economy of elections

49
Economy of Elections Krystal Okonkwo, Millicent Usoro, Paul Strader, Charles Tilley, William Warren

Upload: jolie

Post on 11-Feb-2016

34 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Economy of Elections. Krystal Okonkwo, Millicent Usoro , Paul Strader , Charles Tilley, William Warren . Public Choice Model. Models Voters, Politicians and Bureaucrats as self-interested. Methodologically individualistic: Public interest is the aggregation of private decision makers - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economy of Elections

Economy of Elections

Krystal Okonkwo, Millicent Usoro, Paul Strader, Charles Tilley, William Warren

Page 2: Economy of Elections

Public Choice Model

Models Voters, Politicians and Bureaucrats as self-interested. Methodologically individualistic: Public

interest is the aggregation of private decision makers

Positive Economics Utility Maximization

Page 3: Economy of Elections

Game Theory

Cooperative games – People only form coalitions to maximize their own utility. As groups increase individual value

decrease so coalitions are unstable. Logrolling or Vote-trading :: quid pro

quo

Page 4: Economy of Elections

Pareto Optimality

Pareto Optimality: Policies that benefit some people and hurt no one. Externalities: effects of a decision on

a third party not considered – Imperfect Information Negative Or Positive

Page 5: Economy of Elections

Negative Externalities

S0 = Marginal Private Cost

D = Marginal Social Benefit

Cost, P

Q

S1 = Marginal Social Cost

P0

P1

Q0

Q1

If there are no externalities, P0Q0 is the

equilibrium If there are externalities, the

marginal social cost differs from the

marginal private cost, and P0 is too low and

Q0 is too high to maximize social

welfare

Cost of externality

21-5

Page 6: Economy of Elections

Government Failure

Failure of Market Outcome: Market is functioning properly but not achieving goals

3 Criteria necessary to correct a problem Recognize Will Ability

Government Interaction Worsens the situation

Page 7: Economy of Elections

Median Voter Theorem

Fundamental process of democracy Politicians will move toward to the other

extreme Explains why extremists won’t get elected Ambiguity of political ideology and actions

Page 8: Economy of Elections

Assumptions

Political preference ordered from left to right

Single-peaked and sloped downward Two-party system/two candidates Only one political question

Page 9: Economy of Elections

Median Voter Model

Simple model of demand aggregation One-dimensional spectrum Center becomes smaller and smaller Elastic demand Primary elections vs. national election

Page 10: Economy of Elections

An Illustration of the Median Voter

Three individuals Al ($5.00), Bob ($10.00), Charlie

($20.00) Bob is the median voter Weak form vs. strong form

Page 11: Economy of Elections

OPTIONS PATTERN OF VOTES RESULT

$10 vs. $20 A: 10 B: 10 C: 20 10

$5 vs. $20 A: 5 B: 5 C: 20 5

$5 vs. $16 A: 5 B: 5 C: 16 5

$10 vs. $5 A: 5 B: 10 C: 10 10

Page 12: Economy of Elections

Limitations

No supply side of the public sector Complex policies cannot be applied Not applicable to multimodal issues

Page 13: Economy of Elections

GerrymanderingGerrymandering is the process of redrawing election districts for political purposes Elbridge Gerry –

1812

Massachusetts Governor

Originally benefitting Democratic-Republicans

Page 14: Economy of Elections

Three Methods of Gerrymandering

Cracking-Spreading voters of one party across multiple districts to diminish their voting power

Packing-Concentrating voters of one party in one district to diminish their broader voting power

Sweetheart-Agreement between two parties to redraw districts to favor incumbents

Page 15: Economy of Elections
Page 16: Economy of Elections
Page 17: Economy of Elections

General Redistricting Practices

Reapportionment of Congressional seats occurs every 10 years with new Census

Based on change in seats, each state legislature redistricts to uphold doctrine of “one person, one vote” (Wesberry v. Sanders 1964)

http://www.redistrictinggame.org/launchgame.php?level=basic&mission=2

Page 18: Economy of Elections

Collusion is an effective method to achieve sweetheart districts

The Democratic and Republican parties collude to maintain the status quo, ensuring incumbents achieve re-election

Collusion

Page 19: Economy of Elections

Racial Gerrymandering

Voting Rights Act of 1965 allowed for the creation of majority-minority districts

Aim is to help systematically disenfranchised populations

Can be viewed as either packing or cracking based on specifics of district

Page 20: Economy of Elections

Illinois Congressional District 4

Created in a 1990 court order

“Earmuff District” 73.8% Hispanic Rep. Luis Gutierrez

(D)

