enders4e ppts ch01.684105

43
W ALTER ENDERS, UNIVERSITY OF ALABAMA Chapter 1: Difference Equations APPLIED ECONOMETRIC TIME SERIES FOURTH EDITION

Upload: sh4dowstrid3r9581

Post on 14-Apr-2016

239 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

DESCRIPTION

Applied Econometric Time Series_Walter Enders 4e Ch1

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

WALTER ENDERS, UNIVERSITY OF ALABAMA

Chapter 1: Difference Equations

APPLIED ECONOMETRICTIME SERIES

FOURTH EDITION

Page 2: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

TIME-SERIES MODELSSection 1

Page 3: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

The traditional use of time series models was for forecasting

If we knowyt+1 = a0 + a1yt + t+1

then Etyt+1 = a0 + a1yt

and since yt+2 = a0 + a1yt+1 + t+2

Etyt+2 = a0 + a1Etyt+1

= a0 + a1(a0 + a1yt)= a0 + a1a0 + (a1)2yt

Page 4: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Capturing Dynamic Relationships

• With the advent of modern dynamic economic models, the newer uses of time series models involve– Capturing dynamic economic relationships– Hypothesis testing

• Developing “stylized facts” – In a sense, this reverses the so-called scientific method

in that modeling goes from developing models that follow from the data.

Page 5: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

The Random Walk Hypothesis

yt+1 = yt + t+1

oryt+1 = t+1

where yt = the price of a share of stock on day t, and t+1 = a random disturbance term that has an expected value of zero.

Now consider the more general stochastic difference equation

yt+1 = a0 + a1yt + t+1

The random walk hypothesis requires the testable restriction:

a0 = a1 = 0.

Page 6: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

The Unbiased Forward Rate (UFR) hypothesis Given the UFR hypothesis, the forward/spot exchange rate relationship is:

st+1 = ft + t+1 (1.6)where t+1 has a mean value of zero from the perspective of time period t.Consider the regression

st+1 = a0 + a1ft + t+1

The hypothesis requires a0 = 0, a1 = 1, and that the regression residuals t+1 have a mean value of zero from the perspective of time period t.

The spot and forward markets are said to be in long-run equilibrium when t+1 = 0. Whenever st+1 turns out to differ from ft, some sort of adjustment must occur to restore the equilibrium in the subsequent period. Consider the adjustment process

st+2 = st+1 – a[ st+1 – ft ] + st+2 a > 0 (1.7)ft+1 = ft + b [ st+1 – ft ] + ft+1 b > 0 (1.8)

where st+2 andeft+1 both have an expected value of zero.

Page 7: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Trend-Cycle Relationships

• We can think of a time series as being composed of:

yt = trend + “cycle” + noise

– Trend: Permanent – Cycle: predictable (albeit temporary)

• (Deviations from trend)– Noise: unpredictable

Page 8: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 9: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Series with decidedly upward trend

Figure 3.1 Real GDP, Consumption and Investment

GDP Potential Consumption Investment

Trill

ions

of 2

005

dolla

rs

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 20100

2500

5000

7500

10000

12500

15000

Page 10: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

GDP Volatility?

Figure 3.2 Annualized Growth Rate of Real GDP

Per

cent

per

yea

r

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

Page 11: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Figure 3.3: Daily Changes in the NYSE US 100 Index: (Jan 4, 2000 - July 16, 2012)

perc

ent c

hang

e

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012-10.0

-7.5

-5.0

-2.5

0.0

2.5

5.0

7.5

10.0

12.5

Stock Market Volatility

Page 12: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Co-Movements

Figure 3.4 Short- and Long-Term Interest Rates

T-bi l l 5-year

perc

ent p

er y

ear

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 20100

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

Page 13: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Figure 3.5: Daily Exchange Rates (Jan 3, 2000 - April 4, 2013)

Euro Pound Sw iss Fr

curr

ency

per

dol

lar

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 20120.50

0.75

1.00

1.25

1.50

1.75

2.00

2.25

Common Trends

Page 14: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

DIFFERENCE EQUATIONS AND THEIR SOLUTIONS

Section 2

Page 15: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Consider the function yt* = f(t*)

We can then form the first differences:

yt = f(t) – f(t–1) yt – yt–1yt+1 = f(t+1) – f(t) yt+1 – ytyt+2 = f(t+2) – f(t+1) yt+2 – yt+1

More generally, for the forcing process xt a n-th order linear process is

*

* *

( * ) ( *)t h

t h t

y f t h f t y y

01

n

t i t i ti

y a a y x

Page 16: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

What is a solution?

A solution to a difference equation expresses the value of yt as a function of the elements of the {xt} sequence and t (and possibly some given values of the {yt} sequence called initial conditions).

The key property of a solution is that it satisfies the difference equation for all permissible values of t and {xt}.

