economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

50
Economic sanctions and their unintended effects: A case study of the French weapon embargo on Israel of 1967 Faculty of Economics and Business MSc. International Economics and Globalization Name: Maxime van Gelder Student number: 5927560 Email address: [email protected] Supervisor: Dr. D.J.M. Veestraeten Second reader: Drs. N.J. Leefmans Date: August 15 th 2016 Number of words: 18,902

Upload: others

Post on 02-Apr-2022

7 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

 

         

Economic  sanctions  and  their  unintended  effects:  

 

A  case  study  of  the  French  weapon  embargo  on  Israel  of  1967  

         

Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business    

MSc.  International  Economics  and  Globalization                                        

Name:   Maxime  van  Gelder    

Student  number:   5927560    

Email  address:   [email protected]    

Supervisor:   Dr.  D.J.M.  Veestraeten    Second  reader:   Drs.  N.J.  Leefmans  

 

Date:   August  15th  2016    

Number  of  words:   18,902  

Page 2: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

2    

Table  of  Contents    Section   Content   Page  

1.   Introduction    

3  

2.   Economic  sanctions    

2.1  Classification  of  objectives  of  economic  sanctions    

2.2  The  construction  and  trends  in  the  use  of  economic  sanctions    

2.3  Types  of  economic  sanctions    

2.4  Effectiveness  of  economic  sanctions  

11    

5    

8    

11    

12  

3.   The  development  of  the  French  Israeli  relationship  from  1948  to  1967    3.1  French  arms  policy  to  the  Middle  East  from  1948  to  1967  

 

x 3.1.1The  Tripartite  Declaration  of  May  1950    

x 3.1.2  The  Suez  War  of  October  29  to  November  7  1956    

x 3.1.3  The  French-­‐Israeli  nuclear  cooperation  from  1949  to  1957    

x 3.1.4  The  Six-­‐Day  War  from  5  to  10  June  1967        3.2  The  early  development  of  Israel's  military  industry  up  to  1967  

13    17  

 

17    

20    

22    

24        27  

4.   The  unintended  effects  of  the  French  weapon  embargo  on  Israel  in  1967      4.1  Short  term  effects  for  Israel  

 

4.2  Short  term  effects  for  France    

4.3  Long  term  effects  on  Israel's  economy  

12        31  

 

35    

38  

5.   Conclusions   45  

6.   Reference  list   47  

 Statement  of  Originality  

This  document  is  written  by  Student  Maxime  van  Gelder,  who  declares  to  take  full  

responsibility  for  the  contents  of  this  document.  

I  declare  that  the  text  and  the  work  presented  in  this  document  is  original  and  that  no  sources  

other  than  those  mentioned  in  the  text  and  its  references  have  been  used  in  creating  it.  

The  Faculty  of  Economics  and  Business  is  responsible  solely  for  the  supervision  of  completion  

of  the  work,  not  for  the  contents.  

Page 3: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

3    

Section  1:  Introduction    The  role  and  usefulness  of  economic  sanctions  as  a  tool  of  foreign  policy  have  been  debated  for  

almost  a  century  (Elliot  and  Hufbauer,  1999).  Much  of  the  literature  about  economic  sanctions  is  

focused  upon  the  effectiveness  of  economic  sanctions  (Nossal,  1989).  An  economic  sanction  is  seen  

as  a  tool  of  the  governments  of  one  or  more  sender  countries  to  do  economic  harm  to  a  target  

country  (Baldwin  and  Pape,  1998).  Whether  economic  sanctions  are  effective  or  not,  and  what  the  

factors  are  that  make  them  an  often  used  instrument  in  foreign  policy  by  governments  have  been  

discussed  (Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg,  1988).  An  extensive  literature  has  been  written  on  the  

negative  effects  that  economic  sanctions  can  bear  for  the  target  country  and  the  positive  effects  

they  may  have  for  the  sender  country.  While  these  findings  contribute  to  the  understanding  of  the  

effects  of  economic  sanctions,  there  seems  to  be  an  absence  of  literature  focused  on  the  positive  

externalities  that  can  result  from  economic  sanctions.  These  externalities  are  the  unintended  effects  

for  both  the  sender  and  target  country  and  can  have  large  consequences  both  on  short  and  long-­‐  

term  for  the  national  economy.    Marinov  (2005)  argues  that  economic  sanctions  vary  a  lot  in  scope  and  intensity.  One  of  the  most  

harsh  economic  sanctions  is  a  comprehensive  trade  boycott,  also  referred  to  as  an  embargo  

(Greenwood,  2012).  This  paper  examines  one  specific  case,  namely  that  of  a  weapon  embargo.  The  

purpose  of  this  paper  is  to  explore  the  relation  between  an  economic  sanction  and  the  positive  

effects  it  can  have  for  a  local  industry  in  the  target  country.  Such  positive  effects  would  undermine  

the  economic  sanction  and  make  it  ineffective  or  even  counterproductive  in  the  long  run.  This  paper  

examines  one  specific  case,  namely  that  of  a  weapon  embargo.  By  studying  a  case,  the  French  

weapon  embargo  of  1967  on  Israel,  this  paper  looks  for  an  answer  on  the  following  research  

question:    

How  did  the  weapon  embargo  of  1967  of  France  on  Israel  had  a  positive  effect  on  Israel's  economy?    In  order  to  provide  a  substantiated  answer  to  the  research  question  a  literature  review  is  conducted.  

This  paper  is  structured  as  follows.  Section  2  gives  an  overview  of  the  extant  literature  on  economic  

sanctions  and  describes  the  most  important  concepts  such  as  the  different  objectives,  types,  the  

construction  of  and  trends  concerning  economic  sanctions  and  their  effectiveness.  Section  3  

describes  the  development  of  the  French-­‐Israeli  relationship  prior  to  the  imposed  weapon  embargo.  

This  section  describes  the  French  arms  policy  towards  the  Middle  East  from  1948  to  1967,  and  the  

early  development  of  Israel’s  military  industry  up  to  1967.  Section  4  examines  the  unintended  

effects  of  the  French  weapon  embargo  on  Israel,  both  for  Israel  and  France.  For  Israel  these  

Page 4: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

4    

unintended  effects  are  described  for  the  short-­‐term  as  well  for  the  long-­‐term.  Section  5  presents  the  

conclusions.  

Page 5: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

5    

Section  2:  Economic  Sanctions      In  order  to  create  a  better  understanding  of  the  notion  of  economic  sanctions  this  section  focuses  on  

four  main  elements  that  are  relevant  while  looking  into  economic  sanctions.  Although  there  are  

numerous  more  elements  when  it  comes  to  sanctions,  for  the  sake  of  clarity  and  link  to  the  below  

case  study  the  following  four  will  be  discussed.  First  the  variety  in  objectives  of  economic  sanctions  

are  discussed  and  classified  in  a  structured  manner.  Secondly,  the  construction  and  trends  in  the  use  

of  economic  sanctions  are  discussed.  Furthermore,  different  types  of  economic  sanctions  are  

outlined.  Finally,  an  overview  is  given  of  the  voluminous  literature  on  the  effectiveness  of  economic  

sanctions.    

2.1  Objectives  of  economic  sanctions      The  need  to  intervene  is  a  practical  necessity  in  a  world  in  which  the  government  and  citizens  of  

some  states  choose  to,  or  are  forced  to,  take  interest  in  activities  that  take  place  beyond  the  border  

of  territory  they  live  in  (Marinov,  2005).  According  to  Baldwin  and  Pape  (1998)  economic  sanctions  

are  part  of  a  larger  set  of  policy  instruments  available  to  governments,  in  addition  to  diplomacy,  

propaganda,  and  military  interference.  Since  economic  sanctions  are  a  tool  for  governments  it  is  

useful  to  conceive  them  as  instruments  of  state  power  within  the  context  of  international  relations  

(Baldwin  and  Pape,  1998).  Convicting  via  a  diplomatic  note  of  protest  is  a  mild  and  common  

measure,  while  sending  troops  to  invade  a  country  is  a  dramatic  but  infrequent  example  of  

intervention  (Marinov,  2005).  Marinov  (2005)  states  that  economic  sanctions  occupies  the  middle  

ground  between  'words  and  war'  and  its  relatively  frequent  use  can  be  explained  as  a  result  of  high  

demand  and  available  supply.  Thence  Pape  (1997)  argues  that  economic  sanctions  have  come  to  be  

seen  by  the  'traditional  understanding’  as  a  more  advanced  alternative  to  war,  being  potentially  as  

effective  as  military  force  nevertheless  more  humane.    

In  order  to  make  any  insightful  statement  about  the  effectiveness  of  economic  sanctions  it  is  

meaningful  to  have  a  better  understanding  about  the  different  objectives  that  sanctions  can  have.  

Barber  (1979)  categorizes  the  objectives  of  economic  sanctions  into  three  main  categories  and  in  this  

section  the  varying  (sub)objectives  are  outlined  on  the  basis  of  Barber's  framework.  Barber  (1979)  

states  that  economic  sanctions  can  have  'primary  objectives'  which  are  concerned  with  the  actions  

and  behaviour  of  the  target  state.  The  'primary  objectives'  can  be  explained  easiest  as  trying  to  hurt  

the  target  state  (Barber,  1979).  These  primary  objectives  are  themselves  diverse  and  may  include  

attempts  to  induce  internal  political  change  within  the  target  state  as  a  consequence  of  economic  

harm,  in  line  with  the  so-­‐called  'traditional  understanding'  (Barber,  1979).  This  so  called  

Page 6: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

6    

'traditional  wisdom'  is  best  described  by  the  idea  that  target  countries  suffer  the  disutilities  that  

result  from  the  actions  of  sender  countries  imposing  the  economic  sanctions,  and  therefore  will  

change  policy  in  the  direction  of  the  sender  countries  (Baldwin  and  Pape,  1998).  Baldwin  and  Pape  

(1998)  explain  economic  sanctions  as  such  that  it  is  an  attempt  from  a  sender  country  to  change  the  

target  country's  behaviour.  In  line  with  this,  Galtung  (1967)  states  that  economic  sanctions  have  

either  or  both  of  two  purposes  namely,  to  punish  the  receivers  by  depriving  them  of  some  value  

and/or  to  make  the  receivers  comply  with  certain  norms  the  senders  deem  important.  The  resulting  

costs,  or  the  fear  of  such  costs,  in  turn  may  cause  target  countries  to  moderate  their  behaviour  in  the  

direction  demanded  by  the  sending  countries  (Dasthi-­‐Gibson,  Davis  and  Radcliff,  1997).  Much  of  the  

'traditional  wisdom'  on  sanctions  implicitly  assumes  that  their  real  goal  is  to  alter  policies  by  

imposing  economic  harm  in  the  target  country,  making  economic  sanctions  an  instrumental  tool  for  

achieving  political  objectives  (Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg,  1988).  An  economic  sanction  that  is  

instrumental  is  designed  for  the  results  it  is  expected  to  produce  instead  of  for  its  own  sake  or  any  

symbolic  reason,  which  can  be  a  'secondary  objective'  (Nossal,  1989).  Drury  (1988)  argues  that  when  

used  properly,  these  economic  sanctions  can  assist  policymakers  of  sender  countries  to  avert  war  by  

enforcing  their  nation's  will  while  still  allowing  time  and  room  to  settle  the  dispute  diplomatically  

and  without  bloodshed.    Nossal  (1989)  categorizes  the  instrumental  role  of  economic  sanctions  into  three  smaller  purposes,  

namely  for  prevention,  for  compulsion,  and  for  retribution.  Nossal  (1989)  explains  that  firstly  a  

sanction  can  be  imposed  in  order  to  deter  or  prevent  future  wrongful  behaviour.  Secondly,  

punishment  may  be  inflicted  in  order  to  compel  an  offender  to  directly  stop  wrongful  behaviour  

(Nossal,  1989).  In  this  case  sanctions  are  inflicted  until  the  target  country  obeys  to  the  sender's  will.  

The  third  purpose  is  retribution,  whereby  the  economic  sanction  is  a  response  to  the  target  as  a  

return  for  an  evil  inflicted  on  the  sender  state  or  community  of  sender  states  (Nossal,  1989).  In  the  

case  of  retribution  the  harm  is  seen  as  an  appropriate  response  of  the  sender  countries  to  the  target  

country  that  had  the  choice  to  act  otherwise  but  chose  to  act  wrongfully  (Nossal,  1989).  The  response  

of  the  sender  countries  can  be  seen  as  a  result  of  a  'Tit  for  Tat'  strategy.  A  'Tit  for  Tat'  strategy  is  a  

strategy  whereby  an  agent,  first  cooperates  and  then  subsequently  replicates  the  other  agents  action  

(Hargreaves-­‐Heap  and  Varoufakies,  2004).  In  the  case  of  retribution,  the  sender  states  reply  the  non-­‐

cooperative  action  of  the  target  state  by  imposing  economic  sanctions.  Nossal  (1989)  argues  that  the  

first  two  purposes  are  oriented  to  influence  a  change  in  direct  or  future  behaviour  of  the  target  

country,  while  the  third  purpose  is  backward  looking  and  based  on  what  has  occurred  and  went  

wrong  in  the  past.  Although  there  is  no  clear  future  oriented  end  in  such  a  formulation,  this  does  not  

suggest  that  the  sanctions  cannot  be  instrumental  (Nossal,  1989).  

Page 7: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

7    

Kirshner  (2007)  argues  that  a  state  may  initiate  economic  sanctions  not  just  to  comply  action  on  the  

part  of  the  target  state,  but  also  to  communicate  its  preferences,  support  allies,  deter  other  states  to  

behave  alike,  and  dissuade  the  target  from  expanding  its  objectionable  activity.  Economic  sanctions  

may  also  be  designed  to  punish,  weaken,  distract,  or  contain  the  adversary  (Kirshner,  2007).  Lindsay  

(1986)  argues  that  states  installing  economic  sanctions  are  seeking  to  achieve  one  or  more  of  five  

broad  ends:  compliance,  subversion,  deterrence,  international  symbolism  and/or  domestic  

symbolism.    In  line  with  these  broader  objectives,  Barber  (1979)  argues  that  economic  sanctions  that  serve  

 

'secondary  objectives'  are  designed  to  enhance  the  status,  behaviour  and  expectations  of  the  sender  

countries  government(s),  directed  to  both  domestic  and  international  audiences.  For  instance,  it  can  

be  a  secondary  objective  for  politicians  to  increase  domestic  support  by  imposing  an  import  

embargo  (Barber,  1979).  These  economic  sanctions  often  contain  a  substantial  symbolic  element  

and  are  imposed  to  demonstrate  a  willingness  as  well  capacity  to  act  (Barber,  1979).  Furthermore  

they  provide  a  way  of  symbolising  a  general  stance  in  international  relations  and  these  symbols  are  

very  important  in  political  relationships  since  it  demonstrates  which  countries  are  more  powerful  

and  in  control  within  the  political  domain  (Galtung,  1967).  Barber  (1979)  explains  that  if  the  primary  

objectives  are  achieved  the  status  of  the  imposing  state  is  likely  to  be  enhanced  and  therefore  the  

symbols  as  well  actions  it  is  seeking  to  condemn  take  on  greater  meaning.  Secondary  objectives  are  

easiest  to  be  explained  as  reinforcing  the  sender  state's  government  via  symbolism  (Barber,  1979).    

Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg  (1988)  exemplify  these  'secondary  objectives'  by  arguing  that  the  level  and  

type  of  economic  sanctions  are  an  outcome  of  the  relative  effectiveness  of  interest  groups  in  

pressuring  domestic  policymakers.  Thereby  the  purpose  of  economic  sanctions  is  to  appease  

domestic  pressure  groups  interested  in  expressing  their  disapproval  of  the  practices  of  a  foreign  

country  (Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg,  1988).  A  common  case  is  that  in  order  to  align  with  the  interests  

of  domestic  pressure  groups  sanctioners  typically  restrict  imports  from  the  target  country  rather  

than  exports  to  that  country  (Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg,  1988).  These  measures  are  installed  to  

reduce  the  competition  on  the  domestic  market  via  the  exclusion  of  foreign  competitors.  Kaempfer  

and  Lowenberg  (1988)  state  that  since  domestic  industries  seeking  protection  from  foreign  imports  

have  common  and/or  overlapping  interests  with  other  interest  groups  seeking  to  sanction  the  

exporting  nation,  it  is  likely  that  the  groups  will  ally  themselves.  As  a  consequence  the  type  of  

economic  sanctions  are  unlikely  to  be  designed  to  impose  the  maximum  amount  of  economic  harm  

on  the  target  (Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg,  1988).  Instead  of  that  it  is  more  likely  that  the  types  of  

sanctions  observed  are  designed  to  serve  the  interests  of  influential  domestic  pressure  groups  

operating  in  the  sender  country,  a  so-­‐called  public  choice  approach  (Kaempfer  and  Lowenberg,  

Page 8: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

8    

1988).  In  the  United  States  (US),  Non-­‐Governmental  Organisations  (NGOs)  often  succeed  in  

mobilizing  congressional  support  for  economic  sanctions,  even  in  the  face  of  inconsistency  of  the  

foreign  policy  (Elliot  and  Huffbauer,  1999).  For  instance,  via  lobbying  groups  members  of  US  

congress  can  be  influenced  to  vote  in  a  specific  direction  that  contradicts  the  position  of  the  

government.  Elliot  and  Huffbauer  (1999)  explain  this  seemingly  contradictory  phenomena  by  

showing  that  the  objectives  of  the  sender  country's  politicians  are  not  necessarily  'primary'  to  

influence  the  target  country,  moreover  to  receive  support  from  domestic  groups  that  strengthens  

the  status  of  the  politicians,  i.e.  a  'secondary  objective'.  This  is  one  of  the  reasons  why  sender  

country  politicians  frequently  claim  that  economic  sanctions  constitute  an  expressive  activity,  a  so-­‐  

called  'release  of  internal  tension'  directed  at  a  domestic  audience  without  other  ends  (Nossal,  

1989).    'Tertiary  objectives'  of  economic  sanctions  are  those  that  deal  with  the  composition  and  behaviour  

 

of  the  international  system  in  general,  or  those  parts  of  it  that  influence  the  imposing  states  (Barber,    

1979).  Barber  (1979)  states  that  this  includes  efforts  of  the  imposing  states  to  ensure  a  certain  

pattern  of  behaviour  in  international  affairs  in  order  to  favour  their  own  position  and  interests.  

According  to  Barber  (1979),  tertiary  objectives  are  usually  directed  to  defending  or  promoting  

existing  structures  or  organisations,  whether  it  be  an  alliance  or  an  international  body.  For  instance,  

economic  sanctions  with  a  tertiary  objective  may  be  an  attempt  to  defend  the  balance  of  power  in  a  

certain  region,  of  which  the  Tripartite  declaration  that  is  discussed  in  section  3.1.1.,  is  an  example.  Or  

to  delegitimize  a  nation  and  its  rights,  which  is  an  attempt  of  Arab  countries  over  the  years  with  

regards  to  Israel  and  exemplified  in  section  3.1.4.  by  the  Yugoslav  resolution  (Barber,  1979).  Tertiary  

objectives  are  easiest  to  be  explained  in  order  to  form  international  bodies  and  alliances  by  sender  

states  (Barber,  1979).    

2.2  The  construction  and  trends  in  the  use  of  economic  sanctions      This  section  briefly  discusses  why  international  cooperation  is  necessary  in  order  to  impose  effective  

economic  sanctions,  explains  why  the  US  is  leading  in  imposing  economic  sanctions  and  outlines  the  

general  trends  that  could  be  observed  over  the  last  decades.    Prior  to  the  imposition  of  economic  sanctions  towards  a  target,  a  domestic  political  process  takes  

place  within  the  sender  country  (Major  and  McGann,  2005).  The  initiative  in  imposing  international  

sanctions  normally  rests  on  one  or  two  particular  states,  but  to  make  the  economic  sanctions  

effective  the  economic  sanctions  have  to  be  multilateral  (Martin,  1993).  Therefore  the  'leading'  state  

have  to  recruit  and  involve  other  states  and/or  international  agencies  and  is  referred  to  as  the  

Page 9: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

9    

cooperation  problem  (Martin,  1993).  A  significant  level  of  international  cooperation  is  necessary  to  

be  effective.  For  instance,  unilateral  trade  restrictions  give  the  target  country  an  opportunity  to  

move  to  other  trading  partners  and  thereby  bypassing  the  trade  restrictions  (Martin,  1993).    

