economic geography of indonesia’s manufacturing industry › attachments › article › 176 ›...

23
1 ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY: Dynamics and Changing Spatial Patterns 1 Mudrajad Kuncoro Professor in economics Faculty of Economics & Business Gadjah Mada University, Yogyakarta, Indonesia 55281 Phone: +62811254255 Email: [email protected] ABSTRACT A number of economists and business strategists have become more interested in spatial analysis, however, very few has examined the industrial clusters in Indonesia using provincial and district data simultaneously. Indonesia, as the world‟s largest archipelago and 4th world most populous country, offers an excellent laboratory for testing both old and new industrial district theories. This article attempts to illuminate the clustering of Large and Medium Establishments (LME) industry in Indonesia and, hence, enrich our understanding of not only the regional development but also the relationship between urbanization and industrial development. Using Geographic Information System (GIS) and Moran‟s I, we found hot and cold spots of industrial clusters. Unlike the majority of manufacturing in US and UK that has concentrated in a relatively small part of the country, within so-called the US manufacturing belt and UK‟s Axial Belt of industry respectively, industrial clusters in Indonesia have concentrated geographically in Java‟s metropolitan regions and major cities in the Outer islands. Our discriminant model suggests that the best predictor of clustering was population density, followed by income per capita, skilled workers, revenue sharing funds, infrastructure, productivity, and wages. Our study confirms that the LME industrial clusters are strongly associated with urban concentration. Key words: industrial cluster, Indonesia, GIS, LME, discriminant, geography JEL classifications: R12, J24, J61 1 This paper is presented in the “Seminar Nasional & Kongres ISEI XIX”, Hotel Bumi Surabaya, 7-9 October 2015. Earlier version of this paper has been presented in the Fourth Global Conference on Economic Geography 2015, Oxford University, Oxford UK, 19-23 August 2015.

Upload: others

Post on 07-Jun-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

1

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF

INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY:

Dynamics and Changing Spatial Patterns1

Mudrajad Kuncoro Professor in economics Faculty of Economics & Business Gadjah Mada University, Yogyakarta, Indonesia 55281 Phone: +62811254255 Email: [email protected]

ABSTRACT

A number of economists and business strategists have become more interested in spatial analysis,

however, very few has examined the industrial clusters in Indonesia using provincial and district

data simultaneously. Indonesia, as the world‟s largest archipelago and 4th world most populous

country, offers an excellent laboratory for testing both old and new industrial district theories.

This article attempts to illuminate the clustering of Large and Medium Establishments (LME)

industry in Indonesia and, hence, enrich our understanding of not only the regional development

but also the relationship between urbanization and industrial development. Using Geographic

Information System (GIS) and Moran‟s I, we found hot and cold spots of industrial clusters.

Unlike the majority of manufacturing in US and UK that has concentrated in a relatively small

part of the country, within so-called the US manufacturing belt and UK‟s Axial Belt of industry

respectively, industrial clusters in Indonesia have concentrated geographically in Java‟s

metropolitan regions and major cities in the Outer islands. Our discriminant model suggests that

the best predictor of clustering was population density, followed by income per capita, skilled

workers, revenue sharing funds, infrastructure, productivity, and wages. Our study confirms that

the LME industrial clusters are strongly associated with urban concentration.

Key words: industrial cluster, Indonesia, GIS, LME, discriminant, geography

JEL classifications: R12, J24, J61

1 This paper is presented in the “Seminar Nasional & Kongres ISEI XIX”, Hotel Bumi Surabaya, 7-9 October 2015.

Earlier version of this paper has been presented in the Fourth Global Conference on Economic Geography 2015,

Oxford University, Oxford UK, 19-23 August 2015.

Page 2: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

2

I. Introduction

With 241 million inhabitants ranked the 4th most populous country in the world in 2012 (BPS,

2013), Indonesia is the world‟s largest archipelago and offers an excellent laboratory for testing

both traditional and new industrial district theories. Since 1969, Indonesia‟s economic

development has been accelerated and the national goal of „Unity in Diversity‟ (Bhinneka

Tunggal Ika) has been accomplished. During the Soeharto era, hyperinflation was reduced

substantially into one to two-digit inflation, a high rate of capital flight was reversed into

substantial private capital inflows, foreign exchange reserve deficits were brought into positive,

self-sufficiency level in rice production was achieved in mid-1980s, sustainable economic growth

was generated, and poverty was reduced substantially (for example, Booth, 1992; Hill, 1996;

Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis resulted in an economic

downturn of 2.9% per year, with the peak -13.1% in 1998. In the period 2000-2004, known as the

period of economic recovery, the economy had a positive growth of 4.5%. Within the period

2005-2008, the economic growth has reached an average of 6%. The Indonesian government

quite effectively steered the national economy through „storm‟ of the 2008 Global Financial

Crisis (Kuncoro, et al. 2009). Among the ASEAN-5, the Indonesian economy has proved to be

remarkably resilient, with output growing at 4.5% in 2009 compared with 1.75% for the ASEAN-

5 as a whole, thanks to strong domestic demand (Kuncoro, 2013).

This remarkable record in economic performance has been supported by the emergence of

the manufacturing sector as a leading sector in the economy. Figure 1 shows the declining role of

agriculture to GDP has been replaced by the increasing share of industry, especially the

manufacturing sector. In 1965, the agricultural sector had the dominant share of GDP (56%),

while the share of industry, including manufacturing, was only 13% of GDP. Indeed, with an

average of annual growth of 11.9% and 6.1% during 1965-1980 and 1980-1994 respectively,

industry has replaced agriculture as the leading sector in the Indonesian economy. In 1994, the

industry contributed 41% to GDP, in which the manufacturing sector had played a significant

role since it contributed 24% to GDP. At the same time the contribution of agriculture dropped

drastically to only 17% of GDP, while its growth declined steadily from 4.3% per annum during

1965-1980 to 3.1% during 1980-1994. Furthermore, the manufacturing sector has played an

important role in non-oil exports since it contributed to about 30% of non-oil GDP growth and

about three-fourths of non-oil export growth during 1986-1992 (Abimanyu, 1996: 26).

Nevertheless, manufacturing industry has grown below the Indonesia‟s economic growth since

2005.

Figure 1. Percentage share of agriculture and manufacturing industry to GDP: Indonesia, 1960-2011

Source: Calculated from BPS, various years

Page 3: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

3

Given the increased importance of the industrial sector to Indonesia‟s economy, it seems

important to understand more fully patterns of industrial development, particularly its spatial

patterns. Mainstream economics has made only limited progress toward integrating spatial

considerations into its analytical corpus (Fujita, et al. 1999; Krugman, 1995; Krugman, 1998;

Ohta and Thisse, 1993). There are only few rigorous studies that explore spatial analyses of

industrial development in Indonesia, albeit with important exceptions (for example, Aziz, 1994;

Dick, et al. 1993; Henderson and Kuncoro, 1996; Hill, 1990; Kuncoro, 2000b). In addition,

Indonesian diversity in natural resources, population density, size of areas, and infrastructures

makes it imperative to take into account spatial considerations in industrial and regional

development. The lack of spatial consideration, together with the uneven development and an

unstable central government, resulted in serious problems of regional insurrection during the

1950s (Hill, 1989; Kuncoro, 1996b, 2000c).

The major purpose of this article is to illuminate the regional clustering of Large and

Medium Establishments (LME) of manufacturing industry in Indonesia and, hence, enrich our

understanding of the regional development. LME in Indonesia consist of large establishments

employing 100 workers or more, while medium establishments hiring 20 to 99 workers.

Manufacturing industry is an economic activity involving processing materials and transforming

them mechanically, chemically, or manually into finished or semi finished products and/or

converting them into other goods having higher value and closer to the final user (BPS, 2015).