01

n

t i t i ti

y a a y x

Page 17: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

SOLUTION BY ITERATION

Section 3• Iteration without an Initial Condition• Reconciling the Two Iterative Methods• Nonconvergent Sequences

Page 18: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Solution by IterationConsider the first-order equation

yt = a0 + a1yt–1 + t (1.17)

Given the value of y0, it follows that y1 will be given by1 = a0 + a1y0 + 1

In the same way, y2 must bey2 = a0 + a1y1 + 2

= a0 + a1[a0 + a1y0 + 1] + 2= a0 + a0a1 + (a1)2y0 + a11 + 2

Continuing the process in order to find y3, we obtainy3 = a0 + a1y2 + 3

= a0[1 + a1 + (a1)2] + (a1)3 y0 + a121 + a12 + 3

Page 19: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Fromy3 = a0[1 + a1 + (a1)2] + (a1)3 y0 + a1

21 + a12 + 3

you can verify that for all t > 0, repeated iteration yields1 1

0 1 00 0

t ti t i

t i i t ii i

y a a a y a

10 10

/(1 ) it it

i

a a y a

If | a1 | < 1, in the limit

Page 20: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Backwards Iteration

Iteration from yt back to y0 yields exactly the formula given by (1.18). Since yt = a0 + a1yt–1 + t, it follows that

yt = a0 + a1 [a0 + a1yt–2 + t–1] + t

= a0(1 + a1) + a1t–1 + t + a12[a0 + a1yt–3 + t–2]

If | a1 | < 1, in the limit

10 10

(1 ) it -it

i=

= a / a + y a

Page 21: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 22: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

AN ALTERNATIVE SOLUTION METHODOLOGY

Section 4• The Solution Methodology• Generalizing the Method

Page 23: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Does it converge? Characteristic Roots

Since the intercept and the t sequence have nothing to do with the issue of convergence, consider:

yt = a1yt–1

A solution is yt = A(a1)t

Proof:

• If a1 < 1, the yt converges to zero as t approaches infinity. Convergence is direct if 0 < a1 < 1 and oscillatory if –1 < a1 < 0.

• If a1 > 1, the homogeneous solution is not convergent. If a1 > 1, ytapproaches ∞ as t increases. If a1 < –1, the yt oscillates explosively.

• If a1 = 1, any arbitrary constant A satisfies the homogeneous equation yt = yt–1. If a1 = –1, the system is meta-stable: = 1 for even values of t and –1 for odd values of t.

11 1 1t tAa a Aa

Page 24: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Generalizing the Method

1

n

i t iti

a yy

A t – a1A t-1 – a2At-2 – … – anA t-n = 0

There are n roots

In the nth-order case

= A1(1)t + A2(2)t + …

For convergence, all of the roots must be less than unity in absolute value (or inside the unit circle if complex).

  hty

Page 25: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

1

1n

ii

a

1

| | 1n

ii

a

1

1n

ii

a

In an nth-order equation, a necessary condition for all characteristic roots to lie inside the unit circle is

Since the values of the ai can be positive or negative, a sufficient condition for all characteristic roots to lie inside the unit circle is

Any sequence that contains one or more characteristic roots that equal unity is called a unit root process.

For a third-order equation, the stability conditions can be written as1 – a1 – a2 – a3 > 01 + a1 – a2 + a3 > 01 – a1a3 + a2 – a3

2 > 03 + a1 + a2 – 3a3 > 0 or 3 – a1 + a2 + 3a3 > 0Given that the first three inequalities are satisfied, one of the last conditions is redundant.

At least one characteristic root equals unity if

Page 26: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

STEP 1: form the homogeneous equation and find all nhomogeneous solutions;

STEP 2: find a particular solution;

STEP 3: obtain the general solution as the sum of the particular solution and a linear combination of all homogeneous solutions;

STEP 4: eliminate the arbitrary constant(s) by imposing the initial condition(s) on the general solution.

The Solution Methodology

Page 27: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

THE COBWEB MODEL

Section 5• Stability Conditions• Higher-Order Systems

Page 28: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Setting supply equal to demand:

b + pt–1 + t = a – ptor

pt = (–/)pt–1 + (a – b)/ – t/

The homogeneous equation is pt = (–/)pt–1.

If the ratio / is less than unity, you can iterate (1.39) backward from pt to verify that the particular solution for the price is

0

1 ( / )p it t i

i

a bp

Stability requires | / | < 1

Page 29: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 30: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

SOLVING HOMOGENEOUSDIFFERENCE EQUATIONS

Section 6• Stability Conditions• Higher-Order Systems

Page 31: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Consider the second-order equation

yt – a1yt–1 – a2yt–2 = 0

A t – a1A t-1 – a2A t-2 = 0

If you divide (1.46) by At–2, the problem is to find the values of that satisfy

2 – a1 – a2 = 0

There are two characteristic roots. Hence the homogeneous solution is

A1(1)t + A2(2)t

Page 32: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

THE THREE CASES

CASE 1If a1

2 + 4a2 > 0, d is a real number and there will be two distinct real characteristic roots.