According  to  Kirshner  (1997)  trade  restrictions  are  the  most  common  form  of  economic  sanctions  and  

can  be  divided  into  two  categories:  export  sanctions  and  import  sanctions.  The  export  sanctions  ban  

export  to  the  target  state  while  the  import  sanctions  prohibit  imports  from  the  target  state  (Kirshner,  

1997).  Kirshner  (1997)  states  that  although  the  two  categories  differ  from  each  other  both  aim  to  

deprive  the  target  from  the  gains  of  international  trade.  Martin  (1993)  argues  that  in  order  

for  economic  sanctions  like  trade  restrictions  or  an  embargo,  a  complete  prohibition  of  commerce,    

to  be  effective  international  cooperation  is  crucial.  Martin  (1993)  outlines  that  in  many  unsuccessful  

cases  the  lack  of  international  cooperation  was  the  main  issue,  since  states  considering  the  use  of  

export  restrictions  rarely  have  unilateral  control  over  the  goods  they  wish  to  deny  to  the  target  and  

therefore  the  target  can  purchase  the  goods  from  other  states.  The  target  state  may  have  to  pay  

higher  prices  for  imports  due  to  transition  costs,  but  unless  sender  states  achieve  a  significant  level  

of  international  cooperation  trade  restrictions  and/or  embargoes  in  general  will  fail  (Martin,  1993).    

Martin  (1993)  explains  that  the  process  of  organizing  multilateral  economic  sanctions,  trade  

restrictions  from  more  than  one  state  to  one  target  state,  typically  occurs  under  conditions  of  

significant  asymmetry  of  interests  among  potential  sanctioners.  The  asymmetry  of  interests  is  

because  one  state  has  a  strong  interest  in  seeing  sanctions  imposed  on  the  target  while  other  

potential  sender  states  have  lower  interests  in  doing  so  (Martin,  1993).  Martin  (1993)  explains  that  

due  to  this  asymmetry  one  state  is  usually  taking  a  leading  role  in  organizing  the  multilateral  effort,  

the  so-­‐called  'leading  sender'.  While  the  leading  sender  attempts  to  organize  sanctions,  other  states  

often  appear  willing  to  free  ride  on  its  efforts  and  need  extensive  persuasion  before  they  will  agree  

to  cooperate  (Martin,  1993).    

The  US  government  was  in  many  cases,  particularly  between  1945  and  1989,  the  leading  force  and  

has  turned  more  frequently  than  other  countries  to  economic  sanctions  in  response  to  demands  to  

'do  something',  about  ethnic  conflict,  human  rights  violations,  drug  trafficking,  terrorism,  or  nuclear  

proliferation  (Elliot  and  Hufbauer,  1999).  Cox  and  Drury  (2006)  state  that  two  democracies  would  

preferably  sanction  each  other  instead  of  engage  in  military  action,  since  the  key  factors  that  

underlie  the  democracies  are  the  common  norms  for  conflict  resolution  as  well  the  high  level  of  

trades  between  democracies  provides  a  shared  interest  not  to  go  into  war.  Cox  and  Drury  (2006)  

suggest  that  democracies  may  use  non-­‐military  types  of  coercion,  like  economic  sanctions,  as  a  

substitute  to  military  confrontation  when  engaged  in  a  dispute  with  another  democracy.  These  

Page 10: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

10    

norms  for  conflict  resolution  as  well  the  pursuit  of  human  rights  and  democratization  goals  explain  in  

part  why  democracies  employ  sanctions  more  than  any  other  type  of  regimes  (Cox  and  Drury,  2006).  

In  the  vast  majority  of  cases,  77  out  of  120  between  1970-­‐1998,  the  US  was  the  leading  sender  of  

economic  sanctions  and  in  even  52  sanctions  the  US  acted  unilaterally  (Elliott  and  Huffbauer,  1999).  

Elliot  and  Huffbauer  (1999)  state  that  over  the  years  the  targets  as  well  senders  have  changed,  

reflecting  the  end  of  the  Cold  War.  During  the  Cold  War  the  Soviet  Union  and/or  its  allies  were  targets  

of  the  Western  economic  sanctions  mainly  led  by  the  US,  while  after  the  Cold  War  Western  sanctions  

to  former  Soviet  Union  states  decreased  but  Russia  subjected  more  sanctions  to  these  states  (Elliot  

and  Huffbauer,  1999).  Furthermore  the  US  saw  itself  forced  to  impose  several  economic  sanctions  in  

its  'backyard'  to  Latin  American  countries  to  settle  disputes  and  to  push  these  states  towards  a  more  

democratic  governance  (Elliot  and  Huffbaeur,  1999).  Another  big  change  was  the  

rise  in  initiative  of  European  countries  when  ethnic  unrest  struck  in  the  Balkans  or  when  their  

traditional  sphere  of  influence  in  Africa  declined  (Elliot  and  Huffbauer,  1999).    According  to  Marinov  (2005),  around  1950  only  five  countries  were  subject  to  economic  sanctions  

while  that  number  had  increased  to  47  by  the  mid-­‐1990s.  In  June  2016  economic  sanctions  are  still  

active  on  44  countries  in  one  form  or  another,  varying  from  Afghanistan  to  Zimbabwe,  showing  that  

they  still  are  a  commonly  used  tool  in  international  politics  (Business  and  Sanctions  Consulting  

Netherlands,  2016).  In  the  last  decade,  virtually  nowhere  could  democratic  rights  and  freedoms  be  

suspended,  human  rights  grossly  abused,  or  a  civil  war  break  out  without  causing  a  group  of  states  

to  react  with  economic  sanctions  (Marinov,  2005).  Cortright  and  Lopez  (2000)  even  referred  to  the  

1990s  as  'the  sanctions  decade'.  Kirshner  (1997)  foresees  that  economic  diplomacy  will  play  an  

increasingly  large  role  in  the  post-­‐Cold  War  era  for  the  following  four  reasons.  Firstly  Kirshner  (1997)  

explains  that  although  conflicts  between  Eastern  and  Western  European  countries  are  likely  to  

increase,  these  conflicts  will  almost  certainly  be  fought  with  economic  tools  as  opposed  to  military  

techniques  as  a  consequence  of  the  democratization  process.  Furthermore,  due  to  the  collapse  of  

communism  the  number  of  small  market  economies  has  increased  and  thereby  the  number  of  states  

that  are  vulnerable  to  economic  coercion  increased  (Kirshner,  1997).  Thirdly,  many  great  democratic  

powers  such  as  US,  Japan,  Germany  appear  reluctant  to  use  force  to  resolve  conflicts  since  they  

prefer  to  settle  disputes  in  a  more  peaceful  manner  (Kirshner,  1997;  Cox  and  Drury,  2006).  Fourthly,  

Kirshner  (1997)  explains  that  due  to  the  lack  of  urgency  that  was  related  to  many  Cold  War  crises,  

states  are  likely  to  apply  economic  sanctions  as  an  early  method  to  affect  the  conflict  whereby  the  

use  of  force  is  only  brought  in  as  a  last  resort.  

Page 11: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

11    

2.3  Types  of  economic  sanctions      Similar  to  the  variety  of  objectives  of  economic  sanctions,  the  types  of  economic  sanctions  are  also  

various  and  numerous.  For  the  sake  of  clarity  this  section  briefly  touches  upon  the  most  common  

types  of  economic  sanctions.    

Marinov  (2005)  states  that  coercive  measures  vary  a  lot  in  scope  and  intensity.  Some  are  relatively  

mild  like  partial  withholding  of  economic  aid,  while  others  are  much  harsher  like  a  comprehensive  

trade  boycott  (Marinov,  2005).  Such  comprehensive  trade  boycott  is  in  general  referred  to  as  an  

embargo  and  is  considered  as  a  complete  prohibition  of  commerce  and  trade  with  a  particular  

country  or  group  of  countries  (Greenwood,  2012).    Kirshner  (1997)  argues  that  due  to  the  fact  that  each  particular  case  has  different  goals  and  

constraints  it  is  useful  to  differentiate  economic  sanctions.  Kirshner  (1997)  argues  that  since  

economic  sanctions  have  distinct  characteristics  varying  over  robustness,  publicity  and  speed  making  

one  kind  of  economic  sanction  not  uniformly  better  or  worse  than  others.  According  to  Kirshner  

(1997)  economic  sanctions  take  five  general  forms:  Firstly,  the  so  called  trade  restrictions  that  are  

most  common  in  use  and  disrupt  trade,  finance,  currency,  and  trading  in  assets  of  the  target  state.  

These  trade  restrictions  are  further  divided  into  export  sanctions  and  import  sanctions  (Kirshner,  

1997).  Another  form  of  economic  diplomacy  is  aid,  which  has  been  employed  to  advance  political  

goals  and  has  traditionally  been  seen  as  a  mechanism  for  maintaining  alliances  (Kirshner,  1997).  

Kirshner  (1997)  refers  to  it  as  a  positive  economic  sanction  that  is  quite  popular  because  of  its  

exchangeability  for  things  like  basing  rights,  for  instance  for  oil  or  mining  companies,  and  other  

privileges.  Thirdly,  a  relatively  modern  instrument  of  sender  states  to  influence  a  target  is  to  

manipulate  international  financial  relations  of  the  target  state  (Kirshner,  1997).  Kirshner  (1997)  

clarifies  that  financial  sanctions  can  involve  the  withdrawal  of  either  loans  or  investments,  but  both  

techniques  aim  to  restrict  the  flow  of  financial  resources  to  the  target  and  thereby  increase  pressure  

on  the  target.  Fourthly,  Kirshner  (1997)  mentions  monetary  sanctions  that  aim  to  destabilize  the  

stability  and  value  of  the  target  state's  currency.  Monetary  sanctions  have  been  used  in  a  

considerable  amount  of  cases  with  dramatic  consequences  for  the  target  due  to  its  real  economic  

effects  like  increasing  inflation  and  debt  burdens,  and  upsetting  public  and  private  economic  

planning  (Kirshner,  1997).  For  instance,  the  ability  of  the  US  to  force  the  withdrawal  of  Great  Britain  

during  the  Suez  War  of  1956  by  exploiting  the  weakness  of  the  pound  is  an  example  of  a  threat  of  a  

monetary  sanction  (Kirshner,  1997,  II).  Fifthly,  Kirshner  (1997)  mentions  the  least  commonly  used  

form  of  economic  sanctions,  the  seizure  of  a  target's  assets.  This  can  take  the  form  of  physical  

property,  securities  and  bank  accounts  in  order  to  prevent  the  target  from  accessing  them  (Kirshner,  

Page 12: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

12    

1997).  Furthermore  in  extreme  cases,  such  as  wartime,  ownership  of  the  assets  can  be  transferred  

from  the  target  to  the  sender  state  as  part  of  a  strategy  to  weaken  the  opponent  or  providing  

leverage  to  influence  the  target  (Kirshner,  1997).    

In  a  more  general  way,  Pape  (1997)  categorizes  international  economic  sanctions  into  two  main  

categories,  trade  restrictions  and  financial  restrictions,  each  of  which  can  be  employed  with  varying  

intensity  and  scope.  In  order  to  be  more  effective,  economic  sanctions  can  be  employed  on  a  

personal  base,  for  instance  freezing  the  personal  assets  of  political,  military  and/or  economic  leaders  

in  rogue  states  (Elliot  and  Huffbauer,  1999).  Recent  effective  types  of  economic  coercion  in  the  case  

of  Iran  are  the  increase  of  trade  costs,  restrictions  on  cross  border  imports  of  financial  and  transport  

services  and  eventually  a  full  embargo  (Ianchovichina  et  al.,  2016)    

2.4  Effectiveness  of  economic  sanctions      This  section  gives  an  overview  of  the  broad  literature  on  the  effectiveness  of  economic  sanctions.  In  

order  to  state  anything  insightful  about  effectiveness  it  is  important  to  understand  what  the  

objectives  of  a  sender  state  were  at  forehand.  Therefore  to  evaluate  effectiveness,  Barber's  (1979)  

framework  of  objectives  is  useful  to  differentiate  between  'primary  objectives'  and  'secondary  

objectives'.  To  simplify,  if  economic  sanctions  are  imposed  for  primary  objectives  the  aim  is  to  shift  

the  target's  behaviour  towards  a  more  favourable  policy  for  the  sender  state,  therefore  these  

economic  sanctions  are  also  referred  to  as  'instrumental'  tools  of  foreign  policy  (Barber,  1979).  If  

economic  sanctions  serve  secondary  objectives  they  concern  the  status,  reputation  and  position  of  

the  government(s)  imposing  them,  thereby  serving  a  more  symbolic  purpose  (Barber,  1979).  In  the  

case  of  'tertiary  objectives',  the  structuring  and  behaviour  of  international  bodies,  evaluation  of  

effectiveness  is  too  hard  to  measure  since  the  range  of  factors  to  be  taken  into  account  is  so  large  

that  it  is  impossible  to  isolate  the  particular  part  played  by  the  economic  sanctions  (Barber  1979).  

Therefore  this  section  focuses  on  the  effectiveness  of  instrumental  and  symbolic  economic  

sanctions.    

Wagner  (1988)  refers  to  a  situation  whereby  two  countries  have  trade  relations  and  the  large  

country,  with  a  relatively  smaller  stake  in  the  common  trade  than  the  small  country,  wants  to  bend  

the  small  country  into  a  different  policy  by  threatening  with  the  use  of  economic  sanctions.  In  this  

case  there  is  an  asymmetrical  interdependence,  because  of  the  different  relative  stakes  that  the  

trade  relation  has,  and  the  threat  or  use  of  economic  sanctions  could  in  theory  be  effective  (Wagner,  

1988).  Nevertheless,  Wagner  (1988)  argues  that  in  such  case  economic  sanctions  are  seldom  an    

effective  instrument  for  foreign  policy  for  the  following  two  reasons.  Firstly,  Wagner  (1988)  argues  

Page 13: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

13    

that  one  of  the  most  important  reasons  that  the  economic  sanction  is  not  effective  is  because  the  

commitment  of  the  weaker/smaller/target  state  can  be  much  greater  than  the  bigger  sender  state,  

and  the  target  state  is  more  willing  to  suffer.  Another  argument  that  Wagner  (1988)  refers  to  is  that  

the  cost  of  the  target  state  to  agree  upon  the  terms  of  the  sender  state  can  be  higher  than  the  

possible  burden  of  the  economic  sanctions.  In  such  case  the  expected  costs  of  an  economic  sanction  

is  too  small  to  change  the  target's  policy.  Furthermore,  Hovi  et  al.  (2005)  argue  that  if  economic  

sanctions  are  installed  unilaterally,  the  target  might  reduce  the  effects  by  moving  to  other  clients  or  

suppliers,  and  by  employing  other  counterstrategies  such  as  rationing,  stockpiling,  import  

substitution  and  if  necessary  smuggling.    

Bergeijk  (1989)  agrees  that  quite  generally  economic  sanctions  are  ineffective,  but  for  different  

reasons.  Bergeijk  (1989)  argues  that  economic  sanctions  like  trade  restrictions  and/or  embargoes  are  

ineffective  since  it  is  practically  impossible  to  create  the  necessary  political  unity  for  a  forceful  

embargo,  and  even  if  embargoes  are  established  they  are  easy  to  circumvent.  This  might  explain  

why  Elliot  (1998)  claims  that  in  the  early  post-­‐World  War  II  era  economic  sanctions  were  a  relatively  

effective  tool  of  US  foreign  policy.  During  that  period,  from  1945  to  1970,  the  US  had  a  political  and  

economic  hegemony  making  US  economic  sanctions  at  least  a  partial  success  in  half  of  the  cases  

(Elliot,  1998).  As  a  result  of  the  increasing  international  economic  integration,  economic  sanctions  by  

the  US  decreased  in  effectiveness  since  target  countries  had  more  alternatives  to  trade  with  (Elliot,  

1998).  Furthermore,  Bergeijk  (1989)  mentions  that  the  plausibility  of  a  change  in  behaviour  as  a  

consequence  of  economic  sanctions  is  doubtful  since  the  target  can  have  strong  incentives  not  to  

comply.  Bergeijk  (1989)  mentions  that  one  of  the  incentives  not  to  comply  is  the  fear  of  losing  face  

by  the  target's  leadership.  Since  economic  sanctions  are  public  measures,  compliance  may  damage  

the  target  leadership's  international  prestige  or  diminish  the  leadership's  domestic  support  (Bergeijk,    

1989).    Pape  (1997)  argues  that  the  target's  leadership  can  misuse  the  economic  sanctions  that  are  imposed  

to  stimulate  nationalistic  feelings  among  the  target's  country  population.  By  framing  the  economic  

sanctions  to  the  population  as  a  foreign  threat  the  target's  government  can  even  strengthen  its  own  

position  making  the  economic  sanctions  counterproductive  (Pape,  1997).  Pape  (1997)  argues  that  

this  pervasive  nationalism  can  result  in  the  fact  that  states  and  societies  are  willing  to  undergo  

substantial  punishment  as  well  economic  damage  rather  than  leave  what  is  framed  as  the  interests  

of  the  nation.  Pape  (1997)  refers  to  this  phenomenon  as  the  'dance  around  the  flag',  and  this  trend  

may  be  seen  nowadays  in  Putin's  Russia  after  the  international  criticism  as  a  result  of  the  annexation  

of  the  Crimea.  

Page 14: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

14    

Another  reason  why  economic  sanctions  are  ineffective  as  instrumental  tools  is  that  modern  states  

have  administrative  capabilities  to  mitigate  and/or  transfer  the  damage  done  by  economic  sanctions  

(Pape,  1997).  For  instance,  in  the  case  of  a  monetary  sanction  whereby  the  national  currency  of  a  

target  is  depreciated,  the  target  government  can  buy  its  own  currency  to  undo  the  depreciation.  