The distribution of manufacturing establishments over space tends to cluster in certain

Indonesia‟s regions. We will show that LME manufacturing sector in Java and the Outer Island

has tended to cluster in and around major cities and towns. Manufacturing firms in Java seek to

locate in more populous and densely populated areas to enjoy both localization economies, which

are associated with the size of a particular industry, and urbanization economies, which reflect

the size of market of a district in a particular urban area (for example, Henderson, 1988; Kuncoro,

2000a). Manufacturing industries tend to concentrate geographically because agglomeration

economies have the effect of reducing cost or increasing sales for many types of industry. An

agglomeration represents not only a densely industrialised and urbanised region with diverse

industrial structure, but also amplified by agglomeration economies stemming from provision of

infrastructure services and public goods (Scott, 1993: 25-27). Manufacturing firms have tended to

locate their sites in and around urban regions as the regions offer various advantages in terms of

higher productivity and incomes that attract new investment, new technology, educated and

skilled workers to a disproportionate degree (Malecki, 1991). For the proponents of the new

economic geography, intersectoral linkages confined within these regions, together with thick

labour market, represents one of the key centripetal forces that tend to pull population and

production into agglomerations (Fujita and Thisse, 1996; Krugman, 1996: 7-10).

This paper attempts to analyze the dynamics of Indonesia‟s LME manufacturing industry

using spatial analysis and industrial district theories. In line with a dramatic increase in research

on economic geography -- that is, on „where‟ economic activity occurs and „why‟ (Fujita et al.

1999), this paper will address the following fundamental questions: Where are the main locations

of LME manufacturing industries in Indonesia? Why they tended to concentrate geographically

in some metropolitan and urban regions?

II. Theoretical background: old vs new industrial clusters An industrial cluster was initially associated with the Marshallian industrial district. Alfred

Marshall (1919), first observed the disposition of certain kinds of industries to localise in specific

areas in England, Germany and other countries, defined an industrial district as a specialised

Page 4: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

4

geographical cluster of production. Interestingly, he distinguishes between „manufacturing town‟

and an „industrial district‟ as follows (Bellandi, 1989; Marshall, 1919: 285):

„Almost every industrial district has been focused in one or more large towns. Each such

large town, or city, has been at first the leader in the technique of industry, as well as in

trade; and the greater parts of its inhabitants have been artisans. After a time factories,

requiring more space than was easily to be had where ground values were high, tended to

move to the outskirts of the city; and new factories grew up increasingly in the

surrounding rural districts and small towns.‟

Marshall highlighted the role of three types of external economy as giving rise to the industrial

district: the concentration of a mass of skilled workers, the proximity of specialist suppliers and

the availability of facilities for obtaining knowledge. The presence of a large pool of skilled

workers facilitates economies of labour supply. The proximity of specialist suppliers produces

economies of specialisation arising from an extended division of labour between firms in

complementary activities and processes. The availability of facilities for obtaining knowledge

enhances economies of information and communication via joint production, invention and

improvements in machinery, processes and general organisation.

The relevance of Marshall‟s work is reflected by the growing development of similar

ideas in the more recent work of the Italian industrial district. Becattini (1990), for example,

defines the industrial district as a „socio-territorial entity which is characterised by the presence

of both a community of people and a population of firms and both tend to merge‟. He tries to

explain the Italian experience, especially in a region called the Third Italy (that is Tuscany,

Emilia Romagna, and nearby regions), which have been perceived by many authors since the

early 1980s as a model for the competitive success of clusters of small firms. Some major

features of the structure of manufacturing in the Italian industrial districts are geographical

concentration, sectoral specialisation, and predominance of strong network of small firms. These

characteristics have been observed in Silicon Valley (US), West Jutland (Denmark), and Baden-

Wurttemberg (Germany), Madrid, Fuenlabrada, Castellon, Mondragon and Valles Oriental

(Spain) (Pyke and Sengenberger, 1992); and some cases from Africa, Asia and Latin America

(Nadvi and Schmitz, 1994). However, a closer reading of those case studies reveals that there are

substantial differences between them in terms of their origins and consolidation as industrial

districts. Moreover, the applicability of the Italian model remains uncertain because of its highly

specific socio-historical context, mainly culture and institutions (Zeitlin, 1992).

Traditionally industrial districts have been centres of craft industry. Craft based, design-

intensive industries such as clothing, textiles, furniture, jewellery, ceramics, sporting goods, and

so forth, are found in old centres of craft production such as the Third Italy, parts of France,

Greece, Portugal, Germany, Spain, and Scandinavia (Scott and Storper, 1992). They may also be

found in the inner city areas of large metropolitan regions such as New York, Paris, Los Angeles,

and London. Modern-high technology clusters also emerge, such as ribbons, hardware, and

specialty steel in St Etienne; edge tools, cutlery, and specialty steel in Solingen, Remscheid and

Sheffield; and electronics in Southern California. Although a cluster is often characterised by a

particular industry, this may incorporate various „sub-industries‟. The obvious example is the

electronics manufacturing cluster in Southern California with multi-faceted focus on computers,

military and space communications equipment and avionics, and a diversity of components from

printed circuit boards to advanced semiconductor devices (Scott, 1993: chap.7).

A notable case discussed in the literature is the Brazilian supercluster in Sinos Valley. In

the 1960s it was a specialised cluster of craftsmen. Through success in export markets, by the

Page 5: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

5

1990s it had become an internationally competitive industrial complex with flexible

specialization between firms of different sizes, from small (less than 20) to very large (over 500

workers). Its emergence as a supercluster reflected increased depth and density of the local

economy, which now includes almost the entire range of supply industries and producer services.

Besides four hundred and eighty shoe manufacturers, there are 1,341 related firms in service

industries: workshops, tanning industry, leather and footwear machine industry, component

industry, rubber industry, leather article industry, export and forwarding agents. Two causes of

this impressive development have been identified (Schmitz, 1995: 14). First, local and central

government incentives yielded quick results because export agents had connected Brazilian

producers with the United States market. Second, export growth increased the demand for local

inputs and machinery, thus contributing to development of the cluster.

Since the 1980s a post-Fordist literature has drawn attention to the flexibility (flexible

specialisation) and dynamism (employment generation) of industrial districts. As in the case of

the Brazilian supercluster, the elements of a cluster can be linked in three ways: (1) vertically or

convergently, when different stages of a process are involved, as in the case of spinning or

weaving or where assembly lines are fed by different sub-processes; (2) laterally, where the same

stage in a like process is involved, as in the case of men‟s clothing and women‟s clothing; and (3)

diagonally, when service processes are involved, such as repairing, trading, collecting, and so

forth. (Bellandi, 1989; Florence, 1961). Empirical studies have identified as major reasons for

the growth of industrial clusters and districts: (1) concentrations of highly specialised knowledge,

inputs and institutions, (2) the incentives of local competition, (3) the presence of sophisticated

local demand for a product or service, (4) geographical, cultural, and institutional proximity, and

(5) a proliferation of many different producers, all locked together in mutual interdependence

through their transactional relations (Porter, 1994, 1998a; Scott, 1993: chap.2).

The new form of industrial district derives from the industrial complex model, which

emerged from classical and neoclassical economics. The main features of the industrial complex

model are: (1) sets of identifiable and stable relations among firms which are conceived primarily

in terms of trading links; (2) minimisation of spatial transaction costs (that is transport costs,

telecommunication costs, shipment costs) in the formation of crucial, pre-planned or identifiable

linkages (Gordon, 2000). This model is in line with the Markusen‟s and Whittaker‟s study

suggesting the importance of vertical inter-firm linkages between LME and small and cottage

establishment (SCE) of “new” industrial districts in the USA and Japanese urban regions

(Markusen, 1996; Whittaker, 1997). A study of industrial districts in Japan shows the large

concentration of very small firms in the metropolitan centers of Tokyo, Osaka, and Nagoya

(Whittaker, 1997). Unlike hundreds of small firm clusters called sanchi, which produce traditional

or semi-traditional goods and tend to locate outside the main urban centres, Japanese metropolitan

concentrations are remarkable both for their scale and the high proportion of small firms with

their localised industry (jiba sangyo).

