economic policy uncertainty and information asymmetry€¦ · economic policy uncertainty and...

51
Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry * Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld University of Utah Laura Wellman University of Utah October 2017 Abstract This study examines whether economic policy uncertainty exacerbates information asymmetry among investors. We find that increased economic policy uncertainty is associated with decreased stock liquidity, especially for firms more exposed to eco- nomic policy uncertainty. Increased economic policy uncertainty also lowers investors’ reaction to earnings for firms with high liquidity risk. Management in turn increases voluntary disclosure, which only partly reverses the liquidity drop. These results sug- gest that information asymmetry is an important channel through which economic policy uncertainty affects asset pricing. Keywords: Corporate Disclosure; Information Asymmetry; Economic Policy Uncertainty; Stock Liquidity JEL Classification: D80; E61; E65; G12; G14; G18; L50 * We appreciate the helpful suggestions from the Editor (John Core), an anonymous reviewer, Nick Bloom, Steve Davis, Beverly Walther, and workshop participants at BYU, Northwestern University, Temple Univer- sity, and the University of Utah.

Upload: others

Post on 16-May-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Economic Policy Uncertainty and InformationAsymmetry∗

Venky NagarUniversity of Michigan

Jordan SchoenfeldUniversity of Utah

Laura WellmanUniversity of Utah

October 2017

Abstract

This study examines whether economic policy uncertainty exacerbates information

asymmetry among investors. We find that increased economic policy uncertainty is

associated with decreased stock liquidity, especially for firms more exposed to eco-

nomic policy uncertainty. Increased economic policy uncertainty also lowers investors’

reaction to earnings for firms with high liquidity risk. Management in turn increases

voluntary disclosure, which only partly reverses the liquidity drop. These results sug-

gest that information asymmetry is an important channel through which economic

policy uncertainty affects asset pricing.

Keywords: Corporate Disclosure; Information Asymmetry; Economic Policy Uncertainty;Stock LiquidityJEL Classification: D80; E61; E65; G12; G14; G18; L50

∗We appreciate the helpful suggestions from the Editor (John Core), an anonymous reviewer, Nick Bloom,Steve Davis, Beverly Walther, and workshop participants at BYU, Northwestern University, Temple Univer-sity, and the University of Utah.

Page 2: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

1 Introduction

Policymakers are motivated by a variety of factors, including economic, social, and polit-

ical forces. To the extent that investors cannot fully anticipate the effect of these competing

forces on policy outcomes, they face uncertainty over which policies the government will

implement, and ultimately over how these policies impact firm value. Accordingly, em-

pirical evidence suggests that economic policy uncertainty affects firms’ business prospects

and operating decisions, and thus equity prices and volatility (e.g., Baker et al., 2016, p.

1597). However, theory suggests that equity price levels and volatility patterns can change

both in a homogeneous information setting where economic policy uncertainty identically

changes every investor’s beliefs of the mean levels and the priced covariances of firms’ future

payoffs (e.g., the models of Kelly et al., 2016 and Pastor and Veronesi, 2012, 2013, where

all investors are identically informed), and in a heterogeneous information setting where

economic policy uncertainty changes price by changing the information asymmetry among

investors. We therefore empirically examine the effect of economic policy uncertainty on

investor information asymmetry.

Our main proxy for economic policy uncertainty is the economic policy uncertainty (EPU)

index of Baker et al. (2016) that is constructed from textual analysis of news sources. The

EPU index has found widespread acceptance in the literature in part due to the valida-

tion efforts of its creators and in part due to its continuous availability.1 Using a sample

of all U.S. public companies over 2003–2016, we first find that stocks, both on the aggre-

gate and individually, are less liquid in times of a higher EPU index, both at daily and

monthly intervals. This suggests that economic policy uncertainty exacerbates rather than

1Much of Baker et al. (2016) is devoted to validation efforts that show that the EPU index is correlatedwith key macroeconomic, individual firm-level, and political phenomena. We describe these features of theEPU index in detail in Section 2. Also see http://policyuncertainty.com/research.html.

1

Page 3: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

levels information asymmetry among investors.2 Since it is unlikely that the EPU index is

significantly influenced by any individual firm’s liquidity, we have assurance in attributing

causality from the EPU index to individual firm liquidity. To further establish that economic

policy uncertainty is indeed the factor behind this association, we follow Baker et al. (2016,

Section IV.B) and successfully find stronger (weaker) results for a subset of firms that have

high (low) exposure to economic policy uncertainty. We then show that a firm’s exposure to

illiquidity related to economic policy uncertainty also impacts how investors price earnings.

For the same earnings surprise in periods of a higher EPU index, earnings announcement

returns are lower for firms that have high exposure to liquidity risk. This result further

confirms the presence of increased information asymmetry among investors during periods

of increased economic policy uncertainty.

Given the above liquidity implications, we then delve more deeply into our reduced-

form estimation of the link between economic policy uncertainty and liquidity by following

Balakrishnan et al. (2014), who argue that managers shape liquidity and therefore respond

to exogenous liquidity reductions by increasing voluntary disclosure. We find this to be the

case in our setting as well. Managers increase disclosure after economic policy uncertainty

increases, and this disclosure reduces but does not eliminate the liquidity effect.3 These

findings buttress our main contention that economic policy uncertainty has a heterogeneous

impact on investors’ information sets.

We now give a sense of the economic magnitudes of our results. Using year-fixed effect

regressions, we find that a one standard deviation increase in the monthly EPU index is

associated with a 1.01% increase in monthly market-value-weighted quoted spreads and a

2Our proxy for information asymmetry is stock liquidity, as measured by quoted percent bid-ask spreads(from DTAQ) and Amihud illiquidity (from CRSP). Fong et al. (2017) and Holden and Jacobsen (2014) findthat these are the two best measures of stock liquidity. We conduct our tests at several levels of granularity,including monthly and daily data intervals, and at the aggregate market and firm levels. Monthly testsensure that the daily tests are not driven by spurious short-term correlations in the data, whereas firm-leveltests enable us to ascertain meaningful sources of cross-sectional variation in the aggregate tests. Figure 1shows that the EPU index has considerable time-series variation, so we do not examine liquidity effects fordurations longer than a month. We include appropriate fixed effects and error clustering.

3We also use the findings of Balakrishnan et al. (2014) to provide assurance that disclosure is likely drivingliquidity and not the other way around (see Section 3.4).

2

Page 4: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

1.93% increase in monthly market-value-weighted Amihud illiquidity.4 We then conduct

monthly tests at the firm level using firm-year-fixed-effect regressions. We find that a one

standard deviation increase in the monthly EPU index is associated with a 3.48% increase

in monthly firm-level quoted spreads and a 2.52% increase in monthly firm-level Amihud

illiquidity.

We next use daily data to link liquidity to the EPU index. At the aggregate market

level with year-fixed effects, we find that a one standard deviation increase in the daily EPU

index is associated with a 0.45% increase in daily market-value-weighted quoted spreads and

a 0.42% increase in daily market-value-weighted Amihud illiquidity. At the firm level with

firm-year-fixed effects, where we have more confidence in attributing causality, we find that

a one standard deviation increase in the daily EPU index is associated with a 1.8% increase

in daily quoted spreads and a 1.1% increase in daily Amihud illiquidity. By comparison,

Chordia et al. (2001, p. 509) find that the average daily change in a similar spread variable

is on the order of two percent. To corroborate these initial results, we perform several cross-

sectional analyses using both monthly and daily data. The link between the EPU index

and illiquidity is stronger for firms that are more exposed to economic policy uncertainty,

as measured by an EPU index-stock return sensitivity beta, for smaller firms, for firms with

more domestic exposure, and for firms with several additional characteristics. We also ensure

that our main findings generalize to other economic policy uncertainty settings such as being

in the healthcare business during the Affordable Care Act (ACA) policy debates.

To the extent that increased economic policy uncertainty decreases liquidity, this could

cause some investors to trade less aggressively on information or to withdraw from the market

altogether, which means that there would be fewer traders (or less trading) in the market

for important corporate information events such as earnings disclosures (e.g., Chordia et al.,

4Our use of value weights follows Chordia et al. (2005), though our results hold for equal weights aswell. Baker et al. (2016) find that the EPU index could be correlated with general market uncertainty, sowe control for the equity uncertainty (EU) index from Baker et al. (2016) in the above tests and, whenappropriate, in the analyses that follow. Baker et al. (2016, p. 1614) find that the EU index compares wellto other proxies of equity market uncertainty such as the VIX.

3

Page 5: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

2008; Kyle, 1985). Following the research design in Kelly and Ljungqvist (2012, Section

3.4), we compute the Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) liquidity risk exposure beta for each

firm and show that firms in the highest quintile have lower announcement returns for the

same earnings surprise during periods of high economic policy uncertainty, relative to firms

in the lower quintiles.5

We then look to managerial response following Balakrishnan et al. (2014), who argue that

management typically has an incentive to shape liquidity and therefore uses disclosure to

restore exogenous drops in liquidity. At the daily level, we find that a one standard deviation

increase in the average EPU index over the prior 30 days is associated with additional

guidance disclosures that lower spreads on the same day by 0.22%. This indirect effect of

0.22% amounts to 48.89% of the direct effect that the EPU index has on spreads on a daily

basis, suggesting that managers’ additional guidance disclosures offset the adverse liquidity

effects of economic policy uncertainty by about half. Managers attempt to reverse but do not

succeed in fully reversing the liquidity effects of economic policy uncertainty. This further

supports our inference that our reduced-form tests linking liquidity and economic policy

uncertainty reflect an increase in information asymmetry among investors.6

We lastly place our findings in the literature. Baker et al. (2016) argue that economic

policy uncertainty is an important uncertainty to investors in the market. Accordingly,

as stated in our opening paragraph, many studies examine the impact of economic policy

uncertainty on stock prices, but in a manner that does not explore whether investors have the

5Note that earnings disclosure can reduce information asymmetry among investors and thus offset investorpropensity to trade less. To complicate matters further, some investors may respond to economic policyuncertainty and earnings disclosures by increasing their information-acquisition activities and trading moreaggressively, which could also cause other less informed investors to withdraw (Kim and Verrecchia, 1994;Gao and Huang, 2016). The extent of this offset is an empirical issue. Our findings suggest that this offsetis not complete.

6Our findings also obtain when we control for guidance released on earnings announcement days. Ouruse of a daily setting is motivated by endogeneity considerations. If liquidity is low, management mayincrease disclosure, which would result in a positive association between illiquidity and disclosure, potentiallycanceling the liquidity improvement effect of disclosure (Balakrishnan et al., 2014, p. 2271). This is notwhat we find. To the extent that management responds to longer-term declines in liquidity, the impact ofthe endogeneity of disclosure is likely to be more pronounced over longer intervals such as a quarter, whichis why Balakrishnan et al. (2014, p. 2266) find a weak “naive” relationship between liquidity and disclosureover both the contemporaneous and the lagging quarter (see our Section 3.4).

4

Page 6: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

same information sets.7 To be sure, investor information heterogeneity has been examined

in other asset pricing settings such as brokerage closures (e.g., Kelly and Ljungqvist, 2012),

but not in the setting of economic policy uncertainty. Likewise, the impact of liquidity

on investor actions such as the pricing of financial reports and managerial actions such as

voluntary reporting has also been examined before, but in different settings (Balakrishnan

et al., 2014; Guay et al., 2016; Lang and Maffett, 2011; Sadka, 2011; Schoenfeld, 2017).

The remainder of this study is organized as follows. Section 2 describes our data. Section

3 provides our empirical results. Section 4 concludes.

2 Sample and Data

Our sample includes the entire NYSE daily TAQ (DTAQ) database from September 10,

2003 to December 31, 2016. We focus specifically on firms headquartered in the U.S., as

our primary measures for economic policy uncertainty pertain to the U.S. This reduces the

DTAQ universe by about 25%. We also link each DTAQ firm to CRSP data using the linking

table provided by DTAQ, which enables us to compute contemporaneous Amihud illiquidity.

We impose no other survival criteria (except where as noted). Our final sample comprises

nearly 7,000 firms and 15 million daily observations of liquidity, which suggests that our

regression coefficients will be precisely estimated.

To proxy for stock liquidity, we follow Holden and Jacobsen (2014) and use the daily

DTAQ database to compute daily percent quoted spreads for each firm-day over our sample

period. Fong et al. (2017) and Holden and Jacobsen (2014) provide convincing evidence that

this measure is the “first-best” proxy for liquidity. We compute percent quoted spread as

7One exception is Pasquariello and Zafeiridou (2014), who use Roll’s indirect measure of liquidity thatdoes not use bid-ask spreads but instead constructs the liquidity measure based on the covariance of pricemovements assuming an informationally efficient market with no information asymmetry (Fong et al., 2017).

