economics_102_lecture_3_preferences_rev.pdf

Upload: noiraddict

Post on 03-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    1/32

    8/3/200

    Lecture 3 - Theory of the

    Consumer; Preferences

    Consumer preferences: Notations and preference

    relations

    Assumptions on preference relations

    Indifference curves as a graphical representationof consumer preferences.

    Assumptions for well behaved indifference curves

    Marginal Rate of Substitution

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    2/32

    8/3/200

    Consumption bundles

    Give a complete list of goods and services that areinvolved in the consumer choice problem.

    In other words, consumers pick from amongconsumption bundles.

    While we assume that the consumption bundle iscomplete, we usually represent the bundle interms of two goods.

    We can represent consumption bundles as (x1,x2)or byX.

    We assume that consumers can rank

    consumption bundles as to their

    desirability.

    consumers prefer one good over the other in

    the sense that they would choose one bundleover another given the opportunity

    the idea of preference is based on the idea of

    behavior

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    3/32

    8/3/200

    We use the following symbols to denotethese rankings:

    Strict preference

    The consumer definitely wants theX bundlerather than the Y bundle.

    The consumer always choosesXover YwhenXis available.

    ),(to),(prefersstrictlyConsumer

    ),(),(

    preferenceStrictly

    2121

    2121

    yyxx

    yyxx

    Indifference

    Indifference means that the consumer would be

    equally satisfied consuming bundleXor bundle

    Y.

    When bothXand Yare available, consumer

    would choose either bundle

    ),(and),(betweentindifferenisConsumer

    ),(~),(

    ~ceIndifferen

    2121

    2121

    yyxx

    yyxx

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    4/32

    8/3/200

    Weakly prefers

    Consumer prefers or is indifferent between

    ),(),(

    preferenceWeak

    2121 yyxx

    2121 ,and, yyxx

    Relations between these rankings:

    If a consumer weakly prefersXto Yand weaklyprefers YtoX, then the consumer is indifferentbetweenXand Y.

    If a consumer thinks thatXis at least as good as Yand Yis at least as good asX, then the consumermust be indifferent between the two bundles.

    ),(~),(then),,(),(and),(),(If 212121212121 yyxxxxyyyyxx

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    5/32

    8/3/200

    If the consumer thinks thatXis at least

    better than Ybut is not indifferent between

    Xand Y, then the consumer must strictly

    preferXto Y.

    ),(),(then),,(~),(notand),(),(If 212121212121 yyxxxxyyyyxx

    Complete

    any two bundles can be compared, and

    consumers can make a choice between any

    two bundles

    Reflexive: Any bundle is at least as good

    as itself

    bothor),(),(or),(),(Either 21212121 xxyyyyxx

    ),(),( 2121 xxxx

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    6/32

    8/3/200

    Transitive

    If X is as good as Y, and Y is as good as Z, then X is

    at least as good as Z

    ),(),(then),,(),(and),(),(If 212121212121 zzxxzzyyyyxx

    We represent preferences graphically by

    indifference curves or indifference sets

    Indifference curve/set through a bundle

    consists of all consumption bundles that leave

    the consumer indifferent to a given bundle Fig 1

    i.e., the set of all bundles equally preferred to a

    reference bundle x is the indifference curve

    containing x; the set of all bundles y ~ x.

    Weakly preferred set- all consumption bundles

    that are weakly preferred to a specific bundle

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    7/32

    8/3/200

    x2

    x1

    x

    x

    x ~ x ~ xx

    x2

    x1

    z x yp

    x

    y

    z

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    8/32

    8/3/200

    x2

    x1

    xAll bundles in I1 arestrictly preferred to

    all in I2.

    y

    z

    All bundles in I2 are

    strictly preferred to

    all in I3.

    I1

    I2

    I3

    x2

    x1

    I(x)

    x

    I(x)

    WP(x), the set of

    bundles weakly

    preferred to x.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    9/32

    8/3/200

    x2

    x1

    WP(x), the set of

    bundles weakly

    preferred to x.WP(x)

    includes

    I(x).

    x

    I(x)

    x2

    x1

    SP(x), the set of

    bundles strictly

    preferred to x,

    does not

    includeI(x).

    x

    I(x)

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    10/32

    8/3/200

    1

    Indifference curves representing distinct levels of

    preference do not cross.

    Intersecting indifference curves violate the transitivity

    assumption about preferences.

    SupposeXis preferred to Ybut indifferent toZ, Yisindifferent toZand the axiom of transitivity implies that

    Xis indifferent to Ywhich is not the case

    x2

    x1

    x y

    z

    I1I2 From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z.

    Therefore y ~ z.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    11/32

    8/3/200

    x2

    x1

    xy

    z

    I1I2 From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z.