Building upon the pioneering work of Porter (1990) on competitive advantage, recent

research has begun to link the literature on sub-national clusters with that on firm strategy and

innovation (Enright, 1998; Porter and Solvell, 1998). The new theory of the firm with its

emphasis upon transaction costs and the transaction environment has great power to elucidate the

location decision of the firm. Region-specific resources, information flows, innovation,

technological spillovers and the formation of industry-specific skills can thereby be studied

within a consistent framework that has regard to both efficiency and dynamic effects (Porter and

Solvell, 1998: 441-2, figure 19.1). Porter (2003) found that the performance of regional

Page 6: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

6

economies is strongly influenced by the strength of local clusters and the vitality and plurality of

innovation.

Unlike majority of previous studies, this study used combination of regional spatial data

and discriminant model to identify changing spatial patterns of LME manufacturing industry with

special reference to Indonesia. This study will fulfill the gaps, especially studies on industrial

districts and regional development for Indonesia using a discriminant model. Unlike most

previous studies that have discussed Indonesia‟s regional development at the provincial level

(e.g. Aziz 1994; Hill 1989; Manning 1997), this study will examine changing spatial patterns of

Indonesia‟s industrial development at the district (kabupaten/kodya) as well as provincial level.

Every study, which relies on provincial data, has at least two major shortcomings (Kuncoro

2000b: 11, 2012). First, provincial data tend to obscure urban economies. The province is either

too large or too small a unit. Even such large cities as Bandung, Semarang and Surabaya cannot

be seen in provincial data. Whereas the capital city region of Jakarta actually spills over its

provincial borders. Second, provinces are a much too large unit of analysis for any spatial

analysis of agglomeration economies (Gelder 1994: 64) as the heterogeneity within each province

would be too great. The disaggregation into districts, and even at the lower level (subdistrict or

kecamatan), enables us to understand the dynamic of regional clustering in some districts across

provinces.

III. Methodology

Spatial concentration of economic activities within a country indicates that

industrialisation constitutes a geographically selective process. Within the USA, for illustration,

the majority of manufacturing has been concentrated in a relatively small part of the country,

within the so-called manufacturing belt, since the second half of the nineteenth century

(Krugman, 1991: 11-4). Spatial concentration is also found in the UK‟s Axial Belt of industry

and the manufacturing belt of German Ruhr (Hayter, 1997: 45). This is also found in the case of

Indonesia, and to much extent the island of Java. Despite the fact that regional clusters are

usually associated with large cities, clusters can be also located in small and medium-sized

towns. As illustration, in Massachusetts a plastics cluster lies in the western part of state, jewelry

on the Rhode Island border, fiber optics around Sturbridge, textile and apparel near New

Bredford and Fall River (Porter 1994, 1998b).

This section will elaborate upon the methodology to identify LME industrial clusters. It

also attempts to illuminate on which regions the LME manufacturing industries tend to cluster in

Indonesia. The location of industrial clusters at the district (kabupaten/kodya) level will be

examined by using the Geographic Information System‟s (GIS) approach and Industrial Survey

data collected annually by Central Bureau of Statistics of Indonesia (BPS). The GIS is a useful

tool to identify the location of industry and where the manufacturing industries tend to cluster

(Kuncoro, 2001). The Industrial Surveys provide not only regional distribution of manufacturing

establishments but also their dynamics from 1976 to 2010. The surveys provide the plant-level

data of LME manufacturing firms, with more than 20 workers, that can be disaggregated by

industry code (ISIC) and district, providing all data of industry-specific variables.

A growing awareness of the limited explanations offered by the traditional location theory

has led to the surge of new economic geography, namely geographical economics (Kuncoro,

2000a; 2012). A growing number of economists have become interested in the study of location

problems (for example, Krugman, 1995; Lucas, 1988; Fujita, et al. 1999), which triggered a new

tool which has made an interesting contribution to geographical economics.

Page 7: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

7

One of the major trends in the economic geography is employing the GIS in a socio-

economic context that focuses on the processes acting spatial data in its passage through

information system. A GIS is a special type of information system, concerned with the

representation and manipulation of a geographic reality. GIS transforms data into information by

integrating different data sets, applying focused analysis and providing output, all in manner to

support decision making (Juppenlatz and Tian, 1996: chap.1). The inventory, analysis, mapping

and modelling capabilities of GIS inevitably has wide application in a range of discipline,

ranging from information technology to socio-economic or population-related data (Martin,

1996: 4-5). Application of GIS in Indonesia has become more widespread (East Asian Executive

Reports 1996; Juppenlatz and Tian 1996: 103-108). In this study, we follow some typical

procedures involved in creating and using GIS. It includes data acquisition, preliminary data

processing, database construction, spatial search and analysis, and graphical display and

interaction (Kuncoro, 2012).

To identify industrial clusters, we apply the following steps. First, we rank all districts in

Indonesia for LME industry by employment and value added. Ranking all districts in terms of

both employment and value added in LME manufacturing industry reveals that these

establishments are unevenly distributed across Indonesia‟s regions. Figure 2 and 3 show that the

distribution of employment and value-added by districts is skewed rather than normal

statistically. The positive skew of the histograms indicates that there are some districts possess

high industrial density (in terms of employment and value added), while most contain very low

industrial density.

Figure 2. Employment distribution by district in Indonesia 2001 and 2010

Source: Calculated from BPS

Second, we map the employment and value-added data of LMEs to show where the

industrial and non-industrial clusters are located. For mapping purposes, a kotamadya (city) is

included in adjacent kabupaten or municipality (for example, kotamadya Semarang in kabupaten

Semarang). In this step, we differentiate between industrial and non-industrial districts by setting

a certain criteria (that is very high, high, moderate, and low) based on the total employment and

value added of each district (kabupaten/kotamadya). Industrial clusters are identified by either

“high” or “very high” industrial density in terms of both employment and value added. By

employing these criteria simultaneously, most of the top districts with „high‟ or „very high‟ total

employment and value added are found predominantly in Java, particularly in and around its

major cities namely Jakarta, Surabaya, Bandung, Semarang, and Surakarta. The same pattern

also occurs in the Outer Java Island, as most LME establishments are found in and around main

Page 8: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

8

population centres such as Medan, Batam, Samarinda, Palembang, Pontianak, Ujung Pandang,

and Denpasar. The other kabupaten/kotamadya can be regarded as non-industrial areas since their

role in industrial employment and value added is minor.

Figure 3. Value added distribution by district in Indonesia 2001 and 2010

Source: Calculated from BPS

Empirical cluster research has contributed to the understanding the process of cluster

formation. Some experiences with the use of local spatial methods like local Moran‟s Ii and

Getis-Ord Gi tests in pattern recognition have been already available. Moran's I is a measure of

spatial autocorrelation developed by Moran (1950). In contrast, other measures, such as location

quotients, examine only the value for a single areal unit without reference to values in

neighboring areas. Our study utilises Moran‟s I to examine spatial autocorrelation that is

characterised by a correlation in a signal among nearby locations in space. Assessment of

industry location and density patterns becomes the first phase in the identification of potential

cluster regions to be included in a cluster driven development policy. Our study uses Getis-Ord

Gi in the identification of potential cluster regions in the Indonesia‟s LME industry.

One of major issues in economic geography: why do LME concentrate geographically in

some regions? More specifically, we will use discriminant model to show to what extent

Indonesia‟s foremost LME clusters represent industrial districts with distinctive features. If we

may classify those districts as a “separate” group from the rest of Indonesia, can we build a

predictive model, with group membership based on observed characteristics of each region?