Page 21: Economy of Elections

Externalities For those who do not support the

majority party, gerrymandering represents a negative externality

Various tests have been developed to assess election districts, the most common measure is compactness

In most measures of compactness, scores range from 0 to 1, 1 being a perfectly compact district

Page 22: Economy of Elections

Measures of Compactness Polsby-Popper Score

Page 23: Economy of Elections

Measures of Compactness Roeck and Ehrenburg Tests

Page 24: Economy of Elections
Page 25: Economy of Elections

Condorcet Paradox

Page 26: Economy of Elections

What is it? Choosing who to elect When there are only two candidates: chose the

one who would likely get the most votes What do we do when there are more than two

candidates Everybody adds their own rank of to each

candidate But is there a social choice that reflects the will

of the people

Page 27: Economy of Elections

If we consider a situation where we have three voters and three candidates

Each voter ranks the candidates in different orders of preference

The first voter prefers A to B to C The Second: B to C to A The Third: C to A to B

Page 28: Economy of Elections

Given this situation, regardless of who the “social choice” selects, in other words who wins the election, two thirds of the voters will be dissatisfied

A social choice function takes people’s preferences and comes out with the single alternative to win the election and please the most people

This paradox shows however that the function cannot always pick the best outcome

A candidate who can beat all the others in head to head comparisons is called a Condorcet winner

Page 29: Economy of Elections

Selection of the Condorcet Winner

The Condorcet Method provides a solution to the paradox

Whichever candidate would beat all other candidates in head to head elections is the Condorcet winner

I.e. If A would beat B head to head and would beat C head to head then A is the overall Condorcet winner.

Page 30: Economy of Elections

Many studies have been dedicated to finding the probablilities of the paradox occuring

One of two probabilistic models were used for most of the findings multinomial equiprobable

model(Impartial Culture condition) Anonymous Culture Condition(doesn’t

take voter identity into account)

Page 31: Economy of Elections

Maximal Culture Assumption

MC- used to generate profiles of preference

“neutral towards the alternatives and tends to characterize “close” elections”

Page 32: Economy of Elections

Probability of Paradox under MC

First let the set {A,B,C} be a given set of alternatives or in the case of elections candidates

Voters can have six linear preference orders for these three candidates ABC - BCA ACB - CBA BAC - CAB

Page 33: Economy of Elections

Prob. Con’t.

The probability of Condorcet's paradox in three-alternative elections under the Maximal Culture condition is given by: 11/120 +[

(99L4+341L3+474L3+305L+209)/(120(L+1)5)]

• This theorem is a representation of the probability of the Condorcet paradox occurring under MC as a function of the parameter L

Page 34: Economy of Elections

Expected probability

P(n,p) is the probability of a Condorcet winner where n is the number of voters and p is a vector showing the probability that a randomly selected voter has any of six linear rankings of the three candidates, assume all values for p are equally likely

P(n,p) given by 15(n+3)2/[16(n+2)(n+4)]

Page 35: Economy of Elections

Vote for someone outside one’s own true preference in order to prevent an undesirable outcome

Using the 2000 election as an example: Vote for Nader to prevent Gore from

winning This is known as strategic voting

Page 36: Economy of Elections

Example Florida in 2000

2,912,790 for Bush 2,912,253 for Gore 97,488 for Nader

Page 37: Economy of Elections

Voting in open Primaries

Democratic voters may vote in republican primaries and vote for the less qualified candidate so that the Democrat has a better chance of winning a general election

Page 38: Economy of Elections

Rent-Seeking Behavior

Activities designed to transfer surplus from one group to another

Context of tariffs and government intervention

Transferring wealth Lottery

Page 39: Economy of Elections

Elections

Campaigning to win an election Rent = Elected Position

Money, prestige, power

Page 40: Economy of Elections

Incentives

Corruption? Signaling Effect

Voters favor candidates supported by special interests

Page 41: Economy of Elections

Costs

Winner: comes out of rent Loser: comes from supporters

Page 42: Economy of Elections

Tussock’s Game:

Election Game:

Page 43: Economy of Elections
Page 44: Economy of Elections

Social Implications

Benefitting the rich Super PACs Publicly funded elections

Page 45: Economy of Elections

Works Cited http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0962629808000954

http://www.redistrictingthenation.com/glossary.aspx

http://www.redistrictinggame.org/launchgame.php?level=basic&mission=2

http://www.ccrpc.org/planning/pdfs/StatisticalStandards.pdf

http://www.nationaljournal.com/almanac/2010/area/il/04

http://www.yourdictionary.com/images/articles/lg/379.PresidentialElection.jpg

http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/en/thumb/e/e8/Florida_2000.PNG/200px-Florida_2000.PNG

http://www.jpattitude.com/Images/2000Election.jpg

http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/5/5b/Nicolas_de_Condorcet.PNG/220px-Nicolas_de_Condorcet.PNG

http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0165176581901075

Page 46: Economy of Elections

Downs, Anthony. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper & Row, 1957. Print.