5

Page 7: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

follows:

Percent Quoted Spreadsit = 100× Askit −Bidit(Askit +Bidit)/2

. (1)

Subscript i represents each firm, and subscript t represents each observation day. Askit is

the National Best Ask and Bidit is the National Best Bid, where both variables are time

weighted during trading hours for each day according to the procedure described in Holden

and Jacobsen (2014). To ensure that we compute this measure accurately, we vet and

implement the code provided by Holden and Jacobsen (2014).

Our second proxy for liquidity is Amihud illiquidity (Amihud, 2002). Fong et al. (2017)

and Holden et al. (2013) find that Amihud illiquidity is the second-best liquidity measure

behind quoted spreads, and the best measure that can be computed from CRSP. Following

Amihud (2002), we compute daily Amihud illiquidity as follows:

Amihudit = 106 ×∑ |Returnit|

Dollar Trade V olumeit. (2)

Returnit and Dollar Trade V olumeit are firm i’s stock return and dollar trading volume,

respectively, on day t from CRSP. While Chordia et al. (2008, p. 252) note that reporting

errors in the TAQ databases have declined considerably, we mitigate the influence of outliers

by winsorizing our liquidity proxies from the top at the 1% level (our results are qualitatively

similar without winsorizing). Furthermore, our analyses use the log of one plus the liquidity

measures as described in Appendix A, which further reduces outlier concerns and also makes

interpretations of the coefficients easier.8 All of our liquidity measures are available on a

daily basis and move inversely with the level of a firm’s stock liquidity. We conduct both

individual firm-level and aggregate market-level analyses. In our aggregate market analyses,

both of our liquidity proxies are market-value weighted on the day of observation. Our use

8Note that the number of observations in our regressions will differ slightly due to data availability ofour liquidity proxies. For example, on occasion CRSP does not provide trading volume, so for these days wecannot compute Amihud illiquidity.

6

Page 8: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

of value weights follows Chordia et al. (2005), though our results hold for equal weights as

well. We also conduct daily and monthly analyses. In our monthly analyses, we average

each liquidity measure (at both the market and firm level) over the observation month.

Our main proxy for economic policy uncertainty is the economic policy uncertainty (EPU)

index developed by Baker et al. (2016). The EPU index is constructed daily based on

the number of news articles that contain the terms economic or economy ; uncertain or

uncertainty ; and one or more of Congress, deficit, Federal Reserve, legislation, regulation,

and White House.9 Baker et al. (2016, p. 1593) note that several types of evidence—

including human readings of 12,000 newspaper articles—indicate that the EPU index proxies

for movements in economic policy uncertainty. The index spikes near tight presidential

elections, Gulf Wars I and II, the 9/11 attacks, the failure of Lehman Brothers, the 2011

debt ceiling dispute, and other major battles over economic policy. Using firm-level data,

Baker et al. (2016) find that the EPU index is associated with greater stock price volatility

and reduced investment and employment in policy-sensitive sectors like defense, health care,

finance, and infrastructure construction. At the macro level, the EPU index foreshadows

drops in investment, output, and employment in the United States.

We also address the finding in Baker et al. (2016) that the EPU index could be correlated

with the broader construct of general market uncertainty. Specifically, we control for the

equity uncertainty (EU) index when appropriate, as recommended by Baker et al. (2016).

The EU index is constructed based on the number of news articles that contain the terms

uncertainty or uncertain, the terms economic or economy, and one or more of the following

terms: equity market, equity price, stock market, or stock price.10 In our monthly analyses,

we compute the average of these measures over the observation month.

We conduct a cross-sectional analysis on the association between the EPU index and

liquidity based on several static, firm-level attributes. Our first attribute is the sensitivity of

9See http://www.policyuncertainty.com/us_daily.html.10See also http://www.policyuncertainty.com/equity_uncert.html. Our results also obtain when we

use the VIX and squared VIX in place of the EU index (Baker et al., 2016, p. 1614; Drechsler, 2013).

7

Page 9: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

the firm’s returns to the EPU index. We use a firm-level economic policy uncertainty returns

beta (Policy Beta), which we compute by first running firm-level regressions of monthly excess

returns on the daily EPU index over our sample period as follows:

rit = β0i + βEi EPUt + βMi MKTt + βSi SMBt + βHi HMLt + εit, (3)

where r is firm i’s excess return, MKT is the excess return on a market index, and SMB

and HML are long-short return spreads constructed on sorts of market capitalization and

book-to-market ratio (see Fama and French, 1993). Note that we run this regression at the

firm level, not the portfolio level, to ensure that we can directly link each firm’s βEi to its

respective liquidity.11 Our cross-sectional analysis also considers firm size, as measured by

log of market value of equity, as another factor driving the sensitivity of a firm to economic

policy uncertainty.

We also consider a firm’s international exposure, which might affect a firm’s sensitivity

to domestic U.S. economic policy uncertainty (e.g., Boutchkova et al., 2012). For example,

firms with less U.S. exposure might be insulated from economic policy uncertainty in the

U.S., which is our setting. Specifically, we use an indicator variable that equals 1 if a firm

had foreign-subsidiary revenue in any year during our sample period, derived from income

statement data provided by Compustat. The next attribute is the average number of foreign

trade words in a firm’s 10-Ks over our sample period, computed using the Baker et al.

(2016) foreign trade dictionary. This dictionary includes import tariffs, import duty, import

barrier, government subsidies, government subsidy, WTO, World Trade Organization, trade

treaty, trade agreement, trade policy, trade act, Doha Round, Uruguay Round, GATT, and

dumping. As with foreign revenue, foreign trade words in the 10-K might represent a firm’s

11Note that we are not interested in examining if the EPU index is a priced factor. We only want tomeasure how sensitive a firm’s returns are to the EPU index. In the cross-sectional analyses, we use theabsolute value of the beta because both positive and negative beta suggest that a firm’s return is sensitiveto economic policy uncertainty. Our use of absolute values is similar to the research design of Addoum andKumar (2016, p. 3473), who examine return sensitivity to political uncertainty.

8

Page 10: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

international exposure, which might affect its sensitivity to domestic U.S. economic policy

uncertainty.

We also consider two additional cross-sectional measures that could modulate the link

between economic policy uncertainty and the firm’s liquidity. Our first measure is a firm’s

lobbying expenditures, which could represent a firm’s effort to manage the economic policy

process through intervention (Gao and Huang, 2016; Hochberg et al., 2009; Wellman, 2017,

p. 225). We hand collect lobbying data from the Center for Responsive Politics (CRP) and

compute the average number of total lobbying dollars a firm spends per year over our sample

period.12 Our second measure is a firm-level economic policy uncertainty measure derived

from the 10-K (labeled EPU Words in the tables). We compute the average number of

economic policy uncertainty words in a firm’s 10-Ks over our sample period, relying on a set

of terms similar to that of Baker et al. (2016).13 An important caveat about using lobbying

dollars and 10-K policy terms is that both of these measures might proxy for increased

exposure to economic policy uncertainty, rather than effective management of economic

policy uncertainty (e.g., Adelino and Dinc, 2014; Hassan et al., 2017). We therefore do not

have predictions for these measures.

We compute all of the above firm-level measures as their averages for each firm over our

full sample period, because many of these measures do not change significantly over time or

can be measured only over relatively long time intervals. As a result, we cannot use these

measures to conduct meaningful within-firm-year analyses, and thus these measures vary

only in the cross-section of our firms. However, one advantage of this approach is that we

can still include firm-year-fixed effects in all of our cross-sectional tests.

Following the research design in Kelly and Ljungqvist (2012, Section 3.4), we next con-

duct tests to see if economic policy uncertainty changes the stock price reaction to earnings

12Lobbying reports are filed with the Secretary of the Senate’s Office of Public Records and are availableby calendar year beginning in 1998. The CRP maintains the lobbying data, which we manually match toCompustat by company name.

13These terms include economic, economy, uncertain, uncertainty, Congress, deficit, Federal Reserve, leg-islation, regulation, and White House.

9

Page 11: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

announcements based on the firm’s liquidity risk. We use a firm’s liquidity risk instead of

actual liquidity, because we want a measure of the firm’s steady-state return exposure to

liquidity and also because liquidity itself changes endogenously during earnings announce-

ments (Sadka, 2011). We measure a firm’s exposure to expected liquidity risk by the firm’s

βLi from Section 3 of Pastor and Stambaugh (2003). Following Chordia et al. (2014, footnote

7), we compute βLi by running the following regression for each firm using monthly data over

our entire sample period (we are not interested in constructing portfolios for trading):

rit = β0i + βLi Lt + βMi MKTt + βSi SMBt + βHi HMLt + εit, (4)

where L is the Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) Eq. (8) innovation in liquidity measure, r is

firm i’s excess return, MKT is the excess return on a market index, and SMB and HML

are long-short return spreads constructed on sorts of market capitalization and book-to-

market ratio.14 Note that we run this regression at the firm level, not the portfolio level,

to ensure that we can directly link each firm’s βLi to its respective earnings announcement

stock price reactions. Furthermore, note that we are not interested in time-sensitive higher

moments of returns (e.g., autocorrelation, cross-correlation, variance), so we do not need

to be concerned about market microstructure considerations such as bid-ask bounce and

asynchronous trading (Campbell et al., 1996, p. 129; Chordia et al., 2008).

Balakrishnan et al. (2014) argue that managers respond to illiquidity by increasing dis-

closure. Our main disclosure measure, following Balakrishnan et al. (2014), is the frequency

count of management guidance that incorporates capital expenditures, R&D, revenue, or

earnings. We focus on these guidance measures because prior studies have found that eco-

nomic policy uncertainty impacts capital expenditures, R&D, revenue, and earnings (e.g.,

Baker et al., 2016; Bloom et al., 2007; Gulen and Ion, 2016; Julio and Yook, 2012). We

obtain guidance data from I/B/E/S, which covers the universe of public U.S. companies.

14We obtain the innovation in liquidity measure from http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/lubos.

pastor/research/.

10

Page 12: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Similar to Balakrishnan et al. (2014), we find that the I/B/E/S guidance data do not have

the coverage gaps that were identified in Thomson Reuters’ First Call, which was discontin-

ued in 2012 (Chuk et al., 2013). I/B/E/S confirmed this in response to our inquiries. We

therefore follow Balakrishnan et al. (2014) and code no guidance in I/B/E/S as zero.15 We

also do not distinguish between good news and bad news guidance, as the type of the news is

more relevant when management is trying to raise or lower the stock price, which is not our

focus. Our focus is investor information asymmetry, which can be driven by the withholding

or release of any type of news. In our aggregate market analysis, each guidance disclosure

is weighted by a firm’s market-value weight (on the disclosure date) before aggregating the

guidance disclosures into one daily measure of guidance (our results are similar if we use

equal weights). This procedure ensures that our guidance disclosures are weighted in the

same way as our market-value-weighted liquidity measures. For our unexpected earnings

analysis, we obtain the consensus mean analyst earnings forecast and actual earnings from

I/B/E/S as well.16

We complement the EPU index with two additional means to measure economic pol-

icy uncertainty. First, we use the 2009–2010 Congressional healthcare debates as a quasi-

experimental difference-in-differences (D-in-D) setting that reduces economic policy uncer-

tainty for exposed healthcare firms. Second, we use U.S. presidential elections as a quasi-

experimental setting that increases economic policy uncertainty. We motivate these settings

and discuss them in detail in Section 3.5.

15Non-guiding firms rarely change their guidance practices, as noted in Balakrishnan et al. (2014, SectionIII.D), which could reduce the power of our tests and bias against finding results.

16We recognize that our quantitative metric of disclosure, while based on Balakrishnan et al. (2014), pre-cludes us from doing textual analyses that might measure the extent to which the disclosures explicitly referto economic policy uncertainty. However, in theory, managers’ disclosure response need not necessarily beincreased firm disclosure about economic policy uncertainty, but disclosure of any information that decreasesfirm-level uncertainty.

