energy security and climate change policy in the oecd: the … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii...

306
Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The Political Economy of Carbon-Energy Taxation by Érick Lachapelle A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Graduate Department of Political Science University of Toronto Copyright by Érick Lachapelle 2011 2011-02-16

Upload: others

Post on 07-Oct-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD:

The Political Economy of Carbon-Energy Taxation by

Érick Lachapelle

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements

for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

Graduate Department of Political Science

University of Toronto

Copyright by Érick Lachapelle 2011

2011-02-16

Page 2: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

ii

Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD:

The Political Economy of Carbon-Energy Taxation

by

Érick Lachapelle

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements

for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

Department of Political Science

University of Toronto

February 2011

Abstract

Why do countries tax the same fuels at widely different rates, even among similarly

situated countries in the global political economy? Given the potentially destabilizing

effects of climate change, and the political and economic risks associated with a reliance

on geographically concentrated, finite fossil fuels, International Organizations and

economists of all political stripes have consistently called for increasing tax rates on

fossil-based energy. Despite much enthusiasm among policy experts, however, politicians

concerned with distributional consequences, economic performance and competitiveness

impacts continue to be wary of raising taxes on carbon-based fuels.

In this context, this thesis investigates the political economy of tax rates affecting the

price of fossil fuels in advanced capitalist democracies. Through an examination of the

political limits of government capacity to implement stricter carbon-energy policy, as

well as the identification of the correlates of higher carbon-based energy taxes, it throws

new light on the conditions under which carbon-energy tax reform becomes politically

possible. Based on recent data collected from the OECD, EEA and IEA, I develop an

estimate of the relative size of implicit carbon taxes across OECD member countries on

six carbon-based fuels and across the household and industrial sectors. I exploit large

Page 3: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

iii

cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the

correlates of, and constraints on, carbon-energy tax reform. Applying multiple regression

analysis to both cross-section and time-series cross-sectional (TSCS) data, this thesis

leverages considerable empirical evidence to demonstrate how and why electoral systems

matter for energy and environmental tax policy outcomes.

In particular, I find considerable empirical evidence to support the claim that systems of

proportional representation (PR), in addition to the partisan preferences of the electorate,

work together to explain differential rates of carbon-energy taxation. By opening up the

ideological space to a broader spectrum of “green” parties, I argue that PR systems create

a favourable institutional context within which higher rates of carbon-energy taxation

become politically possible. After specifying a key causal mechanism within different

types of electoral systems – the seat-vote elasticity – I argue further that, voters in

disproportional systems actually have more leverage over politicians, and that an increase

in environmental voting can have an impact on rates of carbon energy taxation, even in

the absence of PR. While the accession to power of green political parties in PR systems

is more likely to lead to higher rates of carbon energy taxation, voting for green parties in

highly disproportional systems creates incentives for other parties to adopt “green”

policies, leading to a similar outcome. In this way, the effect of green votes and green

seats will have the opposite effect on policy according to the type of electoral system in

use.

Page 4: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

iv

Acknowledgements

I am extremely grateful to several people that provided generous help and support over

the course of this PhD journey. In particular, I owe much to Professor Stephen Clarkson,

without whom I would not have found myself at the University of Toronto, and Professor

Richard B. Day, an intellectual inspiration early on in my University of Toronto

academic career.

A very big thanks goes to the members of my committee: Louis W. Pauly, Neil Nevitte,

and Rodney Haddow. As my supervisor, Professor Pauly provided excellent guidance

and support, both intellectually and professionally. Always pushing me to clarify my

thinking, Professor Pauly proved to be a great help as a pedagogical and professional

advisor. Professor Nevitte proved to be an excellent mentor, educator and supporter,

while my research benefited a great deal from many stimulating discussions with

Professor Haddow. It was an honour to work with these excellent scholars.

Beyond my committee a number of other professors offered generous time and feedback

along the way. At the University of Toronto: Steven Bernstein, Christian Breunig, Don

Dewees, Danny Harvey, Matt Hoffman, Larry LeDuc, Doug Macdonald and Grace

Skogstad deserve particular mention. Other members of the academic community were

also kind enough to read my work and provide very helpful comments. I am especially

indebted to John Allan, Kathy Harrison, Mike Kraft, Caroline Kuzemko, James

Meadowcroft and Barry Rabe. These scholars provided generous comments and their

own work was a tremendous source of inspiration. Finally, I should also like to thank my

new colleagues at l’Université de Montréal for immediately making me feel welcome in a

leading Canadian research institution.

If a journey is best measured in friends than in miles, my time at the University of

Toronto ranks as one of the best in my life. I cannot acknowledge all of them here, but

should make particular mention of Chris Alcantara, Amar Athwal, Sebastian Baglioni,

Chris Cochrane, Joëlle Dumouchel, Gabe Eidelman, Bill Flanik, Vic Gomez, Josh

Page 5: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

v

Gordon, David Houle, Mike Painter-Main, Vincent Pouliot, Mark Purdon, Reuven

Schlozberg, Anthony Sealey, Deb Thompson, and Ruben Zaiotti. Thanks to Matt Cripps,

Marcus Coutou, Joe Fagioli and Chris Palis for keeping me grounded through it all.

I also gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Social Sciences and Humanities

Research Council of Canada, the Ontario Graduate Scholarship Program, the School of

Graduate Studies, the Royal Bank of Canada, and the Department of Political Science at

the University of Toronto. This support provided me with the means to finance my

research and was thus instrumental in the completion of this project. I should finally like

to thank Laine Russ of the Data Library Services at Robarts Library for all her assistance,

as well as Joan Kalis, Carolynn Branton, Leanne Thomas and all of the administrative

support offered by the Department of Political Science. The essential work of these

individuals too often goes unrecognized in a large institution like the University of

Toronto, and they deserve my special thanks. I am happy to count these wonderful people

among my friends.

Finally my deepest gratitude goes to my immediate family – mom, dad, sister and her two

amazing boys – who loyally supported me throughout all of my academic studies. In

particular, my parents have consistently been a wonderful source of inspiration and

taught me to never give up. I dedicate this work to them – my dear mother and father –

among the most hard working and honest people I know, without whose care and

encouragement none of this would have ever been possible.

Page 6: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

vi

Table of Contents

Abstract………………………………………………………….……………………….ii Acknowledgements……………………………………………………………………...iv List of Tables…………………………………………………………………………...viii List of Figures…………………………………………………………………………….x Acronyms………………………………..……………………………………………....xii

1. ENERGY SECURITY, CLIMATE CHANGE, AND THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TAXING FOSSIL FUELS 1

1.1. CONTEXT: COMPLEX PROBLEMS AND COMMON CHALLENGES IN THE OECD 1 1.1.1. COMMON SOLUTIONS TO THE PROBLEMS OF ENERGY SECURITY AND CLIMATE CHANGE 4 1.1.2. THE POLITICAL LIMITS TO TAXING CARBON 7 1.2. PUZZLE: CROSS-NATIONAL DIFFERENCES IN FOSSIL FUEL TAXATION 11 1.3. TOPIC, RESEARCH QUESTIONS AND PURPOSE 12 1.4. SCOPE 13 1.5. LITERATURE REVIEW 16 1.5.1. THE COMPARATIVE POLITICS OF CARBON TAXATION – WHAT DO WE KNOW? 17 1.5.2. THE ROLE OF POLITICAL INSTITUTIONS 24 1.6. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND ASSUMPTIONS 27 1.7. THEORETICAL ARGUMENT 34 1.8. CHAPTER SUMMARY 39

2. THE ECONOMICS OF PRICING CARBON 40

2.1.1. FOSSIL FUEL EXTERNALITIES: CLIMATE CHANGE 43 2.1.2. FOSSIL FUEL EXTERNALITIES: ENERGY SECURITY 55 2.2. INTERNALIZING EXTERNALITIES: PRICING CARBON 57 2.2.1. OPTIONS FOR PRICING CARBON 59 2.2.3. CARBON TRADING 65 2.2.4. COMPARING TAX AND TRADE 66 2.3. ISSUES IN THE DESIGN OF A CARBON TAX 69 2.4. THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF INSTRUMENT CHOICE 75

3. THE POLITICAL LIMITS TO IMPLEMENTING CARBON TAXES 79

3.1. TAKING STOCK OF EXPLICIT CARBON TAXES IN THE OECD: A CRITICAL APPRAISAL 81 3.2. TRENDS IN EXPLICIT CARBON TAXES 83 3.3. CASE STUDY: MAJORITARIAN ELECTORAL SYSTEMS AND THE BRITISH COLUMBIA CARBON TAX 96

4. ENERGY TAXES AS IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES: EXPLORING CROSS-NATIONAL DIFFERENCES 110

4.1. ENERGY TAXES VS. CARBON TAXES 112 4.2. ENERGY TAXES AS IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES 114 4.3. WHY STUDY IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES? 118 4.3.1. THEORETICAL IMPORTANCE FOR POLITICAL SCIENCE 120 4.3.2. PRACTICAL IMPLICATIONS FOR POLICY 122

Page 7: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

vii

4.4. ESTIMATING IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES 127 4.5. DESCRIPTIVE ANALYSIS 132 4.5.1. DIFFERENCES ACROSS FUELS 135 4.5.2. DIFFERENCES ACROSS SECTORS 137 4.6: THE PUZZLE: DIFFERENCES IN IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES ACROSS COUNTRIES AND OVER TIME 139 4.6.1: CROSS-NATIONAL DIFFERENCES IN IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES 141 4.6.2: IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES OVER TIME 143 4.6.3: THE REAL PUZZLE 145

5. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF TAXING FOSSIL FUELS 147

5.1: ARGUMENT 148 5.2: HYPOTHESES 150 5.3: DATA AND METHODS 151 5.4: EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS AND EVIDENCE 155 5.5: IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES ON FUELS USED BY INDUSTRY 156 5.5.1:STEAM COAL 157 5.5.2: HEAVY FUEL OIL 177 5.6. IMPLICIT CARBON TAXES ON FUELS USED BY HOUSEHOLDS 195 5.6.1: DIESEL 206 5.6.2: GASOLINE 221 5.7: SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION 237

6. CARBON-ENERGY POLICY AT A CROSS-ROADS: PROSPECTS FOR THE FUTURE 243

6.1. KEY FINDINGS 244 6.2. CONTRIBUTIONS 248 6.3. THE WAY FORWARD 250

APPENDIX 1: VARIABLE DEFINITIONS 253

APPENDIX 2: OPERATIONALIZING THE DEPENDENT VARIABLE 258

APPENDIX 3: EMISSION FACTORS 266

BIBLIOGRAPHY 267

Page 8: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

viii

List of Tables Table 1.1: Electoral system and the number of years with at least one

green party member in the elected legislature (1978-2006)..........35 Table 2.1.1.1: Highlights of possible climate impacts discussed by Stern……...52 Table 2.1.2.1: Crude oil imports (2006)..………………………………………..55 Table 2.2.4.1: Main features of carbon tax vs. cap-and-trade………………...…67 Table 3.2.1: Carbon taxes in selected OECD jurisdictions……………………86 Table 3.2.2: Carbon tax rates by fuel type, in current USD/tonne of CO2…….95 Table 3.3.1: Summary of tax departures………………………………………97 Table 3.3.1: Electoral competition in key coal and natural gas districts:

vote shares (in percentages)…………………………………….108 Table 4.4.1: Tax rates on Unleaded Gasoline in Canada (in CAD dollars)….128 Table 4.4.2: Tax rates on Natural Gas in Switzerland (in Swiss Francs)…….129 Table 4.4.3. Emission factors………………………………………………...130 Table 4.5: Implicit carbon tax (constant USD/tCO2) by fuel type (2006)....134 Table 4.5.1: Average implicit carbon taxes across OECD (2006), constant

USD/tCO2………………………………………………………136 Table 5.5.1.1: Summary statistics for coal tax regression models……………..164 Table 5.5.1.2: Coal tax regression models testing the ideological space

hypothesis (H2)…………………………………………………165 Table 5.5.1.3: Implicit carbon taxes on coal by left wing cabinet portfolios

and PR…………………………………………………………..169 Table: 5.5.1.4: Coal tax regression models testing the disproportional

constraints hypothesis (H3)……………………………………..171 Table 5.5.1.5: Robustness checks for (H2) in regression models of

square root coal tax with robust standard errors………………..175 Table 5.5.1.6: Robustness checks for (H3) in regression models of coal tax

with robust standard errors……………………………………..176 Table 5.5.2.1: Summary statistics for HFO tax regression models………….…183 Table 5.5.2.2: HFO tax regression models testing the ideological space

hypothesis (H2)…………………………………………………184 Table 5.5.2.3: Implicit carbon taxes on HFO by left wing cabinet portfolios

and PR….……………………………………………………….188 Table 5.5.2.4: HFO tax regression models testing the disproportional

constraints hypothesis (H3)……………………………………..189 Table 5.5.2.5: Robustness checks for (H2) regression models with

robust standard errors…………………………………………...193 Table 5.5.2.6: Robustness checks for (H3) regression models with

robust standard errors…………………...………………………194

Page 9: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

ix

Table 5.6.1: Summary of variables and hypothesized relationships…………203 Table 5.6.2: Summary statistics for motor fuel tax regression models………204 Table 5.6.1.1: Diesel tax regression models testing the

ideological space hypothesis (H2)……………………………...209 Table 5.6.1.2: Diesel tax regression models testing the

disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3)……………………213 Table 5.6.1.3: Diesel tax regression models testing the electoral incentives

hypothesis (H4)…………………………………………………218 Table 5.6.2.1: Gasoline tax regression models testing the

ideological space hypothesis (H2)…………………………...…225 Table 5.6.2.2: Gasoline tax regression models testing the disproportional

constraints hypothesis (H3)…………………………………….229 Table 5.6.2.3: Gasoline tax regression models testing the electoral incentives

hypothesis (H4)…………………………………………………233 Table 5.7.1: Performance of primary research hypotheses across fuels……..240

Page 10: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

x

List of Figures Figure 1.1: World primary energy demand by fuel type in the IEA Reference

Scenario………………………………………………………………...…2 Figure 2.1.1.1: Changes in temperature, sea level and Northern snow cover……………44 Figure 2.1.1.2: Radiative forcing components…………………………………………...47 Figure 2.1.1.3: Temperature and CO2 concentration in the atmosphere…………………48 Figure 2.1.1.4: Atmospheric concentration of carbon dioxide…………………………..49 Figure 2.1.1.5: Global anthropogenic GHG emissions…………………………………..50 Figure 2.1.1.6: Global GHG emissions by source……………………………………….50 Figure 2.1.2.1: World price of oil (Brent Sweet Crude spot price)……………………...55 Figure 2.3.1: Setting the optimal carbon tax level……......…………………………….72 Figure 3.2.1: Percentage of fossil energy in electricity production……………….…...89 Figure 3.2.2: Change in nominal tax rate over time……………………………………93 Figure 3.2.3: Change in real tax rate over time………………………………………...93 Figure 3.3.1: Tax rates applied under BC’s carbon tax by carbon content of fuels……99 Figure 3.3.2: Share of natural gas in BC mineral production…………………………102 Figure 3.3.3: Support for environmental taxation…………………………………….105 Figure 3.3.4: Geographical distribution of coal and gas in BC……………………….106 Figure 4.3.2.1: Gasoline price and tax differentials, in current USD (2008)…………..125 Figure 4.3.2.2: Total gasoline price by tax rate in current USD/L (2008)……………..126 Figure 4.5.1: Average implicit carbon taxes (USD/tCO2) by fuel, OECD (2006)…...137 Figure 4.5.2: Mean tax rate across sectors in constant (2000) USD/tCO2……………138 Figure 4.6.1: Implicit carbon tax rates for selected OECD countries (2006)…………142 Figure 4.6.2: Implicit carbon taxes on coal, in selected OECD countries…………….144

Figure 5.3: Mean income of OECD countries (2006)………………………………154 Figure 5.5.1.1: Implicit carbon tax rate on steam coal used by industry……………….158 Figure 5.5.1.2: Total coal production………………………………………………...…159 Figure 5.5.1.3: Implicit carbon tax on steam coal by level of corporatism…………….161 Figure 5.5.1.4: Implicit carbon tax rate on steam coal by electoral regime (H1)………162 Figure 5.5.1.5: The marginal effect of left party cabinet portfolios under PR (H2)……168 Figure 5.5.1.6: The marginal effect of left wing cabinet portfolios in disproportional

systems (H3)……………………………………………………………172 Figure 5.5.2.1: Implicit carbon tax rate on heavy fuel oil used by industry……………178 Figure 5.4.2.2: Net crude oil exports in selected OECD countries……………………..179 Figure 5.5.2.3: Implicit carbon tax on HFO by level of corporatism…………………..181 Figure 5.5.2.4: Implicit carbon tax rate on HFO by electoral regime (H1)…………….182 Figure 5.5.2.5: The marginal effect of left party cabinet portfolios under PR (H2)……187 Figure 5.5.2.6: The marginal effect of left wing cabinet portfolios in disproportional

systems (H3)…………………………………………………………....190

Page 11: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

xi

Figure 5.6.1.1: Implicit carbon tax on diesel fuel for household consumer use………..206 Figure 5.6.1.2: Implicit carbon tax rate on (non-commercial) diesel fuel by

electoral regime (H1)…………………………………………………...207 Figure 5.6.1.3: The marginal effect of green parties in the legislature under PR (H2)...211 Figure 5.6.1.4: Marginal effect of green seat share in disproportional systems (H3)….215 Figure 5.6.1.5: Marginal effect of green/new-left votes in

disproportional systems (H4)…………………………………………..220 Figure 5.6.2.1: Implicit carbon tax rate on gasoline for private household use………..222 Figure 5.6.2.2: Implicit carbon tax rate on gasoline by electoral regime (H1)………...223 Figure 5.6.2.3: The marginal effect of green/new left party cabinet portfolios

by electoral regime (H2)……………………………………………….227 Figure 5.6.2.4: The marginal effect of green/left cabinet in

disproportional systems (H3)…………………………………………..231 Figure 5.6.2.4: Marginal effect of green votes in disproportional systems (H4)………235

Page 12: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

xii

Acronyms BC British Columbia Btu British thermal unit CO2 Carbon dioxide CBO Congressional Budget Office EIA Energy Information Administration EC European Commission ETS Emissions Trading Scheme EU European Union FE Fixed effects FPTP First past the post GCF Gross calorific value GDP Gross Domestic Product GHG Greenhouse gases GWh Gigawatt hour HFO Heavy fuel oil IEA International Energy Agency IPCC International Panel on Climate Change IMF International Monetary Fund kcal Kilocalories kt Kilotonne ktoe Kilotonnes of oil equivalent kWh Kilowatt hour LDV Lagged dependent variable LFO Light fuel oil LOSU Level of scientific understanding LSDV Least squares dummy variable Mtoe Million-tonnes of oil equivalent m3 Cubic metres NCV Net calorific value NGO Non-Governmental Organization NRC National Research Council NRTEE National Roundtable on the Environment and the Economy OECD Organization for Cooperation and Economic Development OLS Ordinary least squares PCSE Panel-corrected standard errors Pg Pico grams ppm Parts per million PPP Purchasing Power Parity PR Proportional representation Qbtu Quadrillion British Thermal Units SMP Single member plurality Tg Terra gram toe Tonnes of oil equivalent UNFCCC United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change W m2 Watts per square metre

Page 13: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

1

Chapter 1: Introduction

1. Energy security, climate change, and the political economy of taxing fossil fuels

1.1. Context: complex problems and common challenges in the OECD

Meeting growing energy needs while minimizing the environmental impact of fossil fuel

dependence is one of the central governance challenges of the 21st century. Economic

growth, industrialization, rising population levels and the increased use of electronic and

other energy-consuming devices are fueling rapid increases in energy consumption the

world over. According to the IEA’s Reference Scenario,1 global energy demand is

expected to increase 40 per cent, from 12,000 million tonnes of oil equivalent (Mtoe) in

2007 to 16,800 Mtoe in 2030, with fossil fuels accounting for more than three quarters of

this growth (IEA, 2009b: 42 and 74). Unless governments dramatically change course,

global demand will place additional pressure on already strained energy delivery

infrastructure and finite supply, inevitably raising the price of fossil fuels, the continued

use of which promises to add millions of additional tonnes of CO2 into the current

atmospheric stock. The 2009 IEA Reference Scenario, and the projected dominance of

fossil fuels, is depicted in Figure 1.1.2

1 The IEA reference scenario presents a baseline picture of how global energy markets are likely to evolve in the absence of changes to existing government policies. It thus presents a forecast of trends under a “business as usual” scenario. 2 The dotted line, “WEO-2008” is the Reference Scenario developed in 2008. The 2009 Reference Scenario has slightly revised the forecast in energy demand in light of the impact of the global recession.

Page 14: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

2

Figure 1.1: World primary energy demand by fuel type in the IEA Reference Scenario

Source: IEA (2009b: 75) As can be seen in Figure 1.1, global energy demand is expected to increase about 40%

over the next twenty years as emerging economies in China and India continue to

industrialize at unprecedented rates. Even after the recession of 2009 is accounted for,

revised estimates are just a few percentage points lower than the WEO 2008 Reference

Scenario, indicated by the dotted line in Figure 1.1. Thus, in the business-as-usual

scenario such scarce fossil fuels as oil and gas make up an increasing share of the total

energy mix, while the use of coal also continues to rise.

In light of global energy challenges, like peak oil (Campbell, 1997; Deffeyes, 2001) and

peak gas (Darley, 2004) this reliance on finite fossil fuels to meet growing energy

demand is disconcerting. From an energy security perspective, economic and

geopolitical concerns regarding continued dependence on imported energy, and the

concentration of proven reserves in unstable regions of the world (IEA, 2005:56),

constitute a strategic weakness for energy intensive and energy-importing states (Adelle

et al. 2009; Yergin, 2006). As noted by Hughes (2006) – a geologist with Natural

Resources Canada – the issue is not just one of scarce resources, but also one of

deliverability. Even if Canada quadrupled production of its tar sands, for instance, the

added production would only represent 5% of the IEA’s projected demand. Thus, the real

Page 15: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

3

questions are how fast can oil resources be converted to supply in the face of growing

demand, and at what cost? In addition, most of the remaining reserves are not found in

Canada, and some fear that a dependence on external sources of supply, particularly from

the Middle East and parts of Africa, challenge a variety of “national interests” held by

Western governments. For instance, energy supply disruptions threaten continued

economic growth, and funneling currency to petro-states could threaten the

democratization and counterterrorism objectives of the U.S. and its Western allies

(Deutch and Schlesinger, 2006; Downs, 2006). Such concerns are particularly acute in

energy dependent parts of Europe and the U.S., prompting former U.S. President George

W. Bush to say, “I’ve often said one of the worst problems we have is that we’re

dependent on foreign sources of crude oil, and we are […] we need alternative sources of

energy” (quoted in Collina, 2005, emphasis added).

From an environmental perspective, the continued reliance on fossil fuels, especially an

increase in the use of coal, presents an additional risk. Although coal is the one fossil fuel

for which the world has comparatively large remaining reserves, continued use of this

relatively cheap polluting fuel threatens to emit millions of additional tonnes of carbon

dioxide to the existing stock, which according to some is already too high (Chandler,

2009; Hansen et al. 2008; Harvey, 2010). For this reason, global climate change

continues to attract much attention as potentially one of the most significant economic

and environmental threats facing humanity today (IPCC, 2007b; Stern, 2006).

Notwithstanding some of the recent controversy over a series of leaked emails from the

University of East Anglia, in which climate scientists were caught in a maelstrom of

accusations regarding hidden and manipulated data (Katz, 2010),3 over 97 per cent of

actively publishing climate scientists agree with the main conclusion of the IPCC;

namely, that human activity is responsible for observed increases in mean global

temperatures (Anderegg et al. 2010). Moreover, thousands of the world’s leading climate

scientists who make up the IPCC are calling for massive and immediate reductions to

greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions in order to avert tipping points (Lenton et al. 2008) and

3The subsequent public inquiry into the “Climategate” ordeal has since cleared climate scientists of any wrongdoing (Adam, 2010).

Page 16: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

4

the potentially catastrophic consequences of climate change (IPCC, 2007b; Hansen et al.

2008; Meinshausen et al. 2009). As a result, reducing the primary cause of human-

induced emissions – from burning fossil fuels – is now commonly identified as an

important objective of governments – at all levels – around the world (Pew, 2010).

1.1.1. Common solutions to the problems of energy security and climate change

Although energy security and climate change pose very different problems for

governments, they converge on the solutions commonly proposed to address them (c.f.

Adelle et al. 2009; IEA, 2007a; IMF, 1994; 2008). For instance, policies that discourage

the demand for fossil fuels promote energy conservation (and a reduction in dependence

on energy imports) greater efficiency (and technological innovation) as well as a

reduction in emissions from fossil fuel combustion. For these reasons, economists of all

political stripes – who otherwise rarely agree on anything – have become fervent

advocates of increasing the price of fossil fuels, and almost uniformly, support a carbon

tax.

Among the most prominent carbon tax proponents is former chief economic advisor to

George W. Bush, Gregory Mankiw, who in 2006 proposed an increase in the gas tax of

$1 per gallon which is equivalent to a carbon tax of over $100 per tonne of CO2, or

roughly $367 per tonne of carbon (Mankiw, 2006).4 Evidence of a “carbon tax

consensus” can be found on Mankiw’s pro-carbon tax blog, The Pigou Club, which lists

such prominent economists as William Nordhaus, Martin Feldstein, Alan Greenspan,

Gary Becker, Paul Krugman, Thomas Friedman, Richard Posner, Joe Stiglitz, Robert

Samuelson, Paul Volcker, and Lawrence Summers, among others, as supporters of

increasing taxes on fossil fuels. Adding to the list, a recent poll of economists by the

Wall Street Journal found a majority of economists agreed that a carbon tax is the best

4 Authors own calculation based on an emission factor of 8.8 kg of carbon dioxide per gallon of gasoline using mission factor from the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA, 2005). To convert from a tax on carbon dioxide to an equivalent tax on carbon, multiply the former by the molecular ratio of CO2 to carbon (44/12).

Page 17: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

5

way to encourage investment in alternative energy (Izzo, 2007). Even the right-leaning

American Enterprise Institute (AEI) has published several endorsements of a carbon tax

(Green et al. 2007; Hassett and Metcalfe, 2006). Such evidence highlights the extent to

which an ideologically diverse group of economists – from Nobel Prize winning

conservative economist Garry Becker, to left-leaning economists Paul Krugman and

Joseph Stiglitz – have united under the banner of putting a tax on carbon.

To be sure, part of the reason for its intellectual appeal is rooted in the ability of the

carbon tax to contribute not only to environmental objectives, but to national security

goals as well. As noted by Becker (2009):

A tax on carbon emissions from business and household production would not only help reduce global warming […] but it would also lower the world prices of these fuels through reducing the demand for fossil fuels. Lower prices would cut the revenues received by Middle Eastern states from the sale of oil and natural gas. This is why a carbon tax receives support from many environmentalists and national security advocates.

Framed in terms of national security, carbon taxes garner additional appeal in energy-

dependent states. By raising the price of gasoline and other fossil fuels across the entire

economy (i.e. all sectors including households), some of the costs of foreign energy

dependence (e.g. vulnerability to supply disruptions, financing of the military to protect

infrastructure) can be internalized, all while encouraging energy conservation, investment

in domestic energy alternatives, fiscal room for governments and reductions in emissions

of CO2 (IMF, 1994). In addition, it is often suggested that a carbon tax provides a way of

diminishing OPEC’s rents, which accrue each time the price of fossil fuels rise, thus

diminishing the prospect of petrol dollars being used against Western interests (Liski and

Tahvonen, 2004).5

In addition, increasing tax rates on fossil fuels appeals to environmentalists. Indeed,

many popular voices in the environmental community have been converted to the free-

5 It would take an equivalent carbon tax of close to $400 USD/ tonne of CO2 to match the sharp rise in gasoline prices experienced in the U.S. between February 2008 and July 2008 (about $3.5 per gallon).

Page 18: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

6

market fundamentalism of economists, and have joined the choir advocating an increase

in taxes on energy and fossil fuels (e.g. Brown, 2003; Suzuki and DesRosiers, 2007;

Hansen, 2008). According to its proponents, a revenue-neutral carbon tax shift is the

most “rational” policy (Newbery, 2005), holding the promise of encouraging investment,

innovation and productivity (Lanoie et al. 2008; Martin and Kemper, 2010), more jobs

(Goodstein et al. 2010), all while improving the environment and making the tax system

more efficient. As a result, it is sometimes argued that, if properly designed, carbon taxes

can yield a strong “double dividend” in terms of realizing net welfare gains in addition to

environmental benefits (Bento and Jacobsen, 2007). For all these reasons, advocates

claim that carbon taxes are simply the right thing to do.

Despite their broad intellectual appeal and near universal support from economists –

sometimes perceived as having substantial influence on policy (Babb, 2001; Blyth, 2002;

Fourcade, 2006; Hall, 1989) – governments have been markedly less enthusiastic about

implementing carbon taxes, energy taxes, or other types of climate policy, for that matter.

Indeed, while carbon and energy tax shifts are the most frequently advocated response to

climate change and energy security,6 relatively few jurisdictions across the OECD have

implemented the recommended tax reforms,7 and several high profile energy tax

proposals have failed, oftentimes quite miserably.8 Moreover, as documented in Chapter

3, even those countries that have implemented carbon tax proposals with some degree of

success generally fail to apply uniform rates on carbon economy wide, the sin qua non of

a pure carbon tax. Such a state of affairs raises the question: why is the most frequently

advocated, straightforward and rational policy response to climate change also the

most difficult? 6 In addition to the wealth of supporting evidence provided on the web (see Mankiw’s Pigou Club Manifesto), several studies on expert opinion empirically document the preference of economists for carbon taxes. See for instance GAO (2008), Haab (2009); Holliday et al. (2009), Izzo (2007). 7 To date, only six OECD jurisdictions have implemented the economists preferred policy of a broad-based, revenue-neutral carbon tax; Finland (1990), Sweden (1991), Norway (1991), Denmark (1992), the Netherlands (1996) and British Columbia (2008) fall into this category. Other examples of broader environmental tax shifts include Germany (1999) and the United Kingdon (2001). 8 Notable cases of ill-fated carbon/energy tax proposals include U.S. President Clinton’s proposed Btu tax (1993), Italy’s suspended carbon tax (2000), New Zealand’s abandoned carbon tax following the re-election of a minority government (2005), the dismal election performance of Canadian Liberal Party Leader Stephen Dion, who campaigned and lost on a carbon tax propsosal (2008), and the recent French constitutional court decision to strike down President Sarkozy’s carbon tax plan.

Page 19: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

7

1.1.2. The political limits to taxing carbon Underestimating the political difficulty of responding to climate change and of

implementing a carbon price is common in social science (Rabe, Lachapelle and Houle,

forthcoming), and the case of energy taxation is no exception. To be sure, the

conventional wisdom on the problem of climate change is that it is, first and foremost, a

global problem, in both its causes and consequences, thus requiring an international

solution. However, this approach raises problems of collective action and thorny

questions regarding how to equitably share the mitigation burden (Stern, 2006). Unlike

localized transboundary pollution issues, climate change is truly a global problem, insofar

as a tonne of CO2 emitted will have the same effect on global climate, regardless of

whether it originated from Shanxi or Alberta. Since it is total CO2 emissions from all

countries that is relevant for the climate, coordinated emission reductions are required

around the globe; otherwise, unilateral actions have no substantive impact on the global

stock of atmospheric levels of CO2.9 But cooperation on this issue at the international

level poses a major challenge in terms of getting a large number of sovereign states –

each with varying vulnerabilities to climate change and emission trajectories – to agree

(Hoffmann, 2005; Stern, 2006: 450). As argued by Olson (1965), the larger the group, the

smaller the likelihood of meeting the need for collective goods through voluntary (or

unilateral) actions alone.10 Ceteris paribus, as groups grow in size, the benefits of action

become smaller for individual members, decreasing the incentives for unilateral or

collective action.11 Applied to the global public good nature of a stable climate, rational,

self-interested countries will have an incentive to free-ride on the mitigation policies of

9 As argued by Pezzey (1992) and others, unilateral carbon taxes are largely ineffective, even if coordinated among the OECD, given the relatively small and decreasing share of emissions originating from these countries. 10 Though from a different ontological position, Hoffmann (2005) makes a similar point, arguing that universality enhances the chances of political stalemate due the multiplicity of actors and interests at the negotiating table. 11 In his later work, Olson (1971) points out that the resulting under-supply of collective goods is particularly a problem at the international level. Astutely anticipating the outcome of the recent “Copenhagen Accord,” where states decided to change tracks on multilateral negotiation of mitigation targets, opting instead for a bottom up approach where countries unilaterally set targets and “opt in” to the regime, Olson points out that international cooperation largely occurs through “independent contributions,” or a two-stage process where countries agree in principle to cooperate for some purpose, and then determine the extent of cooperation individually (Olson, 1971: 868).

Page 20: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

8

others, and have absolutely no incentive to take unilateral action in the absence of a

coordinated global response.12

In this sense, responding to climate change can be likened to a prisoner’s dilemma,

forcing governments into a trade-off between collective and individualistic strategies

(Midttun and Hagen, 1997). To the extent that an increase in carbon energy taxation will

place domestic industry at a competitive disadvantage, unilateral action will penalize first

movers, and reward non-cooperation. Thus, even where public support for climate action

is high, governments are constrained by what they can unilaterally implement

domestically by this dilemma. On the other hand, dissimilarities at the international level

– in terms of abatement costs, support for environmental initiatives and ecological

vulnerabilities – will make unanimous multilateral agreements extremely difficult to

achieve (Midttun and Hagen, 1997). From this perspective, the effect of reducing local

emissions in the absence of collective action is to impose the environmental externalities

generated in other countries on one’s own population, and to impose political costs on

domestic political actors who are unlikely to accept them (Pardy, 2007). In these lights,

the question of why energy tax reform is so difficult is turned on its head. Why would

any country unilaterally raise taxes on fossil fuels in the first place?

In addition to the problem of collective action at the international level, governments also

face a series of domestic constraints. Responding to the threat of climate change is

politically complex because the causes (and effects) of climate change (policy) are

inextricably tied to modern lifestyles (consumption habits) and to the functioning of the

modern industrial economy. Given the link between fossil fuel consumption and

economic development, policy-makers have had a century-long interest in promoting the

discovery and use of fossil fuels, with a favourable mix of large subsidies and

disproportionately low taxes. By making fossil fuels cheaper and allowing individuals

12 The requirement of global coordinated action has served as the primary factor used by governments in Canada and the U.S. to legitimate a very slow policy response, and weak emission reduction commitments, to address climate change. For instance, while the U.S. is unwilling to commit to emissions reductions unless China does, Canada has said in the absence of U.S. action, Canadian mitigation efforts are futile (Prentice, 2009).

Page 21: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

9

and firms to emit millions of tonnes of CO2 into the atmosphere without cost,

governments have effectively subsidized the use of carbon-based fuels and encouraged

their over-consumption (Rivers and Sawyer, 2008).13 As a consequence, these policies

have generated path-dependent dynamics like those described by Pierson (2000), creating

vested interests (constituencies) and economic incentives that militate against path-

departing processes and policy shifts like raising taxes on carbon.14 Thus, existing

government policy will be constrained by domestic interests that profit from the

consumption of fossil fuel energy, and other domestic interests that have become

dependent on relatively cheap forms of heavily polluting fuels.

Domestic energy producers and users, for instance, have an interest in keeping energy

taxes low, in order to control costs and maintain their share in international and domestic

markets. Indeed, the need to protect the competitiveness of domestic industry is one of

the most frequently cited economic barriers to unilateral implementation of higher taxes

on fossil fuels.15 In addition, some argue that unilateral carbon constraints can distort

competition in global markets, leading to “carbon leakage”16 and the proliferation of

emissions from pollution havens. According to this line of reasoning, there is no point in

unilaterally implementing climate policy in a single country, or a group of countries, if

such policy leads to the relocation of CO2 emissions to non-complying regions of the

world (Hoel, 1996). Finally, since carbon regulation policy necessarily imposes

concentrated costs on a small group of energy intensive and fossil fuel producing sectors,

these groups have greater incentive (and capacity) to mobilize against carbon tax

13 For instance, Boyd et al. (1995) find that given estimated damage costs, the price of fossil fuels are much lower than optimal. 14 Though external shocks may disrupt the “equilibrium,” and radically alter the course of policy development, policies create powerful economic and political constraints (in the form of constituencies and transaction costs) that complicate reform. According to this logic, such “feedback effects” from existing policies favour the enactment of path-dependent or path-consistent changes that seldom depart from existing institutional logics. This line of reasoning raises the theoretical question of under what conditions path-departing changes (like large increases in energy taxes) might occur? 15 See for instance: Baranzini et al. 2000: 401; Demailly and Quirion, 2005; Ekins and Barker, 2001:348-351; Ekins and Speck, 1999: 386; OECD, 2001: 71; OECD, 2006; Reinaud, 2008; Zhang and Baranzini, 2004: 512. 16 Carbon leakage refers to the potential for firms to relocate production to “pollution havens” in response to asymmetric carbon constraints and cost structures across countries.

Page 22: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

10

increases, as compared to the broader (inter-temporally distributed) interests that would

share the benefit from a more stable climate (Svendsen et al. 2001).

Governments are further constrained by widespread public opposition to taxes, which is

in fact common across the OECD. Taxes impose visible costs on voters (Barthold, 1994)

who consistently express an aversion toward taxes (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998). To the

extent that governments are primarily interested in maximizing electoral gains (Mayhew,

1974), increasing tax rates on fossil fuels is from this perspective politically difficult. For

this reason governments might be expected to eschew tax increases and avoid the

“politics of pain” (Pal and Weaver, 2003).

In sum, several factors at the domestic and international levels combine to constrain the

ability of governments to raise taxes on fossil fuels, and might lead to the expectation of a

convergence toward low rates of carbon energy taxation, particularly among advanced

industrial economies that have historically benefited from the exploitation of fossil fuels.

Concerns over international competitiveness further militate against abnormally high

taxes on common industry inputs, and incentives to free-ride suggest no country should

unilaterally raise the price of carbon-based fuels in the hopes of decreasing its own

emissions. Domestically, powerful industry groups and tax-weary voters are likely to

make increases in fossil fuel taxation politically difficult, especially if we assume self-

interested politicians are primarily interested in maintaining political power. Thus, from

economic (cost) environmental (emissions) and political (votes) perspectives,

governments are constrained in their ability to unilaterally raise taxes on fossil fuels, and

we should expect to see more convergence than divergence in tax rates applied to carbon

(especially among similarly situated – i.e. advanced industrial – countries in the OECD).

Indeed, for all these reasons, we should expect to see consistently low tax rates on

commonly used fossil fuels across the OECD.

Page 23: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

11

1.2. Puzzle: cross-national differences in fossil fuel taxation

In light of the substantial domestic and international incentives to do nothing about

climate change and to keep energy prices low, and if a public choice view of

governments solely motivated by electoral incentives is assumed, one might expect to see

no real increase in taxes on fossil fuels in response to climate change or the energy

security issue. Given the general public’s aversion to taxes (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998:

167), and the “pathological hatred” for taxes on motor fuels in particular (Hsu et al.

2008), one might expect to see no real differences in the taxation of commonly used fuels

across countries, and attempts to raise them should be politically very difficult.

Nonetheless, some countries have unilaterally imposed broad-based carbon taxes, raising

the total effective tax rate applied to various fossil fuels (See Chapters 3 & 4). Moreover,

effective tax rates on the same, commonly used fossil fuels vary enormously, even among

similarly situated countries in the OECD (Chapter 4).17

What factors explain the very large cross-national differences in tax rates applied to the

same fossil fuels? What drives (or enables) certain countries to implement higher energy

taxes? Conversely, what are the political barriers and constraints that prevent energy tax

reform? Are net energy-importing countries more likely to have higher tax rates on

particular fossil fuels, as the national security discourse suggests? Do domestic fossil

fuel energy producers constitute a barrier to higher taxes on particular carbon-based

fuels? Precisely how and why countries differ in the tax rates they impose on carbon-

based fuels is the empirical focus of this dissertation.

17 These non-trivial differences are further explored in subsequent chapters.

Page 24: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

12

1.3. Topic, research questions and purpose

In the context of common pressures (to do something about climate change or hedge

against rising fossil fuel scarcity) and common constraints (in terms of incentives to

maintain the status quo and free-ride), this dissertation explores the political determinants

of large cross-national differences in tax rates applied to carbon-based fuels, the

combustion of which is the single largest source of aggregate GHG emissions, and the

reliance on which is increasingly seen as a strategic weakness for importing states.

Applying a comparative analysis framework to exploit cross-national differences in tax

rates on fossil fuels, the goal is to answer the two following questions:

1. How are fossil fuels taxed in the OECD? 2. Why are the same fossil fuels taxed at widely different rates, even among

similarly situated countries in the global political economy?

Moving beyond the existing literature, which is often limited by small n country

comparisons or a focus on just one (usually gasoline) fossil fuel, I examine the role of

electoral systems in shaping the incentives and ability of political parties to implement

increases in rates of carbon energy taxation. This answer helps to shed some light onto

the broader issue of why – despite overwhelming advocacy from high-ranking

economists – energy tax reform appears so difficult, or conversely, why – given

international and domestic incentives to keep taxes low and free-ride on the Earth’s

climate – countries unilaterally impose higher tax rates on fossil fuels in the first place.

To be sure, the empirical core of the analysis employs mostly quantitative techniques,

allowing for an identification of trends in the data. The purpose is thus to search for

general patterns – common obstacles and conditions – that might facilitate the imposition

of taxes on fossil fuels. With a larger number of cases, the analysis is able to gain

leverage on numerous independent variables than has so far been attempted in the carbon

tax literature. But this analytical breadth does come at the cost of decreased depth, and

careful attention to detail, context and complexity. While much of the detailed analytical

case study work has already been completed in the literature, the findings of this project

Page 25: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

13

contribute by bringing some theoretical parsimony to the comparative study of carbon

taxes, and by suggesting new cases deserving of closer study.

In the context of common challenges, like the revived discussion on energy security, and

the new discourse around climate change, this dissertation speaks to one of the classic

questions in comparative and international political economy. Indeed, like the work of

Gourevitch (1986), Katzenstein (1978) and Weiss (2003), I seek to explain why, in the

presence of common external policy challenges, individual countries respond in different

ways. The objective is to obtain a better sense of the general patterns in tax rates that

systematically emerge across a large number of countries, and to develop probabilistic

generalizations rather than a comprehensive account of the historically contingent and

context specific factors that converge in any one particular case.18 The ultimate purpose

of this research is to garner a better understanding of the political determinants – of the

general forces that shape and constrain taxes on fossil fuels – which can provide insight

into the “big questions” – under what conditions can we expect to successfully overcome

barriers to raising taxes on fossil fuels, and what kind of politics is required in order to

change the tax structure so that it is more consistent with economic efficiency and

compatible with efforts to reduce GHG emissions?

1.4. Scope

This project is concerned with the political economy of carbon taxation.19 It seeks to

explain differential rates in carbon energy taxes across countries, not the particular tax

mix (which is actually used as an independent variable). The focus is not on the politics

18 Being one of the first systemtic, comprehensive accounts of implicit carbon energy taxation, I leave the detailed tracing of causal mechanisms for future work. 19 In terms of scope, the analysis is restricted to a focus on energy taxes affecting the price of carbon-based fuels. Although other types of policies, like subsidies, affect the price of carbon, due to time constraints, and for reasons of data availability, energy subsidies for fossil fuels are left out of the present analysis. Apart from time, the primary reason for this decision is based on the fact that, at present, systematically collected, cross-national data on fossil fuel energy subsidies that is comparable across countries is currently unavailable. Indeed, governments are especially reluctant to disclose information on subsidies to the fossil fuel industry, like tax exemptions, though recently some advances have been made in collecting this type of information (Earth Track; IEA, 2010; OECD, 2010; World Bank et al. 2010). Given the size of fossil fuel subsidies and their importance for energy and fossil fuel prices, future work in this area is highly desirable and can compliment the present research.

Page 26: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

14

of instrument choice, although this topic is briefly considered in a discussion of carbon

taxes and carbon trading in Chapter 2 and raised in the Conclusion. Rather, the primary

concern is with the politics and economics underlying one type of market-based

instrument (MBI) that is most often used by all governments – consumption taxes. To the

extent that taxes on energy consumption have important implications for other areas of

public policy – e.g. social and economic policy – a study of carbon energy taxation can

link and speak to debates surrounding globalization (Hays, 2003; Swank, 2006), the

politics of redistribution (Garrett and Mitchell, 2001; Iversen and Soskice, 2006), and the

financing of the welfare state (Kato, 2003). In terms of environmental and climate policy,

energy taxes are relatively understudied in the literature, even though they have important

economic and environmental effects (Giddens, 2009).20 For these reasons, the dissertation

focuses primarily on the tax approach to pricing carbon.

According to experts, taxation of carbon energy is the simplest and most efficient way of

reducing emissions and fossil fuel dependence, and is the most frequently advocated

policy instrument advocated by economists (Mankiw, 2007; Nordhaus, 2007),

climatologists / environmentalists (Hansen, 2008; Brown, 2003), International

Organizations (EC, 1991; IMF, 2008; OECD, 1997; World Bank, 2010) and even some

members of the business community (Hyndman, 2009; Clark, 2009), who otherwise

make strange bedfellows. Yet for the reasons mentioned above, it is also the most

politically difficult instrument to implement, as evidenced in both the relative

infrequency with which governments adopt carbon taxes, and in the significant

exemptions granted, if successfully implemented at all. From a political science

standpoint, the tax approach to pricing carbon thus raises fascinating questions regarding

20 It can be argued that tax rates on fossil fuels provide a reasonably good proxy for overall environmental policy in countries (c.f. Broz and Maliniak, 2007; Fredriksson and Millimet, 2007; Ward and Cao, 2010), especially when compared to other problematic indexes of environmental sustainability used in the literature (e.g. Cao and Prakash, 2010; Whitford and Wong, 2009). Even in cases where countries engage in emissions trading (e.g. EU-ETS), energy taxation provide a useful indicator of the price of carbon across different sectors of an economy. For instance, the EU ETS imposes a carbon price on a portion of the economy covering several thousand (i.e. about 10,000) installations in the energy and industrial sectors, while taxes on fossil fuels apply to all energy users. Second, the EU ETS is relatively new (implemented in 2005). This time point barely overlaps with the longer coverage provided by the study of energy taxes, which span a much longer time period.

Page 27: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

15

the politics of imposing direct costs on social actors by raising effective rates of carbon

energy taxation.

Unlike most other political science research on carbon taxes, and for reasons that will

become clear in Chapter 4, I examine all energy taxes affecting the price of fossil fuels,

not just those explicitly labeled “carbon taxes.” Indeed, carbon taxes currently

implemented in OECD jurisdictions are not pure Pigouvian taxes, and upon closer

scrutiny, lose their distinctiveness vis a vis more commonly found energy taxes. The

latter have similar economic and environmental effects in terms of raising the relative

price of carbon based fuels, and can thus be analyzed as a de facto carbon tax. In

addition, examining all taxes on fossil fuels provides a more comprehensive, valid

measure of the “effective” tax rate on carbon, allowing for a quantitative analysis of a

much larger number of countries, since all countries tax fossil fuels (to varying degrees).

The analysis of carbon energy tax data is divided into two main parts. In the descriptive

component (Chapter 4), I analyze tax rates on six fossil fuels in all countries for which

data are available from the IEA, which includes the 29 OECD member states.21 The

subsequent empirical analysis of the determinants of cross-national differences in these

tax rates (Chapter 5) is limited to four of the most commonly consumed fossil fuels by

industry (coal and heavy fuel oil) and households (diesel and gasoline) across a smaller

sub-set of these countries. The four fossil fuels were selected based on their uniform use

across all countries in the sample.22 The decision to restrict the empirical analysis to the

traditional 21 advanced industrial economies most frequently analyzed in the

comparative/international political economy literatures (Swank, 2006; Winner, 2005) is

done for reasons of data availability (for key independent variables), and in the interest of

comparing countries sharing a similar history involving a number of similar economic

21 The 29 OECD countries are: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, the Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg, Mexico, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, the Slovak Republic, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States. 22 All of the advanced industrial democracies use coal, heavy fuel oil, diesel and gasoline to varying extents. Light fuel oil and natural gas are more popular in some cases than others, posing some problems for comparison across all industrialized countries. A study of the four most common fossil fuels across industry and household sectors was also more feasible given the amount of analysis invested.

Page 28: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

16

transformations occurring since the late 1970s. Moreover, a focus on the advanced

capitalist democracies holds potential income effects constant, while avoiding the

problem of comparing vastly different countries whose particular economic

circumstances can confound an analysis of the determinants of energy tax policy. A

further justification of the case selection is found in Chapter 5.

Finally, the analysis is temporally bounded between 1978-2006, a period for which most

of the data are available. The year 1978 provides a good starting point insofar as it

corresponds to the end of the second oil shock of the 1970s. The period 1978-2006 also

covers a number of temporally defined developments – e.g. economic recessions,

globalization, Rio Conference, Kyoto – that are potentially important in a study of tax

policy. In addition, the time period under study ends just as the EU-ETS emission trading

system began operations in 2005. Analyzing tax rates over this time period thus avoids

the complicated question of how energy tax structures interact with carbon trading

policies like the EU cap and trade regime.

1.5. Literature review

The politics of carbon energy taxation are covered by an enormous literature spanning a

broad range of academic disciplines. Rather than review all of this work, the following

section identifies two primary literatures of particular relevance to the present research

project – the comparative politics of carbon taxation (1.5.1), and the role of political

institutions (1.5.2). Insights from these literatures are used to inform the theoretical

framework (1.6) argument (1.7) and primary research hypotheses (1.8), presented below.

Page 29: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

17

1.5.1. The comparative politics of carbon taxation – what do we know? Much of what we know about carbon taxes comes from the work of economists. Central

to this research is the question of optimal tax design for reducing emissions at least

aggregate social cost (e.g. Hoel, 1996; Oates, 1995; Parry, 1995; Sandmo, 1975; 1976) or

for balancing the tradeoff between economic efficiency and political feasibility

(Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004; Felder and Schleiniger, 2002). To this end, the economic

literature has primarily examined the likely effects of carbon taxes on, for instance:

aggregate emissions (Botteon and Carraro, 1993; Bruvoll and Larsen, 2004; Cournede

and Gallon, 2003; Enveldsen, 2005; Mathiesen and Mæstad, 2004; Speck et al. 2003);

industrial competitiveness (Demailly and Quirion, 2005; Jenkins et al. 2002; Mæstad,

2003); social incidence (Johnson et al. 1990; Zhang and Baranzini, 2004; Wier et al.

2005; Creedy and Sleeman, 2006); technological diffusion (Jaffe and Stavins, 1995;

Gerlagh and Lise, 2005; Vollebergh, 2007); and, overall economic cost (Andersen and

Ekins, 2009; Carraro and Siniscalco, 1993; Weyant and Hill, 1999; Barker and Ekins,

2004; Wissema and Dellink, 2007). Much of this work is primarily descriptive in nature,

describing carbon energy tax policy and commenting on environmental and economic

effects (Vehmas, 2005; Vehmas et al. 1999). Reflecting a preoccupation with economic

efficiency, and a normative commitment to prescribing policy that is consistent with this

ideal, this literature has also heavily debated the “Porter Hypothesis” (Porter, 1998;

Porter and Van Der Linde, 1995) as well as the potential for a “double dividend” (Pearce,

1991; Goulder, 1995; Bovenberg and de Mooij, 2001), which concerns the extent to

which carbon-energy taxes can lead to an improvement in social welfare in addition to

environmental benefits, by shifting the tax burden from income to environmental

externalities.

Rather than treat the effects of taxes as the main outcome to be explained, other work

models the primary causes of carbon energy taxes, in terms of both their design and

implementation. This literature spans both economics and political science and can be

sub-divided in three main traditions.

Page 30: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

18

The first broad tradition is inspired by theories of public choice (Buchanan and Tullock,

1962; Downs, 1957; Olson, 1965) and the political economy of interest group politics

(Becker, 1983). This literature is primarily concerned with a seminal question asked by

Robert Hahn (1989) regarding how the patient followed the doctor’s orders. Writing at

the end of the 1980s, Hahn noted that despite the many books and articles written by

economists on the relative merits of incentive-based policy instruments, few governments

had actually used them, and even where implemented, their design significantly departed

“…from the role which economists have perceived for them” (Hahn, 1989: 96).

Sometimes called “execution deficits” (Schneider and Volkert, 1999) or “tax departures”

(Vehmas, 2005), this gap between economic prescriptions and political implementation

has turned Hahn’s original inquiry on its head, spawning an entire body of work asking,

“why did the patient not follow the doctor’s orders” (Kirchgassner and Schneider, 2003).

To answer this question, a typical public choice analysis first identifies four main actors

in the environmental policy field – voters, politicians, bureaucrats and industry groups –

and proceeds to examine their interests in the application of different policy instruments,

which is then taken as an explanation for a particular policy outcome.

This is the approach of a seminal paper by Buchanan and Tullock (1975) who provide a

formal model to show why command and control instruments are preferred to market

based instruments by business groups and bureaucrats. In a similar tradition, Svendsen et

al. (2001) employ Olson’s (1965) logic of collective action to explain differences in tax

rates applied to large and weakly organized consumer interests compared to the smaller

and more concentrated interests of industry groups. Their theoretical predictions are then

applied to the experience with carbon taxes in Scandinavian countries, with an emphasis

on Norway. Taking a slightly different tack, Pearce (2006) builds on Becker (1983) to

show that differences between public and private social welfare functions explains why

the UK government opted not to implement a true carbon tax, implementing instead the

Climate Change Levy as economically less efficient but politically more popular in its

design. Though much of the evidence is anecdotally drawn from a relatively narrow

sample of cases, this literature helps to specify the nature and role of government,

bureaucratic, voter and industry interests in the field of environmental policy. In so doing,

Page 31: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

19

it also provides theoretically informed accounts of why energy tax reform is so difficult,

and why, given the political interests involved, carbon-energy taxes may be designed and

implemented inefficiently.

Like the public choice literature, political scientists have also tackled the question of why

carbon-energy taxes are never implemented true to the Pigouvian ideal, and the role of

industry interests play a key role in their analyses. Unlike the public choice literature,

however, political scientists pay much more attention to the role of institutions, political

parties and ideas. But while the political science research is relatively more empirically

focused, and is more causal/descriptive rather than prescriptive in its aims, it too tends to

focus on a relatively small number of carbon tax countries in its comparative analysis.

For instance, one of the first studies on the comparative politics of carbon taxes by

political scientists seeks to explain the first mover phenomenon, asking why (and how)

the Nordic governments in Sweden, Denmark, Norway and Finland unilaterally

implemented carbon taxes, in the absence of an international agreement to partition the

burden (Midttun and Hagen, 1997). Building on Rokkan (1966) Midttun and Hagen argue

that electoral incentives (particularly rising environmental concern and political parties

with a green profile) are responsible for pushing the Nordic governments to take an avant

garde position on environmental issues,23 while corporatist channels allowed industry to

substantially modify the design of carbon tax proposals. Together, both factors explain

how the Nordic countries were first to implement environmental policies while not

sacrificing their economies. In a similar vein, Kasa examines the gap between “ambitious

proclamations and less heroic practices” in terms of the numerous exemptions granted to

mainland carbon-intensive industry in Norway (2000). Preferring the analytical lens of

policy-networks to the relatively broader notion of corporatism, Kasa provides a more

detailed descriptive account of the privileged access to decision-makers these networks

provided, allowing mainland industry to block a proposed broadening of the Norwegian

carbon tax on three separate occasions (Kasa, 2000).

23 Midttun and Hagen (1997) refer specifically to the party platforms of Socialist, Social Democratic and Labor parties in Finland, Sweden, Norway and Denmark (290-291).