Discriminant analysis is widely applied to serve the twin objectives of discrimination and

classification. Group separation is achieved by means of a discriminant function, while

identification of future individuals is handled through a classification rule (Krzanowski and

Marriott, 1995: 1). Discriminant analysis is a statistical technique for classifying individuals or

objects into mutually exclusive groups on the basis of a set of independent variables (Kuncoro,

2006; 2013). Unlike regression analysis, the objective in discriminant analysis is to find a linear

combination of the independent variables that minimise the probability of misclassifying

individuals or objects into their respective groups (Dillon and Goldstein, 1984: 360-3). The

overall test of relationship between predictors and groups in the discriminant analysis is the same

as the test of the main effect in multivariate analysis of variance (MANOVA), where all

Page 9: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

9

discriminant functions are combined and grouping variables are considered simultaneously

(Tabachnick and Fidell, 1996). In other words, MANOVA allows us to look at how groups differ,

while discriminant analysis allows us to predict what variables discriminate between two or more

groups.

The discriminant function analysis was performed to predict the membership of

Indonesia‟s foremost LME industrial districts. To keep the analysis as simple as possible, we

dichotomise all districts into foremost industrial clusters versus the remainder as non-industrial

clusters. Modelling using discriminant approach is suitable given the data available. Our

discriminant function is based on the following equation:

Dik = a+ diX1+ diX2 + diX3 + diX4+ diX5 + diX6 + diX7 (1)

This study attempts to explore spatial discriminant patterns by contrasting discriminative

characteristics of distinct spatial entity classes using some predictors: productivity of labor

(X1), population density (X2), skilled workers (X3), income per capita (X4), infrastructure (X5),

revenue sharing funds (X6), and average wages (X7). We transform the predictors into natural

logarithm in order to normalise the distributions, which are positively skewed.

Productivity of Labour. Porter (1998) pointed out that industrial clusters, characterised

by geographic concentrations of interconnected companies and institutions in a particular field,

appeared to be far more productive industrial organizations than those based on one or two huge,

diversified cities. We define the productivity of labour as the ratio between value of output

and total employees. We test whether higher productivity of LME will influence the decision of

LME to cluster.

Population density. We use the population density by district as to show the effect of

generically named external economies of urbanization (Costa-Compi and Viladecans-Marsal,

1999: 2090). We will test whether a greater population density within a district corresponds to

greater probability that LME choose to locate in that region.

Skilled workers. Skilled workers are viewed by the Neo-classical school as a central

factor in the location decision of manufacturing establishments. A specific agglomeration

economy is that more highly educated and skilled labour concentrates disproportionately in main

cities. The theory of human capital is frequently applied to analyse the effect of education on

labour earnings (Tachibanaki,1998: 3). We will test whether higher skilled workers correspond to

greater probability that LME choose to locate in industrial districts.

Income Per Capita. We include Gross Regional Domestic Product per capita as a proxy

of market size. Krugman (1991: 23-4) argued that the more populated locations will attract a

concentration of manufacturing production, assuming that the location offers a sufficiently larger

local market than others, and fixed costs are large enough relative to transport costs. We will test

the Krugman‟s hypothesis.

Infrastructure. There is a substantial empirical literature showing that income and

production are correlated with market access in the way suggested by new economic geography

models. Fujita et al. (1999: 233-236) argued that a hub or a port city provide the city‟s site with

an advantage over other sites. A fundamental question in regional and urban economics is

whether lower transport costs cause agglomerations to develop, or if, instead, they promote the

dispersion of economic activity. In an infuential paper that started this literature, Krugman (1991)

shows the opposite: reducing transport costs causes agglomeration. Other theories have more

nuanced predictions, and the absence of sharp predictions demands credible empirical work. We

will test different theories of transport costs and economic geography, so that we can better

Page 10: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

10

predict which regions will benefit from infrastructure improvements, and which regions may

suffer.

Revenue Sharing Funds. These funds are central government transfer to regions

reflecting resource endowments are agglomeration forces as argued by neo-classical economists,

such as Heckscher-Ohin (H-O). The H-O analysis establishes that “comparative advantage is

determined by the absolute distribution of resources between countries and particularly by the

relative factor endowment ratios between countries” (Johns, 1985: 178-81). East Kalimantan,

Riau, Aceh, Bangka Belitung are provinces that enjoyed higher revenue sharing funds because

they are known as resource rich regions (Figure 4). East Kalimantan, Aceh, and Riau are the

major producer of oil and gas in Indonesia. East Kalimantan is also home of coal mining and

forestry products. Bangka Belitung, as a new province splitting from South Sumatra, offers a

great tin mines and beauty of its nature based tourism. We will examine whether high revenue

sharing funds attract LME industry to locate in those regions.

Wages. Wages are one of the important variable in labour economics. Kuncoro (2007;

2012) found that wages are important in the textile, wood and miscellaneous industries but turn

out to be a less important variable in more modern LME industries such as machinery, chemical,

and paper. The story of wage trends in Indonesia, however, does not fit either with the modified

Lewis model or a neo-classical theories interpretation of sharply rising wage rates associated

with rapid economic growth (Manning, 1998: 114-131). Two features of the Indonesian labour

market transformation are relevant to our study: (1) the increasing share of non-agricultural,

urban and wage workers in total employment; and (2) a substantial increase in the number of non-

wage workers in urban areas (Manning 1998: 111-2). We include a labour cost variable

(WAGES), which is measured as wages for production workers, both male and female. We will

test whether the increase in wages will encourage LME to cluster in industrial districts.

Figure 4. Revenue Sharing Funds By Province

Source: Ministry of Finance (2013)

Page 11: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

11

IV. Findings and Discussions

1. Where are LME industrial clusters? Most of Indonesian modern manufacturing establishments have persisted to cluster

predominantly on Java and to a much lesser extent, Sumatra Island during 1976-2010. Even when

we classify 33 provinces of Indonesia into five main islands (that is Sumatra, Java, Kalimantan,

Sulawesi, Eastern Islands), Java and Sumatra provided more than 93% of Indonesia‟s

employment and value-added over the period (Table 1). Java contributed about 75-89% of

Indonesian industrial employment and value added from 1976 to 2010, although this dropped

slightly during 1995-2001. Java‟s share declined from 89% and 86% in 1976 to 84% and 76% in

2010 in terms of industrial employment and value added respectively. Sumatra‟s share grew from

7 to 12% in terms of industrial emplyment and from 11 to 18% in terms of industrial value added

in the same period. Other main islands in Indonesia played a minor role in the Indonesia

manufacturing employment and value added. Even when we sum up the share of Kalimantan,

Sumatra, and Eastern Island, their share in Indonesian employment and value added was about

4% and 7% respectively over the period of 1976 to 2010.

Comparison between provinces in Java and the other islands in Indonesia is even more

pronounced. The share of each Java‟s provinces in terms of total employment and value added is

relatively higher than other provinces or islands in Indonesia from 1976 to 2010 (Table 2). Major

industrial regions in Java are found in its western and eastern part -- West Java, Jakarta, and East

Java --which contributed more than 50% of total employment and value added. This infers

relatively heavy regional clustering of manufacturing establishments in Java‟s vis-à-vis the rest of

the economy.