11

Page 13: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

3 Empirical Results

3.1 Univariate Statistics

During our sample period, the EPU index ranges from a low of 0.3821 during December,

2012, to a high of 2.5392 during August, 2011. As Figure 1 shows, other periods of rela-

tively high economic policy uncertainty include national election cycles. Table 1, Panel A

provides the distributions of our aggregate liquidity proxies, and Table 2, Panel A provides

the distributions of our firm-level liquidity proxies, which appear to be consistent with prior

research (Holden and Jacobsen, 2014). Table 1, Panel B and Table 2, Panel B indicate that,

as expected, percent quoted spreads and Amihud illiquidity are positively correlated. We

also find positive correlations between the EPU index and our liquidity proxies, providing

preliminary evidence that increased economic policy uncertainty might be associated with

decreased liquidity (recall that our stock liquidity proxies are inversely related to the level

of liquidity). Table 2, Panel C shows that our firm-level sample includes 6,897 firms, whose

median market value is about $325.2 million. About 29% of firms have foreign income. Table

2, Panel D indicates that market value is correlated with several of the firm-level variables,

underscoring the importance of using firm-year-fixed effects, which control for size and other

firm-specific factors that might vary by year.

3.2 EPU Index and Stock Liquidity

We study the association between the EPU index and stock liquidity using fixed-effect

regressions with clustered standard errors.17 We first study this association at the monthly

level using both aggregate market and firm-level measures of liquidity. For our aggregate

analyses, we weight both of our liquidity proxies by market value at the beginning of the

17For the aggregate regressions, we use time-fixed effects and cluster standard errors robustly or by timeas appropriate. For firm-level regressions, we use firm-time-fixed effects and cluster two way by firm andtime. Such clustering allows for error terms to be correlated both within a firm and across all firms in agiven period of time. The tables contain the exact time-period definitions for fixed effects and clustering.

12

Page 14: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

observation month. Our use of value weights follows Chordia et al. (2005), though our results

hold for equal weights as well. We run our monthly tests with year-fixed-effect regressions to

eliminate factors that might affect liquidity across time, including technological advances in

trading and market growth and attrition. Monthly tests mitigate concerns that the findings

of daily tests are driven by spurious short-term correlations in the data. In addition, the

Dickey-Fuller test rejects the null hypothesis of a unit root in all of our aggregate market

variables (at both the daily and monthly intervals), suggesting that our fixed-effect approach

with clustered standard errors is an appropriate specification.

In addition, since the regressions that follow all include at least year-fixed effects, we

eliminate virtually all time trends in the data. Accordingly, we find Durbin-Watson test

statistics of over two for our fixed-effect regressions, which suggests that Newey-West stan-

dard errors are inappropriate for our analysis. Figure 1 also shows graphically that there

is no apparent time trend in the EPU index.18 Finally, note that our monthly and daily

windows are shorter than those of Balakrishnan et al. (2014), who examine the impact of

disclosure in the current quarter on liquidity in the next quarter. They are interested in the

long-run impact of permanent one-time events such as brokerage closures, whereas Figure 1

shows that the EPU index has considerable time-series variation; it is therefore unlikely that

today’s EPU index will have a long-run liquidity impact.

In Table 3, we regress monthly aggregate market averages of the value-weighted liquidity

proxies on the contemporaneous EPU index average for the same month. Table 3, Columns

1 and 2 show that the coefficient on the EPU index is positive and significant for both value-

weighted quoted spreads and value-weighted Amihud illiquidity (1% level). A one standard

deviation increase in the monthly EPU index is associated with a 1.0% and 1.9% increase

in value-weighted monthly spreads and Amihud illiquidity, respectively.19 These findings

obtain after we control for year-fixed effects and the equity uncertainty (EU) index, which

18Nonetheless, we find qualitatively similar results using Newey-West standard errors and Prais-Winstenregressions (untabulated).

19In these computations, we assume that for small x, x = ln(1 + x).

13

Page 15: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

is significantly positive for spreads but insignificant for Amihud illiquidity. We next perform

the contemporaneous monthly analysis at the firm level with firm-year-fixed effects.20 Table

3, Columns 3 and 4 show that the EPU index is positive and significant for both quoted

spreads and Amihud illiquidity. A one standard deviation increase in the monthly EPU

index is associated with a 3.4% and 2.5% increase in firm-level monthly spreads and Amihud

illiquidity, respectively. The EU index is positive and marginally significant for both quoted

spreads and Amihud illiquidity, but at smaller economic magnitudes relative to the EPU

index.21 We also find qualitatively similar results with no fixed effects, firm-fixed effects,

and firm-year-month-fixed effects. These findings suggest that increased economic policy

uncertainty decreases liquidity.

In Table 4, we use daily data of the EPU index and liquidity. Table 4, Columns 1 and

4 show that the coefficient on the contemporaneous EPU index is positive and significant

for both value-weighted quoted spreads and value-weighted Amihud illiquidity, respectively,

after we control for year-fixed effects and the EU index. A one standard deviation increase in

the daily EPU index is associated with a 0.45% and 0.42% increase in daily value-weighted

quoted spreads and Amihud illiquidity (1% level). At the daily firm level, Table 4, Columns

7 and 10 show that the coefficient on the EPU index is positive and significant for quoted

spreads and Amihud illiquidity, after we control for firm-year-fixed effects and the EU index.

A one standard deviation increase in the daily EPU index is associated with a 2.69% and

1.56% increase in daily quoted spreads and Amihud illiquidity (1% level). By comparison,

Chordia et al. (2001, p. 509) find the average daily change in their spread variables is on

the order of two percent. The EU index is also positive and significant in Columns 7 and

10, but at smaller economic magnitudes relative to the EPU index. These findings suggest

that economic policy uncertainty has a stronger economic effect on liquidity than general

equity market uncertainty, which is consistent with the conclusions of Baker et al. (2016),

20Chordia et al. (2014, p. 45) suggest supplementing portfolio tests with individual stock tests to avoidsensitivity to portfolio grouping procedures.

21We use the EPU and EU indices in their level forms, but all these findings are qualitatively similar whenwe log transform the indices.

14

Page 16: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

who argue that economic policy uncertainty is an important uncertainty to investors in the

market. It is also unlikely that the EPU index is significantly influenced by any individual

firm’s liquidity, so we have some assurance in attributing causality from the EPU index to

individual firm liquidity.

One advantage of our daily data is that we can study how long it takes economic policy

uncertainty to enter into the news (and thus the EPU index), as well as how long it takes

investors to process this information. In Table 4, Columns 2–3 and 5–6, we include five-day

lags and leads of the EPU index. Table 1, Panel A indicates that the daily autocorrelation

coefficient is 0.34 with year-fixed effects, so multicollinearity should not be a severe problem.

The two main results of note are that (1) all the significant EPU index coefficients are

positive, implying that increased economic policy uncertainty decreases liquidity, and (2) the

contemporaneous EPU index is largely significant in the firm-level regressions. Significant

positive lags suggest that asynchronous trading may cause news to be reflected later in

liquidity (Campbell et al., 1996, p. 84).22 Significant positive leads suggest that the EPU

index could be capturing news with some delay relative to investors. The contemporaneous

EPU index regressor is often insignificant in the aggregate regressions, suggesting that its

significance by itself in Columns 1, 4, 7, and 10 indicates that it represents economic policy

uncertainty not just on the day, but also a few days before and after (but it is often significant

in the firm-level regressions). In any event, we are not interested in the time-sensitive

autocorrelation structure, and interpreting the current day EPU index as an amalgamation

of a few days’ lags and leads does not impair our inferences.23

In the above analysis and throughout most of the analysis that follows, we use two-

way clustered errors by firm and an appropriate time dimension. However, since we cannot

directly identify the underlying covariance structure of the error terms, we have ensured

that all of our results obtain with alternative clustering methods, including clustering by

22Note that the EPU index spans from 1985 to current day, so we can include EPU index leads and lagswithout losing any observations.

23Recall that Durbin-Watson tests indicate no presence of autocorrelation in the regressions, suggestingthat EPU index autocorrelation is not driving significance.

15

Page 17: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

day, clustering by firm-year, and two-way clustering by firm and year. Also, the fixed

effects used above control for a number of alternative explanations, including persistent firm-

specific factors (such as industry membership) and time-varying firm-specific factors (such

as size and risk) that might affect liquidity. For example, our within-firm-year analyses

control for across-year variation in liquidity that might be due to time-varying firm-specific

or macroeconomic factors (e.g., Chordia et al., 2000). However, one limitation of these

regression specifications is that they restrict the coefficient on the EPU index to be the same

for all firms, a restriction we now relax by allowing the coefficient on the EPU index to change

with several firm-level factors. We add all the EPU index interaction effects at once and also

include the EPU and EU indices as main effects. We do not include the interacting factors

as main effects because they are firm-invariant and thus subsumed by the firm-year-fixed

effects.

We first check whether the variation in firm-specific exposure to economic policy uncer-

tainty changes the relation between economic policy uncertainty and liquidity. To do this,

we compute an EPU index-stock returns sensitivity beta for each firm. As noted in Section

2, to ensure that this beta does not proxy for risk, we use a specification that controls for

the risk factors identified in Fama and French (1993). We use the absolute value of the beta

coefficient because we do not have a clear theoretical expectation about whether a given firm

will be negatively or positively affected by economic policy uncertainty over time.24 By con-

struction, a higher absolute value of the policy beta suggests that a firm is more sensitive to

economic policy uncertainty. Table 5 indeed indicates that spreads and Amihud illiquidity

both increase more in the cross-section for firms with higher policy betas (1% level).

Our second cross-sectional effect relates to firm size. The asset pricing literature has long

found that larger firms, which potentially operate in a richer information environment, are

easier to value (e.g., Fama and French, 1995). This implies that the magnitude of the negative

relation between the EPU index and liquidity might decrease in firm size. Accordingly, in

24Our use of absolute values is similar to the research design of Addoum and Kumar (2016, p. 3473), whoexamine return sensitivity to political uncertainty.

16

Page 18: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 5, we interact the EPU index with firm size, as proxied for by the log of market value

of equity, and find a significant negative coefficient on the interaction term for spreads and

Amihud illiquidity. This implies that liquidity declines less in larger firms for a given increase

in the EPU index (1% level). Firm size thus appears to partly mitigate the adverse selection

problems driven by economic policy uncertainty.

Our third cross-sectional effect is whether international exposure reduces a firm’s expo-

sure to U.S. economic policy uncertainty, which is what the EPU index represents. Firms

with international exposure are likely affected by the policy forces of all the countries in

which they operate. To the extent that this diversifies a firm’s exposure to U.S. economic

policy uncertainty, these firms might experience an attenuated relation between the EPU in-

dex and liquidity (e.g., Boutchkova et al., 2012; Desai et al., 2008). We use two measures to

proxy for international exposure: (1) an indicator variable for whether a firm had revenue in

a foreign income over our sample period, and (2) the average number of foreign trade words

in a firm’s 10-Ks over our sample period (using the foreign trade dictionary defined in Sec-

tion 2). Table 5 shows that the interaction effect of the EPU index and the foreign income

indicator is significantly negative for Amihud illiquidity, while the interaction effect with

10-K foreign trade words is uniformly negatively significant. A firm’s international exposure

thus appears to mitigate the effect of U.S. economic policy uncertainty on its liquidity.

Our fourth set of cross-sectional effects focus on lobbying expenditures and economic

policy uncertainty related disclosures in the 10-K (labeled EPU Words in the tables). Prior

literature is mixed on whether lobbying would actually mitigate economic policy uncertainty

or simply proxy for a firm’s exposure to it (e.g., Adelino and Dinc, 2014; Christensen et al.,

2017, p. 92). For example, firms may recognize their increased exposure to economic pol-

icy uncertainty but hire ineffective lobbyists. Economic policy uncertainty related 10-K

disclosures could likewise mitigate or proxy for economic policy uncertainty exposure. For

example, a 10-K disclosure about economic policy uncertainty could provide information to

investors about how economic policy uncertainty will impact the firm, or it could simply

17

Page 19: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

describe a firm’s exposure to economic policy uncertainty about which investors are already

informed. Thus, both of these measures could yield results in either direction. To proxy for

lobbying, we use a firm’s annual lobbying dollars averaged over our sample period. We also

compute the average number of economic policy uncertainty related words in a firm’s 10-Ks

over our sample period (see Section 2 for these words). Table 5 shows that the interaction

of the EPU index and lobbying is significantly negative for spreads and Amihud illiquidity,

and the interaction of the EPU index and 10-K economic policy uncertainty words is signifi-

cantly positive for spreads and Amihud illiquidity. Lobbying thus appears to partly mitigate

the adverse effect of economic policy uncertainty on liquidity, whereas 10-K economic policy

uncertainty words appear to proxy for the firm’s exposure to economic policy uncertainty.