Page 32: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

20

Building on the network approach, Daugbjerg and Pedersen (2004) expand on Kasa and

apply the main theoretical argument to a comparative analysis of pesticide and CO2

taxation in Denmark, Norway and Sweden. This more comparative research design

attempts to explain variation within first movers – i.e. in the particular tax designs among

three carbon tax countries – thus considerably improving on the work of Kasa by

introducing variance in the dependent variable. Interestingly, the study highlights the role

of social democratic parties in proposing the new green taxes in all cases examined. And

while the detailed analysis of pre-existing policy networks in all three case studies is

compelling, unlike the work of Midttun and Hagen, Daugbjerg and Pedersen fail to

provide adequate analysis of the electoral incentives and environmental concern that

converged to place the taxation issue on the agenda in the first place.

This latter issue is taken up in Kathryn Harrison’s (2010) recent piece on the comparative

politics of carbon taxes, which compares instances where countries have implemented

carbon tax proposals (Finland and Denmark) with two cases in which such proposals

have failed (Canada and Germany). In contrast to the work of Scandinavian political

scientists, Harrison applies a broader theoretical framework to the issue, eschewing a

corporatist/network approach and instead examining the role of good policy motives,

electoral incentives and political institutions across the four cases. Employing this

framework, Harrison specifically documents a key role for green and leftist political

parties as enthusiastic entrepreneurs whose environmental platforms, which received

increasing electoral support, helped to “green” traditional parties and push environmental

taxation onto the political agenda (Harrison, 2010; Hatch, 1995). Even in Germany,

where the Greens opposed an explicit carbon tax because it would encourage nuclear

energy, the Green party was instrumental in pushing a broader based tax reform to

increase the cost of all energy, including fossil fuels (11-12). Thus, in addition to the role

of corporatism in pulling toward a particular policy design (Midttun and Haggen, 1997;

Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004), Harrison identifies a role for electorally-driven political

parties in the initial “push” for carbon/energy taxation. Harrison’s analysis also points to

proportional representation as a facilitating factor in the implementation of carbon taxes,

Page 33: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

21

highlighting its role in promoting the emergence of small environmentally focused parties

onto the political scene.

While making important contributions in their own right, both economic and political

science scholarship in the area of carbon taxation are inherently limited because of their

small n. For instance, the public choice literature has contributed much in terms of

specifying the micro incentives of particular groups for mobilizing in opposition to

increases in rates of carbon taxation, providing an explanation for the gap between carbon

tax theory and practice found in the OECD (Chapter 3). However, insights from this

theoretical modeling is rarely tested across a large number of countries in the public

choice literature, and often ignores the institutional setting in which interests are formed

and with which interests must work to have an influence on tax policy outcomes.

Nevertheless, these insights into the political role of interests can be readily formulated as

testable hypotheses guiding cross-national empirical work.

Similarly, the qualitative work undertaken by political scientists provides another source

of explanatory hypotheses to be tested in broader cross-national comparative research. To

be sure, the great contribution of scholarship in this tradition has been to specify the

contextual factors that converge to explain how and why particular governments in small

open economies – e.g. the Nordic countries – were able to reconcile domestic pressure for

environmental regulations while also protecting domestic industry exposed to

international competition. What remains to be seen, however, is whether the same

insights are applicable across a broader number of countries to explain differences in

rates of taxation applied to fossil fuels, as is proposed here. As highlighted by Kasa’s

(2005) recent review of the existing literature, comparative carbon tax scholarship could

benefit from more attention to differences in the economic structure and growth of

countries, as well as external economic pressures such as those resulting from trade

(Kasa, 2005: 92). The existing political science research can thus benefit from models

and methods that are better suited for adjudicating among numerous explanatory

variables measured at the domestic and international level, and further specifying the

Page 34: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

22

particular role of political parties, institutions, and electoral incentives across a broader

number of countries.

To this end, recent quantitative work on green taxation has made some important

advances. For instance, a recent paper by Ward and Cao (2010) seeks to explain cross-

national differences in the “green tax burden,” which they operationalize as revenues

from green taxes as a percentage of per capita gross domestic product. Employing spatial

econometric tools to a panel data set, Ward and Cao find that the energy producer lobby

(energy production / GDP) is associated with significantly lower green tax burdens, and

to their surprise, find that higher income tax burdens are positively associated with

significantly higher green tax revenues. Most of their models also find a significant

relationship between the presence of green parties in the legislature and higher green tax

burdens, and separate trade measures (dyadic trade and aggregate flows) produce

significant results consistent with the expected directions. In a separate paper, Ciocirlan

and Yandle (2003) similarly examine revenues from green taxes. Like Ward and Cao,

Ciocirlan and Yandle find evidence of trade effects, with green tax revenues inversely

related to trade openness. Though consistent with expectations, it should be noted that the

dependent variable in both studies, revenues from green taxes, provide only an indirect

proxy for tax level, and so these results should be interpreted with caution. Drawing

specifically on the public choice literature, Ciocirlan and Yandle test a number of

independent variables not included by Cao and Ward, including the number of

exemptions granted to industry and a country’s level of carbon emissions. Reporting

results for just one model, Ciocirlan and Yandle (2003: 213) find some support for their

claim that green taxes “…are not set with a specific concern for the environment; their

purpose is largely to generate revenue.”

In contrast to a focus on tax revenues, other work has specifically examined tax rates. For

instance, a recent PhD dissertation from the Claremont Graduate University examines the

Political Economy of Energy Taxation in the OECD, 1973-1995 and is similar to the

present project in its breadth, method and scope (Morozova, 2005). A limitation in this

work, however, is that Morozova’s statistical analysis deals exclusively with tax rates

Page 35: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

23

imposed on the manufacturing sector, leaving analysis of consumer taxes on fossil fuels

open for further research. This being the case, Morozova’s dissertation provides

interesting insight into the question of comparative environmental taxation. Her primary

hypothesis concerning corporatism, for which she finds only limited empirical support, is

included in the analysis of tax rates on industry fuels in the empirical analysis (Chapter

5).

Also focusing on tax rates, this time on consumers, Hammar et al. (2004) examine

gasoline taxes across a sample of 21 OECD countries over the period 1978-2000, and

generate some interesting (if problematic) results. For instance, one of their main

findings is that gasoline consumption per capita has a substantial and statistically

significant, negative effect on gasoline tax (Hammar et al. 2004:10).24 This finding

seems obvious, and also raises a key problem of causality; are low fuel taxes the result of

higher levels of consumption (and thus increased pressure against higher taxes), or vice

versa? In addition to this endogeniety, Hammar et al. (self-admittedly) fail to incorporate

the potentially crucial role of organized business interests in their model, while the

potential mediating role of different political institutions is not even discussed. This

shortcoming is partially addressed in a recent paper on the political determinants of

environmental taxation. Using gasoline price and tax data from the IEA, Broz and

Maliniak (2009) find that malaportioned electoral systems – i.e. electoral systems where

some “geographical units have shares of legislative seats that are not equal to their share

of population” (9-10) are significantly associated with lower gasoline prices. To the

extent that rural voters are more dependent on gasoline, this argument is plausible.

However, the malapportionment logic seems considerably less well suited to explain

variation in taxation on such other fossil fuels as coal and heavy fuel oil, which are more

often used by industry in urban districts, for instance.

In sum, while the quantitative literature has helped bring some theoretical parsimony to

the question of environmental taxation, it appears as though the empirical range of this

24 Other independent variables examined in Hammar and Sterner’s model include vehicles per capita, income level, pre-tax of gasoline, taxation as a share of GDP, and governmental debt.

Page 36: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

24

literature has so far remained limited. Indeed, no single study has attempted to cover tax

rates on both industry and households. The primary culprit, it would appear, is a lack in

the availability of good data. For instance, some research relies on revenue data (Cao and

Ward, 2010; Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003), which is problematic, since revenues are tied

to consumption, or that which environmental taxation is intended to deter.25 Thus, if the

objective is to explain cross-national differences in levels or the stringency of green

taxation, tax rates appear to be a more valid measure.

Where tax rates have been used, studies remain relatively focused on either industry fuel

taxes (Morozova, 2005), gasoline prices (Broz and Maliniak, 2009), or are otherwise

handcuffed by methodological issues (Hammar et al. 2004). A more satisfactory analysis

would test the efficacy of a coherent political argument against other plausible causes of

differential rates of environmental taxation, across numerous fossil fuels, not just

gasoline, and over time. The existing quantitative literature does not provide a theory that

might plausibly be applied to different fuels for this purpose. As it happens, a burgeoning

literature on the policy consequences of electoral systems exists, and seems well suited to

this task.

1.5.2. The role of political institutions

Inspired by the work of comparative political scientists (e.g. Cameron, 1978; Crepaz,

1998), a recent and growing tide of theoretical research in economics has addressed the

question of cross-national variation in the size of government and government spending

across countries. The basic argument is that electoral rules systematically shape economic

policy, government expenditures and the size of the welfare state (Persson and Tabellini,

2008). Employing Downsian logic, these studies argue that majoritarian (as opposed to

25 As pointed out by Barde and Braathen (2007: 58), tax revenues should not be taken as an indicator of the effectiveness or stringency of environmental tax policy. Revenues from green taxes will be strongly associated with levels of consumption. This is problematic because the green tax component of total tax revenue will rise and fall with levels of consumption, irrespective of what happens to policy. As such, if the goal is to mesure policy, actual tax levels should be preferred.

Page 37: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

25

proportional) electoral systems produce greater competition among parties in key

marginal districts, leading to more targeted policy and fewer public goods (Persson and

Tabellini, 1999). In contrast, parties competing in proportional systems are more likely to

target benefits for the broader population, since a percentage of legislative seats are

determined by the national vote. Though largely focused on developing formal theory

and the specification of micro political incentives, this literature has also begun to

empirically tests model predictions. In particular, numerous studies have found that,

consistent with expectations, majoritarian elections lead to smaller governments, smaller

transfer payments, and smaller welfare states (Milesi-Ferretti et al. 2002; Persson and

Tabellini, 1999; 2002; 2004).26

To be sure, political scientists do not ignore such institutional effects, though they also

pay close attention to the politics of coalitions that electoral systems produce. For

instance, emphasizing the importance of government partisanship in explaining cross-

national differences in redistribution (e.g. Blais et al. 1993; 1996), Iverson and Soskice

(2006) argue that electoral systems affect coalition behaviour, leading to differences in

the partisan composition of governments, and hence redistribution. In a similar vein,

Manow (2009) has argued that majoritarian electoral systems (and associated party

systems) have lead to a “residual-liberal” welfare state, while the interaction of

proportional electoral rules, and the ideological makeup of coalitions, explain the

development of Nordic (red-green) and continental (red-black) welfare states,

respectively. Tackling a somewhat different question, Martin and Swank (2008) trace the

origins of corporatist and pluralist employers’ associations, once again, to the electoral

system and the party systems they foster. Finally, Rogowski and Kayser (2002) find that

national-level prices are strongly influenced by the type of electoral system in use, which

tilt the balance in favour of either consumer (lower prices) or producer (higher prices)

interests.

26 The logic underpinning these findings is firmly based on the micro incentives of actors, and is discussed at greater length in the Argument section of this dissertation (1.7).

Page 38: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

26

At present, this emerging literature on the political and economic effects of electoral

systems has rarely addressed tax policy. In one exception, Steinmo and Tolbert (1998)

examine the impact of dominant party government on shaping cross-national differences

in tax burdens across industrialized democracies. Citing the importance of striking long-

term compromise on taxing and spending in dominant coalitions, and the incentives for

governments to “behave” (i.e. not raise taxes) in majoritarian systems, Steinmo and

Tolbert argue that electoral rules impact tax burdens through the production of three

dominant governing outcomes. Majoritarian elections typically produce majoritarian

governments vulnerable to small changes in vote shares, and thus produce an incentive to

keep taxes low. In contrast, Proportional systems can lead to higher or lower taxes,

depending on whether dominant or shifting coalitions are the norm. Where party

coalitions are relatively stable, long-term compromises on taxing and spending are

common (resulting in higher taxes), while shorter time horizons in shifting-coalition

polities tends to keep taxes low (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998). While making an important

contribution to the study of tax policy, the institutional logic of Steinmo and Tolbert is

devoid of political agency, which presumably matters for (environmental) tax policy

outcomes.

Emphasizing a different causal logic, a more recent study by Fredriksson and Millimet

(2004) explicitly models the effects of electoral institutions on policy. Following Persson

and Tabellini (1999), Fredriksson and Millimet point out that a party vying for power in a

majoritarian system requires only 25 % of the popular vote to win a majority (50% of the

vote in 50% of the districts), whereas in proportional systems, a party requires at least

50% of the national vote. From this, they argue that parties in majoritarian systems will

have an incentive to develop local policies targeted toward key marginal districts, while

parties in proportional systems will have an incentive to target broader, national welfare

goals. Testing their hypotheses against a series of environmental policy indicators,

Fredriksson and Millimet find broad support for their argument, suggesting electoral

systems may have an influence over environmental policies with diffuse benefits, too.

Page 39: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

27

In light of the robust findings across the electoral institutions literature, the argument

developed (1.7) and tested (Chapter 5) in this dissertation draws heavily on this political

institutional framework. I thus attempt to combine insights from the literature on the role

of electoral institutions with those emerging from the literature on the comparative

politics of environmental taxation. The general theoretical framework (1.6) and argument

(1.7) are further discussed and elaborated in the next sections. To be sure, the present

study fills an important gap in the literature just summarized, by testing the efficacy of

electoral systems to explain cross-national differences in rates of fossil energy taxation,

across a broad number of the advanced industrial economies in the OECD.

1.6. Theoretical framework and assumptions

Drawing on what we already know about the comparative politics of environmental

taxes, and the role of political institutions, the general theoretical approach adopted here

suggests that levels of carbon-energy taxation are determined by the primary type of

electoral system used to translate vote shares into seat shares, the electoral preferences of

voters, the ideological stripe of the parties in power, the revenue needs of government,

the size of industry opposition, and the exposure of the domestic political economy to

international trade. As discussed in the review of the literature above, broadly similar

approaches are shared by several studies in the recent literature on comparative

environmental policy, though none explicitly lays out their framework in precisely this

way. Moreover, existing studies often fail to include one or more of the variables

commonly found to be important in the literature taken as a whole.

Following the now common taxonomy in comparative and international political

economy scholarship (Hall, 1997; Harrison and Sundstrom, 2010), I group these

explanatory factors into three broad categories – interests, ideas and institutions – and

comment on each before presenting my theoretical assumptions, argument, and primary

working hypotheses, to be tested in Chapter 5.

Page 40: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

28

Interests

Of all politically salient interests, the role of organized business is often found to play a

key role in explaining public policy outcomes (Layzer, 2007; Quinn and Shapiro, 1991).

Yet contra Marxian notions of a monolithic capitalist class, recent research has shown

that business is not a single interest (Hart, 2004). Rather, important fissures exist within

the business community (Falkner, 2009), and different industrial sectors possess both

different policy preferences and varying incentives to mobilize in an attempt to influence

a given policy outcome. In the area of fossil fuel energy taxation, the relevant interests to

consider include fossil fuel energy producers, energy intensive industry (e.g. in

manufacturing), trade-exposed sectors of the economy, and producers of renewable

energy. Of these primary interests,27 the trade exposed and fossil fuel energy producers

are likely to be the most motivated opponents of fossil fuel energy taxation.

The fossil fuel industry has an inherent interest in keeping the price for its products low,

so as to ensure continued demand for fossil fuels and the profitability of its operations. If

government were to increase the cost of fossil fuels by raising taxes on carbon, producers

of fossil fuels stand to bear the highest and most concentrated burden, since the market

for their product is directly threatened. These concentrated interests thus have the largest

incentive to mobilize against an increase in fossil fuel taxation, and possess a wealth of

resources (e.g. money) to mount well-organized and well-financed campaigns in

opposition to an increase in taxes on fossil fuels (Carpenter, 2001; Layzer, 2007). In

addition, producers of fossil fuels also possess a certain amount of structural power, in

the sense that governments of fossil fuel rich countries are often dependent on this

industry as a major source for wealth creation, jobs, and government revenue (Carter,

2010). The relative size of the fossil fuel industry is thus an important variable to

27 I make a distinction here between “primary” and “secondary” interests. By primary interests, I refer to the interests of those firms whose profitability is directly affected by an increase in tax rates on energy products. In contrast, secondary interests refer to the interest of other firms in the supply chain, which rely on energy producers and energy-intensive industry as consumers and suppliers of their products and services. For simplicity, I consider only primary interests here. It is also reasonable to expect that primary interests are the most politically salient, in that these interests have greater incentives to mobilize, since they are most directly affected.

Page 41: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

29

examine when considering an interest-based explanation for differences in tax rates on

fossil fuels.

Like producers of fossil fuels, large consumers of energy also have an interest in keeping

tax rates on fossil fuels low, though their motivation for doing so is somewhat (if mildly)

less pronounced. Indeed, firms in energy-intensive industry have an interest in

controlling input costs (Svendsen et al. 2001: 392), but they do not necessarily have an

inherent interest in keeping the price of fossil fuels low. All else being equal,28 energy

intensive firms should not have a preference for energy derived from fossil fuels, if they

can obtain the same level of energy from renewable sources, at a similar price. Unlike

producers of fossil fuels, raising taxes on carbon-based energy does not directly threaten

the products and services produced by firms in the energy intensive industry, and

estimates of pollution control typically range between 2-3% of total operation costs,

producing much weaker incentives to mobilize against taxes on carbon (Goodstein, 1999;

Macdonald, 2007; Olewiler, 1994). In addition, some manufacturers producing energy

efficient products, and those interested in maintaining a “green” public image, have an

interest in reaping legitimacy gains from publicly supporting (or at least not opposing)

policies that reduce energy consumption and associated levels of pollution (Layzer,

2007). For these reasons, energy-intensive industry is less likely than the fossil fuel

sector to mobilize against an increase in tax rates on fossil fuels. There are also

important methodological reasons for not including energy-intensive industry in the

empirical analysis.29

In the long term, energy-intensive firms have less of an interest to oppose fossil fuel

taxation, or any other policy designed to decrease greenhouse gas emissions. In the short

term, however, energy-intensive firms in trade-exposed sectors of the economy possess

greater incentives to expend resources and mobilize against an increase in tax rates on

28 Including the cost of capital stock turnover. 29 A commonly used proxy for the relative size of energy intensive industry is total energy consumption per unit of GDP. Including this kind of variable in the model, however, introduces a problem of endogeniety, since tax rates on fossil fuels are just as likely to influence levels of energy consumption/unit of GDP as vice versa.

Page 42: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

30

fossil fuels. As is often argued by firms in trade-exposed sectors of the economy, any

unilateral increase in energy taxation directly affects their cost of doing business,

potentially weakening their international competitiveness (Ekins and Speck, 1999).

Although sometimes questioned in the theoretical and empirical literatures (e.g. Andersen

and Ekins, 2009; Bovenberg and Goulder, 2002a; Jaffe et al. 1995; Jenkins et al. 2002

Porter and van der Linde, 1995), this oft-cited claim resonates with government decision-

makers and the electorate, who are both sympathetic toward any argument invoking the

fear of job losses and self-imposed economic hardship. Indeed, the fear over a tax’s

impact on international competitiveness is the most frequently cited argument against the

unilateral imposition of a carbon tax (OECD, 2001; 2006). Other research has also found

evidence of tax competition, or a “race to the bottom” in open economies (Bretschger and

Hettich, 2002; Genschel, 2002; Winner, 2005).30 As a result, it is important to include the

extent to which a country’s economy is exposed to international competition.

A final group of interests to consider relates to those of the renewable energy sector.

Though relatively new and small in number, producers of renewable energy and

renewable energy technology constitute a constituency of growing importance in several

OECD countries. Their inherent interest in creating a “level playing field” for their

products and services is diametrically opposed to producers of fossil fuels, who currently

benefit from years of investment in a carbon-based infrastructure, low tax rates for their

goods and government subsidies. Most firms in this industry want to see effective action

on climate change, especially those that raise the price of fossil fuel energy. Capturing

the relative size of the renewable energy sector can help to ascertain the political

importance of this emerging industrial sector, as well as to control for the fact that

countries differ in the level of domestically available alternatives to fossil fuel energy.

However, fossil energy taxes are sometimes used to encourage the development of the

green energy sector, and a measure of this variable would thus be endogenous to fossil

energy tax rates. As a result, it is not included in empirical tests in Chapter 5.

30 Interestingly, the effects of trade openness are mixed, with other studies citing larger governments (e.g. Cameron, 1978).

Page 43: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

31

Ideas

In addition to producer group interests, the analytical framework proposed here also

suggests that social values – and in particular, environmentalism – should be associated

with higher rates of carbon energy taxation. More environmentally conscious publics will

prefer such policies and demand stricter environmental regulations. This might also make

it easier for governments to impose taxes on their public, when the taxes can be sold as

environmental, and the public is already highly sensitive to environmental issues. On the

supply side, it is reasonable to expect that the ideological orientation of government will

impact the types of policies implemented. For instance, green parties have been known to

pursue stricter environmental policy.

The problem with the environmentalism argument is that it is difficult to measure ideas,

particularly environmental ones. Lacking sufficiently comparable cross-national public

opinion data covering the time period of interest here (i.e. 1978-2006), one approach is to

use green party seat and vote shares as proxies for the level of “environmentalism” in a

country. To be sure, there are some issues with such indicators. First, environmentalism

cannot always be reduced to green party votes, since some countries don’t have green

parties, yet do have a history of environmentalism (e.g. the U.K., see Rootes, 2003).

Moreover, a decline in the vote for greens may not necessarily be attributable to a decline

in an interest for environmental protection. For instance, Papadakis (1989; 1986) has

argued that the electoral setback of the German Greens in 1990 was at least partially due

to the ability of established parties to co-opt the green agenda.31 In these respects, relying

on electoral data provides an imperfect measure of environmentalism across countries. At

the same time, however, green seat and vote shares are often the indicator of choice in

cross-national, large n comparative research, and are generally accepted as the best of

available measures for this purpose (e.g. Neumayer, 2003). In the empirical analysis to

follow in Chapter 5, I use the share of green party votes as an indicator of public demand

for environmental regulation.

31 Dalton (1994) has noted that traditional (social democratic) left-wing parties often adopt environmental policy preferences in an attempt to court new social movements.

Page 44: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

32

In addition to using electoral data to measure the electorate’s preferences, other studies

have been interested in examining the extent to which party ideology can affect policy.

Beginning with Downs’ (1957), scholars have debated whether parties in general, and

party ideology in particular, matters for policy outcomes (e.g. Blais et al. 1993; 1996).

More recently, several studies have found interesting relationships between the

ideological makeup of government and tax and fiscal policy (e.g. Cusack, 1999; Hart,

2010). As hypothesized by Jahn (1998) and Neumayer (2003) in their cross-national

studies of environmental performance, green and left parties should most likely be

associated with significantly better environmental outcomes, if partisanship matters at all.

It is thus plausible to expect an increase in the electoral and political strength of green

parties (at the polls, in the legislature and in government) to have an effect on rates of

carbon energy taxation. I thus include societal demand-side (i.e. green votes) and political

supply-side (i.e. green seats and cabinet posts) factors in the analytical framework

proposed here, and test for their effects in the empirical analysis of Chapter 5.

Institutions

As noted earlier, it is frequently suggested that certain types of political institutions – like

the electoral system – have implications for public policy. In particular, scholars draw a

key distinction between majoritarian and proportional systems, which shape party

preferences and mediate the relationship between governments and voters. In

majoritarian systems, a party can win an election with just 25 per cent of the popular vote

(50 per cent of the vote in 50 per cent of districts), encouraging politicians to target key

marginal districts that may be decisive in an election (Fredriksson and Millimet, 2004;

Persson and Tabellini, 2008).32 Due to this property, majoritarian elections usually lead to

a disproportionate allocation of seats given a particular distribution of votes, and a small

change in vote can thus have relatively large political consequences. Combined with the

related tendency for majoritarian systems to lead to large majority governments, parties 32 By majoritarian system, I refer to the simple plurality, first-past-the post of counting votes to determine which candidate wins an election, usually in a single-member-district (SMD). I refer to majoritarian, plurality and SMD systems interchangeably.

Page 45: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

33

are more vulnerable under such systems, and thus have an incentive to “please” voters by

appealing to local interests, especially in key districts (Persson and Tabellini, 2008). In

contrast, proportional systems involve various ways of allocating seats in proportion to

the percentage of the popular vote. Though not all proportional systems lead to perfectly

proportional outcomes (hence the importance of measuring disproportionality), they tend

to allocate legislative seats in proportion to the national vote (Gallagher, 1991). As a

result, it is often argued that parties in proportional systems are more likely to adopt

policy preferences targeted to broader, national social welfare goals, like environmental

health and quality, in order to maximize electoral gains (Fredriksson and Millimet, 2004).

For these reasons, I test for the role of electoral systems, and specifically, the effect of

disproportionality, on rates of carbon energy taxation.

In sum, the analytical framework comprises an analysis of the interests, ideas and

institutions that can affect rates of carbon energy taxation across countries. While not

ignoring the role of economic constraints, I argue that the political ideology of parties

interacts with the degree of proportionality in electoral systems as a driver of

environmental and energy tax policy outcomes (1.7). In constructing this argument, I

make a few key assumptions.

First, I assume that the fossil fuel and trade exposed industry, voters and political parties

are the primary units of analysis, and that they are rational actors pursuing their interests.

I assume industry’s preference in the fossil fuel-producing sector and trade-exposed

sectors of the economy are for lower taxes on fossil fuels. I also assume voters in rural or

less densely populated areas will prefer lower taxes, since they presumably have to drive

further distances and are more likely to operate heavy machinery, and are thus more

dependent on fossil fuels. Following other studies in the literature, I assume votes for

green parties indicate support for environmental policy, and that individuals who vote for

green parties are more likely to support environmental taxation. I further assume that

green and left parties support higher taxation of energy products, in accordance with the

findings of other studies (e.g. Damania, 1999; Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004; Harrison,

2010). Following Schumpeter (1950), I assume electoral competition is the essence of

Page 46: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

34

representative democracy, and this implies that political parties compete for the support

of heterogeneous voters with a suite of policies. While not denying that parties

(especially small issue-oriented ones) carry out ideological programs, they are ultimately

driven and constrained by their primary interest in obtaining political power. It follows

that the primary objective of governments, and power-seeking politicians in political

parties, in addition to implementing their ideological program (where they have one) is in

re-election. Finally, I assume that in general, the probability of receiving electoral support

is negatively affected by the imposition of new taxes on fossil fuels, except in the case of

green voters.

1.7. Theoretical argument

In what follows I develop the argument that proportional electoral systems facilitate the

imposition of energy taxes, and in particular, lead to higher rates of implicit carbon

taxation in advanced capitalist democracies. I argue further that electoral systems matter

to the extent that they interact with voter preferences and party politics. This argument is

tested along with elements of the theoretical framework discussed above, in Chapter 5.

This empirical analysis treats the party system and choice of electoral system

exogenously.33

First, I argue that green political parties, and parties of the left, generally support higher

rates of fossil fuel taxation. This argument is not directly tested here, but accords with

previous research. Damania (1999) notes that Green parties in Europe, Australia, New

Zealand and elsewhere support environmental taxes. This observation is further

supported in the recent work of Harrison (2010), which discusses the role of green parties

and their preferences for higher rates of energy taxation. Daugbjerg and Pedersen (2004)

also note that in all cases where carbon taxes were implemented, social democratic (i.e.

33 Though they are related, one could write an entire dissertation on the choice of electoral system or the development of the party system. See for instance: Pilon’s dissertation (York University). Other studies on electoral system choice include Bawn, 1993; Boix, 1999; and Cusack et al. 2007).

Page 47: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

35

traditional left-parties) were in the coalition.34 Traditional left-wing parties may be

expected to support higher rates of environmental taxation in order to court new social

movements to their party (Dalton, 1994; Kitschelt, 1993) and finance a progressive

welfare state (Kato, 2003).

Second, I argue that PR systems are good for parties of the left and greens. To be sure,

the effect of electoral systems and issue dimensions on the “effective” number of political

parties is now well-established (Duverger, 1954; Taagepera and Grofman, 1985). More

recently, Iversen and Soskice (2006) show that proportional electoral rules lead

systematically to a greater number of left governments. In Table 1.1, I show that

proportional electoral systems also lead to systematically greater representation of Greens

in parliament.

Table 1.1: Electoral system and the number of years with at least one green party member in the elected legislature (1978-2006) Green party representation

No greens

Greens

Proportion of years with greens in parliament

Electoral system

Proportional

237

186

0.44

Majoritarian

190

25

0.12

Source: Data from Armingeon et al. (2009)

As is clear from Table 1.1, electoral systems are not politically neutral. They influence

the ideological makeup of the legislature and government, and determine which groups in

society are more likely to see their interests represented in the legislature and in

government policy. For instance, green party representation in the legislature is over three

34 Future work should empirically test this claim using data from the Comparative Manifesto Project.

Page 48: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

36

times more likely in PR (Table 1.1). Similarly, in separate tests now shown, it was found

that green/new-left parties are twice more likely to participate in government under PR

systems (compared to majoritarian systems). Moreover, electoral systems also determine

how well voters can hold governments and politicians accountable for their actions. In so

doing, electoral systems may be expected to shape policy outcomes by (i) creating the

ideological space within which political parties are more/less able to implement their

policy programmes; and, (ii) generating incentives that shape the policy preferences of

vote-maximizing political parties.

Ideological space

Proportional electoral systems create the ideological space for green parties, and those of

the traditional left (i.e. social democratic parties) to increase rates of carbon energy

taxation. By definition, proportional systems produce more proportional outcomes

between a party’s share of legislative seats and its share of the votes. This tends to

increase the number of “effective” parties (Rae, 1967; Taagepera and Shugart, 1989;

Lijphart, 1990). As the effective number of parties increases, so does the ideological

range of parties, and the issues claimed to be their own. To the extent that such systems

favour smaller, issue-oriented parties, it can be expected that environmental issues will

increase in political importance.

Moreover, it has also been found that proportional systems are more likely to produce

multi-party coalition government (Taagepera and Shugart, 1989; Strom, 1990), increasing

the chances of smaller parties forming government. Responsibility over government

cabinet portfolios can be expected to increase the influence of smaller green parties, as

well as their intra-coalition negotiation power. Coalition government also makes it harder

for voters to know who to blame for unfavourable policy (e.g. tax increases), as lost votes

for poor governing performance are shared among coalition partners (Persson and

Tabellini, 2008; Powell, 2000), thus decreasing the political costs of tax increases. In

contrast, the lines of accountability in majoritarian systems are clearer, since they tend to

produce majority governments. This will encourage “good behaviour” among

Page 49: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

37

governments fearful of the electoral consequences of increasing taxes (Persson and

Tabellini, 2008). For this reason, green/left parties will be constrained in their ability to

increase taxes under majoritarian (disproportional) systems where majority governments

are the norm.

Electoral incentives

Electoral systems are not neutral, and create incentives for political parties, regardless of

ideological stripe, to do certain things and avoid others. For instance, proportional

electoral systems encourage politicians to seek a broader national constituency with their

policy, since parties compete for national seats, and the minimal coalition of voters

required to win an election is 50 per cent plus one. Parties thus have an incentive to give

greater importance to nation-wide, public goods issues, and consider the welfare of the

entire population, in order to maximize votes and associated seats. As Persson and

Tabellini (2008) note, “proportional representation diffuses electoral competition, giving

the parties strong incentives to seek electoral support from broad coalitions in the

population through general public goods” like environmental policy (Fredriksson and

Millimet, 2004). In contrast, majoritarian systems typically focus electoral competition in

pivotal districts, producing an incentive for parties to target local interests at the expense

of broader welfare goals (Persson and Tabellini, 2008; Fredriksson and Millimet, 2004).

Moreover, compared to systems of proportional representation, majoritarian systems can

translate small changes in voter sentiment into larger changes in legislative seats

Sometimes referred to in the literature as the “seat-vote elasticity” (Rogowski and

Kayser, 2002) or “seat-vote proportionality” (Powell, 2000), such disproportionality

produced by the electoral system leverages the effect of votes and “strengthens the

incentives of politicians to please voters” (Persson and Tabellini, 2008). Combined with

the fact that disproportional electoral systems typically produce majority governments

where the lines of policy accountability are clear, a high seat-vote elasticity will constrain

the ability of government, no matter which political stripe, to increase taxes on carbon

based energy. This is because governments in such disproportional systems will be more

Page 50: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

38

vulnerable to voters. By the same logic, given the incentives to seek votes, changing

voter preferences under highly disproportional systems will encourage parties to adjust

policy preferences in order to win new votes. Thus, while green seats and green

government will be constrained in their ability to increase taxes under disproportional

systems, green votes are expected to have exactly the opposite effect as the degree of

disproportionality increases.

Summary of hypotheses

These arguments can be distilled in four primary working hypotheses, which will be

tested in Chapter 5.

H1: The PR hypothesis: Relative to majoritarian electoral systems, countries with PR will impose higher implicit tax rates on carbon. H2: The ideological space hypothesis: Relative to majoritarian electoral systems, greater representation from parties of the left and greens will be positively associated with significantly greater implicit carbon tax rates under PR. H3: The disproportional constraints hypothesis: Relative to proportional systems, greater representation from parties of the left and greens will not be positively associated with greater implicit carbon tax rates under more disproportional systems, as these parties will be constrained in their ability to raise tax rates, regardless of their ideological program or policy preferences. H4: The electoral incentives hypothesis: Relative to more proportional systems, increasing support for green parties will lead to an increase in rates of implicit carbon taxation under more disproportional systems, as parties/governments have greater incentive to respond to mounting electoral threats where the seat-vote elasticity is high.

Page 51: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

39

1.8. Chapter summary

The general outline of this dissertation is as follows. Chapter 2 examines the economic theory of carbon-energy taxation and answers the question: why tax carbon? Chapter 3 examines the empirical record of carbon-energy taxation and demonstrates key political shortcomings when economic ideas are put into political practice. It also offers an initial analysis of why this gap exists, applying insights from the theoretical argument about electoral systems to the case of the British Columbia carbon tax. Chapter 4 expands the analysis to consider other forms of carbon-energy taxation and develops the argument that these “implicit” carbon taxes warrant closer empirical study. Chapter 5 develops an empirical analysis to assess the political determinants of cross-national variation in rates of taxation for coal, heavy fuel oil, diesel and gasoline. The analysis finds broad support for hypotheses H1 to H4, as the interaction between parties and electoral systems consistently emerges as a robust predictor of carbon energy taxation. Chapter 6 concludes.

Page 52: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

40

Chapter 2: Carbon taxes in theory

2. The economics of pricing carbon Economic models have long demonstrated that market-based approaches to pollution

abatement are generally more cost-effective than are subsidies, voluntary programs, and

regulation (Baumol and Oates, 1985). More recently, countless government and NGO

studies from the climate policy community now espouse the relative merits of putting a

price on carbon (NRTEE, 2007; Metcalf, 2007; CBO, 2008; Demerse and Bramley, 2008;

Mintz and Olewiler, 2008; Rivers and Sawyer, 2008). Apart from “getting the prices

right,” market-based approaches strike at the core of the climate change issue and energy

security issues; namely, they target the need to “decarbonize” the economy and de-couple

economic growth from the use of scarce fossil fuels like crude oil.

By adjusting prices so that they better reflect the environmental and social costs of fossil

fuel use, policy-makers can help re-shape deeply entrenched patterns of production and

consumption by making emissions-intensive goods and practices relatively more

expensive, while making environmentally superior choices relatively less costly. In

addition, there is now a broad-based, cross-cutting consensus among economists,

environmentalists, and members of the business community that a carbon tax is, in

theory, the most efficient and in many circumstances the most effective policy instrument

to price carbon, and by association, reduce the use of fossil fuels and man-made

emissions of greenhouse gasses (GHG).

For these reasons member countries in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and

Development (OECD) have generally come to accept the need to “put a price” on carbon

(OECD, 2001; 2006; 2009).35 At the same time, pricing carbon has proven to be a

35 As discussed in Chapter 3, carbon taxes have been implemented in several jurisdictions across the OECD, and carbon markets have been established or are in the process of being established in Europe, parts of North America, and the South Pacific (e.g. Australia, Japan).

Page 53: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

41

politically difficult sell, engendering debate over appropriate policy instruments and their

design.

The following chapter sets out the theory of carbon pricing and answers the question,

“why tax carbon”? The first section of this chapter discusses the economic concept of

externality (2.1), and demonstrates how the burning of fossil fuels imposes substantial

environmental and social costs in the form of climate change (2.1.1) and the costs

associated with continued dependence on increasingly scarce fossil fuels (2.1.2). Next,

the chapter outlines two options for internalizing such costs (2.2), which involve putting a

price on carbon – either directly, through an emissions tax (2.2.1), or indirectly, through

an emissions cap and permit trading system (2.2.2). After comparing the two pricing

options (2.2.3) and key design issues that affect the nature and effectiveness of a carbon

tax (2.3) the chapter concludes with a discussion of the political economy of instrument

choice (2.4).

2.1. External economies It is somewhat ironic that economists, often criticized for some of the social ills afflicting

society, have long developed answers to the related problems of public goods and social

cost. Following Marshall’s (1890) pioneering work on external economies, Pigou (1920

[1932]) developed the concept of externality as a divergence between private and social

cost. According to Pigou, economic activity can generate both positive and negative

externalities, that is, costs and benefits external to an economic transaction that affect the

welfare of third parties in negative or, in positive ways.36 Such costs and benefits are

external insofar as: (i) they are borne not by participants in an economic transaction but

by third parties; and (ii) they are not reflected in price signals and thus fail to be

considered by economic agents as they make private production and consumption

decisions in the market. To the extent that external costs and benefits are not reflected in

price signals, the market mechanism will not lead to a Pareto Optimal competitive

equilibrium. Private agents may engage in too much (or too little) of an activity,

36 A positive externality involves a private transaction resulting in net benefits, while a negative externality imposes net costs, on third parties.

Page 54: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

42

ultimately leading to a mis-allocation of resources and market failure. For instance, by

not having to pay for the pollution/costs caused by an industrial activity (a negative

externality), a firm responding to distorted market signals will have an incentive to

produce more than the socially optimal amount of their product, thus reducing the

availability of public goods like clean air, water or un-congested highways.37

The classic example of a negative, production-based38 externality is the case of a smoke-

emitting factory whose economic production fails to account for the smoke emitted into

the atmosphere (Coase, 1960). In the absence of appropriate price signals, a firm will

over-exploit the social capital stock of clean air (without cost), which may negatively

affect (i) the production possibilities of firms in other industries relying on clean water

and air (e.g. fishing), or (ii) the public health of nearby communities. In either case, a

negative externality is created. Since air pollution may harm other firms or individuals in

society, and since this cost imposed onto third parties is unaccounted for in the price or

production function of the factory, a negative externality results.

When prices fail to reflect the “true” social and environmental costs of an activity or

good, markets are distorted, leading to perverse incentives to produce more (or less) than

the socially optimal amount of a good, which leads to an inefficient allocation of

resources. Economists refer to such a mis-allocation of resources as a market failure in so

far as resources are used inefficiently and outcomes are sub-optimal (Sandmo, 2005: 34).

Under such conditions, economists have advocated “full cost pricing,” which may

involve government intervention (e.g. pollution taxes), to force polluters to internalize

37 In the case of a positive externality, the opposite may be true. For instance, since the benefit to society of an educated population is not considered in the economic transaction between a paid teacher and his or her pupil, education tends to be under-supplied relative to the social optimal output, which might call for a corrective subsidy to bring the private benefits and costs of education in line with the social benefits and costs of an educated population. Since the central problem of the present research is assessing policy responses to the economic and social costs of climate change, the focus is on negative externalities here. 38 In addition to there being positive and negative externalities, requiring different kinds of policy response, externalities can either be production or consumption based. An example of a consumption-based externality is the number of cars on the road. Car travel brings private utility but also decreases the quality of air and roads, and increases pollution and traffic congestion. Since individuals that drive fail to consider the costs imposed onto others by their driving, by for instance creating traffic or pollution, driving can impose a negative, consumption-based external cost not considered when individuals opt to drive instead of taking public transit (Sandmo, 2005).

Page 55: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

43

social costs. It follows that, in the absence of corrective taxes, “an economy with

externalities is not efficient, since the externality itself creates a distortion” (Salanié,

2003, emphasis added).

2.1.1. Fossil fuel externalities: Climate change Despite attempts by special interests to confuse the debate (Hoggan and Littlemore, 2009;

Michaels and Monforton, 2005), and the uncertainties inherent in scientific inquiry

(Cooke, 1991), the science of climate change is now well established. To be sure, all

science is based in probabilities, and some areas of climate science are better understood

than others. That average global temperatures are increasing, for instance, is now

established as scientific fact (IPCC, 2007b, NRC, 2010). Moreover, notwithstanding

some of the recent controversy over a series of leaked emails from the University of East

Anglia, over 97 per cent of actively publishing climate scientists agree with the main

conclusion of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC); namely, that

human activity is responsible for observed increases in mean global temperatures

(Anderegg et al. 2010). As a result, thousands of the world’s leading climate scientists

are calling for massive and immediate reductions to greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions in

order to avert tipping points (Lenton et al. 2008) and the potentially catastrophic

consequences of climate change (IPCC, 2007b; Hansen et al. 2008; Meinshausen et al.

2009). Although the consequences of climate change are difficult to model (given that the

climate system is complex and adaptive), its effects pose significant risks to human lives,

as evidenced in what has already been observed that is attributable climate change.

To be sure each successive report of the IPCC – a collaboration of climate scientists from

around the world working on the physical basis of climate change – has established with

increasing levels of certainty that the Earth is warming, and the US National Academy of

Sciences agrees (NRC, 2010). For instance, Working Group 1 of the Fourth Assessment

Report of the IPCC concluded that, “[w]arming of the climate system is unequivocal, as

is now evident from observations of increases in global average air, and ocean

temperatures, widespread melting of snow and ice and rising global average sea level”

(IPCC, 2007b: 5, emphasis added). This conclusion is based on the latest measurements

Page 56: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

published by the IPCC, which clearly depict the global warming phenomenon in three

main areas (Figure 2.1.1.1).

Figure 2.1.1.1: Changes in temperature, sea level and Northern snow cover

Source: Figure SPM.1. (IPCC, 2007b) As depicted in Figure 2.1.1.1, global average temperatures have been rising since the

beginning of the industrial revolution, and three independent lines of eviden

the IPCC’s scientific claim of a warming climate: (a) rising global average temperatures

in the sea and air; (b) widespread melting of snow and ice; and, (c) the concomitant rise

published by the IPCC, which clearly depict the global warming phenomenon in three

es in temperature, sea level and Northern snow cover

Source: Figure SPM.1. (IPCC, 2007b)

As depicted in Figure 2.1.1.1, global average temperatures have been rising since the

beginning of the industrial revolution, and three independent lines of eviden

the IPCC’s scientific claim of a warming climate: (a) rising global average temperatures

in the sea and air; (b) widespread melting of snow and ice; and, (c) the concomitant rise

44

published by the IPCC, which clearly depict the global warming phenomenon in three

As depicted in Figure 2.1.1.1, global average temperatures have been rising since the

beginning of the industrial revolution, and three independent lines of evidence support

the IPCC’s scientific claim of a warming climate: (a) rising global average temperatures

in the sea and air; (b) widespread melting of snow and ice; and, (c) the concomitant rise

Page 57: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

45

in global average sea level. In fact, the IPCC has found that since 1850, eleven of the last

twelve years between 1995 and 2006 are among the 12 warmest years on record. It is

estimated (and commonly agreed amongst accredited climate scientists) that the total

temperature increase between the pre-industrial and present era is approximately 0.76

[0.57 – 0.95] degrees C (the difference between current mean global temperatures and

that of the last ice age is roughly 5 degrees C, which is why some call for an urgent

reduction of emissions to limit warming to 20).39 In addition, scientists fear a “snow ball”

effect whereby even small temperature differences can cause small events (e.g. loss of

permafrost and release of methane) that lead to much larger changes and exponential

warming (Lenton et al. 2008). To be sure, the rate at which the planet is warming is

unprecedented, and is nearly double the rate over the last 50 years relative to the last 100

(IPCC, 2007: 5). Observed declines in mountain glaciers, hemispheric snow cover, and a

concomitant rise in global average sea level (about 3.1 mm per year between 1993 –

2003, up from 1.8 mm per year during the period 1961 – 2003) is also consistent with

global warming science and now threatens the livelihood of the nearly 40% of world

population that live within 100 km of the coast.

To be sure, scientists who study climate change have a good understanding of the

mechanics and underlying cause. For close to two hundred years, scientists have

understood the “greenhouse effect” – i.e. the process by which carbon dioxide and other

gases form an insulating blanket around the Earth’s atmosphere. As their name suggests,

these “greenhouse gasses” trap some of the heat generated by solar radiation, which

would otherwise be reflected back towards space (Drake, 2000; Harvey, 2000; Houghton,

2004). This concept was first identified by French mathematician and physicist Joseph

Fourier in 1824, and further developed by Swedish scientist and chemist Svante

Arrhenius at the turn of the century. Arrhenius estimated that a doubling of atmospheric

concentrations of CO2 released from the combustion of fossil fuels would result in a

warming of approximately 2.1 degrees Celsius (when water vapor feedback was taken

39 See Jaeger and Jaeger (2010).

Page 58: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

46

into account), which is very close to the most recent “climate sensitivity”40 estimates of

approximately 1.5 – 4.5 degrees Celsius (Harvey, 2000; Hoggan and Littlemore, 2009;

IPCC, 2007b).

Since this early work, scientists have continually refined and built confidence in the idea

of anthropocentric (i.e. human-induced) climate change. In fact, consistent with this

early work, the most recent and authoritative IPCC publication concludes:

Most of the observed increase in globally averaged temperatures since the mid- 20th century is very likely due to the observed increase in anthropogenic greenhouse gas concentrations. This is an advance since the [Third Assessment Report’s] conclusion that “most of the observed warming over the last 50 years is likely to have been due to the increase in greenhouse gas concentrations.” Discernable human influences now extend to other aspects of climate, including ocean warming, continental-average temperatures, temperature extremes and wind patterns (IPCC, 2007b: 10).

Successive IPCC reports have thus built confidence in the likelihood that humans are

primarily responsible for the observed changes in climate. Indeed, the IPCC has

increased its level of confidence in anthropocentric causes of warming from likely

(carrying a > 66% probability) to very likely (>90% probability), and have concluded that

it is very likely that the observed warming is not due to known natural causes alone

(IPCC, 2007b: 10). According to the IPCC, key among the human drivers of climate

change are global atmospheric concentrations of greenhouse gases, which have rapidly

increased as a result of industrialization and economic growth. In particular, carbon

dioxide has been singled out as the key greenhouse gas with the highest radiative forcing,

i.e. the gas most responsible for trapping heat inside the Earth’s atmosphere and thus

altering the balance between inward and outward solar radiant energy flows (Figure

2.1.1.2).41

40 Equilibrium climate sensitivity is commonly understood as being an estimate of equilibrium global average warming for a doubling of CO2. 41 The IPCC (2007b) defines radiative forcing as “a measure of the influence that a factor has in altering the balance of incoming and outgoing energy in the Earth-atmosphere system and is an index of the importance of the factor as a potential climate change mechanism. Positive forcing tends to warm the surface while negative forcing tends to cool it.” See the IPCC glossary for further details.

Page 59: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

47

Figure 2.1.1.2: Radiative forcing components

Source: Figure SPM.2 (IPCC, 2007b)

Figure 2.1.1.2 illustrates radiative forcing values for 2005 relative to pre-industrial

conditions and is expressed in watts per square metre (W m2). As can be seen, carbon

dioxide is the leading GHG with the relatively largest, positive radiative forcing impact,

meaning it has a warming effect on the Earth’s climate. Moreover, as indicated by the

right hand column, the level of scientific understanding (LOSU) for this mechanism is

high. From this perspective, it is not surprising that scientists have found a direct, positive

correlation between emissions of CO2 – the most important greenhouse gas – and

changes in global average temperature (Matthew et al. 2009). Others have found an

equally striking relationship between atmospheric concentrations of carbon dioxide and

temperature changes, as depicted in Figure 2.1.1.3.

Page 60: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

48

Figure 2.1.1.3: Temperature and CO2 concentration in the atmosphere

Source: Petit et al. (1999)42

As can be seen in Figure 2.1.1.3, temperature changes over the past 400,000 years are

tightly correlated with CO2 concentrations. Although the data in the Figure end at 1950,

this relationship appears robust over time. More recently, patterns of industrialization and

economic growth since 1950 have fueled an exponential increase in the concentration of

CO2 and other GHG, raising concern over the impact of such emissions for the global

climate (Figure 2.1.1.4).

42 http://www.earthingfaith.org/2010/01/25/is-climate-change-natural-3/

Page 61: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Figure 2.1.1.4: Atmospheric concentration of carbon dioxide

Source: Reay and Pidwirny 200643

Figure 2.1.1.4 plots the rise in CO

time using data from the Mauna Loa Observatory in Hawaii and ice core data for earlier

years. As can be seen, the atmospheric concentration of CO

industrial revolution, and has increased exponentially in the post World War II period,

reaching 379 ppm in 2005. The primary culprit contributing to this rise is the b

fossil fuels, upon which modern industrial countries and the global economy depends

(Figures 2.1.1.5 and 2.1.1.6).

43 http://www.eoearth.org/article/carbon_dioxide

mospheric concentration of carbon dioxide

Figure 2.1.1.4 plots the rise in CO2 concentrations (measured in parts per million) over

time using data from the Mauna Loa Observatory in Hawaii and ice core data for earlier

ars. As can be seen, the atmospheric concentration of CO2 has risen steadily since the

industrial revolution, and has increased exponentially in the post World War II period,

reaching 379 ppm in 2005. The primary culprit contributing to this rise is the b

fossil fuels, upon which modern industrial countries and the global economy depends

arth.org/article/carbon_dioxide

49

concentrations (measured in parts per million) over

time using data from the Mauna Loa Observatory in Hawaii and ice core data for earlier

has risen steadily since the

industrial revolution, and has increased exponentially in the post World War II period,

reaching 379 ppm in 2005. The primary culprit contributing to this rise is the burning of

fossil fuels, upon which modern industrial countries and the global economy depends

Page 62: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Figure 2.1.1.5: Global anthropogenic GHG emissions

Source: SPM.3. IPCC (2007b)

Figure 2.1.1.6: Global GHG emissions by source

Source: Emission Database for Global Atmospheric Research (2009)

44 http://energy.antp.co.kr/epbrd/bbs/board.php?bo_table=bbs5&wr_id=48&page=10

Figure 2.1.1.5: Global anthropogenic GHG emissions

Figure 2.1.1.6: Global GHG emissions by source

Source: Emission Database for Global Atmospheric Research (2009)44

http://energy.antp.co.kr/epbrd/bbs/board.php?bo_table=bbs5&wr_id=48&page=10

50

Page 63: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

51

Figures 2.1.1.5 and 2.1.1.6 illustrate the role of fossil fuels as the primary source of GHG

emissions and concomitantly, a key cause of climate change. As can be seen, since the

1970s yearly GHG emissions have grown steadily, topping 45 pico grams of CO2

equivalent in 2005 (i.e. over 45 billion metric tonnes of CO2 in a single year).45 The

majority of this increase (approximately 60 per cent) is attributable to fossil fuel

combustion (Figure 2.1.1.6). In particular, emissions of carbon dioxide – the primary

greenhouse gas identified in Figure 2.1.1.2 – have grown by approximately 80 per cent

between 1970 and 2004 (Figure 2.1.1.5). Therefore, it is not just GHG, but anthropogenic

(i.e. man-made) emissions that are causing climate change.

According to the available science, the emissions patterns just described pose significant

threats to the physical and biological systems that help sustain life on earth. For instance,

as a result of a changed climate, scientists fear increasing negative effects in the areas of

fresh water availability, bio-diversity loss, increased intensity and frequency of violent

storms, increased flooding and drought, declining agriculture yields (in large regions of

the world), and concomitant problems for human health, nutrition and disease (IPCC,

2007: 10). In addition, increased concentrations of carbon dioxide, a key driver of

climate change, have led to the world’s oceans becoming more acidic, which is expected

to negatively impact marine shell-forming organisms like corals, upon which much ocean

life depends (IPCC, 2007: 9). Many of these risks are discussed in Stern’s (2006)

economic review of the risks and costs associated with climate change, summarized in

Table 2.1.1.1.

45 In order to compare different greenhouse gas emissions from individual sources and gases, it is common to convert emissions to CO2 equivalents.

Page 64: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

52

Table 2.1.1.1: Highlights of possible climate impacts discussed by Stern

Source: Stern (2006: 57)

The basic message in Stern’s review of the potential impacts of climate change – and

associated human and social costs – is that climate change is a serious issue that will also

impose serious economic costs. While such costs to the environment and human health

are very difficult to measure in quantitative terms (c.f. Ekins and Barker, 2001: 329),

Stern (2006) uses an integrated assessment model (PAGE2002) to estimate the damage

costs of climate change, which the Review finds could range between 5 and 20% of

global GDP if no action is taken to stabilize emissions between 450 and 550 ppm.

Page 65: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

53

Applied to the issue of climate change, it becomes apparent that current patterns of

energy production and consumption constitute a large, negative externality of the kind

discussed in section 2.1. In fact, current patterns of energy production and consumption

impose external environmental and social costs in the form of an unstable climate and the

concomitant risks associated with rising global average temperature. The risks of a

warming climate, such as increased droughts, flooding, violent storms, and their

associated impacts on living organisms, can be interpreted as costs borne not by

individual emitters of GHG but as collective costs borne by society and the environment.

The potentially devastating costs of such risks, and their known anthropogenic causes,

have prompted Stern (2006) to call climate change the single largest market failure the

world has ever known.46 According to this view, government policies and price supports

have systematically distorted energy markets, making the price of fossil fuels artificially

low, encouraging the burning of fossil fuels at the expense of other, cleaner forms of

energy, ultimately leading to a mis-allocation of resources. Though difficult to quantify,

especially when considering the future value of a stable climate, the risks posed by

climate change are likely to impose substantial economic costs in the future (c.f. Stern,

2006).

In economic terms, these costs are externalities in the sense discussed in section 2.1, but

with important qualifications (Stern, 2006: 310). First, the nature of climate change

makes it an inherently global problem. Unlike other environmental externalities like acid

rain, climate change is not a transboundary issue. A tonne of CO2 emitted into the

atmosphere in one part of the world will have the same environmental impact as a tonne

of CO2 emitted in another. Second, the environmental harm done by the emission of

GHG involves a pure public good – the earth’s climate. Together, the global

characteristic of the climate change externality, combined with its public good nature,

produce incentives for countries to free-ride on the GHG abatement policies of other

46 In addition to bringing the climate change externality onto the political agenda, the Stern report is also famous for turning the climate change policy debate on its head. Rather than discuss the cost of climate change mitigation, the report examines the costs of climate change, and concludes that the costs of inaction (e.g. the collapse of the eco-systems upon which the environment depends) significantly outweigh the cost of measures taken to significantly reduce anthropogenic emissions of GHG.

Page 66: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

54

countries. International coordination is therefore a central requirement to address climate

change, however cross-national differences in GHG abatement costs have so far made

such cooperation extremely difficult.