Cowen, Tyler. “Why Politics is Stuck in the Middle.” The New York Times. 27 Feb.2010. Web. 21 April 2010.

Congleton, Roger. “The Median Voter Model.” The Encyclopedia of Public Choice. Kluwer Academic Press, 2002.

http://www.yourdictionary.com/images/articles/lg/379.PresidentialElection.jpg http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/en/thumb/e/e8/Florida_2000.PNG/200px-Florida_2000.PNG http://www.jpattitude.com/Images/2000Election.jpg http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/5/5b/Nicolas_de_Condorcet.PNG/220px-Nicolas_de_Condorcet.PNG http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0165176581901075

Page 47: Economy of Elections

http://www.yourdictionary.com/images/articles/lg/379.PresidentialElection.jpg http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/en/thumb/e/e8/Florida_2000.PNG/200px-Florida_2000.PNG http://www.jpattitude.com/Images/2000Election.jpg http://upload.wikimedia.org/wikipedia/commons/thumb/5/5b/Nicolas_de_Condorcet.PNG/220px-

Nicolas_de_Condorcet.PNG http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0165176581901075 http://www.jstor.org/stable/30025637?seq=1 http://www.jstor.org/stable/30025235?seq=1 Buchanan, James M., and Gordon Tullock. The Calculus of Consent ; Logical

Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 1965. Print.

David Colander, Microeconomics 8th Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2010), 189-190 , 487, 532-537

Bullock, David S. "Cooperative Game Theory and the Measurement of Political Power." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78.3 (1996): 745. Print.

Page 48: Economy of Elections

http://www.jstor.org/stable/30025637?seq=1

http://www.jstor.org/stable/30025235?seq=1

Buchanan, James M., and Gordon Tullock. The Calculus of Consent ; Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, 1965. Print.

David Colander, Microeconomics 8th Edition (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2010), 189-190 , 487, 532-537

Bullock, David S. "Cooperative Game Theory and the Measurement of Political Power." American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78.3 (1996): 745. Print.

Su, Francis E., et al. "Social Choice and the Condorcet Paradox." Math Fun Facts. http://www.math.hmc.edu/funfacts.

http://www.sccs.swarthmore.edu/users/08/ajb/tmve/wiki100k/docs/Condorcet_method.html

Felsenthal, Dan S., and Moshé Machover. "Voting Power Measurement: A Story of Misreinvention." Social Choice and Welfare 25.2-3 (2005): 485-506. Print.

Page 49: Economy of Elections

Su, Francis E., et al. "Social Choice and the Condorcet Paradox." Math Fun Facts. http://www.math.hmc.edu/funfacts.

http://www.sccs.swarthmore.edu/users/08/ajb/tmve/wiki100k/docs/Condorcet_method.html

http://re5qy4sb7x.search.serialssolutions.com/?ctx_ver=Z39.88-2004&ctx_enc=info:ofi/enc:UTF-8&ctx_tim=2012-04-22T12%3A18%3A06IST&url_ver=Z39.88-2004&url_ctx_fmt=infofi/fmt:kev:mtx:ctx&rfr_id=info:sid/primo.exlibrisgroup.com:primo3-Article-sciversesciencedirect_elsevier&rft_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:&rft.genre=article&rft.atitle=Condorcet%27s%20paradox%20under%20the%20maximal%20culture%20condition&rft.jtitle=Economics%20Letters&rft.btitle=&rft.aulast=Gehrlein&rft.auinit=&rft.auinit1=&rft.auinitm=&rft.ausuffix=&rft.au=Gehrlein%2C%20William%20V&rft.aucorp=&rft.date=1997&rft.volume=55&rft.issue=1&rft.part=&rft.quarter=&rft.ssn=&rft.spage=85&rft.epage=89&rft.pages=85-89&rft.artnum=&rft.issn=0165-1765&rft.eissn=&rft.isbn=&rft.sici=&rft.coden=&rft_id=info:doi/10.1016/S0165-1765(97)00046-3&rft.object_id=&svc_val_fmt=info:ofi/fmt:kev:mtx:sch_svc&svc.fulltext=yes&rft_dat=%3Csciversesciencedirect_elsevier%3ES0165-1765(97)00046-3%3C/sciversesciencedirect_elsevier%3E&rft.eisbn=&rft_id=info:oai/%3E