3.3 EPU Index and Unexpected Earnings

To the extent that increased economic policy uncertainty decreases liquidity, this could

cause some investors to trade less aggressively on information or withdraw from the market

altogether, which would result in fewer traders (or less trading) in the market for important

corporate information events such as earnings disclosures (e.g., Chordia et al., 2008; Kyle,

1985). We therefore test whether economic policy uncertainty affects the stock price response

to unexpected earnings for firms with high liquidity risk exposure. For a given firm-quarter,

we follow Lys and Sohn (1990) and measure unexpected earnings using actual earnings minus

the analyst consensus mean earnings forecast at day −1 scaled by stock price at day −1,

where day 0 is the quarterly earnings announcement date. Our returns measure is [−1, +1

day] abnormal returns, computed as firm returns minus contemporaneous value-weighted

market returns. Table 6, Column 1 shows that, consistent with prior research, unexpected

earnings is significantly positively associated with [−1, +1 day] abnormal returns. Table 6,

Column 2 further shows that the interaction of unexpected earnings and the EPU index is

significantly negatively associated with [−1, +1 day] abnormal returns, after we control for

firm-year-fixed effects and the EU index. This result implies that increased economic policy

18

Page 20: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

uncertainty lowers the stock price response to and information content of earnings news (see

also footnote 5).

However, Table 6, Columns 1 and 2 do not indicate whether economic policy uncertainty

impacts the stock price reaction to unexpected earnings through liquidity. To estimate this

effect, we include a firm’s exposure to expected liquidity risk, as proxied for by βLi from

Section 3 of Pastor and Stambaugh (2003).25 Our focus on the firm’s exposure to liquidity

risk as opposed to its actual liquidity follows the research design in Kelly and Ljungqvist

(2012, Section 3.4).26 Since a firm’s exposure to expected liquidity risk is increasing in βLi ,

we set an indicator variable equal to 1 if a firm is in the top quintile of βLi and interact this

with the EPU index and unexpected earnings.27 We also include similar interaction terms

for a firm’s log of market value of equity and book-to-market ratio.

In Table 6, Column 3, we find a negative coefficient on the three-way interaction term

for the EPU index, unexpected earnings, and the βLi quintile indicator (1% level), which

suggests that for the same level of earnings surprise, investors of firms with high liquidity

exposure react less during periods of high economic policy uncertainty. Economic policy

uncertainty thus appears to have a liquidity channel for earnings. As expected, we also

find that the three-way interaction term with log of market value of equity is positive and

significant, which is consistent with there being fewer pricing frictions for larger firms. The

three-way interaction term with the book-to-market ratio is positive and significant, which

is consistent with there being fewer pricing frictions in relatively mature firms (Fama and

French, 1993).28

The triple-interaction results in Table 6, Column 3 also obtain in a sample that requires

25The exact equation for βLi is in Section 2.

26We want a measure of the firm’s steady-state return exposure to liquidity risk, which a firm’s liquidityby itself does not capture because it changes endogenously during earnings announcements (Sadka, 2011).

27We follow much of the literature by using βLi in a quantile as opposed to a raw form (e.g., Pastor and

Stambaugh, 2003). We also check and find that βLi in our sample is negatively correlated with the betas for

HML and MKT, as in Pastor and Stambaugh (2003, Table 3, Panel B, discussed on p. 668). However, ourcorrelation with the SMB beta is positive, perhaps because we use a later sample than Pastor and Stambaugh(2003).

28Note that we do not have two-way interactions for these risk factors; we assume that the firm-year-fixedeffects are adequate.

19

Page 21: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

each firm to have at least five years of monthly returns data in CRSP. This requirement

further ensures that each firm’s βLi is precisely estimated in Eq. (4) of Section 2. If this indeed

occurs, we should find a stronger triple-interaction effect. As expected, in this untabulated

sample we find that the coefficient on the three-way interaction term for the EPU index,

unexpected earnings, and the βLi quintile indicator increases in magnitude by about 21% (-

0.0635 to -0.0767 in levels; 1% level). This is despite the fact that the five-year requirement

decreases the sample by about 18%. This finding suggests that the liquidity channel through

economic policy uncertainty is strong in our setting.

3.4 EPU Index and Voluntary Disclosure

Following Balakrishnan et al. (2014), who argue that managers on average have an incen-

tive to shape liquidity and therefore respond to exogenous liquidity reductions by increasing

voluntary disclosures, we next link economic policy uncertainty to guidance disclosures and

guidance disclosures to liquidity.29

In Table 7, Column 1, we regress current day guidance disclosures on the average EPU

and EU indices from the 30 days prior. Balakrishnan et al. (2014, Section III.D) argue

that changing disclosure policy is costly, and therefore managers may look to longer-term

past EPU index trends rather than daily EPU index trends. To ensure that the market-

level regressions are consistent with and comparable to our liquidity regressions, we weight

each guidance disclosure by the market-value weight of the firm before aggregating all the

disclosures (similar to our liquidity measures). We find that a one standard deviation increase

in the daily EPU index is associated with a 15.87% increase in value-weighted guidance

disclosures, after controlling for year-fixed effects (1% level). In equal-weighted levels, this

translates to about 26 additional daily guidance disclosures. The EU index is insignificantly

associated with guidance disclosures.30 Following Balakrishnan et al. (2014, Table 5), in

29Balakrishnan et al. (2014, p. 2254) note that managers do not respond to liquidity drops due to marketmicrostructure shocks such as market-maker closures. We thus view economic policy uncertainty shocks asnon-market microstructure shocks.

30We also find similar results with equal-weighted guidance disclosures (untabulated).

20

Page 22: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 7, Column 2, we validate this finding using a Poisson count model with year-fixed

effects and find that guidance frequency continues to be positively associated with the EPU

index.

The next challenge is linking management guidance to liquidity. This can be problematic

because management may issue guidance to shore up low liquidity. However, as noted above,

Balakrishnan et al. (2014, Section III.D) argue that managers are more likely to respond to

longer-term trends in liquidity, suggesting that at the daily level, liquidity responds to guid-

ance as opposed to the other way around. In fact, if management does respond in a day,

it would result in a positive association between daily illiquidity and disclosure, potentially

canceling the liquidity improvement effect of disclosure (Balakrishnan et al., 2014, p. 2271).

Indeed, Balakrishnan et al. (2014, p. 2266) find a weak “naive” relationship between liq-

uidity and disclosure over both the contemporaneous and the lagging quarter, while Healy

(2015) cites several studies that find a similar positive relation between guidance and mea-

sures of uncertainty (which could reflect both overall investor uncertainty and information

asymmetry among investors). Healy (2015) further notes that guidance is often issued along

with earnings announcements, and some studies show that liquidity is lower on these days

(e.g., Krinsky and Lee, 1996). We therefore show below that our results are not sensitive to

controlling for earnings announcement days. This means that if we find a positive relation

between liquidity and guidance at the daily level, we can be reasonably assured that the

relation is from disclosure to liquidity and not the other way around.31

In Table 7, Columns 3 and 4, we estimate daily aggregate liquidity models by regressing

quoted spreads and the Amihud illiquidity measure on daily guidance disclosures and the

daily EPU index. Most days, firms do not issue guidance and the guidance variable is zero,

which suggests that much of the variation in the guidance variable is coming from guidance

versus non-guidance days. To compute the indirect effect of economic policy uncertainty

(through disclosure) on liquidity, we multiply the guidance coefficients in Columns 3 and 4

31Following the findings of Balakrishnan et al. (2014), we are assuming that managers who do not wish toshape liquidity only reduce the power of our tests and work against our finding a result.

21

Page 23: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

by the EPU index coefficient in Column 1. The resulting negative product of −0.0034 for

spreads (0.2383×−0.0141; 1% level) signifies that the indirect effect is present and significant

in our sample.32 For a one standard deviation increase in the EPU index, the indirect effect

decreases spreads by 0.22%, which amounts to 48.89% of the direct effect that the EPU

index has on increasing spreads. This result implies that the additional guidance disclosures

associated with increased economic policy uncertainty increase liquidity, reversing by about

half the adverse liquidity consequences of increased economic policy uncertainty. There is

also a negative indirect effect for Amihud illiquidity, but this effect is statistically insignificant

at the aggregate level (the direct effect is still significant). The presence of year-fixed effects

implies that these magnitudes are to be interpreted as within-year.

We next conduct the same analysis at the firm level using firm-year-fixed effects. In Table

7, Columns 5 and 6, we find that the EPU index is again positively associated with guidance

disclosures (1% level). In Table 7, Columns 7 and 8, the indirect effect of additional guidance

on spreads and Amihud illiquidity is significantly negative (1% level), and the direct effect of

the EPU index on spreads and Amihud illiquidity is significantly positive (1% level). These

results are qualitatively consistent with those at the aggregate market level in Columns 3 and

4. However, the indirect effect reverses the direct effect by only 1.2%, which is smaller than

before. One reason for the difference could be that the aggregate market results are market-

value weighted, which means that those results are driven by proportionally larger firms that

tend to provide more guidance (Anilowski et al., 2007, p. 45). By contrast, the individual

firm analysis weights firms equally.33 Second and related, since large firms disclose guidance

more often, we have many small firms with guidance frequencies of zero that now have equal

weight in the regressions. Such firms rarely change their guidance practices, as noted in

Balakrishnan et al. (2014, Section III.D), which could reduce the power of the individual

firm tests and bias against finding our results. Note that the presence of firm-year-fixed

32We use the delta method (or the linear Taylor expansion) to compute standard errors (Krull and MacK-innon, 2001; Sobel, 1987).

33Consistent with this, when we limit the individual firm analysis to firms in the top market-value quintileof our sample, the ratio of the indirect effect to the direct effect increases.

22

Page 24: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

effects implies that these magnitudes are to be interpreted as within-firm, within-year.34

We also find that our firm-level results in Table 7, Columns 5–8 obtain when we include

a firm-level indicator variable for days when firms announce earnings.35 This indicator is

not significantly correlated with the EPU index regressor (the correlation is 0.02), which is

to be expected given that there is no reason for economic policy uncertainty to covary with

earnings announcement dates. Across Columns 5–8, this indicator is positive and significant,

consistent with studies that show that liquidity is lower on earnings announcement days

(e.g., Krinsky and Lee, 1996), and with studies that find that managers bundle guidance with

earnings announcements (e.g., Billings et al., 2015; Healy, 2015). However, the announcement

indicator does not quantitatively change the EPU index coefficient in Columns 5 and 6 or

the guidance and EPU index coefficients in Columns 7 and 8, which further affirms that the

relation we are capturing above is from disclosure to liquidity.36

Management of firms exposed to economic policy uncertainty might invest in lobbying in

part to gain access to additional information about pending policy (e.g., Christensen et al.,

2017; Wellman, 2017). Such managers may be more likely to make disclosures. To check for

such cross-sectional variation in disclosure response, we also run the regression in Table 7,

Column 5 with all the EPU index interaction terms from Table 5, except that we interact the

firm-level terms with the EPU index averaged over t(−30, 0). We find positive significance

for the policy beta and market-value interaction terms, which suggests that managers of

larger firms, who are more likely to provide guidance to begin with (Anilowski et al., 2007,

p. 45), and firms more exposed to economic policy uncertainty disclose more. However, we

do not find significance for the other interaction terms, including the log of lobbying dollars,

which suggests that management’s lobbying efforts (as we measure them) have no effect on

34In papers concurrently released with this study, Bird et al. (2017) and Boone et al. (2017) examinemanagement’s disclosure behavior during political elections for firms in battleground states. But theirinterest is political uncertainty, not economic policy uncertainty.

35We use an indicator instead of a continuous variable because most days are non-announcement days.36Management disclosures could also occur as a response to investors’ information-acquisition activities

as a result of economic policy uncertainty. We cannot directly measure these activities except throughfirm-year-fixed effects and the EPU index.

23

Page 25: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

their disclosure activities.

3.5 Additional Tests without the EPU Index

All our tests thus far have used the Baker et al. (2016) EPU index. This index is of high

quality, is widely used, and is available on a continuous basis, which allows us to perform

tests such as the stock price response to earnings in Table 6. However, it would be useful

to document our main results in other settings to ensure that our main results generalize.

We first exploit a recent and important setting that increases economic policy uncertainty

exposure for only a subset of firms. Specifically, we focus on the 2009–2010 Congressional

healthcare debates that occurred during the period leading up to the enactment of the

Affordable Care Act (ACA). This setting is unique in that, as we describe below, it potentially

reduces economic policy uncertainty for healthcare firms (our treatment sample), but not

for other types of firms (our control sample).37

The brief history that follows provides background on this setting. Discussions around

comprehensive healthcare reform emerged in great number over the course of the 2008 presi-

dential campaign, as virtually all of the Democratic platforms espoused significant healthcare

reform (Clinton, 2007; Edwards, 2007; Obama, 2007). Following Barack Obama’s inaugura-

tion in January, 2009, what began as his signature campaign promise became the focus of his

administration. Healthcare reform thus dominated the 2009 and early 2010 Congressional

meeting schedule (see Appendix B for the full schedule of these meetings). These meetings

culminated in the ACA, a 2,500-page bill that was signed into law on March 30, 2010.38 The

37To the extent that these debates increase economic policy uncertainty, this will work against our findinga result.