Furthermore,  Pape  (1997)  argues  that  in  case  of  economic  damage  is  done  by  sanctions,  the  target's  

government  is  still  capable  to  protect  itself  and  its  supporters  by  shifting  the  economic  burden  to  

opponents  or  disenfranchised  groups.  For  instance,  in  case  of  an  economic  sanction  like  freezing  

assets  of  a  target  that  hurts  the  ruling  elite,  the  ruling  elite  might  be  able  to  transfer  the  burden  to  

the  population  by  raising  taxes  or  reducing  subsidies.  Major  and  McGann  (2005)  explain  that  if  costs  

are  transferred  to  other  groups  the  economic  sanctions  are  not  likely  to  be  effective  since  those  

groups  are  potential  agents  of  change  within  the  target  state.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  costs  of  

sanctions  are  borne  by  groups  that  do  have  the  ability  to  change  policy  but  are  unwilling  to  do  so,  

the  economic  sanction  will  be  ineffective  as  well  (Major  and  McGann,  2005).    On  the  other  hand,  Hovi  et  al.  (2005)  argue  that  economic  sanctions  can  be  effective  under  certain  

conditions.  According  to  Hovi  et  al.  (2005),  economic  sanctions  can  be  effective  only  if  the  target  

country  initially  underrates  the  consequences,  miscalculates  the  sender's  determination  to  impose  

them,  or  wrongly  believes  that  economic  sanctions  would  be  imposed  and  maintained  irrespectively  

of  the  target's  behaviour.  Before  an  economic  sanction  is  imposed,  the  sender  state  usually  threatens  

to  do  so,  if  the  target  does  not  comply  to  its  demands  (Hovi  et  al.,  2005).  Hovi  et  al.  (2005)  explain  

that  this  threat  should  bear  the  following   three  elements  in  it:  credibility  in  the  eyes  of  the  target,  

the  threat  should  be  potent,  meaning  that  the  costs  of  sanctions  for  the  target  outweighs  yielding,  

and  the  threat  should  be  non-­‐contingent,  meaning  that  the  economic  sanctions  will  not  be  installed  if  

the  target  complies  to  the  sender's  demands.  In  the  situation  where  the  target  has  complete  

information  and  the  threat  of  an  economic  sanction  does  not  make  the  target  yield,  nor  will  the  

imposition  of  the  economic  sanction  do  so  since  policymakers  made  an  informed  decision  (Hovi  et  al.,  

2005).  On  the  contrary,  economic  sanctions  can  only  be  effective  if  the  target's  policymakers  

misinterpreted  at  least  one  of  the  three  factors,  namely  credibility,  potency  and  non-­‐  contingency,  of  

the  sender's  threat  (Hovi  et  al.,  2005).  In  spite  of  the  fact  that  this  reasoning  is  highly  intuitive,  in  fact  

it  represents  something  completely  new  in  the  literature  on  economic  sanctions  (Hovi  et  al.,  2005)    Marinov  (2005)  looks  at  the  effectiveness  of  economic  sanctions  via  the  destabilizing  effect  they  can  

have  on  the  target's  government.  The  reasoning  behind  this  is  that  sender  states  impose  economic  

sanctions  if  the  target  does  not  yield  to  the  sender's  demands  to  weaken  the  target's  government  in  

the  hope  the  target  will  eventually  change  their  policy  (Marinov,  2005).  Marinov  (2005)  shows,  by  

Page 15: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

15    

using  panel  date  on  136  countries  over  an  average  of  37  years,  that  the  presence  of  economic  

sanctions  in  a  given  year  makes  it  significantly  more  likely  that  the  target's  government  will  lose  

power  in  the  following  year.  In  a  number  of  cases,  the  entrance  of  new  leaders  has  brought  a  policy  

change  in  favour  of  the  sender  country  and  makes  it  more  likely  that  economic  sanctions  are  lifted  

(Marinov,  2005).  Marinov  (2005)  argues  that  imposed  economic  sanctions  increase  the  baseline  risk  

of  losing  power  by  28%  for  the  target  government.    Numerous  scholars  refer  to  the  study  by  Hufbauer,  Schott  and  Elliot  of  1985,  that  was  later  revisited  

in  1990,  (hereafter  HSE)  as  key  evidence  that  economic  sanctions  can  achieve  ambitious  foreign  

policy  goals.  HSE  published  the  first  empirical  large  N-­‐study  of  economic  sanctions,  reviewing  

economic  sanctions  from  1914  to  1990  and  identifying  115  cases  in  total  of  which  they  reported  40  

cases  as  a  success.  This  35%  of  success  rate  of  economic  sanctions  was  much  higher  than  most  

scholars  expected,  and  in  many  cases  the  use  of  economic  sanctions  is  to  be  viewed  as  a  credible  

alternative  to  military  force  (Hufbaeur  et  al.,  1990).  Hovi  et  al.  (2005)  argue  that  the  HSE  study  is  also  

the  most  important  attempt  to  point  out  the  conditions  for  effective  economic  sanctions.  Hufbauer  et  

al.  (1990)  conclude  that  economic  sanctions  work  best  if  the  following  eight  conditions  are  met:  

(1)  the  goals  of  the  sender  are  limited,  (2)  the  target  is  already  experiencing  economic  difficulties,  (3)    

there  are  generally  friendly  relations  and/or  trade  relations  between  sender  and  target  countries,  (4)    

sanctions  are  forcefully  implemented  in  a  single  step  so  that  the  target  does  not  have  the  

opportunity  to  adapt  itself,  (5)  sanctions  entail  significant  costs  for  the  target,  (6)  the  costs  for  

sender  countries  are  modest,  (7)  the  sanctions  are  not  accompanied  by  covert  action  or  military  

operations,  (8)  few  countries  are  needed  to  implement  the  economic  sanctions.    

As  a  response  on  the  HSE  study,  Pape  (1997)  argues  in  his  article  'Why  economic  sanctions  do  not  

work'  that  the  HSE  study  is  seriously  flawed.  Pape's  (1997)  standard  of  judging  the  success  of  

economic  sanctions  requires  three  criteria.  Firstly,  that  the  target  state  concede  to  'a  significant  part  

of  the  sender's  demands'  (Pape,  1997).  Secondly,  economic  sanctions  were  threatened  and/or  

actually  applied  before  the  target  changed  its  behaviour  (Pape,  1997).  If  this  is  not  the  case  the  

change  of  behaviour  can  also  be  a  result  of  any  other  cause.  Finally,  no  other  plausible  explanation  

exists  for  the  target's  change  of  behaviour  (Pape,  1997).  These  criterion  do  not  allow  for  gradations  

in  the  degree  or  kind  of  success  (Baldwin  and  Pape,  1998).  Pape  (1997)  claims  that  practically  none  of  

the  40  cases  that  are  claimed  as  a  success  of  economic  sanctions  in  the  HSE  study  stands  up  this  type  

of  examination.  Pape  (1997)  outlines  that  eighteen  cases  were  actually  settled  by  direct  or  indirect  

use  of  force,  in  eight  cases  there  is  no  evidence  that  the  target  made  the  demanded  concessions,  six  

cases  do  not  qualify  as  instances  of  economic  sanctions  and  three  cases  are  indeterminate.  This  

leaves  the  HSE  study  with  only  five  out  of  115  cases  that  can  be  considered  

Page 16: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

16    

effective  (Pape,  1997).  Since  in  very  few  of  the  cases  the  criteria  of  an  economic  sanction  are  

verified,  Pape  (1997)  claims  economic  sanctions  to  be  ineffective.    

Kirshner  (2007)  argues  that  although  economic  sanctions  fail  to  change  a  target's  policy  as  the  sender  

demands,  they  may  be  successful  along  in  serving  secondary  objectives,  complement  other  policies,  

and  remain  an  appropriate  policy  instrument.  Morgan  and  Swebach  (1997)  state  that  economic  

sanctions  continue  to  be  applied  in  a  variety  of  contexts,  yet  we  have  not  developed  a  sufficient  

understanding  of  the  processes  involved  to  determine  when,  or  even  if,  sanctions  can  work.  

According  to  Gordon  (1983),  in  general  there  is  little  evidence  indicating  that  economic  sanctions  

alone  have  been  effective  in  past  instances.  Though  some  have  argued  that  the  main  function  of  

sanctions  is  symbolic  or  to  serve  the  domestic  political  interest  of  the  sanctioning  state  and  that  

sanctions  have  often  served  these  ends  (Gordon,  1983).  This  symbolic  function  of  economic  

sanctions  might  explain  why  policymakers  often  seem  to  hold  contradictory  views  to  scholars  and  do  

impose  economic  sanctions  on  a  frequent  base  (Nossal,  1989).  Nossal  (1989)  states  that  with  the  

ongoing  debate  about  the  effectiveness,  economic  sanctions  as  an  instrument  of  foreign  policy  have  

become  more  and  more  controversial.  Therefore,  Nossal  (1989)  outlines  that  it  is  perhaps  not  

surprising  that  much  of  the  literature  on  economic  sanctions  focuses  on  a  dominant  puzzle:  if  

sanctions  do  not  work,  why  do  states  continue  to  impose  them?  Lindsay  (1986)  provides  a  possible  

answer  to  this  question  by  outlining  the  broad  objectives  of  economic  sanctions,  to  be  known  as  

compliance,  subversion,  deterrence,  international  symbolism  and  domestic  symbolism.  Both  

compliance  and  subversion  can  be  categorized  in  primary  objectives,  while  the  latter  two  are  

examples  of  secondary  objectives.  Deterrence  is  hard  to  put  into  one  of  these  two  categories,  since  

both  instrumental  sanctions  as  international  symbolism  can  deter  other  states.  In  general,  it  seems  

to  be  that  economic  sanctions  are  quite  effective  in  serving  a  secondary  objective  as  a  symbolic  

function,  and  they  can  often  be  useful  in  support  of  other  policy  initiatives  (Daoudi  and  Dajani,  1983;  

Baldwin,  1985;  Lindsay,  1986;  Nossal,  1989).    Section  2  has  aimed  to  present  an  overview  of  the  most  relevant  concepts  and  underlying  principles  

of  economic  sanctions.  The  different  objectives,  construction  and  trends,  types  and  effectiveness  of  

economic  sanctions  were  outlined  to  get  a  better  understanding  of  the  notion  of  economic  

sanctions.  Section  3  outlines  the  development  of  the  French-­‐Israeli  relationship  from  1948  to  1967,  

prior  to  the  French  weapon  embargo.  

Page 17: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

17    

Section  3:  The  development  of  the  French-­‐Israeli  relationship  

from  1948  to  1967    

To  understand  the  effects  of  the  French  weapon  embargo  of  1967  it  is  important  to  gather  a  better  

understanding  of  the  French-­‐Israeli  relationship  before  and  at  that  time,  as  well  the  condition  and  

development  of  the  Israeli  military  industry.  Therefore  section  3.1  focuses  on  the  French  arms  policy  

to  the  Middle  East  from  1948  to  1967,  and  section  3.2  outlines  the  early  development  of  Israel's  

military  industry  up  to  1967.    

3.1  French  arms  policy  to  the  Middle  East  from  1948  to  1967      According  to  Kolodziej  (1980),  to  understand  the  direction  and  scope  of  French  arms  sales  policy  and  

decisions  with  regards  to  the  Middle  East  we  have  to  take  into  account  three  factors.  Firstly,  French  

arms  sales  decisions  are  based  on  the  regional  and  global  security  issues  and  the  efforts  of  the  

French  governments  to  influence  and  adapt  France  to  this  environment.  Furthermore,  the  economic  

incentives  that  encourage  an  open  arms  transfer  policy  play  an  important  role  in  decisions  made  by  

the  French  government.  Thirdly,  the  decision  power  of  a  political  figure  and  his/her  preferences  to  

influence  the  transfer  of  production,  arms  and  knowhow  to  Israel  or  any  Arab  state  (Kolodziej,  

1980).    This  section  looks  into  the  three  factors  mentioned  above  that  vary  over  time  and  provides  insights  

in  the  French-­‐Israeli  relationship  prior  to  the  weapon  embargo  of  1967.  The  French  foreign  policy  

towards  the  Middle  East  from  1948  to  1967  is  mainly  influenced  by  four  events,  which  are  

distinguished.  At  first,  the  Tripartite  Declaration  of  1950,  secondly  the  Suez  War  of  1956,  thirdly  the  

nuclear  ambition  of  both  countries  and  finally  the  Six-­‐Day  War  of  1967.    

3.1.1  The  Tripartite  Declaration  of  May  1950    During  the  Nazi  occupation  of  France  powerful  political  and  military  connections  had  been  made  

because  of  the  Jewish  exploits  within  the  Résistance  and  in  the  Free  French  Forces  (Crosbie,  1974).  

Due  to  this,  a  large  number  of  Jewish  leaders  could  count  on  the  support  of  leading  figures  in  the  

first  Gaullist  government,  1944-­‐1946  (Crosbie,  1974).  Crosbie  (1974)  states  that  in  1946,  Ben  Gurion  

and  other  Haganah  -­‐  Jewish  underground  defence  army  -­‐  leaders  established  their  headquarters  in  

Paris  with  the  tacit  acceptance  of  the  French  government.  During  a  meeting  in  Paris,  the  Zionist  

Directory  openly  collected  money  to  purchase  arms,  while  the  police  closed  their  eyes  for  the  

comings  and  goings  of  underground  leaders  (Crosbie,  1974).  According  to  Crosbie  (1974),  it  is  in  

Page 18: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

18    

large  part  due  to  the  personal  relations  and  effective  diplomacy  that  the  Haganah  combed  France  

for  arms  and  ammunition  right  after  WWII.  The  ties  were  even  so  close  that  one  of  the  French  

Zionist  leaders,  Blumel,  flew  to  Prague  in  a  plane  at  the  disposal  of  the  French  government  to  

negotiate  for  arms  (Bar  Zohar,  1964).  Crosbie  (1974)  states  that  it  was  also  with  the  help  of  French  

financial  sources  that  Israel  bought  airplanes  and  twenty  light  aircraft  guns.  The  Résistance  became  a    

major  source  of  weapons  and  by  a  secret  agreement  of  the  French  forces  that  withdrew  from  Syria,  

much  of  their  equipment  like  ancient  tanks  and  other  weaponry  found  their  ways  into  Jewish  hands  

(Crosbie,  1974).    

Immediately  after  Israel  declared  its  independence,  on  May  14  1948,  France  worked  on  a  policy  of  

military  and  scientific  cooperation  with  the  new  state  (Crosbie,  1974).  Yet  the  official  position  of  the  

French  government  at  that  time  was  pro-­‐Arab,  designed  to  maintain  some  measure  of  French  

influence  in  the  Arab  heartland  (Crosbie,  1974).  According  to  Crosbie  (1974),  this  apparent  

contradiction  in  French  foreign  policy  is  largely  explained  by  the  difficulties  that  afflicted  the  

government  of  the  Fourth  Republic:  authority  was  fragmented  and  the  execution  of  policies  often  

sporadic,  inconsistent  and  hesitant  while  responsibility  was  diffused.  Crosbie  (1974)  illustrates  that  

generally  each  minister  treated  his  ministry  as  an  independent  domain,  whereby  the  Minister  of  

Defence  and  the  Interior  Minister  executed  divergent  policies.  When  it  came  to  the  question  of  

support  for  Israel  and  reached  the  Prime  Minister  usually  the  matter  was  decided  in  favour  of  Israel  

(Crosbie,  1974).    

Although  in  the  early  part  of  1949  Israel  and  the  Arab  states  had  concluded  an  armistice  agreement  

that  put  an  end  to  the  1948  Arab-­‐Israeli  conflict,  by  mid-­‐1949  Israeli  concern  was  growing  over  the  

emergence  of  a  Middle  East  arms  race  (Slonim,  1987).  In  fact,  Arab  leaders  were  increasingly  calling  

for  a  'second  round'  of  fighting  to  eliminate  the  Jewish  state  and  Arab  governments  tried  to  obtain  

vast  quantities  of  arms  that  were  intended  for  a  new  military  campaign  (Slonim,  1987).  In  order  to  

deescalate  the  rising  tension  it  was  necessary  to  prohibit  a  Middle  Eastern  arms  race,  for  which  the  

Tripartite  Declaration  was  designed  (Slonim,  1987).  The  Tripartite  Declaration  was  a  joint  statement,  

signed  on  May  25  1950,  by  the  US,  Great  Britain  and  France  to  preserve  the  status  quo  in  the  Middle  

East  and  thereby  stating  their  opposition  to  the  development  of  an  arms  race  (Bickerton  and  

Klausner,  2005).  According  to  Tal  (2009),  the  declaration  outlined  the  parties'  opposition  to  the  use  

or  threat  of  force  and  their  commitment  to  peace  and  stability  in  the  area,  as  well  as  a  pledge  to  

take  action  to  prevent  violations  of  the  frontiers.  Although  peace  in  the  region  may  not  have  been  

the  main  priority  for  the  parties,  they  did  at  least  aim  at  preserving  the  status  quo  and  preventing  

the  Arab-­‐Israel  arms  race  from  eluding  Western  control  (Crosbie,  1974).  Besides  the  trade  restriction    

of  arms  to  the  Middle  East  the  Tripartite  Declaration  also  served  a  so-­‐called  tertiary  objective,  

Page 19: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

19    

namely  the  structuring  of  an  alliance  between  three  great  Western  powers.  Crosbie  (1974)  argues  

that  the  main  interest  of  France  in  deescalating  the  tensions  in  the  region  was  because  France  

controlled  Algeria,  Tunisia  and  Morocco,  and  traditionally  had  great  influence  in  Syria.  The  Tripartite  

Declaration  stated:    

"The  three  governments  recognize  that  the  Arab  states  and  Israel  all  need  to  maintain  a  

certain  level  of  armed  forces  for  the  purposes  of  legitimate  self-­‐defence  of  the  area  as  a  

whole.  All  applications  for  arms  or  war  materials  for  those  countries  will  be  considered  in  the  

light  of  these  principles"  (US  Department  of  State,  1950).    

Due  to  the  Near  Eastern  Arms  Coordinating  Committee  (NEACC),  that  handled  requests  for  arms  

under  the  terms  of  the  declaration,  there  was  a  relatively  controlled  and  balanced  flow  of  arms  to  

the  area  from  1950  to  1954  (Crosbie,  1974).  Although  Steinberg  (1998)  argues  that  the  declaration  

did  not  prevent  the  Arab  states  from  obtaining  weapons  through  their  relationships  with  the  Soviet  

Union,  that  was  not  part  of  the  Tripartite  Declaration,  so  that  effectively  Israel  was  the  only  one  

excluded.  On  the  other  hand,  since  the  declaration  was  initiated  by  the  US  and  Great  Britain,  and  

France  was  invited  to  join  in,  consequently  France  was  less  committed  to  the  declaration  and  found  

it  relatively  easy  to  abandon  the  declaration  when  its  national  security  or  economic  interests  

justified  this  (Tal,  2009).  It  is  important  to  outline  that  over  the  past  decades  France  had  developed  a  

significant  and  highly  successful  arms  industry,  for  a  big  part  based  on  the  export  of  arms  (Major,  

2008).  Still  today  France  belongs  to  the  biggest  arms  producers  in  the  world  and  the  French  arms  

industry  has  a  large  influence  on  France'  economy  (Major,  2008).    According  to  Tal  (2009),  France  struggled  to  uphold  its  position  in  the  Middle  East,  especially  in  Syria.  

Its  unofficial  alliance  with  Syria  placed  France  in  a  hostile  position  towards  Iraq,  Britain's  ally,  which  

had  the  idea  for  a  'Greater  Syria'  that  would  terminate  the  French  hold  over  Syria  (Tal,  2009).  When  in  

1954  a  pro-­‐France  Syrian  colonel  was  replaced  and  about  the  same  time  the  Arab  League  announced  

to  support  the  Algerian  opposition  to  France,  France’s  focus  shifted  to  North  Africa  (Tal,  

2009).  France  took  an  anti-­‐Egyptian  course,  since  it  blamed  the  Egyptian  President  Nasser  of  inciting  

Algerian  rebellion  against  France  (Tal,  2009).  According  to  Tal  (2009),  Israel  and  France  now  had  

mutual  interests  in  the  region,  to  take  stand  against  President  Nasser.  This  mutual  interest  served  as  

the  major  incentive  for  the  French  government  for  a  significant  increase  in  arms  sales  in  1954–1955  

towards  Israel  (Tal,  2009).    

According  to  Steinberg  (1998),  it  was  the  'Czech  arms  deal'  in  September  1955,  in  which  the  Soviet  

Union  sold  modern  weaponry  consisting  of  200  tanks  and  nearly  100  fighter  jets  for  $250  million  to  

Egypt,  that  broke  the  Western  control  over  the  flow  of  arms  to  the  area  and  made  the  declaration  

Page 20: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

20    

collapse.  The  consensus  within  the  French  government  was  that  Egypt  was  the  main  source  of  aid  for  

the  Arab  nationalistic  movement  during  the  Algerian  War  of  Independence  from  1954  to  1962  

(Evron,  1970).  As  a  response  the  French  government  increased  the  sale  of  planes  and  heavy    

weapons  to  Israel  in  April  1956  to  counter  the  Soviet  Union's  arms  supply  of  Egypt  (Steinberg,  1998).  

According  to  Evron  (1970),  both  Israel  and  France  now  had  identical  interests  with  regards  to  Egypt.  