Table 1. Role of Java in the Manufacturing Employment and Value Added, Indonesia 1976-2010 (% of total)

Province/Island/Region Employment Value Added

1976 1985 1995 2001 2010 1976 1985 1995 2001 2010

Jakarta 15.2 13.8 10.7 9.06 6.94 25.7 17.9 17.9 14.29 14.27

West Java 19.1 23.3 35.2 26.99 28.20 19.9 25.3 33.8 20.67 27.82

Central Java and DIY 24.1 17.1 13.6 14.72 17.50 15.9 10.7 6.9 8,79 6,75

East Java 30.6 24.5 22.8 19.78 20.49 24.7 22.4 23.5 19.73 16.36

JAVA 89.1 78.6 82.2 82.04 83.73 86.2 76.3 82.1 74.35 75.73

SUMATRA 6.7 12.2 10.8 11.11 11.61 10.7 13.5 12.3 17.89 18.10

KALIMANTAN 1.8 5.6 3.9 3.73 2.17 1.8 6.7 4.0 4.59 4.12

OTHER EASTERN REGION 2.4 3.7 3.2 3.12 2.49 1.3 3.6 1.6 3.14 2.05

INDONESIA 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0

Source: Calculated from BPS; Putro (2013)

There have been changing patterns in Java‟s employment for the last two decades (Figure

4). First, the declining share of Jakarta in the country‟s employment, albeit persistently

substantial in absolute value, has been offset partly by the rising share of West Java, East Java,

and Central Java‟s employment. In 1976 East Java was the top contributor to Java‟s employment,

followed by Central Java-DIY, West Java and DKI Jakarta (Recall Table 1). East Java has

sustained this record up till the mid of-1980s. However, a decade later the role of East Java

declined substantially and was replaced by West Java.

Page 12: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

12

Table 2. Major Industrial Regions: Indonesia, 2001-2010

Extended Industrial Area

(EIA)

2001 2010

Employ-

ment (000) %

Value Added

(billion Rp) %

Employ-

ment (000) %

Value Added

(billion Rp) %

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Java

2, 423 55.24 134.32 49.82 2.740 60,87 530.21 59.50

Jabodetabek 1,241 28.29 87.57 32.48 1.201 26.68 307.53 34.51

Bandung 562 12.82 19.73 7.32 561 12 .46 102.92 11.55

Surabaya 370 8.43 18.15 6.73 527 11.70 77.75 8.72

Semarang 158 3.59 6.22 2.31 359 7.97 33.05 3.71

Surakarta 92 2.11 2.65 0.98 92 2.05 8.97 1.01

Outer Java 265 6.05 21.04 7.8 289 6.42 57.42 6.45

Sumatera 202 4.61 17.94 6.65 251 5.58 52.12 5 .84

Medan 96 2.19 5.32 1.97 85 1.89 12.07 1.35

Batam 89 2.03 10.73 3.98 150 3.33 31.48 3.53

Palembang 17 0.39 1.89 0.70 16 0.36 8,57 0.96

Kalimatan 33 0.76 1.65 0.61 12 0.27 2.52 0.29

Samarinda 29 0.67 1.54 0.57 9 0.20 1.30 0.15

Pontianak 4 0.09 0.11 0.04 3 0.07 1.22 0.14

Sulawesi 19 0.42 1.08 0.40 19 0.41 2.38 0.27

Makasar 19 0.42 1.08 0.40 19 0.41 2.38 0.27

Bali 11 0.26 0.37 0.14 7 0.16 0.40 0.05

Denpasar 11 0.26 0.37 0.14 7 0.16 0, .40 0.05

Major Industrial Regions 2,688 61.29 155,36 57,62 3 67.28 587.64 65.9

INDONESIA 4,386 100 269,63 100 4.5 100 891.09 100

Source: Calculated from BPS; Putro (2013)

The second essential pattern is that almost every Java province showed a declining share

in the Indonesia‟s manufacturing employment. In 1976 DKI Jakarta, Central Java-DIY, and East

Java accounted for 15.2%, 24.1% and 30.6% of the Indonesian employment respectively. These

figures dropped substantially to be 10.7%, 13.6% and 22.8% in 1995. In contrast, West Java has

played a larger role in the country‟s employment since its share increased from 19.1% in 1976 to

35.2% in 1995, but declined to 28.2% in 2010.

Page 13: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

13

Figure 4. Revenue sharing funds by province

Source: Ministry of Finance (2013)

The emergence of West Java and the declining share of DKI Jakarta in terms of

employment should be interpreted carefully. This is due to the fact that many industries have

expanded their activities around Jabotabek, an extended region which include Jakarta urban area

(DKI Jakarta) and its adjacent municipalities in West Java, namely Bogor and Tangerang

(Botabek). Rapid and massive industrial relocation has occurred as a lot of industries have moved

out of Jakarta to the outskirts to take advantage of lower costs and wages. The share of Jabotabek

employment located in Botabek rose from 43 to 56% between 1986 and 1991, while 73% of all

plant births in Jabotabek in the larger corporate sector occured in Botabek for 1989-1991

(Henderson, et al. 1996: 83-5).

In terms of value added, the picture is far more striking (Figure 5). When we combine

West Java and DKI Jakarta, this region dominates the Indonesian manufacturing value added.

These two provinces contribute more than 50% of the country‟s value added. However, a closer

look at the district level indicates that manufacturing establishments grow unevenly within West

Java and cluster particularly in and around Jabotabek and Bandung. We will show using GIS that

analysis using provincial data rather than municipality data blurs the dynamic of industrial spill-

over across administrative border. Therefore, the next section will analyse the Jabotabek region

as a whole rather than separate Jakarta and its surrounding municipalities (Botabek).

Page 14: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

14

Figure 5. Percentage share of lme employment and value added in Java‟s provinces

Compared to Other Islands in Indonesia, 2001-2010

Source: Calculated from BPS

Outside Java the location of LME manufacturing tend to cluster in and around the

region‟s major cities and towns. At the provincial level, the major locations of LME

manufacturing firms in the Outer Island are found in North Sumatra, Riau, South Sumatra, West

Kalimantan, East Kalimantan, and South Sulawesi (recall Table 2). Known as either resource rich

or relative densely populated regions (for example, Hill, 1989, 1990), the distribution of LME

manufacturing sector in these provinces clusters heavily in a few districts (Table 4). In North

Sumatra most of the manufacturing firms --particularly aluminium, food, and plywood-- tend to

concentrate in Medan, Deli Serdang, and Asahan. In Riau basic metal products and plywood

firms tend to cluster in Kepulauan Riau, Bengkalis and Batam Island. In South Sumatra most

firms, particularly fertiliser, food and cement, are concentrated in Palembang and Musi Banyu

Asin. In West Kalimantan, timber and rubber processing firms are located in and around

Pontianak. Samarinda, Kutai, Bulungan, and Bontang are the major location of manufacturing

firms, particularly plywood and fertiliser, in East Kalimantan. In South Sulawesi, manufacturing

activities has located overwhelmingly in Ujung Pandang, and to lesser extent Pangkajene

Kepulauan.

In the Outer Island, large regional clusters are found in: (a) Batam Island and (b) Medan.

In terms of employment, both are much smaller than the main industrial areas in Java but

contribute substantially to value added. By value-added, Batam is slightly larger than Bandung

metropolitan regions but by employment it ranks only seventh (Kuncoro, 2012; 2004). Since the

mid-1980s Batam has developed rapidly in terms of infrastructure, investments, export, tourism,

and the manufacture of electronics (Smith, 1998: tables 18.1,18.2; Yuan, 1995: tables 12.1,12.2).

However, Batam is not an autonomous industrial agglomeration but an outlying industrial estate

of Singapore, just forty minutes away by ferry. National borders and differential regulations

allow land and labour to be much cheaper on Batam than on Singapore. As a product of both

policy and market forces, Batam, like Johor Baru in Malaysia, has become closely enmeshed with

Singapore as part of the Singapore-Johor-Riau (SIJORI) Growth Triangle. Its situation is quite

unlike that of most of the rest of the province of Riau, whether the adjacent islands or the main

island of Sumatra (Hill, 1996: 217). Batam must therefore be studied as part of the urban

economy of Singapore.