38The ACA was technically signed into law on March 23, 2010, but the Health Care and EducationReconciliation Act of 2010, which was a pre-planned amendment to the ACA, was signed into law on March30, 2010. This completed the ACA legislation process, and we therefore use the date of March 30, 2010. Wehand collect Congressional meeting dates from two sources. First, we review the legislative calendars fromCongress.gov pertaining to (1) The Affordable Health Choices Act (an early version of the ACA), (2) ThePatient Protection and Affordable Care Act (the bill that was ultimately passed), and (3) The Health Careand Education Reconciliation Act of 2010 (the bill that amended the ACA a week later). Second, we useSenate.gov and House.gov to obtain dates for healthcare hearings held prior to the introduction of the HouseTri-Committee Draft Proposal on June 23, 2009.

24

Page 26: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

ACA was the product of significant bargaining within and across party lines during formal

hearings and informal roundtable discussions with corporate interests, consumer groups, and

academic experts (Daschle and Nather, 2010).

One of the more fiercely contested issues throughout the healthcare legislative process was

the so-called “public option” for health insurance, which would allow Americans to select

a government-run healthcare plan. Supporters of the public option argued that it would

lower administrative costs, increase quality of care, and improve access to care (Congress,

2009). With strong support from The White House, House Speaker Nancy Pelosi pushed

to include the public option in the House bill that began circulating in June, 2009 (Bacon

and Kornblut, 2009). But by early July, 2009, as House Democrats were finalizing a version

of the bill, a faction of Democrats (the “Blue Dogs”) voiced concerns over including the

public option (Daschle and Nather, 2010). Meanwhile, Conservatives argued that a public

option would compromise the long-run viability of the private insurance market (Eckerly,

2009). Nonetheless, in the summer of 2009, House committees passed a bill that included

the public option, inciting a contentious debate among Senate Democrats. In October,

2009, Senator Joseph Lieberman, who normally caucused with the Democrats, threatened

to join a Republican filibuster to block any bill that contained a public option (Bash, 2009).

Consequently, the ACA does not include a public option.

The legislative debates surrounding healthcare reform were heated. But what one should

not overlook is that these debates clarified the parameters of healthcare reform and provided

a continuous flow of policy news to the market (e.g., Daschle and Nather, 2010). In other

words, the healthcare debates transformed the disparate proposals and campaign promises

into a fully defined piece of legislation whose design was influenced by healthcare corpora-

tions themselves and their corporate interest groups. As a result, we conjecture that the

Congressional healthcare meetings in 2009 and 2010 reduced economic policy uncertainty in

the healthcare industry.

An important feature of this setting is that we can conduct our analysis in a D-in-D

25

Page 27: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

manner: healthcare firms represent our treatment sample, and non-healthcare firms represent

our control sample. Accordingly, we conduct our analysis over the period of January 1, 2008

to March 30, 2010, and we set an ACA Hearing Period indicator equal to 1 from January

1, 2009 to March 30, 2010, and 0 otherwise. As Appendix B notes, these dates align with

the Congressional healthcare meetings and the enactment of the ACA. Our control period

is January 1, 2008 to December 31, 2008 (the healthcare meetings start in January, 2009);

we implement alternative control periods below. Following Christensen et al. (2017), we use

the following SIC codes to construct an indicator variable for healthcare firms: 2830, 2831,

2833–2836, 6300, 6310–6331, 6350, 6351, 6360, 6361, 6370–6379, 6390–6399, 6400–6411,

and 8000–8099. These SIC codes represent healthcare service companies, pharmaceutical

companies, and insurance companies. As before, we need not include the healthcare firm

indicator as a main effect in our regressions. This variable is constant within each firm,

which means that it is subsumed by the firm-year-fixed effects.

Table 8 shows that during the course of the 2009–2010 Congressional healthcare debates

from January 1, 2009 to March 30, 2010, liquidity decreases significantly for non-healthcare

firms relative to the control period of 2008. The coefficient on the ACA Hearing Period main

effect indicates that, for the control firms (i.e., the non-healthcare firms), quoted spreads in-

crease by 2.5% (5% level) and Amihud illiquidity increases by 4.2% (1% level). One potential

explanation for this is that the healthcare debates coincide with the financial crisis and a

recession. However, when we sum the ACA Hearing Period coefficient and the coefficient on

the interaction term of ACA Hearing Period and Healthcare Firm, we find that, for health-

care firms, spreads decrease by 4.7% and Amihud illiquidity decreases by 2.7% (1% level for

both) during the healthcare debate period.39 We also find qualitatively similar results using

data at monthly intervals. This D-in-D evidence suggests that a reduction in economic pol-

icy uncertainty increases stock liquidity. Importantly, our research design controls for other

39The coefficient for the ACA Hearing Period indicator can be interpreted in isolation only when the health-care firm indicator equals zero (i.e., this coefficient interpreted in isolation applies only to non-healthcarefirms). The result for healthcare firms is the sum of the ACA Hearing Period coefficient and the coefficientfor the interaction term, which is significant at the 1% level.

26

Page 28: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

macroeconomic phenomena that uniformly affect the liquidity of all firms, and we continue

to control for firm-fixed effects, which eliminate persistent firm-specific liquidity factors.

We also run alternative specifications for this analysis. First, we maintain the same ACA

Hearing Period of January 1, 2009 to March 30, 2010, but we tighten the pre period to smaller

windows ranging from three to nine months. Second, we move back the start date of the

ACA Hearing Indicator to June 23, 2009, the date when healthcare reform officially enters

Congress’s agenda. We find qualitatively similar results in both of these tests. In addition,

we find stronger results when we limit our definition of healthcare firms to health insurance

companies, for whom the healthcare debates likely reduce economic policy uncertainty the

most (SIC codes 6300, 6310–6329, 6370–6379, 6390–6399, and 6400–6411). These analyses

suggest that our selection of control windows and our specific definition of healthcare firms

are not driving our results.

We next focus on the timing of presidential elections. Several theories of election cycles

suggest that increased economic policy uncertainty leading up to U.S. presidential elections

stems from a variety of forces, including candidates’ preferences for inflation, labor policy,

trade, taxes, and government spending (e.g., Alesina, 1987, 1988). Furthermore, predicting

policy outcomes in presidential elections involves incorporating not only the probability that

a particular candidate will win, but also the probability that each piece of that candidate’s

policy agenda will actually be implemented. This issue is further compounded by potential

conflicts that the winner might encounter with administrative officials, judges, and members

of the House and Senate, some of whom will be newly elected as well (Brogaard and Detzel,

2015; Fowler, 2006; Goodell and Vahamaa, 2013; Jens, 2017). Accordingly, Baker et al.

(2016) note that the EPU index increases in the months leading up to presidential elections,

which means our previous EPU index analyses already test whether elections affect liquidity.

Nonetheless, we follow up with tests that explicitly use the election setting.

We define as presidential election periods the dates of July 1, 2004–November 2, 2004;

July 1, 2008–November 4, 2008; and July 1, 2012–November 6, 2012. We start each election

27

Page 29: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

period at July 1 because July is the month in which the Democratic and Republican parties

hold their national conventions; the ending November date for each election period represents

election day. To the extent that economic policy uncertainty emerges before July 1 of election

years or persists after election days, this would work against our finding a result (i.e., it might

cause liquidity to decline during the control dates). To appropriately control for time trends

in liquidity, we require that each election period have at least six months of data before and

after the election period. This precludes us from including the 2016 election, as we do not

have data for 2017.

In our first analysis, we regress liquidity on an indicator variable that equals 1 during

the dates of the election periods defined above, and 0 otherwise. We include firm-year-fixed

effects and use all non-election dates from 2003–2015 as our control dates. We exclude

observations from 2016 to mitigate any intervening effect of the 2016 election. Table 9 indi-

cates that our election periods are indeed strongly associated with decreased stock liquidity:

spreads increase by 2.6% and Amihud illiquidity increases by 2.3% (1% level). We also find

qualitatively similar results using data at monthly intervals.40

We then run separate regressions of liquidity for each election, using the same election-

period indicator defined above and using as control dates the non-election-period dates during

the election year, the one year before the election, and the one year after the election. For

example, for the 2008 election we include the years 2007, 2008, and 2009, and we set the

election period indicator to 1 from July 1, 2008–November 4, 2008. In Table 9, Columns 5

and 6, we find that the 2008 election period has the strongest effect (based on coefficient

magnitudes) on liquidity among the three elections that we analyze. In particular, spreads

increase by 5.8% and Amihud illiquidity increases by 3.3% over this period (1% level)—results

that are several times larger than those for the 2004 and 2012 elections. One explanation is

that term limits guaranteed that there would be a new president in 2008, which at the time

40Like Brogaard and Detzel (2015), Jens (2017), and Pasquariello and Zafeiridou (2014), we argue thatelections are exogenous events that unambiguously increase economic policy uncertainty, so we do not includethe EPU or EU index in the election regressions.

28

Page 30: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

was significant because both candidates were promising substantial policy changes from the

existing regime (including healthcare reform). By contrast, in the 2004 and 2012 elections,

there was a reasonable chance that the incumbent president would win and maintain (at least

partly) the status quo. To address the concern that the financial crisis and the recession

might be driving our results, we re-run our 2008 election analysis using as a control period

only the first half of 2009, which is when both the crisis and recession are near their peaks

(e.g., Foucault et al., 2013).41 We continue to find comparably strong results for the 2008

election. Collectively, these analyses provide additional evidence that increased economic

policy uncertainty is driving our election results.

Lastly, we test whether increased economic policy uncertainty due to the October, 2013

U.S. government shutdown affects liquidity. During the shutdown, the U.S. government

closed the majority of its agencies and cancelled the release of nearly all its regularly sched-

uled economic disclosures. Standard and Poor’s predicted that the shutdown “shaved at

least 0.6% off of annualized fourth-quarter 2013 GDP growth.” Macroeconomic Advisers

predicted “that a two-week shutdown would directly trim about 0.3 percentage point from

fourth quarter growth, mainly by interrupting the flow of services produced by federal em-

ployees.” Goldman Sachs predicted “that the shutdown would reduce GDP growth by 0.14

percentage points per week, even after most furloughed Department of Defense employees

returned to work.” Mark Zandi of Moody’s noted that “The 16-day Federal shutdown . . . hit

to fourth quarter real GDP is estimated at half a percentage point of growth.” In addition,

Baker et al. (2016) find that the EPU index spikes upward during the shutdown. The above

uncertainty over the impact of the shutdown implies that it can be viewed as a shock that

increases economic policy uncertainty.

Although the government shutdown period was October 1 to October 16, 2013, Baker

et al. (2016) report that the mention of “government shutdown” in news articles spikes lead-

ing up to and especially during the shutdown, and persists for a couple of weeks thereafter.

41Also see https://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/GPO-FCIC/pdf/GPO-FCIC.pdf.

29

Page 31: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

We therefore define the shutdown period as September 15, 2013 to October 30, 2013 and

construct a government shutdown indicator variable accordingly.42 Since we cannot analyze

liquidity during the shutdown days without an appropriate benchmark, we run our analysis

from August 15, 2013 to November 30, 2013, which provides a one-month control period

both before and after the shutdown period.

We run regressions of daily firm-level spreads and Amihud illiquidity on our government

shutdown indicator over the period of August 15, 2013 to November 30, 2013 with firm-

fixed effects. We find that the shutdown period is insignificantly negatively associated with

spreads and Amihud illiquidity. Our conclusions are similar if we limit the shutdown period

to October 1 to October 16, 2013, and if we expand the control period by a month or two in

both directions. These results imply that the shutdown either does not significantly affect

liquidity (relative to the control period), or our tests for this short period lack statistical

power.

4 Conclusion

Economic policy uncertainty is known to affect equity price levels and volatility (Baker

et al., 2016). However, volatility changes do not imply that information asymmetry among

investors has changed. For example, even in the CAPM setting that has no information asym-

metry among investors, price volatility can change if economic policy uncertainty changes the

covariance matrix of the firms’ payoffs. Furthermore, theory alone cannot predict whether

economic policy uncertainty increases some privately informed investors’ advantage over oth-

ers, or whether it is a common noise factor that levels the information playing field. This

study therefore attempts to understand empirically how economic policy uncertainty affects

information asymmetry among investors. Specifically, we show that increased economic pol-

icy uncertainty is associated with increases in firms’ bid-ask spreads and Amihud illiquidity,

42To the extent that economic policy uncertainty due to the shutdown does not fully materialize duringthe time leading up to and following the shutdown, this would work against our finding a result.