    Therefore y ~ z. But from I1and I2 we see y z, a

    contradiction.

    p

    Since indifference curves are a way to describe

    preferences, then reasonable preferences can be

    described by indifference curves.

    To construct indifference curves ask - for a given

    change in good 1, how does the consumption of good2 have to change so that the consumer is indifferent

    between the old consumption level and the new

    consumption level?

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    12/32

    8/3/200

    1

    When more of a commodity is always

    preferred, the commodity is a good.

    If every commodity is a good then

    indifference curves are negatively sloped.

    Good 2

    Good 1

    Two goods

    a negatively sloped

    indifference curve.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    13/32

    8/3/200

    1

    Bads

    A bad is a commodity that the consumer doesnt like

    Assume that there is some tradeoff between the twogoods

    Suppose a bundleXwithx1 as the good andx2 as thebad. To keep a consumer on the same indifferencecurve, we have to give him more of good 1 in order tocompensate him for having to put up with the bad

    Bads are represented by upward sloping indifference

    curves The direction of increasing preference is down and to

    the right, toward the direction of increasedconsumption of the good and toward decreasedconsumption of the bad

    Good 2

    Bad 1

    One good and one

    bad a

    positively sloped

    indifference curve.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    14/32

    8/3/200

    1

    Perfect substitutes

    If a consumer is willing to substitute one good for

    another at a constant rate, then we consider the two

    goods as perfect substitutes.

    For perfect substitutes, indifference curves have a

    constant slope.

    Since only the total quantities matter, the direction of

    increasing preference is to the right.

    x2

    x18

    8

    15

    15Slopes are constant at - 1.

    I2

    I1

    Bundles in I2 all have a total

    of 15 units and are strictly

    preferred to all bundles inI1, which have a total of

    only 8 units in them.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    15/32

    8/3/200

    1

    Perfect complements

    Goods that are consumed together in fixed proportions.

    The indifference curves for perfect complements are L-shaped, with the vertex occurring where the ratio of theamount of good 1 to the amount of good 2 are at thefixed proportion

    Direction of increasing preferences is up and to theright. Increasing both the quantities of both goods will

    move the consumer to a more preferred condition.

    x2

    x1

    I1

    45o

    5

    9

    5 9

    Each of(5,5), (5,9)

    and (9,5) contains

    5 pairs so each is

    equally preferred.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    16/32

    8/3/200

    1

    x2

    x1

    I2

    I1

    45o

    5

    9

    5 9

    Since each of(5,5),

    (5,9) and (9,5)

    contains 5 pairs,

    each is less

    preferred than the

    bundle (9,9) which

    contains 9 pairs.

    Neutral

    Neutral goods are goods that the consumer

    dont care about.

    the indifference curves are vertical lines

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    17/32

    8/3/200

    1

    x2

    x1

    Satiation point or bliss point most preferred bundle ofgoods

    Represented by

    The closer the consumer is to that bundle, the better offhe is in terms of preferences.

    Points nearer the bliss points lie on higher indifferencecurves while those that are farther lie on lowerindifference curves

    Indifference curve has a negative slope when he has toolittle or too much of both goods.

    Indifference curve has a positive slope when he has toomuch of one of the goods.

    Direction of preference is toward the bliss point.

    ),( 21 xx

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    18/32

    8/3/200

    1

    x2

    x1

    Satiation

    (bliss)

    point

    x2

    x1

    Better

    Satiation

    (bliss)

    point

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    19/32

    8/3/200

    1

    x2

    x1

    B

    etter

    Satiation

    (bliss)

    point

    We will limit our analysis to that region

    where we have less of what we want. Most

    likely, people are below rather than above

    their bliss points.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    20/32

    8/3/200

    2

    Discrete goods consumption is usually in integerunits

    preferences can still be represented as continuousvariables by a suitable redefinition of the good inquestion, e.g., number of automobiles (discrete) vs.hours spent in a car (continuous).

    If not then preferences can still be represented byindifference curves and weakly preferred set Points with the same color are bundles that are indifferent

    to one another

    Vertical lines represent bundles that are at least as good

    Continuou

    s good

    Discrete good

    0 1 2 3 4

    Indifference curves

    are collections of

    discrete points.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    21/32

    8/3/200

    2

    Monotonicity

    This assumption just states that more is

    better

    IfXis a bundle of goods and Yis a bundle of

    goods with at least as much as both goods

    and more of one, then Yis preferred toX.

    XY

    xyxyyyxx

    :then

    ,and,such that),(),,(bundlestwoSuppose 22112121

    Monotonicity implies that indifference curveshave a negative slope.

    From a bundleX, moving up and to the right impliesmoving to a more preferred position

    Moving down and to the left implies moving to a less

    preferred position If we are moving to an indifferent position, then we

    must be moving rightward and down and or movingleftward and up.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    22/32

    8/3/200

    2

    x2

    x1

    x

    Better bundles

    Worse bundles

    Convexity

    Assumes that averages are preferred to extremes

    The distance fromXto the average bundle is just afraction tof the distance from theXbundle to the Y

    bundle along the line that connects the two bundles.