Medan has a long history as a centre for plantation industries such as rubber, tobacco and

oil palm, and its province of North Sumatra is still the most prosperous region in Sumatra

Page 15: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

15

(Barlow and Wie, 1989). By employment and value-added, Medan regional clusters, including

Deli Serdang, achieves ranking with the main industrial areas of Java.

Other industrial areas in the Outer Island contribute only marginally in terms of

employment and value added. Palembang, whose role is significantly underestimated by

exclusion of oil refining, includes both heavy industry (fertiliser, cement) and resource

processing (tin, timber, and agro-industries). Samarinda‟s LMEs are narrowly specialised in the

timber industry, including saw mills, furniture, and plywood. Pontianak has a broader industrial

base consisting of crumb rubber, rubber-milling, coconut oil and paper industries, which are

nevertheless all resource-based. Other industrial areas in the Outer Island, such as Ujung

Pandang, are minor in terms of employment and value added.

Some major patterns with respect to industrial clusters in Indonesia can be drawn. First,

Indonesia‟s rapid industrial development under the New Order was heavily biased towards the

island of Java. The predominance activities in Java might be explained as follows. First,

historically the core of both the modern state and economy was moulded on Java during the

course of the nineteenth century, with the development of the plantation economy under the

Cultivation System (Dick, 1996). Second, the spatial pattern can be fairly readily explained by

the attraction of labour- and skill-intensive industries to heavily populated Java, compared with

the attraction of resource-based industries to the Outer Islands. In the Outer Island, regional

clusters can be associated with resource-based industry and urban attraction. The former is found

in the case of Asahan, Kepulauan Riau, Musi Banyu Asin, Bulongan, Kutai. The latter is

represented by the emergence of Medan and Batam, and to a lesser extent Samarinda, Ujung

Pandang, Palembang, Pontianak, and other cities.

Getis-Ord‟s Gi is proved useful in identifying clusters, particularly since it examines

patterns of LME co-location, or clusters, across areal unit boundaries within a specified

neighborhood district. Smith et al. (2003), for an example, has tested Getis-Ord Gi in the U.S

floriculture industry to measure spatial autocorrelation at the local level and identify “hot spots”,

or concentrations in spatial distributions in which areal units and their neighbors have similar

values of a given phenomena; a high Gi value indicates that high values are clustered near each

other, whereas a low Gi value is low spatial cluster (“cold spot”) indicating of low values being

near each other.

Figure 6 indicates that employment growth of LME (growthcap) has a positive value of

0.6525. It illuminates how spatial clusters of LME industry tended to concentrate on certain

districts. We may identify the hot and cold spot of LME clusters in Indonesia. Strong

concentrations in spatial distributions in which areal units and their neighbors, or hot spots, are

found in Banten, DKI Jakarta, Jawa Barat, dan Central Java (shown by red colour in Figure 7).

These regions have not only high growth of LME employment but also bring high regional

spillover. On the other hand, cold spot region in Indonesia is found in South Sulawesi (shown by

blue colour in Figure 7). It implies that the province has relatively low spatial clusters and

regional spillover.

Page 16: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

16

Figure 6. Moran‟s I and Scatter Plot of GrowthCap Indonesia

Figure 7. Gi growth cap of LME clusters in Indonesia

Source: Calculated from BPS

2. Why LME tended to cluster in some regions?

To address this question, we test a discriminant model as specified in equation 1. Overall,

our discriminant model allocates correctly more than 80.7% of the original group cases. Table 3

Total Employment (TotalTK) Moran‟s I= 0,652548

(Spatial Clustering)

Page 17: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

17

provides a classification summary for the model, which incorrectly allocates only 65 districts out

of 326 to non-industrial districts. In terms of industrial districts, the model fails to allocate just 10

cases. As a result, the correctly predicted group membership is 80.1% for non-industrial

districts and 84.1% for industrial districts.

Table 3 Classification resultsa

Dik

b Predicted Group Membership Total

0 1

Original Count 0 261 65 326

1 10 53 63

% 0 80.1 19.9 100

1 15.9 84.1 100

Note: a 80.7% of original grouped cases correctly classified.

b Dik is 1 for industrial district; 0 for non-industrial districts.

The results of a direct discriminant function analysis using seven predictors suggest

that population density play a key role as the best predictor in discriminating LME between

industrial districts and non-industrial districts (Table 4). The coefficient for this variable

shows a positive sign. This implies that the higher the population density in a district the more

likely that LME will cluster towards industrial districts. Figure 8 shows there are positive

association between industrial density and population density across regions in Indonesia.

Table 4 Discriminant function coefficients

Predictor Function

Population density 0.830

Income per capita 0.374

Skilled workers 0.222

Revenue sharing funds -0.170

Infrastructure 0.050

Productivity 0.044

Average wages -0.029

Pooled within-groups correlations between discriminating variables and standardised

canonical discriminant functions. Variables ordered by absolute size of correlation within

function.

Population density, regional income per capita, and skilled workers show positive

coefficients. The positive coefficient of population density and income per capita show that both

scale economies and large market size explain regional localisation over time that attract LME to

locate in the industrial clusters. The findings confirm the prediction of New Trade Theory and

New Economic Geography: scale economies and home market do matter (Kuncoro, 2012;

Krugman, 1991; Fujita and Venables, 1999). These results suggest that LME manufacturing

firms in Indonesia seek to locate in more populous and densely populated areas to enjoy both

localization economies, which are associated with the size of a particular industry, and

agglomeration economies, which reflect the size of market of a district, in a particular urban area.

Page 18: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

18

Note:

High Urban Center concentration and High Population density

High Urban Center concentration and Low Population density

Low Urban Center concentration and High Population density

Low Urban Center concentration and Low Population density

Figure 8. Employment distribution by main islands and urban centers in Indonesia, 2010

Source: Calculated from BPS; Putro (2013)

Skilled workers, reflecting the availability of skilled workers, played an important role of

LME clustering. The positive coefficient of skilled workers shows that the higher level of labour

force education the higher possibility of LME to locate in the industrial clusters. The finding is

line with Smith and Florida (1994) which examined that big cities has become a magnet for

skilled workers to concentrate geographically in urban regions to seek jobs.

Revenue sharing funds as a central government transfer to regions reflect agglomeration

forces through resource based industry as argued by neo-classical economists (Johns, 1985: 178-

81). The negative coefficient of revenue sharing funds suggest that higher revenue sharing

funds the lower the possibility to attract LME industry to locate in those regions. Known

as rich resource based regions, East Kalimantan, Riau, Aceh, Bangka Belitung are provinces that

enjoyed higher revenue sharing funds. However, only mining companies, rather than LME

manufacturing, that clustered in those provinces.

The infrastructure and productivity are also found as good predictors. The positive sign of

infrastructure coefficient suggests that the better infrastructure availability in a region the greater

possibility of LME to cluster in the region. The theoretical and empirical literature on

agglomeration economies and urban public infrastructure pinpoints that agglomeration economies

exist when firms in the urban areas share public goods as inputs to production (Eberts and

McMillen, 1999). The finding is in line with Fujita et al. (1999: 233-236) and Krugman‟s (1991)

argument. The former argued that a hub or a port city provide the city‟s site with an advantage

over other sites, while the latter shows that reducing transport costs causes agglomeration.

Keterangan:

Page 19: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

19

Likewise, the positive sign of productivity coefficient means that the higher LME

productivity will lead the LME to cluster in and around industrial districts. This findings support

Porter‟s (1998) theory that industrial districts constitute more productive industrial organization

than non-industrial districts.

Wages are one of the important variables in labour economics but play as the least predictor

in discriminating between LME industrial districts and non-industrial districts. The negative

coefficient of wages shows that the higher wages the lower the possibility to attract LME

industry to locate in those regions. We found that increase in wages will discourage LME to

cluster in industrial districts. This finding supports Kuncoro‟s (2007, 2012) argument that wages

are important in the textile, wood and miscellaneous industries but turn out to be a less important

variable in more modern LME industries such as machinery, chemical, and paper. Our findings

suggest that higher wages in the industrial districts will encourage LME to expand

and seek other districts offering lower wages.

