included in the model. It also is not very significant. Something similar happens with the parameter measuring the effect of the quality of institutional infrastructure on fiscal pressure. Even so, the effect is positive, so with better institutional infrastructures, fiscal pressure is higher, and, also, this value does not vary with the two measures we have used. In fact, using the political stability variable has not improved the model, as its significance is very low, and its value is close to 0.

With respect to the geopolitical variables, the effect of ideology of the governing

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

589

political party in each country on fiscal pressure is positive (i.e., when left-wing parties are governing in Europe, there is higher fiscal pressure in these countries). This result is in line with Tavares (2004), who concluded that while right-wing governments are in favor of reducing public expenditure, left-wing parties prefer to increase income tax.

On the other hand, belonging to the Euro area also has a positive and significant effect, so the commitments these countries have had to reach in order to share the same currency, with respect to consolidation of public finances, has lead to an increase in fiscal pressure in the area.

The historical background also exhibits a pattern of tax behavior. Thus we find a positive regressor incidence measuring the effect of belonging to the group of ex-Communist countries on fiscal pressure. Belonging to a Nordic or Mediterranean area also yields higher fiscal pressure results in these countries. As expected, the effect on the fiscal pressure is higher in the case of the Nordic countries than in the case of Mediterranean countries.

Finally, we have not obtained any significant result for religion.

Conclusions Results obtained in our empirical study allow us to conclude that the inclusion of institutional and geopolitical variables in the analysis of determinants of fiscal pressure in the case of European countries is an improvement over the purely economic study. The sample used significantly enriches the analysis by providing differences in the 40 countries studied as to the level of economic development, the economic system in force, and belonging to different economic blocks, yields more interesting results. Besides, based on the assessments obtained, we can say that the level of economic development favorably affects the evolution of fiscal pressure, the same as public expenditure or public deficit do.

The political regime, however, yields a negative result, so a higher level of democracy does not entail higher fiscal pressure. Who is governing may be more important, as the left-wing parties increase fiscal pressure.

On the other hand, belonging to the Euro area and having been a member of the Soviet block have a positive effect on fiscal pressure. Also, Mediterranean and Nordic tax behavior do not differ much from each other; the Nordic countries have an even more intense influence on fiscal pressure.

Notes 1. The most complete analysis on tax illusion is the one by Buchanan (1967). See also Reis-Mourao

(2008). 2. Recently many analyses have been prepared on tax structures, mainly referring to developed countries,

focusing attention on the composition of the tax packages, on searching budgetary balance and convergence of the different tax systems. This case was influenced by the possible tax harmonization among European Union countries. See, among others, Boscá, García and Taguas (2005), Esteve, Sosvilla and Tamarit (2000), Hallerberg, Strauch and Von Hagen (2004), Maroto-Illera and Mulas-Granados (2001), Mierau, Jong-A-Ping and DeHaan (2007), Mulas-Granados (2003), and Pirttilä

590

Molina-Morales, Amate-Fortes and Guarnido-Rueda

(2000). These studies have attended to the most relevant and influential institutional variables for the evolution of fiscal pressure, although that was not their main objective. The study by Alesina and Perotti (1996) can be considered essential, as it was a great incentive for this type of analysis, despite its main objective being to analyze the effects of income inequality on growth.

3. The use of the expression “new institutional economy” has currently become generalized to refer to a wide variety of approaches and new economic theories.

4. Beck and Katz (1995) showed that the standard errors generated by the estimator PCSE are more accurate than FGLS, however, the debate continues between the two estimators.

References

Aixalá, José and Gema Fabro. “Indicadores Institucionales y Crecimiento Económico: Un Panorama.”

Hacienda Pública Española 182, 3 (2007): 115-162. Albi, Emilio, José M. González-Páramo and Ignacio Zubiri. Economía Pública I. Madrid: Ariel, 2004. Alesina, Alberto and Roberto Perotti. “The Political Economy of Growth: A Critical Survey of the Recent

Literature.” World Bank Economic Review 8, 3 (1994): 351-371. ———. “Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment.” European Economic Review 40, 6 (1996):

1203-1228. Bahl, Roy W. “A Regression Approach to Tax Effort and Tax Ratio Analysis.” IMF Staff Papers 18 (1971):

570-612. ———. “Reaching the Hardest to Tax: Consequences and Possibilities.” Paper presented at the Hard to Tax:

An International Perspective Conference, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, May 15–16, 2003.

Beck, Nathaniel and Jonathan N. Katz. “What to Do (and not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data.” American Political Science Review 89, 3 (1995): 634-647.

Benhabib, Jess and Adam Przeworski. “The Political Economy of Redistribution Under Democracy.” Economic Theory 29, 2 (2006): 271-290.

Bird, Richard M. “Assessing the Performance in Developing Countries: A Critical Review of the Literature.” FinanzArchiv 34, 2 (1976): 244-265.

———. “The Administrative Dimension of Tax Reform in Developing Countries.” In Tax Reform in Developing Countries, edited by Malcom Gillis, pp. 315-346. Durham: Duke University Press, 1989.

Bird, Richard M., Jorge Martínez-Vázquez and Benno Torgler. “Societal Institutions and Tax Effort in Developing Countries.” Working Paper no. 2004-21. Basel, Switzerland: Center for Research in Economics, Management and the Arts, 2004.