A further distinguishing characteristic of the climate change externality is that it is also a

generational issue. If current trends in anthropogenic GHG emissions are allowed to

continue, scientists anticipate irreversible and substantial economic and environmental

consequences in the future (IPCC, 2007: 7). The lag between the externality-generating

activity, on the one hand, and the visibility of negative impacts, on the other, means that

the economic and environmental costs from the burning of fossil fuels will be imposed

not only on current, but especially future, generations (Stern, 2006). The time lag

between the causes of climate change and its effects raise thorny issues concerning how

to assess future benefits from mitigation policy implemented today (i.e. the so-called

‘discount rate’ debate).47

A final remark concerning the external costs of fossil fuel use is worth noting. Climate

change is a politically complex issue precisely because its causes and effects are

inextricably linked to the functioning of modern industrial economies. Given the link

between fossil fuel consumption and economic development, governments have had a

century-long interest in promoting the discovery and use of fossil fuels, with a favourable

mix of large subsidies and disproportionately low taxes. While important for economic

growth, by making fossil fuels relatively less expensive, such a policy framework helps

sustain distortions in energy markets, and systematically discriminates against the

adoption of climate friendly energy products and production processes. As a result, the

current policy framework creates perverse incentives to over-consume fossil fuels, and

increase emissions of carbon dioxide into the atmosphere.

47 This debate largely revolves around critics of the Stern review, which suggest Stern’s discount rate is set too low. See: Stern (2006); Tol and Yohe (2006); Byatt et al. (2006); Nordhaus (2007).

Page 67: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

55

2.1.2. Fossil fuel externalities: Energy security Excessive use of fossil fuels is also related to another problem facing many OECD

countries – access to secure and stable sources of energy supply. In the case of energy

security, dependence on foreign sources of petrol can be interpreted as both a negative

externality and a strategic weakness for importing states (Bohi and Toman, 1996). In this

latter case, the externality generated by dependence on foreign sources of petroleum is

the cost of securing resources in geo-politically unstable regions of the world (e.g.

through the financing of wars), or the social costs resulting from energy shortages and

associated price hikes, which impose additional costs on consumers. Figure 2.1.2.1

depicts the volatility in crude oil spot prices while Table 2.1.2.1 summarizes the extent of

crude oil dependency for selected OECD member countries.

Figure 2.1.2.1: World price of oil48

Source: IEA (2009) Table 2.1.2.1: Crude oil imports in 2006 Importing country 1000 bbl/day Population in millions 1000 bbl/year per capita

United States 10,118 298 12 Japan 4,075 128 12 Germany 2,213 82 10 France 1,653 61 10 Italy 1,768 59 10 Spain 1,220 44 10 Netherlands 954 16 21 Great Britain 1,039 61 6 Source: EIA (http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/cfapps/ipdbproject/IEDIndex3.cfm)

48 Series refers to Brent, a high-grade light sweet crude that can be used as an international benchmark.

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

1982 1986 1990 1994 1998 2002 2006 2010

USD

/bbl

Nominal

Real

Page 68: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

56

As can be seen in Figure 2.1.2.1, spot prices for crude are highly volatile, at times

increasing rapidly in a manner of months. Table 2.1.2.1 summarizes crude oil import data

for 8 OECD countries. As can be seen, on a per diem basis, the U.S. is by far the country

most dependent on oil imports, and is therefore most vulnerable to external supply

disruptions and price hikes. When countries are compared on a per capita basis, the U.S.

case is less exceptional. The point is that several countries are heavily dependent on

crude oil imports, and this reliance on external supplies constitutes a key vulnerability

and strategic weakness for these economies.

Though use of the term externality here may be “stretching” the concept somewhat

(Sartori, 1970), energy remains under-theorized in the political science literature. As a

result, an assessment of energy policy might benefit from analysis via a lens more attuned

to political forces rather than simply to economic ones. In this sense, interpreting energy

security as an externality seems to apply. To take one example, Russian actions in the

area of its natural gas exports to Eastern and Western Europe have introduced enormous

volatility in energy prices in the region, just as was the case during the oil shocks of the

1970s. Although these actions necessarily play out through price signals (and thus do not

follow the traditional definition of a market externality), they also create uncertainty for

market actors, as well as inefficiencies and distortions in the energy market.49 In this

broader sense, increased energy imports from unstable regions can be interpreted as costs

(distortions) that can be internalized through forward-looking policy that seeks to

mitigate such negative effects. In fact, following the first and second oil crises of the

1970s, some countries began increasing energy taxes as a means of decreasing their

dependence and vulnerability towards external sources of supply. While most notably

done in places like Sweden, even countries like Canada increased excise taxes on motor

fuels in an attempt to reduce demand, and thus vulnerability to external shocks.50

From both a climate and energy security perspective, therefore, excessive dependence on

fossil fuels can be understood as creating external costs. Ironically, existing government

49 Thanks to Caroline Kuzemko for her assistance in helping me think through this point. 50 Private conversation with former official with Finance Canada, John Allan.

Page 69: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

57

policy, currently biased against climate friendly and domestic sources of alternative

energy, has further entrenched this dependence on fossil fuels.51 Indeed, allowing

polluters to use the atmosphere as a free dumping ground amounts to an indirect subsidy

for fossil fuels. Moreover, as discussed in Chapters 4 & 5, tax rates are systematically

biased in favour of more carbon-intensive forms of energy. Consequently, the issue of

pricing carbon is not just about internalizing external costs associated with the burning of

scarce fossil fuels, but also one of correcting systematically distorted energy markets and

policies.

2.2. Internalizing externalities: Pricing carbon

The burning of fossil fuels – a cornerstone of modern industrialized economies – thus

generates significant external costs that are collectively borne by the environment and the

human societies embedded within it. Current price structures for fossil fuel energy allow

firms and individuals to dump thousands of tonnes of carbon dioxide and other GHG into

the atmosphere, free of charge, thus encouraging over-consumption. If polluters were

forced to pay for the disposal of their emissions, as is usually the case with other types of

human-made waste, then polluters would have an incentive to emit less (Rivers and

Sawyer, 2008). Over-consumption of fossil fuels, like crude oil and natural gas, also

constitute a strategic weakness for states that are dependent on external sources of supply.

If prices on these fuels were higher, users would have an incentive to consume less,

51 Given the dependence of modern industrial economies on fossil fuels, it is no surprise that mitigating the adverse effects of climate change through GHG reduction is a politically contested issue, for at least three reasons. First, and most relevant to the present study, the root cause of anthropogenic climate change – emissions of carbon dioxide – are deeply entrenched in current patterns of consumption and production, buttressed by a distortionary mix of low taxes and large subsidies for fossil fuels. Current policy and price structures have created a condition of fossil fuel dependence – a cornerstone of modern industrial society – raising the difficult challenge of decoupling economic growth from emissions of CO2. Second, climate change is shrouded in uncertainty – both with respect to its causes and especially its predicted effects. As pointed out by the IPCC, however, recent changes to the earth’s climate are unequivocal, and are highly correlated with the exponential increase in atmospheric concentrations of GHG emissions since the industrial revolution (IPCC, 2007b). In light of such evidence, climate change skepticism is often used as a political smokescreen used to justify the status quo. Finally, climate change is a man-made problem, and in particular, a problem created by the industrialized North. As such, calls for costly mitigation in the global South raise issues of international fairness. While a carbon tax plays into the North-South debate, such issues are beyond the scope of the present analysis.

Page 70: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

58

invest in more efficient technology, and substitute for domestically available alternatives

(assuming the latter were somehow made to be cheaper). For this reason, a growing

number of economists (e.g. Mankiw, 2007; Nordhaus, 2007), International organizations

(e.g. EC 1991; OECD, 2001; 2009; IMF, 2008; World Bank, 2010), and NGO’s (e.g.

Pembina, Friends of the Earth) advocate putting a price on carbon emissions as a central

plank in efforts to reduce consumption of fossil fuels and mitigate the adverse effects of

climate change.

The appeal of market instruments to price carbon lies in their ability to satisfy three of the

most oft-cited objectives of environmental policy (Corfee-Morlot and Jones, 1992: 15).

First, market instruments used in climate policy are cost-effective in that the benefits they

bring (reductions in GHG, reduced dependence) outweigh their cost, and the abatement

achieved occurs at minimum cost to society. Second, most studies find market

instruments to be environmentally effective in that their implementation actually reduces

emissions of GHG. Finally, important design features can help satisfy the criterion of

equity, in order to ensure that economic instruments are perceived as being fair. In

addition, carbon taxes present important theoretical advantages over other methods of

pricing carbon52 in terms of encouraging technological progress and being

administratively less complex.

To be sure, decision-makers in the real world must balance these competing objectives,

and there are many obstacles to the proper implementation of market-based instruments.

In particular, valuing the benefits of reduced GHG emissions is especially contentious.

As Corfee-Morlot and Jones (1992: 16) point out, even if we could somehow agree on the

future value of a stable climate, at what level should we discount these values in order to

compare them with present day costs? In addition, GHG emissions can be difficult to

measure, and the cost of a changing climate is difficult to quantify, making

straightforward calculations of the cost-and-benefit of climate policy especially difficult.

Economic instruments also affect the distribution of production and consumption in an

52 For instance, regulation (law enforcing expenditure on mitigation and therefore imposing an emissions price) or an emissions cap and permit trading system.

Page 71: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

59

economy, raising thorny questions regarding social equity. Finally, given the global

public good nature of the earth’s climate, an optimal policy response would be

undertaken at the international level. However, given the distribution of costs and

benefits and incentives to free ride, international climate policy coordination is

notoriously difficult to implement, and governments are apparently unwilling to

surrender control of even a small percentage of their domestic tax base to an international

body (Corfee-Morlot and Jones, 1992).

2.2.1. Options for pricing carbon

Notwithstanding these issues, market-based policies are increasingly seen as the most

promising instruments available for addressing externalities in energy markets (Rivers

and Sawyer, 2008; Baumol and Oates, 1985). In fact, the history of climate policy has

evolved from an emphasis on voluntary mechanisms in the 1990s, to the more recent

focus on “coercive” measures like regulation and carbon pricing (Macdonald et al. 2006;

Houle and Macdonald, 2009). To be sure, a carbon price can be set implicitly through

regulation (i.e. a law forcing expenditure on mitigation and therefore imposing a price on

emissions); however, across the OECD the debate has evolved into one that is more

narrowly focused on using market-based instruments (Hahn, 1989; OECD 2001; 2006;

2009).53

There are two basic ways of using the market price to “internalize” the external costs

associated with fossil fuel use. As described by Weitzman (1974), governments can set a

price on pollution either directly, through the tax instrument (i.e. a price-based approach),

or indirectly, through an emissions cap and permit trading system (i.e. a quantity-based

approach). Both harness market prices to internalize some of the external costs associated

with the burning of fossil fuels, and upon further analysis, the two approaches are much

less different than is sometimes portrayed (Fischer et al. 2008). By adding a price to

53 The main advantage of market instruments over regulation lies in their flexibility. Regulations require continuous updating to reflect changes in the latest technology, while market instruments produce a constant incentive to continually invest in efficiency.

Page 72: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

60

emissions of carbon dioxide, both instruments force market prices to better reflect the

environmental, social and economic harm associated with fossil fuel use, creating an

incentive for polluters to reduce their emissions.

2.2.2. Carbon tax

In strict terms, a carbon tax is a direct charge levied on all fossil fuels, proportionate to

the carbon content (or carbon emissions) of each fuel.54 Since the carbon content of every

fuel is relatively well known, estimates of the amount of carbon dioxide (CO2) released

from the burning of each fuel can be derived.55 It is thus possible to tax energy sources

based on their specific climate-change potential, usually in terms of their carbon content

or carbon dioxide equivalent (Baranzini et al. 2000). Accordingly, under a pure carbon

tax, coal should be taxed at the highest rate, then oil, then natural gas, since coal emits

more CO2 when burned, and natural gas, the least.56 This feature of adjusting the tax rate

proportionate to carbon content is what I refer to as the principle of differentiation, i.e.

the tax differentiates across tax bases (fuels) according to their associated emissions of

carbon dioxide. For all intents and purposes, this feature is the defining characteristic of

a pure carbon tax. To the extent that other energy sources (like wind, solar, hydro and

nuclear) are carbon free, they are exempt from a pure carbon tax. Thus, a carbon tax is

effectively a tax on fossil fuels (Carbon Tax Centre, 2009).

Conceptually, a carbon tax has much in common with selective excise taxes levied on

specific goods. In this case, however, the tax base is the carbon content of a particular

54 Some authors (Baranzini et al. 2000) distinguish between a tax on the carbon content of fuels (a carbon tax) and a tax on emissions of carbon dioxide from the burning of different fuels (a CO2 tax). This distinction is technical and involves a conversion using a carbon to carbon dioxide ratio of 12/44. The present research uses carbon tax, CO2 tax, carbon levy, carbon tariff, and emissions tax interchangeably. 55 Simply multiply carbon content by the carbon to CO2 ratio (12:44) after factoring in that amount of carbon which is un-oxidized during combustion (IPCC, 1996). 56 The carbon content of coal is 25.1 grams of carbon per 1,000 British Thermal Units (BTUs); 20.3 for oil; and, 14.5 for natural gas (Pearce, 1991: 939). It should be noted that of the three main fossil fuels, the carbon content of coal is the most variable. See IEA (2008); and EIA Annex B “Method for Estimating the Carbon Content of Fuels (B-2 Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Sinks: 1990-2001), p.A.47. http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/emissions/downloads09/Annex2.pdf.

Page 73: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

61

fuel, or the associated emissions of carbon dioxide.57 In this way, carbon taxes are

qualitatively distinct from other taxes on energy products more commonly found across

the OECD, such as ad valorem taxes (VAT), which are based on the value of a good or

service, “energy taxes,” which apply to energy consumption regardless of environmental

effect, and excises levied on particular energy sources, such as coal or motor fuels

(Pearce, 1991; Baranzini et al. 2000). Notably, while these latter taxes affect the price of

carbon-based energy, their rates are not set in proportion to the carbon content/emissions

of each fuel, and are thus not a “carbon tax.”58

Carbon taxes create an incentive to reduce emissions of CO2 by forcing individuals and

firms to pay a fee for every tonne of carbon dioxide they emit into the atmosphere. Goods

and services that cause very high emissions become relatively more expensive, and

polluters are forced to either reduce emissions through behavioural change or

technological innovation, or else pay the tax. A carbon tax thus addresses the externality

(more CO2 in the atmosphere) by directly adding a cost proportionate to the carbon

content of, or emissions from, a particular fuel. In this way, carbon taxes are a relatively

simple, direct and straightforward mechanism for “internalizing” the environmental and

social costs of burning fossil fuels.59

At the conceptual level, carbon taxes have certain theoretical advantages that make them

a preferred policy instrument among many climate policy experts (Nordhaus, 2007;

Hansen, 2008; Hyndman, 2009). These advantages can be summarized in terms of

meeting three key policy criteria: efficiency, equity, and effectiveness. They can also be

used as criteria against which existing carbon tax policy can be assessed (Chapter 3).

57 Since the correlation between the carbon content of a particular fuel and carbon emissions of that fuel is very high, a tax on the carbon content will have a similar impact on anthropogenic GHG as a tax on emissions. 58 It is important to note that taxes on energy can be considered an “implicit” or “defacto” carbon tax. This point is elaborated on in chapter 4. 59 Pigouvian tax theory suggests that the “optimal tax” level should be equal to the external costs associated with an externality. To be sure, assigning a monetary value to environmental goods and human health is highly controversial (Ekins and Barker, 2001: 329). From a practical standpoint, however, the notion of internalizing the costs of climate change is less to set an accurate price on the externalities associated with fossil fuel use than increasing the relative price of fossil fuels in order to reduce GHG emissions.

Page 74: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

62

Cost-efficiency. A carbon tax is “cost-effective” in the sense of minimizing the aggregate

social costs of abatement (Pearce, 1991). By imposing a uniform price on carbon that is

applied economy-wide, the marginal cost of emissions reductions is equalized across all

sectors of the economy (a condition for cost-effectiveness), ensuring that those in an

economy with a low marginal cost of abatement (i.e. those for whom the cost of

abatement is lower than the price to pollute) have an incentive to reduce emissions (i.e.

increase abatement).60 The choice of whether to emit and pay the tax, or reduce emissions

(through energy conservation, investing in more efficient technology, or substituting for

less carbon-intensive fuels), thus falls on individual polluters, each possessing their

unique marginal cost function for pollution abatement. Each polluter weighs the cost of

emission control against the cost of emitting and paying the tax, and will invest in climate

friendly technology when the cost of such actions is less than what it would cost to

continue emitting (IPCC, 2007a: 755). Assuming actors are rational,61 low marginal cost

polluters will make greater abatement efforts (since the cost of abatement is less than the

price to pollute), achieving the intended reduction in pollution at the lowest aggregate

cost to society (Pearce, 1991: 941; Baranzini et al. 2000: 396; Grafton et al. 2004: 64).

Equity. The key feature of a carbon tax that makes it cost-effective – a uniform rate

applied economy-wide – also makes a carbon tax potentially regressive, in the sense that

it might impose a relatively larger cost on low-income families. Since lower income

families spend a disproportionate amount of their income on energy, an increase in

energy prices for non-luxury goods will have a relatively greater impact on the disposable

income and welfare of the poor. However, unlike other forms of pricing carbon – either

through an emission cap and permit trading system, or regulations (i.e. standards that

impose a defacto price on emissions) – a tax is also inherently revenue raising.62 With

60 As Hahn (1989: 96) explains, “If all firms are charged the same price for pollution, the marginal costs of abatement are equated across firms, and this result implies that the resulting level of pollution is reached in a cost-minimizing way.” See also: Hahn (1986); Hoel (1996); and IPCC (2007a: 755). 61 Since the debate over climate policy centres primarily on issues of cost, the “rational actor” assumption seems plausible. Applying a price to emissions, however, may have the unintended effect of legitimating the act of polluting, and of increasing emissions (c.f. Danhof 2008). 62 Though there are many theoretical advantages to auctioning permits, in practice, all emissions trading schemes allocate permits based on past emissions, free of charge. Such practice makes it difficult to reward early action, creates barriers to entry for new firms, and does not raise revenue for governments.

Page 75: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

63

the judicious use of revenues, the regressive effects of carbon taxes can largely be offset

if revenues are used progressively, as is done in many Scandinavian countries where

regressive taxes are used to finance a progressive welfare state (Kato, 2003). Thus, the

regressive effects of a carbon tax can be offset with various mechanisms, raising some

debate about how best to use revenues derived from a tax, which can be directed toward

the general government budget, earmarked for other environmental programs, or used to

decrease other taxes and achieve the goal of “revenue neutrality.”63

Environmental Effectiveness. Theoretically, carbon taxes are thought to be effective in

terms of reducing emissions in that they generate monetary incentives to produce energy

efficient goods from low-carbon energy on the supply-side, as well as incentives to

consume such alternatives on the demand side. In fact, more so than any other

instrument, a carbon tax creates on-going incentives to reduce emissions. To be sure,

regulations tend to be technology-based (e.g. fuel efficiency standards), and encourage

emitters to adopt particular technologies. Under such a framework, there is little

incentive for emitters to reduce emissions beyond the prescribed standards, unless

governments continually adjust regulations so that they are slightly above the best

available technology (OECD, 2006; Zhang and Baranzini, 2004: 508). Similarly, an

emission cap and permit trading system also lacks such “dynamic efficiency,” since

permit prices are likely to fall over time as climate friendly technology is diffused,

eliminating the incentive to continue with emission reductions (Baumert, 1998). In

contrast, a carbon tax provides a permanent incentive to innovate and adopt new

technologies, for as long as carbon-based fuels are used (Pearce, 1991: 942). Such

permanence helps to ensure on-going reductions in GHG, ostensibly the primary

motivation underlying any appropriately labeled “carbon tax.”

63 Carbon tax revenues can be used for a variety of policy objectives, and these may not necessarily be environmental. For instance, Scandinavian countries adopting a carbon tax stress the importance of not only decreasing emissions of GHG, but also of making the tax structure more efficient (i.e. the “double-dividend hypothesis”). Others suggest that some of the revenue should be dedicated to ensure that the less well off in society are not systematically disadvantaged by the tax (c.f. Sadik, 2008).

Page 76: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

64

In practice, experience with the direct taxation of CO2 suggests that carbon taxes are in

fact effective instruments for reducing emissions of CO2 and the associated risks of

climate change. Although empirical studies of “environmental effectiveness” are limited

in number and marred by methodological difficulties (Baranzini et al., 2000: Ekins and

Barker, 2001: 345), all of the available evidence suggests that carbon taxes are correlated

with reductions in either absolute emissions of carbon dioxide, or with reductions in the

emissions intensity of production. In addition, it should also be noted that the long-term

environmental impact of a carbon tax is likely to be greater than its short-term impact,

since the price signal given by a rising carbon tax might affect investment decisions

concerning capital stock turnover, which occurs over a longer time-horizon (Baranzini et

al, 2000: 406).

Summarizing the available literature, Baranzini et al. find broad support for the

environmental effectiveness of carbon taxes (2000: 407), as does the IPCC (IPCC, 2007:

756). For instance, emissions of carbon dioxide decreased by 6% in Denmark between

1988 and 1997, while the economy grew by 20 per cent, and Danish emissions dropped 5

per cent between 1996 and 1997, the year the Danish carbon tax was raised (IPCC, 2007:

756). In another oft-cited study, Bruvoll and Larsen report that while emissions did not

decrease since the implementation of the Norwegian carbon tax, emissions intensity

(emissions per unit of GDP) witnessed a significant reduction (2004).64 Even quasi-

carbon taxes, such as the UK’s “Climate Change Levy,” have been found to be effective

in terms of reducing emissions of GHG (IPCC, 2007: 756).

64 It should be noted that the modest success of the Norwegian carbon tax has been attributed to extensive exemptions for energy intensive sectors, and to inelastic demand for carbon-based fuels (Bruvoll and Larsen, 2004).

Page 77: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

65

2.2.3. Carbon trading

An alternative, potentially complimentary,65 means of internalizing the costs associated

with fossil fuel use is the cap-and-trade system.66 Under cap-and-trade, policy-makers

create scarcity for emissions permits by setting a fixed limit (or “cap”) on the total

amount of CO2 emissions for included sectors of the economy. The cap (usually

measured in mega-tonnes of CO2) is then divided into a number of allowances or credits,

and such permits are then issued to emitters by free allocation or auction.67 The number

of permits cannot exceed the cap, and polluters cannot emit beyond their allowances,

ensuring that a given target is met.68 A market is then set up to allow the trading of

permits. Heavy polluters can chose to invest in technology to decrease total emissions, or

must purchase credits from other regulated entities that pollute less. When heavy emitters

purchase credits, they effectively pay a charge for polluting, and reward the seller, who

pollutes less. A cap-and-trade system thus creates property rights for pollution, and the

right to emit becomes a tradable commodity.

As is the case with a carbon tax, the trading of permits imposes a uniform carbon price

for regulated entities under the regime, ensuring that GHG reductions are achieved in a

cost-effective manner. Those for whom the marginal cost of abatement is cheaper will

reduce emissions and sell excess credits to those emitters for whom abatement is

65 Cap-and-trade systems are generally more applicable for regulating large heavy emitters, usually covering roughly half of an economy, while a carbon tax should in principle be applied economy wide. As a result, proponents of carbon pricing sometimes point out synergies in the two approaches, as they can be combined (c.f. Lee et al. 2008). 66 Cap-and-trade is sometimes referred to as emissions trading, carbon trading, and the permit system. These terms are used interchangeably in the present analysis. 67 The auctioning of permits has important advantages over free allocation. First, auctioning generates government revenue that can be used for progressive purposes. Second, auctioning eliminates barriers to entry for new firms that must pay for allowances that were initially given away at no cost under the free allocation design. Third, auctioning gives “credit for early action,” effectively rewarding those firms that undertook early abatement in that they will have to purchase a smaller number of credits. Finally, auctioning avoids the problem of firms ramping up production prior to the free allocation of permits, in anticipation of their being “grandfathered” according to past emissions. Despite these theoretical advantages, however, credits are usually always allocated freely based on a “grandfathering” formula, which makes it politically easier to implement cap-and-trade. 68 In theory, the cap should be reduced over time in order to achieve continued reductions. In practice, removing permits from the system is politically difficult.

Page 78: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

66

relatively more expensive. Thus, in theory, pollution is reduced at the lowest possible

cost. Unlike a carbon tax, however, a well-functioning trading system depends crucially

on an effective monitoring and enforcement regime that imposes penalties at a level

substantially higher than the prevailing price for permits (IPCC, 2007: 759-9).

In practice, cap-and-trade systems have been implemented with some success. The most

often-cited examples include the sulfur-dioxide market in the U.S., and the European

Emission Trading System (ETS) developed under the Kyoto framework.69 The U.S.

experience with sulfur dioxide (SO2) trading is generally cited as a successful case of

market-based policy. Although it took nearly five years to set up, once implemented, the

U.S. sulphur market helped generate very large reductions in sulfur emissions (Sorrell

and Skea, 1999; McLean, 2007). In contrast, the European ETS was implemented in a

relatively short three year time period, but its first phase of implementation (2005 – 2007)

has since been criticized for over-allocating allowances and excessive price volatility. To

be sure, there has always been a sense that the first phase was more of an experiment, and

efforts have been made to improve the European ETS in the second phase (MacKenzie,

2007; Skjærseth and Wettestad, 2008). Recent evidence from Point Carbon indicates that

abatement efforts are now beginning, and overall, analysts suggest the improved EU

system will result in larger GHG reductions in the future (Grubb et al, 2005; Betz et al,

2005; Betz and Sato, 2006).

2.2.4. Comparing tax and trade

Both carbon taxes and emissions trading are examples of market-based approaches to

climate policy. As such, both instruments put a price on carbon, internalizing some of the

external costs associated with the burning of fossil fuels, and both create incentives to

reduce the use of carbon-based energy and become more energy efficient. The main

features of the tax and trade options are summarized in Table 2.2.4.1.

69 The EU ETS is the world’s largest tradable permits system, applying to approximately 11,500 heavy emitters across the EU’s 25 Member States, responsible for about 45% of the EU’s total CO2 emissions.

Page 79: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

67

Table 2.2.4.1: Main features of carbon tax vs. cap-and-trade

Carbon Tax Cap-and-Trade

Price Fixed

(price certainty)

Volatile

(price uncertainty)

Emissions Reduced

(quantity uncertain)

Capped

(quantity certain)

Coverage Economy wide (exemptions for

sensitive industry)

Heavy emitters (sector specific,

initially, high transaction costs)

Economy-wide if applied

upstream (fuel distributors)

Revenue Generates revenue for tax cuts or

expenditures (can be used to

offset regressive effects if spent

progressively)

Only if permits are auctioned

Administration/

Implementation

Less complex, can be readily

implemented in less time and

with existing administrative

bureaucracy

Highly complex, requires

protracted negotiation around

design and creation of new

institutions

Political

feasibility

More visible to consumers

(politically less popular)

Costs are hidden, passed on to

consumers

(politically preferred)

Design Issues Tax base (coverage)

Collection point

Price level

Coverage

Point of obligation (upstream or

downstream)

Cap level

Initial allocation

Price ceiling/floor

Monitoring & enforcement

Note: this table builds on Olewiler (2008)

Page 80: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

68

In theory, the main difference between the two instruments lies in setting the price versus

quantity of emissions (Weitzman, 1974). Taxes are “price-based” instruments, meaning

that the price of carbon is fixed, and the quantity of emissions adjusts according to

decisions made by private actors in the market (i.e. whether to change their emission-

generating behaviour, or pay the tax).70 Conversely, emission trading is “quantity-

based,” meaning that the quantity of emissions is capped by government (or some

authority) at a certain level, creating scarcity, allowing the price of emissions to fluctuate

within a market, through trading or auctions (where heavy emitters buy permits from the

government of from those polluting less). Theoretically, the choice between the two

creates a tradeoff between price certainty (important for investment decisions) and

emissions certainty (important for environmental considerations). For this reason, taxes

are sometimes preferred because they provide emitters with cost certainty, crucial when

making long-term investment decisions, while environmentalists sometimes prefer

trading, because its outcome is more certain with regards to achieving a given reduction

in emissions (Ekins and Barker, 2001: 331).

Despite the differences outlined in Table 2.2.4.1, however, tax and trade options are

broadly equivalent (Elkins and Barker, 2001: 329-330). Indeed, Fischer and Hinchy

(2004) demonstrate that both approaches can be equally cost-effective, if certain

assumptions regarding the design of cap-and-trade are met. For instance, when permits

are auctioned and the system is applied economy-wide, the two approaches are

functionally equivalent. Consistent with the “polluter pays” principle, emitters are forced

to decrease emissions, or else pay a fee. But while the fee is fixed under a tax, and set by

government, it can fluctuate under cap-and-trade according to supply and demand, and in

this sense, a cap-and-auction system is essentially a privatized carbon tax (Hyndman,

2007).

70 A central authority (i.e. government of international organization) sets a price for carbon, and emitters chose how much to emit, according to their marginal abatement costs and future investment decisions.

Page 81: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

69

Crucially, from a policy perspective, the two options face many of the same issues when

considering their design; decisions made on the particular design of either a tax or trading

system can erode the distinctiveness of either approach. For instance, policy-makers

interested in implementing either a tax or cap-and-trade must first decide on what sectors

of the economy will be affected, and what sectors are exempt, and this choice can

minimize a commonly cited difference between the two in terms of coverage (economy-

wide versus sector-specific).71 Similarly, if permits are auctioned under cap-and-trade, it

too can raise government revenue, which can be used to offset any potential regressive

effects, (a carbon tax is inherently revenue raising). To take another example, commonly

cited problems with cap-and-trade, such as price volatility and the associated difficulty

business has with making investment decisions under price uncertainty, have given rise to

discussion of establishing a so-called price-collar (i.e. price ceilings and floors).72 One

option, the “safety-valve,” allows emitters to purchase permits from the government at a

specified trigger price (Jacoby and Ellerman, 2004), effectively removing the “cap” from

cap-and-trade. If implemented, innovations like the safety-valve generate more certainty

regarding price, but at the cost of less certainty regarding whether a particular emissions

level can be met. In these lights, when the pure form of either the tax or trading options

are implemented in actual policy, important design characteristics can blur the theoretical

distinction between “price versus quantity” discussed above (c.f. Fischer et al. 2008).

2.3. Issues in the design of a carbon tax

Although carbon taxes meet the criteria of efficiency, equity and effectiveness in theory,

from a practical standpoint, policy-makers must balance these sometimes-competing

policy objectives. Given the politics of implementing any policy that generates winners

and losers, governments must make compromises and tradeoffs when designing policy

71 Because they are more straightforward to implement, carbon taxes tend to be applied economy-wide. In practice, cap-and-trade systems are usually sector specific, targeting heavy emitters, since it would be administratively complex and increase transaction costs to a prohibitive level were they to cover all emitters. 72 Such innovations are referred to as “hybrid models” in the literature.

Page 82: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

70

instruments. Concerning their implementation, four design issues are of central concern;

tax base, incidence, collection point, and level.

Tax base (What to tax). The first key issue when designing a carbon tax concerns the

relevant tax base, or what to tax. Although the Kyoto Protocol covers six GHG, each with

its own effect on atmospheric warming per unit of emissions, the focus of climate policy

tends to be on carbon dioxide, the most significant contributor to anthropogenic GHG.73

Accordingly, policy-makers can levy a tax on the quantity of carbon embodied in a

particular fuel (i.e. a “carbon tax”), or on the specific amount of CO2 emitted when a fuel

is burned (i.e. a “CO2 tax”).74 The choice of whether to tax carbon content or emissions

is a technical issue, and a tax rate on carbon can easily be transformed to a tax on

emissions using the well-known ratio of carbon to CO2 (44:12). In either case, the tax

base is essentially the carbon content of a particular fuel, and in this way carbon taxes

should differentiate among different fuels according to their environmental effects. This

principle of differentiation is the key distinguishing feature of a pure carbon tax, but as

demonstrated in Chapter 3, is inconsistently applied across all jurisdictions with a so-

called “carbon tax.”

Incidence/coverage (Who to tax). Unlike the relatively straightforward question of what

to tax, policy-makers interested in implementing a carbon tax face the politically

contentious issue of social incidence and coverage, i.e. who should pay? In principle, a

carbon tax should apply equally to all uses (e.g. household and industrial) of the same

fuels, without any exemptions so that they are imposed economy-wide. To be sure, the

ability of existing tax agencies to apply a new tax across all sectors of the economy,

without creating any new institutions or bureaucracy, is a key advantage of the carbon tax

over carbon trading proposals.

73 When considering taxes on other GHG, policy makers can use carbon dioxide equivalents, which provide a standardized measure of atmospheric warming per unit of emissions for different GHG. 74 An alternative tax base proposed by the Carbon Tax Centre, a non-profit carbon tax advocacy NGO established in 2007, is to tax in terms of per million BTU heat content for each fuel. Baranzini et al. (2000: 397) point out that taxing in BTU is more common for energy taxes than for carbon taxes.

Page 83: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

71

Applying a uniform rate across all sectors of the economy is important for two key

reasons. First, all things being equal, a uniform price applied to all sectors of the

economy will be more environmentally effective, since all sources of CO2 emissions are

regulated. By covering all emitters, incentives are created for consumers to demand less

carbon intensive goods and services (because they are made cheaper by the tax) and for

producers to satisfy this demand (on the supply side). Second, universal coverage is also

important for the theoretical efficiency of a carbon tax. As discussed in section 2.2.2, if a

uniform price on the use of a particular fuel is imposed across all emitters, then the

marginal cost of abatement is equated across all polluters, ensuring that only those for

whom the marginal cost of abatement is lower than the tax will make efforts to reduce

their emissions, at lowest cost to society. However, as demonstrated in Chapter 3, the

principle of universal coverage is often sacrificed in order to ease the burden of

implementation, satisfy the demands of import-competing and energy-intensive industry,

and to increase the political acceptability of a new carbon tax more generally.

Collection point. Another question is where to tax, i.e. whether the tax should fall on

producers or consumers. Textbook economic theory suggests that a Pigouvian tax should

be imposed at the point of the externality-generating activity, usually “downstream,”

where the fossil fuels are actually combusted (Pearce, 1991). By taxing at the point of

externality, policy-makers ensure the tax achieves its intended consequence. For

instance, in the case of fossil fuels, petroleum is used in the manufacture of plastics.

Were petroleum to be taxed “upstream,” at the point of production, then plastic

manufacturers would be paying a higher price for their inputs, despite not causing any

emissions. Moreover, a tax levied “upstream,” on production, would essentially be a tax

on extraction, which could disproportionately affect net carbon importers if

internationally applied. As argued by Pearce (1991: 945) and others, (e.g. Zhang and

Barnzini, 2000: 509), if the point is to reduce GHG emissions, then the tax should be

consumption based. Others argue that there are advantages to taxing “upstream” (Carbon

Tax Centre, 2009; Barthold, 1994: 139). Since there are fewer producers and retailers

than fossil fuel energy consumers, a tax administered between producers and retailers

would minimize the collection points for the tax, making collection administratively

Page 84: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

simpler. In addition, by imposing a price at the source, it wou

producers from employing environmentally harmful practices in the production of fossil

fuels, like gas-flaring in Alberta’s oil sands. Regardless of government choice on this

matter, experience suggests prices are ultimately passed on

Price level (What price). A further

carbon tax is deciding on the level that will produce the required level of emissions

reduction (i.e. fully internalize the externality)

carbon price, though they disagree on how high it should be.

optimal level of a carbon tax is relatively straightforward. Economists often use a highly

simplified model to illustrate that an efficient level

refining) is reached when the marginal private cost of pollution abatement equals the

marginal benefit (Figure 2.3.1

Figure 2.3.1: Setting the optimal carbon tax l

Source: Freebairn (2000)

simpler. In addition, by imposing a price at the source, it would discourage energy

producers from employing environmentally harmful practices in the production of fossil

flaring in Alberta’s oil sands. Regardless of government choice on this

matter, experience suggests prices are ultimately passed onto consumers.

A further difficult and controversial issue when designing a

carbon tax is deciding on the level that will produce the required level of emissions

(i.e. fully internalize the externality). Economists call this level the “optimal”

carbon price, though they disagree on how high it should be. In theory, setting the

optimal level of a carbon tax is relatively straightforward. Economists often use a highly

simplified model to illustrate that an efficient level of a given polluting activity (e.g. oil

refining) is reached when the marginal private cost of pollution abatement equals the

.1).

.1: Setting the optimal carbon tax level

72

ld discourage energy

producers from employing environmentally harmful practices in the production of fossil

flaring in Alberta’s oil sands. Regardless of government choice on this

difficult and controversial issue when designing a

carbon tax is deciding on the level that will produce the required level of emissions

l this level the “optimal”

In theory, setting the

optimal level of a carbon tax is relatively straightforward. Economists often use a highly

of a given polluting activity (e.g. oil

refining) is reached when the marginal private cost of pollution abatement equals the

Page 85: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

73

Figure 2.3.1 illustrates the theory underlying the optimality of carbon taxes.75 The model

assumes that there is a direct proportional relationship between output in this particular

industry and pollution discharge, represented on the horizontal axis. Let us assume that

the sector in question is for gasoline production, and that the demand elasticity is

somewhat elastic, as the slope of D would suggest. The demand curve (D) represents the

demand for gasoline, and reflects the intuitive idea that as the price begins to rise, the

quantity demanded (and associated pollution) will decrease. The upward sloping supply

curve, S, reflects the private cost of producing gasoline, in terms of, for instance, land

labour and capital. This curve also represents the intuitive idea that as the price of

gasoline goes up, so will the quantity produced. Finally, the marginal social cost curve

(SS) represents the marginal external (or social) cost of each additional unit of pollution

emitted. The SS curve is therefore an estimate of the cost imposed on the environment

and society (the marginal external cost, i.e. the externality), or what economists call the

“damage cost” (i.e. a measure of society’s loss of wellbeing that results from the damage

imposed by an externality-generating activity), quantified in monetary terms.

According to textbook economic theory, the intersection of curves S and D represents a

market failure insofar as the competitive market equilibrium (quantity Q) ignores the

marginal social or external cost (MEC) of pollution. Under such conditions, the price of

the externality-generating activity is kept artificially low (P), leading to excess economic

activity and higher levels of pollution (in this case, GHG emissions). If a carbon tax is

levied in an attempt to account for MEC, then the private marginal cost rises from S to S1

= S + T, where T is the per unit carbon tax (e.g. $100/tonne of CO2). With the imposition

of the tax, competitive markets choose the quantity where S1 and D intersect, that is, at

quantity Q*, which is, in theory, the socially optimal level of production for this good.76

Assuming the tax is equal to the marginal external cost of pollution associated with fossil

fuel production and consumption,77 the private market chooses the socially optimal

75 Figure 2.3.1 and its interpretation are based on Freebairn (2000). 76 At this level, the price of gasoline increases, while the quantity produced/consumed and associated emissions fall. 77 The empirical validity of this assumption is discussed below.

Page 86: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

74

quantity Q*, where the marginal cost of pollution abatement is equal to the marginal

benefit. As noted by Freebairn (2000), “setting the pollution tax at a rate equal to the

marginal external cost internalizes the externality into private sector decisions.” The task

is to determine the socially optimal level of the good to be maintained (e.g. setting a

target on GHG emissions) and the level of tax required to achieve the intended target

(e.g. setting tax rates on carbon-based energy).

If the goal is to internalize the external costs of a polluting activity, then ideally, the level

of tax should be equal to the marginal external cost (MEC). However, try as they might,

economic estimates of damage costs, and assigning a monetary value to environmental

goods and human health, are highly controversial (Ackerman and Heinzerling, 2004).

Since the true damage cost of emissions can never be known (Ekins and Barker, 2001;

Owen, 2004), economists take the “second best” approach of using “control costs” (i.e.

the costs of abatement) as a surrogate for the damage imposed by pollution, and call the

“optimal” tax the one that minimizes the cost of reaching a given level of GHG

reductions. Setting an optimal tax on emissions of carbon dioxide, therefore, does not

necessarily require an accurate estimate of the damage costs of fossil fuel use. All that is

required is an acceptable standard (target level of GHG) so that pricing options can then

be compared in terms of the relative cost of abatement they impose (Owen, 2004). From

a practical standpoint, the notion of internalizing the costs of climate change is less to set

an accurate price on the externalities of fossil fuel use than increasing their relative price

in order to discourage the use of certain types of energy and reduce GHG emissions.

In practice, setting the tax level is much more an exercise in politics than one of applied

economic theory. As a result, some observers fear that fixing a price on carbon through

tax is too arbitrary – if set too high, a tax might hurt economic growth; if too low, a tax

might not lead to the intended reductions in emissions (McMahon, 2008). Such fears,

however, appear misplaced. As pointed out by carbon tax proponents, unlike technology-

based standards, which are less flexible, taxes can be adjusted more readily as observed

effects of existing price levels on emissions and economic growth come to light. While

this may be politically difficult, governments can also legislate trial periods and

Page 87: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

75

automatic tax increases over time, as is often done in practice. Such flexibility is crucial

given the rapidly changing nature of both economic circumstances and the science of

climate change (Pearce, 1991: 942). To make taxes more politically acceptable and in

order to ease the cost of adjustment, governments are likely to set the level low and

gradually increase the rate. The gradual increase is crucial if the tax is to reflect the

rising costs of atmospheric CO2 concentrations over time. Moreover, a continuous,

legislated and automatic increase in the tax ensures that the real tax rate is not eroded by

inflation, and provides an incentive for innovation and early adoption of efficient

technology as firms and individuals anticipate rising costs of emissions. Thus, a carbon

tax can encourage the desired behavioural change even at lower levels of the tax as

individuals and firms adjust early in anticipation of higher prices (Zhang and Baranzini,

2004; c.f. Cadot and Sinclair-Desgagné 1995).

As will be discussed in Chapters 3 & 4, the price at which CO2 is currently taxed varies

widely across countries and across fuels. In many countries, coal is not taxed at all, while

other fuels are taxed at rates up to as high as $400 USD per tonne of carbon dioxide.

However, these rates are not applied to all fuels. In contrast, the IPCC projects that a

global carbon price of about 30 to 40 Euros will be required by 2020 to achieve

stabilization of atmospheric greenhouse gas concentrations at 450 to 550 ppm (Andersen,

2009).

2.4. The Political Economy of Instrument Choice

For all their similarities, a cap-and-trade approach to pricing carbon has enjoyed

relatively more success in the political arena (Keohane et al. 1998; Andrew et al. 2010).

At the international level, cap-and-trade was included in the Kyoto framework under the

so-called “flexibility mechanisms,” giving rise to the establishment of the world’s largest

carbon market in the European Emissions Trading System (ETS). Although Kyoto

leaves room for (and in fact encourages) domestic actions like carbon taxes, no

jurisdictions has unilaterally implemented a carbon tax since ratification of Kyoto in 1997

Page 88: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

76

(the exception is British Columbia). In contrast, cap-and-trade systems for carbon

dioxide emissions have flowered across Europe since the signing of Kyoto, and plans to

establish national cap-and-trade systems are currently being discussed in Australia and

Japan, among others. In addition, regional initiatives have taken place in North America

(WCI, RGGI), and cap-and-trade proposals currently dominate domestic climate policy

discussions in the U.S. and to a lesser extent, in Canada. Meanwhile, across the Anglo-

Saxon world, carbon tax proposals have faced resistance in such countries as Canada, the

U.S., Ireland, Australia and New Zealand.

A key reason for the adoption of cap-and-trade over carbon tax proposals at the global

level has to do with the interests and power of the U.S., which insisted on the inclusion of

flexibility mechanisms under the Kyoto framework. Initially, the European Union

preferred a system of harmonized carbon taxes to promote low-carbon technologies, but

eventually conceded to U.S. pressure for carbon trading (Christiansen and Wettestad,

2003; Ellerman et al. 2007). To be sure, the success of the sulfur-dioxide market in U.S.

acid rain policy shaped how the Clinton Administration approached Kyoto (MacKenzie,

2007). However, the U.S. preference for trading over taxes can also be explained with

reference to the U.S. energy and emissions profile (Baumert, 1998). Relative to other

countries, the U.S. is characterized by energy inefficiency and high per capita emissions.

As a result, a carbon tax would penalize the U.S. relative to other countries that are less

dependent on fossil fuels. Industry in the U.S. has thus tended to lobby against taxation

and in favour of trading, which would allow U.S. firms to purchase allowances from

other countries and avoid having to reduce emissions through costly GHG reduction

strategies implemented at home. Even though the U.S. eventually backed out of Kyoto,

carbon trading has been institutionalized at the international level, and the EU has opted

for creating an international system for GHG reductions that the U.S. can eventually

join.78

78 In addition to U.S. pressure, deep divisions within the EU itself, and the institutional characteristics of the European Union make a European-wide carbon tax relatively more difficult to implement than carbon trading. Under EU decision-making rules, tax measures require unanimity, while emissions trading falls under environmental policy where decisions can be made under less stringent “qualified majority voting” rules. European plans for a Europe-wide harmonization of carbon taxes thus floundered in 1993 and 1994 in the face of opposition from industry and especially the U.K., which was able to play a veto role. For

Page 89: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

77

A second reason for the relative popularity of trading over taxes has to do with more

general characteristics of the two approaches in terms of visibility and magnitude of

costs. As argued by Barthold (1994: 143), the choice of market-based instrument

presents policy-makers with a choice between hiding and declaring costs. Moreover, as

argued by Weaver and Pal (2003), governments will generally eschew policies that may

cause “pain,” or visible harm to their constituents. In contrast to taxes, which directly

impose costs, existing cap-and-trade systems almost always allocate permits freely, based

on the past emissions of each regulated entity (so-called “grandfathering”).79 Although

such practice creates barriers for new firms entering the industry (since they are forced to

buy permits that were initially given away), and does not create government revenue (as

auctioning the permits would), the practice of free allocation is used in order to make

cap-and-trade more politically acceptable. To be sure, grandfathering allows firms to

ramp up emissions prior to permit allocation, which can lead to over-allocation and

ensures that business can avoid taking costly action to reduce emissions. In addition, a

system of cap-and-trade ensures that some firms will be “winners” in the sense that they

will have excess permits to sell on the carbon market. In this way, grandfathered permits

gives firms something of value, which can be traded, and the costs of reduction can be

passed indirectly to consumers, who believe cap-and-trade makes industry pay. In

contrast, taxing has the appearance of only creating “losers” in the sense that all emitters

subject to the tax are forced to pay.

Notwithstanding the apparent popularity of emissions trading over carbon taxes, the

following chapters examine the politics and economics of carbon taxes exclusively. This

focus is partially the result of limitations in terms of time and space. A review of both

types of instruments is not possible within the confines of this in-depth study of taxation.

Carbon taxes have also been selected as the focus because climate policy experts

other accounts of why the EU abandoned the climate energy tax proposal, see Zito 2002; Haigh 1996; Klok 2002 and MacKenzie, 2007. 79 The relatively new experience of auctioning withing the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative is an exception. Discussions around the Western Climate Initiative also indicate that some permits will be auctioned.

Page 90: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

78

frequently advocate them as the simplest and most direct way to put a price on carbon,

yet governments vary widely in terms of how they tax carbon. Finally, the fact that

carbon-energy taxes are used by all OECD jurisdictions, despite the inherent difficulties

in implementing any type of tax reform, provides an excellent opportunity for an analysis

of the comparative politics of carbon taxation.

Page 91: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

79

Chapter 3: Carbon taxes in practice

3. The political limits to implementing carbon taxes

As highlighted in Chapter 2, a carbon tax (and some forms of cap-and-trade) can reduce

GHG emissions at least cost to society. As a result, countless government and NGO

studies from the climate policy community now embrace market-based approaches to

climate policy, and espouse the relative merits of putting a price on carbon (NRTEE,

2007; 2009; Metcalf, 2007; CBO, 2008; Demerse and Bramley, 2008; Mintz and

Olewiler, 2008; Rivers and Sawyer, 2008). In addition, there is now a broad-based,

cross-cutting consensus among economists (e.g. Mankiw, 2007; Nordhaus, 2007),

environmentalists (e.g. Hansen, 2008; Brown, 2008), and even some members of the

business community (Hyndman, 2009; Clark, 2009),80 who otherwise make strange bed-

fellows, that a carbon tax is the most efficient and in many circumstances the most

effective policy instrument to price carbon, and by association, reduce consumption of

fossil fuels and associated emissions of greenhouse gasses (GHG).

Despite the overwhelming enthusiasm for carbon taxes among experts, however,

governments have been somewhat reluctant to unilaterally implement domestic carbon

taxes at home. Indeed, relative to such alternatives as carbon trading, carbon taxes have

proven to be a politically difficult sell, witnessed in both the frequency with which

jurisdictions decide on implementing a carbon tax, and in terms of fundamental flaws in

their design, once implemented. Moreover, carbon tax proposals have failed in several

parts of the world, sometimes miserably. Notable cases of ill-fated proposals include U.S.

President Clinton’s proposed Btu tax (1993), Italy’s suspended carbon tax (2000), New

Zealand’s abandoned carbon tax following the re-election of a minority government

(2005), the dismal election performance of Canadian Liberal Party Leader Stephan Dion,

who campaigned and lost on a green tax shift proposal (2008), and the recent French

constitutional court’s decision to strike down President Sarkozy’s carbon tax plan (2009).

80 Exxon Mobile in the United States, and the Canadian Association of Petroleum Producers, are among some of the business organizations to make public their preference for a carbon tax.

Page 92: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

80

Such experience with failed tax proposals has shown that important domestic and

international political factors can prevent carbon taxes from being implemented

(Harrison, 2010). In addition to the general aversion to implementing new taxes, and to

“the politics of pain” more generally (Pal and Weaver, 2003), concerns over

distributional consequences (like equity and regressivity) as well as concerns regarding

economic competitiveness, make implementation politically difficult (OECD, 2001;

2006; Weir, 2004; Zhang and Baranzini, 2004). Moreover, and in contrast to such other

policy instruments as emission trading, taxes impose direct and visible costs on society,

which further makes for a tough political sell (Barthold, 1994).

Nevertheless, a few European countries and sub-national jurisdictions in North America

have gone ahead and implemented their own version of a “carbon tax,” though these

taxes are yet applied across the economy with uniform rates for sectors and fuels

(Andersen, 2008; Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003). Moreover, upon further analysis,

important design characteristics, which are adopted to make tax proposals politically

palatable, severely undermine the theoretical advantages of carbon taxes, and blur the

distinction between a textbook carbon tax and other types of more commonly found

energy taxes.

The purpose of this chapter is to “take stock” of the current state of carbon taxes that

have so far been implemented in jurisdictions across the OECD. Building on the

discussion in Chapter 2, this chapter summarizes key defining characteristics of a carbon

tax that may act as criteria against which actual carbon tax designs can be assessed (3.1).

Next, the chapter highlights common trends and key differences (3.2) in the design of

existing carbon taxes. After highlighting significant departures from economic theory, the

chapter assesses the plausibility of the electoral system argument outlined in Chapter 1

for explaining an important limitation of the British Columbia carbon tax (3.3).

Page 93: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

81

3.1. Taking stock of explicit carbon taxes in the OECD: A critical appraisal

Implementing a carbon tax is no easy task. New carbon tax proposals face opposition

from entrenched fossil fuel interests and energy-intensive, trade-exposed sectors of the

economy. In addition, voters are often suspicious of new tax reforms, and seem

categorically opposed to increases in tax rates on motor fuels (Hsu et al. 2008). Given

the politics associated with their implementation, political trade-offs must be made, and

such design characteristics can significantly detract from the theoretical advantages of

carbon taxes discussed in Chapter 2.

If one were to evaluate the carbon taxes currently in place according to the theoretical

ideal (Chapter 2), one might consider at least four key criteria. First, carbon taxes should

differentiate the tax rate imposed on different fuels, according to their carbon content or

associated emissions of carbon dioxide. Second, if a carbon tax is to meet the criteria of

being cost-effective, it should apply a uniform price economy-wide, with no exemptions

in terms of coverage, so that those in society with a low marginal cost of abatement (i.e.

those for whom the cost of abatement is lower than the price to pollute) have an incentive

to reduce emissions (i.e. increase abatement). Both principles of differentiation and

broad coverage also have implications for the third key criterion; namely, environmental

effectiveness. If carbon taxes are to have their intended effect on reducing emissions of

CO2, they should be applied at a relatively high level, gradually increased over time, and

apply to all sectors of the economy so that all sources of pollution are regulated. Finally,

to ensure that taxes meet the criterion of equity and political feasibility, carbon taxes

might be designed so as to be revenue neutral (i.e. not dedicated solely to government

budgets), so that part of the revenues raised can be used to offset any regressive effects.81

Although in principle a simple and straightforward idea, carbon taxes differ substantially

across jurisdictions, and political factors largely determine the final design and substance

81 Economists generally prefer revenue neutral carbon taxes on the basis of their enhanced efficiency – the revenue can be used to increase efficiency in the tax system by reducing other distortionary taxes. Some environmentalists, however, prefer that revenues be earmarked for other GHG reduction measures and programs, so there is a debate here.

Page 94: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

82

of particular carbon taxes as they are implemented in OECD jurisdictions (Daugbjerg and

Pedersen, 2004; Pearce, 2005). In particular, carbon taxes differ in terms of the rates

applied to different tax bases (coal vs. oil vs. natural gas), who pays the tax (sectoral

coverage), and how the revenues are used (affecting social incidence). Though important

for making them politically palatable, certain design features can significantly undermine

the theoretical cost-efficiency and environmental effectiveness of a carbon tax.

To date, several jurisdictions across the OECD have successfully implemented an explicit

form of carbon tax, approximating the theoretical ideal with varying degrees of success.

Finland (1990), Sweden (1991), Norway (1991), Denmark (1992) and the Netherlands

(1996) were among the first countries to do so in the 1990s. Later, a second-wave of

incomplete and pseudo carbon taxation emerged in the OECD with Italy (1999),

Germany (1999) and the UK (2001) implementing their own brand of energy/carbon tax,

in some cases under the broader rubric of ecological or environmental tax reform

(ETR).82 More recently, the City of Boulder, Colorado (2007), and the Canadian

provinces of Québec (2007) and British Columbia (2008) have implemented sub-national

forms of a carbon tax in their effort to meet Kyoto targets for the reduction of GHG

emissions.

Upon further review, however, it is clear that some of these reforms should not be

considered a carbon tax in the sense described in Chapter 2. Indeed, a closer look reveals

that several considerably miss the mark of being a true tax on emissions of CO2. The

Italian carbon tax was controversial from its inception in 1999, and has since been

suspended in light of growing inflation in that country. Its future status is currently

unknown. The same is true of the French carbon tax proposal, which in December of

2009 was struck down by the country’s Constitutional Council on the basis that the initial

plan contained too many exemptions for industry (Parussini, 2009). The Italian and

82 Italy’s controversial carbon tax reform in 1999 has since been subject to suspension in light of concern over rising inflation in that country. Its future status is currently unknown. As such, the Italian carbon tax is excluded from the present analysis. In addition, the present analysis excludes the German and UK cases, since both are better interpreted as energy taxes – i.e. taxes on energy consumption – than an attempt to impose a tax on the carbon content/emissions of different fuels.

Page 95: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

83

French carbon taxes are thus not considered here, as they have yet to be fully

implemented.

In such other places as Germany and the UK, environmental tax reform was successful,

but the final product yielded a new energy tax, as opposed to an explicit price on

emissions of carbon (Pearce, 2006; Harrison, 2010). In the case of Boulder, Colorado,

despite its name, the carbon tax implemented in 2007 is essentially a tax on electricity

consumption. It is levied on the consumption of electricity only, and fails to apply a

uniform price on carbon across all sectors. Although such taxes on electricity and energy

consumption will (indirectly) affect the price of carbon dioxide, they do not explicitly

target the carbon content of fuels as their tax base, providing no real incentive to

substitute for less carbon intensive fuels, and therefore, should not be categorized as a

carbon tax. They are energy taxes, to be sure, but they are not a tax on carbon.