30

Page 32: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

with decreases to investors’ reactions to earnings in firms exposed to liquidity risk, and with

increases in management disclosures that partly reverse the liquidity drops. Collectively,

these findings suggest that economic policy uncertainty exacerbates information asymmetry

among investors.

Our study focuses exclusively on the stock market, but research has documented that

information asymmetry and liquidity in the stock market and the bond market are interlinked

(Chordia et al., 2005; Hu et al., 2013). Pasquariello and Vega (2009) further show how

public macroeconomic disclosures impact bond liquidity when investors have information

asymmetry. Future studies can therefore examine the effect of economic policy uncertainty

on stock market to bond market linkages.

31

Page 33: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

References

Addoum, J. M., Kumar, A., 2016. Political Sentiment and Predictable Returns. The Review

of Financial Studies 29, 3471–3518.

Adelino, M., Dinc, I. S., 2014. Corporate distress and lobbying: Evidence from the Stimulus

Act. Journal of Financial Economics 114, 256–272.

Alesina, A., 1987. Macroeconomic policy in a two-party system as a repeated game. The

Quarterly Journal of Economics 102, 651–678.

Alesina, A., 1988. Macroeconomics and politics. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 3, 13–52.

Amihud, Y., 2002. Illiquidity and stock returns: cross-section and time-series effects. Journal

of Financial Markets 5, 31–56.

Anilowski, C., Feng, M., Skinner, D. J., 2007. Does earnings guidance affect market returns?

The nature and information content of aggregate earnings guidance. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 44, 36–63.

Bacon, Jr., P., Kornblut, A., 2009. Public Option Called Essential; Democratic Lawmakers

Express Concern. The Washington Post.

Baker, S., Bloom, N., Davis, S., 2016. Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty. The Quar-

terly Journal of Economics 131, 1593–1636.

Balakrishnan, K., Billings, M., Kelly, B., Ljungqvist, A., 2014. Shaping Liquidity: On the

Causal Effects of Disclosure and Liquidity. The Journal of Finance 69, 2237–2278.

Bash, D., 2009. Public option would lead him to filibuster, key senator says. CNN Politics (on-

line) http://www.cnn.com/2009/POLITICS/10/27/health.care/index.html?iref=24hours.

Billings, M. B., Jennings, R., Lev, B., 2015. On guidance and volatility. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 60, 161–180.

Bird, A., Karolyi, S., Ruchti, T., 2017. Political uncertainty and corporate transparency.

Working Paper.

Bloom, N., Bond, S., Van Reenen, J., 2007. Uncertainty and Investment Dynamics. The

Review of Economic Studies 74, 391–415.

Boone, A., Kim, A., White, J., 2017. Political uncertainty and firm disclosure. Working

Paper.

32

Page 34: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Boutchkova, M., Doshi, H., Durnev, A., Molchanov, A., 2012. Precarious Politics and Return

Volatility. The Review of Financial Studies 25, 1111–1154.

Brogaard, J., Detzel, A., 2015. The Asset-Pricing Implications of Government Economic

Policy Uncertainty. Management Science 61, 3–18.

Campbell, J., Lo, A., MacKinlay, A. C., 1996. The Econometrics of Financial Markets.

Princeton University Press.

Chordia, T., Roll, R., Subrahmanyam, A., 2000. Commonality in liquidity. Journal of Fi-

nancial Economics 56, 3–28.

Chordia, T., Roll, R., Subrahmanyam, A., 2001. Market Liquidity and Trading Activity.

The Journal of Finance 56, 501–530.

Chordia, T., Roll, R., Subrahmanyam, A., 2008. Liquidity and market efficiency. Journal of

Financial Economics 87, 249–268.

Chordia, T., Sarkar, A., Subrahmanyam, A., 2005. An empirical analysis of stock and bond

market liquidity. The Review of Financial Studies 18, 85–129.

Chordia, T., Subrahmanyam, A., Tong, Q., 2014. Have capital market anomalies attenu-

ated in the recent era of high liquidity and trading activity? Journal of Accounting and

Economics 58, 41–58.

Christensen, D., Mikhail, M., Walther, B., Wellman, L., 2017. From K Street to Wall Street:

Political Connections and Stock Recommendations. The Accounting Review 92, 87–112.

Chuk, E., Matsumoto, D., Miller, G., 2013. Assessing methods of identifying management

forecasts: CIG vs. researcher collected. Journal of Accounting and Economics 55, 23–42.

Clinton, H., 2007. American Health Choices Plan: Quality, Affordable Health Care for Every

American, Hillary Clinton for President.

Congress, U. S., 2009. H.R.3200 - America’s Affordable Health Choices Act of 2009,

https://www.congress.gov/bill/111th-congress/house-bill/3200/text.

Daschle, T., Nather, D., 2010. Getting It Done: How Obama and Congress Finally Broke

the Stalemate to Make Way for Health Care Reform. Macmillan.

Desai, M., Foley, C. F., Hines, Jr., J., 2008. Capital structure with risky foreign investment.

Journal of Financial Economics 88, 534–553.

33

Page 35: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Drechsler, I., 2013. Uncertainty, Time-Varying Fear, and Asset Prices. The Journal of Fi-

nance 68, 1843–1889.

Eckerly, S., 2009. Letter Opposing America’s Affordable Health Choices Act of 2009

(H.R.3200), national Federation of Independent Business.

Edwards, J., 2007. Universal health care through shared responsibility, John Edwards for

President.

Fama, E., French, K., 1995. Size and Book-to-Market Factors in Earnings and Returns. The

Journal of Finance 50, 131–155.

Fama, E. F., French, K. R., 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds.

Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3–56.

Fong, K. Y. L., Holden, C. W., Trzcinka, C. A., 2017. What Are the Best Liquidity Proxies

for Global Research? Review of Finance 21, 1355–1401.

Foucault, T., Pagano, M., Roell, A., 2013. Market Liquidity: Theory, Evidence, and Policy.

Oxford University Press.

Fowler, J. H., 2006. Elections and Markets: The Effect of Partisanship, Policy Risk, and

Electoral Margins on the Economy. The Journal of Politics 68, 89–103.

Gao, M., Huang, J., 2016. Capitalizing on Capitol Hill: Informed trading by hedge fund

managers. Journal of Financial Economics 121, 521–545.

Goodell, J., Vahamaa, S., 2013. US presidential elections and implied volatility: The role of

political uncertainty. Journal of Banking & Finance 37, 1108–1117.

Guay, W., Samuels, D., Taylor, D., 2016. Guiding through the fog: Financial statement

complexity and voluntary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics 62, 234–269.

Gulen, H., Ion, M., 2016. Policy Uncertainty and Corporate Investment. Review of Financial

Studies 29, 523–564.

Hassan, T., Hollander, S., van Lent, L., Tahoun, A., 2017. Aggregate and idiosyncratic

political risk: Measurement and effects. Working Paper.

Healy, P. M., 2015. Discussion of “On Guidance and Volatility”. Journal of Accounting and

Economics 60, 136–140.

34

Page 36: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Hochberg, Y., Sapienza, P., Vissing-Jorgensen, A., 2009. A Lobbying Approach to Evaluating

the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002. Journal of Accounting Research 47, 519–583.

Holden, C., Jacobsen, S., 2014. Liquidity Measurement Problems in Fast, Competitive Mar-

kets: Expensive and Cheap Solutions. The Journal of Finance 69, 1747–1785.

Holden, C., Jacobsen, S., Subrahmanyam, A., 2013. The Empirical Analysis of Liquidity.

Foundations and Trends in Finance 8, 263–365.

Hu, G., Pan, J., Wang, J., 2013. Noise as Information for Illiquidity. The Journal of Finance

68, 2341–2382.

Jens, C. E., 2017. Political uncertainty and investment: Causal evidence from U.S. guber-

natorial elections. Journal of Financial Economics 124, 563–579.

Julio, B., Yook, Y., 2012. Political Uncertainty and Corporate Investment Cycles. The Jour-

nal of Finance 67, 45–83.

Kelly, B., Ljungqvist, A., 2012. Testing Asymmetric-Information Asset Pricing Models. The

Review of Financial Studies 25, 1366–1413.

Kelly, B., Pastor, L., Veronesi, P., 2016. The Price of Political Uncertainty: Theory and

Evidence from the Option Market. The Journal of Finance 71, 2417–2480.

Kim, O., Verrecchia, R., 1994. Market Liquidity and Volume around Earnings Announce-

ments. Journal of Accounting and Economics 17, 41–67.

Krinsky, I., Lee, J., 1996. Earnings announcements and the components of the bid-ask spread.

The Journal of Finance 51, 1523–1535.

Krull, J., MacKinnon, D., 2001. Multilevel Modeling of Individual and Group Level Mediated

Effects. Multivariate Behavioral Research 36, 249–277.

Kyle, A., 1985. Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading. Econometrica 53, 1315–1336.

Lang, M., Maffett, M., 2011. Transparency and liquidity uncertainty in crisis periods. Journal

of Accounting and Economics 52, 101–125.

Lys, T., Sohn, S., 1990. The Association Between Revisions of Financial Analysts’ Earnings

Forecasts and Security-Price Changes. Journal of Accounting and Economics 13, 341–363.

Obama, B., 2007. Barack Obama’s Plan for a Healthy America: Lowering health care costs

and ensuring affordable, high-quality health care for all, Barack Obama for President.

35

Page 37: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Pasquariello, P., Vega, C., 2009. The on-the-run liquidity phenomenon. Journal of Financial

Economics 92, 1–24.

Pasquariello, P., Zafeiridou, C., 2014. Political Uncertainty and Financial Market Quality.

Working Paper.

Pastor, L., Stambaugh, R., 2003. Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. Journal of

Political Economy 111, 642–685.

Pastor, L., Veronesi, P., 2012. Uncertainty about Government Policy and Stock Prices. The

Journal of Finance 67, 1219–1264.

Pastor, L., Veronesi, P., 2013. Political uncertainty and risk premia. Journal of Financial

Economics 110, 520–545.

Sadka, R., 2011. Liquidity risk and accounting information. Journal of Accounting and Eco-

nomics 52, 144–152.

Schoenfeld, J., 2017. The effect of voluntary disclosure on stock liquidity: New evidence from

index funds. Journal of Accounting and Economics 63, 51–74.

Sobel, M., 1987. Direct and Indirect Effects in Linear Structural Equation Models. Sociolog-

ical Methods & Research 16, 155–176.

Wellman, L., 2017. Mitigating political uncertainty. Review of Accounting Studies 22, 217–

250.

36

Page 38: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Appendix A: Variable Definitions for DTAQ Firms from 2003–2016Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day/month. CRP stands for the Center for Responsive Politics. For our monthly tests, we average the EPUand EU indices and the liquidity proxies over the observation month. For our daily tests, we use the daily values of the EPU and EU indices and the liquidity proxies. For theaggregate market tests, we value weight the liquidity proxies and each guidance disclosure based on firm market capitalization on the observation day or at the beginning of theobservation month (depending on daily/monthly tests). Each firm-level static is constant for each firm. See Section 2 for more details on all the variables.