V. Conclusions

Although a number of economists and business strategists have recently become more

interested in spatial analysis, very few has examined the phenomena of regional clustering in

Indonesia using provincial and district data simultaneously. Some studies focus on urban

agglomeration, while others relate clustering to the competitive advantage of firms (Anselin and

Florax, 1995; Enright, 1998; Hill, 1997; Krugman, 1995; Lucas, 1988; Porter and Solvell, 1998).

This growing awareness on the spatial aspects of economies, the theoretical insights that have

been developed are as yet little tested empirically.

Our study sought to inject empirical content to the emerging interest in the literature by

examining regional clustering in the context of Indonesia‟s recent industrial transformation.

Using a GIS and recent perspectives in the literature of cluster, our study demonstrates that

Indonesia represents an excellent example of both the uneven geographic distribution of

manufacturing industry and the relationship between urbanization and industrial development.

Indonesia contains many regional clusters within a fairly homogeneous economic and regulatory

environment.

Indonesia‟s rapid industrial and regional development during the last two decades has

been heavily biased towards the densely populated island of Java. This is most striking in the

case of LME manufacturing, corresponding with the modern sector of manufacturing. The

predominant activities in Java can be explained as follows. First, historically during the course of

the nineteenth century, the core of both the modern state and economy was moulded on Java,

with the development of the plantation economy under the Cultivation System (Dick, 1996).

Second, the spatial pattern can be quite readily explained by the attraction of labour- and skill-

intensive industries to the heavily populated Java, compared with the attraction of resource-based

industries to the Outer Islands (Kuncoro, 2012; 2013).

This study confirms that the LME industrial clusters are associated with urban

concentration in Indonesia. Important distinguishing features of the industrial district have been

identified by a discriminant analysis. The results suggest that the best predictor was population

density, followed by income per capita, skilled workers, revenue sharing funds, infrastructure,

productivity, and averages wages. Thus, LME in industrial districts differ statistically from the

rest of Indonesia in terms of those key variables.

The Indonesian government has given attention to clustering perspective in the new

National Industrial Policy and MP3EI recently (Kuncoro, 2007, 2013). As pointed out by

Minister of Industry and Trade, the benefit of industrial clusters is to encourage product

Page 20: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

20

specialisation and to change comparative advantage into competitive advantage (Kompas, 2000;

Kuncoro, 2012). In line with this policy direction, understanding the locations, causes, and

consequences regional clustering is imperative. This study serves as a valuable input to the

government in formulating the new direction for industrial policy.

References

Abimanyu, A. (1996) The Indonesian economy and total factor productivity. The Singapore

Economic Review, 40(1), 25-40.

Anselin, L., and Florax, R. J. G. M., eds. (1995) New Directions in Spatial Econometrics.

Springer: New York.

Aziz, I. J. (1994) Ilmu Ekonomi Regional Dan Beberapa Aplikasinya Di Indonesia [Regional

Economics and its Some Applications in Indonesia], Lembaga Penerbit Fakultas Ekonomi

Universitas Indonesia: Jakarta.

Barlow, C., and Wie, T. K. (1989) North Sumatra: Growth with unbalanced development, in H.

Hill (ed.), Unity and Diversity: Regional Economic Development in Indonesia since 1970

(pp. 409-36), Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Bellandi, M. (1989) The Industrial District in Marshall, in E. Goodman, J. Bamford, and P.

Saynor (eds.), Small firms and industrial districts in Italy, Routledge: London and New

York.

Booth, A. ed. (1992) The Oil Boom and After: Indonesian Economic Policy and Performance in

the Soeharto Era. Oxford University Press: Singapore.

Dick, H., Fox, J. J., and Mackie, J. (eds). (1993) Balanced Development: East Java in the New

Order. Oxford University Press: Singapore.

Dick, H. W. (1996) The emergence of a National Economy, 1808-1990s. in J. T. Lindblad (ed.),

Historical Foundations of a National Economy in Indonesia, 1890s-1990s, 21-51, Royal

Netherlands Academy of Arts and Science: Amsterdam.

Djidin, D. A. (1997) The political economy of Indonesia's new economic policy. Journal of

Contemporary Asia, 27(1), 14-36.

Eberts, R. W., and McMillen, D. P. (1999) Agglomeration economies and urban public

infrastructure, in P. Cheshire and E. S. Mills (eds.), Handbook of regional and Urban

Economics: Applied Urban Economics, 3: 1457-1495. North-Holland: Amsterdam.

Enright, M. J. (1998) Regional clusters and firm strategy. in A. D. J. Chandler, P. Hagstrom, and

O. Solvell (eds.), The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, Organization,

and Regions, 3150-42. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Fane, G. (1996) Deregulation in Indonesia: Two steps forward, one step back, Agenda, 3(3), 341-

50.

Florence, P. S. (1961) The Logic of British and American Industry. London: Routledge and

Kegan Paul.

Fujita, M. Krugman, P. and Venables, A. J. (1999) The Spatial Economy: Cities, regions, and

International Ttrade. The MIT Press: Cambridge and London.

Fujita, M., and Thisse, J.-F. (1996) The economics of agglomeration, Journal of Japanese and

International Economics, 10: 339-78.

Gee, T. G., and Robinson, I. M. (eds.) (1995) The Mega Urban Regions of Southeast Asia. UBC

Press: Vancouver.

Page 21: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

21

Gelder, L. v. (1994) Industrial agglomeration and factor market segmentation with empirical

applications to Indonesia. Unpublished PhD dissertation, Cornell University, US:

Cornell.

Gilmour, J. M. (1974) External economies of scale, inter-industrial linkages and decision making

in manufacturing. in F. E. i. Hamilton (ed.), Spatial Perspectives on Industrial

Organization and Decision Making, 335-62. John Wiley and Sons: London.

Hardjono, J., and Hill, H. (1989) West Java: Population pressure and regional diversity, in H. Hill

(ed.), Unity and Diversity: Regional Development in Indonesia since 1970, 255-282.

Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Henderson, J. V. (1988) Urban Development,Theory, Fact, and Illusion. Oxford University

Press: New York.

Henderson, J. V., and Kuncoro, A. (1996) Industrial centralization in Indonesia, The World Bank

Economic Review, 10(3), 513-40.

Henderson, J. V., Kuncoro, A. and Nasution, D. (1996) The dynamic of Jabotabek development,

Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 32(1), 71-95.

Hill, H. (ed.) (1989) Unity and Diversity: Regional Economic Development in Indonesia Since

1970. Oxford University Press: Singapore.

Hill, H. (1990) Indonesia's industrial transformation Part 1, Bulletin of Indonesian Economic

Studies, 26(2), 79-120.

Hill, H. (1996) The Indonesian Economy Since 1966: Southeast Asia's Emerging Giants.

Cambridge University Press: Cambridge.

Hill, H. (1997) Indonesia's Industrial Transformation. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies:

Singapore.

Jong, T. D., and Floor, H. (1996) Analysis of interaction data in a GIS environment-a case study

in Indonesia, in T. Fung, P. C. Lai, H. Lin, and A. G.-O. Yeh (eds.), GIS in Asia,chap. 32.

GIS Asia Pacific: Singapore.

Juppenlatz, M., and Tian, X. (1996) Geographic Information Systems and Remote Sensing.

McGraw-Hill Book Company: Sydney.

Kompas. (2000) Kebijakan nasional sektor industri: Aglomerasi dengan kemitraan {The national

policy of industrial sector: Agglomeration with partnership], Kompas. Available:

http://www.kompas.com.kompas-cetak/008/19/EKONOMI/aglo14.html [2000, 19

August].

Krugman, P. (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography, Journal of Political Economy,

99, 483-499.