The following sections are primarily concerned with carbon as opposed to energy

taxation, and are thus limited to analysis of jurisdictions coming closest to the theoretical

textbook carbon tax, in Finland, Sweden, Norway, Denmark, and British Columbia. Due

to data limitations, and in the interests of making results easier to replicate, the carbon tax

in Québec83 is excluded from more thorough analysis. In addition, the low tax rate is

largely symbolic, and was not presented as a comprehensive, revenue-neutral carbon tax,

as was the case in BC

3.2. Trends in explicit carbon taxes

In general, successful carbon tax proposals in the OECD share a few characteristics in

common.84 First, nearly all carbon taxes in existence were implemented incrementally,

by increasing the rate over time, or by gradually extending coverage (and removing 83 The province of Québec’s carbon tax covers hydrocarbons (petroleum, natural gas and coal) on 50 energy-producing refiners (including Ultramar, Petro-Canada, and Shell Oil) as well as wholesale distributers (including Imperial Oil, Irving Oil, and independent retailers). To be sure, this fits nicely with the view that, in the interests of broader coverage, a carbon price is best applied “upstream” (e.g. Parry and Pizer, 2007). However, data limitations prevent a more complete analysis of this tax here. 84 As the experience of failed proposals suggest, this is not to say that the following characteristics guarantee success.

Page 96: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

84

exemptions and/or rebates for sensitive industry). For instance, tax rates in Finland were

introduced at a relatively modest level (approximately $1.4USD/tonne of CO2) in 1990,

and increased (to approximately $22USD/tonne of CO2) in 1998. Initially limited to heat

and electricity production, the Finish tax was also broadened over time to cover

transportation and heating fuels (Barde and Braathen, 2007: 54). In other jurisdictions,

an increase in carbon tax revenues is generated through the progressive reduction of

exemptions, an approach taken by Sweden and Denmark in the early 1990s. Finally,

increases to the carbon tax can be automatic, as in BC’s annual carbon tax increase of

$5.00 CDN each year, rising to $30CDN in 2012 (British Columbia, 2008).

Gradual implementation is important for several reasons. First, a low initial tax rate, and

allowing both the tax rate and tax base to increase over time, is often required to make

carbon taxes politically palatable. Second, an initially low rate (or initially large but

gradually decreasing refunds) allows emitters time to adjust. For instance, amidst

concern from business, industry in Denmark was granted a 100% rebate on the carbon tax

applied to low sulphur fuel oil, when the tax was first implemented in May 1992. The

rebate was subsequently decreased over time to 50% (1993), 40% (1997), 30% (1998),

20% (1999), to just 10% (2000) where it stands as of first quarter 2008 (IEA, 2008:

117).85 In addition, legislated increases in the tax can help alleviate concern that

governments adjust the tax for self-interested reasons. Automatic adjustment also sends a

clear price signal for longer-term investment decisions, and encourages behavioural

change even at lower tax rates, as emitters anticipate higher costs in the future. Finally, a

legislated, automatic and gradual increase effectively adjusts the tax rate for inflation,

ensuring that real tax revenues are not compromised.

A second common trend in carbon taxes in the OECD relates to who is taxed, and how

much of the economy is covered. Contrary to the theory of Pigouvian taxation, which

stipulates a tax should be uniform across all sectors of the economy, most carbon taxes

apply different rates to different uses of the same fuel (e.g. commercial versus household 85 A similar staggered refund system was implemented for light fuel oil used by industry (IEA, 2008: 118). As of 1 January 1993, the rebate granted to industry using steam coal was cut in half from 100% to 50%, where it remains as of First Quarter 2008.

Page 97: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

85

use), and all carbon tax countries in the OECD provide special tax rebates, reductions or

exemptions for certain sectors of their economy.

Due to the difficulty in implementing harmonized carbon taxes on a regional or global

scale, and the accompanying concern of losses to international competitiveness, sectoral

exemptions appear necessary in order to make carbon tax proposals politically palatable.

Unilateral carbon taxes are often implemented in such a way as to minimize their impact

on sensitive industries, by providing a complex mix of tax loopholes, refunds and

exemptions (Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004). Although necessary for political feasibility

(Midttun and Hagen, 1997), however, specialized exemptions violate the spirit of carbon

taxes, undermine their environmental effectiveness, and blur the distinction between

“carbon taxes” and other taxes levied on the same energy products. As a result of major

exemptions for industry, the majority of the tax burden imposed by carbon taxes, like

energy taxes more generally, falls on oil for transport and for household use (Haugland et

al., 1992; Barde and Braathen, 2007; Svendsen et al. 2001).

In the absence of an international system of harmonized taxes, and given the perceived

negative impact of carbon taxes on international competitiveness, different countries will

apply different rates, and will exempt different industries from carbon tax obligations,

depending on the domestic constellation of interests opposing such taxes, and pre-

existing business-government networks, which privilege certain industries over others

(Kasa, 2000; Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004; Pearce, 2006). As a result, carbon tax

designs vary substantially across the OECD. Key distinguishing features include: time of

implementation; tax level; rebates and exemptions; and, how the revenues are used,

whether allocated to the general government budget, recycled back to the economy, or

earmarked for tax cuts or government expenditures. These differences are summarized in

Table 3.2.1.86

86 In addition, carbon tax schemes can also be distinguished in terms of: the purpose and motivation of the tax; how the proposal was implemented – on its own or as part of a broader tax reform; fuels covered and varying rates applied to each fuel; and, the sectors of the economy to which the tax applies. Where possible, these differences are discussed below.

Page 98: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

86

Table 3.2.1: Carbon taxes in selected OECD jurisdictions

Year

Initial tax rate8

7 Coverage

Revenue

Finland

1990

$2.63 USD

/tCO2

(24.5 FIM/tC)

All fossil fuels. Exempt: fuels used in electrical

generation (due to separate electricity tax) and fuels

in industrial processing

About 5 b.   in 2008 (6.3% total tax rev)

allocated to gen. gov budget w

ith som

e reductions

in other taxes

Sweden

1991

$66 USD

/tCO2

(27 Euro/tCO2)

All fossil fuels. Exempt: fuels used in electrical

generation. M

anufacturing initially given 75%

rebate, reduced to 50%

in 1997.

About 25.7 b. SEK in 2008 (1.7% total tax rev)

allocated to budget and som

e offsetting of other

taxes

Norway

1991

$30 USD

/tCO2

($21 USD

/tCO288)

Most fossil fuels. Exempt: coal and coke in cem

ent

and lim

e industry; fuels in international m

arine/air

travel; fuels used in oil/gas refining. Electricity not

affected (hydro). About 64%

of emissions covered.

About 7.118 b. N

OK (0.9% total tax rev.)

allocated to general governm

ent budget w

ith

some effort to tax shift away from

income tax

Denmark

1992

$28 USD

/tCO2

(100 DKK/tCO2)

All fossil fuels incl. fuels used in electricity gen.

Rebates: for industry. Progressively lowered from

100%

in 1992 to 50%

(coal) and lower depending

on fuel.

About 5.1 b DKK in 2008 (0.6% of total tax rev)

recycled back to industry

Netherlands

1992/

96

$5 USD

/tCO2

(5.16 DGL/tC

O2)

All fossil fuels (initially). New regulatory energy

tax (50%

energy 50% CO2) introduced in 1996

covers only fuels used in “small scale” energy

consum

ption.

Exempt: Fossil fuels used in electricity gen,

industry and greenhouse horticulture. Coal, heavy

fuel oil and motor fuels covered by “env. fuel tax”

and excise, respectively.

About 3.2 b   in 2004 (close to 3% of total tax

rev.) for mixed purposes.

Revenue from

old environmental fuel tax

allocated to gov. budget for revenue purposes;

new regulatory tax (1996) recycled through tax

relief and a portion is earmarked for programs to

prom

ote energy saving and environm

ental

behaviour.

British

Colum

bia

2008

$8 USD

/tCO2

(10 CDN/tCO2)

All fossil fuels. Exempt: bio-fuels, fugitive

emissions from

industrial processing, fuels used in

inter-jurisdictional air and marine travel, fuels for

export. Electricity not affected (hydro). About 70%

of emissions are covered.

About 338 m CDN$ in expected revenue (roughly

1.9%

total tax revenue) returned through various

personal and business income tax cuts.

Source: Barde and Braathen (2007); Truc (2009); Bruvoll and Larsen (2004); W

ier et al. (2005); Environmental A

gency (Governm

ent of Japan); Ministry

of Environment (Finland); M

inistry of Taxation (Denmark); Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and Environment (Netherlands); Tax Statistical

Yearbook of Sweden (2009); Statistics Norway; British Colum

bia (2008).

87 The initial (starting) tax rates are converted into real (2005) USD

per tonne of CO2 to allow for more meaningful cross-time comparison. O

riginal (nominal)

data are in parentheses. Where necessary, data are converted to real 2005 $U

SD using OECD country-specific consum

er price data (energy items), current

exchange rate, and a carbon to carbon dioxide ratio of 12/44. See methodological appendix for more details.

88 Bruvoll and Larsen (2004) estimate of the average carbon tax rate across all fossil fuels in 1999.

Page 99: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

87

As can be seen from Table 3.2.1, many discrepancies exist between the theoretical ideal of a

carbon tax, on the one hand, and actual carbon tax policy implemented in the OECD, on the

other. The first major departure that will be discussed has to do with coverage – both in terms of

what is taxed, and who is liable to pay.

Recall that for carbon taxes to be cost-effective, they must apply a uniform price on emissions

that applies to all products and all uses of fossil fuels equally. In OECD jurisdictions with a

carbon tax, however, this is rarely, if ever, the case. Table 3.2.1 briefly summarizes the

numerous exemptions and rebates offered. A close look reveals that carbon tax jurisdictions in

the OECD apply different rates to different sectors (or uses) of the same fuel, and all jurisdictions

grant exemptions and rebates to particular sectors of the economy, effectively violating the

principle of comprehensive coverage. Sweden, the country with the highest carbon tax rate in the

OECD, is a case in point. For instance, as of 1 January 2006, the carbon tax on light fuel oil in

Sweden was 50% higher in the household sector compared to the same tax on the same fuel used

by industry, once the 50% rebate granted to Swedish industry is applied. Similarly, Denmark

varies its carbon tax rate according to whether a fuel is used for space heating (80 /tonne of

CO2), “light industrial processes” (12 /tonne of CO2), or “heavy industrial processes” (3 /tonne

of CO2). In both instances, an important feature of carbon tax theory – a uniform price applied

economy-wide – is violated in practice.

Other carbon tax jurisdictions apply the same rate to different sectors; however, after rebates and

exemptions are accounted for, the result is much the same, if not greater. In Finland, for instance,

the carbon tax imposed on households can in some cases be 100% greater than that imposed on

industry, given that fossil fuels used for industrial purposes are fully exempt in that country.

Similarly, although the tax rate applied to industrial and household use of steam coal in Denmark

is identical (242 DKK/tonne), industry is refunded 50% of what is paid in the tax. To take

another example, Norway granted a full exemption to the cement and lime industry, which is

responsible for 90% of coal consumption in that country (Vehmas et al. 1999). Eventually, coal

was simply taken off the list of taxable fuels under the Norway carbon tax (Norway Ministry of

Finance). Finally, even where carbon taxes are viewed as comprehensive, emissions from some

industrial processes are exempt from paying the carbon tax, resulting in 30% of the provincial

Page 100: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

88

economy being unregulated by the BC carbon tax (British Columbia, 2008).89 While these

exemptions are understandable given the difficulty of measuring “fugitive emissions”90 and in

ascribing “responsibility” to inter-jurisdictional travel, they could be reduced with a tax designed

upstream, which would then be passed down to all uses of carbon in an economy.

Besides the problem of uniform sectoral coverage in a downstream tax, carbon tax policy in the

OECD also departs from the theoretical ideal in terms of the object of taxation (i.e. what is

taxed). In some instances, particular fossil fuels are singled out for a complete exemption. Thus,

Norway exempts natural gas from its carbon tax, and since 2003, has abolished the carbon tax

applicable to coal and coke. As a result, the Norwegian carbon tax now covers only the use of

petrol, automotive diesel, and mineral oils (heavy and light fuel oils), and these rates do not apply

to protected sectors (e.g. fisheries). Similarly, the complex carbon tax system in the Netherlands

applies only to a select few fossil fuels. Notable exemptions include heavy fuel oil, coal and

motor fuels, which are covered by other taxes explicitly for the purpose of generating revenue. In

these respects, Denmark, Finland, Sweden, and British Columbia stand out as the most

comprehensive carbon taxes in place, in terms of imposing tax rates on all fossil fuels. However,

it should be noted that fuels used in electrical generation in Denmark, the Netherlands, Finland

and Sweden are exempt from the carbon tax, and a separate tax is instead levied on the

consumption of electricity. Vehmas (1999: 346) reports that in the case of Finland, electricity-

generating companies successfully received the exemption by arguing that, in a liberalized

electricity market, increasing the price of energy inputs would pose disproportionate costs on

domestic electricity production. Another reason for the exemption may also relate to the relative

importance of fossil fuels in the domestic electricity generation mix (Figure 3.2.1). Of all carbon

taxes in the OECD, it should be noted that the BC tax is the most comprehensive.

89 According to the government of BC, the exemptions are for “the time being.” The idea is that unregulated industries (e.g. landfill and agricutlture) will eventually fall under plans for some form of inter-jurisdictional cap-and-trade. 90 These emissions refer to where carbon dioxide is emitted as a result of a chemical reaction (e.g. cement manufacture) rather than through on site-combustion. I am grateful to Kathy Harrison for pointing this out.

Page 101: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Figure 3.2.1: Percentage of fossil

Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators As can be seen in figure 3.2.1, three of the four carbon tax jurisdictions that grant an exemption

to carbon-based fuels in power generation also have very high percentages of fossil fuels in their

domestic electricity fuel mix (Fin

generators, competing in a liberalized European market,

largely explain why the exemptions were granted. From the perspective of climate change

policy, however, these exemptions are

fossil-fuel use in electricity production, it is reasonable to assume that a large portion of

emissions in these countries are generated from the power producing sector.

compromise solution - a consumption tax on electricity

penalizes renewable electricity generation, despite the latter’s

some countries, like Denmark and Finland, of

fossil energy in electricity production

Development Indicators

1, three of the four carbon tax jurisdictions that grant an exemption

based fuels in power generation also have very high percentages of fossil fuels in their

domestic electricity fuel mix (Finland, the Netherlands and Denmark). The political role of p

competing in a liberalized European market, and national energy security interests,

explain why the exemptions were granted. From the perspective of climate change

however, these exemptions are concerning. Indeed, with such high concentrations of

fuel use in electricity production, it is reasonable to assume that a large portion of

emissions in these countries are generated from the power producing sector. Moreover, while the

a consumption tax on electricity - may encourage conservation, it equally

ctricity generation, despite the latter’s carbon-free status. And while

some countries, like Denmark and Finland, offer other incentives to make renewable electricity

89

1, three of the four carbon tax jurisdictions that grant an exemption

based fuels in power generation also have very high percentages of fossil fuels in their

the Netherlands and Denmark). The political role of power

rgy security interests,

explain why the exemptions were granted. From the perspective of climate change

. Indeed, with such high concentrations of

fuel use in electricity production, it is reasonable to assume that a large portion of

Moreover, while the

may encourage conservation, it equally

free status. And while

fer other incentives to make renewable electricity

Page 102: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

90

more competitive relative to fossil fuel electricity generation, a tax on fossil fuel would seem a

much more efficient and straightforward approach to promoting renewable power.91

A second major tax departure illustrated in Table 3.2.1 relates to how carbon tax revenues are

spent. In general, revenues from environmental taxation can be used in several ways, including:

allocated to the general government budget; earmarked for government programs/expenditure; or

used to reduce existing distortions in the tax system. Vehmas et al. (1999) report that revenues

from carbon taxes in Finland, Norway and Sweden go directly into the general government

budget, although Sweden and Norway have each introduced measures aimed at offsetting the tax

burden from business and personal income taxation. Similarly, the carbon tax in BC is

essentially revenue neutral, with revenues going to a host of tax deductions for business and

individual tax payers (BC, 2008). In Denmark, revenues are recycled back to industry in order to

ease the burden of implementation (Danish Ministry of Finance, 1995). Finally, the Netherlands

has taken a mixed approach. The “Environmental Fuel Tax,” now levied only on coal, is

explicitly a revenue-generating tax, while revenues from the newer energy regulation tax is both

used to offset reductions in other taxes applied to business and consumers, and to finance

programs aimed at increasing energy savings and conservation behaviour (Ministry of Housing,

Spatial Planning and Environment).

For reasons of efficiency, economists generally disapprove of new taxes geared toward increasing

government revenue or earmarked for government programs and subsidies, as is explicitly done

in the Netherlands. Rather, their preference is for revenue-neutral designs where funds are used

to reduce other distortionary taxes, which may actually work to increase the overall efficiency of

the tax system and create net welfare gains. Indeed, it is argued in the economic literature that an

environmental tax shift may potentially yield a “double-dividend” in the form of realizing

economic benefits (i.e. a more efficient tax system) that are additional to the environmental

improvements derived from an environmental tax (c.f. De Mooij, 2000; Goulder, 1995;

Bovenberg, 1999). At the same time, use of revenues has important implications for the

regressive effects of carbon taxes. While reducing distortions can make economies more

91 The Netherlands applies a preferential electricity tax rate for electricity generated from renewables. Once in the grid, however, it is impossible to know where electrons came from, and since electrons do not contain any carbon, a tax on carbon inputs seems a much simpler and straightforward approach.

Page 103: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

91

efficient, the end result may be to reduce taxes on business as opposed to labour, depending on

where distortions are greatest in a particular tax system (Zhang and Baranzini, 2004: 510).92

Thus, in some instances, there may be a tradeoff between using revenues to meet two opposing

ends – a reduction in distortionary taxes (efficiency) vs. using revenues to offset any regressive

impacts of the tax (equity). In practice, the balance between these two potentially competing

objectives is settled politically. Indeed, governments use revenues in order to make taxes more

politically acceptable, allocating funds to assuage concerns expressed by the most influential

groups in society, including industry (Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004). To date, analysis of a

government’s inclination to use revenue for equity vs. efficiency vs. political gain is lacking, and

while some governments go to great lengths to ensure revenue neutrality (e.g. BC), evidence of

any systematic attempt by governments to identify and reduce only the most distortionary taxes

in their political system is limited. As a result, whether existing carbon tax reforms meet the

criteria of economic efficiency or social equity, or whether revenues are purely used out of

government self-interest, is a context-specific question requiring further investigation (c.f. Wier

et al. 2004; Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003).

A final group of tax departures analyzed in this paper have to do with tax levels and rates. Recall

that from an ideal type perspective, rates per tonne of CO2 should be set relatively high, be

progressively increased over time, and differentiate according to the carbon content of the

different fuels covered.

Levels. To be sure, ascertaining the “optimal rate” is shrouded in methodological and ethical

controversy. Indeed, it is very difficult (if not impossible) to measure the “social cost” of carbon,

since the true cost of emissions is unknown (Ekins and Barker, 2001: 329; Owen, 2004), and

since the benefits (and costs) from a (un) stable climate will be felt well into the future. In

addition, it is questionable whether individuals can objectively agree on the monetary value of

environmental public goods, like clean air and a stable climate, since we all attach a different

value to environmental goods. Nevertheless, economists have attempted to estimate the “optimal

92 Depending on the existing structure of the tax system, using revenues to make the tax system more efficient may systematically disadvantage the poor. For instance, if taxes on capital are more distortionary than income taxes, as they are in the U.S., seeking a “double dividend” from a carbon tax will lead to a reduction in taxes on capital, which does nothing to offset any regressive effects of a carbon tax.

Page 104: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

92

carbon price,” and this exercise has been facilitated by the COP-15 agreement, which sets an

upper limit on global average temperature change to 2 degrees Celsius warming. The task of

setting a commensurate tax rate is facilitated with this number, as designers can now work

backward and come up with a more realistic estimate of what level of tax is required in order to

reduce emissions to a point where a maximum 2 degree warming is probabilistically assured.93

Cross-national comparisons, however, remain difficult. Indeed, in the absence of a global carbon

price, or system of harmonized carbon taxes, domestic carbon prices must be set relative to

prevailing economic and environmental conditions at the domestic level. As a result, estimates of

the optimal carbon price vary across jurisdictions based on projected levels of emissions with and

without a carbon price, and on country-specific demand elasticities. Rather than compare

existing carbon tax levels to some abstract ideal, therefore, a better approach is to compare

carbon tax levels to country-specific estimates of what is required to meet a particular country’s

emission targets. Lacking these numbers, the following briefly compares carbon tax levels

relative to each other, and places greater emphasis on both the speed with which they have been

increased, and the extent to which rates are set in proportion to the carbon content of different

fuels.

As indicated in Table 3.2.1 and further demonstrated in Figures 3.2.2 and 3.2.3, carbon tax

schemes currently implemented in OECD jurisdictions vary widely in terms of the average tax

imposed on per tonne of CO2, that is, the tax rate per tonne of CO2 averaged across all fuels. On

average, carbon tax rates are highest in Sweden, which currently reflect a rate of 93 $USD per

tonne of CO2, or about 80 $USD in constant (2005) prices. In nominal prices, Sweden is

followed by Finland (about 60 $USD) and Norway (about 40 $USD). If real tax rates are

compared, the Netherlands emerges with the second highest average carbon tax. At the other end

of the scale, carbon tax rates are lowest in Denmark and British Columbia, in both real and

nominal prices. In the case of British Columbia, this is to be expected, given that the carbon tax

was just implemented in 2008, and is set to rise by 5 $CDN each year, reaching 30 $CDN in

2012 (British Columbia, 2008). In contrast, the carbon tax in Denmark was brought in at an

93 Of course, assumptions regarding price elasticities and climate sensitivity are still required, so it remains an imperfect science.

Page 105: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

initially low rate, where it has stayed the same, in nominal terms, and actually

terms, since being introduced in 1992.

Figure 3.2.2: Change in nominal tax rate over time

Source: See Table 1 and data from IEA Figure 3.2.3: Change in real tax rate over time

Source: See Table 1 and data from IEA

initially low rate, where it has stayed the same, in nominal terms, and actually decreas

terms, since being introduced in 1992.

2: Change in nominal tax rate over time

Source: See Table 1 and data from IEA Energy Prices and Taxes, 3 Quarter 2009.

: Change in real tax rate over time

Source: See Table 1 and data from IEA Energy Prices and Taxes, 3 Quarter 2009.

93

decreased, in real

Page 106: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

94

Large differences in carbon taxes can be seen in Figures 3.2.2 and 3.2.3. The order of countries

changes between the two because some countries (e.g. Denmark) fail to increase nominal tax

over time, leading to a net decline in tax rates when examined in real terms. Conversely, large

increases in the nominal tax rate over time produces similar increases in real terms, as tax rates

are increased at a higher rate than inflation (e.g. the Netherlands, Finland and Sweden). Indeed,

as a function of percent change, the Dutch carbon tax grew by over 90%, the Finnish tax by 85%,

and the Swedish tax by about 15% when real tax rates are examined. The real tax rate in Norway

grew moderately (about 3%), while the Danish tax shrunk, in real terms, by about 75%, since the

overall carbon tax rate was left unchanged.

To be sure, part of the reason for such high average tax rates in Sweden, the Netherlands, and

Norway has to do with the disproportionate burden imposed on household energy use. Indeed,

tax rates imposed on things like motor fuels and fuels for household heating are much larger in

these countries, despite being less carbon intensive than other fuels like coal. Therefore, Figures

3.2.2 and 3.2.3 are somewhat misleading, masking the sometimes large and potentially

inconsistent differences in the carbon tax structure, which are analyzed further in Chapters 4 &5.

Differentiation. It has already been shown that carbon taxes in the OECD fail to impose a

uniform price across the entire economy. But how well do existing carbon taxes perform in

terms of applying a different price according to the carbon content, and associated emissions, of

different fuels? To answer this question, tax data need to be transformed into the equivalent tax

on emissions of carbon dioxide, using standard emission coefficients.94 Table 3 summarizes the

transformed data, across different fuels.

94 The figures quoted in table 3 are calculated using standard EIA emission coefficients. For details on the emissions factors used and calculations performed, please refer to the methodological appendix.

Page 107: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

95

Table 3.2.2: Carbon tax rates by fuel type, in current USD/tonne of CO2 Carbon

content95 British Columbia

Denmark Finland Netherlands Norway Sweden

Coal

26 $6.79 $17.99 $27.38 $6.82 $34.03 $25.98

Heavy Fuel Oil

21.5 $9.52 $16.51 $27.01 (not covered)

$28.37 $25.20

Light Fuel Oil

19.95 $9.45 $16.86 $27.59 $77.89 $34.39 $145.46

Diesel

19.6 $9.45 $16.86 $27.54 (not covered) * $145.46

Gasoline

19.3 $9.41 $17.51 $27.90 (not covered) $58.68 $124.75

Nat. Gas

14.5 $9.44 $20.87 $14.31 $110.21 (not covered) *

Cor (r=) -0.76 -0.57 0.73 -0.98 -0.48 -0.80 Source: IEA (2008) and British Columbia (2008). *Data unavailable at this time. The data in Table 3.2.2 are derived from IEA and official government statistics on carbon taxes

in selected OECD countries. Based on the most recent data available, taxes have been

transformed from tax rates per base unit of fuel (e.g. tax in $/litre) to the corresponding tax rate

per tonne of CO2. Such a transformation gets to the heart of the issue; namely, what is the

corresponding tax rate on emissions of carbon dioxide, and allows for a comparison across fuels

with different carbon contents and measured in different base units (e.g. litres of gasoline vs.

cubic metres of natural gas). These data are also expressed in current US dollars, using market

exchange rates, in order to allow for cross-national comparison. For illustrative purposes, fuels

in the table are arranged from most to least polluting in descending order, accompanied by

estimates of their corresponding carbon content (in Teragrams of carbon per quadrillion Btu).

If governments applied a uniform carbon tax across fuels in proportion to the carbon contained

and released when a fuel is combusted, we should expect to see a constant tax rate as we move

down each column from carbon intensive (i.e. coal) to less carbon intensive (i.e. natural gas)

fuels. However, it is apparent from Table 3.2.2 that the equivalent tax per unit of carbon dioxide

is not uniform across fossil fuels, as would be the case in the presence of a pure carbon tax.

95 EIA Annex B “Method for Estimating the Carbon Content of Fuels” (B-2 Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Sinks: 1990-2001); p.A.47. Available online at http://www.epa.gov/climatechange/emissions/downloads09/Annex2.pdf

Page 108: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

96

Rather, more carbon intensive fuels appear to be taxed at a lower rate, on a per tonne of CO2

basis.96 For instance, in some instances, coal is among the least taxed fuel, and in such

jurisdictions as Denmark, the Netherlands and BC, natural gas is taxed at a higher rate per unit of

carbon dioxide than coal. This inverse relationship between carbon content of fuels and the rate at

which a fuel is taxed is summarized in the simple bivariate correlation, used for illustrative

purposes only, of the general pattern that exists between carbon content and carbon tax rate. If the

purpose of a “carbon tax” really is to decrease atmospheric concentrations of GHG, including

carbon dioxide, then these findings indicate that the design of existing carbon taxes seems

flawed. With the exception of Finland, and potentially BC, the logic of carbon taxes is

inconsistently applied across all jurisdictions with a carbon tax.

3.3. Case study: Majoritarian electoral systems and the British Columbia carbon tax

To summarize, it appears as though no jurisdiction has successfully implemented a true carbon

tax. Indeed, the foregoing analysis has identified several important “tax departures,” or

discrepancies between Pigouvian theory and actual carbon tax design. These tax departures,

summarized in Table 3.3.1, can be grouped in terms of (i) failing to apply to all fossil fuels,

regardless of fuel type or application; (ii) providing rebates and exemptions, in violation of the

principle of uniform coverage; (iii) departures from the efficient use of revenue; (iv) stagnant or

declining tax rates, in real terms; and (v) weak correspondence between carbon content of fuels

and the applicable tax rate.

96 To be sure, different agencies report slightly different emission factors, which may affect the calculation of tax rate per tonne of CO2. I used several emission factors and consistently found the same result – inconsistent application of carbon taxes – though there was some minor variation in the precise differences. I am currently working on my own emission coefficients, which take into account different qualities of fuels used in different countries.

Page 109: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

97

Table 3.3.1: Sum

mary of tax departures

Tax base

(Covers all fossil fuels)

Coverage

(No exemptions)

Revenue recyclin

g (For social goals)

Tax level

(Relatively high)

Differentiation

(Acc. to carbon

content)

BC

All fossil fuels.

Bio-fuels, fuels used in

inter-jurisdictional travel

and fuels for export exempt.

Broad-based

Industrial processing

exempt.

Revenue neutral tax

deductions, double-

dividend?

Scheduled moderate

increase to 2012

Inverse relationship.

Coal under-taxed

relative to other fuels

depending on which

emission factor is

used

Denmark

All fossil fuels.

Fuels for elec gen. exempt

Rebates for industry

reduced to 50%

(coal)

and 10% (other fuels)

Recycled back to

industry (earmarked)

Declined in real terms

Moderately negative

relationship.

Natural gas over-

taxed relative to other

fuels

Finland

All fossil fuels.

Fuels for elec gen. exempt

Exemptions for

industrial processing

Allocated to general

government budget

Rapid increase in real

terms

Positive relationship.

Consistent rate

applies according to

carbon content

Netherlands

Coal, heavy fuel oil and

motor fuels now covered by

excise. Fuels for elec gen

exempt

Exemptions for

sensitive sectors (e.g.

horticulture)

Mixed – partially

revenue raising;

reductions in other

taxes, and earmarked

Rapid increase in real

terms

Strong negative

relationship. Coal

under-taxed, natural

gas much higher.

Norway

Natural gas and coking coal

now exempt.

Exemptions for

sectors (e.g. fisheries)

Allocated to general

government budget

Stagnant

Moderate negative

relationship. M

otor

fuels over-taxed.

Sweden

All fossil fuels.

Fuels for elec gen. exempt

Rebate to

manufacturers now

50%

Allocated to general

government budget,

some offsetting

Moderate increase in

real terms

Strong negative

relationship. M

otor

fuels and home

heating over-taxed.

Page 110: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

98

To be sure, the reasons for the incongruence between the ideal carbon tax found in

introductory economics textbooks, and the carbon taxes in practice, are primarily

political. For instance, the need to protect the competitiveness of domestic, energy-

intensive and trade-exposed industry is often used as a justification by governments for

maintaining at least one of the tax departures identified here; namely, exemptions for

certain sectors of the economy (e.g. Norwegian Ministry of Finance).97 However, these

arguments do not directly translate into a justification for taxing more carbon-intensive

fuels at a lower rate, the last tax departure described in Table 3.3.1. Similarly, while the

existing literature does a good job of explaining why tax exemptions exist, in terms of the

influence of domestic lobbies and their connection to government decision-makers (Kasa,

2000; Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004; Pearce, 2006), such studies overlook and fail to

account for the inverse relationship summarized in Table 3.2.2. What accounts for the

weak and in some sense inverse relationship between the carbon content of fuels and

corresponding tax rates?

As a preliminary assessment (or “plausibility probe”) of the theoretical argument outlined

in Chapter 1, I briefly consider the role of electoral rules in accounting for some of the

exemptions and apparently weaker tax on coal in British Columbia. The case of BC is

very recent and is the only OECD jurisdiction with a carbon tax where a majoritarian

electoral system is used. It is also the first carbon tax to be implemented in a non-

European setting, and has so far not been analyzed in the carbon tax literature (with the

exception of Harrison, 2010). Moreover, of particular interest is the fact that BC is one

of Canada’s leading producers of both natural gas and coal. In this light, the discrepancy

between the carbon tax rate applied to coal, and that applied to natural gas, is particularly

puzzling (Figure 3.3.1).

97 Some studies cast doubt on the competitiveness argument, suggesting these justifications should be scrutinized carefully. See, for instance, Ekins and Speck (1999).

Page 111: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

99

Figure 3.3.1: Tax rates applied under BC’s carbon tax by carbon content of fuels

Source: BC (2008) and EIA (2005) As can be seen in Figure 3.3.1, the carbon tax in BC seems biased in favour of coal when

an emission factor of 2.77 tonnes of CO2 per tonne of coal is applied to the BC carbon tax

rate on HHV coal. As can be seen, the primary discrepancy is between the tax rate

applied to coal (approximately $6.79 USD), on the one hand, and the tax rates on all

other fuels (approximately $9.50 USD), on the other. To be sure, this apparent

inconsistency in the relationship between carbon content and tax rate is not unique to

British Columbia’s carbon tax (Table 3.2.2). In fact, the BC case is illustrative of a

general pattern – with the exception of Finland, jurisdictions with carbon taxes

inconsistently apply the logic of differentiated rates. With a Pearson’s r correlation

coefficient of r = -0.98 and -0.80, the Netherlands and Sweden are similar in this regard.

In fact, 5 out of the 6 carbon tax jurisdictions in Table 3.2.2 apply rates under the carbon

tax that are inversely related to the carbon content of fossil fuels, raising the question:

what accounts for this discrepancy? In the case of BC, which we can take as

representative, why is coal taxed at a lower rate?

Page 112: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

100

Emission Factors. First, it might be the case that individual jurisdictions use average

carbon content rather than actual carbon content when determining tax levels to be

applied to different fuels. As a result, the tax rates set by governments and/or those

summarized in Table 3.2.2 might be the product of differential emission factors. To be

sure, this explanation is not trivial and requires careful consideration, as anyone who has

worked with emission factors knows they are variable. The carbon emitted from the

combustion of a tonne of coal, for instance, can vary by a factor of 60%, when comparing

high quality anthracite (black) with low quality lignite (brown) coal (IEA, 2008). Given

the variability of coal qualities (ranked in terms of heat content) used cross-nationally,

some emission factors may be more or less well-suited for coal in some countries rather

than others, and care must be taken to avoid using inappropriate emissions factors,

particularly for coal. This being the case, the majority of coal burned in most

industrialized countries tends to be bitumen or sub-bitumen. The corresponding emission

factors for these coal types is closer to 15-20 per cent (Harvey, 2010). Although the

chemical composition of other fuels also varies cross-nationally, the differences are

relatively minor.

In order to correct for the sensitivity of tax rates to the emission factor used, and to guard

against the possibility that Table 3.2.2 might lead to false conclusions, I apply two sets of

emission factors and find roughly the same results. The emission factors, taken from the

U.S. Energy Information Agency, and the IPCC, both authoritative sources, can be found

in the methodological appendix. The EIA factors apply a consistent emission factor to

the tax data (and assume bituminous coal), while the default carbon content data from the

Revised 1996 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Reporting are the de facto

international standard. In addition, the IPCC factors were adjusted for country-specific

Net Calorific Values of the most commonly used coal in the country (IEA, 2008). In

contrast, correspondence with BC officials indicate that the emission factors used to

determine the BC carbon tax rates on coal correspond to an average of the three emission

factors for coal in BC reported by Canada’s National Inventory Report, which also vary

substantially (NIR, 2008). While more research could help reduce uncertainty in the

estimates provided in Table 3.2.2, they provide as accurate a depiction as possible given

Page 113: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

101

the information available. In addition, the large differences in tax rates across fuel types

– for example, between motor fuels and coal – are very likely real and not the product of

using different emission factors. That the choice of emission factors used by the

government in calculating the tax rate may be politically driven is a distinct possibility.

Interests. A second potential explanation is to be found in the literature on carbon tax

exemptions. Much of the literature on the political economy of carbon taxes in European

and Nordic countries, for instance, takes an interest-group/policy-network approach

(Kasa, 2000; 2005; Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004; Pearce, 2006). Applied to the present

problem, we might hypothesize that the tax rates do not correspond to carbon content,

because producers and large scale consumers of more carbon-intense fuels have greater

influence on government, and were somehow involved, or at least consulted, when the

carbon tax was being designed, and the rates set. On the surface, evidence confirming the

interest group explanation for the discrepancy in the BC carbon tax is mixed. On the one

hand, a carbon tax was introduced by the BC Liberals, a political party less known for its

environmental credentials than for its business-friendly demeanor. In fact, the left-

leaning New Democratic Party has consistently attacked the BC Liberal party for its

previous support of expanding oil and gas production in the province, and elections BC, a

non-partisan government agency responsible for administering elections in the province,

lists several large companies, including some in the area of natural resource and mining,

as contributors to the Liberal party in its last electoral campaign. If the “privileged

access” of business interests inside the BC Liberal government is true, then, given the

structure of the BC tax, which favours coal at the expense of natural gas, we should

expect that the coal industry is somehow more important to the provincial government or

economy of BC. But a closer look at the economic profile of British Columbia reveals

just the opposite.

In fact, natural gas is in several respects more important for the overall provincial

economy, and the domestic use of coal appears quite limited. While BC is Canada’s

largest exporter of coal, contributing 1.8 billion $CDN to provincial GDP, the value of

Page 114: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

102

provincial natural gas production was roughly three times larger, or 5.9 billion $CDN in

2005 (BC Stats, 2006).

Figure 3.3.2: Share of natural gas in BC mineral production

Source: BC Stats (2006) As can be seen in Figure 3.3.2, natural gas production accounted for the majority (56%)

of revenues derived from BC’s mineral economy in 2004, which is over 5 times the share

of coal. Similarly, in terms of power generation, natural gas is the second largest source

of primary energy in BC’s provincial electricity mix, after hydro. Here again, the

contribution of natural gas is relatively more significant, contributing more power to the

provincial grid than coal. In 2007, for instance, natural gas was used to generate 2,950

GWh of relatively clean electricity, while no coal was used at all (NIR, 2009: 490).

Finally, as a source of industrial energy, natural gas is used in more industrial settings

than coal. This is due to the relatively small contribution of such coal intensive industries

as aluminum, cement and lime. Based on all of these indicators, it would appear that

relative to coal, natural gas is more important to the provincial economy as a source of

energy. Based on its relative importance, and following the logic of the interest group

account, we should expect larger, more vocal opposition to a carbon tax from the

Page 115: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

103

producers and users of natural gas. Yet the carbon tax in BC is systematically biased in

favour of coal. The reason must lie somewhere else.

Political Institutions. A third possible explanation for the discrepancy between the tax

applied to coal and that on all other fuels under the BC carbon tax can be found in a

recent literature exploring the relationship between political institutions and

environmental policy (Harrison & Sundstrom, 2010). From this perspective, researchers

are encouraged to look at the institutional context as a potential mediating variable,

conditioning the influence of interests and ideas on policy outcomes. Building on the

argument developed in Chapter 1, we might expect the majoritarian electoral system in

BC to play a role. First, and most broadly, electoral systems are one of the mechanisms

through which social preferences are aggregated and articulated to governments, which

can be particularly influential during elections. Second, electoral systems shape the

character of party systems and the nature of party competition, and produce an incentive

for parties in majoritarian systems to target local interests, especially in key ridings

(Persson and Tabellini, 2008). Applied to the case of the BC carbon tax, one might

expect that the distribution of resources across the province’s electoral districts, and the

political competition within those districts, will have an influence on shaping the ultimate

design of the BC carbon tax.

As previously mentioned, the BC carbon tax was implemented by a party commonly

viewed as right of centre and with a less than stellar environmental record. But by 2007,

in the context of rising environmental concern shown at the polls and in a province with

an already heightened level of environmental consciousness,98 the BC Liberal party,

under Gordon Campbell, launched one of the most progressive climate policy agendas in

the country at the time. In a government throne speech in early 2007, the Premier

announced a host of new policy initiatives, including new emissions reductions targets,

promises to “green the grid,” and to work with other jurisdictions (notably California) on

other initiatives to “reduce net greenhouse gases in the Pacific Coast Region” (Office of

98 British Columbia has consistently been among the provinces with the highest percentage of votes for the Green Party in Canadian federal elections.

Page 116: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

104

the Premier, 2007). Later that year, the government began consulting on the idea of a

carbon tax, which was enthusiastically supported by a host of NGOs and academics

working in the climate policy community, as well as notable opinion leaders like David

Suzuki (Harrison, 2009). Taking a page out of the Green Party’s policy platform, the

Liberals forced the rival New Democratic Party (NDP) to criticize a path-breaking (for

North America) policy proposal in the provincial election of 2008, to the dismay

environmentalists, who had traditionally supported the more environmentally conscious

NDP, and felt betrayed by the seemingly opportunistic “axe the tax” campaign. Initially,

the proposal also received broader public support (Environics, Harrison, 2009), until the

price of gasoline rose, an issue that was subsequently eclipsed by economic recession. In

these lights, the BC carbon tax appears to have been as much good policy as it was good

politics. Indeed, reaching a low in 2000, support for environmental taxation in British

Columbia was on the rise when Campbell introduced his tax reform (Figure 3.3.3).99 In

the end, Campbell survived the election of 2008, and drew a new constituency to his

party. And while most attribute the victory to the confidence voters had in his

competency as an economic manager (Harrison, 2009), rather than to a resounding

approval of his carbon tax plan, Campbell’s environmental turn also reflected a new kind

of politics, where a right-leaning conservative party embraced the virtues of free-market

environmentalism, uniting free-market economists with environmentalists alike.

99 This particular question probes support for an environmental tax with revenues to reduce pollution, something that was not specifically done in BC. It is used here as a proxy to show support for environmental taxation in general.

Page 117: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

105

Figure 3.3.3. Support for environmental taxation: Percent agreeing with the statement “I would agree to an increase in taxation if the money raised were used to reduce pollution”

Source: World Values Surveys

In addition to the impact elections have on the development of party platforms and party

politics, expanding the limits of the possible at times, electoral “rules of the game” and

electoral boundaries more particularly, also condition the room for political maneuver.

For instance, as argued in Chapter 1, highly disproportional systems, typical of

majoritarian elections like those in BC, produce incentives for politicians to target policy

in line with public opinion, since small shifts in the popular vote can translate into

relatively large shares in seats. Moreover, political institutions, like electoral rules,

systems, and boundaries, shape how interests are represented. Thus, in addition to the

relative size or importance of the natural gas industry, the geographical distribution of

resources must also be taken into account. Figure 3.3.4 provides a visual representation

of electoral districts in British Columbia, overlaid with the location of coal mines and gas

fields in the province.

50

55

60

65

70

75

1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

British Columbia Canada

Page 118: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

106

Figure 3.3.4: Geographical distribution of coal and gas in BC

Source: GIS data from Elections BC; Ministry of Energy, Mines and Petroleum Resources; BC Oil and Gas Commission

Page 119: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

107

Figure 3.3.4 illustrates the geographic distribution of coal and gas in the province of BC,

using geological GIS files, overlaid with a political map of electoral districts in the

province. Coal mines are represented in black, and natural gas fields in yellow. As can

be seen, natural gas fields are concentrated in North Eastern British Columbia,

exclusively. In contrast, there are several coal mines geographically dispersed across the

province. Crucially, the coal mines cover more electoral ground, so to speak, in that coal

is actively mined in several electoral ridings. In contrast, natural gas fields are found in

only two electoral districts (Peace River North and South), and in both cases, coal is also

prominent.

Interestingly, the 8 electoral districts with active coal production were well represented

by members of the Liberal Party at the time when the carbon tax was proposed and

designed, with several high ranking and relevant positions in the provincial cabinet. The

representatives included Minister of Energy, Mines and Resources, Richard Neufeld

(Peace River North), Minister of Community Development, Blair Lekstrom (Peace River

South), Minister of Agriculture, Stan Hagan (Comox Valley), Minister of State for

Mining, Bill Bennett (Kootney East), and Caucus Liason to the Minister of State for

Mining, Dennis Mackay (Stikine). In total 4 of the 5 members of the provincial

legislature were in cabinet, and the fifth held a special liaison position with the Minister

of State for Mining. Needless to say, districts with active coal mines are well represented

not only the Liberal caucus but also in cabinet. Although lacking access to the levers of

power, coal mines in the remaining districts are also able to make their views on the

carbon tax known through members of the opposition, and in the context of electoral

competition and criticism of the carbon tax, it appears as though some of these voices

were heard.

Moreover, of the 8 districts actively producing coal, 4 were considered to be “tight” races

(i.e. with a projected vote difference of less than 4%) in the months leading up to the

provincial general election of 2009.100 Based on seat projections, a shift in just 6 districts

100 See http://bc2009.com/ridings/

Page 120: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

108

could lead to a majority NDP government.101 In this way, coal districts could be

perceived as being pivotal, especially in light of the campaign, in which Campbell’s

carbon tax was hotly debated. The electoral success of the two largest parties (i.e. the BC

Liberals and NDP) is summarized for the two most recent general elections in Table

3.3.1.

Table 3.3.1: Electoral competition in key coal and natural gas districts: vote shares (in percentages) 2005 2009 BC Liberal NDP BC Liberal NDP Comox Valley 43 46 47 43 Fraser Nicola102 40 49 43 49 Kootenay East 48 44 51 36 Nanaimo 34 52 36 53 North Island 43 45 39 52 Peace River N 59 27 43 14 Peace River S 58 33 63 27 Stikine103 48 40 45 50 Source: Elections BC As is clear from Table 3.3.1, only two of the primary coal and gas ridings can be

considered “safe” for the BC Liberal party, based on the vote shares accruing to the

largest parties in 2005.104 Interestingly, the safe ridings of Peace River North and Peace

River South are also the two districts actively producing natural gas in North Eastern BC,

which might explain why the BC Liberal government was able to impose a relatively

higher tax rate on natural gas. In contrast, the vote difference in ridings where coal is

actively mined is considerably smaller. These latter districts are those that could be

considered pivotal for winning the next election, producing an incentive for the BC

Liberals to target these constituencies with favourable policy.

101 Based on data from the 2005 provincial election and overlaying the new districts, BC Liberals were expected to win 48 compared to 37 for the NDP. 102 This riding was substantially re-arranged between 2005 and 2009 by the Electoral Boundaries reform in 2008. I use electoral data for Yale-Lillooet for 2005. 103 This riding was also substantially redrawn by the Electoral Boundaries Act. Data for 2005 are for Bulkey Valley-Stikine. 104 By “safe” I mean a vote difference of greater than 10%.

Page 121: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

109

In light of the above, it would thus appear as though the BC Liberal government

consciously designed the carbon tax in such a way as to not jeopardize their electoral

chances in coal-producing districts, which are also among the largest and least populated

(increasing the weight of individual votes in these districts).105 This is consistent with the

theory outlined in Chapter 1, which suggests that majoritarian systems will target policies

so as to benefit (or at least not harm) narrow constituencies that may be pivotal in an

election.

In sum, one might explain the structure of the BC carbon tax with reference to the

political economy of coal and natural gas in the province. There are many unionized coal

mines across BC, which overlap numerous electoral ridings. In contrast, the natural gas

industry is much less labour-intensive, is non-unionized, and is concentrated in just two

electoral ridings in North Eastern British Columbia, that are electorally “safe” for the BC

Liberals. It might be argued, therefore, that the natural gas industry has much less

political clout, and that the majoritarian electoral system, combined with the distribution

of resources across the provincial districts, biases policy in favour of coal, reflected in a

lower tax and exemptions on coal exports. This argument is distinct from the currently

dominant explanation found in the literature on carbon taxation, which identifies a key

role for corporatism and policy networks in the design of carbon taxes.

Having found some support for the theoretical argument in Chapter 1, the following

chapters develop a more comprehensive analysis of the extent to which electoral systems

matter for carbon-energy taxation. As discussed in the literature review, relatively less

attention has focused on analyzing and explaining the factors behind the more general

energy tax structure – including all taxes affecting the price of CO2. The following

chapters attempt to begin filling gaps in this literature, and analyze carbon-energy taxes

in a large-n, cross-national setting.

105 For instance, Stikine is the largest riding in British Columbia, and also the least populated.

Page 122: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

110

Chapter 4: Measurement and description

4. Energy taxes as implicit carbon taxes: exploring cross-national differences Much thinking around climate policy now focuses largely on explicitly labeled “carbon

taxes” and “cap-and-trade” programs as a means of putting a price on emissions of

carbon dioxide (CO2). The analysis of carbon taxes in Chapter 3, however, demonstrates

that no government has successfully implemented a pure carbon tax, in the strict

Pigouvian sense. Indeed, existing carbon taxes in OECD jurisdictions either fail to

differentiate across fuels based on associated emissions of carbon dioxide, or fail to apply

a uniform rate economy wide, or in nearly every instance, fail to do both. Similarly,

existing cap-and-trade systems are often limited to certain emitters and sectors of the

economy.

At the same time, all countries levy taxes on different fossil fuels, and these taxes affect

the overall price of carbon in a country, and associated CO2 emissions, even if this is not

their stated intent. For instance, all countries levy taxes on the use of motor fuels and oil

for heating, and these taxes impact the consumption of fossil fuels and, as a result, final

CO2 emissions. This underlying tax structure produces a less visible framework of

incentives and constraints that has important implications for climate policy, and thus

warrants closer analysis. It is also important for policy-makers to understand the existing

tax structure when developing climate policy.

The following Chapter will argue that, contrary to conventional wisdom, the carbon taxes

examined in Chapter 3 are less distinct, in both their design and effects, when compared

to more commonly found energy taxes in the OECD. As a result, if a researcher wants to

ascertain the effective “price of carbon” across countries, then it makes sense to analyze

energy taxes on fossil fuels in addition to carbon taxes, both of which affect the price of

carbon. Indeed, an analysis of these “implicit” carbon taxes paints a more comprehensive

and accurate picture of cross-national variation in the price of carbon, insofar as both

Page 123: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

111

energy and carbon taxes are taken into account. In addition, if researchers want to better

understand the determinants of taxes on fossil fuels, they can benefit from a measure that

allows for deeper and broader comparative analysis across a larger number of countries,

across different sectors of the economy (like household, transport and industrial sectors),

across different fossil fuels, and across time. A better understanding of implicit (or

indirect) carbon taxes, and of why they vary so much across countries, can help to

provide crucial insight into the factors that may facilitate and constrain energy tax reform,

specify the conditions under which higher taxes on fossil fuels are politically possible, as

well as help identify barriers to energy tax reform more generally. These insights can

then be further examined in future work on carbon taxes and climate policy.

To be sure, pre-existing fossil fuel taxes have important implications for climate policy.

For instance, tracking the structure of implicit carbon taxes across countries can assist

policy-makers in: (i) determining the cost of abatement in particular countries; (ii)

deciding on which policy instruments to implement and how they should be designed in

light of pre-existing taxes; and, and, (iii) evaluate the effectiveness of instruments (e.g.

carbon taxes) once implemented. Despite such implications for climate policy goals and

objectives, however, the actual energy tax structure is not well understood (Baranzini et

al. 2000; Giddens, 2009). Although researchers sometimes lament the fact that energy

taxes are poorly adapted to the problem of climate change, no study has yet examined the

energy tax structure in terms of the way in which different countries tax carbon-based

fuels (and associated emissions of carbon dioxide), let alone try to explain these

differences.

The following Chapter develops an estimate what shall be referred to as the implicit

carbon tax for six fossil fuels commonly consumed in OECD jurisdictions – coal, heavy

fuel oil (HFO), light fuel oil (LFO), diesel, gasoline, and natural gas. Estimates are based

on energy price and tax data from the International Energy Agency (IEA) and cover 29

Page 124: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

112

OECD countries over the period 1978-2006.106 The Chapter begins by setting out the

main theoretical distinction between explicitly labeled carbon taxes, on the one hand, and

energy taxes, on the other (4.1) before developing an argument in favour of

conceptualizing energy taxes as implicit carbon taxes (4.2). Building on the carbon tax

literature, the Chapter then develops a justification for examining implicit carbon taxes

(4.3) and reviews the procedure for their estimation across 29 OECD countries over the

period 1978-2006 (4.4). After describing trends in implicit carbon taxes in the OECD

(4.5), the Chapter proceeds to specify the puzzling differences that exist across countries

and over time (4.6), the empirical analysis of which are the subject of Chapter 5.

4.1. Energy taxes vs. carbon taxes

Economists (Pigou, 1920; Sandmo, 1975) and international organizations (EC, 1991;

IMF, 2008; OECD, 1997; World Bank, 2010) have long advocated carbon taxes as a

cost-effective instrument for reducing greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Indeed, it is

now well established in economic theory that – by equalizing the marginal cost of

abatement across an economy – a carbon tax can bring about a given level of emissions

reductions at least cost (Baumol and Oates, 1971). In addition, if the objective is to

reduce emissions of CO2, then a carbon tax (i.e. a tax on carbon content) is preferred to

an energy tax (i.e. a tax on energy consumption), on cost-efficiency grounds (Zhang and

Baranzini, 2004; Manne and Richels, 1993).

For a given level of GHG reductions, a carbon tax is more efficient than an energy tax

because it creates incentives for both reducing energy consumption (i.e. the conservation-

effect107) and switching to less carbon intensive fuels (i.e. the substitution-effect108).109 In

106 By the implicit tax on carbon, I refer to the sum of all taxes (e.g. excise + VAT + specialized taxes) on each carbon-based fuel just mentioned. 107 By “conservation-effect,” I refer to the incentive to reduce consumption of a taxed good. Applied to energy, a tax will increase the cost of energy consumption, and produce an incentive to conserve. 108 By “substitution-effect,” I refer to the incentive to substitute for less carbon-intensive fuels, which are taxed at a lower rate. 109 Andersen (2008) refers to a “demand” and “substitution” effect.

Page 125: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

113

contrast, an energy tax does not set rates in proportion to carbon content, and the second

incentive for fuel switching is therefore weakened.110 As a result, an energy tax achieves

GHG reductions primarily through its influence on price-induced conservation, and

ceteris paribus, must be set at a higher level (implying higher abatement costs) in order to

achieve the same level of reduction as a carbon tax (Zhang and Baranzini, 2004).

In practice, the difference between carbon and energy taxes is not so clear-cut. As

demonstrated in Chapter 3, carbon taxes currently implemented in OECD jurisdictions

often apply rates that are inconsistently related to the carbon content of particular fuels,

and often include numerous exemptions for industry. In other words, the carbon taxes in

place do not equalize the marginal cost of carbon abatement across the economy, and

provide only weak (and in some cases perverse111) incentives for fuel substitution. Thus,

existing carbon taxes cannot be considered a “pure” tax on carbon emissions, in the strict

Pigouvian sense (c.f. OECD, 2001: 56; Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003). An implication is

that “carbon taxes” currently implemented in the OECD lose much of their

distinctiveness vis a vis other, more common forms of energy taxation. Indeed, under

these circumstances, the theoretical cost-efficiency advantages and the substitution-

effects of a carbon tax are weakened, and the distinction between energy taxes, and

carbon taxes proper, is effectively blurred.112

110 An energy tax on electricity consumption does not usually distinguish between electricity generated from coal vs. electricity generated from nuclear sources. 111 I use the term perverse here from an environmental perspective. The explicit goal of a CO2 tax is to reduce carbon emissions. However, under existing carbon tax regimes, coal is systematically taxed at a lower rate relative to other fuels. As a result, a perverse incentive is created – to continue burning coal – which is diametrically opposed to the stated intent of a carbon tax. 112 Only when the marginal cost of emitting an additional unit of CO2 is equalized across all sectors of an economy will emissions reductions occur at lowest aggregate social cost. Application of a uniform carbon price (e.g. $10 per tonne of CO2) ensures that, a) economic actors will have an incentive to switch to less carbon-intensive fuels; and, b) economic actors for who the marginal cost of abatement is lower will have an incentive to take greater efforts at reducing emissions. In the absence of a uniform carbon price, the carbon tax will not be efficient (in the sense of minimizing aggregate abatement costs) and may be expected to increase the macroeconomic cost of reducing carbon emissions (Ekins and Barker, 2001: 341).

Page 126: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

114

4.2. Energy taxes as implicit carbon taxes

Compared to the relatively few jurisdictions with explicitly labeled “carbon taxes”

discussed in Chapter 3, energy taxes are much more commonly found in OECD

jurisdictions. In fact, all OECD jurisdictions levy taxes on the consumption of such fossil

fuels as gasoline, diesel, oil, and natural gas.113 These energy taxes are sometimes

referred to as “indirect environmental taxes” (Albrecht, 2006: 92), or “implicit carbon

taxes” (Hoeller and Coppel, 1992; Baranzini et al. 2000; Yokoyama, 2000), in the sense

that they affect the price of energy products and associated emissions, even though such

effects are not their stated intent.