Variable Definition Source

Uncertainty IndicesEconomic Policy Uncertainty (EPU) indext Daily index based on the number of news articles that contain the terms defined in Section 2 Baker et al. (2016)

Equity Uncertainty (EU) indext Daily index based on the number of news articles that contain the terms defined in Section 2 Baker et al. (2016)

Stock Liquidity Proxies Computed Daily

Log of Percent Quoted Spreadsit ln[1 +

[100× Askit−Bidit

(Askit+Bidit)/2

]], time weighted as in Holden and Jacobsen (2014) DTAQ

Log of Amihud Illiquidityit ln[1 +

[106 ×

∑ |Returnit|Dollar Trade V olumeit

]], as in Amihud (2002) CRSP

Disclosure ProxiesUnexpected Earningsit Actual earnings minus the analyst consensus mean earnings forecast at t = −1 scaled by

stock price at t = −1, where t = 0 is the quarterly earnings announcement date I/B/E/S

Log of Guidance Disclosuresit ln[1+ Frequency of guidance that incorporates capital expenditures, R&D, revenue,

or earnings], 0 in the absence of disclosure I/B/E/S

Firm-Level Statics|Policy Beta|i |βE

i | from the regression rit = β0i + βE

i EPUt + βMi MKTt + βS

i SMBt + βHi HMLt + εit, CRSP,

which we run monthly by firm over our sample period Baker et al. (2016)

Log of Market Valuei ln[1 +

[Price× Shares Outstanding

]], averaged over our sample period CRSP

Log of Foreign Incomei 1 if a firm had revenue in a foreign income over our sample period, 0 otherwise Compustat

Log of Trade Wordsi ln[1+The average number of foreign trade words in a firm’s 10-Ks over our sample period

using the foreign trade dictionary defined in Section 2]

SEC EDGAR

Log Lobbying Dollarsi ln[1+ A firm’s annual lobbying dollars averaged over our sample period

]CRP

Log of EPU Wordsi ln[1+The average number of economic policy uncertainty words in a firm’s 10-Ks over our

sample period using the policy uncertainty dictionary defined in Section 2]

SEC EDGAR

Liquidity Risk Exposure (βLi ) βL

i of the regression rit = β0i + βL

i Lt + βMi MKTt + βS

i SMBt + βHi HMLt + εit, CRSP,

which we run monthly by firm over our sample period Pastor and Stambaugh (2003)

37

Page 39: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Appendix B: Affordable Care Act (ACA) Meeting Schedule

Date Chamber Title

1/29/2009 Senate Crossing the Quality Chasm in Health Reform

2/23/2009 Senate Principles of Integrative Health: A Path to Health Care Reform

2/24/2009 Senate Addressing Underinsurance in National Health Reform

2/25/2009 Senate Scoring Health Care Reform: CBO’s Budget Options

3/10/2009 Senate The President’s Fiscal Year 2010 Health Care Proposals

3/11/2009 House Hearing on Health Reform in the 21st Century: Expanding Coverage, Improving Quality, Controlling Costs

3/12/2009 Senate Workforce Issues in Health Care Reform: Assessing the Present and Preparing for the Future

3/18/2009 Senate What is Health Care Quality and Who Decides?

3/24/2009 Senate Addressing Insurance Market Reform in National Health Reform

3/25/2009 Senate The Role of Long-Term Care in Health Reform

4/1/2009 House Health Reform in the 21st Century: Reforming the Healthcare Delivery System

4/22/2009 House Health Reform in the 21st Century: Insurance Market Reforms

4/28/2009 Senate Learning from the States: Individual State Experiences with Health Care Reform Coverage Initiatives in the Context of National Reform

4/29/2009 House Health Reform in the 21st Century: Employer Sponsored Insurance

5/6/2009 House Health Reform in the 21st Century: A Conversation with Health and Human Services Secretary Kathleen Sebelius

6/11/2009 Senate Healthcare Reform

6/23/2009 House The Tri-Committee Draft Proposal for Health Care Reform

6/23/2009 House Comprehensive Health Reform Discussion Draft (Day 1)

6/24/2009 House Health Reform in the 21st Century: Proposals to Reform the Health System

6/24/2009 House Comprehensive Health Reform Discussion Draft (Day 2)

6/25/2009 House Comprehensive Health Reform Discussion Draft (Day 3)

7/14/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

7/15/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

7/16/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

7/17/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

7/20/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

7/21/2009 House Markup of H.R. America’s Affordable Health Choices Act

7/31/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

9/17/2009 Senate Affordable Health Choices Act

9/17/2009 House Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

9/22/2009 Senate Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

9/23/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

9/24/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

9/25/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

9/29/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

9/30/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

(continued on next page)

38

Page 40: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Appendix B: Affordable Care Act (ACA) Meeting Schedule (continued)

Date Chamber Title

10/1/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

10/7/2009 House Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

10/8/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

10/8/2009 House Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

10/13/2009 Senate Continuation of the Open Executive Session to Consider an Original Bill Providing for Health Care Reform

10/13/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

10/14/2009 House America’s Affordable Healthcare Choices Act

11/19/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

11/20/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

11/21/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

11/30/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/1/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/2/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/3/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/4/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/5/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/6/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/7/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/8/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/9/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/10/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/13/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/14/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/15/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/16/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/17/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/19/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/20/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/21/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/22/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/23/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/24/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

12/29/2009 Senate Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

3/17/2010 House Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010

3/21/2010 House Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010

3/21/2010 House Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

(continued on next page)

39

Page 41: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Appendix B: Affordable Care Act (ACA) Meeting Schedule (continued)

Date Chamber Title

3/22/2010 House Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

3/23/2010 Senate Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010

3/23/2010 House Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

3/23/2010 President Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

3/24/2010 Senate Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010

3/25/2010 Senate Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010

3/30/2010 President Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010

40

Page 42: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Figure 1: The Baker et al. (2016) Economic Policy Index Plotted from 2003–2016

This figure charts the Baker et al. (2016) economic policy uncertainty (EPU) index averaged by year-month for display purposes (we use the dailyvalue in our regressions). The index is provided on a daily basis on http://www.policyuncertainty.com/. The source for news articles is Newsbank,which covers U.S.-based media ranging from large national media like USA Today to small local media. See Baker et al. (2016) for more details.

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

2003

01

2003

05

2003

09

2004

01

2004

05

2004

09

2005

01

2005

05

2005

09

2006

01

2006

05

2006

09

2007

01

2007

05

2007

09

2008

01

2008

05

2008

09

2009

01

2009

05

2009

09

2010

01

2010

05

2010

09

2011

01

2011

05

2011

09

2012

01

2012

05

2012

09

2013

01

2013

05

2013

09

2014

01

2014

05

2014

09

2015

01

2015

05

2015

09

2016

01

2016

05

2016

09

Eco

nom

ic P

olicy

Unce

rtain

ty I

ndex

Year-Month

41

Page 43: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 1: Variable Descriptive Statistics for Daily Aggregate Measures from 2003–2016Value-weighted (VW) measures are weighted by market capitalization at day t and logged for all analyses. The column AR(1) ρ w/ yr. F.E. inPanel A is the autocorrelation coefficient with year-fixed effects (i.e., within year). For display purposes, we multiply the value-weighted aggregatedisclosures by 100. Index t represents the observation day. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

Panel A: Descriptive Statistics of the Uncertainty Variables and the Aggregate Liquidity and Guidance Variables

AR(1) ρVariable N Mean σ P25 P50 P75 AR(1) ρ w/ yr. F.E.

EPU Indext 3,351 0.978 0.666 0.510 0.803 1.262 0.55 0.34EU Indext 3,351 0.469 0.679 0.121 0.259 0.542 0.45 0.40Log VW Quoted Spreadt 3,351 0.086 0.059 0.069 0.077 0.089 0.07 0.04Log VW Amihud Illiquidityt 3,351 0.025 0.043 0.009 0.013 0.026 0.18 0.12Log VW Aggregate Guidance Disclosurest × 100 3,351 1.258 0.834 0.564 1.188 1.863 0.49 0.38

Panel B: Correlation Matrix of the Uncertainty Variables and the Aggregate Liquidity and Guidance Variables

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

EPU Indext 1.00EU Indext 0.40∗∗∗ 1.00Log VW Quoted Spreadt 0.07∗∗∗ 0.11∗∗∗ 1.00Log VW Amihud Illiquidityt 0.21∗∗∗ 0.13∗∗∗ 0.18∗∗∗ 1.00Log VW Aggregate Guidance Disclosurest -0.02 -0.01 -0.23∗∗∗ -0.04∗ 1.00

42

Page 44: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 2: Variable Descriptive Statistics for Daily Firm-Level Measures from 2003–2016The number of observations in Panel A and in our regressions vary according to data availability in DTAQ and CRSP. We multiply |Policy Beta|i by1,000 for display purposes. Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day. All variables are defined in Appendix A.

Panel A: Descriptive Statistics of the Daily Economic Policy Uncertainty Index and Daily Firm-Level Liquidity Variables

Variable N Mean σ P25 P50 P75

Log Quoted Spreadit 15,127,411 0.455 0.520 0.115 0.243 0.579Log Amihud Illiquidityit 14,775,942 0.146 0.446 0.001 0.005 0.042Log Guidance Disclosuresit 15,129,038 0.013 0.129 0.000 0.000 0.000

Panel B: Correlation Matrix of the Daily Economic Policy Uncertainty Index and Daily Firm-Level Liquidity Variables

EPU Indext EU Indext Log Quoted Spreadit Log Amihud Illiquidityit Log Guidance Disc.it

EPU Indext 1.00EU Indext 0.40∗∗∗ 1.00Log Quoted Spreadit 0.08∗∗∗ 0.06∗∗∗ 1.00Log Amihud Illiquidityit 0.07∗∗∗ 0.04∗∗∗ 0.68∗∗∗ 1.00Log Guidance Disclosuresit 0.01∗ -0.01∗∗∗ -0.04∗∗∗ -0.03∗∗∗ 1.00

Panel C: Descriptive Statistics of Static Firm-Level Variables

Variable N Mean σ P25 P50 P75

|Policy Beta|i×1, 000 6,897 0.011 0.023 0.003 0.007 0.014Log of Market Valuei 6,897 19.820 1.811 18.522 19.682 21.000Foreign Incomei 6,897 0.287 0.453 0.000 0.000 1.000Log of Trade Wordsi 6,897 0.074 0.283 0.000 0.000 0.000Log Lobbying Dollarsi 6,897 2.552 5.051 0.000 0.000 0.000Log of EPU Wordsi 6,897 2.120 2.005 0.000 3.1381 3.9576

Panel D: Correlation Matrix of Static Firm-Level Variables

|Policy Beta|i Log of Market Valuei Foreign Incomeit Trade Wordsit Log Lobbying Dollarsit Log of EPU Wordsit

|Policy Beta|i 1.00Log of Market Valuei -0.15∗∗∗ 1.00Foreign Incomei -0.07∗∗∗ 0.21∗∗∗ 1.00Log of Trade Wordsi -0.00 0.07∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 1.00Log Lobbying Dollarsi -0.10∗∗∗ 0.37∗∗∗ 0.12∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 1.00Log of EPU Wordsi 0.00 0.25∗∗∗ -0.02∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 0.07∗∗∗ 1.00

43

Page 45: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 3: Regressions of Stock Liquidity on the Economic Policy Uncertainty Index using Monthly Data from 2003–2016This table uses the monthly average value of all variables. The EPU Index stands for the economic policy uncertainty (EPU) index, and the EU Indexstands for the equity uncertainty (EU) index. This analysis spans our entire sample of 2003 to 2016. Value-weighted (VW) measures are weightedby market capitalization at the beginning of observation month t. We find Durbin-Watson test statistics of over two for all of our regressions, whichindicates that standard errors clustered across time are appropriate for our analysis (see Section 3.2). When two parameters are separated by acomma in the S.E. Clustering row, this implies two-way clustering. YM stands for year-month. Index i represents each firm, and index t representsthe observation month. All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Monthly Data

Aggregate Market Level Firm Level

Log VW Quoted Spreadt Log VW Amihud Illiquidityt Log Quoted Spreadit Log Amihud Illiquidityit

(1) (2) (3) (4)

EPU Indext 0.0151*** 0.0290*** 0.0523*** 0.0379***(3.18) (3.17) (3.16) (3.43)

EU Indext 0.0217*** -0.0029 0.0639** 0.0263**(2.97) (-0.35) (2.51) (1.69)

Fixed Effects Year Year Firm-Year Firm-YearS.E. Clustering Robust Robust Firm, YM Firm, YMObservations 160 160 725,842 720,960R2 0.47 0.57 0.94 0.88

44

Page 46: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 4: Regressions of Stock Liquidity on the Economic Policy Uncertainty Index using Daily Data from 2003–2016This table uses the daily value of all variables. The EPU Index stands for the economic policy uncertainty (EPU) index, and the EU Index stands forthe (EU) equity uncertainty index. This analysis spans our entire sample of 2003 to 2016. Value-weighted (VW) measures are weighted by marketcapitalization at day t. We find Durbin-Watson test statistics of over two for all of our regressions, which indicates that standard errors clusteredacross time are appropriate for our analysis (see Section 3.2). When two parameters are separated by a comma in the S.E. Clustering row, this impliestwo-way clustering. Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day. All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statisticsare in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Daily Data

Aggregate Market Level Firm Level

Log VW Quoted Spreadt Log VW Amihud Illiquidityt Log Quoted Spreadit Log Amihud Illiquidityit

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

EPU Indext−5 0.0035* 0.0051*** 0.0104*** 0.0079***(1.68) (3.63) (3.39) (4.50)

EPU Indext−4 0.0098*** 0.0019 0.0111*** 0.0064***(4.39) (1.25) (3.11) (3.34)

EPU Indext−3 0.0008 0.0017 0.0155** 0.0068***(0.37) (1.15) (2.18) (3.24)

EPU Indext−2 0.0008 0.0048*** 0.0082* 0.0048***(0.37) (3.21) (1.93) (2.69)