Krugman, P. (1995) Development, Geography, and Economic Theory. The MIT Press:

Cambridge and London.

Krugman, P. (1996) Urban concentration: The role of increasing returns and transport costs,

International Regional Science Review 19(1 and 2), 5-30.

Krugman, P. (1998) Space: The final frontier, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(2), 161-74.

Kuncoro, M. (2000a) Beyond agglomeration and urbanization, Gadjah Mada International

Journal of Business, 2(3).

Kuncoro, M. (2000b) The Economics of Industrial Agglomeration and Clustering, 1976-1996:

the case of Indonesia (Java). Unpublished PhD thesis, the University of Melbourne:

Melbourne.

Kuncoro, M. (2000c) Ekonomi Pembangunan: Teori, Masalah dan Kebijakan. UPP AMP

YKPN: Yogyakarta.

Page 22: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

22

Kuncoro, M. (2001) Regional clustering of Indonesia‟s manufacturing industry: a spatial analysis

with Geographic Information System (GIS), Gadjah Mada International Journal of

Business, 3 (3).

Kuncoro, M. (2006) Quantitative Methods: Theory and Applications for Business and

Economics, 3rd

ed., UPP STIM-YKPN: Yogyakarta.

Kuncoro, M. (2011a) Koridor ekonomi Indonesia [Economic corridors of Indonesia], Investor

Daily, Retrieved February 28, 2011, from http://website.mudrajad.com/content/koridor-

ekonomi-indonesia.

Kuncoro, M. (2011b) MP3EI: mitos atau realitas? [MP3EI: a myth or reality?], Retrieved August

1, 2011, from

http://cetak.kompas.com/read/2011/08/01/0415106/mp3ei.mitos.atau.realitas.

Kuncoro, M. (2012) Ekonomika Aglomerasi: Dinamika dan Dimensi Spasial Kluster Industri

Indonesia [Economics of Agglomeration: Dynamics and Spatial Dimension of

Indonesia’s Industrial Clusters]. UPP STIM YKPN: Yogyakarta.

Kuncoro, M. (2013) Economic Geography of Indonesia, South East Asian Journal of

Comtemporary Business, Economics, and Law, 2(2), 17-33.

Kuncoro, M., Adji, A. and Pradiptyo, R. (1997) Ekonomi Industri: Teori, kebijakan, dan Studi

Empiris di Indonesia [Industrial Economics: Theory, Policy, and Empirical Studies in

Indonesia]. Widya Sarana Informatika: Yogyakarta.

Kuncoro, M, Widodo, T. and McLeod, R. (2009). Survey of recent developments, Bulletin of

Indonesian Economic Studies, 45(2), 151-176.

Lucas, R. E. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development, Journal of Monetary

Economics, 22, 3-22.

Malecki, E. J. (1991) Technology and Economic Development: The Dynamics of Local, Regional,

and National Change. John Wiley and Sons, Inc: New York.

Manning, C. (1997) Regional labor markets during deregulation in Indonesia: Have the outer

islands been left behind?, Policy Research Working Paper, No.1728. The World Bank,

East Asia and Pasific, Country Department III: Washington, DC.

Markusen, A. (1996) Sticky places in slippery space: A typology of industrial districts, Economic

Geography, 72(3), 293-.

Marshall, A. (1919) Industry and Trade. Macmillan: London.

Martin, D. (1996) Geographic Information System: Socioeconomic Applications, 2nd ed.

Routledge: New York.

Ministry of Finance. (2013) Data Pokok APBN 2007–2013, Retrieved January 31, 2014, from

http://www.anggaran.depkeu.go.id/dja/acontent/Data%20Pokok%20APBN%202013.pdf.

Moran, P. A. P. (1950) Notes on continuous stochastic phenomena, Biometrika, 37(1): 17–23.

Nadvi, K., and Schmitz, H. (1994) Industrial clusters in LDCs: Review of experiences and

research agenda, IDS Discussion Paper No.339. IDS, University of Sussex: Brighton.

Nakamura, R. and Sendouw, R.H.E.(2009) Market potential and regional per capita GRP

differentials: application of the NEG model to Indonesian provinces. Retrieved June 14,

2013, from

http://www.researchgate.net/publication/32199787_Market_Potential_and_Regional_Per_

Capita_GRP_Differentials__Application_of_the_NEG_Model_to_Indonesian_Provinces.

Nasution, A. (1991) Recent economic reform, The Indonesian Quarterly, 29(1), 12-26.

Ohmae, K. (1995) The End of the Nation State: The Rise of Regional Economies. London: Harper

Collins.

Page 23: ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY OF INDONESIA’S MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY › attachments › article › 176 › Economic... · Kuncoro, et al. 1997). In the period 1997-1999, the economic crisis

23

Ohta, H., and Thisse, J.-F. (eds.) (1993) Does Economic Space Matter? Essays in Honour of

Melvin L. Greenhut. St. Martin's Press: New York.

Porter, M. E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage of Nations. The Free Press: New York.

Porter, M. E. (1994) Comment on interaction between regional and industrial policies: Evidence

from four countries, by Markusen. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on

Development Economics 1994, Washington DC.

Porter, M. E. (1998a) Clusters and the new economics of competition, Harvard Business Review,

November-December (6), 77-91.

Porter, M. E. (1998b) Competing across locations: Enhancing competitive advantage through a

global strategy, in M. E. Porter (ed.), On Competition,309-48. Harvard Business School

Publishing: Boston.

Porter, M. E., and Solvell, O. (1998) The role of geography in the process of innovation and the

sustainable competitive advantage of firms, in J. Alfred D. Chandler, P. Hagstrom, and O.

Solvell (eds.), The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy, Organization, and

Regions, 440-457. Oxford University Press: Oxford.

Putro, S.S. (2013) Analisis lokasi aglomerasi dan kluster industri besar sedang Indonesia Tahun

2001-2010 [A locational analysis of Indonesia's large and medium industrial clusters

2001-2010]. Master of Economic Development Program UGM: Yogyakarta. unpublished

Master thesis.

Pyke, F., and Sengenberger, W. (eds.) (1992) Industrial Districts and Local Economic

Regeneration. ILO: Geneva.

Schmitz, H. (1995) Small shoemakers and fordist giants: A tale of a supercluster, World

Development, 23(1), 9-28.

Scott, A. J. (1993) Technopolis: High Technology Industry and Regional Development in

Southern California. University of California Press: Berkeley.

Scott, A. J., and Storper, M. (1992) Regional development reconsidered, in H. Ernste and V.

Meier (eds.), Regional Development and Contemporary Industrial Response: Extending

Flexible Specialisation, 3-24. Belhaven Press: London.

Smith, B.W., Carroll, M.C., Reid, N. (2003) Potential cluster regions: The case of the floriculture

industry, http://uac.utoledo.edu/nwoerc/FloriculturePCRs.pdf. April 2, 2013.

Smith, S. L. (1998) Batam Island and Indonesia's high technology strategy, in H. Hill and T. K.

Wie (eds.), Indonesia's Technological Change, 342-363. Institute of Southeast Asian

Studies: Singapore.

Statistics Indonesia (BPS). 2015. Concept and methodology of Large and Medium

Manufacturing, http://www.bps.go.id/Subjek/view/id/9#subjekViewTab1|accordion-

daftar-subjek2. July 22, 2015.

Yuan, L. T. (1995) The Johor-Singapore-Riau growth triangle: The effect of economic

integration, in T. G. McGee and I. M. Robinson (eds.), The Mega-Urban Regions of

Southeast Asia, UBC Press: Vancouver.

Zeitlin, J. (1992) Industrial districts and local economic generation: Overview and comment, in

F. Pyke and W. Sengenberger (eds.), Industrial Districts and Local Economic

Regeneration, ILO: Geneva.