In a recent study on the political struggle to address climate change, Anthony Giddens

(2009: 149) argues that,

…we should not focus only on carbon taxes as such, but upon the consequences

of a given fiscal system as a whole for outputs that are relevant to climate change. We should recognize that existing taxes which have not been devised for environmental purposes may nevertheless in some part serve them – in that sense, they are carbon taxes.

Following Giddens, I adopt a similar approach to the issue of environmental/carbon

taxation. To be sure, existing fossil fuel energy taxes are not necessarily introduced to

reduce CO2 emissions, and are instead justified on the basis of other reasons, including

government revenue requirements, reduced foreign energy dependence, improved local

air, noise and water quality, decreased urban congestion and traffic accidents, and road

maintenance, to name a few. Nevertheless, existing energy taxes on fossil fuels have the

unintended benefit of reducing GHG because they increase the price of fossil fuels

(decreasing demand for these fuels and encouraging conservation). These effects on

consumption are precisely the reason why some prominent economists advocate higher

taxes on things like motor fuels (e.g. Mankiw, 2006).

113 Coal is almost always exempt.

Page 127: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

115

At the same time, even formal “carbon taxes,” explicitly imposed to reduce emissions,

inconsistently apply rates to carbon content (c.f. Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003: 207), and

have yet to be applied economy-wide (Andersen, 2008), thus weakening their status as a

pure “environmental” or Pigouvian tax. To the extent that rates under a carbon tax are

inconsistent with carbon content (as is often the case), incentives for fuel substitution are

weakened, and a carbon tax’s emission reduction effects derive exclusively from price-

induced conservation, just like an energy tax. Thus, irrespective of their label or

environmental rationale, poorly designed carbon taxes implemented in the OECD lose

some of their distinctiveness vis a vis more commonly found energy taxes, in terms of

their (theoretical) environmental effectiveness.

Moreover, upon closer analysis, a second distinguishing characteristic of carbon taxes is

effectively muddied in the real-world application of carbon taxes; namely, the cost-

efficiency advantages of a carbon tax relative to energy taxes. It has already been

suggested that inconsistent rates set by carbon tax regimes reduce the incentives for fuel

switching, necessitating higher overall tax rates to achieve a given level of abatement.

This argument can be pushed further in light of the exemptions commonly granted under

carbon tax regimes. Just as “implicit” carbon taxes “are not efficient, in the sense of

equalizing the marginal cost of carbon abatement across the tax base” (Ekins and Barker,

2001: 340), carbon taxes also fail to meet this distinctive criterion. Indeed, all carbon tax

regimes contain exemptions, violating the necessity of having a uniform carbon price

across all sectors of an economy (a condition for cost-effectiveness). In the absence of a

uniform carbon price, the carbon tax will not be efficient (in the sense of minimizing

abatement costs) as lack of this feature may be expected to increase the macroeconomic

cost of reducing emissions (c.f. Ekins and Barker, 2001: 341). Thus, in practice, the

distinction between carbon and energy taxes – in terms of both economic efficiency and

environmental benefits – is not as pronounced as is commonly assumed.

In fact, in the absence of a uniform carbon price on CO2 emissions applied economy

wide, energy or fiscal taxes imposed upon carbon-based energy will have the same

economic and environmental impact as those levies explicitly labeled “carbon taxes,”

Page 128: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

116

provided that the tax rates on the different tax bases (i.e. fuels) are the same (OECD,

2001: 56).114 This is due to the simple fact that standard energy taxes increase the

relative price of the fuels to which they are applied, but like carbon taxes which fail to set

rates in proportion to carbon content, provide no incentive to substitute for less carbon-

intensive fuels, reducing emissions only via price-induced conservation. The end result is

that, regardless of label, rationale, or stated intent, excise, VAT, and other specialized

taxes are functionally equivalent to “carbon taxes” when the latter fail to impose a

uniform rate in proportion to the carbon content of fuels.

To be sure, it is not always obvious whether an energy tax or a tax on a particular fossil

fuel can be considered environmental. Indeed, there is some controversy over what

constitutes an “environmental tax” in the literature, and this debate has some bearing on

the question of whether it is appropriate to consider energy taxes on fossil fuels as

“implicit” carbon taxes, as is done here. Two distinct lines of argument fall into two

general camps. On the one hand, some researchers adopt a formalist view, arguing that

only those taxes justified on the basis of an explicit environmental purpose should be

considered “environmental” (Bruvoll, 2009). From this perspective, a formal distinction

is made between fiscal (i.e. revenue-raising) taxes on the one hand, and environmental

levies (i.e. with an explicit environmental purpose), on the other. Thus, Vehmas (2005),

following Määttä, (1997), excludes motor fuel taxes from their definition of an

environmental tax, on the basis that such taxes are not solely (or even primarily) raised

for environmental purposes (Vehmas et al. 1999: 345). Similarly, the U.S. tax code does

not include the tax on gasoline under its four main categories of “environmental taxes,”

since revenues are often used to fund transportation projects and not dedicated for

explicitly environmental purposes (EPA, 2001). However, as pointed out by Gayer and

Horowitz (2005: 66-67), the same U.S. tax code does label its excise tax on crude oil an

114 To be sure, carbon taxes retain their theoretical advantages, and properly designed and implemented, are to be preferred over broader “energy taxes” as instruments of climate policy (Zhang and Baranzini, 2004: 508-509). The point is that existing carbon taxes fail to be implemented as theory suggests, and so their theoretical advantages, and distinctiveness, is effectively blurred.

Page 129: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

117

“environmental tax,” even though it is much smaller and has almost identical effects as

the U.S. federal tax on gasoline (not considered an “environmental tax”).115

On the other hand, international statistical agencies like Eurostat, the OECD and the IEA

take a consequentialist view of environmental taxes, defining a tax as environmental

“…based on the potential environmental effects of a given tax, which is determined by

the impacts of the tax on the producer and consumer prices in question, in conjunction

with the relevant price elasticities” (OECD, 1999: 57). This broader view of

“environmentally-related” taxation acknowledges the fact that pollution taxes are often

“piggybacked onto existing taxes on energy consumption and motor transport” (Ward

and Cao, 2010: 3), and thus environmental taxes are conceptually and practically

“intertwined,” something even proponents of the formalist approach explicitly recognize

(c.f. Bruvoll, 1999). In fact, previous research has suggested that even “green taxes” are

“…not set with a specific concern for the environment; their purpose is largely to

generate revenue” (Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003: 213) and that all taxes, whether labeled

environmental or not, are fundamentally fiscal in nature, helping governments to raise

revenue and only labeled “environmental” in an attempt to legitimate them in the eyes of

the public (Svendsen et al. 2001: 497). From this, broader, consequentialist perspective,

scholars like Fredriksson and Millimet (2007) use gasoline taxes as a proxy for the

overall environmental policies of a country, while Broz and Maliniak (2009: 2)

conceptualize gasoline taxes as being environmental, in the sense that they “…influence

the level of environmental externalities both nationally and internationally.” I adopt a

similar, consequentialist view of environmental taxation and consider energy taxes as

implicit carbon taxes for the reasons given above. To be sure, this is largely a semantic

issue, however, since the findings of the present research – in terms of the political

determinants of fossil fuel energy taxation – apply equally to “energy taxes” as they do to

“implicit carbon taxes.”116

115 The U.S. gasoline taxes “…implicitly target the same externality as the crude oil tax and are larger in magnitude, but their revenue is not assigned to an environmental fund. They therefore are not labeled as environmental taxes by statute” (Gayer and Horowitz 2006: 67). 116 The data are converted with a fuel-specific emission factor. The coefficients on both transformed (CO2) and untransformed (base unit) data are therefore identical. Though results are insensitive to this

Page 130: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

118

4.3. Why study implicit carbon taxes?

Given the apparent constraints associated with implementing a pure carbon tax, the

resulting similarity between carbon and energy taxes in terms of non-universal coverage,

a loose connection between tax rates and carbon content of fuels, and the resulting similar

effects in terms of pricing emissions of CO2, an analysis of total taxes on fossil fuels is

warranted. Indeed, if one’s purpose is to ascertain and explain cross-national differences

in the effective “price of carbon,” then it makes sense to compare countries in terms of

both “implicit” and “explicit” carbon taxes, which together constitute the energy tax

structure affecting the price of fossil fuels. In addition, if one wishes to uncover the

correlates and constraints (or barriers) to environmental taxation, then taking a deeper

and broader approach to the study of carbon taxes increases the researcher’s leverage

over various potential explanatory factors, while maintaining ample degrees of freedom.

To be sure, previous research has explicitly recognized the importance of implicit carbon

taxes for climate change policy and politics. One of the earliest studies on the implicit

carbon tax examined its role in determining cross-national variation in energy prices

across OECD countries, the economic costs of superimposing carbon taxes on top of

existing energy taxes, and the prospects for restructuring taxes on energy to achieve a

reduction in emissions of CO2 (Hoeller and Coppel 1992). This important study by

Hoeller and Coppel was one of the first to develop concrete estimates of implicit carbon

taxes, which documented the tendency for OECD countries to tax mineral oils and oil

products at a higher rate than coal and natural gas. Though limited in considering

implicit carbon taxes for a single year (1988) and by its grouping together oil and oil

products, the study broke new ground by emphasizing the importance of existing energy

taxes for broader climate policy objectives, and for advancing the argument that the

introduction of new and explicitly labeled “carbon taxes” should be accompanied by a

reform of the existing energy tax structure (Baranzini et al. 2000).

transformation, the conversion is done out of theoretical interest for interpreting tax rates in terms of the price they place on emissions.

Page 131: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

119

Building on this work, one emerging research agenda assesses the prospects for “green

tax reform,” which can be seen as the process of integrating environmental concerns in

the pre-existing tax and fiscal systems (OECD, 1997) by, for instance, converting implicit

carbon taxes to a common carbon price (in dollars per tonne of CO2 equivalent), and

uniformly applying this price to all carbon-based fuels. Recent work, for instance, has

proposed a conversion of implicit carbon taxes to a common carbon price, thereby

“rationalizing” the energy tax system for consistency with environmental and climate

policy objectives (e.g. Albrecht, 2006; Yokoyama et al. 2000). In one particularly

interesting study, Jack Mintz and Nancy Olewiler (2008) develop a strong case for

replacing the Canadian federal excise tax with a broad-based carbon tax to cover other

fuels.117 Using the existing federal excise tax on gasoline consumption in Canada, the

proposed tax amounts to roughly $42 Canadian dollars per tonne of CO2. Importantly,

the proposed tax would not impact the price of gasoline – it would rather bring other,

more heavily polluting fuels, like coal, under the same level of tax that consumers already

pay each time they fuel up at the pump – thus alleviating one potential source of political

opposition.

The existing studies on implicit carbon taxes share in common the view that considerable

progress can be made, in terms of pricing carbon and reducing GHG emissions, by

adjusting existing energy taxes. In so doing, these studies make a considerable

contribution to what appears to be a stalled political discussion on carbon taxes, which

too often ignores the important and multi-faceted role of implicit carbon taxes.118

Existing studies are limited, however, in terms of their inability to differentiate between

tax rates applied to similar fossil fuels with different carbon content – like diesel and

gasoline – as well as changes in the implicit carbon tax rate over time. For instance,

117 Mintz and Olewiler advocate a broadening of the Canadian federal excise tax on gasoline (equivalent to approximately $42/tonne of CO2) to cover other fossil fuels in an effort to reduce emissions of greenhouse gases and other air contaminants. 118 It now appears that President Obama will not be successful in passing a comprehensive climate bill in this Congress, and the Canadian government is unlikely to unilaterally impose a domestic carbon price. Yet short of an explicit carbon tax or emissions cap and permit trading system, governments in both countries could go some way in jointly undertaking a more straightforward rationalization of their respective energy tax systems.

Page 132: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

120

Mintz and Olewiler (2008: 22) base their estimates of implicit carbon taxes on the work

of Hoeller and Coppel, which does not distinguish among the unique tax rates applying to

different mineral oils and oil products. Where they do offer a more detailed analysis of

energy taxes disaggregated by fuel, Mintz and Olewiler (2008: 20) do not convert tax

data (in Canadian dollars per base unit) to a common base (e.g. CO2), thus making cross-

fuel comparison difficult.119 Finally, Mintz and Olewiler extrapolate the Hoeller and

Coppel estimates (developed for 1988) to 1997 and 2005 by adjusting the tax data for

inflation using consumer price indices, making the assumption that no change in nominal

tax rates occurred over this period.

At best, the implicit carbon price has been calculated for a particular fuel in a particular

country (e.g. Mintz and Olewiler, 2008), or for numerous countries and numerous energy

products, but for just a single year (e.g. Hoeller and Coppel, 1992; Baranzini et al. 2000).

While making important contributions, these studies are limited in terms of providing

data that can be analyzed cross-nationally and/or over time. Cross-nationally and

temporally comparable data are necessary if one were to answer the “interesting” and

relevant question of “…the factors explaining the actual tax structure and the obstacles to

its reform” (Baranzini et al. 2000: 397n11). To date, “…it seems that no country has

attempted a full-scale carbon tax audit” of the tax system (Giddens, 2009: 155). Thus, a

comprehensive analysis of the actual energy tax structure, and the correlates of and

constraints on high implicit carbon taxes, is important for several reasons, both

theoretical and practical.

4.3.1. Theoretical importance for political science

At present, economists dominate the literature on energy taxes (e.g. Andersen and Ekins,

2009; Baranzini et al. 2000). With few exceptions (e.g. Fredriksson and Millimet, 2007),

119 For instance, the difference between a 0.10 $/litre tax on a litre of gasoline in Canada, and a $75 tax on 107 kilocalories of natural gas in Denmark, is not immediately recognizable unless data are converted to a common base unit.

Page 133: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

121

this literature rarely considers important political and institutional variables in its

treatment of the energy tax and price structure (e.g. Hammar et al. 2004). While there

exists substantial potential for political science to bring fresh insights into questions

surrounding energy tax policy, political scientists have only just begun to examine

institutional factors underlying the environmental tax structure (Broz and Maliniak, 2009;

Ward and Cao, 2010). As a result, a large data set on energy taxes such as the one

collected allows the political scientist to answer some fundamental questions, including:

why do implicit carbon tax rates vary so widely across countries and across sectors?

What are the political determinants of energy taxes? Why is energy tax reform so

difficult?

Insights from political science can help shed new light on these fundamental questions.

Indeed, taxes – whether levied on environmental externalities, energy

consumption/production, or personal and corporate income – are fundamentally about

redistribution, the “essence of politics” (McGillivray, 2004). Difficulties in raising energy

taxes provide an interesting case of the politics of cost distribution (Svendsen et al. 2001),

and political science scholarship potentially has a great deal to offer in terms of

explaining and understanding cross-national differences in energy taxes. For instance,

insights from the comparative politics of electoral systems literature, and the international

political economy of taxation, have already made substantial contributions to the

understanding of how advanced capitalist states finance their welfare regimes, and why

cross-national differences exist (Kato, 2003; Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998). These

literatures hold the promise of shedding new light on the issue of energy taxation in

cross-national perspective, allowing researchers to test hypotheses and theories developed

by political scientists in other areas of the discipline. In this context, researchers can

better ascertain the generalizability of current theories of tax policy in new domains, and

further explore the extent to which insights from political science can help to explain

cross-national variance in energy taxes.

In testing hypotheses familiar to the political scientist, this type of research can also help

to refine existing theories in political science, and to formulate new hypotheses to be

Page 134: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

122

tested in future work on climate policy. It has been noted elsewhere that cross-national

variation in the implicit price of carbon “…is one of the main problems to implementing

internationally co-coordinated [climate policy]” (Baranzini et al. 2000: 397). Indeed, to

the extent that energy prices affect the relative cost of abatement across countries

(Hoeller and Coppel, 1992), the existing level of energy taxation will make it more or

less costly for countries for to implement a price on carbon domestically (i.e. existing

energy taxes may produce differential incentives for national action on climate change).

As a result, the current dependent variable in this study, implicit carbon taxes, may prove

to be an important independent variable in future analyses of climate policy. For

instance, existing energy taxes may structure the incentives and determine country

positions on whether to adopt an internationally harmonized carbon price, or agree to new

international norms and rules governing the climate (i.e. low energy tax countries may

have incentives to free ride on international agreements). Any hope at international

agreement will have to take these differential costs into account and propose an

appropriate mechanism of burden sharing. But these costs must first be determined, and

analysis of the existing energy tax structure is a crucial piece of the puzzle.

4.3.2. Practical implications for policy

In addition to its theoretical importance, the study of implicit carbon taxes is also of

practical interest as well. A better understanding of implicit carbon taxes is important for

policy-makers, for two primary reasons. First, such information can help identify the

potential scope for “green tax” or “environmental tax” reform (OECD, 1997) via, for

instance, the undertaking of a comprehensive “carbon audit” of the tax system (Giddens,

2009). Much can be learned from descriptive statistics on implicit carbon taxes in terms

of how the existing tax structure produces incentives to consume particular fuels, and

“[m]any existing taxes can be changed so as to benefit the environment” (Barde and

Braathen, 2007: 45). Data on implicit carbon taxes can help determine how consistent

Page 135: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

123

energy taxes are with overall climate policy objectives, and identify where reforms are

most urgently needed.120

Moreover, as pointed out by climate policy experts, assessing “initial” carbon taxes is an

important prerequisite for the eventual implementation of an explicit carbon price, at both

the domestic and international level (Gupta et al. 2007: 756). For instance, Nordhaus

(2007: 40) responding to Victor (2001: 86) stresses the need to measure “net carbon

taxes,” that is, the size of a carbon tax (proposal) relative to pre-existing fiscal policies

like taxes and subsidies affecting the price of fossil fuels. Collecting energy tax data and

estimating the corresponding implicit tax on carbon is an important part of such an

endeavor, providing policy-makers with crucial information for deciding on how to

account for initial taxes in the design of a carbon tax (c.f. Yokoyama et al. 2000).

Information on implicit tax levels is also important for efforts to internationally

harmonize carbon taxes as well. As Nordhaus (2007: 42) points out, given the disparity

in energy taxes between some North American countries and those in Europe (discussed

below), “…it would make no economic sense to require Europe to add even higher

carbon taxes on top of its existing ones before other countries impose even modest carbon

taxes.”121

Second, understanding the current energy tax structure can help determine what level of a

carbon tax is needed, if one is to be implemented. For instance, key questions for

governments considering a carbon tax concerns the costs (and benefits) it will impose on

the economy, and the level at which it should be set. Information on implicit carbon

taxes can thus feed into the estimation of the marginal cost of abating an additional unit

120 As argued in the literature, governments would benefit from exploring the potential for integrating environmental considerations in their fiscal system (OECD, 1997; OECD 2001). Such coordination would help to increase the overall coherence of the tax system with other environmental, economic and fiscal objectives. 121 A first step is to better understand the structure of the tax system, and how it relates to the economic and environmental objectives of the state. For instance, a carbon-tax audit, as advocated by Giddens (2009), would allow for a better understanding of how the existing tax structure creates incentives to over-consume particular fuels, and under-consume other, more climate-friendly alternatives. Such an audit would require an analysis of the tax system in terms of how the current tax structure affects, for instance, the price of emissions of CO2. The present research provides a rich source of data for such an audit.

Page 136: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

124

of CO2, as well as the design of a carbon tax. While many economic studies examine the

so called “tax-interaction effect” (Goulder 1998; Goulder et al. 1999), and the prospects

for a “double-dividend” (Bovenberg, 1999; De Mooij, 2000; Bento and Jacobsen, 2007),

relatively less attention has been paid to the important question of how existing energy

taxes are to be accounted for in international agreements and domestic reform (Nordhaus,

2007).122

It is well-known that the marginal cost of abatement differs substantially across countries

and over time (Zhang and Baranzini, 2004: 509), and that the marginal cost of abating

CO2 emissions is a function of the availability and rate of development of non-carbon

fuels, the flexibility of an economy, and the use of revenue derived from price

instruments like a carbon tax or an auctioned emissions permit trading system (Ekins and

Barker, 2001: 369). In addition to such factors, OECD models demonstrate that:

…the economic cost of a carbon-tax [or climate] policy and its effectiveness in terms of abatement reduction depends importantly on the existing level of energy prices […] Countries with high energy prices will require larger carbon taxes [or a larger carbon price] than low energy-price nations to achieve a certain degree of abatement (Hoeller and Coppel, 1992: 186).

Existing energy prices thus play an important role in determining the cost of abating

emissions of CO2, and presumably in the aggressiveness and timing of climate policy as

well. As a result, “[i]t is relevant, therefore, to analyse what factors explain the large

difference in energy prices per tonne of carbon across countries (Hoeller and Coppel,

1992: 186, emphasis added). And a key determinant of energy prices is the energy tax

applied to different fuels.

To see the importance of energy taxes in energy prices, and thus for the cost of abating

CO2, consider the relationship between prices and taxes for gasoline (Figure 4.3.2.1.).

122 While the tax-interaction effect is concerned with the interaction between an environmental tax and pre-existing factor taxes on land, labour and capital, the “double-dividend” adds consideration of how revenues are used. Both consider the optimal design of environmental taxes on efficiency grounds, but generally do not consider distributional impacts of environmental taxes and their interaction with pre-existing energy taxes in their analysis.

Page 137: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Figure 4.3.2.1: Gasoline price and tax differentials,(2008)

Source: IEA (2009a) As can be seen in Figure 4.3.2.

compared to differences in energy taxes (red). For instance, the tax component

differential between the U.S. and U.K. ($1.22/litre) is over 30 times larger than the pre

tax price differential ($0.03/litre). In fact, closer analysis suggests that cross

$0.00 $0.50

MXCUSACANAUSNZLGRCJPN

SWZSPACZELUX

HUNIRESVKPOLKORAUTSWE

FINITA

DENPORGERFRAGBRBELNETNOR

: Gasoline price and tax differentials, Unleaded Gasoline, in current USD

4.3.2.1, the pre-tax price differential (in blue) is small when

compared to differences in energy taxes (red). For instance, the tax component

differential between the U.S. and U.K. ($1.22/litre) is over 30 times larger than the pre

/litre). In fact, closer analysis suggests that cross

$1.00 $1.50 $2.00 $2.50

USD/litre

Ex-

Tax Component

125

in current USD

tax price differential (in blue) is small when

compared to differences in energy taxes (red). For instance, the tax component

differential between the U.S. and U.K. ($1.22/litre) is over 30 times larger than the pre-

/litre). In fact, closer analysis suggests that cross-national

-tax Price

Tax Component

Page 138: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

126

differences in gasoline pump prices are largely attributable to differences in rates of

energy taxation (Figure 4.3.2.2).

Figure 4.3.2.2: Total Gasoline Price by Tax Rate in current USD/L (2008)

As can be seen in Figure 4.3.2.2, there is a near perfect correlation (Pearson’s r=0.975)

between the price of gasoline and the corresponding tax rate. Indeed, much of the cross-

national variance in total gasoline prices (i.e. ex-tax price plus tax component) is

explained by tax differentials (R-square =0.95). If, as suggested by Hoeller and Coppel

(1992), a better understanding of energy prices, and factors affecting energy prices, is

desirable (for determining such things as the marginal cost of abatement, level of a

carbon tax, or negotiating an international burden sharing agreement), then a

comprehensive understanding of the existing tax structure, and its political determinants,

is required.

Page 139: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

127

4.4. Estimating implicit carbon taxes

In order to get a better sense of the energy tax structure, data on fossil fuel tax rates from

the International Energy Agency (IEA) were collected over the period 1978-2006. From

these data, systematic estimates of implicit carbon taxes in 29 OECD countries were

estimated. I develop this estimate of the “implicit carbon tax,” defined as the sum total

of all taxes (i.e. excise + VAT + specialized taxes, per unit) levied on the most commonly

used fossil fuels. Because VAT is refunded to industry in all countries, estimates of the

effective implicit tax rate on fossil fuels used for industrial purposes do not include

VAT.123 All calculations are based on energy price and tax data published by the

International Energy Agency (IEA)’s quarterly publication, Energy Prices and Taxes

(various issues).124 The data cover the following fuels and sectors:

1) Coal i. Industry and Household data (combined due to under-reporting)

2) Heavy fuel oil (HFO)

i. Industrial use (HFO is only used for industrial purposes)

3) Light fuel oil (LFO) i. Industrial use ii. Household use

123 Aggregating different taxes, like VAT and excise, may be seen to introduce a certain degree of “noise” in the measure. Indeed, the politics driving VAT and excise taxes are potentially quite different. Nevertheless, I have opted to combine VAT and excise where applicable (i.e. where VAT is not refunded), and aggregate the estimate of the effective implicit carbon tax, for an important substantive reason. I’m interested in knowing what the energy tax structure as a whole looks like, and in particular, what the level of taxes paid on carbon based fuels is (i.e. what is the implicit tax/price on carbon). Aggregation is therefore necessary. In addition, I exclude VAT when it is refunded (i.e. in the case of industry). So, in the case of industry, only excise is examined, and interested readers can compare the results for taxes applied to industry versus taxes applied to households if there is concern over including VAT. It should be stressed that the decision to not include VAT in estimates of the implicit tax on industry was done for a substantive reason (business is refunded VAT, so the effective tax rate is only the excise), and not out of a methodological concern for the validity of the measure. 124 The IEA has developed a standardized protocol for collecting and aggregating yearly energy price and tax data. To maintain consistency, no attempt was made to fill missing data with that obtained from national statistical agencies.

Page 140: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

128

4) Diesel i. Commercial use (industry) ii. Non-commercial use (private transportation)

5) Gasoline

i. Household use (IEA data does not differentiate across sectors)

6) Natural gas i. Industrial use ii. Household use

For fuels commonly used for industrial and residential purposes, the data capture

differences in tax rates applied across sectors of the economy (e.g. industry vs. household

use of light fuel oil), allowing for an analysis of the tax incidence within countries.

Although data for the tax on fossil fuels used in electricity generation are also available

(e.g. coal and heavy fuel oil), I do not consider such tax rates in this analysis, since

electricity is also taxed downstream, raising complicated issues of dual taxation.

Moreover, the electricity fuel mix varies greatly from country to country (and even within

regions of a single country) as well as over time, making it very difficult to consistently

and reliably capture the CO2 content of electricity consumption across countries and over

time.

Original data were obtained from various volumes of the IEA’s quarterly publication,

Energy Prices and Taxes. A sample table from which the data are drawn appears below.

Table 4.4.1: Tax rates on Unleaded Gasoline in Canada (in Canadian dollars)

Regular Unleaded (92 RON) Gasoline (per litre)

X-Tax Price Excise Tax GST Total Tax Total Price 2003 0.437 0.252 0.048 0.300 0.737 2004 0.508 0.254 0.053 0.307 0.815 2005 0.612 0.254 0.060 0.314 0.926 2006 0.661 0.260 0.064 0.324 0.985 Source: IEA (2008)

Page 141: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

129

Table 4.4.2: Tax rates on Natural Gas in Switzerland (in Swiss Francs)

Natural Gas for Households (per 107 kilocalories GCV)

X-Tax Price Excise Tax GST Total Tax Total Price 2003 699.4 3.8 53.4 57.2 756.6 2004 704.2 3.8 53.8 57.6 761.8 2005 773.0 3.7 59.0 62.7 835.7 2006 887.1 4.3 67.7 72.0 959.1 Source: IEA (2008) These data are yearly averages calculated by the IEA and based on statistics collected

from national sources, expressed in terms of national currency, in this case, Canadian

dollars and Swiss Francs. The fact that these data are expressed in units of national

currency makes direct cross-national comparison difficult, unless market exchange rates

are used to convert to a common currency, like U.S. dollars, Euros, or international

dollars at purchasing power parity (PPP). Moreover, the data are expressed in base units

(e.g. litres, tonnes, kilocalories), which are not directly comparable. For instance, the

difference between a 0.324$ tax on one litre of gasoline in Canada, and a 72$ tax on 107

kilocalories of natural gas is difficult to grasp, given the different units of measurement

used by the IEA to quantify different types of energy products. In order to make the data

comparable across countries and across fuels, a common metric is needed, and the data

need to be transformed.

If one is interested in the relationship between the structure of energy taxes in a given

country and its implications for climate policy, it makes sense to transform the data in

Tables 4.4.1 and 4.4.2 into the equivalent tax per tonne of CO2. Such a conversion

allows for a more intuitive comparison of tax rates across fuels, in terms of a common

base unit, carbon dioxide. The conversion factors used for this purpose are derived from

the Revised 1996 IPCC Guidelines for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories, the most

authoritative source for GHG emissions accounting. Additional data, like country-

specific Net Calorific Values (NCV) for fuels, were also used in the calculations from

mass to volume, ensuring that the emission factors are the most accurate available (IEA,

Page 142: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

130

2008). The final emission factors used in the transformation to implicit carbon tax rates

are summarized in Table 4.4.3.125

Table 4.4.3. Emission factors Emission Factor Units Coal126 2.77 tCO2/tonne Heavy fuel oil127 2.955 tCO2/kilolitre Light fuel oil 2.642 tCO2/kilolitre Diesel 0.00269 tCO2/litre Gasoline 0.00232 tCO2/litre Natural gas 2.34 tCO2/107kilocalories (GCV) Source: IPCC (1996) and IEA (2008a) The above emission factors are used to convert tax data into the equivalent tax per tonne

of carbon dioxide, making the tax data comparable across fuels. In order to estimate the

implicit carbon tax on different fossil fuels across countries, converting tax rates to USD

(or PPP) on emissions of carbon dioxide makes the most sense, allowing for a

comparison of tax rates across fuels and across countries.128 Data for this purpose are

drawn from the Penn World Tables 6.3 (Heston, Summers and Aten, 2009). Moreover,

when making comparisons over time, I use inflation-adjusted data, using country-specific

consumer price indices for energy goods. These data are taken from the OECD’s Main

Economic Indicators (OECD 2009) Price Indices (base year 2000=100).129

125 For a detailed discussion of emission factors and the conversion of tax data, refer to the Appendices 2 and 3. 126 For coal, an emission factor for bituminous is used. Bituminous coal is the most commonly consumed type of coal in the OECD. 127 If converted to tCO2/tonne, the emission factor for HFO is 3.078. It is higher than the emission factor for coal due to the fact that HFO is a denser form of energy. Conversely, on an energy unit basis, which is the more common way to measure carbon content, coal is the dirtiest fuel, containing more carbon per TJ. On a per energy unit basis, coal is “dirtier” because more tonnes of coal must be burned in order to get the same amount of energy as from burning a tonne of HFO. For further details, please consult Appendix 1. 128 Different options for standardizing the IEA tax data were also considered. Please refer to the appendices for a more complete discussion. 129 This approach involves first standardizing tax rates in U.S. dollars (or PPP), using exchange rates (Heston, Summers and Aten, 2009), then deflating by country-specific consumer prices, if across-time comparisons are being made (OECD, 2009). Next, standardized tax rates (in current or constant USD/base unit) are divided by corresponding emission factors for each type of fuel (IPCC, 1996), in order to transform the data from a “tax per unit” to a “tax per tonne” of CO2. Refer to Appendix 2 for a detailed methodology of the tax data transformation.

Page 143: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

131

The result of these transformations is an estimate of the implicit tax rate on a particular

fossil fuel, by year and by country, expressed in terms of US dollars per tonne of carbon

dioxide emitted. To guard against the influence of exchange rates, I compare results

across models in Chapter 5 using data converted to USD and Purchasing Power Parity.

When making comparisons across time, data are adjusted for inflation in real prices. The

resulting measure allows for meaningful comparison of implicit carbon tax rates across

countries, across fuels, across sectors, and over time. And while this approach is prone to

the possibility that estimates will be sensitive to fluctuating exchange rates,130 such a

conversion is standard practice (OECD, 2010), appears less harmful than alternatives

(discussed in Appendix 2), and provides several advantages.

First, converting tax rates into constant (2000) US dollars facilitates meaningful

comparison across countries, and over time. Converting to US dollars makes the data

meaningful across countries because, since the Second World War, the US dollar has

served as the international currency and thus provides a common frame of reference.

Regression results using data converted to USD can also be checked against results in

PPP for robustness.131 Once converted to USD, the data are also deflated according to

country-specific national consumer price data for energy (OECD 2009) in order to

facilitate comparisons of real tax rates over time.132 Where CPI data for energy products

is not available, I use the general CPI for all goods.133

130 It should be noted that some country differentials between national end-use prices and taxes expressed in US dollars will, to some extent, be influenced by exchange rates, which are determined by market forces (IEA, 2008: 48). In order to guard against the potential bias created by conversion to USD, I include the exchange rate as a control variable in regressions where tax data are reported in USD. Moreover, I compare results across models converting to USD and PPP as a check for robustness. 131 The OECD (2010) suggests using multiple base currencies as a check against bias created by market exchange rates. Comparing results across models using USD and PPP conversions is thus an important robustness check. In addition, though US dollars are more meaningful for interpretation, the rational for using PPPs is to obtain rates of currency conversion that eliminate differences between countries while also permitting volume comparisons (Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003). 132 I first convert to USD, then adjust for inflation using country-specific CPI. 133 The Consumer Price Index for energy goods (OECD 2009) contains missing data in the following countries: Czech Republic (1991-1995); Greece (1978-1988); Hungary (1978-1989); South Korea (1978-1989); Mexico (1978-1979); Poland (1978-1994); Portugal (1978-1990); Slovak Republic (1978-1994); and Turkey (1978-1993). In these countries, tax data are inflation-adjusted using the general CPI – all goods, to avoid breaks in the CPI series. In all other countries, including Norway where one data point is missing (1978), the more energy-specific CPI measure is used.

Page 144: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

132

Second, given the primary interest in examining taxes on energy products as they pertain

to fossil fuel use and the associated emissions of carbon dioxide, converting rates to

tonnes of CO2 allows for direct comparison of taxes across different fuel types, according

to the GHG abatement incentives they embody. Expressing tax rates in terms of tonnes of

CO2, rather than base unit, is much more intuitive and facilitates comparison of tax rates

across fuels, sectors and countries. It also allows for some leverage on the question of

how well existing energy tax structures reflect the environmental harm of different fuels.

4.5. Descriptive Analysis

Table 4.5 summarizes estimates of the implicit carbon tax across different fossil fuels in

29 countries in the OECD. As explained in section 4.4, these estimates were derived

from my own calculations, which adjusted IEA tax data in USD with country-specific

consumer price indices for energy products, then divided by emission coefficients that

were developed consistent with the Revised 1996 Guidelines for National Greenhouse

Gas Inventories. The result is a tax rate on a given fuel, in constant (2000) USD, per

tonne of CO2 emitted, which allows for comparison across fuels. Unless otherwise

indicated, all data are reported in constant (2000) USD per tonne of CO2. For illustrative

purposes, the data in table 4.5 refer to the sector-specific implicit tax on steam coal

(industry),134 heavy fuel oil (industry),135 light fuel oil (households),136 diesel (non-

134 Steam coal is used primarily by industry and for generating electricity, though it is also used by households in parts of Europe as well. Steam coal was not used by industry in Mexico over the time period analyzed here. Coking coal was used instead. 135 Heavy fuel oil is primarily used for industrial purposes and electricity generation. The IEA data distinguishes between two types of heavy fuel oil – high sulphur fuel oil and low sulphur fuel oil. Both are in fact “heavy fuel oil,” i.e. residual fuel (No.’s 5 and 6) that are left over from crude after gasoline and the distillate fuel oils are extracted through distillation. Increasing concern with sulphur emissions led many to phase out high sulphur fuel oil used by industry and in electricity generation in the 1990s. My data refer to high sulphur fuel oil, which contains the most observations. However, for years where tax rates on high sulphur fuel oil are not available (i.e. for many countries post-1990s), I impute tax rates on light sulphur fuel oil. Given the similar carbon content in both types, this imputation is justified. Moreover, care was taken to ensure that imputations did not cause artificial jumps in the tax data. For instance, between 1995 and 1998, Austria taxed both types of heavy fuel oil equally, so the imputations are reasonable. Therefore, where tax rates between the two are similar, an imputation is made. In cases where the tax rates vary widely (e.g. Luxembourg), no imputation is made to avoid creating an artificial changes in the series.

Page 145: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

133

commercial use),137 gasoline138 (non-commercial use),139 and natural gas (household

use).140

In most cases, data are for 2006. Otherwise, data are for the most recent year

available.141 Since not all data are drawn from the same year, tax rates in Table 4.5 are

reported in constant (2000) USD per tonne of CO2. A “.” indicates the data are not

available, while “n/a” indicates the data are not applicable.142

Finally, I compare results using the imputed data (USD) with non-imputed data (PPP) as a check for robustness. 136 These data are tax rates on light fuel oil for household use. The equivalent of light fuel oil is Kerosene in Japan and Korea. Mexico is the only country in table 4.4 for which the data refer to the tax imposed on industry, due to a lack of data for that country. This imputation in Table 4.4 is for illustrative purposes only. Later empirical analyses of tax rates on light fuel oil (Chapter 5) make no such cross-sector imputations, since tax rates between the two sectors tend to be quite different. 137 The Canadian tax rate is for commercial use of diesel. All others refer to private non-commercial use. 138 Since fuel grades bought and sold vary across countries, tax rates on the most commonly reported fuel grade are described and analyzed in this dissertation. From a climate perspective, this mixing of fuel grades is not problematic, as all fuel grades are roughly equal in carbon content. The data refer to regular unleaded 91 RON (Research Octane Number) for Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Japan, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, and the USA; mid-grade unleaded 95 RON for all others. 139 The IEA tax data on gasoline are reported only for private non-commercial use. No cross-sector comparisons are therefore possible on tax rates for gasoline. 140 All data refer to tax rates on household use of natural gas. Taxes on both sectors are analyzed separately in Chapter 5. 141 For coal, Australia (1989), Belgium (1991), Czech Republic (2002), France (2003), Germany (1994), Hungary (1998), the Netherlands (1991), New Zealand (1984), Portugal (2003), and Slovak Republic (1999) are the latest data available. For heavy fuel oil, Australia (1983), Greece (2005), Italy (2002), Luxembourg (1994), Portugal (2002) are latest available. For light fuel oil, Australia (1983), Greece (2005), Hungary (1994), New Zealand (1986) are the latest available. Due to data constraints, the Mexican tax rate on light fuel oil refers to the tax levied on industry use, while all others refer to households. For diesel, Greece (2005) is the latest available. The Canadian tax on diesel is for commercial purposes, while all others are for private household use. For gasoline, Greece (2005) is the latest available. For natural gas, Belgium (2000), Denmark (2005), Germany (2000), Greece (2005), Italy (1999), Japan (2004) and Luxembourg (2005) are the latest available. All others refer to tax rates in 2006. 142 For instance, the cell for natural gas in Norway reads “n/a,” since close to 99% of electricity consumed in that country is from hydro.

Page 146: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

134

Table 4.5: Implicit carbon tax (constant USD/tCO2) by fuel type, 2006 Coal HFO LFO Diesel Gasoline Nat.Gas Cor (carbon content) 26 21.5 19.95 19.6 19.3 14.5 (r=) Australia $0.00 $2.82 $3.20 $101.53 $115.61 . -0.62 Austria $18.42 $22.23 $85.81 $190.89 $266.08 $75.73 -0.35 Belgium $0.00 $4.92 $45.30 $194.44 $359.76 $35.82 -0.23 Canada $0.00 $8.68 $20.69 $58.77 $89.37 . -0.72 Czech Rep. $0.00 $5.92 $73.68 $209.11 $275.73 $32.34 -0.25 Denmark $6.07 $16.22 $189.88 $225.52 $355.50 $232.10 -0.68 Finland $16.91 $15.79 $74.01 $196.28 $370.34 $31.61 -0.19 France $0.00 $6.21 $63.72 $228.07 $352.58 $37.40 -0.24 Germany $0.00 $7.44 $49.27 $212.59 $329.08 $37.94 -0.24 Greece . $6.49 $95.23 $147.69 $194.79 $17.48 0.22 Hungary $0.00 $7.74 $23.52 $170.51 $226.73 $13.19 -0.19 Ireland . $4.01 $45.03 $187.93 $248.74 $33.66 0.09 Italy $0.00 $19.72 $228.01 $230.63 $342.77 $141.34 -0.50 Japan $1.02 $6.30 $11.24 $109.47 $203.95 $25.92 -0.24 S. Korea . $18.86 $86.40 $188.91 $330.59 $45.04 0.12 Luxembourg . $6.74 $23.97 $138.93 $235.96 $9.51 0.15 Mexico . $0.00 $0.00 $18.31 $29.57 $26.32 -0.65 Netherlands $2.24 $9.00 $116.16 $174.78 $335.45 $87.08 -0.38 New Zealand $0.38 $0.00 $41.79 $21.84 $123.95 $29.63 -0.34 Norway $18.95 $46.43 $91.21 $219.68 $324.89 na -0.72 Poland $0.00 $5.43 $73.69 $194.51 $253.80 $36.93 -0.27 Portugal $0.00 $7.79 $65.30 $202.10 $351.93 $17.41 -0.19 Slovak Rep. $0.00 $0.00 $18.90 $188.48 $228.61 $27.23 -0.24 Spain . $4.76 $65.21 $160.44 $235.09 $36.11 0.09 Sweden $16.26 $113.38 $192.13 $208.69 $299.36 . -0.92 Switzerland $0.00 $0.88 $16.20 $223.58 $249.00 $20.70 -0.21 Turkey $0.76 $12.66 $81.96 $87.07 $153.62 $7.73 -0.19 UK $2.32 $27.97 $43.11 $313.58 $360.03 $9.78 -0.16 USA $0.00 $3.47 $4.87 $28.78 $28.62 . -0.69 OECD avg $3.62 $13.51 $66.53 $166.66 $250.74 $44.50 -0.29 Source: adapted from IEA Energy Prices & Taxes (various editions); and Ministry of Housing, Spatial Planning and Environment

(Netherlands).

As can be seen in Table 4.5, the implicit tax on carbon varies widely across fuels

(horizontally) and across countries (vertically). Closer analysis reveals clear patterns in

the way OECD countries tax on fossil fuels, as well as less obvious, non-trivial variance

in the way different countries tax the same fuels.

Page 147: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

135

4.5.1. Differences across fuels

At one level, there are substantial within country differences in terms of how individual

fuels are taxed. For illustrative purposes, tax rates in Table 4.5 are arranged from most to

least polluting fuels in descending order (i.e. coal to natural gas), accompanied by

estimates of each fuel’s corresponding carbon content (in Teragrams of carbon per

quadrillion Btu).143 Reading across the rows in Table 4.5, it is clear that, generally

speaking, the more carbon intensive a fuel (i.e. carbon content), the lower the tax rate.

For instance, with the highest carbon level per quadrillion Btu, coal is the most carbon

intensive, yet least taxed fuel. On the other hand, relatively less carbon-intensive fuels

used in transport, tend to bear the highest implicit carbon tax in the OECD. Between the

two motor fuels, and consistent with this pattern, all OECD countries (save the United

States) tax diesel at a lower rate than unleaded gasoline, on a per tonne of CO2 basis,

despite the fact that diesel is more polluting. While diesel vehicles may cause lower CO2

emissions per kilometer driven (due to greater efficiency), this tax trend is concerning

from the perspective of climate change, as such fuel economy might actually encourage

additional consumption through the so-called “rebound effect,” also known as “Jevon’s

paradox” (OECD, 2001: 57; Jaccard and Bataille, 2000; Alcott, 2005).144

Further illustrating the tendency for more carbon-intensive fuels to be least taxed, the last

column of Table 4.5 reports Pearson’s correlation coefficient between implicit carbon

taxes for different fossil fuels and their corresponding carbon content. In all but 5 of 29

cases, implicit carbon taxes are inversely related to the carbon content of fossil fuels. In

some cases (e.g. Australia, Canada, Denmark, Mexico, Norway, Sweden, and the USA),

the correlation is rather large (i.e. > |0.6|), meaning that lower tax rates tend to be strongly

143 Carbon content of figures are taken from Table A-34: Carbon Content Coefficients (Tg Carbon/QBtu) in EIA Annex B “Method for Estimating the Carbon Content of Fuels” (B-2 Inventory of U.S. Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Sinks: 1990-2001), p.A-47. 144 Perhaps the trucking industry, which relies on diesel fuel, may explain this difference, as the interests of this industry are more concentrated than the diffuse interests of consumers of gasoline. In their work on the Dutch policy experience with green tax reform, Vermeend and der vaart (1998: 80) discuss the role of the trucking industry in keeping diesel fuel taxes relatively low.

Page 148: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

136

associated with higher carbon content fuels in these countries.145 Most others fall within

the range of -0.2 to -0.59. While the implicit tax rate is positively correlated with carbon

content in five countries (Greece, Ireland, South Korea, Luxembourg and Spain), these

countries are exceptions to the general pattern, and the correlations are comparatively

weak (ranging from 0.09 to 0.22). Overall, it is clear from Table 4.4 that the tax structure

in OECD countries is biased in favour of fuels that are more carbon intensive. And

surprisingly, this pattern is equally apparent in countries with a carbon tax (e.g. Sweden

r = -0.92) as it is in non-carbon tax countries (e.g. USA r = -0.69). Table 4.5.1 and Figure

4.5.1 summarize this general trend for the OECD countries as a whole.

Table 4.5.1: Average implicit carbon taxes across OECD in 2006, constant USD/tCO2

Average Tax per t/CO2

Carbon Content Tg Carbon/QBtu

Coal $3.62 26 HFO $13.51 21.5 LFO $66.53 19.95 Diesel $166.66 19.6 Gasoline $250.74 19.3 Natural Gas $44.50 14.5 Source: adapted from IEA Energy Prices & Taxes (various editions)

r=-0.29

Average implicit carbon taxes for each fuel are reported in Table 4.5.1 and Figure 4.5.1.

The data are averaged across all 29 OECD countries for which data are available, for six

fossil fuels, in constant (2000) USD, for year 2006. Consistent with what is often the case

within countries, the general pattern is for more carbon intensive fuels like coal, to be

least taxed.

145 Such correlations are largely the result of extremely low tax rates on coal as compared to less carbon intensive fuels like motor fuels and natural gas.

Page 149: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

137

Figure 4.5.1: Average implicit carbon taxes (USD/tCO2) by fuel, OECD 2006

Source: adapted from IEA Energy Prices & Taxes (various editions)

With the exception of natural gas, Table 4.5.1 and Figure 4.5.1 illustrate how implicit

carbon taxes are inversely related to the carbon content of fossil fuels across the OECD.

In this respect, implicit carbon taxes, summarized in Tables 4.5 and 4.5.1, are similar to

the explicit carbon taxes described in Chapter 3.

4.5.2. Differences across sectors

In addition, the implicit carbon tax rate demonstrates a further similarity to what was

found in the analysis of carbon taxation (Chapter 3). As is the case with explicit carbon

taxes, the tax burden associated with implicit carbon levies tends to fall

disproportionately onto the household and transport sectors (c.f. Barde and Braathen,

2007: 48 & 58). Indeed, transportation fuels (diesel and gasoline) are consistently the

highest taxed fuels in all countries. With the notable exceptions of the USA, Canada, and

Mexico, motor fuel taxes in 2006 correspond to an equivalent carbon tax of over $100

USD/tonne of CO2. Ironically, the “carbon taxes” discussed in Chapter 3, levied with the

Page 150: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

138

explicit purpose of reducing GHG emissions, are comparatively smaller in magnitude.

The implicit carbon tax rate on motor fuels often exceeds $200 USD/tonne of CO2, while

taxes of over $300 USD/tonne of carbon dioxide are not uncommon.

In addition, households tend to pay much more in taxes on energy products than does

industry. This difference can be seen when comparing tax rates on heavy fuel oil (HFO)

used by industry, and light fuel oil (LFO) used for household purposes, like heating. In

most cases, the tax on LFO is substantially larger than the tax on HFO (e.g. $187.22 to

$51.93 in Sweden), despite the fact the HFO is more carbon intensive and polluting

(Table 4.5).146 Such differences are also present in tax rates on different uses of the same

fuel (Figure 4.5.2).

Figure 4.5.2: Mean tax rate across sectors in constant (2000) USD/tCO2

Source: adapted from IEA Energy Prices & Taxes (various volumes)

Figure 4.5.2 shows the mean tax rate on three fuels for which IEA data provide distinct

tax rates across the industrial and household sectors. The data represent the implicit

carbon tax rate by sector, and by fuel, averaged across all OECD countries for which data

146 The LFO data in Table 4.5 are for tax rates on households, allowing for a comparison between industry and household use of heavy and light fuel oil. The IEA tax data further distinguishes LFO for industry and household use. Comparing tax rates between industrial and household use of LFO reveals the same story – households face a much larger tax burden.

Mean tax rate across sectors in constant (2000) USD/tCO2

$32.79

$58.25

$113.56

$156.21

$2.11

$27.14

$0$20$40$60$80

$100$120$140$160$180

ind hh ind hh ind hh

light fuel oil diesel natural gas

Page 151: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

139

are available, over the period 1978-2006. As can be seen, households tend to pay much

higher energy taxes than industry for use of the same fuels. For light fuel oil, industry

tends to pay, on average, about $25 USD less in taxes than households, and this

difference is statistically significant.147 For diesel, the difference in mean tax is $42.65

USD per tonne of CO2, while industry pays about $25.03 less than households for natural

gas, on a per tonne of CO2 basis. In each case, the mean difference in the implicit carbon

tax paid by industry and households is statistically significant at a level of P<0.00005.148

These findings corroborate with other studies that show a tendency for the transport and

household sectors to pay a higher tax, though such studies usually do not examine

differences between distinct tax rates paid by industry and households for the same fuels

(c.f. Barde and Braathen, 2007). In addition, the findings confirm what others sometimes

assert without empirical documentation; namely, the tendency for implicit carbon taxes to

be inversely related to carbon content, thus penalizing low carbon content fuels on a per

tonne of CO2 basis (c.f. Baranzini et al. 2000; Baron, 1997). The description of energy

taxes in Tables 4.5 and 4.5.1 offers support on both counts, and provides one of the first

empirical documentations of the way in which the energy tax structure is biased in favour

of industrial use of more carbon intensive fuels.

4.6: The Puzzle: differences in implicit carbon taxes across countries and over time

While concerning from the perspective of climate policy, the structure of energy taxes

just described is not entirely surprising. To be sure, the cross-fuel and cross-sector

differences in implicit carbon taxes are readily explained from both an economic and

political perspective. From an economic vantage point, and as Baranzini et al. (2000:

147 The difference in mean tax rates between industry and households is thus real and statistically greater than 0. The t-test further gives a 95 per cent confidence interval around values of $18.34 and $28.70 USD per tonne of carbon dioxide. 148 Both mean differences in tax rates for diesel and natural gas are statistically significant at P <0.00005. On average, industry can be expected to pay between $34.92 to $39.80 USD less on taxes per tonne of CO2 for diesel than households, while the mean difference in taxes paid for natural gas is likely to fall between $18.55 to $22.78 USD, 95 times out of 100.

Page 152: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

140

397) point out, consumers of motor fuels bear a comparatively larger tax burden because

demand for these energy products is relatively inelastic. With inelastic demand, it is

easier for governments to extract revenues from such fuels. Tax rates on motor fuels

might therefore be expected to be higher, as they constitute an important tax base for

raising revenue (about 90% of “environmentally related” tax revenue, according to the

OECD, 2001). On the other hand, the theory of public choice might also lead to the

expectation of higher tax rates on certain fuels. In the language of Olson (1965),

households constitute a large group with diffuse interests, and thus have less incentive to

mobilize against taxes, relative to small groups bearing concentrated costs. Following

this logic, it is easier for governments to impose higher tax rates on the household sector,

compared to the small, well-organized interests of energy-intensive industry, which stand

to lose much from higher energy taxes (Svendsen et al. 2001). The energy tax structure is

thus consistent with what we might expect from the economic perspective of energy

demand elasticities, and with the classic problem of collective action described by Olson

(1965). Thus, cross-fuel differences in implicit carbon taxes are not very surprising.

More puzzling, however, is the fact that energy taxes are consistently biased in favour of

more heavily polluting fuels. As documented in Table 4.5, this is true even among

countries that have taken efforts to correct environmental externalities through green tax

reforms and the imposition of explicit carbon taxes. It thus appears as though reforming

the energy tax structure for consistency with climate policy objectives is even more

difficult than initially thought. Indeed, despite a handful of cases where energy tax

reform proposals were politically successful in terms of implementation, such success

stories are limited by what is shown in Table 4.5. Energy tax reform for climate policy is

thus extremely challenging, raising the question – why is it so difficult?

In order to offer insight into this question, much can be gained from an analysis of the

cross-national differences in the way different countries tax the same fuels. Indeed, the

cross-sector and cross-fuel comparisons described in sections 4.5.1 and 4.5.2 mask

important differences at the cross-national level. As documented in the next section,

fossil fuel energy taxes vary enormously across the OECD, even among similarly situated

Page 153: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

141

(i.e. advanced, industrial capitalist) countries in the global political economy, and this is

the real puzzle. Such cross-national differences exist despite incentives to keep energy

taxes low, pressures that are common to all countries (Chapter 1). At the same time, this

variance persists despite common and increasing international and domestic pressure to

reduce dependence on increasingly scarce and environmentally harmful fossil fuels. The

fact that taxes vary so widely, and change over time, suggests that some countries have

overcome common political barriers and there may be scope for reform. In addition, an

analysis of these cross-national differences may point to important correlates of and

constraints on raising taxes affecting the price of carbon-based fuels.

4.6.1: Cross-national differences in implicit carbon taxes

Returning to the main table summarizing implicit carbon taxes in 2006, it is clear that

different countries tax the same fuels at widely different rates. Reading down the

columns in table 4.5, it is apparent that carbon is taxed at a higher rate in some countries

than others, despite that fact that, as argued in Chapter 1, there are numerous reasons to

expect energy taxes among the advanced industrial democracies to converge downward.

For instance, implicit carbon taxes on coal vary from effectively $0 in several countries

to nearly $20 USD per tonne of CO2 in Austria and Norway, and this is true despite the

fact that Austria does not have an explicit “carbon tax.”

To further illustrate the substantial cross-country differences in the way countries tax

carbon energy, Figure 4.6.1 visually depicts implicit tax rates for six fossil fuels,

arranging countries in descending order, from highest to lowest energy tax rates.

Page 154: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

142

Figure 4.6.1: Implicit carbon tax rates for selected OECD countries, 2006

Source: IEA (2009) As can be seen in Figure 4.6.1, implicit tax rates levied on the same fuels vary widely

among advanced industrial democracies in the OECD. Though some countries first

appear to be consistently high implicit carbon tax countries, this is not always the case.

For instance, Norway and Sweden tax oil products and coal relatively heavily. Italy,

Sweden and Denmark have comparably high taxes on light fuel oil. Great Britain is

consistently among the highest in taxes on motor fuels, but one of the lowest for natural

gas. Denmark and Italy have some of the largest taxes on natural gas in the OECD, but

their taxes on heavy fuel oil are closer to the OECD average. On the other hand,

Page 155: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

143

Australia, New Zealand, Canada and the United States tend to have lower implicit carbon

tax rates, though not for all fossil fuels. Thus, no single country consistently appears in

the extreme case of abnormally high carbon taxes for all fossil fuels.

Looking more closely at the transportation sector, there are large and substantial cross-

national differences in the way countries tax motor fuels, and the reasons for these

differences are not obvious. For instance, in the case of diesel, countries as similar in

their cultural, political and legal traditions as Canada ($58.77 USD per tonne of CO2) and

Great Britain ($313 USD per tonne of CO2) lie at opposite ends of the implicit carbon tax

spectrum. In fact, the tax differential between the two countries is larger than 80 per

cent, and a carbon tax of over $200 USD per tonne of CO2 would be required in order to

harmonize the implicit carbon tax rate on diesel in Canada with that in the UK. More

broadly, these large differences in fossil fuel taxation persist even among countries at

similar levels of economic development. The implicit carbon tax on diesel in Norway

(real per capita GDP $46,729.19) is roughly seven times as large as that in the United

States (real per capita GDP $42,683) in 2006. Similarly, the implicit carbon tax on diesel

in Italy (real per capita GDP $28,410.67) is over ten times that which existed in New

Zealand (real per capita GDP $24,817.14) that same year. These large and non-trivial

differences among similarly situated countries in the OECD suggest that some countries

are more willing and able to overcome domestic barriers and incentives to keep taxes

low, and impose higher rates of taxation on carbon-based fuels.