The  French  government  saw  the  link  with  Israel  as  the  base  of  an  informal  alliance  that  was  formed  in  

order  to  depose  the  Egyptian  President  Nasser  (Evron,  1970).  Evron  (1970)  argues  that  this  

military  cooperation  took  an  unprecedented  level  and  secured  a  large  export  market  for  France  since  

the  entire  Israeli  air  force  had  been  built  up  with  French  fighter  jets.  At  this  stage  France  was  seen  as  

the  closest  ally  of  Israel  (Pinkus,  2002).  According  to  Rubenberg  (1998),  President  Nasser,  as  a  

response  to  the  increase  in  arms  sales  between  France  and  Israel,  nationalized  the  French-­‐controlled  

Suez  canal  on  July  1956.  Thereby  prohibiting  Israeli  shipping  through  the  Straits  of  Tiran,  a  vital  link  

for  Israel’s  imports  and  exports  to  the  rest  of  the  world  (Rubenberg,  1998).    3.1.2  The  Suez  War  from  October  29  to  November  7  1956    Since  the  establishment  of  Israel  in  1948,  cargo  shipments  to  and  from  Israel  via  the  Strait  of  Tiran  

had  been  subjected  to  Egyptian  approval  (ElBaradei,  1982).  The  Egyptian  authorities  controlled  the  

goods  while  attempting  to  pass  through  the  Suez  Canal  (ElBaradei,  1982).  Besides  this  Egyptian  

control  of  goods,  Nasser  encouraged  the  Fedayeen,  Palestinian  nationalistic  militants,  to  attack  on  

Israeli  soldiers  and  civilians  (Azar,  1972).  The  French  had  their  own  reasons  to  oppose  Nasser,  whom  

actively  incited  the  Algerian  rebels  in  their  battle  against  France  and  through  the  shipment  of  arms  

(Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  Crosbie  (1974)  outlines  that  when  the  Algerian  struggle  for  

independence  erupted  in  violence,  on  November  1  1954,  France  was  afraid  that  the  Arab  nationalist  

movements  would  force  the  end  of  French  presence  in  the  region  and  would  remove  once  and  for  all  

any  illusions  that  France  could  retain  its  position  as  a  global  power.  French  Prime  Minister  of  the  

Fourth  Republic  from  1957  until  1958,  Mollet,  saw  the  removal  of  Nasser  as  the  best  way  to  protect  

French  interests  in  the  region  and  Israel  and  France  had  mutual  animosity  towards  Egypt  (Bickerton  

and  Klausner,  2005).  The  remnants  of  French  influence  in  Syria  had  further  declined,  French  interest  

in  Tunisia  and  Morocco  eroded  progressively  and  the  threat  of  a  pan  Islamic  danger  to  French  Sub-­‐  

Saharan  Africa  rode  with  the  spectre  of  a  hostile  coalition  on  France's  exposed  southern  flank  

(Crosbie,  1974).    

Another  important  aspect  was  that  around  50%  of  French  oil  was  imported  through  the  Suez  Canal  

and  France  feared  that  Nasser,  by  controlling  the  Suez  Canal,  might  use  his  power  against  France  

(Crosbie,  1974).  Also  for  the  British  the  Suez  Canal  was  still  the  most  important  gateway  as  well  of  

Page 21: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

21    

strategic  importance  to  their  oil  interests  in  the  Persian  Gulf  (Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  The  

British  were  also  concerned  about  Nasser's  policy  to  destabilize  the  region,  in  particular  because  of  

big  interests  and  military  presence  in  Jordan,  and  agreed  to  take  action  on  Nasser  (Bickerton  and  

Klausner,  2005).  By  nationalizing  the  Suez  Canal  on  July  26  1956  Nasser  supplied  France  the  excuse  

for  intervention  that  it  sought  already  (Crosbie,  1974).  An  alliance  between  Great  Britain,  France  and  

Israel  was  set  up  to  prepare  for  war  with  Egypt  and  on  July  29  French  defence  officials  began  formal  

contingency  planning  with  Israeli  air  and  naval  forces  and  exchanged  personnel  with  Israel  to  secure  

the  flow  of  information  (Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  For  instance,  Israeli  pilots  received  intensive  

training  on  the  French  aircrafts  during  the  preparations  of  the  Suez  invasion  (Crobsie,  1974).    

From  October  22  to  27  French  war  material  was  brought  into  Israel  for  the  preparation  of  the  

planned  Suez  invasion.  Some  of  the  equipment,  consisting  of  more  than  100  planes,  200  tanks  and  

200  army  trucks,  was  paid  for  at  commercial  rates  while  part  of  the  supply  was  a  gift  to  Israel  

(Crosbie,  1974).  On  October  29,  Israel  invaded  the  Sinai  followed  by  an  ultimatum  for  Egypt  to  

withdraw  ten  miles  on  either  side  of  the  Suez  Canal,  issued  by  France  and  Britain  (Rubenberg,  1998).  

As  expected,  Nasser  rejected  the  ultimatum  and  this  provided  France  and  Britain  with  an  excuse  to  

"intervene  in  such  strength  as  was  necessary"  (Rubenberg,  1998).  Therefore  British  and  French  

troops  landed  along  the  canal  and  by  November  7  the  coordinated  campaign  was  completed  

(Rubenberg,  1998).    From  a  military  perspective  the  Suez  War  can  be  seen  as  a  victory  for  the  French-­‐British-­‐Israeli  

alliance,  but  from  a  political  perspective  it  was  not  successful  for  French  and  British  esteem  within  

the  international  community  (Farr,  1999).  At  the  end  of  the  Suez  War  Israel  was  in  command  of  the  

Gaza  strip,  where  the  bases  of  Fedayeen  terrorism  were,  and  the  entire  Sinai  up  to  ten  miles  from  

the  Suez  Canal  thereby  affording  control  over  entry  to  the  Strait  of  Tiran  (Rubenberg,  1998).  But  the  

French  and  British  attempts  to  move  South  along  the  Suez  Canal  was  stopped  due  to  fierce  pressure  

of  both  the  US  and  the  Soviet  Union  (Farr,  1999).  For  instance,  the  US  threatened  with  a  monetary  

sanction  to  exploit  the  weakness  of  the  pound  if  British  troops  would  not  withdrew  immediately  

(Kirshner,  1997,  II).  Both  for  Britain  and  France  this  was  a  tremendous  loss  of  face  that  showed  the  

new  world  order  and  hierarchy  (Farr,  1999).  For  Britain  the  situation  is  been  referred  to  as  'The  Lion's  

Last  Roar'  since  it  abruptly  decreased  the  British  influence  in  the  region,  specifically  in  Jordan  that  

was  inspired  by  Nasser's  idea  of  Arab  nationalism,  and  accelerated  the  process  of  decolonisation  

(Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  For  France,  the  Suez  War  had  an  immense  impact  on  French  

domestic  politics  since  much  of  the  French  army  officers  felt  betrayed  by  their  politicians  

(Sowerwine,  2009).  According  to  Sowerwine  (2009),  the  Suez  War  helped  to  set  the  stage  for  the  

military  disillusionment  with  the  Fourth  Republic,  which  contributed  to  the  collapse  of  the  Republic  

Page 22: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

22    

in  1958.  Besides  all  political  damage  France  was  cut  off  from  export  markets  in  the  Middle  East  

worth  of  51  billion  Francs  annually  and  lost  cultural  influence  and  prestige  in  the  region  (Crosbie,  

1974).  According  to  Crosbie  (1974),  at  this  stage  Israel  was  the  most  certain  and  solid  ally  of  the  

West  in  the  region,  but  the  alliance  came  with  big  consequences  for  France  and  Britain.  The  French  

support  for  Israel  was  repeated  in  public  by  Mollet  in  March  1957  during  a  foreign  policy  debate  

(Crosbie,  1974).  Mollet  stated  that  security  guarantees  for  Israel's  borders  as  well  free  navigation  

through  the  Suez  Canal  were  essential  and  that  France  was  committed  to  ensure  that  this  would  be  

respected  (Crosbie,  1974).  Egypt  agreed  to  the  stationing  of  a  United  Nations  Emergency  Force  

(UNEF)  in  the  Sinai  to  ensure  all  parties  would  comply  with  the  1949  Armistice  agreements  

(Rauschning  et  al.  1997).    

3.1.3  The  French–Israeli  nuclear  cooperation  from  1949  to  1957    The  French-­‐Israeli  nuclear  cooperation  between  1949  and  1957  originated  that  the  relationship  

moved  from  friendly  ambivalence  to  an  unwritten  alliance  (Pinkus,  2002).  Eventually  this  tacit  

alliance  led  to  far  reaching  cooperation  and  exclusive  friendship  in  some  of  the  most  sensitive  areas  

of  national  interest  (Pinkus,  2002).  This  'nuclear  connection'  was  initially  formed  right  after  the  

establishment  of  the  state  of  Israel  and  peaked  around  the  mid-­‐1950s  (Pinkus,  2002).    De  Gaulle,  the  national  figure  most  involved  in  developing  the  French  atomic  bomb,  realized  soon  

the  role  that  nuclear  power  would  play  in  international  relations  (Mongin,  1997).  De  Gaulle  stated,  

"From  this  point  on  there  would  be  two  classes  of  countries,  those  who  have  the  bomb  and  the  

others"  (Mongin,  1997).  According  to  Gaullist  doctrine,  the  capacity  of  a  state  to  remain  

independent  and  to  make  authoritative  judgement  for  other  states,  was  ultimately  based  on  its  

ability  to  enforce  them  (Koldziej,  1971).  Therefore  De  Gaulle  believed  that  France's  international  

authority  was  derived  from  its  own  military  power  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Kolodziej  (1971)  argues  that  

during  De  Gaulle's  second  period  as  the  head  of  French  government  from  1958  to  1968,  France's  

global  status  tended  to  be  identified  with  this  creation  of  a  nuclear  strike  force.  An  elaborate  

strategic  doctrine  developed  around  the  force  de  frappe  -­‐  strike  force-­‐  as  a  credible  military  

instrument  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Besides,  first  Mollet  and  later  De  Gaulle  thought  that  when  Israel  had  

nuclear  capability  it  could  be  a  counterforce  against  Egypt  in  France’s  fight  in  Algeria  (Farr,  1999).    

Israel's  early  leaders  realized  the  possibilities  that  the  exploitation  of  nuclear  power  offered  and  soon  

after  the  establishment  of  the  state  nuclear  research  and  development  began  under  the  wings  of  

Weizmann,  an  acclaimed  organic  chemist  (Cochran,  2000).  Weizmann  had  a  vision  and  actively  

expressed  his  hope  that  via  the  development  of  nuclear  science  Israel  would  become  "a  centre  of  the  

new  scientific  development  which  would  get  the  world  past  the  conflict  arising  from  the  monopolistic  

Page 23: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

23    

position  of  oil"  (Cochran,  2000).  The  first  political  figure  aware  of  this  post-­‐WWII  hierarchy  and  

unwavering  supporter  of  Israel's  atomic  development  was  Ben  Gurion  (Pinkus,  2002).  The  nuclear  

ambition  have  to  be  seen  in  the  primary  lesson  that  Ben  Gurion  took  from  the  Holocaust.  That  was  

that  other  nations  would  not  sacrifice  their  interests  to  fight  a  'Jews'  war  (Cochran,  2000).  According  

to  Cochran  (2000),  the  traumatic  impact  of  the  Holocaust  made  the  Jewish  people  aware  that  the  

matter  of  physical  survival  was  too  important  to  leave  to  others.  Cochran  (2000)  argues  that  in  

contrast  to  Israel's  counterparts,  security  is  not  just  about  safeguarding  political  values,  institutions  

and  a  way  of  life.  Security  is  first  and  foremost  about  the  very  existence  of  a  people  and  therefore  

Israel  must  strive  to  be  as  self-­‐reliant  as  possible  in  matters  of  defence  and  security  (Cochran,  2000).  

Ben  Gurion  foresaw  that  Israel  needed  nuclear  capability,  before  any  Arab  country,  to  solve  its  

security  problem  (Cochran,  2000).    According  to  Farr  (1999),  right  after  WWII,  Israel  and  France  were  at  a  similar  level  of  expertise  in  

nuclear  science  and  Israeli  scientists  could  make  significant  contributions  to  the  French  effort.  

Progress  in  nuclear  science  and  technology  in  France  and  Israel  remained  closely  linked  throughout  

the  early  1950s  (Farr,  1999).  World  class  research  institutions,  first-­‐rate  chemists  and  nuclear  

physicists  would  be  needed  and  Israel  already  had  three  top  institutes,  Hebrew  University  in  

Jerusalem,  Technion  in  Haifa  and  the  Weizmann  Institute  for  Science  in  Rehovot,  active  in  nuclear  

development  (Pinkus,  2002).  The  fact  that  a  number  of  Jews  worked  in  top  positions  as  nuclear  

scientists  and  administrators  in  the  1950s  in  France  had  a  positive  influence  on  the  rapprochement  

between  the  atomic  energy  commission  of  France  (CEA)  and  Israel’s  equivalent  (IAEC)  (Pinkus,  2002).  

During  the  first  half  of  the  1950s,  two  atomic  research  centres  began  operating  in  France  (Pinkus,  

2002).  According  to  Farr  (1999),  Israel  supplied  essential  technology  and  hardware  and  several  Israeli    

observers  were  at  the  French  nuclear  tests  where  they  had  'unrestricted  access  to  French  nuclear  

test  explosion  data'.  According  to  Pinkus  (2002),  one  of  the  factors  that  helped  Israel  in  

strengthening  ties  with  France  was  the  belief  of  top  CEA  administrators  that  via  Israel,  France  could  

profit  from  the  fruits  of  already  existing  international  Jewish  nuclear  expertise.  Another  essential  

factor  in  the  cooperation  was  the  possibility  of  sending  Israeli  chemists  and  nuclear  physicists  to  

advanced  studies  in  French  universities  (Pinkus,  2002).  The  collaboration  was  a  pragmatic  and  

fruitful  two-­‐sided  affair,  resulting  in  progress  in  nuclear  technology,  avionics  and  missiles  (Cochran,  

2000).  According  to  Cochran  (2000),  the  cooperation  was  so  close  that  Israeli  engineers  even  worked  

on  the  development  of  French  weapons  system  like  the  design  of  the  new  Mirage  fighter  jets  that  

were  able  to  carry  nuclear  bombs.    

Cochran  (2000)  notes  that  it  was  in  1957,  right  after  the  Suez  War  in  which  France  and  Israel  fought  

together  against  Egypt,  that  the  greatest  boost  to  the  Israeli  nuclear  programme  came.  France  

Page 24: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

24    

agreed  to  construct  an  underground  reactor  and  associated  research  facilities  in  Dimona,  a  town  in  

the  Negev  desert  that  served  as  the  base  for  Israel's  nuclear  weapons  (Cochran,  2000).  The  

cooperation  between  France  and  Israel  created  an  historical  conjuncture  that  was  both  

advantageous  and  exceptional,  and  resulted  in  the  full  implementation  of  the  bilateral  'nuclear  

initiative'  (Pinkus,  2002).    Pinkus  (2002)  argues  that  the  basis  of  cooperation  between  the  nuclear  scientists  of  both  countries  

was  the  determination  of  Prime  Minister  Ben  Gurion,  Minister  of  Defence  Peres  and  a  number  of  

French  leaders  in  their  pursuit  of  nuclear  weapons.  The  Suez  War  created  a  French  obligation  to  its  

ally,  and  France  was  ready  to  risk  harming  its  relations  with  the  Arab  world  by  extending  assistance  

to  Israel  for  establishing  a  nuclear  infrastructure  with  an  indisputable  military  capability  (Pinkus,  

2002).    3.1.4  The  Six-­‐Day  War  from  5  to  10  June  1967    For  a  long  time,  the  arms  trade  and  nuclear  cooperation  between  France  and  Israel  was  a  tangible  

expression  of  their  growing  friendship  (Evron,  1970).  Over  the  years,  the  entire  Israeli  air  force,  

consisting  of  300  combat  aircrafts,  had  been  built  up  with  French  planes  not  only  securing  a  large  

export  market  that  became  increasingly  important  for  the  French  arms  industry,  but  also  secured  a  

form  of  French  presence  in  the  Middle  East  (Evron,  1970).  According  to  Evron  (1970),  from  the  end  

of  the  Algerian  War  of  Independence  in  1962,  the  French  foreign  policy  gradually  and  cautiously  

shifted  to  rebuild  French  relations  with  Arab  countries.  The  appointment  of  De  Murville  as  French  

Foreign  Minister,  whom  was  known  to  favour  a  pro-­‐Arab  policy,  might  have  been  seen  as  a  sign  that  

things  would  change  (Evron,  1970).  The  return  to  power  of  De  Gaulle  in  1958,  and  the  centralization  

of  power,  led  to  the  revival  of  traditional  French  policy  in  the  Middle  East  (Crosbie,  1974).  Although  

the  Constitution  makes  no  provision  for  such  a  situation,  French  foreign  policy  since  1958  was  part  of  

the  private  preserve  of  President  De  Gaulle  (De  Carmoy,  1969).  De  Gaulle  conducted  his  own  foreign  

policy  of  which  the  tenet  was:  independence  is  the  prize  held  out  to  national  ambition  (De  Carmoy,  

1969).  This  means  that  for  France,  in  order  to  entirely  make  its  own  decisions  within  the  context  of  

the  Cold  War,  it  has  to  create  a  form  of  independency.  De  Gaulle  linked  this  desire  for  independency  

to  the  nuclear  ambition  of  France.  In  De  Gaulle's  point  of  view  alliances  are  unstable,  and  so  France  

"must  keep  her  options  open  and  maintain  her  own  freedom  of  action"  (De  Carmoy,  

1969).  That  policy  was  not,  as  other  policies  were,  first  formulated  by  the  responsible  minister,  

debated  in  the  cabinet  and  then,  so  far  as  the  major  policy  decisions  were  involved,  submitted  to  

parliament  for  approval  (De  Carmoy,  1969).  De  Gaulle  wanted  France  to  establish  an  independent  

position,  that  would  reassert  France  as  a  global  power  and  keep  distance  from  Cold  War  

Page 25: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

25    

entanglement  (Evron,  1970).  By  aligning  with  the  Arab  countries  and  maintaining  close  relations  with  

Israel,  a  so-­‐called  dual  approach,  De  Gaulle  thought  France  could  secure  a  strong  independent  

position  for  herself  (Evron,  1970).    

While  France  developed  her  dual  approach  towards  the  Middle  East,  the  new  Eshkol  government,    

1963-­‐1969,  gradually  shifted  Israeli  foreign  policy  from  French  oriented  more  towards  an  US  

alignment  (Evron,  1970).  The  replacement  of  Ben  Gurion  in  1963  with  Eshkol  as  the  new  Prime  

Minister  of  Israel  and  the  removal  of  Peres  in  1965  from  government  had  negative  effects  on  the  

relations  with  France  (Crosbie,  1974).  Crosbie  (1974)  argues  that  when  it  came  to  policymaking,  the  

differences  between  Ben  Gurion  and  Eskhol  were  more  a  question  of  style  than  of  substance.  

Nevertheless,  Eshkol's  lack  of  awareness  of  Israel's  need  for  good  public  relations  as  well  his  

misunderstanding  of  France  were  criticized  (Crosbie,  1974).  At  the  same  time  decentralization  of  the  

defence  ministry  in  Israel  opened  France-­‐Israel  relations  to  the  precariousness  of  coalition  politics,  a  

process  that  could  only  have  damaging  effects  when  rapid  decisions,  discretion  and  manoeuvrability  

were  crucial  to  success  (Crosbie,  1974).  Crosbie  (1974)  argues  that  these  internal  political  

developments  played  a  role  in  the  diverging  alliance.  Despite  continued  goodwill  between  the  

defence  establishment  and  the  arms  industries,  developments  within  the  governmental  structure  of  

both  countries  and  the  changing  role  of  France  in  regional  politics  increasingly  weakened  the  alliance  

(Crosbie,  1974).  Crosbie  (1974)  mentions  that  the  two  countries  had  simply  diverged  to  the  point  

where  France  no  longer  felt  a  need  to  protect  Israel's  interests  in  imports  and  exports.    