    ),())1(,)1((:Then

    ),(~),(Assume

    10weight,abeLet t

    212211

    2121

    xxyttxyttx

    yyxx

    t

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    23/32

    8/3/200

    2

    Geometrically, it means that the bundlesweakly preferred to X is a convex set.

    A convex set has the property that if you takeany two points in the set and draw a linesegment connecting these two points, then theline segment is entirely in the set.

    Reason for assuming convex preferences-most goods are consumed together Example of nonconvex preferences- two goods that

    somebody might not prefer to consume together.

    Strictly convex - Assumes that theweighted average of two bundles isstrictly preferred to the two extremebundles. convex preferences- indifference curves

    may have flat spots strictly convex preferences have rounded

    indifference curves

    indifference curves for perfect substitutesare convex but not strictly convex.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    24/32

    8/3/200

    2

    x2

    y2

    x1 y1

    x

    y

    z =(tx1+(1-t)y1, tx2+(1-t)y2)is preferred to x and y

    for all 0 < t < 1.

    x2

    y2

    x2+y2

    2

    x1 y1x1+y1

    2

    x

    y

    z =x+y

    2

    is strictly preferred

    to both x and y ift=.50

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    25/32

    8/3/200

    2

    x2

    y2

    x1 y1

    x

    y

    Preferences are strictly convex

    when all mixtures z

    are strictly

    preferred to their

    component

    bundles x and y.

    z

    x

    y

    z

    Preferences are

    weakly convex ifat

    least one mixture z

    is equally preferred

    to a componentbundle.

    xz y

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    26/32

    8/3/200

    2

    x2

    y2

    x1 y1

    z

    The mixture z

    is less preferred

    than x or y.

    x2

    y2

    x1 y1

    z

    The mixture z

    is less preferred

    than x or y.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    27/32

    8/3/200

    2

    Marginal rate of substitution slope

    of the indifference curve. The slope

    denotes the rate at which the

    consumer is just willing to substitute

    one good for another.

    Suppose we take a little bit of good 1, x1 from theconsumer and give him x2, an amount that is justsufficient to put him back on his indifference curve

    The ratio x2/x1 is the rate at which the consumeris willing substitute good 2 for good 1.

    If we think of the changes as very small changes, thenthe ratio measures the marginal rate of substitutionof good 2 for good 1. As x1 gets smaller, the ratioapproaches the slope of the indifference curve

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    28/32

    8/3/200

    2

    x2

    x1

    MRS at x is

    lim {x2/x1}x1 0

    = dx2/dx1 at xx2

    x1

    x

    x2

    x1

    dx2dx1

    dx2 = MRS dx1 so, at x, MRS isthe rate at which the consumer is

    only just willing to exchange

    commodity 2 for a small amount of

    commodity 1.x

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    29/32

    8/3/200

    2

    x2

    x1

    x

    MRS at x is the slope of the

    indifference curve at x

    MRS is typically a negative number. Monotonicpreferences imply that indifference curves have anegative slope.

    Marginal rate of substitution measures the rate atwhich the consumer is just on the margin of tradingor not trading. At any rate of exchange other thanthe MRS, the consumer would want to trade onegood for another. If the rate of exchange equals the

    MRS, then the consumer stays put.

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    30/32

    8/3/200

    3

    x2

    x1

    x

    E

    Other interpretation of the MRS: Slope of the

    indifference curve can also be interpreted as the

    marginal willingness to pay

    Using the concept of a composite good or spending

    on all other goods - interpretation is how many

    pesos you are willing to give up spending on other

    goods in order to increase consumption of one good.

    marginal willingness to pay is different from what

    you have to pay

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    31/32

    8/3/200

    3

    Behavior of the MRS

    MRS for different preferences

    perfect substitutes = constant MRS

    perfect complements = MRS is zero or infinity

    neutrals = MRS is everywhere infinite, youcannot compensate one for consuming anextra good because he doesnt care about theother good

    Since monotonicity of preferences implies thatslope of indifference curves are negative - thenMRS always involves reducing the consumptionof one good in order to get more of another

    Convexity, in particular strict convexity, implies

    that the slope of indifference curves decreases in

    absolute value as we increase x1.

    Diminishing marginal rates of substitution rate at

    which a person is willing to trade good 1 for good 2

    decreases as we increase the amount of good 1

  • 7/28/2019 Economics_102_Lecture_3_Preferences_rev.pdf

    32/32

    8/3/200

    Good 2

    Good 1

    MRS = - 5

    MRS = - 0.5

    MRS always increases with x1 (becomes less

    negative) if and only if preferences are strictly

    convex.