4.6.2: Implicit carbon taxes over time

In addition to the large tax differentials across countries, temporal differences in implicit

carbon tax rates exist within countries. Indeed, some governments have increased tax

rates on certain fossil fuels over time, and such policy change can be seen in the

evolution of nominal tax rates. By examining temporal changes in the nominal tax rate on

different fossil fuels within countries, we can identify policy shifts, which provide

important windows through which insights regarding the conditions under which raising

Page 156: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

144

carbon taxes might be politically possible can be gleaned. For instance, despite common

pressures to keep taxes on industrial inputs low (for reasons of industrial

competitiveness), some countries have increased implicit tax rates over time. To take the

“tough case” of coal, apparently the most difficult fuel to tax, there are some cases in

which countries have been able and willing to increase implicit carbon taxes.

Figure 4.6.2: Implicit carbon taxes on coal, in selected OECD countries

Source: IEA 2009 Figure 4.6.2 documents the “tough case” of changing tax policy affecting the price of

coal, consistently the least taxed fuel across OECD countries. The data are in national

currency, which allows for a more accurate picture of tax policy change,149 but are

therefore not directly comparable across countries. For instance, the Swedish and

Norwegian taxes seem relatively large in comparison to Finland because the tax data are

149 The idea is to illustrate change in policy over time (i.e. a change in the nominal tax rate). Data are left in national currency to avoid year to year fluctuations caused by movements in exchange rates.

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Evolution in implicit carbon tax on steam coalin national currency/tCO2

Canada Denmark Finland Norway Sweden UK USA

Page 157: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

145

expressed in Swedish and Norwegian Crowns, as compared to Euros (Finland).

Moreover, the data are nominal, and thus provide no indication of the “real” tax rate, but

they do present a clear picture of when and by how much tax rates on coal changed.150

What is to be taken from the illustration is that tax policy changes have occurred in some

countries where they have decided to unilaterally increase the price of, in this case coal,

despite the kinds of pressures and constraints commonly thought to impair the ability of

countries to increase taxes on fossil fuels. Thus, contrary to pessimistic views, it is

possible to increase taxes on fossil fuels, even coal, and such temporal differences in

energy taxes provides analysts with a window to examine the conditions under which

such increases were politically possible.

4.6.3: The real puzzle

Thus, the real puzzle, and the area in which one can garner the most empirical traction

and gain the most theoretical insight, is to assess the substantial cross-national and within

country temporal variation that exists in the way advanced capitalist democracies in the

OECD tax fossil fuels. Analysis of cross-national differences and within country tax

policy change can provide insight into the barriers to energy tax reform, and help shed

light onto the conditions under which we may reasonably expect higher energy taxes to

be politically possible. Indeed, the large and substantial cross-national differences in fuel

tax policy, and within country changes over time, suggest that some types of political

conditions are relatively more conducive to higher rates of carbon taxation. These cross-

national and cross-time differences can be exploited in order to uncover some of the

correlates of, and constraints on, energy tax reform.

Ultimately, the goal of this research is to work toward answering the broader, more

fundamental questions of: what are the barriers to energy tax reform? Why is energy tax

reform so difficult? Why have some countries been able to increase taxes on fossil fuels?

What kind of politics is required for change in the energy tax structure, and under what 150 Note: though an effort was made to account for rebates and exemptions, data do not necessarily reflect the exemptions put in place to protect some industry. Moreover, it should be noted that the years in the graph (5 year interval scale) do not necessarily correspond to the specific year of tax policy changes.

Page 158: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

146

conditions might one expect to see it happen in the future? In order to answer these

questions, Chapter 5 tests several hypotheses commonly found in the international and

comparative politics literatures, and documents empirical evidence to support the claim

that political institutions matter for rates of energy-energy and environmental taxation.

Page 159: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

147

Chapter 5: Empirical analysis

5. Empirical analysis: the political economy of taxing fossil fuels

As demonstrated in Chapter 4, implicit carbon taxes vary considerably across countries in

the OECD, and the reasons for such differences are not immediately obvious. No country

imposes consistently high or low tax rates on all fossil fuels, and substantial differences

exist even among similarly situated countries. For instance, countries as similar in their

cultural, legal and political institutions as Canada and Great Britain lie at opposite ends of

the implicit carbon tax spectrum. Even countries as similar as Canada and the United

States, both among the lightest taxers of energy, tax the same fuels at substantially

different rates. More broadly, countries at similar levels of economic development vary

considerably in the way they tax fossil fuels and associated emissions of carbon dioxide.

These differences are even found among countries that have successfully implemented an

explicit carbon tax, where surprisingly, more carbon-intensive energy continues to be

taxed at comparatively lower rates.

These cross-national differences in rates of carbon energy taxation invite a political

analysis to explain why the OECD’s most advanced industrial economies tax the same

fuels at widely different rates. In addition, the fact that implicit carbon tax rates continue

to be inversely related to carbon content even in countries with explicit carbon taxes begs

the question of why environmental tax reform is so difficult. And instances of countries

increasing tax rates invite analysis of the temporally and contextually specific conditions

under which energy tax increases are politically possible. In order to answer these

questions, I analyze cross-national and cross-time differences in implicit carbon tax rates

levied on different fossil fuels. In analyzing each fuel discretely, key explanatory

variables can be controlled, and cross-country differences can be leveraged, allowing the

researcher to uncover the factors that are generally associated with differential rates of

carbon energy taxation.

Page 160: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

148

In what follows, this Chapter tests the theoretical argument outlined in Chapter 1 in a

series of empirical models. Considerable evidence to support the primary research

hypotheses concerning the role of electoral systems in shaping tax rates is found using

both cross-sectional and time-series cross sectional (TSCS) data, for different fossil fuels.

Given constraints of space and time, I analyze cross-national differences in 4 of the most

commonly fuels used in the OECD – industrial use of coal and heavy fuel oil; and,

household use of diesel and gasoline.

The chapter begins with a brief summary of the main argument (5.1). Next, I specify the

theoretical expectations as key primary hypotheses that will be tested (5.2). After

discussing data and methods (5.3) I examine the empirical evidence (5.4) through an

analysis of implicit carbon tax rates on fuels used by industry (coal and heavy fuel oil)

(5.5) and household use of motor fuels (diesel and gasoline) (5.6). I then summarize and

discuss results (5.7) before concluding in Chapter 6.

5.1: Argument

Building on the theoretical argument outlined in Chapter 1, this Chapter develops the

argument that proportional electoral systems facilitate the imposition of higher energy

taxes, and in particular, lead to higher rates of implicit carbon taxation in advanced

capitalist democracies. I thus expect to find higher implicit carbon taxes in countries

where PR is the primary method used to translate vote shares into seat shares.

Two causal logics underlie this expectation. First, I argue that PR systems create the

“ideological space” necessary for those parties predisposed to favour higher energy taxes

– i.e. parties of the left and green parties (which previous research has shown favour

higher rates of energy taxation) – to implement their political programs. This is due to the

well-documented fact that PR systems produce a larger number of “effective” political

parties (Duverger, 1954; Laakso and Taagepera, 1979; Lijphart, 1990) and a higher

Page 161: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

149

incidence of coalition government (Taagepera and Shugart, 1989; Strom, 1990). The key

mechanism here is the greater degree of proportionality generated by PR systems – i.e. a

more faithful allocation of seat shares relative to vote shares – which implies, inter alia,

that a) dominant parties are less likely to win a majority; b) smaller parties (e.g. greens)

or those with broader social welfare goals (e.g. left-wing social democrats) will more

easily win seats in the legislature; and, c) these smaller parties will have a greater chance

of participating in coalition government. However, opening up the ideological range in

the party system is necessary but not sufficient for explaining higher rates of energy

taxation. I argue that the impact of PR is conditional on the ideological makeup of the

legislature and on the composition of government. Electoral systems thus open the door,

so to speak, but do not by themselves explain higher rates of carbon energy taxation.

Equally important is the presence of green/left parties – who favour energy tax increases

– in the legislature or government that enable these parties to implement their preferred

policies. This enabling effect stems from these parties being in power, or because

coalition partners will have an incentive to implement green/left programs (e.g. higher

energy taxes, higher spending) in exchange for political support, or in order to gain votes.

In this perspective, higher rates of energy taxation depend on both the presence of

green/left parties in the legislature/government combined with PR systems. We should

therefore expect to see larger implicit carbon taxes when green/left parties are represented

in the legislature and in government under systems of PR.

Second, I argue that electoral systems also create electoral incentives that can shape party

preferences. One of the ways through which electoral systems shape party preferences is

via the mechanism of government accountability, which increases under disproportional

electoral systems. Indeed, governments may be held more accountable in disproportional

systems because even a small change in the vote share can lead to relatively large

changes in a party’s share of legislative seats, making governments more vulnerable to

shifts in public opinion. Rogowski and Kayser (2002) call this the seat-vote elasticity,

though they never test its effects empirically. Moreover, to the extent that disproportional

systems tend to produce single-party majority governments, voters know precisely who to

punish for unfavourable policy (Persson and Tabellini, 2008). It follows that

Page 162: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

150

disproportional systems increase transparency and government accountability, producing

an incentive for governments (and parties) to “please” voters, by for instance, not

increasing taxes. Thus, disproportional systems will tend to constrain the ability of

green/left parties to implement their political program, if this means higher energy taxes

that are politically unpopular. Power-seeking political parties know that they are more

vulnerable and accountable under majoritarian rules, and therefore will be constrained in

their ability to increase energy taxes when the seat-vote elasticity is high, as is the case in

disproportional systems.

Just as disproportional systems make governments and parties more accountable and

vulnerable, however, they also make parties and governments more responsive to small

changes in voter preferences. Indeed, while green/left parties might be constrained from

implementing their preferred tax and spending policies while in government, a rise in

support for a particular issue or issue-oriented party may very well result in the

implementation of policy consistent with this support, irrespective of which party is in

power. For instance, a sudden rise in support for green parties in disproportional systems

may lead to changes in policy, even if the green parties never actually gain power

(because of disproportional electoral results in majoritarian electoral systems). This is

due to the fact that parties competing for votes in an electoral system where the seat-vote

elasticity is high will have greater incentive to respond to the shift in popular sentiment,

in order to maximize vote gains and minimize vote losses. As a result, I expect to see a

rise in rates of implicit carbon taxation to follow a rise in popular support for green

parties, under highly disproportionate electoral systems.151

5.2: Hypotheses

The above logic can be reformulated in a series of empirically testable hypotheses. With

reference to the theory outlined above, the observable implications of the argument can

be distilled into four hypotheses, which are empirically tested in the sections that follow.

151 But a rise in the share of (cabinet) seats for greens and the left parties under disproportional systems will not lead to such an increase, since the incentive for all parties in such systems is to keep energy taxes low (H2).

Page 163: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

151

H1: The PR hypothesis: Relative to majoritarian electoral systems, countries with PR will impose higher implicit tax rates on carbon. H2: The ideological space hypothesis: Relative to majoritarian electoral systems, greater representation from parties of the left and greens will be positively associated with significantly greater implicit carbon tax rates under PR. H3: The disproportional constraints hypothesis: Relative to proportional systems, greater representation from parties of the left and greens will not be positively associated with greater implicit carbon tax rates under more disproportional systems, as these parties will be constrained in their ability to raise tax rates. H4: The electoral incentives hypothesis: Relative to more proportional systems, increasing support for green parties will lead to an increase in rates of implicit carbon taxation under more disproportional systems, as parties/governments have greater incentive to respond to mounting electoral threats where the seat-vote elasticity is high.

5.3: Data and methods

In order to test these hypotheses, I develop a series of empirical models using both cross-

sectional and time-series cross-sectional (TSCS) data. The data are drawn from various

sources, including the IEA, OECD, World Bank (World Development Indicators), Penn

World Tables 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009), the Database of Political Institutions (Keefer,

2007), the Political Parties Data Set (Swank, 2007), and the Comparative Political Data

Set (Armingeon et al. 2009). Detailed data descriptions and summary statistics are

provided below and in the data appendix.

For the purpose of the present analysis, it was decided to focus on a particular sub-set of

OECD countries; namely, the advanced, capitalist, industrialized democracies that are

commonly studied together in the CPE and IPE literatures (Becher, 2010; Garrett and

Mitchell, 2001; Holzinger et al. 2008; Iversen and Stephens, 2008; Quinn, 1997; Swank,

2006; Swank and Steinmo, 2002; Winner, 2005). The number of countries and years

examined varies by the availability of data, but typically ranges between the 18 and 22 of

the richest industrial democracies in the OECD, over the period 1978-2006. Based on

Page 164: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

152

their status as advanced industrialized democracies, and subject to data availability, the

countries in the sample include: Australia (AUS), Austria (AUT), Belgium (BEL),

Canada (CAN), Denmark (DNK), Finland (FIN), France (FRA), Germany (DEU),

Greece (GRC), Ireland (IRL), Italy (ITA), Japan (JPN), Luxembourg (LUX), the

Netherlands (NLD), New Zealand (NZL), Norway (NOR), Portugal (PRT), Spain (ESP),

Sweden (SWE), Switzerland (CHE), Great Britain (GBR) and the United States (USA).

Tax rates for all other countries described in Chapter 4 – including the Czech Republic

(CZE), South Korea (KOR), Hungary (HUN), Slovak Republic (SVK), Mexico (MEX),

Poland (POL), and Turkey (TUR) – are omitted from the empirical analysis developed in

this Chapter.152

Studying this particular sub-set of OECD countries carries with it numerous advantages

and can be justified on several grounds. First, the developed democracies included in this

analysis share a set of characteristics in common, rooted in a shared history involving a

number of similar economic transformations since the late 1970s. In addition, this group

continues to face common challenges (like financing their welfare states, renewed

concern over energy security, and addressing climate change), and share a limited range

of potential policy responses. As a result, these countries are more closely comparable,

while differences among them are of particular theoretical interest (c.f. Katzenstein,

1979).

Theoretically, the hypotheses tested in this Chapter draw from the literature on advanced

capitalist welfare states; as such, they are more applicable to these cases. Moreover,

much of the data required for testing these hypotheses are missing for the out of sample

cases, and there are substantive differences that suggest the hypotheses might not be

appropriate even if these data were available. As will be discussed in the Conclusion, the

focus on advanced capitalist countries in the OECD puts these countries front and centre.

Developed economies are the ones most commonly looked upon to provide leadership in

making the largest emission cuts to address global climate change, because of their

152 Note: country codes are based on ISO 3166.

Page 165: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

153

historical emissions and because of their available resources. Thus, a focus on these

countries is pertinent, and pushes the present analysis to consider the conditions under

which the advanced OECD countries might take a lead role in making the GHG

reductions necessary to mitigate the adverse implications of climate change.

Finally, the restricted sample is also justified on methodological grounds as well.

Looking at only a subset of advanced capitalist OECD democracies allows the researcher

to control for level of economic development, thus holding national wealth effects and

regime type relatively constant. According to the literature on the Environmental

Kuznet’s curve, which postulates an inverted U shape function between economic

development and pollution, such control is important (Grossman and Krueger, 1995;

Raymond, 2004). Figure 5.3 lists the OECD countries in ascending order in terms of per

capita GDP.

Page 166: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Figure 5.3: Mean income of OECD countries in 2006

Source: World Bank (2009) The threshold for the present analysis is between New Zealand and Korea ($25,000 USD

per capita). Limiting the analysis to the richest OECD countries with established

democratic histories is important, since it is challenging to make sense of implicit carb

tax differences across, for instance,

democratic Canada, and the formerly Communist and relatively less affluent Czech

Republic, especially in light of the fall of the Soviet Union in the 1990s, and the hype

0 10000 20000

TURMEXPOLSVK

HUNPRTCZE

KORNZLGRCESPITA

FRAJPNFIN

DEUBELGBRSWEDNKAUTAUSCANNLDCHEIRL

USANORLUX

(constant 2005 international PPP)

Figure 5.3: Mean income of OECD countries in 2006

The threshold for the present analysis is between New Zealand and Korea ($25,000 USD

per capita). Limiting the analysis to the richest OECD countries with established

is important, since it is challenging to make sense of implicit carb

tax differences across, for instance, Japan and Korea, or consistently affluent and

democratic Canada, and the formerly Communist and relatively less affluent Czech

Republic, especially in light of the fall of the Soviet Union in the 1990s, and the hype

20000 30000 40000 50000 60000 70000

Per capita GDP in 2006(constant 2005 international PPP)

154

The threshold for the present analysis is between New Zealand and Korea ($25,000 USD

per capita). Limiting the analysis to the richest OECD countries with established

is important, since it is challenging to make sense of implicit carbon

consistently affluent and

democratic Canada, and the formerly Communist and relatively less affluent Czech

Republic, especially in light of the fall of the Soviet Union in the 1990s, and the hyper-

70000 80000

Page 167: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

155

inflation among other economic challenges that occurred in many less developed

countries since the late 1980s.153

5.4: Empirical analysis and evidence

The following sections examine cross-national macroeconomic statistical evidence to

demonstrate the theoretical argument regarding the role of political institutions in shaping

tax policy outcomes. Aggregate data for each country are examined for statistical

relationships among key independent variables and tax policy levels. The analysis is

broken up into two main parts.

First, I examine tax rates on fuels used for commercial-industrial purposes; coal and

heavy fuel oil. Due to missingness in these data, I am unable to test all of the primary

working hypotheses in a panel model. Instead, I run OLS regression on a cross-section of

18 countries for which complete data are available. While multiple imputation of missing

values is sometimes advocated (King et al. 2001), this method requires that data be

missing at random.154 However, in the case of tax rate data for coal and heavy fuel oil,

long stretches of data are missing for each country. It was therefore decided to convert

the panel data structure to a simple cross-section by averaging yearly tax data over the

time period for which data are available, and regressing the country-specific mean tax on

key independent variables, also averaged over the same period. Although this data

structure considerably reduces degrees of freedom and does not allow for an analysis of

time trends and dynamics, it nevertheless can provide a sense of whether statistically

significant relationships exist among variables. Moreover, analysis of such data is often

used as a compliment to time-series cross-sectional techniques (e.g. Steinmo and Tolbert,

1998; Rogowski and Kayser, 2002).

153 It is worth emphasizing the fact that inflation rates are very similar across the sub-set of countries that make up the present analysis. In contrast, hyper-inflation occurred in several of the omitted countries. Had these countries not been omitted, large differences in tax rates among high and low inflation countries would artificially emerge where tax rates are adjusted for inflation (i.e. where cross-time comparisons are made). 154 Missing at random here implies that the probability of any observation for tax rate being missing should not be conditional on unobserved values of any of the variables used to impute incomplete values.

Page 168: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

156

The second major component of the empirical analysis focuses primarily on fuels used by

ordinary energy consumers, with a particular emphasis on motor fuels. Due to the more

complete nature of tax rate data on the household sector, I construct a time series cross-

sectional (TSCS) data structure, which includes an annual time series for each of the

countries in the data set. This data structure is now common in the political science

literature, and the relatively larger n it yields produces lower bias and greater efficiency

in point estimates, due to its asymptotic properties. This allows me to include a larger

number of independent variables in empirical models without sacrificing degrees of

freedom. At the same time, certain technical issues are raised by the use of TSCS, which

are addressed in greater detail below.

5.5: Implicit carbon taxes on fuels used by industry

For the purpose of the present analysis, I divide implicit carbon tax rates in two groups –

taxation on fuels used primarily by industry, and taxation of fuels used primarily by the

non-commercial sector (i.e. households). To be sure, there are good reasons to believe

that the political dynamics inducing governments to push for higher/additional energy

taxation, or preventing them from doing so, will be somewhat different across the two

sectors. For instance, relative to households, energy-intensive industry is more sensitive

to international competitiveness concerns, while the energy-producing sector will oppose

taxes affecting the price (and competitiveness) of its primary products. In addition,

“industry” represents a small group with concentrated interests, and is therefore more

likely to overcome barriers to collective action and effectively mobilize against increased

fossil fuel taxation. For these reasons, one might expect different variables to influence

tax rates levied upon different fuels, different sectors, and different uses of the same

fossil fuels.

In one of the few previously existing large-n cross-national studies of energy taxation by

a political scientist, Morozova (2007) hypothesizes that tax rates on fuels used by

Page 169: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

157

industry should be strongly influenced by cross-national differences in levels of

corporatism. Building on the qualitative literature on the comparative politics of carbon

taxes, which suggests tripartite corporatist networks help to explain the ultimate carbon

tax design selected (Midttun and Hagen, 1997; Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004),

Morozova argues that corporatist decision-making networks decrease the bargaining

costs between business and government, leading her to expect higher carbon tax rates in

more corporatist countries. Empirically, she finds limited empirical support. An

alternative and not necessarily contradictory perspective developed here suggests that

electoral systems help explain the decision to implement higher energy taxes in the first

place, facilitating the political implementation of left wing and green party policy

programs, like increasing rates of energy taxation for the purpose of decreasing energy

use, decreasing pollution, and raising government revenue to finance a more progressive

welfare state. In order to test both hypotheses empirically, the following sections analyze

two types of fossil fuels most commonly used by heavy industry -- steam coal and heavy

fuel oil.

5.5.1:Steam coal As documented in Chapter 4, coal is the least taxed fuel in OECD countries. At the same

time, substantial cross-national differences exist in the way countries tax coal. Figure

5.5.1 illustrates large tax differentials across OECD countries on tax rates applied to

steam coal used for industrial processes.155 Data for Luxembourg, Ireland, Greece and

Spain are missing, resulting in an n of 18.

155 This analysis examines tax rates on steam coal used by industry. Other types of coal and coal derivatives, e.g. coking coal, are excluded, as are tax rates on coal used for electricity generation (for reasons mentioned in Chapter 4). Here I use the term coal and steam coal interchangeably, and the tax on coal refers to the tax on coal used for industrial purposes.

Page 170: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

158

Figure 5.5.1.1: Implicit carbon tax rate on steam coal used by industry

Source: IEA Energy Prices and Taxes (various volumes) Note: Country codes are based on ISO 3166 The data in Figure 5.5.1.1 summarize the effective tax rate on steam coal used by

industry for 18 countries, in constant (2000) USD per tonne of CO2, averaged over the

years 1978-2006.156 As can be seen, large cross-national differences in the implicit tax

rate on coal exist. At one end of the spectrum, the United States, Portugal, Italy, France,

Germany, Canada, Belgium and Australia have no tax on coal between 1978-2006. All

of these countries, except for Portugal and Italy, are coal-producing countries. In contrast,

Sweden and Norway apply tax rates equivalent to over $10 USD per tonne of carbon

dioxide, while the Finnish tax averages to about $7 USD per tonne of CO2. Although we

might expect to see higher tax rates in countries that do not produce coal (e.g. Finland

and Sweden), Norway is a coal-producing country that nevertheless imposes one of the

156 Effective tax rate here refers to the total tax rate incurred by industry once rebates and exemptions are accounted for.

Page 171: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

159

largest implicit carbon tax levels on coal in the entire OECD. Between these extremes,

Denmark, Austria, Switzerland, New Zealand, Japan, Great Britain and the Netherlands

are among the countries to impose taxes on coal, though their levies are comparatively

smaller, falling under $5 USD per tonne of CO2.

Figure 5.5.1.2: Total coal production

Source: EIA (2009) and Heston et al. (2009) Figure 5.5.1.2. summarizes the data on coal production across the sample of 18 OECD

countries for which tax data on steam coal used by industry are available. This measure

can be conceptualized as the power of the coal lobby in that it provides an indication of

the size of the coal producing sector (measured in tonnes of oil equivalent) expressed as a

percentage of real gross domestic product (in constant 2005 international dollars at

purchasing power parity). Thus, it can be used as a proxy for the relative size of the coal

producing sector in a particular jurisdiction, standardized in terms of the size of the

economy. It might be hypothesized that the level of implicit carbon tax applied to

Page 172: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

160

industry use of steam coal will vary according to the size of the coal lobby.157

Interestingly, as suggested by Figures 5.5.1.1 and 5.5.1.2, the presence of coal producers

does not preclude taxes on coal, nor does the absence of a coal lobby guarantee them. For

instance, Italy produces no coal, nor does it apply a tax to industry use of steam coal. Of

the modest coal-tax countries (Figure 5.5.1.1), Great Britain, New Zealand and Belgium

produce relatively large amounts of coal, while Austria and Japan are also coal-producing

countries with moderate taxes on coal (Figure 5.5.1.2).

One potential reason for this particular distribution of coal tax rates across OECD

countries can be found in the work of Morozova (2007), who hypothesizes a relationship

between high levels of corporatism and higher tax rates on heavy fossil fuels. Applied to

the present study, the ability to impose higher tax rates on coal might be due less to the

absence of a coal lobby, than to the presence of corporatist decision making networks,

which decrease the cost of bargaining, and increase the potential for multi-stakeholder

compromise. A simple bivariate scatter plot provides some evidence in support of this

view.

157 Industries using steam coal might also be expected to mobilize against tax increases on coal, but including a measure of energy intensity in a statistical model raises an issue of endogeniety, therefore energy intensity is excluded. In its place, I substitute trade exposure for coal production, which yields similar results to those reported in the regression table below. The significant finding for the interaction between PR electoral systems and left cabinet governments is robust to this alternative specification.

Page 173: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

161

Figure 5.5.1.3: Implicit carbon tax on steam coal by level of corporatism

Source: IEA Energy Prices and Taxes (various volumes) and Siaroff (1999)

As can be seen in Figure 5.5.1.3, there is a moderately strong, positive relationship

(r=0.66) between the implicit carbon tax rate on steam coal, averaged over the period

1978-2006, and Siaroff’s (1999) index of corporatism, though there is considerably more

variation at higher levels of tripartite coordination. An additional pattern is also to be

found when comparing the distribution of implicit carbon tax rates on steam coal across

the two primary categories of electoral systems (5.5.1.4).

Page 174: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

162

Figure 5.5.1.4: Implicit carbon tax rate on steam coal by electoral regime (H1)

Figure 5.5.1.4 plots the distribution of implicit carbon tax rates on steam coal across the

two primary categories of electoral regime – single member plurality (i.e. majoritarian)

and proportional representation (i.e. PR) systems. As can be seen, both the median and

mean implicit carbon tax on steam coal used by industry is greater among countries

employing proportional electoral systems. Moreover, implicit carbon tax rates are

comparatively lower in countries employing single member plurality electoral formulae,

and a ttest of unequal variances confirms this difference as real at conventional levels of

significance (i.e. p<0.05). At the same time, however, the variation among PR systems is

rather large, suggesting that this variable, on its own, does not account for the large cross-

national differences in rates of implicit carbon taxation for steam coal. Indeed, while the

median under PR is higher than the median tax under majoritarian systems, some PR

countries have comparably low tax rates on coal.

Page 175: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

163

In order to more closely analyze the political determinants of implicit tax rates on coal,

the 18 countries for which data are available are included in a series of regression models.

Following the theoretical framework discussed in Chapter 1, the models include measures

of business interests, political institutions and partisan ideology. Business interests are

operationalized with the variable coal_prod, which is a measure of the size of the coal

lobby, in terms of total coal production (in kilotonnes of oil equivalent) divided by real

gross domestic product. Data on coal production are taken from the EIA, and data for real

gross domestic product are from the Penn World Tables 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009). The

interests of trade-exposed, energy intensive sectors, who fear a loss of international

competitiveness from energy taxes, are operationalized by the variable openk, which is a

measure of trade openness (imports + exports / gross domestic product), taken from the

Penn World Tables 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009). Given the nature of the coal tax falling

specifically on the business community, I also include a measure of corporatism

developed by Siaroff (1999), which is expected to facilitate the imposition of taxes on

industry (Morozova, 2005). Another institutional variable of particular interest for the

theoretical argument analyzed here is called pr, which is a dummy variable indicating

whether the majority of legislative seats are allocated according to a proportional or

majoritarian formula (Keefer, 2007).158 To measure the role of left ideology, I include

left_cab, an indicator of left-wing representation in government, measured in terms of the

percent of cabinet portfolios occupied by members of traditional left-wing (i.e. social-

democratic) parties (Armingeon et al. 2009). Following insights from the qualitative

literature on carbon taxes (Daugbjerg and Pedersen, 2004; Harrison, 2010), I expect

green and left parties to be associated with higher rates of carbon energy taxation.

Finally, the theoretical argument outlined in 5.1 specifies that PR regimes are likely to

have an effect on tax rates because they mediate the political power of green/left political

parties. I therefore create two multiplicative interaction terms pr_leftc (left_cab*pr), and

left_diss (left_cab*dis_gall). Following the theoretical expectations outlined in 5.2, I

expect left party cabinet to lead to higher taxes under PR (H2), and this effect to be 158 The variable PR is a dummy variable indicating the way in which the majority of legislative seats are allocated in the lower legislature. The measure, adapted from Keefer (2007) is thus able to distinguish between electoral systems that contain both plurality and proportional formulae (e.g. Australia, Germany, and Japan).

Page 176: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

164

constrained under disproportional systems (dis_gall) (H3). Summary statistics for these

variables are provided in Table 5.5.1.1.

Table 5.5.1.1: Summary statistics for coal tax regression models Variable Observations Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum coal_tax 18 2.49 4.54 0 15.82 coal_prod 18 0.16 0.02 0 0.06 net_coal_xp 18 -46.83 74.54 -100 184 openk 18 57.00 25.73 18.6 131.8 corporatism 18 2.78 1.42 1 5 left_cab 18 32.83 19.87 0 72.41 pr 18 0.67 0.48 0 1 dis_gall 18 6.02 5.13 1.02 16.3 left_dis 18 188.5 222.9 0 728.44 pr_leftc 18 25.08 22.93 0 72.41 Notes: Refer to data appendix for detailed variable definitions Each independent variable in Table 5.5.1.1 is sequentially included in separate regression

models, beginning with the interests of coal producers and consumers, followed by

corporatism, the percent of all cabinet portfolios held by parties from the left, a dummy

for proportional electoral systems, and an interactive term between PR and left cabinet

portfolios. The variable net_coal_xp is a measure of a country’s import dependency or

export prowess (highly correlated with production) and is used later on with additional

controls in the robustness checks. The results of the primary models are summarized in

Table 5.5.1.2. In all models (1 to 6), the dependent variable is the average implicit carbon

tax rate on coal over the period 1978-2006, measured in constant (2000) USD.

Page 177: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

165

Table 5.5.1.2: Coal tax regression models testing the ideological space hypothesis (H2) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) coal_prod -15.52 -19.48 -2.427 -10.26 -10.98 -6.342 (18.62) (19.32) (15.63) (15.12) (16.36) (12.16) openk -0.0471 -0.0514 -0.0485 -0.0463 -0.0258 (0.05) (0.04) (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) corporatism 2.585*** 1.656 1.736 0.366 (0.74) (0.86) (1.03) (0.86) left_cab 0.0958* 0.0955 0.0110 (0.05) (0.06) (0.05) pr -0.434 -6.929** (2.73) (2.81) pr_leftc 0.260*** (0.07) _cons 3.833** 6.718* -1.585 -2.226 -2.271 0.810 (1.63) (3.78) (2.51) (2.35) (2.46) (2.04) N 18 18 18 18 18 18 Adj. R2 0.014 0.028 0.392 0.477 0.435 0.692 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 The basic results summarized in Table 5.5.1.2 support the hypothesis that PR electoral

systems shape rates of implicit carbon taxation by mediating the ability of left wing

parties to implement their green/energy tax policy preferences. Interestingly, however, a

few surprises emerge. Indeed, models including only business interests (1 & 2) reveal

little in terms of explaining why countries tax coal at different rates. However, building

on this base each successive model builds explanatory power. With six variables, the

final model (6) provides the best fit to the data, explaining close to 70 per cent of the

variation in coal taxes. It should be noted that an F test for Model 6 confirms the joint

significance of all the independent variables included.

Page 178: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

166

Looking at each independent variable separately, evidence of interest group influence

over policy is limited, while evidence of the mediating role of political institutions is

more pronounced. Although higher tax rates on industrial use of steam coal are

negatively associated with larger coal lobbies and greater exposure to international trade,

the coefficients on coal production and trade exposure do not attain significance across

all models. Robustness checks explained later fail to reveal multicolinearity as a problem,

and when net_coal_xp is substituted for coal_production the models yield virtually

identical results.

In contrast to the relatively weak performance of economic interests, the political

variables perform much better. As expected, corporatism is positively associated with tax

rates on coal. Holding coal production and trade exposure constant, the degree of

corporatism is positively related to higher tax rates on coal, and this relationship is

significant at the p<0.01 level (Model 3). However, when other political predictors are

subsequently included (Models 4 through 6), the coefficient on corporatism loses

significance. As anticipated, the percentage of left cabinet portfolios is positively

associated with higher tax levels on coal, though this relationship achieves only modest

levels of significance (Model 4). Once the PR variable is entered into the model, both

left_cab and pr appear to have no impact. However, when both are included in a

multiplicative interaction term, the combined effect is highly significant (Model 6). More

precisely, left wing cabinet representation has no impact when pr is at zero (i.e. in

plurality systems), while pr is associated with significantly lower tax rates when there are

no left parties in cabinet. Consistent with the theory, the impact of PR is conditional on

the presence of left parties in government. Holding other factors in the model constant,

the combination of left wing party cabinet posts and PR leads to higher rates of implicit

carbon taxation on steam coal. Proportional electoral regimes are thus “good” for the

environment, but only where social democratic parties are in government, and vice versa.

Controlling for business opposition, exposure to international trade, and corporatist

decision-making networks, a 5 per cent increase in left party cabinet portfolios is

Page 179: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

167

associated with an average increase in tax on coal of about $1.355 USD (i.e. 5 times 0.26)

per tonne of carbon dioxide in proportional systems. The inverse – where left parties are

in government under plurality systems, which sometimes occurs (e.g. Great Britain under

a Labour government), appears to have no effect, on average, as indicated by the

relatively large standard error.159 With only 18 cases and 6 independent variables, the

statistical significance of the interaction term in Model 6 is impressive. To be sure, both

the proportional representation and left cabinet variables are consistently strong

predictors of coal tax rates across alternative model specifications not reported here.160 In

fact, of the 6 independent variables included in the model, the standardized beta

coefficient for the interaction pr_leftc is nearly a full order of magnitude larger than the

next strongest predictor.161 These results persist even after additional model

specifications are introduced in robustness checks (below).

To better illustrate the interactive relationship between PR electoral systems and social

democratic parties, and associated levels of significance, Figure 5.5.1.5 graphs the

marginal effect of left wing party in government at different theoretical levels of PR.

159 The one exception to this pattern is Great Britain, whose Labour Government implemented a tax on coal as part of the UK Climate Change Levy (2001). 160 For instance, left cabinet portfolios is nearly always significantly associated with higher tax rates no matter what other independent variables are included in the model. 161 For simplicity I do not report the beta coefficients in regression tables.

Page 180: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

168

Figure 5.5.1.5: The marginal effect of left party cabinet portfolios under PR (H2)

Figure 5.5.1.5 graphically depicts the marginal effect of increasing cabinet portfolios on

implicit carbon tax rates on steam coal. The dotted lines indicate the 95% confidence

interval and allows the reader to determine the conditions under which an increase in left

wing government participation has a statistically significant effect on implicit carbon tax

rates. While interpreting this graph, it is important to keep in mind that the marginal

effect is only significant when both the upper and lower bounds are above or below the

zero line. From this, we see that the marginal impact of left cabinet portfolios is positive

and significant in PR regimes (i.e. where PR is equal to 1), but that the marginal effect of

left party cabinet positions on coal taxation is not significant in countries where

majoritarian elections are used to elect governments (i.e. where PR is equal to 0). This

conditional relationship is exactly what we would expect from our theory regarding why

PR systems matter – they open up space for green/left-wing party policy preferences.

Page 181: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

169

The substantive impact of this interaction on tax policy is further demonstrated in a

simple 2 by 2 table (Table 5.5.1.3).

Table 5.5.1.3: Implicit carbon taxes on coal by left wing cabinet portfolios and PR Majoritarian (smp)

Proportional representation (pr)

Left wing cabinet >40%

New Zealand ($0.83)162 Australia ($0.00) France ($0.00)

Sweden ($15.82) Norway ($11.49) Finland ($7.66) Austria ($2.04)

Left wing cabinet <40%

Japan ($0.66) Great Britain ($0.53)163 Canada ($0.00) United States ($0.00)

Denmark ($3.53) Switzerland ($1.90) Netherlands ($0.43) Belgium ($0.00) Germany ($0.00) Portugal ($0.00) Italy ($0.00)

As can be seen from Table 5.5.1.3, the data fit the theory quite nicely. As expected, left

wing cabinet composition makes little difference under majoritarian SMP systems.

However, in the third column (PR), the distribution of tax rates is clearly divided between

countries having had experience with relatively large left-wing cabinet government,

relative to those with comparatively fewer left wing cabinet posts. Substantively, 11 of

the 18 countries in the sample fall under this category of PR. Of these, several are also

characterized by strong representation from left wing parties, resulting in relatively

higher taxes on coal (e.g. Sweden, Norway, Finland, Austria). On the other hand, PR

countries with relatively lower left party cabinet representation (e.g. Germany, Belgium,

Italy, Switzerland) have had continuing difficulty in raising environmental taxes.164 The

only real outlier here is Denmark, and it levies only a moderate coal tax by comparative

standards. Conversely, greater (i.e. >40%) left wing party representation in plurality

162 In 1993 New Zealand adopted a more proportional electoral system. It is included in the SMP category here only because it was a plurality system for the majority of the 1978-2006 period. 163 A left-wing Labour government implemented the U.K. climate change levy in 2001. 164 As of 1999 the tax on steam coal in Switzerland is actually $0.00. Moreover, numerous fossil fuel tax proposals have met great political difficulty in Switzerland (e.g. Thalmann, 2004).

Page 182: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

170

countries (e.g. Australia, New Zealand, Great Britain and France) has not resulted in

substantially higher tax levels on industrial use of coal, as expected. New Zealand is an

exception, where it recently changed its electoral system to PR in 1994, and Great Britain

introduced a moderate coal tax as part of the “Climate Change Levy” introduced by the

Labour government after Thatcher had dismantled the coal unions. Meanwhile, zero left

wing cabinet portfolios and plurality systems combine to explain non-existent tax rates in

Canada and the U.S. All of this lends considerable support to the idea that countries with

relatively high left-wing party representation in PR systems should have the highest taxes

on fossil fuels.

As a further test of the theory, and to ensure that the pr variable is really capturing the

effect of the electoral system, and not some other idiosyncratic differences, I substitute

dis_gall for pr. The dis_gall variable is Gallagher’s (1991) index of disproportionality.

Recall that the argument suggests PR should lead to higher taxes because it opens up

political space for smaller parties to implement their preferred policies. Conversely, it

follows that more disproportional systems should constrain the ability of small and left

wing parties to implement their policy programs. This is due to the fact that majoritarian

(disproportional) systems produce incentives to target geographically concentrated

interests in pivotal districts at the expense of targeting broader social welfare goals

(Persson and Tabellini, 2008; Rodden, 2007), like reducing GHG emissions and other air

and water pollutants associated the burning of fossil fuels. Moreover, disproportional

systems typically produce majority governments, thereby clarifying the lines of

accountability for unpopular policy, reducing the electoral threat of smaller green/left

parties, as well as their importance as coalition partners (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998).

Finally, I argue that the ability of any party to increase taxes is constrained under

disproportional systems, since the public is likely to oppose an increase in taxes, and

governments are more accountable and vulnerable to small changes in vote share under

disproportional systems. If true, the observable implication is to expect lower tax rates in

disproportional systems, and the marginal effect of social democratic parties on tax rates

should disappear as electoral systems produce more disproportional results. These ideas

are tested and summarized in Table 5.5.1.4.

Page 183: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

171

Table: 5.5.1.4: Coal tax regression models testing the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) coal_prod -18.71 -17.06 -2.427 -10.26 -10.47 -11.41 (18.23) (19.87) (15.63) (15.12) (15.75) (13.39) openk 0.0116 -0.0514 -0.0485 -0.0491 -0.0492 (0.0455) (0.0390) (0.0361) (0.0377) (0.0320) corporatism 2.585*** 1.656* 1.490 0.764 (0.743) (0.858) (1.230) (1.089) left_cab 0.0958* 0.101 0.250** (0.0528) (0.0616) (0.0818) dis_gall -0.0496 0.554 (0.253) (0.333) left_dis -0.0201** (0.00849) _cons 3.015** 2.328 -1.585 -2.226 -1.625 -4.460 (1.183) (2.955) (2.506) (2.350) (3.916) (3.536) N 18 18 18 18 18 18 adj. R2 0.003 -0.059 0.392 0.477 0.436 0.592 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 The disproportional constraints hypothesis is empirically supported in Table 5.5.1.4. As

expected, the coefficient on coal production is negatively associated with tax rates on

coal, though this variable never attains even a modest level of significance across Models

1 to 6. Similarly, trade exposure, measured by the variable openk, generally has the

expected sign (with the exception of Model 2), though it too never attains statistical

significance. Corporatism is positive and significant, as expected, in Models 2 and 3, but

loses its significance once dis_gall, the measure of proportionality, is included. Once

again, the last model including the interaction term provides the best fit to the data, and a

joint F test confirms that all independent variables in the model are jointly significant.

Page 184: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

172

Model 6 tests the interactive hypothesis and finds an inverse relationship between social

democratic cabinet posts and implicit carbon tax rates on steam coal under

disproportional electoral systems. As expected, the marginal impact of left wing cabinet

portfolios decreases to insignificance as electoral systems produce more disproportional

outcomes. Figure 5.5.1.6 provides a graphical illustration.

Figure 5.5.1.6: The marginal effect of left wing cabinet portfolios in disproportional systems (H3)

As can be seen in Figure 5.5.1.6, the impact of left wing cabinet portfolios on rates of

implicit carbon taxation for coal is positive and significant at low levels of

disproportionality, just as the argument in 5.1 suggests. However, as disproportionality in

the electoral system increases, left wing parties are increasingly constrained in their

ability to implement higher energy taxes, and the marginal impact thus decreases with

increasing levels of disproportionality. Having substituted the simple pr dummy variable

with a measure that more adequately captures the key causal mechanism underpinning

Page 185: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

173

the hypothesis of electoral constraints, the theoretical relationship postulated among

electoral systems, political parties, and carbon taxes garners further empirical support.

Robustness checks In order to build confidence in these results, I conduct a series of diagnostic and

robustness checks. First, correlation matrices and graphs are examined to check for

multicolinearity in the independent variables (see data appendix). Visual inspection of

these outputs provides no clear indication of collinearity issues, and this was confirmed

by low VIF scores, none of which exceeded the ‘rule of thumb’ threshold of values

greater than 10 (the largest was 8.70 for pr_leftc, which as an interaction term is expected

to be correlated with other independent variables). Theoretically, corporatism might be

expected to be correlated with left_cab. When corporatism is removed from the

regressions testing H2, the core results remain unchanged; pr_leftc retains its significance

at the p<0.01 level and the coefficient remains relatively unchanged (from 0.260 to

0.276). In addition, the adjusted R-square increases moderately to 0.713, as might be

expected when a non-essential independent variable is removed from the explanatory

model.

To check for heteroskedasticity (i.e. non constant variance in the error term), I plot the

residuals against predicted values of the dependent variable in a rvfplot. Some of the

residuals appear to cluster at values closer to zero, relative to higher values, indicating

some potential heteroskedasticity. A Breusch-Pagan / Cook-Weisberg test further

confirms the suspicion that the null hypotheses of homogenous variance should be

rejected.165 The heteroskedasticity in the errors suggests that the standard errors and

hypothesis tests might be invalid. The small sample size, and a few cases of large tax

rates relative to a cluster of countries with zero tax rates thus appear to pose a potential

problem. In order to guard against the possibility of influential outliers and observations

with greater leverage, I run a robust regression using Huber-White sandwich estimates of

165 This test is implemented in Stata with the command “estat hettest” following a regression. After estimating model 6, a hettest produces a value of 0.0086, suggesting the null of constant variance should be rejected in favour of the alternative.

Page 186: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

174

standard errors (Huber and Ronchetti, 2009). After running models with this more

conservative estimator, both variables that were significant in the original model with

potential heteroskedasticity (i.e. pr and pr_leftc) remain significant. In fact, their

significance increases. The results are thus robust to different methods – principally

designed to deal with heteroskedasticity and influential observations – of estimating the

size of the standard errors.

As a final robustness check, I re-run the models with a transformed dependent variable,

use an alternative measure of the size of the coal producing sector, net_coal_xp, and

include several other control variables in the model, including average GDP per capita,

average central government debt (expressed as a percentage of GDP) and average

revenues from income taxes in GDP (Table 5.5.1.5). Although normality is not necessary

for OLS to produce unbiased estimates of regression coefficients, the dependent variable

is positively skewed due to most countries having low or no tax rate on coal, while a

handful have relatively large taxes.166 Erring on the side of conservatism and as a

robustness check, I transform tax rates by taking the square root of coal_tax, yielding a

distribution that more closely approximates normality. When the transformed tax rate is

regressed against the predictors in the original models, substituting net_coal_xp for

coal_production, adding controls, and using estimates of robust standard errors, the basic

results remain unchanged (Table 5.5.1.5).

The same is true in the robustness check of H3, summarized in Table 5.5.1.6. With

different estimators and model specifications, the coefficient on left wing government

under disproportional systems is consistently negative and statistically significant, just as

our theory predicts.

166 The normality assumption applies only to residuals and is important for hypothesis testing. Nevertheless, some researchers insist on the importance of normally distributed independent and dependent variables. I therefore run separate regressions using a transformed dependent variable that more closely approximates normality. The results between models using the original and transformed variables are virtually identical.

Page 187: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

175

Table 5.5.1.5: Robustness checks for H

2 in regression models of square root coal tax with robust standard errors

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

pr

1.057*

1.057**

0.589

-1.654**

-1.981***

-1.749**

-1.701**

-1.711**

-1.877***

-1.585**

(0.570)

(0.472)

(0.456)

(0.572)

(0.573)

(0.763)

(0.632)

(0.668)

(0.561)

(0.519)

left_cab

0.0345**

0.00327

0.00861

0.00965

0.00631

0.00595

0.00304

0.00423

(0.0139)

(0.00802)

(0.0101)

(0.0109)

(0.0104)

(0.0167)

(0.0174)

(0.0128)

pr_leftc

0.0688***

0.0654***

0.0640***

0.0447***

0.0449***

0.0492***

0.0448***

(0.0129)

(0.0145)

(0.0159)

(0.0117)

(0.0140)

(0.0140)

(0.0127)

net_coal_xp

-0.00418

-0.00420

-0.00379

-0.00375

-0.00507

-0.00851*

(0.00285)

(0.00306)

(0.00305)

(0.00378)

(0.00423)

(0.00386)

openk

-0.00609

-0.00966

-0.00966

-0.00670

-0.00848

(0.0104)

(0.00657)

(0.00682)

(0.00497)

(0.00457)

corporatism

0.435**

0.441

0.391

0.190

(0.179)

(0.287)

(0.307)

(0.235)

avg_rgdpc

-0.00000199

-0.0000122

0.000000780

(0.0000556)

(0.0000548)

(0.0000447)

avg_debt

-0.00730

-0.0147*

(0.00753)

(0.00654)

itax_gdp

0.0958*

(0.0451)

_cons

0.350

0.350**

-0.520

0.268

0.173

0.365

-0.0548

-0.00540

0.611

-0.391

(0.446)

(0.163)

(0.481)

(0.246)

(0.127)

(0.372)

(0.314)

(1.435)

(1.596)

(1.491)

N

18

18

18

18

18

18

18

18

18

18

adj. R2

0.125

0.125

0.350

0.602

0.616

0.598

0.654

0.620

0.591

0.756

Standard errors in parentheses

* p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Page 188: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

176

Table 5.5.1.6: Robustness checks for H

3 in regression models of coal tax with robust standard errors

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

coal_tax

dis_gall

-0.0634

-0.0682

1.101

0.749*

0.533

0.782***

0.788***

0.787***

0.571

(0.0508)

(0.0522)

(0.742)

(0.355)

(0.304)

(0.120)

(0.131)

(0.143)

(0.382)

left_cab

0.0149

0.329**

0.346***

0.326***

0.290***

0.288***

0.288***

0.300**

(0.0137)

(0.0899)

(0.0661)

(0.0577)

(0.0294)

(0.0371)

(0.0409)

(0.110)

left_dis

-0.0355*

-0.0264**

-0.0253**

-0.0243***

-0.0243***

-0.0244***

-0.0213*

(0.0175)

(0.00873)

(0.00748)

(0.00305)

(0.00334)

(0.00373)

(0.0100)

net_coal_xp

-0.0140

-0.0120

-0.00921**

-0.00891

-0.00908

-0.0225

(0.0115)

(0.0101)

(0.00406)

(0.00501)

(0.00669)

(0.0191)

openk

-0.0532*

-0.0517***

-0.0516**

-0.0512**

-0.0509

(0.0287)

(0.0115)

(0.0125)

(0.0152)

(0.0406)

corporatism

1.674**

1.736**

1.720**

-0.249

(0.384)

(0.545)

(0.636)

(1.711)

avg_rgdpc

-0.0000150

-0.0000148

0.000269

(0.0000875)

(0.0000962)

(0.000256)

avg_debt

-0.000936

-0.0103

(0.0202)

(0.0558)

itax_gdp

0.163

(0.189)

_cons

1.019**

0.636

-7.970*

-9.096**

-3.905

-8.956***

-8.713**

-8.661**

-13.01

(0.397)

(0.645)

(3.854)

(2.934)

(2.830)

(1.210)

(2.344)

(2.850)

(7.705)

N

18

18

17

18

18

18

18

18

18

adj. R2

0.032

0.073

0.542

0.676

0.716

0.960

0.953

0.945

0.538

Standard errors in parentheses

* p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.001

Page 189: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

177

As can be seen in Tables 5.5.1.5 and 5.5.1.6, the variables of theoretical importance for

H2 and H3 (i.e. pr_leftc and left_dis) retain their significance across all models. These

results are robust when an alternative measure of the size of the coal producing sector,

net_coal_xp (also a measure of coal dependence) is used. Interestingly, the adjusted R-

square measure decreases beginning at model 7 as might be expected when additional

variables are included without adding any explanatory power to the model.

In sum, the core finding – that a combination of proportional systems and left wing

governments produce higher fossil fuel taxes (H2) – is robust across the various model

specifications and operationalizations of the dependent presented here. Similarly, the

disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3) is further supported in the robustness checks,

at even higher levels of significance. Moreover, the results hold regardless of which

estimators are used, and in particular the findings are consistent even when using

alternative estimators specifically designed to deal with moderate levels of

heteroskedasticity, influential outliers and observations with greater leverage. These

findings increase confidence that the results are robust and insensitive to alternative

model specifications.

5.5.2: Heavy fuel oil As is the case with coal, the implicit carbon tax on heavy fuel oil (HFO) also tends to be

lower across OECD countries, in terms of the higher carbon content of this fuel (Chapter

4). Also commonly known as “residual” fuel oil, HFO refers to Number 5 and Number 6

fuel oils – the last of what remains of crude after gasoline and distillate fuel oils are

extracted. As the name implies, HFO is very dense, and is primarily burned in furnaces

and boilers for industrial processes and in the generation of heat power.167 Though tax

rates on heavy fuel oil are generally low, some rather large cross-national differences

167 This analysis examines tax rates on heavy fuel oil used by industry, exclusively. For reasons mentioned in Chapter 4, I do not analyze implicit carbon taxes on fossil fuels used for electricity generation.

Page 190: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

178

exist across OECD countries. Figure 5.5.2.1 summarizes implicit carbon tax rates on

heavy fuel oil for industry in the 21 OECD countries for which data are available.168

Figure 5.5.2.1: Implicit carbon tax rate on heavy fuel oil used by industry

Source: IEA Energy Prices and Taxes (various volumes) Note: Country codes are based on ISO 3166 Figure 5.5.2.1 summarizes the effective industry tax rate on heavy fuel oil for 21 OECD

countries, in constant (2000) USD per tonne of CO2, averaged over the years 1978-

2006.169 For illustrative purposes, I include a vertical line at approximately $7 USD,

indicating the median tax. As can be seen, though several countries apply tax rates

equivalent to the median tax value of $7 USD per tonne of carbon dioxide, substantial

differences exist. In particular, Sweden, Norway and Greece apply very large taxes on

HFO, relative to all other countries in the sample. Portugal, Italy, the UK, Finland,

Austria and the Netherlands also apply tax rates substantially above the median. At the

168 I include all countries for which data are available here. 169 By the effective tax rate, I refer to the total tax incurred after rebates and exemptions (e.g. VAT) are accounted for.

Page 191: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

179

other end of the spectrum, Australia, Japan the United States, Belgium, Switzerland,

Spain and Germany are somewhat below the median, while all other countries apply tax

rates that are relatively close to the $7 USD per tonne of CO2 median tax value.

To be sure, the reasons for these differences are not obvious. Countries at substantially

similar levels of economic development – e.g. the U.S. ($32,399 PPP mean income) and

Norway ($33,619 PPP mean income) lie at opposite ends of the HFO tax spectrum. In

addition, the largest oil producers (i.e. Norway, Canada, Great Britain, Australia,

Denmark, USA, New Zealand) tax HFO at widely different rates. Figure 5.5.2.2 arranges

countries in terms of net crude oil exports, a proxy for the size of the oil producing sector

(and import dependence), measured as the difference between exports of crude oil minus

imports, expressed as a percentage of total domestic crude oil consumption in a given

year.

Figure 5.5.2.2: Net crude oil exports in selected OECD countries

Source: IEA Energy Balances of OECD Countries (various volumes)

Page 192: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

180

As can be seen in Figure 5.5.2.2, few rich OECD countries are net exporters of crude oil.

Large negative values indicate low crude oil production and increased dependence on

imports. Larger positive numbers indicate net exporters of crude. For instance, a value of

-100 indicates that 100% of the oil in a country is imported, while a value of + 50

indicates that a country exports 50% more oil than it consumes. As such, this measure

doubles as a proxy for both the size of the oil producing sector and its oil lobby, as well

as the dependence of a particular country on external sources of supply. In fact, this

measure is highly correlated with the measure of crude oil production also discussed later

in this analysis (r=-0.74) and the two can be used interchangeably as an indicator of the

size of the oil lobby.

Interestingly, the largest oil exporting countries in Figure 5.5.2.2 have substantially

different tax rates on HFO. For instance, Canada, Great Britain and Norway have

historically been among the rich OECD’s largest crude oil economies, yet they tax HFO

(and other oil products) at substantially different rates (Figure 5.5.2.1). Conversely, large

tax differentials exist among the most oil dependent countries. Contrary to the theory of

groups (Olson, 1965; Svendsen et al. 2001) countries with large oil producing sectors can

and do impose relatively large taxes on heavy fuel oil, while the absence of an oil

producing sector does not automatically translate into higher taxes on oil and its products.

Thus, differences in the implicit carbon tax rate on HFO cannot be explained with

reference to the availability of domestic resources and the interests of the oil-producing

sector alone.

Moreover, the simple bivariate relationship between HFO tax rates and levels of

corporatism also leaves much to be explained (Figure 5.5.2.3).

Page 193: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

181

Figure 5.5.2.3: Implicit carbon tax on HFO by level of corporatism

As can be seen in Figure 5.5.2.3, the relationship between HFO taxes and corporatism is

weaker than the relationship between implicit carbon taxes on coal and level of

corporatism examined earlier. The correlation between the two variables is a modest

r=0.41. When regressed on coal, corporatism explains approximately 12 per cent of the

variation in tax rates on its own, leaving a substantial amount of the distribution in tax

rates unexplained.