It  was  during  the  Arab-­‐Israel  War  of  June  1967,  known  as  the  Six-­‐Day  War,  that  the  special  

relationship  that  had  survived  for  more  than  a  decade  was  unilaterally  disrupted  by  De  Gaulle  

(Crosbie,  1974).  Tensions  heightened  again  between  Egypt  and  Israel  due  to  the  Egyptian  takeover  

of  UNEF  positions  and  the  closing  of  the  Strait  of  Tiran  to  Israeli  shipping  on  May  22  1967  (Crosbie,  

1974).  Until  this  closing  of  the  Strait  of  Tiran,  the  limits  of  French-­‐Israeli  co-­‐operation  had  not  been  

fully  tested  (Kolodziej,  1971).  The  end  of  the  Algerian  War  of  Independence  in  1962  and  the  

continuous  decrease  of  French  influence  in  the  region  had  effectively  eroded  much  of  French  and  

Israeli  foreign  policy  perspectives  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Eskhol  replied  to  Egypt  that  Israel  would  see  any  

interference  with  freedom  of  Israeli  shipping  as  an  act  of  aggression  and  immediately  sent  Foreign  

Minister  Eban  to  Paris  to  outline  the  threat  posed  by  Egypt  (Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  Eban  

reminded  De  Gaulle  to  France's  commitment  from  1957  to  interpret  any  Egyptian  attempt  to  close  

the  Strait  of  Tiran  as  an  act  of  war  and  respond  adequate  to  that  act  of  war  (Bickerton  and  Klausner,  

2005).  The  refusal  of  France  to  honour  its  obligation  to  defend  Israel's  access  to  the  Strait  of  Tiran  is  

to  some  degree  explained  by  the  fact  that  De  Gaulle's  thought  no  settlement  of  the  Middle  East  was  

possible  without  the  approval  of  the  Soviet  Union  (Kolodziej,  1971).  France  was  not  willing  to  oppose  

Page 26: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

26    

against  the  Soviet  Union,  whom  supported  Egypt,  and  thereby  make  a  mess  of  its  foreign  policy  since  

the  possibility  of  a  global  war  arising  from  a  regional  conflict  was  a  genuine  concern  of  De  Gaulle  

(Kolodziej,  1971).  In  case  of  such  an  event  the  Eastern  Mediterranean  struggle  would  inevitably  spill  

over  into  the  Maghreb,  France's  sphere  of  influence,  and  threaten  to  spread  into  Sub-­‐Saharan  

Francophone  Africa  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Siding  with  Israel  would  also  extinguish  the  emerging  French  

effort  to  improve  its  relations  with  the  Arab  countries  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Furthermore,  De  Gaulle  

hoped  to  secure  France's  oil  supply  independently  from  other  Western  nations  and  saw  

opportunities  for  the  widening  of  export  markets  for  French  arms  sales  (Crosbie,  1974).  During  the  

meeting  with  Eban,  De  Gaulle  acutely  said  the  following:  "You  must  on  no  account  start  a  war.  The  

country  that  fires  the  first  shot  will  lose  the  friendship  of  France"  (Kimche  and  Bawley,  1968).  As  a  

response  Eban  explained  that  in  fact  the  war  had  already  started  by  the  closing  of  the  Strait  of  Tiran  

and  reminded  De  Gaulle  of  the  French  statement  supporting  the  right  of  free  passage  in  the  Strait  of  

Tiran  that  had  been  issued  in  1957  (Kimche  and  Bawley,  1968).  According  to  Kimche  and  Bawley  

(1986),  De  Gaulle  answered  by  saying  that,  "Times  have  changed  since  then,  and  besides,  I  was  not  

President  then".    

In  reaction  to  the  Egyptian  mobilisation  and  the  closing  of  the  Strait  of  Tiran,  Israel  launched  a  pre-­‐  

emptive  airstrike  attack  destroying  most  of  the  Egyptian  air  force  on  the  ground  (Bickerton  and  

Klausner,  2005).  This  strike  gave  Israel  air  control  over  the  region,  which  was  crucial  in  its  strategy.  

Because  of  a  signed  defence  pact  between  Egypt,  Syria  and  Jordan  and  misleading  information  from  

Nasser  that  Egypt  was  successful  at  the  southern  front  with  Israel,  Jordanian  troops  began  to  fire  

from  across  the  borders  of  Jerusalem  (Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  This  gave  the  Israelis  the  

possibility  to  take  control  over  the  Old  City  of  Jerusalem  and  the  entire  West  Bank  from  Jordan  

(Bickerton  and  Klausner,  2005).  Israel  then  turned  towards  Syria  that  had  been  attacking  Israel's  

northern  towns  by  air  and  artillery.  Israel  destroyed  two  thirds  of  the  Syrian  air  force  and  did  not  

stop  until  the  Golan  Heights  were  captured  and  a  ceasefire  was  signed  (Bickerton  and  Klausner,  

2005).    According  to  Kolodziej  (1971),  although  France  officially  announced  its  neutrality  in  response  to  the  

Six-­‐Day  War,  within  the  UN  it  supported  the  general  Arab  position.  France  biased  neutrality  in  favour  

of  the  Arab  view  is  also  confirmed  in  its  UN  votes  on  key  issues,  like  the  Yugoslav  resolution  from  June  

1967,  where  it  called  for  the  immediate  withdrawal  of  Israeli  forces  without  reference  to  security  

guarantees  for  Israel  (Kolodziej,  1971).  This  pro-­‐Arab  vote  of  France  has  to  be  seen  in  the  

context  of  the  structuring  of  an  international  alliance  and  therefore  can  be  typed  as  serving  a  tertiary  

objective  in  Barber's  (1979)  framework.  

Page 27: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

27    

It  was  on  June  5,  the  first  day  of  the  Six-­‐Day  War,  that  De  Gaulle  on  behalf  of  France  officially  

imposed  an  embargo,  thereby  suspending  the  delivery  of  war  materials  to  Israel  (Evron,  1970).  The  

official  definition  of  the  embargo  was  that  it  applied  to  all  offensive  weapons,  but  it  later  appeared  

that  this  definition  effectively  only  covered  the  delivery  of  new  Mirage  V  fighter  jets  that  had  to  

replace  the  Mirage  III's,  until  then  Israel's  main  striking  force  (Evron,  1970).  France  refused  to  deliver  

the  fifty  Mirage  V’s  that  were  ordered  by  Israel  previously,  and  continued  to  refuse  even  after  the  

Six-­‐Day  War  and  complete  payment  in  April  1968  (Crosbie,  1974).    The  French  embargo  has  to  be  seen  in  relation  to  the  threat  of  an  Arab  oil  boycott  in  1967.  On  June  

 

4,  oil  ministers  from  a  number  of  Arab  oil  producing  countries  gathered  in  Baghdad  and  agreed  upon  

an  embargo  that  was  aimed  at  countries  that  'commit  or  take  part  in  aggression  against  the  

sovereignty,  territory  or  territorial  waters  of  any  Arab  state'  (Daoudi  and  Dajani,  1984).  The  Arab  oil  

embargo  was  firstly  installed  in  order  to  deter  Western  nations  from  lending  military  support  to  

Israel  in  its  war  with  the  Arab  states  and  secondly  to  punish  those  nations  which  did  not  responded  

to  Arab  warnings,  but  actively  intervened  on  Israel's  side  by  supplying  it  with  arms  and  ammunition  

(Daoudi  and  Dajani,  1984).    

3.2  The  early  development  of  Israel's  military  industry  up  to  1967      Since  the  beginning  of  the  post  WWII  era  Israel  has  been  most  concerned  with  its  national  security  

(Rodman,  2001).  Israel's  preoccupation  with  security  must  be  seen  in  the  context  of  an  alien  and  

hostile  environment  in  which  the  state  is  established  by  force  of  arms  (Naaz,  2000).  The  primary  

motivation  for  Israel  to  build  a  military  industry  was  survival  and  a  series  of  wars  made  it  natural  for  

Israel  to  develop  a  military  industry  of  its  own  (Naaz,  2000).  Only  during  the  first  five  decades  of  its  

existence  Israel  already  fought  six  full  scale  wars  with  its  Arab  neighbours:  The  1948-­‐1949  War  of  

Independence,  the  1965  Suez  War,  the  1967  Six-­‐Day  War,  the  1969-­‐1970  War  of  Attrition,  the  1973  

Jom  Kippoer  War  and  the  1982  Lebanon  War  (Rodman,  2001).  In  order  to  survive  as  a  state  and  even  

try  to  prevent  future  wars  Israel  had  to  develop  a  capable  arms  industry,  which  had  great  

consequences  for  the  state's  economy.  This  section  describes  the  early  launch  and  development  of  

Israel's  military  industry  from  1933  until  the  Six  -­‐Day  War  in  1967.    The  Israeli  military  industry  is  older  than  the  state  itself  and  traces  its  origins  back  to  the  days  of  the  

Haganah  fighters  (Naaz,  2000).  During  the  struggle  for  a  Jewish  independent  state,  the  military  

strategy  was  focused  on  self-­‐reliance  (Naaz,  2000).  Therefore  in  the  period,  1946-­‐1948,  Haganah  

fighters  were  in  need  of  small  arms  and  explosives  and  in  order  to  produce  these,  early  efforts  were  

made  to  improvise  a  munitions  base  (Naaz,  2000).  According  to  Naaz  (2000),  the  military  workshops,  

Page 28: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

28    

collectively  known  as  Israeli  Military  Industries  (IMI),  were  set  up  from  1933  onwards  and  formed  

the  base  of  the  defence  industry  that  played  a  vital  role  in  the  survival  of  Israel  during  the  War  of  

Independence  in  1948.  As  soon  as  the  British  left  Palestine,  the  Haganah  fighters  came  out  from  

underground  and  set  up  several  military  plants  for  production  and  increased  the  level  of  arms  

procurement  in  order  to  create  military  preparedness  in  case  of  war  (Naaz,  2000).    According  to  Naaz  (2000),  during  the  first  two  decades  Israel's  priority  was  to  establish  proper  

circumstances  for  modern  military  production  lines.  In  the  early  1950s,  the  military  industry  was  still  

small  and  its  extent  was  quite  limited,  nevertheless  it  was  already  providing  employment  and  

specific  training  for  its  workforce  and  introduced  some  new  technology  (Steinberg,  1985).  Due  to  the    

continuous  threat  to  national  survival,  Israel  had  to  find  an  external  source  for  the  procurement  of  

weapons  and  military  technology  and  found  its  partner  in  France  (Sadeh,  2001).  Minister  of  Defence,  

Peres,  outlined  in  an  early  stage  the  significance  of  self-­‐sufficiency  and  demanded  that  all  necessary  

equipment,  including  more  sophisticated  material,  would  be  produced  in  Israel  (Sadeh,  2001).  

Nevertheless,  such  level  of  production  both  in  quantity  and  quality  would  take  a  long  time,  and  until  

then  Israel  had  to  fight  for  its  existence  with  imported  military  equipment  (Sadeh,  2001).  According  

to  Sadeh  (2001),  this  concept  of  Israeli  self-­‐sufficiency  in  the  military  industry  was  a  result  of  four  key    

principles  varying  from  political  to  economical  and  pragmatic.  Firstly,  the  refusal  of  foreign  powers  to  

sell  essential  weaponry  (Sadeh,  2001).  Secondly,  the  accomplishments  of  Israeli  developers  that  

allowed  the  Israeli  Defence  Force  (IDF)  to  obtain  a  crucial  advantage  on  the  conventional  battlefield.  

Thirdly,  the  lower  cost  for  producing  the  military  equipment  in  Israel,  instead  of  importing.  Finally,  

the  necessary  weapons  systems  that  were  needed  for  a  regional  deterrence  posture  were  not  

attainable  from  other  sources.    Despite  the  fact  that  in  the  decision  to  launch  a  military  industry,  political  factors  such  as  security  

were  leading,  Ben  Gurion,  Eshkol  and  Peres  foresaw  a  pioneering  role  for  the  military  industry  in  the  

economic  development  of  the  state  (Steinberg,  1985).  According  to  Steinberg  (1985),  the  

industrialization  of  Israel  was  second  in  importance,  only  after  the  security  issues,  and  technology  

was  seen  as  the  base  of  industrialization.  The  military  industry  in  lower  developed  countries,  like  

Israel  at  that  time,  could  be  an  important  force  for  both  modernization  and  industrialization  and  

thereby  for  economic  progress  (Benoit,  1978).  Benoit  (1978)  argues  that  the  military  industry  has  

positive  effects  on  the  national  economy  via  four  main  channels.  Firstly,  in  creating  employment  for  

the  workforce.  Furthermore,  in  providing  education,  technical  training  and  medical  care  that  can  

have  a  high  civilian  utility.  Thirdly,  for  military  operations  a  variety  of  public  infrastructure  like  

airports,  communication  networks,  roads,  etc.  were  needed.  Finally,  the  military  industry  stimulated  

Page 29: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

29    

scientific  and  technical  progress  that  was  necessary  for  the  military  industry  and  that  could  have  spill  

over  effects  for  the  civilian  industry  (Benoit,  1978).    

According  to  Steinberg  (1985),  local  military  production  would  be  valuable  in  providing  high-­‐level  

employment  for  the  more  educated  immigrants  and  bring  opportunities  for  others  to  learn  technical  

skills  while  contributing  to  their  country.  Steinberg  (1985)  argues  that  many  high-­‐skilled  employees  

might  have  left  the  country  given  the  underdeveloped  state  of  the  civilian  industry  and  the  absence  

of  a  military  industry.  However,  the  employment  in  the  military  industry  averted  such  a  'brain  drain'  

and  even  attracted  high-­‐skilled  immigrants  (Steinberg,  1985).  One  of  the  immigrants  and  

representative  of  the  Israeli  approach  towards  modernization  was  the  American  aviation  engineer,  

Al  Schwimmer  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Schwimmer  was  asked  personally  by  Peres  to  launch  the  

Israeli  aviation  industry,  after  Peres  stated  that  "A  high  standard  of  living,  and  a  rich  culture  of  

spiritual,  political  and  economic  independence  are  not  possible  without  aerial  control"  (Senor  and  

Singer,  2009).  This  was  in  line  with  both  the  short-­‐term  military  strategy  as  well  the  bigger  purpose  

of  creating  industries  in  Israel  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Schwimmer  argued  that  there  was  no  reason  

why  Israel  could  not  buy  planes  cheaply,  repair  and  improve  them,  and  export  them  to  militaries  and  

airlines  while  building  its  own  commercial  industry  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Within  five  years,  

Bedek,  the  airplane  maintenance  company  Schwimmer  founded  in  1953  that  later  was  renamed  

Israel  Aircraft  Industries  (IAI),  became  the  largest  private  employer  in  Israel  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  

In  1966  already  around  4,000  people  worked  at  IAI  and  by  1980  the  workforce  was  around  22,500  

(Naaz,  2000).  Soon  the  military  industry  had  the  capacity  to  tailor  and  develop  new  weapons  that  

were  not  available  yet  on  the  market  and  created  for  Israel  a  possibility  to  even  export  military  

products  (Sadeh,  2001).    The  development  of  the  military  industry  in  the  first  two  decades  after  the  proclamation  of  the  state  

of  Israel  can  be  best  explained  in  two  different  stages.  The  first  stage,  from  the  late  1940s  until  the  

mid-­‐1950s,  focused  on  increasing  the  degree  of  self-­‐sufficiency  in  the  field  of  small  arms,  

ammunition  and  mortars  and  repairing  WWII  remnants  in  order  for  direct  use  by  the  IDF  (Sadeh,  

2001).  During  that  time  around  5,000  people  were  directly  employed  by  the  military  industry  (Sadeh,    

2001).  The  second  stage,  between  1955  and  1967,  was  marked  by  the  close  cooperation  between  

Israel  and  France  and  resulted  in  licensed  production  of  more  complex  weaponry  (Sadeh,  2001).  As  a  

consequence  of  the  Suez  War  of  1956,  Israel  faced  a  swift  inflow  of  fighter  jets,  tanks,  helicopters  

and  new  communication  systems  that  led  to  a  growing  demand  for  the  maintenance  facilities  

(Sadeh,  2001).  As  a  result,  several  military-­‐related  industries  and  military  concerns  like  IAI  and  the  

National  Armaments  Development  Authority  (RAFAEL)  expanded  quickly  (Naaz,  2000).  Israel  now  

gained  the  capability  to  modify  and  disassemble  aircrafts,  tanks  and  even  electronic  systems  and  in  

Page 30: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

30    

the  early  1960s  attention  shifted  to  establish  an  electronics  industry  (Naaz,  2000).  By  the  1960s,  

Israel's  military  industry  had  developed  from  producing  small  arms  into  coproducing  sophisticated  

weaponry  like  aircrafts  and  complex  electronics  (Naaz,  2000).  This  expansion  was  also  reflected  in  

the  growth  in  employment  of  the  military  industry,  that  by  1967  had  reached  14,000  employees,  a  

significant  amount  for  Israel  (Sadeh,  2001).  Benoit  (1978)  outlines  that  for  lower  developed  

countries  military  establishment  can  have  a  significant  impact  in  the  process  of  modernization  via  so-­‐  

called  productive  investments  and  spill  overs  from  the  military  to  the  civilian  industry.  In  Israel  the  

growing  military  industry  had  a  tremendous  impact  on  the  national  economy  and  over  the  period  of  

1950  until  1965  Israel's  annual  GDP  growth  was  around  ten  percent,  making  the  GDP  growth  the  

second  highest  of  all  lower  developed  countries,  while  Israel's  investment  rate  was  highest  with  

around  30%  (Benoit,  1978).    Section  4  focuses  on  the  unintended  effects  of  the  French  weapon  embargo  on  Israel  in  1967.  First  

the  short  terms  effect  for  both  France  and  Israel  are  outlined,  and  finally  the  long  term  effects  of  the  

embargo  for  Israel  are  discussed.  

Page 31: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

31    

Section  4:  The  unintended  effects  of  the  French  weapon  

embargo  on  Israel  in  1967    

This  section  describes  what  the  unintended  effects  of  the  French  weapon  embargo  on  Israel  in  1967  

have  been  for  the  target  country,  Israel,  and  the  sender  country,  France.  The  short  term  effects  for  

Israel  and  France  are  focused  around  three  segments  that  are  heavily  intertwined  with  each  other  

for  both  countries:  military,  economically  and  politically.  Section  4.1  focuses  on  the  short  term  

effects  for  Israel,  while  section  4.2  outlines  the  short  term  effects  for  France.  Section  4.3  focuses  on  

the  long  term  effects  for  Israel's  economy,  specifically  with  regards  to  spill-­‐over  effects  from  the  

military  industry  to  the  civilian  industry.    