Boscá, José E., José R. García and David Taguas. “La Fiscalidad en la OCDE.” Documentos de Trabajo no. 2005-06. Madrid: Ministerio de Economía y Hacienda, 2005.

Buchanan, James M. Public Finance in Democratic Process: Fiscal Institutions and Individual Choice. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1967.

Cheibub, José A. “Political Regimes and the Extractive Capacity of Governments: Taxation in Democracies and Dictatorships.” World Politics 50, 3 (1998): 349-376.

Chelliah, Raja J. “Trends in Taxation in Developing Countries.” IMF Staff Papers 18, 2 (1971): 254-331. Chelliah, Raja J., Hessel J. Bass and Margaret R. Kelly. “Tax Ratios and Tax Effort in Developing

Countries, 1969-71.” IMF Staff Papers 22, 1 (1975): 187-205. Easterly, William and Sergio Rebelo. “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth. An Empirical Investigation.”

Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 3 (1993): 459-483. Eshag, Eprime. Fiscal and Monetary Policies and Problems in Developing Countries. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press, 1983. Esteve, Vicente, Simón Sosvilla and Cecilio Tamarit. “Convergence in Fiscal Pressure Across UE

Countries.” Applied Economics Letter 7, 2 (2000): 117-124. Feenberg, Daniel R. and Harvey S. Rosen. “Tax Structure and Public Sector Growth.” Journal of Public

Economics 32, 2 (1987): 185-201. Gwartney, James and Robert Lawson. “The Concept and Measurement of Economic Freedom.” European

Journal of Political Economy 19, 3 (2003): 405-430. Hallerberg, Mark, Rolf Strauch and Jürgen Von Hagen. “The Design of Fiscal Rules and Forms of

Economic and Institutional Determinants in Fiscal Pressure

591

Governance in European Union Countries.” Working Paper no. 419. Frankfurt am Main: European Central Bank, 2004.

Hinrichs, Harley H. A General Theory of Tax Structure Change During Economic Development. Cambridge: Law School of Harvard University, 1966.

Kaldor, Nicholas. “Will Underdeveloped Countries Learn to Tax?” Foreign Affairs 41 (1963): 410-419. Lammert, Christian. “Modern Welfare State under Pressure: Determinants of Tax Policy in a Globalizing

World.” Working Paper no. 2004-01. Montreal: Institute for Research on Public Policy (IRPP), 2004.

Lotz, Joergen R. and Elliott R. Morss. “A Theory of Tax Level Determinants for Developing Countries.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 18, 3 (1970): 328-341.

Maroto-Illera, Reyes and Carlos Mulas-Granados. “Duration of Fiscal Consolidation in the European Union.” Working Paper no. 2001-19. Madrid: Fundación de Estudios de Economia Aplicada (FEDEA), 2001.

Mauro, Paolo. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 3 (1995): 681-712. Mierau, Jochen, Richard Jong-A-Ping and Jakob De Haan. “Do Political Variables Affect Fiscal Policy

Adjustment Decisions? New Empirical Evidence.” Public Choice 133, 4-5 (2007): 297-319. Mulas-Granados, Carlos. “The Political and Economic Determinants of Budgetary Consolidation in

Europe.” European Political Economy Review 1, 1 (2003): 15-39. Musgrave, Richard A. Fiscal Systems. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969. Peacock, Alan T. and Jack Wiseman. The Growth of Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom, 2d ed. London:

Allen & Unwin, 1961. Piancastelli, Marcelo. “Measuring the Tax Effort of Developed and Developing Countries. Cross Country

Panel Data Analysis – 1985/95.” Discussion Paper. Río de Janeiro: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada (Institute for Applied Economic Research [IPEA]), September 2001.

Pirttilä, Jukka. “Fiscal Policy and Structural Reforms in Taxation Economies: An Empirical Analysis.” Working Paper no. 5-2000. Helsinki: Bank of Finland, 2000.

Putnam, Robert D. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1993.

Puviani, Amilcare. Teoria della Illusione Finanziaria. Palermo: Sandron, 1903. Reis-Mourao, Paulo. “Towards a Puviani’s Fiscal Illusion Index.” Hacienda Pública Española 187, 4 (2008):

49-86. Tait, Alan A., Wilfrid L. M. Gratz and Barry J. Eichengreen. “International Comparisons of Taxation for

Selected Developing Countries, 1972-76.” IMF Staff Papers 26, 1 (1979): 123-156. Tanzi, Vito. “Structural Factors and Tax Revenue in Developing Countries: A Decade of Evidence.” In

Open Economies: Structural Adjustment and Agriculture, edited by Ian Goldin and L. Alan Winters, pp. 267-281. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.

Tavares, José. “Does Right or Left Matters? Cabinets, Credibility and Fiscal Adjustment.” Journal of Public Economics 88, 12 (2004): 2447-2468.

Torgler, Benno. “Tax Morale and Direct Democracy.” European Journal of Political Economy 21, 2 (2005): 525-531.

Wallace, Sally and Roy W. Bahl. “Public Financing in Developing and Transition Countries.” Public Budgeting and Finance 25, 4 (2005): 83-98.

Wicksell, Knut. Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen nebst Darstellung and kritik des Steuerwesen Schwedens. Jena: Gustav Fischer, 1896.