Similarly, simple reference to the electoral system does not by itself explain differences

in implicit carbon tax rates on heavy fuel oil (Figure 5.5.2.4).

Page 194: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

182

Figure 5.5.2.4: Implicit carbon tax rate on HFO by electoral regime (H1)

As can be seen from Figure 5.5.2.4, both the median and mean implicit carbon tax on

heavy fuel oil is greater among countries employing proportional electoral systems, while

implicit carbon tax rates are comparatively smaller in countries employing single member

plurality electoral formulae. However, a T-test (just barely) fails to confirm this

difference as significant.170 While less variance in the tax level under SMP suggests

carbon tax rates are more difficult to raise and change under majoritarian systems,

proportional representation does not by itself guarantee larger tax rates on heavy fuel oil

(or other fossil fuels). Indeed, the large variability in the box plot, and the cascading list

of countries in Figure 5.5.2.1, clearly show that some taxes are low, sometimes below the

median, even in countries with PR.

170 P value of 0.0609 in a test assuming equal variances (barely confirmed by robvar).

Page 195: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

183

In order to more satisfactorily analyze and explain cross-national differences in implicit

tax rates on heavy fuel oil, and to empirically test key explanatory hypotheses, I include

21 OECD countries for which comparable data are available in a series of regression

models. Following the template established in 5.5.1, the models test the causal efficacy of

the same variables, including business lobbies (in this case, the oil producing sector), the

interests of trade exposed sectors, corporatist decision-making networks, the electoral

regime and its degree of proportionality, left party cabinet seats, and interactive variables

between left party and electoral regime/disproportionality. The summary statistics for

each variable are summarized in Table 5.5.2.1.

Table 5.5.2.1: Summary statistics for HFO tax regression models Variable Observations Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum hfo_tax 21 12.69 15.28 0.47 66.79 crude_prod 21 0.048 0.130 0 0.599 net_oil_xp 21 -67.63 45.39 -100 42.79 openk 21 55.65 26.74 18.6 131.8 corporatism 21 2.55 1.41 1 5 left_cab 21 34.99 20.20 0 72.41 pr 21 0.67 0.48 0 1 dis_gall 21 6.08 4.77 1.02 16.3 left_dis 21 207.31 223.28 0 728.44 pr_leftc 21 26.59 23.97 0 72.41 Notes: Refer to data appendix for detailed variable definitions Following the same procedure that was used for analyzing tax rates on coal (5.5.1), each

independent variable summarized in Table 5.5.2.1 is sequentially included in separate

regression models, beginning with the interests of crude oil producers and consumers,

followed by corporatism, the percent of all cabinet portfolios held by parties from the left,

a dummy for proportional electoral systems, a measure of disproportionality, followed by

interactive terms between PR/disproportionality and left cabinet government portfolios.

The variable net_oil_xp is used later in the robustness checks. The results of each model

are summarized in Table 5.5.2.2.

Page 196: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

184

Table 5.5.2.2: HFO tax regression models testing the ideological space hypothesis (H2) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) crude_prod 33.57 33.40 17.45 13.54 15.95 5.865 (25.76) (26.44) (26.58) (22.98) (23.96) (21.94) openk 0.0302 -0.116 -0.0628 -0.0897 0.00278 (0.129) (0.147) (0.129) (0.141) (0.134) corporatism 5.193* 2.902 2.386 1.906 (2.937) (2.681) (2.913) (2.617) left_cab 0.392** 0.366** 0.0370 (0.150) (0.161) (0.209) pr 4.321 -18.59 (8.194) (12.84) pr_leftc 0.647** (0.298) _cons 11.09*** 9.418 5.079 -5.575 -4.855 1.296 (3.501) (7.991) (7.946) (7.975) (8.274) (7.929) N 21 21 21 21 21 21 adj. R2 0.034 -0.017 0.091 0.323 0.291 0.432 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 The results of regression models 1 through 6 are summarized in Table 5.5.2.2. In each

model, the dependent variable is the implicit carbon tax rate on HFO, in constant (2000)

USD. As was the case with coal taxes, we find support for the hypothesis that PR

electoral systems condition the ability of left wing (social democratic) parties to

implement higher rates of energy taxation. Interestingly, we again find a few surprises.

As was the case with coal taxes, business interests provide a weak explanation for

variance in tax rates on HFO, while inclusion of political predictors produces increased

explanatory power. For instance, inclusion of left-wing party government substantially

increases the adjusted R-square moving from model 4 to 5, as does the inclusion of an

interaction between left-wing government and PR. However, the same model produces a

much better account of coal taxes (adjusted R2 of over 0.6) than of implicit rates of

Page 197: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

185

carbon taxation on HFO (adjusted R2 of only 0.432). Although the framework as a whole

provides a markedly weaker account of variance in tax rates affecting the price of HFO,

the primary importance of the conditioning effect of electoral system appears to hold.

Moreover, a joint F test confirms the joint significance of all the independent variables

included in Model 6.

Looking at each independent variable on its own, we again find limited support for the

role of domestic interest groups. This is true regardless of whether crude oil production or

net crude oil exports is used as a proxy for the size of the fossil fuel lobby directly

affected by a tax on its product. Interestingly, crude oil production appears to be

positively associated with higher tax rates on HFO, though this variable fails to achieve

significance. In contrast, the coal production variable was consistently negative in the

coal tax regressions. Though never significant, the results do suggest that the coal lobby

is potentially a more effective or powerful constraint on the government’s ability to

impose taxes on its product. The fact that crude oil production consistently appears

positively (though insignificantly) associated with rates of implicit carbon taxation on

HFO is more consistent with a revenue-maximizing view of government than with a

general view of governments being responsive to fossil fuel producer interests.

Similarly, evidence of governments keeping taxes low to protect trade-exposed sectors of

the economy is also quite weak. This finding is consistent with the coal tax regressions.

Apart from the small sample size, one potential reason for this variable’s poor

performance is that the tax data do not fully account for exemptions granted to particular

industries. This shortcoming in the data might be corrected in future work with additional

research on tax exemptions for energy-intensive trade exposed industries.

As expected, the level of corporatism is positively associated with higher rates of HFO

taxation, and this relationship is significant at a level of p<0.1, though only when other

political variables are excluded from the model. When left wing party representation is

included, the coefficient on corporatism loses significance. Consistent with theoretical

expectations, the percentage of left cabinet portfolios is positively associated with

Page 198: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

186

significantly higher tax rates, and this relationship disappears once we specify an

interaction between electoral system and left wing government, which is significantly

associated with higher rates of implicit carbon taxation on HFO, as expected. Holding all

other factors in the model constant, the combination of left wing parties in government

and PR electoral regimes leads to higher rates of implicit carbon taxation on heavy fuel

oil. Thus, it appears as though PR systems are associated with significantly higher taxes,

but only where left parties are represented in government. Controlling for business

opposition, exposure to international trade, and level of corporatism, a 5 per cent increase

in left party cabinet portfolios is significantly associated with an average increase in tax

on HFO of about $3.24 USD (i.e. 5 times 0.647) per tonne of carbon dioxide in

proportional systems. The inverse – where left parties are in government under plurality

systems, like Labour in the U.K. – appears to have no effect.

Of all independent variables included in model 6, the standardized beta coefficient for the

interaction pr_leftc is by far the best predictor of HFO tax rates in terms of both

significance and effect size.171 To better capture the nature of the interactive relationship,

Figure 5.5.2.5 plots the marginal effect of left wing party cabinet posts at different

theoretical levels of PR.

171 Note: beta coefficients are not reported in the regression tables.

Page 199: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

187

Figure 5.5.2.5: The marginal effect of left party cabinet portfolios under PR (H2)

As can be seen in Figure 5.5.2.5, the same conditional relationship found in the analysis

of tax rates on steam coal is applies to HFO. From this, we see that the marginal impact

of left cabinet portfolios is positive and significant in PR regimes (i.e. where PR is equal

to 1), but that the marginal effect of left party cabinet positions on HFO taxation is not

significant in countries where members are elected based on a majoritarian formula (i.e.

where PR =0). This conditional relationship mirrors what was found in the analysis of tax

rates on steam coal for industry, and is exactly what might be expected from the

theoretical argument outlined in 5.1. By increasing the probability of left wing members

being elected, and by association, becoming members of government, PR systems

facilitate the implementation of higher tax rates on fossil fuels. The substantive impact of

this conditioning role of the electoral system on tax policy is further demonstrated in a

simple 2 by 2 table (Table 5.5.2.3).

Page 200: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

188

Table 5.5.2.3: Implicit carbon taxes on HFO by left wing cabinet portfolios and PR

Majoritarian (smp)

Proportional representation (pr)

Left wing cabinet >40%

France ($7.34) New Zealand ($6.56) Australia ($0.47)

Sweden ($66.79) Norway ($35.57) Greece ($33.61) Finland ($11.43) Austria ($10.47)

Left wing cabinet <40%

Great Britain ($11.64) Canada ($6.92) United States ($2.73) Japan ($1.75)

Italy ($12.19) Netherlands ($9.17) Denmark ($8.03) Ireland ($6.64) Germany ($5.69) Switzerland ($5.48) Belgium($3.54)

The data in Table 5.5.2.3 fit with the theory, though one observation emerges as

potentially problematic. As we would expect, there appears to be no relationship between

left wing cabinet portfolios and tax rates under majoritarian systems. Indeed, countries

with lower left wing cabinet are just as likely to have relatively moderate rates of taxation

on HFO as those countries with higher levels of left wing government, under SMP. In

contrast, left wing government appears to have a greater effect under PR, consistent with

the theory. With the exception of Italy (which in fact does have a history of left wing

cabinet government), countries with both high levels of left wing cabinet posts and PR

electoral systems consistently tax HFO at higher rates, relative to countries with lower

levels of left wing cabinet government under PR. However, the Swedish tax rate on HFO

stands out as very large and may exert greater leverage in the regression analysis. This

hunch is examined further in a later section on regression diagnostics.

As a further test of the theory, and to ensure that the pr variable is in fact capturing the

effect of the electoral system and not some other difference, I substitute dis_gall for pr in

a separate series of regression models, as was done earlier in the analysis of taxation on

coal. Recall that dis_gall is Gallagher’s (1991) index of disproportionality, and that our

Page 201: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

189

theory suggests left wing parties will be constrained in their ability to raise taxes in more

disproportional systems. If correct, the marginal effect of social democratic parties on tax

rates should decline as disproportionality in the electoral system increases. This

hypothesis is tested and empirical results are summarized in Table 5.5.2.4.

Table 5.5.2.4: HFO tax regression models testing the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) crude_prod 33.57 33.40 17.45 13.54 16.96 12.88 (25.76) (26.44) (26.58) (22.98) (24.79) (22.31) openk 0.0302 -0.116 -0.0628 -0.0640 -0.0484 (0.129) (0.147) (0.129) (0.132) (0.119) corporatism 5.193* 2.902 1.829 0.00988 (2.937) (2.681) (3.650) (3.379) left_cab 0.392** 0.407** 0.897*** (0.150) (0.157) (0.267) dis_gall -0.399 1.892 (0.893) (1.330) left_dis -0.0719** (0.0333) _cons 11.09*** 9.418 5.079 -5.575 -1.019 -13.26 (3.501) (7.991) (7.946) (7.975) (13.07) (13.02) N 21 21 21 21 21 21 adj. R2 0.034 -0.017 0.091 0.323 0.287 0.427 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01 The general results found in the analysis of coal taxes is again replicated in this analysis

of implicit rates of carbon taxation on HFO. As can be seen in Table 5.5.2.4, the

disproportional constraints hypothesis is supported. Interestingly, the coefficient on crude

oil production is positive, indicating that oil producing countries tend to tax HFO at

higher rates, though this relationship is not significant. The sign on the coefficient for

Page 202: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

190

trade exposure is consistent with expectations, yet it too fails to achieve significance

across all models. In contrast, the corporatism variable is consistently positive (as

expected) and significant in model 3, yet loses significance when other political

predictors are included. In particular, left wing cabinet posts are significantly associated

with higher tax rates on HFO. The sixth model tests the disproportional constraints

hypothesis, and findings are consistent with the theory. The interaction between social

democratic government portfolios and disproportional electoral systems is negative, as

expected. This relationship is depicted in Figure 5.5.2.6.

Figure 5.5.2.6: The marginal effect of left wing cabinet portfolios in disproportional systems (H3)

As can be seen, the impact of left wing cabinet portfolios on rates of implicit carbon

taxation for HFO is positive and significant at low levels of electoral disproportionality.

This impact decreases as electoral systems produce increasingly disproportional electoral

Page 203: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

191

outcomes. At larger levels of disproportionality, the impact of left cabinet members on

HFO tax rates has no effect. Consistent with the disproportional constraints hypothesis

outlined in 5.2, Figure 5.5.2.6 clearly shows that left wing parties are increasingly

constrained in their ability to implement higher rates of carbon energy taxation as

disproportionality in the electoral system increases. Having substituted the pr dummy for

a variable that more adequately captures the key causal mechanism underlying the

importance of electoral systems for green taxes, we find additional support for an

important role for electoral systems in shaping energy tax policy outcomes, a finding

consistent with the earlier analysis of implicit rates of carbon taxation on steam coal used

by industry.

Robustness checks

As was done earlier, I run a series of robustness checks to build greater confidence in the

results. First, correlation matrices and graphs are examined to check for multicolinearity

in the independent variables (see data appendix). Visual inspection of this output failed to

identify any obvious collinearity issues, and this was confirmed by low VIF scores, none

of which exceeded worrisome values of 10. The two most correlated independent

variables in the models analyzed above are dis_gall and corporatism (r=0.67), which are

theoretically distinct concepts. When corporatism is removed from the model testing

disproportional constraints, the coefficients barely change, and the two significant

variables (left_cab and left_dis) become slightly more significant. In addition, the

adjusted R square increases to 0.46 from 0.42, as might be expected when an independent

variable with limited additional explanatory power is removed. None of this raises any

concern for the validity of the results.

Having ruled out multicolinearity as a problem, I proceed to check for heteroskedastic

errors. Visual examination of residuals reveals that they are quite normally distributed.

However, an rvfplot identifies Sweden as an outlier, and a Breusch-Pagan / Cook-

Weisberg test further confirms that there may be a mild problem of heterogeneously

distributed errors. Further tests (including leverage tests and a leverage versus residual

Page 204: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

192

squared plot) suggest Sweden does not exert that much leverage.172 Nevertheless, I re-run

the models using robust estimates of the standard errors (Huber and Ronchetti, 2009), and

include additional control variables as was done in the robustness checks for coal. The

results are not substantively different across most models, as reported in Tables 5.5.2.5

and 5.5.2.6.

Unlike the case of the robustness checks on coal, the coefficient on the interaction terms

testing H2 and H3 lose significance in models 8 and 9 in Tables 5.5.2.5 and 5.5.2.6 when

debt and income tax variables are included. This might be expected given the reduced

degrees of freedom in models 8 and 9, which also lower the R-square. Given the

consistent significance across all other models, and the higher proportion of variance

explained in the restricted models, I conclude that the relationships found in the original

models are robust and significant.173

To summarize the results so far, the analysis of implicit carbon taxes on coal and heavy

fuel oil lend considerable support to both the ideological space (H2) and disproportional

constraints (H3) hypotheses. The distribution of tax rates on fuels used by industry – for

both coal and heavy fuel oil – differs systematically across the two primary electoral

systems used in the OECD. More precisely, the degree of disproportionality in electoral

systems appears to condition the ability of left wing parties to implement higher tax rates

on carbon based fuels used by industry. When disproportionality is low (i.e. in PR

regimes), left wing parties are associated with significantly higher tax rates on heavy fuel

oil. Conversely, when disproportionality increases, this effect disappears. Whether these

relationships can account for differences across other fossil fuels used by consumers is a

subject to which I now turn.

172 In fact, leverage tests indicate Norway and Canada are the most influential observations. 173 Finally, I rerun the model without Sweden in the sample. When this is done, all coefficients lose significance. However, a restricted model with all variables minus the interaction brings up a significant coefficient on pr. I conclude that PR retains a significant effect, regardless of Sweden. Moreover, given the small sample size and limited statistical evidence of Sweden’s influential status, I conclude that Sweden should remain in the analysis when testing the interactive hypothesis.

Page 205: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

193

Table 5.5.2.5: Robustness checks for H

2 regression models with robust standard errors

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

pr

11.02

4.696

-16.44*

-15.14

-17.76

-19.03

-24.84

-21.56

-22.00

(6.805)

(4.151)

(9.407)

(11.77)

(16.70)

(17.61)

(18.43)

(19.54)

(20.32)

left_cab

0.431**

0.0500

0.0479

0.0410

0.0328

-0.123

-0.0372

-0.0402

(0.204)

(0.0605)

(0.0588)

(0.0597)

(0.0716)

(0.136)

(0.172)

(0.177)

pr_leftc

0.670**

0.660*

0.691*

0.660*

0.781**

0.657

0.656

(0.281)

(0.312)

(0.360)

(0.327)

(0.345)

(0.397)

(0.423)

net_crude_xp

0.0222

0.0185

0.00668

0.0377

0.0503

0.0586

(0.0471)

(0.0525)

(0.0587)

(0.0538)

(0.0639)

(0.0799)

openk

0.0440

0.00193

-0.00943

-0.0626

-0.0590

(0.152)

(0.124)

(0.101)

(0.119)

(0.119)

corporatism

2.068

4.398

5.018

5.373

(3.343)

(4.134)

(4.339)

(4.949)

avg_rgdpc

-0.00107

-0.000820

-0.000864

(0.000659)

(0.000819)

(0.000850)

debt

0.119

0.122

(0.118)

(0.122)

itax_gdp

-0.150

(0.802)

_cons

5.349

-5.517

4.087**

5.077**

3.525

1.749

30.73*

18.86

21.72

(5.556)

(6.338)

(1.532)

(2.366)

(6.340)

(7.626)

(15.62)

(23.91)

(27.45)

N

21

21

21

21

21

21

21

21

21

adj. R2

0.075

0.340

0.500

0.473

0.443

0.429

0.450

0.437

0.388

Standard errors in parentheses

* p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Page 206: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

194

Table 5.5.2.6: Robustness checks for H

3 regression models with robust standard errors

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

hfo_tax

dis_gall

-0.705

-0.584

2.140*

2.133

2.052

2.131

2.086

2.062

2.043

(0.628)

(0.515)

(1.087)

(1.360)

(1.357)

(1.496)

(1.562)

(1.602)

(1.729)

left_cab

0.462**

0.932**

0.931**

0.938**

0.909**

0.879**

0.831*

0.836*

(0.193)

(0.331)

(0.368)

(0.375)

(0.369)

(0.391)

(0.384)

(0.410)

left_dis

-0.0752**

-0.0751*

-0.0759*

-0.0739*

-0.0729*

-0.0656

-0.0678

(0.0346)

(0.0395)

(0.0402)

(0.0384)

(0.0399)

(0.0399)

(0.0421)

net_crude_xp

0.000787

0.000451

-0.00504

0.00507

0.0298

0.0550

(0.0540)

(0.0560)

(0.0604)

(0.0622)

(0.0662)

(0.0855)

openk

-0.0462

-0.0590

-0.0680

-0.146

-0.140

(0.0874)

(0.0908)

(0.0869)

(0.117)

(0.115)

corporatism

0.835

1.375

3.061

3.442

(3.489)

(4.045)

(3.878)

(4.297)

avg_rgdpc

-0.000252

0.00000464

-0.0000945

(0.000598)

(0.000742)

(0.000758)

debt

0.205**

0.206**

(0.0901)

(0.0845)

itax_gdp

-0.361

(0.741)

_cons

16.99**

0.0919

-17.36

-17.26

-14.27

-15.95

-8.852

-23.72

-15.57

(6.666)

(4.176)

(10.33)

(14.81)

(15.15)

(18.43)

(21.75)

(30.24)

(37.39)

N

21

21

21

21

21

21

21

21

21

adj. R2

-0.002

0.355

0.509

0.478

0.450

0.414

0.373

0.440

0.404

Standard errors in parentheses

* p < 0.1, ** p < 0.05, *** p < 0.01

Page 207: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

195

5.6. Implicit carbon taxes on fuels used by households

As demonstrated in the previous sections, implicit carbon taxes on the industrial use of

fossil fuels – steam coal and heavy fuel oil – vary systematically across countries

employing proportional and majoritarian electoral systems. In particular, the cross-

sectional data provide substantial evidence in support of the claim that electoral systems

condition the ability of left-wing party government to implement higher rates of energy

taxation. The following section extends this analysis by examining the role of electoral

regimes in shaping rates of implicit carbon taxation on other forms of energy most

commonly used by the non-commercial, household sector: motor fuels used in

transportation.

Due to the nature of data on motor fuels and the different interests at play, slightly

different models and tests are applied in this section. Indeed, the present analysis focuses

on tax rates imposed on a large group made up of diffuse and less well-organized

interests, i.e. consumers. As such, the corporatism variable drops out of the equation.174

In its place, I include additional controls for the plausible influence of central government

debt, population density, rural dwellers, election years, and the relative size of other types

of taxes that contribute to government revenue, namely, income taxes on personal and

corporate income.175 A larger number of observations of motor fuel tax rates allows for a

broader, more comprehensive empirical analysis including all of these variables.

It should also be noted that the transportation sector accounts for nearly half of total

world oil consumption (IEA, 2004: 84) and two thirds of GHG emissions (IPCC, 2007:

325). Taxes on motor fuels can thus be understood as being an important instrument for

mitigating emissions from the transport sector (Sterner, 2007) or decreasing dependence

on externally sourced crude oil (Becker, 2009). At the same time, motor fuel taxes are an

important source of government revenue. According to the OECD (2001: 55) roughly 90

174 Methodologically, the time-invariant nature of this variable makes it difficult to test using a panel data model structure (Plumper..). 175 These measures and the data sources are discussed in greater detail below as well as in the data reference appendix.

Page 208: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

per cent of total revenues generated from “environmentally related” taxes are derived

from tax rates on motor fuels. Owing to a lack of substitutes, demand for motor fuels is

relatively inelastic, thus providing governments with a reliable source of revenue. At the

same time, taxes on motor fuels are systematically among the most disliked by

(Hsu et al. 2008). These factors add additional political dynamics to the energy tax

calculation, especially for governments facing growing levels of debt and emissions, and

who also face stiff electoral competition at the polls.

The tax data on motor fuels are collected from the IEA’s

quarterly publication, and cover the period 1978

complete, allowing for an analysis of a time

data analyzed here consist of 22 panels (rich OECD countries) over a time period of 29

years. Panel data taking this form

narrow panels, and are commonly analyzed by economists and political scientists

interested in explaining macro

allows for greater leverage and produces point estimates with less bias and more

efficiency, thanks to the asymptotic properties of a larger sample size. The models thus

include additional independent variables that were excluded from the earlier cross

sectional regressions, due to a lack of degrees of freedom. The cross

data also allow for the modeling of causal dynamics, which was not possible in the

previous coal and heavy fuel oil regressions.

For the empirical analysis using this TSCS panel data, I specify the general functional

form as:

where represents the general intercept,

represent the slope of each explanatory

The nature of this panel data structure

sectional units (i) over time (t)

per cent of total revenues generated from “environmentally related” taxes are derived

om tax rates on motor fuels. Owing to a lack of substitutes, demand for motor fuels is

relatively inelastic, thus providing governments with a reliable source of revenue. At the

same time, taxes on motor fuels are systematically among the most disliked by

(Hsu et al. 2008). These factors add additional political dynamics to the energy tax

calculation, especially for governments facing growing levels of debt and emissions, and

who also face stiff electoral competition at the polls.

motor fuels are collected from the IEA’s Energy Prices and Taxes

quarterly publication, and cover the period 1978-2006. This data is relatively more

complete, allowing for an analysis of a time-series cross-sectional (TSCS) data set. The

e consist of 22 panels (rich OECD countries) over a time period of 29

years. Panel data taking this form – where t exceeds n – are typically known as long and

narrow panels, and are commonly analyzed by economists and political scientists

laining macro-comparative trends. The larger number of observations

allows for greater leverage and produces point estimates with less bias and more

efficiency, thanks to the asymptotic properties of a larger sample size. The models thus

independent variables that were excluded from the earlier cross

sectional regressions, due to a lack of degrees of freedom. The cross-section time

data also allow for the modeling of causal dynamics, which was not possible in the

heavy fuel oil regressions.

For the empirical analysis using this TSCS panel data, I specify the general functional

represents the general intercept, X1 to Xn the explanatory variables,

represent the slope of each explanatory variable, and denotes the errors.

The nature of this panel data structure – combining repeated observations of cross

sectional units (i) over time (t) – enriches empirical analysis in ways not possible using

196

per cent of total revenues generated from “environmentally related” taxes are derived

om tax rates on motor fuels. Owing to a lack of substitutes, demand for motor fuels is

relatively inelastic, thus providing governments with a reliable source of revenue. At the

same time, taxes on motor fuels are systematically among the most disliked by consumers

(Hsu et al. 2008). These factors add additional political dynamics to the energy tax

calculation, especially for governments facing growing levels of debt and emissions, and

Energy Prices and Taxes

2006. This data is relatively more

sectional (TSCS) data set. The

e consist of 22 panels (rich OECD countries) over a time period of 29

are typically known as long and

narrow panels, and are commonly analyzed by economists and political scientists

comparative trends. The larger number of observations

allows for greater leverage and produces point estimates with less bias and more

efficiency, thanks to the asymptotic properties of a larger sample size. The models thus

independent variables that were excluded from the earlier cross-

section time-series

data also allow for the modeling of causal dynamics, which was not possible in the

For the empirical analysis using this TSCS panel data, I specify the general functional

the explanatory variables, to

combining repeated observations of cross-

enriches empirical analysis in ways not possible using

Page 209: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

197

simple cross-section or time series data, producing several distinct advantages for

empirical research (Baltagi, 1995: 3-6). For instance, analysis of panel data allows

researchers to study the dynamics of change across units, and a fixed-effects model

allows researchers to control for unit-specific variables that are often difficult to measure

but of theoretical interest to empirical research (e.g. political culture). Despite these

advantages, however, many features of TSCS data (e.g. heterogeneous units, time series)

cause panel data regression models to depart from the statistical ideal of independent and

identically distributed (i.i.d.) error assumptions, a key requisite for Ordinary Least

Squares (OLS) regression techniques and the underlying mathematical properties that

justify statistical inference. Since panel data consist of repeated observations on the same

entity, unit heterogeneity becomes a distinct possibility, calling into question the i.i.d.

error assumption (Hamilton, 2006: 193).

In particular, panel data sets are often characterized by three features, which can violate

key assumptions in OLS. All three statistical problems relate to assumptions about panel

residuals, requiring more complex error specifications, and include groupwise

heteroskedasticity, contemporaneous correlation and serial correlation. After testing for

and decisively rejecting the null hypotheses of homoskedasticity and no serial-

correlation,176 I derive standard errors from Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) using

variance-covariance matrix panel corrected for contemporaneous correlation and cross-

sectionally heteroskedastic errors, and employ panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE) as

the primary estimator. As shown by Beck and Katz (1995), PCSEs provide more

consistent estimates when there is panel-specific heteroskedasticity, though they also tend

to increase the standard errors of estimates (and thus decrease their statistical

significance). Since the number of years (29) is larger than the number of panels (21), the

data structure is known as a “long narrow” panel, which further justifies the choice of

PCSE as the preferred estimator. In addition, the PCSE estimator is by now the most

widely used estimator for TSCS data in political science (Beck, 2001). 176 I used a modified Wald test for heteroskedasticity, and a Breusch-Pagan test for cross-sectional correlation. Both tests involved user-created commands in STATA by Chistopher Baum (xttest3 and xttest2). I also tested for serial correlation using the Wooldridge test (xtserial) described by Drukker (2003). All tests produced significant results, leading me to reject the null of no serial correlation and heterosckedasticity.

Page 210: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

198

Recognizing the stickiness of tax rates over time, I also include a lagged dependent

variable (LDV). Although this approach does not completely “cure” the model from

serial correlation, I include the LDV for substantive reasons; namely, in an attempt to

control for the slow temporal dynamics of the processes I am attempting to model. As

Beck and Katz (2009) point out, this approach is also favourable to alternative ways of

modeling dynamics, on methodological grounds as well.177 Following the advice of Beck

and Katz (1995), I estimate the diesel and gasoline tax models using OLS with PCSE and

a lagged dependent variable (LDV). The LDV is included to control for serially

correlated errors over time. Correlograms indicate that imposing a first order Markov

process (AR1) on the model would be inappropriate given the dynamics in the DV, so I

include only the LDV, which as Beck and Katz suggest, should remove much of the

autocorrelation (as confirmed by low rho).

To be sure, some authors have challenged the “new orthodoxy” and suggest that

practitioners often use PCSEs without providing any evidence that they considered

alternatives or tested their suitability (Wilson and Butler, 2007).178 When panel data are

characterized by unit heterogeneity, as they are here, one of the alternatives suggested by

Kristensen and Wawro (2007) is to use OLS regression with cluster robust standard

errors and fixed effects (FEs), as proposed by Arellano’s update of White’s sandwich

estimates. They argue this approach is more suitable than PCSEs when unit effects are

particularly strong and when the number of time periods grows. As a robustness check

throughout my analysis, I estimate all models with this alternative estimator, which

produces standard errors that are robust to group-wise heteroskedasticity and

contemporaneous correlation. This method is used primarily as a robustness check, and

generally produces the same results, as demonstrated below.

177 Correlograms indicate that imposing a first order Markov process (AR1) on the model would be inappropriate for the dynamics in the DV. 178 Thanks to Rodney Haddow for assistance on thinking through the choice of estimator and on the overall methodological discussion presented here.

Page 211: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

199

Finally, I estimate all models using unit fixed effects (FE).179 The fixed effects models

help control for unobserved differences across panels, which often exist across countries.

I thus control for slowly changing institutional differences, and such unobservable factors

as political culture, using unit fixed effects. The FE estimates make time-invariant

institutional variables (like federalism) redundant, and they are therefore excluded from

the analysis on such methodological grounds. In order to circumvent the problem of

including time-invariant variables with FE models (Bollen and Brand, 2008; Plumper and

Troeger, 2007), I include electoral system variables in interactive terms, which increase

over time variance and are thus permissible when using FE models, as shown by Trieman

(2009). Tests for unit roots are discussed in the Robustness section.

The hypotheses tested in this section are the same as those presented earlier, with an

additional hypothesis. At the risk of being repetitive, they are summarized here.

H1: The PR hypothesis: Relative to majoritarian electoral systems, countries with PR will impose higher implicit tax rates on carbon. H2: The ideological space hypothesis: Relative to majoritarian electoral systems, greater representation from parties of the left and greens will be positively associated with significantly greater implicit carbon tax rates on diesel and gasoline under PR. H3: The disproportional constraints hypothesis: Relative to proportional systems, greater representation from parties of the left and greens will not be associated with greater implicit carbon tax rates on diesel and gasoline under more disproportional systems, as these parties will be constrained in their ability to raise tax rates. H4: The electoral incentives hypothesis: Relative to more proportional systems, increasing support for new left and green parties will lead to an increase in rates of implicit carbon taxation on diesel and gasoline under more disproportional systems, as governments have greater incentive to respond to mounting electoral threats where the seat-vote elasticity is high. In order to test these primary working hypotheses, and build more confidence in the

results, I run a series of tests using time-series cross-sectional data. These statistical tools

allow me to test the primary hypotheses while also holding other potentially confounding

variables constant. Identical tests are repeated for both diesel and gasoline motor fuels.

179 A Hausman test confirms that a Random Effects model would be inappropriate due to systematic differences across panel units.

Page 212: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

200

The first hypothesis, H1, is tested with a simple ttest seeking to establish a statistically

significant difference in mean tax rates between countries employing PR and SMP

electoral regimes. Due to the slowly changing (time invariant) nature of this variable, it is

not tested using the TSCS data (Plumper and Troeger, 2007), but is included in

interactions, which are time variant and thus amenable to statistical analysis using TSCS

techniques (Bollen, 2009). Next, I build several models with the following variables to

test hypotheses H2 to H4. As done in the cross-sectional regressions, I include

crude_rgdp as a measure of the size of the domestic crude oil lobby. This variable is a

measure of total crude oil production in a country in a given year, divided by real gross

domestic product in 2005 international dollars at purchasing power parity.180 Consistent

with a public choice framework and the theory of interest group influence on policy, I

expect crude oil production to be inversely related to tax rates on motor fuels. Other

models substitute crude production with net crude exports, net_crude_xp, which captures

crude production levels and import dependency. Like crude production, I expect this

variable to be negatively correlated with tax rates. Next, I include openk as a measure of

exposure to international trade and the related competitive pressures to keep taxes low.

This variable, commonly used in the literature on tax policy to test for a “race to the

bottom,” is measured as the sum of imports and exports divided by GDP, in constant

national currency, and is taken from the Pen World Tables 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009).

Following the logic developed in the literature, I expect this variable to be inversely

related to tax rates on fossil fuels. The variable pr is a dummy variable for countries

employing electoral systems that can be categorized as proportional representation.

Recognizing that in some cases both plurality and proportional methods of assigning

legislative seats are used (e.g. Australia, Germany, Japan), countries are coded either PR

or majoritarian (SMP) according to the way in which the majority of seats are allocated in

the lower legislature. This measure is thus able to distinguish between electoral systems

that make use of both plurality (SMP) and proportional formulae, and is adapted from the

housesys variable in the Database of Political Institutions (Keefer, 2007).

180 Data on crude oil production is from the EIA, and real gross domestic product data is taken from Heston et al. 2009. See variable definitions for more information.

Page 213: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

201

Testing the disproportionality hypotheses H3 to H4 involves including Gallagher’s

(1991) index of disproportionality, a measure of the difference between a party’s share of

the popular vote and their share of total seats.181 The variable, labeled dis_gall, is

measured at an interval/ratio level and can be conceptualized as reflecting not just the

degree of disproportionality in a particular electoral system, but also the seat-vote

elasticity, which is often discussed but rarely examined in empirical tests (e.g. Steinmo

and Tolbert, 1998; Rogowski and Kayser, 2002). Given the greater disproportionality

between seats and votes generated by more disproportional electoral systems, all parties

in power will be constrained in their ability to raise taxes (since it increases the chances

of electoral defeat if the population does not want taxes). At the same time, small changes

in public opinion – like increasing support for green parties – will provide an incentive

for vote-maximizing parties in power to adopt part of the green program. As a result, we

should expect to see a greater willingness to increase energy taxes when the share of

green votes increases under disproportional systems.

Testing all of the electoral system hypotheses H2 to H4 involves including three variables

measuring the strength of left and green parties. Gov_left measures the cabinet

composition of government by expressing the percentage of cabinet portfolios held by

social-democratic and other left parties as a percentage of total cabinet posts, weighted by

days in government.182 The variables llc and llv measure the size and strength of “new

left” parties (as defined by Kitschelt, 1994) in terms of percentage of total cabinet posts

(llc) and share of total votes (llv). To be sure, green parties are included in the llc and llv

measures. Unfortunately, I do not have a measure for just green parties in cabinet. But

the llc and llv variables provide a reasonably good proxy, and are used in other studies

testing the role of green parties (e.g. Neumeyer, 2003). The variable green_dum is a

dummy variable indicating the presence or absence of green parties in parliament. The

variables greens and greenv measures the share of seats and votes received by parties

labeled “green” respectively, and are provided by Armingeon et al. (2009) following the

classification recommended by Lane, McKay and Newton (1997). The party variables

181 See data reference for the precise mathematical definition of this variable. 182 Adapted from Armingeon et al. 2009. See data references.

Page 214: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

202

are combined with disproportionality and PR scores to form multiplicative interaction

terms to test the conditional hypotheses H2 to H4. These include prgreen

(pr*green_dum), prgreens (pr*greens) prleft (pr*gov_left); prllc (pr*llc); disgreen

(dis_gall*green_dum); disgreens (dis_gall*greens) disllc (diss_gall*llc); disllv

(dis_gall*llv); and disgreenv (dis_gall*greenv).

A number of other variables are also included to control for the plausible influence of

several factors. First, all models include ln_rgdppc to control for potential income effects

and suggested by the literature on the Environmental Kuznet’s curve (Grossman and

Krueger, 1995; Raymond, 2004).183 I also control for a potential source of opposition to

motor fuel taxes coming from countries with a larger percentage of the population living

in rural areas with the variable rural_pop. Rural dwellers might oppose higher taxes on

gasoline and diesel because they are more likely to depend on fossil fuels to travel greater

distances by personal transportation and for machinery operated in rural areas (e.g.

generators, tractors, etc.). The same is true for less urbanized and less densely populated

countries where public transportation is less likely an option for personal travel, so I

include a control for population density, pop_den. To control for the possibility that

governments lower tax rates in an election year (as argued in the electoral cycle

literature), I include a dummy variable, electy, which is coded as 1 during years in which

an election is held.184 Finally, I control for public debt, other forms of taxation and

inflation. Consistent with a revenue maximizing view of government, especially in light

of the inelastic demand for fossil fuels, I expect greater public debt, debt_gdp to be

associated with higher rates of taxation. In contrast, I expect taxes on personal income,

itax_gdp, to be inversely related to implicit tax rates on gasoline and diesel, since the

latter can be used as a partial substitute for income taxes as a means of raising

183 The environmental Kuznet’s curve suggests a non-linear relationship between mean incomes and environmental outcomes. At low levels of economic development the environment is assumed to be a relatively low priority. However, with economic growth, environmental health is believed to take on growing importance. 184 From Swank (2007). For the United States, both Congressional and Presidential election years are coded; for Fifth Republic France, both Presidential and National Assembly elections are coded. For all other nations, national elections to the lower chamber of the national legislature are coded 1.

Page 215: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

203

government revenue.185 A control for inflation, inf_cpi_all is included to absorb the

influence of rising prices over time, and I also control for temporal autocorrelation with a

lagged dependent variable, lag_tax.

Table 5.6.1 lists all variables and identifies their label and expected relationship with

implicit carbon taxes. Further details on all variables analyzed below can be found in the

data references appendix.

Table 5.6.1: Summary of variables and hypothesized relationships Variable Label Expected relationship crude_rgdp crude oil production – openk exposure to trade – pr proportional representation + dis_gall disproportionality index – gov_left soc.dem party cabinet posts + leftv share of votes for soc.dem parties + llc new left government cabinet + llv share of votes for new left + green_dum dummy for green party rep + greens share of seats for green parties greenv share of votes for green parties + prleft left government in pr + prgreens green party seats in pr + prllc new left government in pr + disgreens green party seats in disproportional system – disllc new left government in disproportional system – disllv new left votes in disproportional system + disgreenv green party votes in disproportional system + ln_gdppc log per capita income + ln_sqgdppc186 log per capita income squared – electy election year – rural_pop rural population (% total) – pop_den population density (persons per square km) + debt_gdp total central government debt (% GDP) + itax_gdp taxes on personal income (% GDP) – inf_cpi_all general inflation rate + lag_tax lag of tax rate (t-1) + Source: see data references appendix. In order to better test the role of electoral regimes in shaping energy tax policy on motor

fuels, and to control for other variables, I run a series of regressions in separate empirical

185 In addition, we might expect citizens in countries with higher income tax rates to more forcefully oppose additional tax increases on energy. 186 Note: log per capita income squared is removed from all models analyzed in this chapter due to issues of multicolinearity. I instead analyze only the unsquared version of the variable.

Page 216: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

204

models containing a battery of independent variables. Summary statistics for all variables

are summarized in Table 5.6.2.187 These variables are variously employed in different

empirical models where the dependent variables are the implicit carbon tax rate on non-

commercial use of diesel (5.6.1) and gasoline (5.6.2).

Table 5.6.2: Summary statistics for motor fuel tax regression models Variable Observations Mean Std. Dev Min Max diesel_tax_usd 557 153.62 77.36 6.31 383.40 diesl_tax_ppp 557 160.22 80.65 7.52 385.44 gas_tax_usd 420 254.28 114.75 21.98 467.42 gas_tax_ppp 420 238.26 104.45 21.98 437.32 crude_rgdp 594 0.46 0.14 0 0.97 crude_oil_xp 583 -70.61 42.52 -100 44.96 openk 638 63.44 46.94 11.90 296.60 pr 638 0.66 0.47 0 1 dis_gall 638 5.98 5.26 0.37 24.61 green_dum 638 0.33 0.47 0 1 greens 638 1.74 2.91 0 13.33 greenv 638 2.26 3.29 0 14.4 llc 609 0.74 3.63 0 28.5 llv 609 3.48 3.76 0 18.2 gov_left 638 35.20 38.50 0 100 leftv 609 38.07 14.12 0 62 prgreen 638 0.29 0.45 0 1 prgreens 638 1.62 2.88 0 13.33 prgreenv 638 1.87 3.18 0 14.4 disgreen 638 1.24 2.97 0 23.22 disgreens 638 10.32 25.39 0 229.88 disgreenv 638 4.97 8.84 0 38.93 prllc 609 0.66 3.59 0 28.5 prllv 609 2.83 3.54 0 15.9 disllc 609 3.20 14.99 0 119.68 disllv 609 15.27 34.88 0 330.88 prleft 638 26.62 35.22 0 100 disleft 638 195.23 362.18 0 1870 ln_rgdppc 638 10.09 0.30 9.22 11.22 electy 638 0.29 0.46 0 1 pop_den 638 129.56 121.23 1.86 482.47 rural_pop 638 26.36 11.55 2.68 58 debt_gdp 509 49.98 29.70 0.822 163.83 itax_gdp 638 13.84 5.10 2.86 31.18 inf_cpi_all 638 4.89 4.81 -0.89 28.88 Each independent variable summarized in table 5.6.2 is included in various regression

models summarized and described in separate sections on diesel and gasoline. In

particular, I present results of several models in three distinct tables for each fuel, for a

187 Table reports data file totals. Regression models do not necessarily use all observations.

Page 217: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

205

total of 6 primary tables. Each model is estimated with two different estimators – panel-

corrected standard errors and clustered (robust) standard errors.

The first table in each section examines H2, the “ideological space hypothesis” and looks

to find a positive and statistically significant relationship between green and left party

representation and tax rates under PR, holding other factors constant. This hypothesis is

tested in several models using prgreen (the effect of at least one green member in the

lower legislature under PR); prgreens (the incremental effect of increasing the proportion

of green seats in parliament under PR); prllc (the impact of green/new-left cabinet

portfolios in government under PR); and prleft (the incremental effect of left party

cabinet government under PR).

The second table examines H3, the “disproportional constraints” hypothesis and looks to

find a negative and statistically significant relationship between green and left party

representation in government/legislature and tax rates under disproportional systems,

holding constant other variables in the model. This hypothesis is tested in several models

using the interaction terms disgreen (the effect of at least one green member in the lower

legislature interacted with disproportionality); disgreens (the effect of increasing the

share of total legislative seats held by green parties interacted with disproportionality);

disllc (the effect of increasing the share of cabinet posts to green/new-left parties

interacted with disproportionality); and, disleft (the effect of increasing the share of

cabinet posts held by left-wing parties interacted with disproportionality).

The third table examines H4, the “electoral incentives” hypothesis and looks to find a

positive and statistically significant relationship between the share of votes for green and

green/new-left parties and tax rates under disproportional systems, controlling for other

determinants of energy tax rates. This hypothesis is tested in different models using the

interaction terms disgreenv (the effect of increasing the share of votes to the green party

interacted with disproportionality) and disllv (the effect of increasing the share of votes to

new-left/green parties interacted with disproportionality).

Page 218: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

206

5.6.1: Diesel In contrast to fossil fuels used for industrial purposes, implicit carbon tax rates on non-

commercial use of diesel fuel are relatively large (with the exception of the U.S., New

Zealand and Canada, where diesel is taxed at a rate roughly equal to the average implicit

carbon tax on heavy fuel oil in Sweden). Like the tax rates levied on industrial fuels,

however, large cross-country differences exist. Figure 5.6.1.1 arranges countries from

high to low in terms of the average implicit carbon tax rate levied on diesel fuel used for

non-commercial use (i.e. private transport). 188

Figure 5.6.1.1: Implicit carbon tax on diesel fuel for household consumer use

Source: IEA Energy Prices and Taxes (various volumes) As can be seen in Figure 5.6.1.1, large tax differentials exist, even among similarly

situated countries in the global political economy. For instance, the average implicit

carbon tax on diesel in oil producing Norway (average real per capita GDP $33,619) is

188 Note: Canada refers to industry tax. Households for all others.

Page 219: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

207

roughly four times as large as that in oil exporting Canada (average real per capita GDP

$26,577). Although equally dependent on crude oil imports, the implicit carbon tax on

diesel in Japan is roughly half that applied in Switzerland. Part of the reason for these

differences appears to be accounted for by differences in political institutions, like the

electoral system (Figure 5.6.1.2).

Figure 5.6.1.2: Implicit carbon tax rate on (non-commercial) diesel fuel by electoral regime (H1)

As is clear from Figure 5.6.1.2, countries with proportional representation tax diesel fuel

at a higher rate than do countries with majoritarian electoral systems. The box plot on the

left compares the distribution of implicit carbon tax rates on diesel across the two

categories of electoral regimes. Consistent with H1, it is clear from this box plot that the

median tax rate under PR tends to be higher (close to $200USD/tonne of CO2) than the

median tax rate under majoritarian single member plurality systems (about

$100USD/tonne of CO2). Similarly, the bar chart to the right provides further evidence of

an institutional effect. The bar chart depicts the mean difference in tax rates on diesel, in

Page 220: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

208

constant 2000 USD per tonne of carbon dioxide over the period 1978-2006, across two

categories of electoral systems. The mean under PR ($168USD/tCO2) is substantially

larger than the mean implicit carbon tax rate on diesel under majoritarian systems

($125USD/tCO2). Moreover, a ttest of unequal variances confirms this difference as

being statistically significant at a level of p<0.0005, with majoritarian countries applying

an tax rate averaging between $28 and $58 USD/tCO2 less than those applied on the same

fuel under PR, 95 times out of 100. We thus find some empirical support for the

hypothesis that PR systems should impose higher implicit carbon taxes than majoritarian

regimes (H1). The next three tables test hypotheses H2 to H4, controlling for the

plausible effects of other variables.

Page 221: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

209

Table 5.6.1.1: Diesel tax regression models testing the ideological space hypothesis (H2) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster lag_rtax 0.702*** 0.702*** 0.743*** 0.743*** 0.750*** 0.750*** 0.756*** 0.756*** (0.0603) (0.0294) (0.0606) (0.0352) (0.0569) (0.0401) (0.0607) (0.0385) crude_rgdp 35.46 35.46 67.06 67.06 78.44 78.44 80.60 80.60 (129.3) (85.88) (131.8) (115.9) (130.4) (134.1) (130.0) (128.3) openk -0.587* -0.587** -0.590* -0.590** -0.374 -0.374 -0.447 -0.447* (0.274) (0.201) (0.270) (0.198) (0.289) (0.268) (0.261) (0.181) log_rgdppc 27.82 27.82 37.86 37.86* 38.44 38.44 40.26 40.26* (20.65) (18.68) (21.17) (17.24) (21.67) (21.27) (21.82) (18.03) debt_gdp 0.307*** 0.307* 0.244** 0.244 0.355*** 0.355* 0.311** 0.311* (0.0924) (0.128) (0.0895) (0.118) (0.0946) (0.132) (0.0964) (0.123) electy 2.250 2.250 2.325 2.325 2.384 2.384 2.891 2.891 (2.159) (2.143) (2.160) (2.285) (2.128) (2.302) (2.203) (2.276) inf_cpi_all -0.748 -0.748 -0.753 -0.753 -0.484 -0.484 -0.563 -0.563 (0.604) (0.568) (0.584) (0.714) (0.566) (0.753) (0.599) (0.717) pr -19.91** -19.91* -2.355 -2.355 -0.621 -0.621 4.709 4.709 (7.283) (7.357) (7.733) (6.452) (7.453) (5.555) (8.569) (5.503) green_dum -5.752 -5.752 (5.393) (5.517) greenpr 32.99*** 32.99*** (7.700) (8.387) greens -0.545 -0.545 (0.923) (1.279) greenspr 3.020** 3.020 (1.142) (2.060) llc -5.632** -5.632*** (1.784) (0.805) llcpr 5.204** 5.204*** (1.710) (0.931) gov_left -0.0204 -0.0204 (0.0449) (0.105) leftpr 0.0171 0.0171 (0.0456) (0.126) _cons -234.9 -203.8 -341.5 -317.3 -358.0 -341.9 -373.2 -357.1 (210.1) (183.0) (214.6) (169.5) (219.2) (203.8) (222.2) (176.5) N 377 377 377 377 362 362 377 377 R2 0.918 0.753 0.914 0.741 0.915 0.739 0.912 0.734 Standard errors in parentheses; panel coefficients excluded * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001

The basic results in Table 5.6.1.1 support the ideological space hypothesis. Indeed,

excluding the left-wing PR interaction, five of six coefficients on green party and PR are

significant at least the 0.05 level. In each model, the dependent variable is the implicit tax

rate on diesel fuel for non-commercial (i.e. household) consumer use, in constant 2000

Page 222: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

210

USD per tonne of CO2. Using different measures of green party representation and

green/left party cabinet, the argument that PR systems open up ideological space for the

imposition of higher diesel tax rates generally holds. Interestingly, the coefficient on

crude oil production is consistently positive, though it is never significant. Consistent

with expectations, the coefficient on trade exposure is consistently negative and

significant across most models. The controls for election year and inflation appear to

have no impact, while the size of the central government’s debt is consistently associated

with significantly higher tax rates on diesel fuel, as expected. As indicated by the

adjusted R-square, the models estimated with PCSE’s consistently perform better in

terms of explained variance.

Models 1 & 2 examine the impact of PR when green parties are represented in the

legislature. Holding constant crude oil production, exposure to trade, income levels,

central government debt, election year, levels of inflation and controlling for a temporal

lag, the marginal impact of green party representation is positively and significantly

associated with higher implicit carbon tax rates on diesel fuel in PR regimes. This is true

whether green party representation is measured with a simple dummy indicating the

presence or absence of greens in the legislature (model 1) or when the percentage of total

legislative seats held by greens is used (model 2). In each case, PR systems appear to

open up political space for the implementation of green taxes, as expected. The one

caveat – the cluster robust estimates are significantly less forgiving in one instance, and

using this estimator produces insignificant results in model 2.

Similarly, PR systems appear to condition the ability of green/new-left parties to

implement higher taxes on diesel, once in government. Models 3 and 4 present the results

of regressions when using green/new-left parties in cabinet (model 3) and social

democratic party cabinet posts (model 4), respectively. Controlling for all other variables

in the model, green/new-left cabinet posts are associated with significantly higher tax

rates on diesel under PR regimes, as expected. This result is robust across both types of

estimators used (model 3). However, the coefficients on social democratic cabinet posts

and PR (leftpr) fail to achieve significance. In contrast to what was found in earlier

Page 223: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

211

regressions on industry fuels, the impact of social democratic parties on diesel tax for

private household use is less clear. Interestingly, when the same model is fit to the same

data, but for industrial use of diesel, the social democratic and PR interaction becomes

significant. It thus appears as though left parties are more effective in imposing tax rates

on industry than consumers. Returning to consumer taxes, it is clear that the impact of

green and new/left green parties on household diesel tax rates under PR is consistently

significant. This interactive relationship is illustrated in Figure 5.6.1.3, using greens in

parliament under PR as an example.

Figure 5.6.1.3: The marginal effect of green parties in the legislature under PR (H2)

Figure 5.6.1.3 graphically depicts the marginal effect of green party representation on

diesel tax rates by electoral regime. As can be seen, the presence of green parties in the

legislature has a large positive effect on diesel tax rates in proportional systems (where

PR =1). As expected, this impact is decreasing and becomes insignificant moving from

PR to plurality SMP systems (PR=0). Under plurality systems, the dominant parties, who

Page 224: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

212

rarely require green party support to implement their preferred policy programs, can

safely ignore the policy preferences of greens. In such systems, therefore, the impact of

green party representation is muted, as suggested in Figure 5.6.1.3.

Having found some evidence to support H2, the ideological space hypothesis, I now turn

to a different measure of proportionality that more adequately captures the effect of

electoral systems. Recall that the argument in 5.1 predicts that more disproportional

systems should constrain the ability of smaller parties – e.g. green/new-left parties – to

implement their policy programs. This is due to multiple factors. First, it is often

remarked that disproportional systems typically favour large parties that depend on and

target the electoral support of geographically concentrated interests at the expense of

policies targeting broader welfare (Rodden, 2007; Fredriksson and Millimet, 2004).

Moreover, disproportional systems typically produce majority governments, thereby

reducing the electoral threat of smaller parties, as well as their importance as coalitional

partners (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998). Finally, in light of its impact on the governing

regime, disproportional systems generate clearer lines of accountability between voters

and governments, making it easier for voters to “punish” governments who raise taxes

(Persson and Tabellini, 2008). For all of these reasons, we should expect the marginal

effect of green/new-left parties on tax rats to decline under more disproportional systems

(H3). The empirical validity of this hypothesis is examined in the models summarized in

Table 5.6.1.2.

Page 225: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

213

Table 5.6.1.2: Diesel tax regression models testing the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3) Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster lag_rtax 0.696*** 0.696*** 0.721*** 0.721*** 0.721*** 0.721*** (0.0577) (0.0321) (0.0564) (0.0353) (0.0569) (0.0412) net_oil_xp 0.0320 0.0320 0.0439 0.0439 0.0982 0.0982 (0.0485) (0.0465) (0.0433) (0.0382) (0.0506) (0.0533) openk -0.546* -0.546* -0.650** -0.650** -0.605* -0.605* (0.238) (0.225) (0.244) (0.217) (0.274) (0.232) log_rgdppc 44.47* 44.47* 59.30** 59.30** 62.70** 62.70** (20.72) (21.01) (20.71) (19.03) (22.11) (20.39) debt_gdp 0.282** 0.282 0.220* 0.220 0.328** 0.328 (0.0995) (0.175) (0.0917) (0.163) (0.101) (0.180) itax_gdp -2.235* -2.235* -2.103* -2.103 -1.987* -1.987 (1.060) (1.027) (0.969) (1.075) (0.962) (1.106) electy 1.794 1.794 1.777 1.777 2.206 2.206 (2.308) (1.900) (2.225) (1.983) (2.326) (2.002) inf_cpi_all -0.844 -0.844 -0.749 -0.749 -0.595 -0.595 (0.765) (0.707) (0.704) (0.825) (0.693) (0.843) yr_dis_gall 0.423 0.423 0.811 0.811 -0.320 -0.320 (0.464) (0.663) (0.420) (0.763) (0.361) (0.895) green_dum 20.27*** 20.27** (6.114) (5.744) greendis -1.473* -1.473 (0.734) (0.839) greens 3.596*** 3.596* (0.752) (1.358) greensdis -0.926*** -0.926** (0.236) (0.297) llc 0.497 0.497 (0.372) (0.380) llcdis -0.203 -0.203** (0.105) (0.0637) _cons -373.2 -349.3 -530.8* -491.6* -559.6* -527.6* (217.8) (196.5) (212.7) (179.0) (224.4) (190.2) N 336 336 336 336 321 321 R2 0.891 0.768 0.890 0.766 0.888 0.760 Standard errors in parentheses; panel coefficients excluded * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001

Page 226: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

214

The results in Table 5.6.1.2 provide additional evidence of the conditioning effect of PR

electoral regimes for the relationship between small green parties and implicit carbon tax

policy outcomes. In all, four of six coefficients on the interaction terms are significant at

a level of 0.05, and all are significant at a level of 0.1. Again the dependent variable is the

implicit tax rate on diesel fuel for non-commercial private use, in constant 2000 USD per

tonne of CO2. I substitute net crude exports for crude oil production to see if results on

this variable change, and add an additional independent variable to measure the plausible

impact of other taxes – notably taxes on personal income and capital gains – on implicit

carbon tax rates for diesel. As can be seen, the evidence of a significant mediating role

for electoral institutions is fairly robust.