4.1  Short  term  effects  for  Israel      According  to  Galtung  (1967),  a  nation  that  is  exposed  to  an  embargo  is  forced  to  find  either  internal  

or  external  substitutes  for  the  goods  in  question.  Galtung  (1967)  explains  that  the  receiving  nation  of  

an  economic  sanction,  in  this  case  Israel  as  a  target  of  the  French  weapon  embargo,  is  left  with  three  

options.  The  first  option  for  the  target  is  to  train  itself  in  doing  without  certain  commodities  that  are  

embargoed  (Galtung,  1967).  In  the  case  of  Israel  this  counterstrategy  was  not  an  option  since  the  

supply  of  weaponry  was  necessary  for  its  survival  and  existence,  and  building  up  an  own  capacity  

was  not  possible  in  the  short  term.  Therefore  Israel  fell  back  to  its  pre-­‐state  manner  in  getting    

weaponry,  namely  smuggling  (Crosbie,  1974).  De  Gaulle's  main  miscalculation  while  imposing  the  

embargo  was  that  he  did  not  fully  understood  the  depth  and  extent  of  pro-­‐Israel  feeling  that  was  

apparent  in  French  society  and  particularly  at  a  few  important  leaders  of  the  military  industry  

(Crosbie,  1974).  According  to  polls  on  June  6  1967,  65%  of  the  French  population  pronounced  itself  

as  pro-­‐Israel,  while  only  20%  was  pro-­‐Arab  (Crosbie,  1974).  Some  key  figures  in  the  French  aircraft  

industry  were  powerful  political  and  funding  personalities  and  of  Jewish  origin,  for  example  Dassault  

and  Szydlowski  (Crosbie,  1974).  Szydlowski  was  the  owner  of  a  manufacturer  of  engines  for  

helicopters  called  Turboméca,  and  visited  Israel  several  times  since  his  company  had  a  long  history  

of  doing  business  with  the  Israel  defence  establishment  (Crosbie,  1974).  The  response  of  the  

industry  not  to  follow  the  imposed  embargo  was  without  a  doubt  driven  by  the  fear  that  the  

embargo  would  obstruct  future  arms  sales  both  with  Israel  and  other  countries  (Crosbie,  1974).  

Particularly  once  Israel  had  completed  the  $65  million  payment  for  the  Mirage  V  and  France  still  

refused  to  deliver  the  planes  (Crosbie,  1974).  According  to  Crosbie  (1974),  on  the  eve  of  the  Six-­‐Day  

War  large-­‐scale  arms  shipments  were  ferried  to  Israel  by  French  military  transport,  while  twenty  

Mystere  III  jets  loaned  to  the  Israeli  Air  Force.  The  military  establishment  and  related  defence  

Page 32: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

32    

industries  continued  to  elude  the  embargo  on  arms  to  Israel  (Crosbie,  1974).  Crosbie  (1974)  states  

that  spare  parts,  replacements,  'defensive  material'  and  'low  offensive  capacity  material'  evaded  the  

embargo  until  by  the  end  of  1967  only  the  Mirages  remained  under  embargo.  In  fact,  during  1968  

arms  supplies  from  France  to  Israel  reached  the  high  pre  Six-­‐Day  War  levels  and  relations  between  

the  French  arms  industry  and  Israel  could  never  have  been  better  (Evron,  1970).  For  De  Gaulle  it  was  

extremely  irksome  to  be  confronted  with  such  disobedience  from  a  vital  industry  and  in  particular  

from  people  he  expected  to  be  among  his  closest  supporters  (Crosbie,  2015).    Besides  smuggling,  the  second  counterstrategy  for  an  embargoed  nation  could  be  to  trade  via  third  

parties  or  change  imports  to  a  third  party  (Galtung,  1967).  This  is  what  Israel  had  to  do  now  that  the  

arms  race  in  the  Middle  East  was  accelerated  at  the  moment  that  Israel  lost  its  most  reliable  arms  

supplier  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Israel  immediately  initiated  a  new  and  apparently  more  effective  

source  of  arms  with  the  US,  that  already  had  begun  to  sell  weapons  to  Israel  in  1962  (Evron,  1970;  

Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  From  the  Six-­‐Day  War  on  the  US–Israeli  relationship  assumed  a  profound  

new  orientation  and  dimension  with  Israel  as  a  strategic  asset  to  American  interests  (Rubenberg,  

1989).  According  to  Rubenberg  (1985),  the  idea  of  Israel  as  a  strategic  ally  became  an  absolute  

doctrine  of  orthodox  American  politics  and  resulted  in  virtually  unlimited  quantities  of  military  

equipment  and  economic  assistance,  so  de  facto  a  new  alliance  was  formed.  Nevertheless  the  

French  betrayal  had  built  a  consensus  in  Israel  that  it  could  no  longer  rely  so  heavily  on  foreign  arms  

suppliers  and  Israel  had  to  find  ways  for  not  becoming  too  dependent  (Senor  and  singer,  2009).  This  

succeeded  partially  due  to  the  activism  of  the  American  Jews  that  stimulated  the  general  public's  

fascination  with  Israel  since  the  Six-­‐Day  War  and  was  also  due  to  the  broad  ties  with  American  

business  that  benefitted  from  trade  with  Israel  (Steinberg,  1985;  Oberg,  1975).  Rodman  (2001)  

mentions  that  at  an  early  stage  Ben  Gurion  foresaw  that  perhaps  Israel  could  never  be  completely  

self-­‐sufficient,  leading  to  a  guiding  principle  in  Israel's  national  security.  Ben  Gurion  realized  that  as  a  

small  state  with  limited  resources,  Israel  could  not  afford  to  be  isolated  from  the  world  community  

during  wartime  and  Israel  should  always  have  at  least  one  'great  power  patron'  (Rodman,  2001).  The  

relation  that  Israel  established  with  the  US  was  broader,  also  in  the  civilian  field,  than  the  previous  

relation  with  France  (Oberg,  1975).  According  to  Oberg  (1975),  the  US  established  63  manufacturing  

subsidiaries  in  Israel  of  which  22  were  active  in  the  electronics  and  aerospace  industries,  but  not  

mainly  in  the  production  of  arms.  Companies  like  General  Electric  Engines  and  Wright  Aeronautical  

were  keen  to  establish  research  and  development  centres  in  Israel,  in  part  due  to  the  advantage  of  

relatively  low  labour  costs  of  Israeli  high-­‐skilled  engineers  with  $6  an  hour  compared  to  $15  in  the  

US  (Oberg,  1975).  All  this  in  combination  with  a  specific  government  policy  to  stimulate  the  high-­‐  

skilled  industry  brought  employment  towards  Israel  and  secured  the  basis  and  infrastructure  for  a  

Page 33: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

33    

local  high  tech  industry  (Oberg,  1975).  As  if  today  Israel  is  also  known  as  the  "Startup  Nation"  and  

has  an  economy  that  is  strong  in  technological  innovation  that  traditionally  had  been  pushed  by  the  

demands  of  the  military  industry  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).    

Thirdly,  the  target  could  restructure  its  national  economy  in  order  to  absorb  the  shock  of  the  

boycott,  by  producing  locally  the  imported  commodities  denied  (Galtung,  1967).  In  order  to  survive,  

Israel  had  to  restructure  its  economy  and  focus  on  the  development  of  a  full-­‐scale  military  and  

civilian  industry  that  were  closely  integrated  (Oberg,  1975).  The  embargo  included  weaponry  for  

which  Israel  already  had  paid,  specifically  Mirage  aircraft  and  fast  patrol  boats  (Steinberg,  1985).  Now  

that  the  Mirage  could  not  be  imported  anymore,  IAI  started  to  produce  an  Israeli  version  of  the  

Mirage  III,  the  Nesher  and  later  the  more  advanced  version  called  the  Kfir  (Oberg,  1975).  This  led  to  

gradual  accumulation  of  technical  capabilities  and  production  skills  that  later  resulted  in  the  

development  of  tanks,  various  types  of  missiles,  artillery  and  ammunition  for  these  various  weapons  

(Steinberg,  1985).  Or  as  one  of  Israel's  first  high  tech  entrepreneurs,  Yossi  Vardi  said  "The  two  real  

fathers  of  Israeli  high  tech  are  the  Arab  boycott  and  Charles  De  Gaulle,  because  they  forced  on  Israel  

the  need  to  go  and  develop  an  industry"  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).    

Immediately  after  the  French  weapon  embargo  of  June  1967,  Israel  had  to  shift  its  policy  towards  

more  self-­‐sufficiency  with  regards  to  producing  its  defence  needs  (Naaz,  2000).  According  to  Naaz  

(2000),  it  was  this  sense  of  urgency  that  led  Israel  into  a  ground  breaking  industrial  revolution  of  

which  the  main  priority  was  the  manufacturing  of  military  equipment.  Israel  launched  its  military  

industry  on  a  large  scale  and  within  three  years  it  had  established  an  advanced  arms  industry  that  

was  unmatched  in  terms  of  technological  sophistication  by  other  lower  developed  countries  (Naaz,  

2000).    Naaz  (2000)  argues  that,  partly  in  line  with  Benoit  (1978),  besides  the  urgent  need  for  security  four  

economic  arguments  form  the  base  of  Israel's  policy  on  the  military  production  of  that  period.  

Firstly,  an  increase  in  employment  opportunities  for  both  the  low-­‐skilled  as  well  as  the  high-­‐skilled  

labour  force  (Naaz,  2000).  Secondly,  Naaz  (2000)  mentions  the  spill-­‐over  effects  that  are  a  result  

from  research  and  development  in  the  military  industry.  These  spill-­‐over  effects  could  increase  the  

level  of  sophistication,  technological  innovation  and  other  applications  in  the  civilian  industry  (Naaz,  

2000).  Thirdly,  domestic  production  would  reduce  the  amount  the  import  of  military  products  and  

thereby  narrow  or  reduce  the  Israeli  trade  gap  (Naaz,  2000).  Fourth,  Naaz  (2000)  argues  that  foreign  

sales  of  Israeli  military  products  would  earn  foreign  currency  through  import  substitution  and  

subsequent  export  promotion.  

Page 34: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

34    

In  the  period  from  1967  to  1970,  the  military  industry  intensified  research  and  development  and  its  

output  quadrupled  (Naaz,  2000).  Benoit  (1978)  mentions  Israel  as  an  example  of  a  country  where  

because  of  military  tensions  employees  cooperated  more  effectively  and  productively,  which  had  

positive  effects  for  the  national  economy.  Benoit  (1978)  explains  that  a  threat  on  national  security  

inflicts  a  strong  influence  on  most  individual  consciences  and  appears  to  justify  imposing  difficult  

and  often  painful  adjustments  on  the  individual,  like  pay  cuts  or  working  more  shifts.  Furthermore,  a  

common  enemy  can  work  as  an  amplifier  in  nation  building  and  national  pride,  which  both  can  have  

positive  effects  for  the  nation's  productivity  since  employees  believe  their  work  is  essential  (Benoit,  

1978).  Employment  in  the  military  industry  rose  from  14,000  in  1966  to  34,000  in  1972  and  Israel  

was  now  able  as  an  independent  producer  to  make  major  military  subsystems  as  well  fighter  jets  

(Sadeh,  2001).  In  particular  the  aircraft  industry  grew  rapidly  with  4,000  employees  in  1967  to  more  

than  7,500  one  year  later  (Steinberg,  1985).  As  Table  1  shows,  in  the  period  from  1968  to  1979  

employment  almost  tripled,  making  the  IAI  Israel's  largest  employer  with  21,500  employees  

(Steinberg,  1985).  As  a  result,  the  procurement  of  local  produced  weapons  system  experienced  a  

real  growth  of  around  85%  in  that  period  and  the  metals  and  electronics  industries  also  benefited  

from  that  growth  by  absorbing  around  35%  of  industrial  investment  (Naaz,  2000).  It  was  this  post  

Six-­‐Day  War  period  that  set  the  basis  for  the  Israeli  military  industry  to  become  the  fifth  largest  arms  

exporter  in  the  world,  competing  successfully  against  market  leading  conglomerates  (Sadeh,  2001).    Table  1:  Number  of  employees  in  the  Israeli  Aircraft  Industries  

 

 Source:  Steinberg  (1985).    According  to  Sadeh  (2001),  the  tremendous  growth  of  the  Israeli  military  industry  was  a  combination  

of  policy  and  circumstances,  of  which  the  French  embargo  and  the  sense  of  urgency  due  to  the  Six-­‐  

Day  War  were  crucial.  Sadeh  (2001)  argues  that  in  spite  of  the  traumatic  experiences  of  WWII,  the  

Jewish  nation  and  state  were  still  subjected  to  existential  threat  by  the  Arab  world  and  this  led  to  

the  institutionalization  of  the  'centrality  of  security'  concept,  both  psychologically  as  well  materially.  

The  'centrality  of  security'  is  best  explained  by  the  principles  of  defence  and  foreign  affairs  policies  

Page 35: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

35    

that  had  a  pro-­‐Western  orientation,  a  preference  for  self-­‐reliance,  a  'Realpolitik'  that  is  based  on  

practical  rather  than  ideological  considerations,  acceptance  of  the  territorial  status  quo  of  1948,  a  

military  strategy  of  deterrence  and  pre-­‐emptive  war  and  striving  for  autarky  in  military  weapons  and  

equipment  (Peri,  1981).  The  unexpected  embargo  by  Israel's  closest  ally,  France,  strengthened  this  

philosophy  and  reaffirmed  that  in  order  to  survive  Israel  has  to  be  as  self-­‐sufficient  as  possible  when  

it  came  to  military  needs  (Sadeh,  2001).    

4.2  Short  term  effects  for  France      Evron  (1970)  outlines  that  the  French  embargo  had  three  negative  effects  for  France.  Firstly,  France  

lost  the  position  of  potential  mediator  in  the  Arab-­‐Israeli  conflict  and  this  further  reduced  its  status  

as  a  superpower  (Evron,  1970).  Since  De  Gaulle  returned  as  President  in  1958  he  was  determined  to  

regain  the  French  status  as  an  international  superpower  and  therefore  was  not  willing  to  jeopardize  

its  relation  with  the  Soviet  Union  by  supporting  Israel  (Heimann,  2010).  De  Gaulle  believed  that  a  

four  power  agreement  between  the  US,  Great  Britain,  the  Soviet  Union  and  France,  should  settle  the  

conflict  between  Egypt  and  Israel  without  war  (Heimann,  2010).  France's  role  as  a  potential  mediator  

in  the  Middle  East  legitimized  in  large  part  its  presence  on  the  security  council  of  the  UN  (Kolodziej,  

1971).  Since  France  supported  Israel  during  the  1950s  and  the  early  1960s  it  had  some  amount  of  

influence  in  Middle  East  affairs  (Crosbie,  1974).  Moore  (2010)  argues  that  arms  sales  are  

fundamentally  different  from  other  commodities  since  it  represents  a  direct  transfer  of  the  

capability  to  carry  out  political  violence,  making  arms  export  decisions  uniquely  political  decisions.  

Nevertheless,  when  it  came  to  Israel's  decision  to  launch  an  attack  on  Egypt  at  the  beginning  of  the  

Six-­‐Day  War  in  1967,  France  failed  to  deter  Israel  to  do  so  and  thereby  lost  its  reputation  and  

prestige  as  a  superpower  (Heimann,  2010).  Heimann  (2010)  argues  that  the  threat  of  a  French  

embargo  was  ineffective  since  the  Israelis  perceived  the  crisis  very  differently  from  the  French.  For  

Israel  survival  was  at  stake  and  therefore  French  war  material  mattered  less  than  political  support  

from  the  US  (Heimann,  2010).  The  Six-­‐Day  War  exposed  the  limits  of  France's  patronage  of  Israel  and  

is  best  symbolized  by  De  Gaulle's  words,  "Israel  has  nothing  to  ask  from  us  and  we  have  nothing  to  

offer  it."  (Heimann,  2010).  At  the  same  time  the  disobedience  of  some  military  industry  leaders  in  

combination  with  the  public  rage  in  the  case  of  the  embargo  on  Israel,  weakened  the  prestige  of  De  

Gaulle's  internal  position  (Kolodziej,  1980).    Secondly,  one  of  the  motives  of  the  Tripartite  Declaration  signed  by  France,  was  to  reduce  the  

polarization  between  the  US  and  the  Soviet  Union  by  controlling  the  arms  supply  to  the  Middle  East  

(Evron,  1970).  By  imposing  an  embargo,  France  lost  this  special  role  and  forced  Israel  into  a  situation  

whereby  it  had  to  purchase  a  large  part  of  her  arms  from  the  US,  thereby  accelerating  the  

Page 36: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

36    

polarization  in  the  Middle  East  since  the  Soviet  Union  delivered  arms  to  Egypt  (Evron,  1970).  It  

appears  that  these  so-­‐called  'superpower  arms  sales'  reinforce,  rather  than  restrict,  arms  sales  

resulting  in  an  arms  race  (Kolodziej,  1980).  Evron  (1970)  states  that  an  embargo  in  the  Middle  East  or  

the  idea  that  future  supplies  of  arms  are  endangered,  paradoxically  leads  to  an  acceleration  of  the  

arms  race  since  it  gives  a  strong  argument  for  buying  immediately.    Evron  (1970)  states  that  the  third,  negative  effect  for  France  was  the  fast  drive  of  Israel  towards  self-­‐  

sufficiency  in  arms  production  as  a  consequence  of  the  embargo.  As  a  result,  France  lost  a  lucrative  

market  if  it  would  ever  decide  to  lift  the  embargo,  as  well  a  new  competitor  in  the  market  for  arms  

sales  since  Israel  joined  the  weapons  producing  and  exporting  countries  (Evron,  1970).  It  was  only  

when  De  Gaulle  imposed  a  complete  embargo,  on  3  January  1969  as  a  response  to  the  Israeli  attack  

on  Beirut  airport,  that  the  drop  in  orders  for  French  arms  fell  (Evron,  1970).  Compared  with  orders  of  

1968  in  the  aircraft  industry  fell  by  52%  and  in  overall  arms  industry  sales  decreased  by  38%  (Evron,    

1970).  Evron  (1970)  states  that  this  fall  in  arms  sales  created  heavy  pressure  since  the  French  arms  

industry  employed  280,000  workers  and  its  production  could  not  be  fully  absorbed  by  the  French  

demand.  Therefore  the  continued  sales  of  arms  and  aircraft  were  thought  necessary  in  order  to  

sustain  the  French  arms  industry  (Crosbie,  1974).  Nevertheless,  as  a  result  of  the  loss  of  Israel  as  an  

export  market,  new  opportunities  arose.  Kolodziej  (1980)  argues  that  France  was  no  more  restricted  

in  arms  sales  to  Israel  and  the  economic  considerations,  not  strategic  or  foreign  policy,  have  become  

the  major  pillar  for  French  arms  transfer.  By  1970  French  focus  concerning  arms  sales  moved  from  

Israel  towards  Latin  and  South  America,  but  mainly  to  the  Arab  states  (Crosbie,  1974).    

As  a  reward  from  the  Arab  world,  orders  were  placed  in  France  from  February  1968  to  1970  worth  of    

$296  million  in  heavy  weaponry  by  Saudi  Arabia  while  Iraq  placed  an  order  of  $150  million  for  the  

delivery  of  52  Mirages  fighter  jets  (Crosbie,  1974).  By  1970  total  arms  export  increased  by  11,5%  

over  1969  with  a  total  of  $453  million  and  arms  exports  was  around  ten  percent  of  all  national  

exports  (Crosbie,  2015).  Now  France  was  able  to  expand  arms  exports  and  focused  on  the  Arab  

countries  with  successful  deals  with  Iraq,  Saudi  Arabia,  Libya,  Algeria  and  Lebanon  (Evron,  1970;  

Kolodziej,  1971).  In  1970  already  25%  of  all  French  heavy  arms  sales  was  to  Arab  countries  and  it  

opened  more  commercial  opportunities  with  a  population  of  100  million  compared  to  Israel  with  3  

million  at  that  time  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Specifically  the  French  sale  to  Libya  in  1970  of  110  Mirage  

aircrafts  strengthened  France's  alignment  with  the  Arab  countries  and  was  seen  as  a  support  for  

Libya  as  an  independent  state  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Kolodziej  (1971)  argues  that  this  sale  of  $400  million  

opened  the  way  to  the  delivery  of  more  supporting  military  equipment  as  well  gave  French  oil  

companies  some  limited  rights  in  Libya.  This  was  in  particular  important  since  at  that  time  90%  of  

French  oil  imports  was  provided  by  six  Arab  countries  while  France  itself  could  only  supply  two  

Page 37: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

37    

percent  of  its  petroleum  energy  need  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Because  oil  supply  was  crucial  to  French  

economic  growth,  there  was  a  big  incentive  to  take  the  role  as  main  arms  supplier  for  the  Arab  

countries,  even  if  this  would  further  destabilize  the  region  (Kolodziej,  1980).    