EPU Indext−1 -0.0008 0.0019 0.0052 0.0048***(-0.37) (1.28) (1.60) (2.68)

EPU Indext 0.0067*** 0.0020 0.0006 0.0063*** 0.0009 0.0021 0.0269*** 0.0054 0.0097*** 0.0156*** 0.0050*** 0.0069***(3.47) (0.92) (0.27) (4.87) (0.61) (1.27) (8.28) (1.46) (2.82) (9.78) (2.92) (3.90)

EPU Indext+1 0.0031 0.0017 0.0089** 0.0041**(1.32) (0.75) (2.27) (2.39)

EPU Indext+2 0.0032 0.0052 0.0117*** 0.0069***(1.40) (1.72) (3.24) (3.65)

EPU Indext+3 0.0020 0.0038 0.0082** 0.0047**(0.89) (1.69) (2.06) (2.51)

EPU Indext+4 0.0029 -0.0002 0.0081** 0.0041**(1.26) (-0.16) (2.23) (2.42)

EPU Indext+5 0.0072** 0.0024 0.0154*** 0.0068***(2.58) (1.43) (4.39) (3.94)

EU Indext 0.0047*** 0.0032* 0.0024 0.0037*** 0.0083*** 0.0019 0.0183*** 0.0098*** 0.0113*** 0.0078*** 0.0046*** 0.0043***(2.88) (1.96) (1.23) (3.37) (4.76) (1.29) (6.74) (3.99) (4.43) (5.08) (3.56) (3.03)

Fixed Effects Year Year Year Year Year Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-YearS.E. Clustering Year-Qtr. Year-Qtr. Year-Qtr. Year-Qtr. Year-Qtr. Year-Qtr. Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, DayObservations 3,351 3,351 3,351 3,351 3,351 3,351 15,127,411 15,127,411 15,127,411 14,775,942 14,775,942 14,775,942R2 0.06 0.08 0.08 0.20 0.21 0.21 0.84 0.84 0.84 0.57 0.57 0.57

45

Page 47: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 5: Regressions of Stock Liquidity on Firm-Level Statics Interacted with the Economic Policy Uncertainty Index from2003–2016This analysis spans our entire sample of 2003 to 2016. The interacted variables with subscript i are constant for each firm and vary only in the cross-section, which means that they are collinear with the fixed effects. Our interaction tests should thus be interpreted as across-firm, not within-firm,results. We include the main effect for the EPU and the EU indices. When two parameters are separated by a comma in the S.E. Clustering row,this implies two-way clustering. YM stands for year-month. Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day/month. Allvariables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Log Quoted Spreadit Log Amihud Illiquidityit

Monthly Daily Monthly Daily(1) (2) (3) (4)

EPU Indext 0.0533824*** 0.226018*** 0.039977*** 0.233178***(3.17) (13.88) (3.09) (12.84)

EPU Indext× |Policy Beta|i 5.630217*** 1.515130*** 7.620135*** 3.098189***(4.39) (3.85) (3.97) (6.12)

EPU Indext× Log of Market Valuei -0.000300** -0.010349*** -0.000786*** -0.011545***(-2.60) (-14.27) (-5.05) (-13.02)

EPU Indext× Foreign Incomei -0.000022 -0.000002 -0.000021** -0.000014***(-1.56) (-0.51) (-2.48) (-5.66)

EPU Indext× Log of Trade Wordsi -0.000057*** -0.000028*** -0.000069*** -0.000029***(-4.57) (-8.08) (-4.42) (-7.82)

EPU Indext× Log of Lobbying Dollarsi -0.000012*** -0.000001*** -0.000001*** -0.000003***(-4.56) (-2.74) (-4.30) (-12.26)

EPU Indext× Log of EPU Wordsi 0.000015** 0.000020*** 0.000035*** 0.000041***(2.18) (6.18) (5.12) (11.78)

EU Indext 0.063782** 0.018273*** 0.026221* 0.007768***(2.52) (6.76) (1.70) (5.07)

Fixed Effects Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-YearTwo-Way S.E. Clustering Firm, YM Firm, Day Firm, YM Firm, DayObservations 725,842 15,127,411 720,960 14,775,942R2 0.94 0.84 0.88 0.57

46

Page 48: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 6: Stock Price Reaction to Unexpected Earnings from 2003–2016For a given firm i quarter, we measure unexpected earnings as actual earnings minus the analyst consensus mean earnings forecast at t = −1 scaled bystock price at t = −1, where t = 0 is the earnings announcement date (Lys and Sohn, 1990). The EPU and EU indices are averaged over year-quarterq prior to the earnings announcement date. Returns are firm returns minus the value-weighted market return from CRSP. To estimate the effect ofeconomic policy uncertainty on the stock price reaction to unexpected earnings through liquidity, we first follow Section 3 of Pastor and Stambaugh(2003) and run the following regression for each firm using monthly data over our sample period: rit = β0

i +βLi Lt+β

Mi MKTt+β

Si SMBt+β

Hi HMLt+

εit, where L is the Pastor and Stambaugh (2003) innovation in liquidity measure (which we obtain from their website), r is firm i’s excess return,MKT is the excess return on a market index, and SMB and HML are long-short return spreads constructed on sorts of market capitalization andbook-to-market ratio (see Fama and French, 1993). Note that we run this regression at the firm level, not the portfolio level, to ensure that we candirectly link each firm’s βL

i to its respective stock price reaction to earnings. Since a firm’s exposure to expected liquidity risk is increasing in βLi ,

we then set an indicator variable equal to 1 if a firm is in the top quintile of βLi (0 otherwise) and interact this with the EPU index and unexpected

earnings. We interpret this three-way interaction term as the effect of economic policy uncertainty on the stock price reaction to unexpected earningsthrough liquidity (see Section 3.3). Note that we do not have two-way interactions for these risk factors; we assume that the firm-year-fixed effectsare adequate. Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day. All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are inparentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

(1) (2) (3)Returns [−1, +1 day]it Returns [−1, +1 day]it Returns [−1, +1 day]it

Unexpected Earningsit 1.0078*** 1.2239*** 1.2124***(25.50) (13.09) (14.72)

EPU Indexq -0.0019 -0.0022(-0.54) (-0.64)

EPU Indexq × Unexpected Earningsit -0.1776*** -1.3110***(-3.37) (-4.53)

EU Indexq -0.0046 -0.0047(-1.61) (-1.59)

EPU Indexq × UEit × Top βLi Quintileit -0.0635***

(-2.70)

EPU Indexq × UEit × Log of Market Valueit 0.1010***(4.11)

EPU Indexq × UEit × BTMit 0.0003***(2.97)

Fixed Effects Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-YearS.E. Clustering Year-Quarter Year-Quarter Year-QuarterObservations 198,414 198,414 198,414R2 0.32 0.33 0.33

47

Page 49: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 7: Daily Stock Liquidity, Voluntary Disclosure, and the Economic Policy Uncertainty Index from 2003–2016We estimate the effect of economic policy uncertainty induced disclosure on liquidity by first regressing daily guidance on the daily EPU index inColumn 1. In Columns 3 and 4, we then regress daily quoted spreads and Amihud illiquidity on daily guidance and the EPU index. We estimatethe effect of aggregate guidance disclosures on aggregate quoted spreads and Amihud illiquidity by multiplying the guidance disclosure coefficient inColumns 3 and 4 by the EPU index coefficient in Column 1. We likewise estimate the effect of firm-level guidance disclosures on firm-level quotedspreads and Amihud illiquidity by multiplying the guidance disclosure coefficient in Columns 7 and 8 by the EPU index coefficient in Column 5. Wedescribe the model further and interpret the results in Section 3.4. Z-statistics are provided in parentheses for the Poisson count regressions; otherwiset-statistics are in parentheses. We do not log guidance frequency for the Poisson count regressions. Value-weighted (VW) measures are weighted bymarket capitalization at day t. Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day. Variables with only subscript t representday t = 0. Variables with subscript t(−30, 0) are averaged over days t = −30 to t = 0. When two parameters are separated by a comma in the S.E.Clustering row, this implies two-way clustering. All variables are defined in Appendix A. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

Daily Data

Aggregate Market Level Firm Level

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)Log VW Guidancet

∑iGuidanceit Log VW Spreadst Log VW Amihudt Log Guidanceit Guidanceit Log Spreadsit Log Amihudit

EPU Indext(−30,0) 0.2383*** 0.0392*** 0.0225*** 0.0124***(3.39) (9.21) (2.83) (6.65)

EU Indext(−30,0) -0.1443 -0.0149** -0.0015 -0.0112*(-1.19) (-2.44) (-1.25) (-1.96)

Log VW Guidancet -0.0141*** -0.0005(-6.96) (-1.35)

Log Guidanceit -0.0143*** -0.0026***(-4.04) (-8.53)

EPU Indext 0.0068*** 0.0063*** 0.0269*** 0.0156***(3.60) (4.86) (8.28) (9.78)

EU Indext 0.0044*** 0.0036*** 0.0183*** 0.0078***(2.77) (3.35) (6.74) (5.08)

Estimation OLS Poisson OLS OLS OLS Poisson OLS OLSFixed Effects Year Year Year Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-YearS.E. Clustering Robust Robust Robust Robust Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, DayObservations 3,351 3,351 3,351 3,351 15,129,038 15,129,038 15,127,411 14,775,942R2 0.02 0.01 0.12 0.20 0.01 0.01 0.86 0.58

48

Page 50: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 8: Difference-in-Differences Regressions of Stock Liquidity for the 2009–2010 Affordable Care Act Congressional DebatesThe sample period is January 1, 2008 to March 30, 2010, the date when the ACA was signed into law. The ACA Hearing Period indicator equals 1from January 1, 2009 to March 30, 2010 (0 otherwise). Following Christensen et al. (2017), the healthcare indicator variable represents firms withSIC codes of 2830, 2831, 2833–2836, 6300, 6310–6331, 6350, 6351, 6360, 6361, 6370–6379, 6390–6399, 6400–6411, and 8000–8099. These SIC codesinclude healthcare service companies, pharmaceutical companies, and insurance companies. The remainder of the sample is included as non-healthcarecontrol firms. As in Table 5, we do not include the healthcare firm indicator as a main effect in our regressions. This variable is constant within eachfirm and varies only in the cross-section, which means it is collinear with the firm-fixed effects. As Section 3.5 notes, we also run several alternativespecifications. When two parameters are separated by a comma in the S.E. Clustering row, this implies two-way clustering. Index i represents eachfirm, and index t represents the observation day. All variables are defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05,*** p < 0.01.

(1) (2)Log Quoted Spreadit Log Amihud Illiquidityit

ACA Hearing Periodt 0.024783** 0.041764***(1.99) (4.84)

ACA Hearing Periodt× Healthcare Firmi -0.071629*** -0.068840**(-3.17) (-2.46)

Fixed Effects Firm FirmS.E. Clustering Firm, Day Firm, DayObservations 2,769,827 2,694,356R2 0.80 0.56

49

Page 51: Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry€¦ · Economic Policy Uncertainty and Information Asymmetry Venky Nagar University of Michigan Jordan Schoenfeld ... we control

Table 9: Regressions of Stock Liquidity for the U.S. Presidential Elections of 2004, 2008, and 2012The U.S. presidential election period indicator equals 1 for the following dates: July 1, 2004–November 2, 2004 (2004 election); July 1, 2008–November4, 2008 (2008 election); and July 1, 2012–November 6, 2012 (2012 election); and 0 otherwise. We start each election period at July 1 because Julyis the month in which the Democratic and Republican parties hold their national conventions; the ending November date for each election periodrepresents election day. As Section 3.5 notes, we also run several alternative specification windows. When two parameters are separated by a commain the S.E. Clustering row, this implies two-way clustering. Index i represents each firm, and index t represents the observation day. All variablesare defined in Appendix A. T-statistics are in parentheses. * p < 0.10, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01.

2004, 2008, 2012 Elections 2004 Election 2008 Election 2012 Election

Log of Log of Log of Log of(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

Spreadsit Amihudit Spreadsit Amihudit Spreadsit Amihudit Spreadsit Amihudit

Presidential Election Periodt 0.0262*** 0.0232*** 0.0105*** 0.0287*** 0.0581*** 0.0333*** 0.0039** 0.0072***(2.97) (6.88) (3.13) (12.05) (2.91) (3.84) (2.30) (4.07)

Fixed Effects Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-Year Firm-YearS.E. Clustering Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, Day Firm, DayObservations 14,015,922 13,677,327 3,314,059 3,222,753 3,661,403 3,557,507 3,421,711 3,357,980R2 0.84 0.57 0.83 0.52 0.83 0.59 0.84 0.58

50