CASE 2If + 4a2 = 0, it follows that d = 0 and a1 = a2 = a1/2. A homogeneous solution is a1/2. However, when d = 0, there is a second homogeneous solution given by t(a1/2)t.

CASE 3If a1

2 + 4a2 < 0, it follows that d is negative so that the characteristic roots are imaginary.

Page 33: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 34: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 35: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Page 36: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

WORKSHEET 1.1: SECOND-ORDER EQUATIONSExample 1: yt = 0.2yt-1 + 0.35yt2. Hence: a1 = 0.2 and a2 = 0.35

Form the homogeneous equation: yt 0.2yt1 0.35yt2 = 0

d = + 4a2 so that d = 1.44. Given that d > 0, the roots will be real and distinct. Substitute yt = t into the homogenous equation to obtain: t – 0.2t1 – 0.35t2 = 0

Divide by t2 to obtain the characteristic equation: 2 – 0.2 0.35 = 0

Compute the two characteristic roots: 1 = 0.7 2 = −0.5

The homogeneous solution is: A1(0.7)t + A2(0.5)t. Example 2: yt = 0.7yt-1 + 0.35yt2. Hence: a1 = 0.7 and a2 = 0.35

Form the homogeneous equation: yt 0.7yt-1 0.35yt2 = 0

Thus d = + 4a2 = 1.89. Given that d > 0, the roots will be real and distinct. Form the characteristic equation t – 0.7t1 – 0.35t2 = 0

Divide by t2 to obtain the characteristic equation: 2 – 0.7 – 0.35 = 0

Compute the two characteristic roots: 1 = 1.037 2 = 0.337

The homogeneous solution is: A1(1.037)t + A2(–0.337)t.

Page 37: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

THE METHOD OF UNDETERMINED COEFFICIENTS

Section 8

Page 38: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

The Method of Undetermined Coefficients

Consider the simple first-order equation: yt = a0 + a1yt–1 + t

Posit the challenge solution:

b0 + a0t + a1t–1 + a2t–2 + … = a0 + a1[b0 + a0t–1 + a1t–2 + ] + t

0 − 1 = 0a1 – a1a0 = 0a2 – a1a1 = 0b0 – a0 – a1b0 = 0

0 i t iti=0

= b +y

01

011i

t iti

a aya

Page 39: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

The Method of Undetermined Coefficients IIConsider: yt = a0 + a1yt–1 + a2yt–2 + t (1.68)

Since we have a second-order equation, we use the challenge solutionyt = b0 + b1t + b2t2 + a0t + a1t–1 + a2t–2 +

where b0, b1, b2, and the ai are the undetermined coefficients. Substituting the challenge solution into (1.68) yields

[b0+b1t+b2t2] + a0t + a1t–1 + a2t–2+ = a0 + a1[b0 + b1(t – 1) + b2(t – 1)2

+ a0t–1 + a1t–2 + a2t–3 + ] + a2[b0 + b1(t – 2) + b2(t – 2)2

+ a0t–2 + a1t–3 + a2t-4 + ] + t

Hence:a0 = 1a1 = a1a0 [so that a1 = a1]a2 = a1a1 + a2a0 [so that a2 = (a1)2 + a2]a3 = a1a2 + a2a1 [so that a3 = (a1)3 + 2a1a2]

Notice that for any value of j 2, the coefficients solve the second-order difference equation aj = a1aj–1 + a2aj–2.

Page 40: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

LAG OPERATORS

Section 9• Lag Operators in Higher-Order Systems

Page 41: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Lag Operators

The lag operator L is defined to be:

Liyt = yt-i

Thus, Li preceding yt simply means to lag yt by i periods.

The lag of a constant is a constant: Lc = c.

The distributive law holds for lag operators. We can set:

(Li + Lj)yt = Liyt + Ljyt = yt-i + yt-j

Page 42: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

Lag Operators (cont’d)

• Lag operators provide a concise notation for writing differenceequations. Using lag operators, the p-th order equation

yt = a0 + a1yt-1 + ... + apyt-p + εt can be written as:

(1 - a1L - a2L2 - ... - apLp)yt = εtor more compactly as:

A(L)yt = εt

As a second example,yt = a0 + a1yt-1 + ... + apyt-p + εt + β1εt-1 + ... + βqεt-q as:

A(L)yt = a0 + B(L)εt

where: A(L) and B(L) are polynomials of orders p and q, respectively.

Page 43: Enders4e Ppts Ch01.684105

Copyright © 2015 John, Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved.

APPENDIX 1.1: IMAGINARY ROOTS AND DE MOIVRE’S THEOREM