The  argument  that  economic  incentives  shifted  France's  policy  towards  a  pro-­‐Arab  position  is  

supported  by  the  data  shown  in  Table  2  (Kolodziej,  1971).  Table  2  shows  the  trade  relations  between  

France  and  the  Arab  states  in  the  period  1965  to  1970,  divided  into  Eastern  and  Western  

Mediterranean  states.  The  reason  for  this  division  is  that  the  Eastern  Mediterranean  states  were  

more  involved  in  the  wars  and  conflicts  with  Israel  than  the  Western  Mediterranean  states.  This  

table  gives  a  clear  overview  of  the  fast  growth  in  trade  between  France  and  the  Eastern  Arab    

countries  particularly  after  1967.  The  total  growth  of  French  imports  from  the  East  Arab  countries  in  

the  period  of  1965  to  1970  is  56%,  while  exports  even  increased  with  136%  over  the  same  period  of  

time.  Most  of  the  trade  growth  happened  after  1967  and  can  be  directly  linked  to  the  French  

weapon  embargo  on  Israel  and  the  subsequent  extensive  arms  sales  to  these  Arab  countries.  At  the  

same  time  the  increase  of  French  imports  from  Western  Arab  countries  over  the  same  period  was  

less  than  5%,  while  French  exports  even  decreased  with  0,4%  to  Western  Arab  countries.    

Table  2:  French  imports  and  exports,  including  oil,  with  selected  Eastern  and  Western  Arab  states  

from  1965  to  1969  in  millions  of  Francs.  

 

 Source:  Kolodziej  (1971).  

Page 38: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

38    

4.3  Long  term  effects  on  Israel's  economy      This  section  describes  the  long  term  effects  on  Israel's  economy  that  are  a  result  from  the  French  

weapon  embargo  of  1967.  The  effects  on  the  Israeli  economy  are  versatile,  but  this  section  focuses  

mainly  on  the  spill-­‐over  effects  of  the  military  industry.  Two  successful  cases  that  are  both  

connected  to  the  French  weapon  embargo  of  1967,  are  highlighted.  Firstly,  Israel's  exports  of  

Unmanned  Aerial  Vehicles  (UAVs)  and  secondly  the  revolutionary  medical  device  called  PillCam.    According  to  Senor  and  Singer  (2009),  Israel's  economic  development  is  one  of  two  great  expansions  

of  which  the  first  occurred  from  1948  to  1970  and  the  second  from  1990  until  today,  see  Figure  1  

and  Figure  2.  During  the  first  great  leap,  GDP  per  capita  almost  quadrupled  and  the  population    

tripled,  despite  of  Israel's  confrontation  in  three  full  scale  wars  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  The  first  

great  leap  was  accomplished  through  an  entrepreneurial  government  investing  heavily  in  the  

military  industry  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Israel's  military  industry  at  that  time  was  bigger  than  the  

primitive  private  sector  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Figure  2  shows  that  in  one  year,  between  1967  and    

1969,  Israel's  arms  exports  increased  from  about  $280  million  to  $1.3  billion.  The  quadrupling  of  the  

arms  export  can  be  seen  as  a  direct  result  of  the  Six-­‐Day  War  and  Israel's  accelerated  arms  industry.  

The  second  period  of  great  expansion  was  realized  because  of  a  thriving  entrepreneurial  private  

sector,  specifically  in  the  high  tech  industry,  that  at  first  was  catalysed  by  government  action  (Senor  

and  Singer,  2009).    Figure  1:  Israel’s  GDP  per  capita  compared  to  World  average  from  1960  to  2014  

 

 

 Data:  World  Bank  (2016).  

Page 39: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

39    

Figure  2:  Israel's  arms  exports  from  1960  to  2014  

 

Data:  World  Bank  (2016).    According  to  Naaz  (2000),  the  acceleration  in  development  of  the  military  industry  had  two  primary  

reasons,  namely:  the  unreliability  of  arms  suppliers  and  economic  factors  that  played  an  important  

role.  The  years  between  the  Six-­‐Day  War  and  the  Jom  Kippoer  War,  from  1967  to  1973,  were  marked  

by  a  tremendous  rise  in  defence  expenditures  because  of  new  security  requirements  and  the  shift  to  

more  costly  US  technology,  see  Figure  3  (DeRouen,  2000).  In  general  Israel's  overall  defence  

production  strategy  is  one  of  military  import  substitution  and  more  of  the  defence  consumption  is  

spend  domestically  as  Figure  4  shows  (DeRouen,  2000).  Economically,  the  potential  to  save  foreign  

capital  via  the  export  of  military  goods,  and  secure  spinoffs  from  the  sophisticated  defence  research  

and  developments  are  perhaps  the  most  salient  factors  (DeRouen,  2000).  After  the  Six-­‐Day  War  

Israel  devoted  around  two  thirds  of  its  military  budget  to  domestic  enterprises  (see  figure  4).  At  the  

same  time  there  was  an  increase  in  total  defence  consumption  in  Israel  from  7%  of  GDP  in  1965  to  

20%  in  1969  (see  figure  3).  A  spill  over  effect  that  Looney  (1989)  mentions  is  that  defence  spending  

leads  to  an  increase  demand  for  industrial  sector  products  and  this  in  turn  creates  a  greater  demand  

for  high-­‐skilled  employees.  According  to  DeRouen  (2000),  the  Arab-­‐Israeli  arms  race  moved  more  

towards  a  qualitative  arms  race,  which  essentially  is  a  competitive  hunt  for  high-­‐tech  defence  

systems  (DeRouen,  2000).  These  factors  created  facilities  as  a  pull  factor  for  high-­‐skilled  labour  and  

stimulated  a  'brain  gain'  to  Israel,  in  particular  from  former  SU  states  that  faced  a  brain  drain.  For  

instance,  in  1990  about  184,000  Jews  left  the  SU  for  Israel  of  which  40%  was  highly  educated  

(Jałowiecki  and  Gorzelak,  2004).  In  the  period  from  1980  to  1987,  about  70,000  specialists  and  

Page 40: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

40    

10,000  students  emigrated  from  Poland  to  Israel  and  them  were  47,000  engineers  and  technicians,    

3,500  physicians,  4,800  economists  and  about  4,000  science  professionals  (Jalowieckie  and  Gorzelak,    

2004).  According  to  Senor  and  Singer  (2009),  although  less  than  two  percent  of  the  Soviet  population  

was  Jewish  they  counted  for  30%  of  doctors,  20%  of  engineers  and  so  on.  Senor  and  Singer  (2009)  

explain  this  phenomenon  as  an  unintended  effect  of  fierce  antisemitism  in  the  SU.  The  only  way  to  

build  some  kind  of  protection,  in  such  an  anti-­‐Semitic  society,  was  to  be  exceptional  in  your  

profession  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Once  the  SU  collapsed  and  borders  were  open  to  

emigrate,  a  lot  of  Jewish  scholars  left  to  Israel  to  build  a  new  life  and  expected  to  find  high-­‐level  

employment  in  the  military  industry  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).    

Figure  3:  Defence  spending  and  overall  investments  as  percentage  of  GDP  from  1953  to  1992.    

 Source:  DeRouen  (2000).    Figure  4:  Defence  consumption  as  percent  of  GDP  from  1956  to  2002    

 

 Source:  Central  Bureau  of  Statistics  (2016)  

Page 41: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

41    

DeRouen  (2000)  argues  that  Israel  is  the  only  third-­‐world  country  that  has  done  more  than  

reinventing  first-­‐world  arms  technology.  The  level  of  sophistication  of  the  Israeli  arms  industry  

exceeds  that  of  most  countries  (DeRouen,  2000).  The  Israeli  aircraft  industry  developed  at  a  fast  

pace  and  as  a  consequence  of  new  security  needs  the  development  of  UAVs,  also  known  as  drones,  

took  off,  see  Table  3.  Israel's  pioneering  work  with  drones  dates  back  to  the  1970s  and  in  1973  the  

Israeli  'Tadiran  Mastiff'  was  operational  and  seen  as  the  first  modern  battlefield  drone  since  it  was  

able  to  send  data  such  as  live  video  streaming  (Tucker  and  Roberts,  2008).  Because  of  this  new  

technology  during  the  1973  Yom  Kippoer  war,  the  IDF  was  able  to  look  "over  the  hill"  into  hostile  

territory  in  a  safe  manner  (Tucker  and  Roberts,  2008).  According  to  Tucker  and  Roberts  (2008)  the  

use  of  drones  was  a  big  advantage  for  the  field  commanders  and  gave  them  a  lead  in  the  battle.  This  

early  development  and  production  of  UAVs  driven  by  military  needs,  led  to  a  worldwide  export  

market  for  IAI.  Nowadays  Israel  is  considered  to  be  the  leading  exporter  of  UAVs  (Stockholm  

International  Peace  Research  Institute,  2015).  According  to  Stockholm  International  Peace  Research  

Institute  (2015)  Israeli  defence  companies  exported  more  than  60%  of  all  drones  in  the  world  from  

1985.  As  Figure  5  shows,  the  UAV  industry  is  nowadays  around  $10  billion  and  is  expected  to  grow  

over  the  next  decade  in  both  military  as  well  civilian  use  (the  Drones  Report,  2015).    

Figure  5:  Global  Unmanned  Aerial  Vehicle  market                                                              Source:  http://uk.businessinsider.com/uav-­‐or-­‐commercial-­‐drone-­‐market-­‐forecast-­‐2015-­‐  

 

2?r=US&IR=T  

Page 42: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

42    

Table  3:  Israel's  progress  in  weapons  and  military  technology  from  1940s  to  1990s    

Source:  Sadeh  (2001).    According  to  DeRouen  (2000),  Israel  went  from  a  developing  economy  to  a  mature  and  diversified  

one.  DeRouen  (2000)  argues  that  along  the  way  Israel  experienced  an  increase  in  skilled-­‐labour  

through  immigration,  investment  in  high  tech  companies,  defence  spending  as  a  result  of  the  

entrenched  military  industry  and  the  qualitative  arms  races  and  defence  spin  offs  to  the  civilian  

industry  and  these  phenomena  are  all  interconnected.  Due  to  a  certain  level  of  production  in  the  

military  industry  and  the  qualitative  arms  race,  many  former  SU  scholars  immigrated  to  Israel  in  their  

pursuit  of  high-­‐level  employment.  This  influx  of  high-­‐skilled  employees  raised  the  level  of  production  

as  well  launched  a  boom  in  high  tech  companies,  since  not  all  of  the  high-­‐skilled  workers  could  find  

employment  in  the  military  industry  and  moved  to  the  high  tech  industry.  The  role  of  the  military  

has  been  a  critical  factor  in  government  supported  research  and  development,  and  the  issue  of    

civilian  spill  overs  continue  to  be  a  major  topic  of  interest  (Honig  et  al.,  2006).  Military  research  and  

development  has  generated  a  wealth  of  civilian  industries,  including  commercial  aircraft,  computers,  

semiconductors,  microwaves,  radar,  satellites  and  nuclear  energy,  see  Table  4  (Honig  et  al.,  2006).  

According  to  Honig  et  al.  (2006),  the  Israeli  military  accounts  for  the  majority  of  government  

research  and  development  expenditure  and  has  a  tradition  of  operating  in  an  innovative,  cost-­‐  

efficient  manner.  Employees  of  Israeli  military  research  and  development  firms  seem  to  

demonstrate  considerable  entrepreneurial  behaviours  that  may  account  for  a  vibrant  and  robust  

industrial  environment  (Honig  et  al.,  2006).  Since  Israel  has  a  conscription  army  while  in  other  

countries  students  are  preoccupied  with  deciding  which  college  to  attend,  Israeli  students  are  

Page 43: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

43    

focusing  on  the  benefits  of  different  military  units  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  In  Israel,  the  military  can  

selects  from  the  best,  while  in  most  countries  that  is  the  other  way  around  and  the  military  can  just  

hope  for  the  best  (Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  According  to  Senor  and  Singer  (2009),  the  IDF  provides  a  

broad  and  deep  training  to  adolescents  to  produce  innovative,  adaptive,  communicative,  leadership  

and  problem  solving  skills  under  tremendous  pressure  of  life  and  death.  This  kind  of  training  

accelerates  the  process  of  maturity  and  at  the  same  time  can  increase  practical  technical  skills  that  

cannot  be  taught  in  university,  like  disassembling  a  tank.  All  these  skills  can  be  useful  in  case  of  

entrepreneurial  activity.  According  to  Senor  and  Singer  (2009),  in  Israel  private  sector  experiences  

and  education  are  important,  but  at  every  job  interview  the  recruiter  asks  about  the  military  service  

of  the  candidate.  It  is  the  military  service  that  provides  the  critical  standardized  metric  for  

employers,  since  everyone  knows  what  it  means  to  be  an  officer  or  to  have  served  in  an  elite  unite    

(Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  Thus,  the  IDF  is  often  credited  with  playing  a  major  role  in  the  creation  and  

sustained  success  of  the  Israeli  high  tech  industry  (Breznitz,  2002).  In  2015  the  high  tech  industry  

accounted  for  about  40%  of  Israel's  exports  and  around  a  third  of  Israel's  GDP.  The  high  tech  

industry  employed  around  12%  of  Israelis  and  technology  exists  in  2015  were  about  $15  billion    

(Ackerman,  2016).    The  institutionalized  development  of  Israeli  high  tech  industry  since  the  1960s  has  been  connected  to  

the  state's  security  needs,  to  academic  research,  to  entrepreneurial  activity,  and  to  government  

policies  (Zilber,  2006).  According  to  Roper  and  Frenkel  (2000)  the  Israeli  high  tech  industry  has  

become  an  international  leader  for  research  intensive  activities  funded  by  both  Israeli  and  

international  venture  capitalists,  overcoming  Israel's  lack  of  prolonged  industrial  tradition  and  

shortage  of  capital.  Part  of  Israel's  current  economic  success  in  the  field  of  high  tech  entrepreneurial  

activity  is  explained  by  the  spill  overs  of  the  military  research  and  development  centres  (Senor  and  

Singer,  2009).  Table  4  exemplifies  how  developments  in  certain  military  research  fields  had  their  

effect  on  civilian  applications.  For  instance,  most  of  the  technology  that  is  integrated  in  modern  

smartphones  originate  from  communication  systems  used  in  the  military  field.    

According  to  Honig  et  al.  (2006),  a  technology  spill  over  arises  when  the  activities  of  one  organization  

lead  to  an  upgrade  in  the  technology  or  productivity  of  another  organization  (Honig  et  al.,  2006).  To  

highlight  one  case,  out  of  many,  as  an  example  of  spill  over  effects  from  the  military  industry  to  the  

civil/medical  industry  we  look  at  PillCam,  a  medical  device  with  disruptive  technology  in  it.  PillCam  is  a  

pill  with  a  tiny  colour  camera  inside  that  transmits  data  to  a  computer  and  reconstructs  the  image  of  

the  patient's  insides  on  the  screen  (Shamah,  2015).  This  new  technology  changes  the  way  doctors  can  

diagnose  their  patients  and  treat  all  sorts  of  diseases  and  problems  in  ways  that  were  never  possible  

before  (Shamah,  2015).  Iddan,  the  founder  of  PillCam,  was  employed  at  Israel  Military  

Page 44: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

44    

Industries  (RAFAEL).  While  speaking  with  an  Israeli  doctor  about  the  challenges  in  using  traditional  

endoscopies,  Iddan  realized  that  the  optics  work  he  was  doing  could  provide  an  alternative  solution  

for  looking  into  the  digestive  track  (Shamah,  2015).  Iddan  used  technology  that  was  a  result  of  

developments  in  different  fields  in  the  military  industry,  such  as  micro-­‐electronics,  electro  optics,  

communication  and  computing,  to  create  a  medical  device  like  the  PillCam,  see  Table  4.  Eventually  

the  PillCam  company,  in  which  Rafael  was  a  stakeholder,  was  sold  in  2013  for  $860  million  (Shamah,  

2015).    Table  4:  Area  of  military  research  that  facilitated  civilian  applications  in  Israel  

                         Source:  Sadeh  (2001).  

Page 45: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

45    

Section  5:  Conclusions      Economic  sanctions  are  part  of  a  larger  set  of  policy  instruments  available  to  governments,  which  

among  various  also  consists  of  diplomacy,  propaganda,  and  military  interference  (Baldwin  and  Pape,  

1998).  In  general,  economic  sanctions  are  categorized  into  two  main  categories:  financial  restrictions  

and  trade  restrictions,  each  of  which  can  be  employed  with  varying  intensity  and  scope  (Pape,  1997).  

A  weapon  embargo  is  a  form  of  a  trade  restriction  that  is  very  harsh,  since  arms  sales  are  different  

from  all  other  goods  because  they  give  a  state  the  most  powerful  tool  of  statecraft.    

Economic  sanctions  also  vary  within  the  objectives  they  have.  Economic  sanctions  with  so-­‐called    

‘primary  objectives’  are  imposed  to  change  the  target’s  policy  towards  a  more  favourable  stand  of  

the  sender(s)  (Barber,  1979).  Economic  sanctions  that  have  ‘secondary  objectives’  are  both  directed  

to  domestic  and  international  audience  and  are  more  symbolic  in  nature  (Baber,  1979).  These  

economic  sanctions  are  imposed  to  reinforce  the  sender  state’s  government  or  to  showcase  where  

the  sender  stands  (Barber,  1979).    From  the  establishment  of  Israel  in  1948  to  1967,  France  was  Israel’s  greatest  ally  and  main  arms  

supplier  (Crosbie,  1974).  Once  the  mutual  interests  of  France  and  Israel  diverted,  due  to  the  end  of  

the  Algerian  War  of  Independence  with  France,  the  alliance  also  collapsed  (Kolodziej,  1971).  In  this  

context,  of  diverting  interests  and  international  symbolism,  we  have  to  interpret  the  unilateral  

French  weapon  embargo  on  Israel.  The  French  threat  of  economic  sanctions  might  have  served  a  

primary  objective  to  shift  Israel's  behaviour  to  avoid  a  war,  but  was  ineffective  and  did  not  changed  

Israel's  policy.  The  main  reason  for  Israel  not  to  comply,  was  that  for  Israel  the  blockade  of  the  Strait  

of  Tiran  was  a  matter  of  national  security.  Therefore  the  costs  of  a  potential  economic  sanction  was  

too  small  to  deter  Israel  from  going  into  war.  The  moment  Israel  went  into  war  with  Egypt,  France  

imposed  a  weapon  embargo,  but  arms  were  still  shifted  from  France's  military  industry  to  Israel.  

Therefore,  I  tend  to  believe  that  this  economic  sanction  predominantly  served  a  secondary  

objective,  namely  signalling.  President  De  Gaulle  signalled  France’  position  to  the  Arab  world  which  

improved  trade  relations  with  the  Arab  states  and  opened  an  export  market  for  the  French  arms  

industry  (Crosbie,  1974).    

The  French  weapon  embargo  effectively  resulted  in  the  fact  that  Israel  was  not  able  to  receive  the  

fighter  jets  that  it  already  had  ordered.  Since  the  supply  of  such  weaponry  was  necessary  for  its  

survival  and  existence  Israel  had  to  substitute  its  main  arms  supplier  and  did  so  by  shifting  towards  

the  US  as  its  new  source  of  arms  (Evron,  1970).  At  the  same  time  the  French  weapon  embargo  led  to  

the  ‘centrality  of  security’  concept,  which  means  that  Israel’s  security  needs  in  order  to  physically  

Page 46: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

46    

survive  were  too  important  to  let  to  others  (Cochran,  2000).  The  embargo  shifted  Israel’s  policy  

towards  more  self-­‐sufficiency  and  Israeli  leaders  were  aware  that  political  and  economic  

independence  were  not  possible  without  aerial  control  (Naaz,  2000;  Senor  and  Singer,  2009).  

Therefore  Israel  restructured  its  national  economy  and  focused  on  the  development  of  a  full-­‐scale  

military  and  civilian  industry  that  were  closely  integrated  (Oberg,  1975).  The  Israeli  Aircraft  Industry  

(IAI)  started  to  produce  an  Israeli  version  of  a  fighter  jet,  the  Kfir,  and  from  now  on  would  be  the  

only  third  world  country  able  to  produce  very  sophisticated  weapon  systems  (Oberg,  1975;  

DeRouen,  2000).  Out  of  security  needs  the  IAI  developed  further  into  a  qualitative  arms  race  and  

attracted  more  high-­‐skilled  employees,  and  eventually  became  Israel’s  largest  employer  with  more  

than  20,000  employees  (Oberg,  1975).  For  instance  the  IAI  was  pioneering  in  the  development  of  

Unmanned  Aerial  Vehicles  (UAVs),  also  known  as  drones,  and  Israel  was  the  first  country  that  had  a  

battlefield  drone  operational  (Tucker  and  Roberts,  2008).  Furthermore  the  military  industry  has  

been  crucial  in  government  supported  research  and  development  (Honig  et  al.,  2006).  According  to  

Honig  et  al.  (2006),  the  Israeli  military  industry  accounts  for  the  majority  of  government  research  

and  development  expenditures  and  has  a  tradition  of  operating  in  an  innovative,  cost  efficient  

manner.  Many  of  nowadays  technology  originates  out  of  security  needs  or  military  research  and  

development  and  spilled  over  to  the  civilian  industry  that  gave  the  technology  a  different  

application.  The  Israeli  high  tech  industry  has  become  an  international  leader  for  research-­‐intensive  

activities,  funded  by  both  Israeli  and  international  venture  capitalist,  overcoming  Israel’s  lack  of  

prolonged  industrial  tradition  and  shortage  of  capital  (Roper  and  Frenkel,  2000).  Thus  the  IDF  is  

often  credited  with  playing  a  major  role  in  the  creation  and  sustained  success  of  the  Israeli  high  tech  

industry  (Breznitz,  2002).  The  spill  over  effects  of  the  military  industry  can  be  found  in  nearly  every  

industry  in  Israel,  varying  from  software  developing  companies,  online  security,  communication  

systems,  electronics  industry  and  even  medical  devices.    Therefore  it  is  reasonable  to  agree  with  Vardi,  one  of  Israel’s  most  successful  high  tech  

entrepreneurs  when  he  says  that:  “The  two  real  fathers  of  Israeli  high  tech  are  the  Arab  boycott  and  

Charles  De  Gaulle,  because  they  forced  on  Israel  the  need  to  go  and  develop  an  industry”  (Senor  and  

Singer,  2009).  

Page 47: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

47    

Section  6:  Reference  list      Ackerman,  G.  (2016,  February  17).  Israel  High  Tech  Industry  Growth  Slowing  Amid  Manpower  Shortage.  Retrieved  August  20,  2016,  from  http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-­‐02-­‐17/israel-­‐high-­‐tech-­‐  industry-­‐growth-­‐slowing-­‐amid-­‐manpower-­‐shortage  

 Azar,  E.  E.  (1972).  Conflict  escalation  and  conflict  reduction  in  an  international  crisis:  Suez,  1956.  Journal  of  Conflict  Resolution,  183-­‐201.  

 Baldwin,  D.  A.  (1985).  Economic  statecraft.  Princeton  University  Press.  

Baldwin,  D.  A.,  &  Pape,  R.  A.  (1998).  Evaluating  economic  sanctions.International  Security,  23(2),  189-­‐198.  

Barber,  J.  (1979).  Economic  sanctions  as  a  policy  instrument.  International  Affairs  (Royal  Institute  of  International  Affairs  1944-­‐),  55(3),  367-­‐384.  

 Bergeijk,  P.  A.  V.  (1989).  Success  and  failure  of  economic  sanctions.  Kyklos,  42(3),  385-­‐404.  

 Benoit,  E.  (1978).  Growth  and  defense  in  developing  countries.  Economic  Development  and  Cultural  Change,  26(2),  271-­‐280.  

Bickerton,  I.  J.,  &  Klausner,  C.  L.  (2005).  A  concise  history  of  the  Arab-­‐Israeli  conflict.  Prentice  Hall.  Breznitz,  

D.  (2002).  Conceiving  new  industrial  systems:  the  different  emergence  paths  of  high-­‐technology  companies  in  Israel  and  Ireland.Science  Technology  and  the  Economy  Program  of  the  Samuel  Neaman  Institute,  Technion-­‐Israel  Institute  of  Technology-­‐Working  Paper  Series.  

 

Business  and  Sanstions  Consulting  Netherlands,  2016.  Retrieved  19th  June  2016  from:  http://www.bscn.nl/sanctions-­‐consulting/sanctions-­‐list-­‐countries  

 Cochran,  E.  S.  (2000).  Israel's  nuclear  history.  Israel  Affairs,  6(3-­‐4),  129-­‐156.  

 Cortright,  D.,  Lopez,  G.  A.,  Conroy,  R.  W.,  Dashti-­‐Gibson,  J.,  Wagler,  J.,  Malone,  D.  M.,  &  Axworthy,  L.  (2000).  The  sanctions  decade:  assessing  UN  strategies  in  the  1990s  (Vol.  1).  Boulder,  CO:  Lynne  Rienner  Publishers.  

 Cox,  D.  G.,  &  Drury,  A.  C.  (2006).  Democratic  sanctions:  Connecting  the  democratic  peace  and  economic  sanctions.  Journal  of  Peace  Research,43(6),  709-­‐722.  

 Central  Bureau  of  Statistics,  (2016).  Defence,  Introduction-­‐Explanatory  Notes,  Definitions  and  Sources.  Retrived  on  August  21,  http://www.cbs.gov.il/www/publications/security/pdf/e_mavo.pdf  

 Crosbie,  S.  K.  (1974).  A  tacit  alliance:  France  and  Israel  from  Suez  to  the  Six  Day  War.  Princeton  University  Press.  

 Daoudi,  M.  S.,  &  Dajani,  M.  S.  (1983).  Economic  sanctions,  ideals  and  experience.  Routledge  Kegan  &  Paul.  

Daoudi,  M.  S.,  &  Dajani,  M.  S.  (1984).  The  1967  oil  embargo  revisited.  Journal  of  Palestine  Studies,  13(2),  65-­‐90.  

Dashti-­‐Gibson,  J.,  Davis,  P.,  &  Radcliff,  B.  (1997).  On  the  determinants  of  the  success  of  economic  sanctions:  An  empirical  analysis.  American  Journal  of  Political  Science,  608-­‐618.  

 De  Carmoy,  G.  (1969).  The  Last  Year  of  De  Gaulle's  Foreign  Policy.International  Affairs  (Royal  Institute  of  International  Affairs  1944-­‐),  45(3),  424-­‐435.  

 DeRouen,  K.  (2000).  The  guns-­‐growth  relationship  in  Israel.  Journal  of  Peace  Research,  37(1),  69-­‐83.  

Drury,  A.  C.  (1998).  Revisiting  economic  sanctions  reconsidered.  Journal  of  Peace  Research,  35(4),  497  -­‐509.  

ElBaradei,  M.  The  Egyptian-­‐Israeli  Peace  Treaty  and  Access  to  the  Gulf  of  Aqaba:  A  New  Legal  Regime’(1982).  American  Journal  of  International  Law,76,  532.  

Page 48: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

48    

Elliott,  K.  A.  (1998).  The  Sanctions  Glass:  Half  Full  or  Completely  Empty?.  International  Security,  23(1),  50-­‐65.    Elliott,  K.  A.,  &  Hufbauer,  G.  C.  (1999).  Same  song,  same  refrain?  Economic  sanctions  in  the  1990's.  The  American  Economic  Review,  89(2),  403-­‐408.  

 Evron,  Y.  (1970).  French  Arms  Policy  in  the  Middle  East.  The  World  Today,26(2),  82-­‐90.  

Farr,  W.  D.  (1999).  The  Third  Temple's  Holy  of  Holies:  Israel's  Nuclear  Weapons.  Air  war  Coll  Maxwell  AFB  al.  

Galtung,  J.  (1967).  On  the  effects  of  international  economic  sanctions,  with  examples  from  the  case  of  Rhodesia.  World  politics,  19(03),  378-­‐416.  

 Gordon,  D.  F.  (1983).  The  Politics  of  International  Sanctions:  A  Case  Study  of  South  Africa.  Dilemmas  of  Economic  Coercion:  Sanctions  in  World  Politics,  183-­‐210.  Greenwood,  2012  "Blockade  as  Act  of  War".  Crimes  of  War  Project.  Retrieved  2012-­‐07-­‐01.  

 Greenwood,  2012  "Blockade  as  Act  of  War".  Crimes  of  War  Project.  Retrieved  2012-­‐07-­‐01.  

Hargreaves-­‐Heap,  S.,  &  Varoufakis,  Y.  (2004).  Game  theory:  a  critical  introduction.  Routledge.  

 

Heimann,  G.  (2010).  In  Search  of  a  Route  to  World  Power:  General  de  Gaulle,  the  Soviet  Union,  and  Israel  in  the  Middle  Eastern  Crisis  of  1967.The  International  History  Review,  32(1),  69-­‐88  

 Honig,  B.,  Lerner,  M.,  &  Raban,  Y.  (2006).  Social  capital  and  the  linkages  of  high-­‐tech  companies  to  the  military  defense  system:  Is  there  a  signaling  mechanism?.  Small  Business  Economics,  27(4-­‐5),  419-­‐437.  

 Hovi,  J.,  Huseby,  R.,  &  Sprinz,  D.  F.  (1998).  When  do  (imposed)  economic  sanctions  work.  International  Security,  23(1).  

 Hufbauer,  G.  C.,  Schott,  J.  J.,  &  Elliott,  K.  A.  (1990).  Economic  sanctions  reconsidered:  History  and  current  policy  (Vol.  1).  Peterson  Institute.  

 Ianchovichina,  E.,  Devarajan,  S.,  &  Lakatos,  C.  (2016).  Lifting  economic  sanctions  on  Iran:  global  effects  and  strategic  responses.  World  Bank  Policy  Research  Working  Paper,  (7549).  

 Jałowiecki,  B.,  &  Gorzelak,  G.  J.  (2004).  Brain  drain,  brain  gain,  and  mobility:  Theories  and  prospective  methods.  Higher  Education  in  Europe,29(3),  299-­‐308.  

 Kaempfer,  W.  H.,  &  Lowenberg,  A.  D.  (1989).  The  theory  of  international  economic  sanctions:  A  public  choice  approach:  Reply.  The  American  Economic  Review,  79(5),  1304-­‐1306.  

 Kimche,  D.,  &  Bawley,  D.  (1968).  The  sandstorm:  the  Arab-­‐Israeli  war  of  June,  1967:  prelude  and  aftermath.  Harvill  Secker.  

 Kirshner,  J.  (1997).  Currency  and  coercion:  the  political  economy  of  international  monetary  power.  Princeton  University  Press.  

 Kirshner,  J.  (1997  II).  The  microfoundations  of  economic  sanctions.  Security  Studies,  6(3),  32-­‐64.  

 Kolodziej,  E.  A.  (1971).  French  Mediterranean  Policy:  The  Politics  of  Weakness.  International  Affairs  (Royal  Institute  of  International  Affairs  1944-­‐),  47(3),  503-­‐517.  

 Kolodziej,  E.  A.  (1980).  France  and  the  arms  trade.  International  Affairs  (Royal  Institute  of  International  Affairs  1944-­‐),  54-­‐72.  

 Lindsay,  J.  M.  (1986).  Trade  sanctions  as  policy  instruments:  A  re-­‐examination.  International  Studies  Quarterly,  153-­‐173.  

 Looney,  R.  E.  (1989).  Impact  of  arms  production  on  income  distribution  and  growth  in  the  third  world.  Economic  Development  and  Cultural  Change,  38(1),  145-­‐153.  

Page 49: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

49    

Major,  C.  (2008).  The  French  White  Paper  on  Defense  and  National  Security.CSS  Analyses  in  Security  Policy,  3,  1-­‐3.  

 Major,  S.,  &  McGann,  A.  J.  (2005).  Caught  in  the  Crossfire  “Innocent  Bystanders”  as  Optimal  Targets  of  Economic  Sanctions.  Journal  of  Conflict  Resolution,  49(3),  337-­‐359.  

 Marinov,  N.  (2005).  Do  economic  sanctions  destabilize  country  leaders?  American  Journal  of  Political  Science,  49(3),  564-­‐576.  

 Martin,  L.  L.  (1993).  Credibility,  costs,  and  institutions:  Cooperation  on  economic  sanctions.  World  Politics,  45(03),  406-­‐432.  

 Mintz,  A.,  Ward,  M.  D.,  &  Bichler,  S.  (1990).  Defense  spending  in  Israel.  The  Economics  of  Defense  Spending:  An  International  Survey.  London:  Routledge.  

 Mongin,  D.  (1997).  La  bombe  atomique  française  1945-­‐1958.  Bruylant.  

 Moore,  M.  (2010).  Arming  the  embargoed:  A  supply-­‐side  understanding  of  arms  embargo  violations.  Journal  of  Conflict  Resolution,  54(4),  593-­‐615.  

 Morgan,  T.  C.,  &  Schwebach,  V.  L.  (1997).  Fools  suffer  gladly:  The  use  of  economic  sanctions  in  international  crises.  International  Studies  Quarterly,  41(1),  27-­‐50.  

 Naaz,  F.  (2000).  Israel's  arms  industry.  Strategic  Analysis,  23(12),  2077-­‐2087.  

Neff,  D.  (1988).  Warriors  at  Suez:  Eisenhower  Takes  America  into  the  Middle  East.  Amana  Publications.  

Nossal,  K.  R.  (1989).  International  sanctions  as  international  punishment.  International  Organization,  43(02),  301-­‐322.  

 Øberg,  J.  (1975).  Third  world  armament:  Domestic  arms  production  in  Israel,  South  Africa,  Brazil,  Argentina  and  India  1950-­‐75.  Instant  Research  on  Peace  and  Violence,  5(4),  222-­‐239.  

 Pape,  R.  A.  (1997).  Why  economic  sanctions  do  not  work.  International  Security,  22(2),  90-­‐136  

Peri,  Y.  (1981).  Political-­‐Military  Partnership  in  Israel.  International  Political  Science  Review,  2(3),  303-­‐315.  

Pinkus,  B.  (2002).  Atomic  power  to  Israel's  rescue:  French-­‐Israeli  nuclear  cooperation,  1949-­‐1957.  Israel  Studies,  7(1),  104-­‐138.  

 Rauschning,  D.,  Wiesbrock,  K.,  &  Lailach,  M.  (1997).  Key  Resolutions  of  the  United  Nations  General  Assembly  1946-­‐1996.  CUP  Archive.  

 Rodman,  D.  (2001).  Israel’s  National  Security  Doctrine:  An  Introductory  Overview.  Middle  East  Review  of  International  Affairs,  5(3),  71-­‐86.  

 Roper,  S.,  &  Frenkel,  A.  (2000).  Different  paths  to  success—the  growth  of  the  electronics  sector  in  Ireland  and  Israel.  Environment  and  Planning  C:  Government  and  Policy,  18(6),  651-­‐665.  

 Rubenberg,  C.  A.  (1989).  Israel  and  the  American  national  interest:  A  critical  examination.  University  of  Illinois  Press.  

 Sadeh,  S.  (2001).  Israel’s  Beleaguered  Defense  Industry.  Middle  East  Review  of  International  Affairs,  5(1),  64-­‐  77.  

Senor,  D.,  &  Singer,  S.  (2009).  Start-­‐up  nation:  The  story  of  Israel's  economic  miracle.  McClelland  &  Stewart.  

Shamah,  D.  (2015,  December  8).Pillcam's  inventor  regret  sale  of  'Biblical'  tech  to  foreign  firm.  The  Times  of  Israel.  Retrieved  from  http://www.timesofisrael.com/pillcams-­‐inventor-­‐regrets-­‐sale-­‐of-­‐biblical-­‐tech-­‐to-­‐foreign-­‐  firm/  

Page 50: Economicsanctionsandtheir!unintended! effects

50    

Slonim,  S.  (1987).  Origins  of  the  1950  tripartite  declaration  on  the  Middle  East.  Middle  Eastern  Studies,  23(2),  135-­‐149.  

Sowerwine,  C.  (2009).  France  since  1870:  Culture,  Society  and  the  Making  of  the  Republic.  Palgrave  Macmillan.  

Steinberg,  G.  M.  (1985).  Technology,  weapons,  and  industrial  development:  The  case  of  Israel.  Technology  in  Society,  7(4),  387-­‐398.  

 Steinberg,  G.  (1998).  Israel  and  the  United  States:  Can  the  Special  Relationship  Survive  the  New  Strategic  Environment?.  Middle  East,  2(4),  62.  

 Stockholm  International  Peace  Research  Institute.  (2015).  SIPRI  Yearbook  2015:  Armaments,  Disarmament,  and  International  Security.  Oxford  University  Press,  USA.  

 Tal,  D.  (2009).  The  Making,  Operation  and  Failure  of  the  May  1950  Tripartite  Declaration  on  Middle  East  Security.  British  Journal  of  Middle  Eastern  Studies,  36(2),  177-­‐193.  

 The  Drones  Report:  Market  forecasts,  regulatory  barriers,  top  vendors,  and  leading  commercial  applications.  (2016,  June  10).  Retrieved  August  13,  2016,  from  http://uk.businessinsider.com/uav-­‐or-­‐commercial-­‐drone-­‐  market-­‐forecast-­‐2015-­‐2?r=US&IR=T  

 Tucker,  S.  C.,  &  Roberts,  P.  (Eds.).  (2008).  The  Encyclopedia  of  the  Arab-­‐Israeli  Conflict:  A  Political,  Social,  and  Military  History  [4  volumes]:  A  Political,  Social,  and  Military  History.  Abc-­‐Clio.  

United  States  Department  of  State  Bulletin,  vol.  22,  n.  570  (1950),  p.  886.  

Wagner,  R.  H.  (1988).  Economic  interdependence,  bargaining  power,  and  political  influence.  International  Organization,  42(03),  461-­‐483.  

 World  Bank,  World  Development  Indicators  (2016),  Economic  Policy  and  Debt,  GDP  per  Capita.  Retrieved  from  https://www.google.nl/publicdata/exploreds=d5bncppjof8f9_&met_y=ny_gdp_mktp_kd_zg&idim=country:ISR  :FRA:SWE&hl=en&dl=en#!ctype=l&strail=false&bcs=d&nselm=h&met_y=ny_gdp_pcap_kd&scale_y=lin&ind_y  =false&rdim=region&idim=country:ISR&ifdim=region&hl=en_US&dl=en&ind=false  

 World  Bank,  World  Development  Indicators  (2016),  Public  Sector,  Arms  Trade.  Retrieved  from  https://www.google.nl/publicdata/exploreds=d5bncppjof8f9_&met_y=ny_gdp_mktp_kd_zg&idim=country:ISR  :FRA:SWE&hl=en&dl=en#!ctype=l&strail=false&bcs=d&nselm=h&met_y=arms_trade_constant_1990_us&fdim  _y=direction_of_trade:1&scale_y=lin&ind_y=false&rdim=region&idim=country:ISR&ifdim=region&hl=en_US&  dl=en&ind=false  

 Zilber,  T.  B.  (2006).  The  work  of  the  symbolic  in  institutional  processes:  Translations  of  rational  myths  in  Israeli  high  tech.  Academy  of  management  journal,  49(2),  281-­‐303.