Substituting net crude oil exports for crude oil production changes little across all models.

As was the case with crude oil production, net oil exports is consistently positive, but

never significant. The coefficient for trade exposure continues to be moderately

significant and negative across all models, as expected. In models 5 to 7, average per

capita income also emerges as significant. Holding other variables in the model constant,

richer countries tax diesel at relatively higher rates. Central government debt is also

significant in models estimated using the PCSE estimator. On average and holding other

variables constant, larger debt results in higher diesel taxes. Conversely, as shown by the

income tax variable, countries with relatively higher taxes on personal income and capital

gains tend to tax diesel at a lower rate. This finding provides evidence that governments

balance revenue requirements with different mixes of income and consumption taxes. It

also suggests that individuals already paying relatively high income taxes will more

strongly oppose additional taxes on consumption. Finally, the variables measuring the

impact of an election year and inflation are not significant across all models tested in

Table 5.6.1.2.

Turning to the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3), it is clear that the general

results are consistent with expectations of a conditioning role for electoral regimes.

Regardless of which measure is used – greens in parliament, share of total parliamentary

seats held by green party members, and share of cabinet posts held by green/new-left

Page 227: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

215

parties – more disproportional systems appear to constrain the ability of smaller, pro

environmental tax parties to impose higher tax rates on non-commercial use of diesel

fuel, as expected. Conversely, green party representation in parliament in proportional

systems (i.e. when disproportional is at 0) is associated with significantly larger tax rates

on diesel fuel (models 5 and 6). There are, however, two exceptions. First, when using

the Clustered estimate of standard errors in model 5, greendis is not significant at a level

of p<0.05. It is however, significant at a level of p<0.1. The same is true for the second

exception in model 7, llcdis, which is not significant at the conventional p<0.5, but is

significant at p<0.1. Figure 5.6.1.4 illustrates this reductive effect of disproportionality in

the electoral system.

Figure 5.6.1.4: Marginal effect of green seat share in disproportional systems (H3)

As can be seen from Figure 5.6.1.4, the marginal impact of increasing the share of green

seats in the legislature on implicit carbon tax rates for household use of diesel decreases

as disproportionality in the electoral system increases. Controlling for net oil exports,

Page 228: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

216

exposure to trade, per capita income level, central government debt, other sources of tax

revenue, elections, inflation and the prior year’s tax rate, the impact of additional green

seats in parliament decreases with increasing disproportionality in the electoral system.

At high levels of proportionality (i.e. low levels of disproportionality), the marginal

impact of greens in parliament on tax rates is, as expected, positively associated with

significantly higher tax rates. However, at higher levels of disproportionality, this

positive impact disappears, and actually becomes negative at higher levels of

disproportionality. As indicated in Table 5.6.1.2, the same is true for green/new-left

parties in cabinet (as measured by llc), and is consistent with the theory that in

disproportional systems, green parties are constrained – as are all other parties – in

raising tax rates, especially those that are highly visible among voters.

Because they inflate the share of seats won by particular parties (relative to their share of

votes), disproportional systems tend to favour large governing majorities, or coalitions

made up of a relatively small number of coalitional partners (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998).

In the context of dominant party government, the lines of accountability between the

government in power and policy outcomes are clearer, and voters know whom to punish

for unpopular policies, like an increase in consumption taxes.189 But just as

disproportionality makes governments more accountable – thereby constraining their

ability to make unpopular policies, the hypotheses in 5.2 suggest they also make

governments and political parties competing for power more responsive. Indeed, in

disproportional systems, small changes in the vote share can have relatively large impacts

in a party’s seat share, given the higher seat-vote elasticity inherent in disproportional

systems (c.f. Rogowski and Kayser, 2002). In contrast, governments and parties in more

proportional systems are relatively insulated from the vagaries of public opinion, since a

small change at the polls will have less of an electoral impact on their proportionally

allocated seats. It follows that while green/left parties might be more constrained to raise

taxes while in government and in the legislature, the government of the day – of

whichever political stripe – will have a greater incentive to respond to public opinion in

189 In contrast, it is more difficult for voters to identify and punish parties responsible for increasing taxes in highly proportional systems favouring coalition governments, where multiple parties can share the blame.

Page 229: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

217

disproportional systems, relative to those in proportional regimes. Vote-maximizing

parties in disproportional systems are more vulnerable vis a vis changes in public

opinion, and for this reason, policy in such systems should be more responsive to

changing popular sentiment.

This final speculation, the electoral incentive hypothesis (H4), is examined in Table

5.6.1.3. Model 8 examines the impact of increasing the share of the popular vote for

green parties (greenv) under conditions of increasingly disproportional elections

(greenvdis). Model 9 fits an identical model using an alternative measure of the green

vote (llv) under conditions of increasing disproportionality in the electoral system (llvdis).

Page 230: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

218

Table 5.6.1.3: Diesel tax regression models testing the electoral incentives hypothesis (H4) Model 8 Model 9 PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster lag_ppp 0.937*** 0.820*** 0.823*** 0.823*** (0.0138) (0.0297) (0.0170) (0.0327) crude_rgdp 3.284 68.93 66.05 66.05 (12.58) (62.21) (116.5) (51.47) openk 0.0126 -0.00829 0.184* 0.184 (0.0183) (0.169) (0.0929) (0.208) log_rgdppc -9.938* 3.772 2.840 2.840 (3.927) (11.30) (9.001) (10.68) debt_gdp 0.00882 0.335* 0.382*** 0.382* (0.0134) (0.132) (0.0481) (0.140) itax_gdp -0.111 -0.726 -0.858 -0.858 (0.109) (0.559) (0.479) (0.624) rural_pop -0.0107 1.722 2.042*** 2.042 (0.0559) (1.403) (0.298) (1.409) electy -0.308 0.314 0.560 0.560 (1.106) (1.184) (1.090) (1.206) inf_cpi_all 0.362 0.374 0.526* 0.526 (0.202) (0.913) (0.263) (0.894) yr_dis_gall -0.198 -0.998 -2.469*** -2.469 (0.187) (0.741) (0.403) (1.370) greenv 0.412* 1.157 (0.201) (0.857) greenvdis 0.0490 0.000757 (0.0273) (0.0607) llv -0.584 -0.584 (0.433) (0.845) llvdis 0.126*** 0.126 (0.0280) (0.0825) _cons 110.7** -62.62 -14.63 -65.24 (40.53) (127.3) (93.14) (122.8) N 382 382 367 367 R2 0.941 0.821 0.950 0.821 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 The fourth and final hypothesis concerning the conditioning effect of electoral

institutions is tested and summarized in Table 5.6.1.3. Though somewhat weaker, two of

four models provide some empirical support. The model specifications are similar to

those already examined except for two major differences. First, in order to test the

Page 231: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

219

sensitivity of results to alternative specifications, the dependent variable is measured in

2005 international dollars at purchasing power parities (PPP). Second, the interaction

terms examine the effect on tax levels of increasing the share of votes to green/new-left

parties under electoral systems with increasingly disproportional outcomes. Although

results are somewhat mixed, they do suggest, consistent with our hypothesis,

governments in more disproportional systems are relatively more responsive to a rise in

votes for green and new left/green parties than in less proportional systems. To be sure,

few of the variables are significant across all models. Those that obtain significance –

openness, per capita income, and debt – have been among the best performing variables

so far.

Similarly, the interaction between the share of votes for green/new-left parties and

disproportional systems also achieves significance in one of the models (Model 9). In this

model, estimated with PCSEs, greater disproportionality when green votes are at 0 is

associated with significantly smaller tax rates on diesel, as our theory predicts. Moreover,

as expected, the same model predicts an increase the vote share accruing to green/new-

left parties will result in greater tax rates in disproportional systems. Though the

alternative estimator does not result in as significant results, the interaction between

green votes and disproportional systems (greenvdis) is significant at a level of p<0.1

when PCSEs are used. Thus, using PCSEs, we find empirical support for the argument

that parties competing for power in disproportional systems are more likely to increase

tax rates on motor fuels as the share of green votes rises. This relationship, illustrated in

Figure 5.6.1.5 is worth examining in future work.

Page 232: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

220

Figure 5.6.1.5: Marginal effect of green/new-left votes in disproportional systems (H4)

Consistent with expectations, Figure 5.6.1.5 illustrates that the marginal increase in the

share of total votes for green/new-left parties is associated with significantly higher tax

rates on diesel in more disproportional systems. In other words, as the seat-vote elasticity

increases, governments are more responsive to an increase in votes for green parties. As

can be seen, this relationship only emerges when the level of disproportionality exceeds a

value of 10. As governments become more vulnerable to small changes in popular

sentiment, they have more of an incentive to adopt elements of the policy program of

increasingly popular parties. This relationship is entirely consistent with our theoretical

argument developed in Chapter 1 and the perspective of vote-maximizing parties under

conditions of increased electoral vulnerability.

Page 233: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

221

5.6.2: Gasoline The foregoing analysis of diesel tax rates provides additional evidence of the

conditioning role of electoral institutions on the capacity of green/new-left parties to

impose higher rates of taxation on carbon-based fuels, and on the incentives for other

parties to do so. This section adopts the same methodology in order to assess the extent to

which similar patterns can be found in the distribution of tax rates on a different type of

commonly used motor fuel, gasoline. Together with diesel taxes, proceeds from gasoline

taxes constitute an important source of government revenue, making up a over 90 per

cent of revenues derived from “environmentally related” taxes, which contribute

substantial revenues for OECD governments (OECD, 2007).190 At the same time, tax

rates on gasoline are among the most unpopular forms of revenue generation (Hsu et al.

2004), creating a tradeoff for governments interested in raising revenue while also

remaining in power.

As was the case with diesel tax rates, implicit rates of carbon taxation on gasoline fuel are

relatively large across OECD countries, especially when compared to explicitly labeled

carbon taxes or with implicit carbon taxes levied on other fuels. However, substantial

cross-national differences exist. Figure 5.6.2.1 arranges countries from high to low in

terms of average implicit carbon tax rates applied to gasoline. The data cover 22 of the

richest countries – on a per capita GDP basis – in the OECD.191

190 Across the OECD, revenues from environmentally related taxes are in the order of 2 – 3% of GDP. Their contribution to total tax revenues varies widely by country, however. For instance, revenues from environmentally related taxes in Denmark accounted for over 10 per cent of total tax revenues in 2003, while environmental tax revenues accounted for less than 3.5 per cent of total tax revenues in the U.S. for that same year (OECD, 2007). 191 Since fuel grades bought and sold vary across countries, tax rates on the most commonly reported fuel grade are described and analyzed in this dissertation. From a climate perspective, this mixing of fuel grades is not problematic, as all fuel grades are roughly equal in carbon content. The data refer to regular unleaded 91 RON (Research Octane Number) for Australia, Austria, Canada, Denmark, Japan, Korea, Mexico, New Zealand, and the USA; mid-grade unleaded 95 RON for all others.

Page 234: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

222

Figure 5.6.2.1: Implicit carbon tax rate on gasoline for private household use

Source: IEA Energy Prices and Taxes (various volumes) The data in Figure 5.6.2.1 summarize the average implicit tax rate on gasoline for private

household use for 22 of the richest OECD countries, in constant (2000) USD per tonne of

CO2 averaged over the years 1978-2006. Tax rates on gasoline are comparatively higher

than tax rates on diesel, and on average, gasoline is the highest taxed fossil fuel in the

OECD, on a per tonne of carbon dioxide basis. At the same time, substantial cross-

national differences exist. For instance, oil-exporting countries Canada and Norway again

lie at opposite ends of the implicit carbon tax spectrum, while substantial differences

exist among geographically proximate countries in Europe. For instance, over the period

1978-2006, the average implicit carbon tax rate applied to gasoline in Spain and

Switzerland is substantially lower than those applied in neighboring countries.

At first glance, visual inspection of the data casts some doubt on the proportional systems

hypothesis (H1), as Great Britain and France stand out as a clear cases with high implicit

Page 235: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

223

carbon taxes in the absence of PR. Notwithstanding these deviant cases, which are in part

the result of idiosyncratic factors that do not refute the primary hypotheses,192 a ttest

confirms the pattern of a significant difference (p<0.0005) in the distribution of tax rates

across PR and SMP regimes. As anticipated, implicit carbon tax rates are significantly

higher in countries where PR is the primary system for allocating legislative seats. In fact,

we can expect tax rates on gasoline in majoritarian systems to be, on average, between

$111 to $154 USD per tonne of CO2 lower than those applied in proportional systems, 95

times out of 20. This significant difference is illustrated in Figure 5.6.2.2.

Figure 5.6.2.2: Implicit carbon tax rate on gasoline by electoral regime (H1)

Figure 5.6.2.2 displays the distribution of implicit carbon tax rates on gasoline across the

two primary categories of electoral regime used in rich democratic OECD countries. As

can be seen, tax rates on gasoline used in transportation tend to be higher in PR relative to

192 These factors are discussed in section 5.7.

Page 236: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

224

majoritarian systems. For instance, the median tax rate under PR is nearly three times as

high as the median tax rate under majoritarian systems. Similarly, the difference in mean

tax rate between the two systems is a non-trivial $133 USD per tonne of CO2. These

differences are consistent with the hypothesized effect of electoral regimes (H1). In order

to better test hypotheses H2 to H4, and to control for the plausible effects of other

variables, the data are more closely examined in a series of regression models, just as was

done earlier in the case of diesel fuels. Table 5.6.2.1 begins by summarizing results of

models testing the ideological space hypothesis (H2). Like the earlier panel regressions,

models estimated with PCSEs tend to have substantially higher adjusted R-squares.

Page 237: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

225

Table 5.6.2.1: Gasoline tax regression models testing the ideological space hypothesis (H2) Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster lag_tax 0.986*** 0.801*** 0.991*** 0.804*** 1.009*** 0.806*** (0.0391) (0.0264) (0.0367) (0.0269) (0.0368) (0.0301) crude_rgdp 5.344 28.13* 4.505 26.45 -3.092 26.60 (10.26) (12.91) (9.661) (12.86) (8.944) (14.53) openk 0.000651 0.138 0.00809 0.0731 0.0662 0.239 (0.0371) (0.266) (0.0377) (0.271) (0.0571) (0.334) log_rgdppc 3.511 43.18* 2.201 43.86* 6.012 36.52 (12.83) (16.04) (13.61) (16.48) (12.95) (18.30) debt_gdp -0.0371 0.0847 -0.0507 0.0775 -0.0807* 0.127 (0.0427) (0.0641) (0.0355) (0.0624) (0.0353) (0.0898) electy 2.643 2.734 2.757 2.613 1.915 1.084 (3.086) (3.841) (3.094) (3.795) (3.043) (3.826) inf_cpi_all -0.154 1.145 -0.178 1.004 -0.0537 0.978 (0.953) (0.917) (0.939) (0.906) (0.909) (0.917) pr 5.667 -15.51 4.041 -21.68* 0.608 -32.17*** (5.154) (7.952) (4.200) (7.783) (5.165) (4.308) greenv 0.715 -0.0935 (0.868) (0.817) greenvpr -0.362 -2.264 (0.882) (2.567) greens -0.134 -1.448 (1.136) (2.522) greenspr 0.466 0.432 (1.344) (3.469) llc -4.643 -9.671*** (2.408) (1.632) llcpr 4.334* 8.867*** (2.147) (1.786) _cons -28.11 -392.0* -14.05 -394.0* -54.42 -324.5 (130.9) (151.3) (139.2) (154.7) (132.7) (170.5) N 348 348 348 348 333 333 R2 0.934 0.699 0.934 0.697 0.937 0.718 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001

Page 238: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

226

Models 1 to 3 in Table 5.6.2.1 test the hypothesis that PR systems create ideological

space for green and green/new-left parties to impose higher rates of implicit carbon

taxation on gasoline, while controlling and testing other factors. The basic results suggest

that while green legislative seats and votes do little to affect gasoline tax rates in

proportional systems, green cabinet government does play a role. At the same time, the

general findings are less conclusive than those for the previous fossil fuels – coal, heavy

fuel oil and diesel. For instance, of all the independent variables examined in model 1,

few of the variables of theoretical interest are significant. Even variables that consistently

performed well – like the inverse relationship between carbon tax rates and trade

exposure – fail to conform to expectations in the gasoline tax regressions presented in

Table 5.6.2.1. The only exceptions are crude oil production and per capita income, which

are moderately significant when the cluster robust estimator is used. However, there is no

evidence to support the claim that increasing the vote for green parties under proportional

systems will lead to an increase in tax rates on gasoline, regardless of which estimator is

used.

The same is true for the second model (2). As expected, per capita income is significantly

associated with higher tax rates on gasoline, but this is only the case using the cluster

robust estimates of standard errors. The only other variable to attain significance (besides

the temporal lag) is PR. Here, PR is significantly associated with lower tax rates on

gasoline when the share of green seats is 0. This is consistent with the theory that the

effect of PR regimes on implicit rates of carbon taxation is conditioned by the presence of

green/left parties. When PR is included by itself (without the interaction in a model not

shown), its effect is positive and significant, as expected. However, the non-significance

of greenspr is not consistent with theoretical expectations. As is the case with green party

votes, increasing the share of green party seats in the legislature appears to have no effect

on gasoline tax rates under PR systems.

In all, model 3 is most consistent with expectations. Using both estimators, the coefficient

on the share of green/new-left party cabinet posts is associated with significantly higher

taxes under PR systems, consistent with the ideological space hypothesis. This might be

Page 239: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

227

expected, given the fact that green/new left cabinet portfolios is the best measure used

here that captures green party participation in government.193 Holding constant crude oil

production, exposure to trade, per capita income levels, debt, election year, and

controlling for the inflation rate and autocorrelation, the interaction between green/new-

left parties in cabinet and systems of proportional representation is associated with

significantly higher tax rates on gasoline, as expected. This is true using both estimates

for standard errors in the presence of heteroskedasticity and contemporaneously

correlated errors across panels. The marginal effect of green party members in cabinet in

plurality and proportional systems is visually depicted in Figure 5.6.2.3.

Figure 5.6.2.3: The marginal effect of green/new left party cabinet portfolios by electoral regime (H2)

Figure 5.6.2.3 depicts the marginal effect of increasing green and new left party

representation in government, under plurality and proportional electoral systems. As can 193 To be sure, the llc is a measure of greens and other “new left” parties in government as coded by Swank, who does not have a separate measure for green party only.

Page 240: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

228

be seen, moving from simple plurality (PR=0) to a proportional electoral system (PR=1)

results in a significant increase in the marginal impact of green/left cabinet posts on

gasoline taxes (about $8 USD per tonne of carbon dioxide), when holding other variables

in Model 3 at their mean. This result is consistent with expectations and lends support to

the ideological space hypothesis, which suggests that green parties are more able to

increase environmental taxes when in power under proportional electoral systems.

Turning now to the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3), Models 4 to 6 test the

idea that the ability of green parties in the legislature/government to increase implicit

carbon tax rates on gasoline will be reduced under more disproportional electoral systems

(H3). The empirical results of each model are summarized in Table 5.6.2.2.

Page 241: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

229

Table 5.6.2.2: Gasoline tax regression models testing the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3) Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster lag_rtax 0.667*** 0.667*** 0.664*** 0.664*** 0.661*** 0.661*** (0.0920) (0.0352) (0.0902) (0.0326) (0.0854) (0.0348) net_oil_xp 0.0512 0.0512 0.0535 0.0535 0.119 0.119 (0.208) (0.290) (0.232) (0.294) (0.201) (0.296) openk -0.676 -0.676* -0.623 -0.623 -0.526 -0.526 (0.424) (0.278) (0.372) (0.348) (0.350) (0.339) log_rgdppc 42.01* 42.01 42.66* 42.66 35.05 35.05 (20.49) (20.78) (21.39) (22.10) (20.48) (22.31) debt_gdp 0.239 0.239 0.236 0.236 0.328* 0.328 (0.174) (0.217) (0.155) (0.216) (0.150) (0.231) itax_gdp -4.095*** -4.095* -4.171*** -4.171* -3.447*** -3.447 (1.168) (1.873) (1.091) (1.861) (0.918) (1.867) electy 3.205 3.205 3.133 3.133 2.825 2.825 (3.268) (4.821) (3.167) (4.806) (3.241) (4.710) inf_cpi_all -0.971 -0.971 -1.002 -1.002 -0.925 -0.925 (1.542) (1.595) (1.458) (1.554) (1.391) (1.561) yr_dis_gall 0.193 0.193 0.159 0.159 -0.277 -0.277 (0.602) (0.697) (0.499) (0.719) (0.459) (0.780) green_dum -4.700 -4.700 (12.75) (6.905) greendis -0.610 -0.610 (1.242) (0.590) greens 0.481 0.481 (1.390) (2.432) greensdis -0.946* -0.946 (0.466) (0.529) llc 0.0507 0.0507 (0.642) (0.586) llcdis -0.382* -0.382** (0.161) (0.102) _cons -297.6 -248.6 -304.2 -254.4 -237.8 -193.1 (202.1) (200.9) (211.0) (209.0) (199.8) (210.9) N 327 327 327 327 327 327 R2 0.941 0.624 0.942 0.630 0.943 0.635 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001

Page 242: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

230

The basic results in Table 5.6.2.2 provide additional evidence of the conditioning effect

of PR electoral regimes for the relationship between green parties and implicit carbon

taxes. Models 4 to 6 present regression results using tax rates on gasoline in constant

2000 USD per tonne of carbon dioxide. I substitute net crude oil exports for crude oil

production to see if results change, and add an additional independent variable – the

personal and corporate taxes on income and capital gains as a percentage of GDP – to test

for the plausible impact of the tax mix on implicit carbon tax rates for gasoline. Even

after these alternative model specifications are introduced, evidence of a significant

mediating effect of electoral institutions on implicit carbon tax rates is fairly robust.

Substituting net crude oil exports for crude oil production makes little difference to the

expected direction and significance of the effect of oil producers on gasoline tax rates,

which remain positive and insignificant. The coefficient on trade openness is, as

expected, negative, but is only significant in model 4 using the cluster robust estimator.

Per capita income is consistently positive and significant in two of the three models using

PCSEs, suggesting that richer countries levy higher taxes on gasoline. Although central

government debt fails to reach significance across all models, coefficients are positive as

expected (more debt translates into greater need for revenue and thus higher taxes).

Consistent with expectations, the income tax variable is associated with significantly

lower gasoline tax rates. This finding is consistent with the expectation that the overall

tax mix is an important explanatory factor in accounting for differences in consumption

taxes on fossil fuels, as well as the idea that high income tax countries will face greater

resistance to additional consumption taxes. This also helps explain why, in the absence of

PR (but in the presence of greens), France is a high motor fuel tax country, as it has the

lowest tax rates on personal and corporate taxes on income and capital gains of all

countries in the sample. The variables indicating an election year and the inflation rate

are not significant.

Returning to the disproportional constraints hypothesis (H3), two of the three models

produce results that are consistent with theoretical expectations. The interaction between

Page 243: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

231

at least one member of the green party in the legislature, and disproportionality in the

electoral system, is negative but insignificant (model 1). However, when a more precise

measure of green representation is used (i.e. share of legislative seats held by green

parties), the results are significant at a level of p<0.05 (using PCSE) and p<0.01 (using

cluster robust standard errors) in model 5. Moreover, model 6 finds that increasing

green/new left cabinet government has a reductive effect on gasoline tax rates in

disproportional regimes, just as the theory predicts. This last result is illustrated in Figure

5.6.2. 4.

Figure 5.6.2.4: The marginal effect of green/left cabinet in disproportional systems (H3)

As shown in Figure 5.6.2.4, the marginal impact of the share of cabinet portfolios held by

green/new-left parties on implicit carbon tax rates for gasoline decreases as

disproportionality in the electoral system increases. Controlling for net exports of crude

oil, exposure to trade, per capita income, central government debt, other sources of tax

Page 244: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

232

revenue, elections, inflation and the prior year’s tax rate, the impact of additional cabinet

portfolios held by green/new-left parties decreases with increasing disproportionality in

the electoral system. Consistent with theoretical expectations, the marginal impact of

green/new-left government on tax rates is higher at low levels of disproportionality.

However, as disproportionality increases, the ability of green/new-left government to

impose higher tax rates on gasoline appears to diminish, as parties become more

vulnerable to voters in disproportional electoral systems, just as H3 suggests.

The key causal mechanism that is responsible for the disproportional constraints is the

seat-vote elasticity, which is greater in disproportional systems. As the label implies,

disproportional systems are those that allocate a disproportionate amount of seats to a

given level of the popular vote. In such situations, typically the product of majoritarian

systems, small changes in the vote share can have relatively large impacts in terms of

seats, resulting in high seat-vote elasticity. Under such conditions, I hypothesize that the

electoral fortunes of parties are more vulnerable, and therefore more likely to respond to

changes in popular sentiment. This electoral incentives hypothesis (H4) is examined in

Table 5.6.2.3. The dependent variable (gasoline tax) in both models is measured at

purchasing power parities (PPPs) as opposed to USD, as a check for robustness.

Page 245: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

233

Table 5.6.2.3: Gasoline tax regression models testing the electoral incentives hypothesis (H4) Model 7 Model 8 PCSE Cluster PCSE Cluster lag_ppp 0.949*** 0.715*** 0.707*** 0.707*** (0.0160) (0.0337) (0.0593) (0.0338) crude_rgdp 14.42 57.79*** 59.76 59.76*** (9.676) (9.582) (39.03) (9.530) openk 0.0331 0.0615 0.0594 0.0594 (0.0317) (0.107) (0.138) (0.155) log_rgdppc -17.07* -6.326 -4.556 -4.556 (7.239) (9.536) (9.189) (10.36) debt_gdp 0.00201 0.381*** 0.384*** 0.384** (0.0269) (0.0990) (0.0928) (0.105) itax_gdp -0.269 -0.547 -0.693 -0.693 (0.184) (0.860) (0.611) (0.895) rural_pop -0.0869 0.750 0.673 0.673 (0.0748) (0.727) (0.824) (0.770) electy 0.344 0.655 -0.105 -0.105 (1.888) (2.381) (1.621) (2.319) inf_cpi_all -2.055*** -1.332** -1.262 -1.262* (0.570) (0.450) (0.690) (0.467) yr_dis_gall -0.378* -0.637** -0.927** -0.927* (0.185) (0.188) (0.334) (0.395) greenv 0.509 -0.477 (0.366) (0.710) greenvdis 0.0708* 0.0927 (0.0339) (0.0468) llv -1.402 -1.402** (0.879) (0.459) llvdis 0.0819** 0.0819* (0.0316) (0.0373) _cons 195.3* 102.6 95.78 95.82 (77.24) (104.1) (98.67) (108.4) N 336 336 321 321 R2 0.975 0.774 0.983 0.777 Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001 The basic results presented in Table 5.6.2.3 provide evidence to support the electoral

incentives hypothesis. In fact, 3 of 4 coefficients on the interactive vote variables are

significant at conventional levels. For instance, model 7 examines the impact of

Page 246: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

234

increasing the share of popular vote obtained by green parties (greenv) on tax rates, under

conditions of increasingly disproportionate (or highly elastic) electoral systems. As can

be seen crude oil production, per capita income, debt and inflation are variously

significant depending on which estimator is used. The only variable to be consistently

significant across both estimates is yr_dis_gall, which is the 5 year moving average of the

level of disproportionality produced by a country’s electoral system. Consistent with

theoretical expectations, more disproportional election results are associated with

significantly lower tax rates on gasoline fuel. For the theoretical reasons discussed earlier,

it is more difficult for governments in disproportional systems to raise taxes on gasoline,

because such charges are visible and can therefore jeopardize a government’s chances of

re-election, especially where the seat-vote elasticity is particularly high, as it is in highly

disproportional systems. In addition, as indicated by the greenvdis, increasing the share

of total votes to green parties is positively associated with higher implicit carbon tax rates

on fossil fuels, like gasoline. This variable is significant at a level of p<0.05 using PCSEs

and at a level of p<0.1 using cluster robust estimates of standard errors, as presented in

model 7.

As a further test, I substitute green vote with votes for green and other new left parties, as

coded by Swank (2007). The results provide additional empirical support. Crude oil

production is again significant, but only in one model. Debt emerges as associated with

significantly higher tax rates on gasoline, as expected since gasoline taxes can provide a

non-trivial amount of government revenue for governments in debt. Consistent with our

theory, the variable measuring disproportionality – when green votes is at 0 – produces

smaller tax rates on gasoline. As the environment becomes increasingly salient, to the

point where an increasing proportion of the population votes green, implicit carbon tax

rates tend to rise in disproportional systems, as governments seek to maximize votes to

assure re-election.194 This dynamic is illustrated in Figure 5.6.5.6.2.4.

194 Alternatively, one might speculate that the rising support for greens creates the conditions for governments to raise gasoline taxes for revenue purposes.

Page 247: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

235

Figure 5.6.2.4: Marginal effect of green votes in disproportional systems (H4)

As can be seen in Figure 5.6.2.4, the marginal increase in the share of total votes for

green parties is associated with significantly higher tax rates on gasoline in more

disproportional systems, just as our theory predicts. At low levels of disproportionality,

there is less incentive for small changes in votes for greens to have a direct influence on

tax policy. As disproportionality in the electoral increases, however, and as governments

become more vulnerable to a small change in the popular vote, there are more incentives

to respond to popular sentiment. This relationship is consistent with a view of political

parties as vote-maximizers, and with the argument that electoral systems shape not just

the access to power of greens, but also the strategies of other parties engaged in electoral

competition.

Page 248: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

236

Robustness checks As should be clear, the foregoing analysis of implicit carbon taxes on motor fuels

includes a series of built-in robustness checks integrated into the various models

examined. Different models were estimated using different operationalizations of the

dependent variable (USD and PPP), different estimators (PCSE and Clustered robust

standard errors), and different model specifications included/excluded different

independent variables. In addition, a series of pre and post estimation checks were run

discussed in section 5.6, which determined the appropriateness of using fixed effects,

temporal lags, and estimators robust to serial and contemporaneous correlation. This

section briefly extends robustness and diagnostic checks by commenting on two further

issues in TSCS data, multicolinearity and unit roots.

Multicolinearity tests, specifically a correlation matrix of all variables included in the

models (excluding the interactive terms) reveal no problems of collinearity. The two most

correlated independent variables are PR (pr) and disproportioanlity (yr_dis_gall), which

are expected to be correlated and are never used in the same regression models. The two

second most highly correlated independent variables are PR (pr) and income tax

(itax_gdp). These latter variables are theoretically distinct, but it is interesting to note that

PR systems tend to be correlated with lower levels of income tax (and as shown here,

higher consumption taxes). The correlation matrix is provided in the data appendix.

Finally, I follow the advice of Beck (2006) in checking for unit roots. While variables

containing unit roots can invalidate results (Kennedy, 2003: 325), the tendency for

“random walks” in TSCS data is not very common (Beck and Katz, 2009). However,

Beck (2006) warns that estimation of models with a lagged dependent variable and or

with serially correlated errors (as is the case here) can lead to such misleading results as

spurious regressions. To guard against this possibility, I check to see if residuals appear

stationary after estimating the dynamic models discussed in 5.6. Regressing the residuals

Page 249: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

237

on their lags, all coefficients approximate a value of 1. According to this test, the

residuals appear stationary and no further tests are performed.195

5.7: Summary and discussion

The results presented in sections 5.5 (implicit carbon taxes on industry) and 5.6 (implicit

carbon taxes on households) provide considerable evidence in support of the hypotheses

examined in this dissertation. In general, the results clearly demonstrate systematic

differences in carbon energy tax rates across majoritarian and proportional systems. I

also find that the partisan makeup of government matters for policy, particularly in

proportional systems.196 These results hold across the 4 commonly used fossil fuels

examined here, covering both the industrial and household sectors. Specifically, with

reference to political parties favouring higher energy taxes, and to electoral competition

between parties, the theoretical argument developed in Chapter 1, and analyzed in

Chapter 5, helps to better understand why these institutional differences matter, and to

specify the conditions under which proportional systems are most likely to result in

higher rates of implicit taxes on carbon-based energy sources. Methodologically, the

difference between models estimated with PCSEs and cluster-robust standard errors is

substantial in terms of the adjusted R-squares.

H1: The PR hypothesis

In general, the most robust finding is that the type of electoral system employed by

countries has an influence on rates of carbon-energy taxation. This hypothesis is

consistently supported by statistically significant differences in mean tax rates across

majoritarian and proportional systems. Across all fuels examined here, PR systems

generally tax fossil fuels at a higher rate, consistent with theoretical expectations. I argue

that PR systems better insulate governments from the vagaries of public opinion,

195 Attempts at implementing a Levin-Lin-Chu test were unsuccessful due to the requirement of a strongly balanced panel. 196 To be sure, whether the ideological preferences of government matters is an important debate in political science. The evidence presented here suggests that the ideological makeup of government matters most under proportional systems.

Page 250: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

238

allowing them to increase taxes on energy without necessarily being “punished” by

voters. They also produce incentives for parties to target broader social welfare goals

(like a better environment), given the larger constituency districts. In contrast,

governments in majoritarian systems are more vulnerable to small changes in public

opinion, and for this reason are less likely to implement tax increases. They are also more

likely to target policy benefits for key districts, foregoing policy with broader social

welfare goals (Persson and Tabellini, 2008). However, the PR variable by itself leaves

much to be explained.197 Indeed, there are some exceptional cases unaccounted for by

PR, and there are clear differences in tax rates even among countries with PR as well. In

order to better understand these differences, I consider the interaction between the

electoral system and the ideological orientation of different parties.

H2: The ideological space hypothesis

Evidence in support of the disproportional constraints hypothesis is strong across all

fossil fuels. This hypothesis specifies that, by increasing the importance of smaller

parties, PR systems should lead to higher taxes. Thus, the political agency is in the form

of green and left parties, which previous studies clearly show prefer higher taxes on

energy for environmental and other reasons. For industrial use of coal and heavy fuel oil,

tax rates are clearly influenced by left-wing cabinet government, and this influence is

particularly pronounced in countries using PR systems to translate vote shares into seat

shares, as our theory suggests. Interestingly, traditional left-wing governments are less

able to predict tax rates on household use of motor fuels used for transportation. Instead,

green/new-left parties are associated with significantly higher tax rates for household

fuels, under PR. This might be expected given the former’s emphasis on protecting

labour rights while the latter’s emphasis tends to be for environmental protection and

broader equity goals (Kitschelt, 1988; 1994). For instance, in the case of diesel fuel,

green party strength – whether measured by the presence/absence of greens in the

legislature, the share of seats to green parties, or the share of cabinet posts held by

green/new-left parties – are strongly associated with significantly higher tax rates across

all models analyzed. In contrast, left wing cabinet government appears to have no

197 This is why I consider the evidence in support of H1 to be “moderate,” as indicated in Table 5.7.1.

Page 251: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

239

influence on household tax rates for diesel fuel (though they are associated with higher

tax rates on industry use of diesel fuel, not reported here). Perhaps owing to more

complicated politics, the results are somewhat less consistent in the case of gasoline. The

share of green votes and the share of green seats appear unrelated to rates of gasoline

taxation under PR (Table 5.6.2.1.). However, when green/new-left parties are in power in

PR systems, we find significantly larger taxes on gasoline, as expected. To be sure, green

members in cabinet are precisely where we might expect greens to have the greatest

influence on policy, so the fact that greens in the legislature fail to translate into higher

taxes on gasoline makes intuitive sense.

H3: The disproportional constraints hypothesis

The idea that disproportional systems constrain the ability of parties to increase green

taxes is also strongly supported across all fossil fuels. The causal logic specifies that

disproportional systems increase the lines of accountability between governments and the

electorate. Since disproportional systems tend to produce majority government, voters

know whom to “punish” when taxes are increased. Moreover, governments are more

vulnerable to small changes in the vote share, since disproportionality implies that even a

small change in votes can have a large impact on the composition of the legislature. For

both these reasons, governments are more accountable and vulnerable, and will thus be

constrained in their ability to increase taxes (usually unpopular policy). It follows that the

ability of green/left parties to implement higher taxes will be constrained under

disproportional systems, and evidence of this effect can be found across the board. For

instance, this argument holds for the ability of left-wing parties to increase taxes on coal

and heavy fuel oil, even when robustness checks are performed. Similarly, nearly all

models show an inverse relationship between greens/new-left party strength under

increasing disproportionality, and the opposite (i.e. higher taxes with increasing

green/new-left strength under proportional systems) is by definition also true.

H4: The electoral incentives hypothesis

The final hypothesis regarding the institutional incentives created by electoral systems

also receives some empirical support, and should be investigated in further work. This

Page 252: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

240

hypothesis specifies that, while green parties will be constrained in disproportional

systems, voting for green parties in such systems will induce other parties to adopt green

policies, in order to maximize vote gains and minimize vote losses, thus leading to higher

rates of green taxation. This hypothesis is tested in the diesel and gasoline tax

regressions, both of which provide empirical support. For instance, I find that voting for

greens and green/new-left parties is associated with significantly higher tax rates on

gasoline under highly disproportional systems. Though weaker, these findings also hold

for diesel when the PCSE estimator is used (Table 5.6.1.3).

To conclude, the general performance of each hypothesis is summarized in Table 5.7.1.

Table 5.7.1: Performance of primary research hypotheses across fuels H1 H2 H3 H4 coal

moderate

very strong

very strong

not tested

heavy fuel oil

moderate

strong

strong

not tested

diesel

moderate

very strong

very strong

moderate

gasoline

moderate

moderate

strong

strong

Empirically, the variables used to test hypotheses H2 to H4 are consistently the best

performing variables used in the fossil fuel tax regressions. Other variables that perform

well include government debt levels, suggesting that fossil fuel tax rates are also

influenced by government revenue needs. This is particularly true in the case of tax rates

on gasoline. Consistent with the existing literature, exposure to international trade is only

sometimes associated with lower tax rates, and the interests of fossil fuel producers varies

by fuel type, with coal producers apparently having the most influence over tax rates

affecting their product.

Page 253: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

241

Outliers While the goal of this research is to identify patterns in the way countries tax fossil fuels,

and to explain these differences with a parsimonious account of the interaction between

parties and the electoral systems, two outlying cases deserve brief mention as cases for

further exploration. These cases include France and Great Britain, which apply relatively

large tax rates to motor fuels, despite their use of majoritarian electoral systems. To be

sure, further research into the electoral incentives in both countries could assist in

accounting for these deviant cases within the logic outlined in this dissertation. In

addition, the outlier status of both is likely best explained with reference to a confluence

of idiosyncratic factors. I briefly offer some initial thoughts here.

The French case appears to be a clear example of the importance of a country’s overall

tax-mix. For instance, when considering France’s historical tax policy mix, it is clear this

country has consistently maintained relatively low rates on personal and corporate

income (Peters, 1980). In fact, averaged over the period between 1978-2006, France

imposes the lowest personal and corporate taxes on income and capital gains (category

1000 in OECD Revenue Statistics) across the entire 22 countries examined in section 5.6.

As such, the deviant nature of the French case might be understood as a historically

rooted tradeoff between relatively low income taxes and higher consumption taxes. A

more detailed account of how and why such choices were historically made in France,

while not directly in opposition to the theoretical argument made here, is beyond the

scope of the present study.

In the case of the U.K., the reason for higher tax rates on gasoline and diesel fuel is

relatively more recent. Indeed in 1979, diesel tax rates in Great Britain were among the

lowest in the world. However in 1993 a fuel escalator duty was imposed, increasing fuel

taxes at 3% annually above inflation. This was done partly in response to growing public

concern over poor air quality pollution and traffic congestion in London, and as a means

of generating government revenue. To be sure, the London protests and the factors

leading to the fuel escalator are not well covered in the existing literature and merit

further analysis, which is beyond the scope of this project. That said, in more recent

Page 254: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

242

times, and consistent with the disproportional constraints and electoral incentives

hypotheses, the escalator was abandoned in 1999 in response to country-wide protest. As

might be expected from the theory developed here, rising opposition to the fuel escalator,

under highly disproportional conditions, produced incentives for Tony Blair’s Labour

Government to abandon the escalator in 1999, and sacrifice this source of revenue, or else

suffer at the polls.

Page 255: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

243

Chapter 6: Conclusion

6. Carbon-energy policy at a cross-roads: prospects for the future Ten years into the twenty-first century, countries face the unenviable task of finding ways

to reduce dependence on carbon-based energy, in order to become more secure and

environmentally sustainable. From a security perspective, price volatility and a

concentration of reserves in geopolitically unstable regions of the world constitute

significant economic and security vulnerabilities for fossil-energy dependent states.

Moreover, even where fossil energy is cheap and abundant (e.g. coal), a continuation of

its use threatens to destabilize the Earth’s climate, further producing economic and

security risks for the advanced developed democracies that make up the OECD.198 In

response to these challenges, taxing the consumption of carbon-based fuels is now widely

advocated by economists and other experts as a key instrument for internalizing the costs

of energy security and climate change.

At the same time, the introduction of this dissertation opened with the idea that, for a

variety of well-known reasons, increasing tax rates on carbon-based energy is politically

very difficult. At present, fossil fuels constitute the single largest energy source used

across the globe. Crucially, these patterns in energy consumption have been encouraged

by a favourable mix of tax and subsidy policy aimed at helping countries to modernize,

industrialize, and accelerate the process of economic development. Given the public good

nature of a stable climate, and incentives to free-ride on the GHG mitigation of others,

why would any country unilaterally impose higher domestic rates of carbon-energy

taxation? In addition to this question, it was found that even in instances where an

explicit “carbon tax” is successfully implemented, numerous design characteristics (e.g. 198 If countries do not dramatically change course, the best estimates of a “business as usual” scenario project that global GHG emissions will double by 2030, leading to a CO2 equivalent concentration of over 500 ppm, and a temperature increase of greater than 2 degrees Celsius, representing a potential cost in the range of 5 to 20 per cent of global GDP (Jowit and Wintour, 2008).

Page 256: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

244

non-uniform rates and sectoral exemptions) lead to more heavily polluting fuels and

sectors being taxed at lower rates, suggesting that taxing fossil fuels may actually be

more difficult than is commonly understood. In the presence of such constraints,

explaining large cross-national differences in implicit rates of carbon energy taxation is

the fundamental question this dissertation set out to answer. Specifically, what

characteristcs are shared by countries where rates of carbon-energy taxes are relatively

higher? Exploiting large cross-national differences in the way countries tax the same

fuels, I attempt to identify the political conditions that help explain when and why energy

tax reform is politically possible.

6.1. Key findings

Conventional thinking around carbon-energy taxation suggests two variables are key –

the ability to overcome resistance from domestic energy producers and the need for bold

political will. There is some evidence to support both perspectives. Case study research

has found empirical evidence of successful business opposition to carbon energy taxation,

resulting in numerous sectoral exemptions (Anger et al. 2006; Kasa, 2000; 2005).

Moreover, some authors argue that tripartite policy networks (corporatism) and the

consensual decision-making they foster is what allows such reforms to materialize

politically (Midttun and Hagen, 1997). But while these arguments are helpful in

explaining the ultimate design of carbon taxes and the sectoral exemptions they offer,

they are of limited use in explaining why carbon tax proposals appear on the political

agenda in the first place.

On this score, notions of political will and leadership help to identify the source of

political agency. To be sure, some form of political will is necessary for any type of

policy change. For instance, Harrison (2009) identifies the environmental transformation

of Gordon Campbell as constituting an important factor explaining the emergence of the

BC carbon tax. In another work, Simpson et al. (2007: 157) go as far as saying a lack of

political will among the Federal Liberal Party is a reason for Canada’s poor performance

Page 257: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

245

in mitigating GHGs. But political will alone does not seem to explain the large cross-

national differences in rates of carbon energy taxation described in this dissertation.

Moreover, one can find several instances of political will being decisively denied by

opposing forces, as evidenced in the 2008 Federal election in Canada. Despite

personifying political will and having the courage to propose a broad-based carbon tax

reform, Liberal leader Stéphane Dion saw his proposal fail, miserably, costing his party

to lose 16 seats in one of the most dismal campaigns in Liberal party history (Harrison

2010; MacKenzie, 2009). Nor were such charismatic leaders as Bill Clinton and Al Gore

able to overcome opposition to their much more modest BTU tax in 1993 (Erlandson,

1994; Royden, 2002). As these leaders learned, political will takes one only so far.

In contrast to this received wisdom, the analysis developed in this dissertation points to

one currently under-appreciated causal pathway that appears to account for much of the

variation in energy tax rates across the advanced capitalist democracies in the OECD.

Indeed, empirical analysis of rates of carbon energy taxation on four fossil fuels (coal,

heavy fuel oil, diesel and gasoline) in roughly 20 OECD countries demonstrates that

energy taxes vary systematically across countries employing majoritarian and

proportional (PR) electoral formulae, and suggests that tax increases might be easier

under different conditions depending on which system is used. At the same time, tax rates

differ even among countries employing the same type of electoral system. I argue that the

electoral system helps to explain differences in rates of carbon energy taxation, and that

this variable interacts with party votes, seats and the ideological composition of

government.

The analysis developed in this dissertation finds substantial evidence supporting the

claim that systems of proportional representation, in addition to partisanship preferences,

work together to explain differential rates in carbon energy taxation. By opening up the

ideological space for “green” and “green/new-left” political parties to win legislative

seats and participate in government, I argue that PR systems create the institutional

context within which higher rates of carbon-energy taxation become politically possible.

By specifying a key causal mechanism within different types of electoral systems – the

Page 258: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

246

seat-vote elasticity – I argue further that, voters in disproportional systems actually have

more leverage over politicians, and that an increase in environmental voting can have an

impact on rates of carbon energy taxation, even in the absence of PR. This is due to the

fact that disproportional systems clarify the lines of accountability between voters and

government, whereas in proportional systems, which typically produce coalition

government, parties share the blame. In sum, while the accession to power of green

political parties in PR systems is more likely to lead to higher rates of carbon energy

taxation, voting for green parties in highly disproportional systems will provide the

incentive for other parties to adopt “green” policies, leading to the same outcome (i.e.

higher taxation of carbon based energy). In this way, the effect of green votes and green

seats will have the opposite effect on taxes according the type of electoral system in

use.199

To be sure, the precise nature of which fuels are taxed, and by which parties, varies under

PR regimes. Given the analysis developed in Chapter 5, it appears as though social

democratic parties are more effective at implementing higher rates of carbon-energy

taxation on industry use of fossil fuels, like coal and heavy fuel oil (and industry use of

diesel) under proportional electoral systems. In contrast, green and green/new-left parties

are more effective at implementing environmental taxes on household consumption of

commonly used fossil fuels used for private transportation, diesel and gasoline (again,

under proportional electoral systems). The ideological orientation of the party in power

appears less important under majoritarian systems, where electoral incentives generated

by shifting voter preferences under disproportionality, not ideology, explain when and

why governments increase (or fail to increase) rates of energy taxation. I thus find

evidence for both sides of the debate in political science, on whether the partisanship

makeup of government matters, and offer an important specification indicating the

conditions (i.e. proportional systems) under which the ideological makeup of parties are

most likely to matter. Future research in this area would benefit from more refined

199 For instance, under increasingly disproportional electoral systems, green parties in the legislature and green parties in government are increasingly constrained in their ability to raise taxes on carbon-based energy. Under these same systems, however, increasing the vote share for green parties produces an incentive to adopt greener policy, like an increase in carbon energy taxation.

Page 259: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

247

measures of the political preferences of various parties in their country-specific context,

as well as cross-nationally comparable data on the policy preferences of the voting

public.

In addition to the role of parties under PR, and votes in disproportional systems, I find

some evidence of other determinants of carbon energy taxation. In particular, exposure to

trade is often found to be associated with lower rates of carbon energy taxation,

consistent with the view that governments need to protect energy intensive, trade exposed

sectors in their economy. While posing an important barrier, this finding points to the

political importance of developing internationally harmonized rates of carbon-energy

taxation. In the absence of such an arrangement, the pricing of carbon-based fuels for

environmental and other objectives will lead to the application of border tax adjustments

and concerns over “environmental protectionism,” as is already evident in current

discussions at the WTO. These climate trade wars can best be prevented through the

careful reform and “ratcheting up” of domestic taxes on carbon-based fuels. Preliminary

evidence of countries adopting taxes in line with their largest trading partners is evident

in the data examined in this dissertation (e.g. a NAFTA block, a European block), and

requires further research. Moreover, when examining tax rates for industry, greater

attention should be paid to the many rebates, exemptions and loopholes granted to

industry.200

Finally, the analysis developed in Chapter 5 also finds evidence of governments raising

taxes in order to meet revenue needs. For instance, while greater coal production (and a

larger coal lobby) tends to be associated with lower taxes on coal (though not

significantly lower), greater oil production has the opposite effect, where countries

producing larger quantities also tax oil products at relatively higher rates. While

suggesting that coal lobbies are more effective at keeping tax rates on their products low

(perhaps due to the relatively more labour intensive and unionized coal producing sector),

this also suggests that countries tax energy sources that are relatively inelastic (like crude

200 As much as possible, the analysis developed in this dissertation accounts for rebates and exemptions to industry, based on information provided in the detailed country notes published in the IEA’s Energy Prices and Taxes. It is possible that some tax loopholes are excluded from this publication.

Page 260: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

248

oil and oil products). Consistent with this, empirical models of gasoline taxes are more

complex, and central government debt consistently emerges as an important predictor.

All of this suggests that tax rates on fossil fuels are an important source of government

revenue, and that tax rates can at times be expected to follow from the financial needs of

the state.

6.2. Contributions

As one of the first studies of the political determinants of implicit rates of carbon energy

taxation across a large number of countries, fuels and sectors, this dissertation makes a

number of unique contributions to the literature on the comparative politics of energy

taxation, and builds our understanding of why energy tax rates differ so widely.

Importantly, the very fact that different countries tax the same fuels at widely different

rates suggests there is scope for reform of carbon-energy taxation. To the extent that

these differences exist even among the similarly situated, advanced industrial economies

that make up the OECD, there appears to be considerable room for harmonizing rates of

carbon energy taxes upward, without necessarily harming a country’s international

competitiveness. Though more research is required in this area – in order to cluster the

tax rates of countries that trade together – there is no a priori reason to reject coordinated

harmonization among the OECD countries out of hand. Similarly, the fact that rates of

carbon-energy taxation vary over time, in some countries more than others, suggests tax

rates in some areas may not be keeping up with inflation, further providing room for tax

policy maneuver. Whether and how the advanced industrial OECD can lead in this area is

a research area that warrants further study.

Turning to the empirical focus of the present study, this dissertation is the first to test the

role of electoral systems across more than just one fossil fuel, and over a longer time

period. As such, it improves on existing studies in at least two important ways. First, this

study provides a novel explanation of cross-national differences in carbon-energy

Page 261: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

249

taxation. Previous studies have relied on corporatism as a key independent variable.

While the qualitative literature on explicit carbon taxes finds some support for the claim

that corporatist decision-making networks help shape the ultimate design of carbon taxes

(Midttun and Hagen, 1997), quantitative studies testing this variable find only limited

support (Morozova, 2005).

In contrast, the present study finds that PR electoral systems help explain why increased

carbon energy taxes appear in the first place. Moreover, the plausibility probe in Chapter

4 suggests that, at least in the case of British Columbia, the distribution of resources and

votes across districts, and the associated electoral incentives, help to explain the ultimate

design of the BC carbon tax. Testing for both the effects of corporatism and the electoral

system in tax rates affecting fossil fuels used by industry also suggests that the electoral

system explanation performs better in empirical tests. The electoral system argument

advanced here thus adds value to existing studies, and may potentially explain both the

ultimate design of carbon taxes, and why they emerge in the first place. Second, the

present study improves on existing analyses of the electoral system (e.g. Fredriksson and

Millimet, 2004) by applying this variable to a larger number of different types of fossil

fuels, and by specifying the causal mechanism at work. Thus, the present study develops

a more comprehensive and coherent analysis of the role of electoral systems for carbon-

energy taxation, and develops an argument explaining when and why they should matter.

In addition, the present research has developed an alternative measure of “carbon taxes,”

that is deeper and applicable across a wider number of countries. This measure allows for

a more comprehensive account of the effective rate of carbon energy taxation across

countries, allowing an analysis across fuels, sectors and countries, for which data are

available. This measure can be used in future work on the comparative politics of carbon

energy taxation.

While open questions remain, this dissertation points to one particularly robust pattern,

and a coherent argument explaining cross-national differences in rates of carbon energy

taxation. To be sure, the results of empirical tests point to probabilistic generalizations

Page 262: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

250

only. Future work might consider more closely instances of broad-based tax policy

change in the absence of PR electoral systems, or the case of gasoline taxation, the

politics of which appear comparatively more complex. Where instances of broad-based

tax reform occurs, the theoretical argument developed here suggests one should pay

particular attention to the electoral incentives and constraints produced by

(disproportional) electoral systems and the distribution of votes across the political

system.

6.3. The way forward

Returning to the discussion of carbon taxes and cap-and-trade raised in Chapter 2, it

appears as though the debate is far from settled. To be sure, the received wisdom is that

carbon taxes simply won’t work. Especially in a North American context, it is sometimes

said that the “t” word is simply too toxic, and that carbon taxes are too difficult to

implement politically. In these lights, the BC carbon tax stands out as an important

anomaly deserving of closer study. Indeed, Gordon Campbell not only successfully

implemented a comprehensive, broad-based carbon tax in the absence of PR, but also

survived an election in which his policy was fiercely debated. The analysis developed

here suggests electoral incentives in a highly disproportional electoral system help to

explain this successful green shift.

Moreover, notwithstanding the apparent popularity of emissions trading over carbon

taxes (Chapter 2), recent events suggest that participants in the climate policy debate may

have underestimated the political difficulty inherent in designing and implementing a

system of cap-and-trade. As the example of policy debate in Canada and the U.S.

demonstrate, emissions trading policy is not necessarily easier than carbon taxes to

implement. For instance, Congressional consideration of cap-and-trade legislation in the

U.S. reached a high water mark in June 2009, when the House narrowly passed a 1,482

page bill (much longer than any carbon tax proposal) known as the American Clean

Page 263: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

251

Energy and Security Act.201 Subsequently, the Senate, which over-represents the less

populated, GHG-intensive states, has consistently blocked all climate legislation.

Meanwhile, the Western Climate Initiative (WCI) once heralded as an opportunity to

move forward with cap-and-trade in the absence of a federal role, has seen one of its

members (Arizona) back out, citing concerns over the economic recession. Moreover, the

current status of the WCI was recently in peril, as Proposition 23, which was recently

voted on in November, threatened to repeal California’s monumental Global Warming

Solutions Act of 2006, upon which the future of the WCI depends. Backed by out-of-state

oil interests in the California Jobs Initiative, Proposition 23, if passed, would have

prevented California from participating in the WCI, which could effectively kill the

regional cap-and-trade effort. While Proposition 23 failed to materialize, there is no

reason to believe the interests behind this effort will not continue their efforts to block

regional cap-and-trade, as well as other carbon policy.

Finally, though two distinct Canadian governments have attempted since 2003 to

implement a system of cap-and-trade for large final emitters in Canada, these efforts have

consistently failed. Despite proposing ostensibly the same policy in his party’s

misleadingly labeled, “Turning the Corner,” Stephen Harper has recently made explicit

his policy of harmonizing Canadian climate policy with whatever happens in the U.S.,

which given the legislative gridlock in the Washington, effectively constitutes an excuse

for doing nothing. Less cynically, the difficulty in reconciling regional differences across

provinces, which are empowered with the sole constitutional responsibility for the

management and ownership of their natural resources, is often cited as the key reason for

the lack of a federal role, prompting former leader of the Liberal Party of Canada,

Stéphane Dion to quip, “that’s why I proposed a carbon tax – I would not have to consult

the provinces!” (Dion, 2010).

In sum, the future of cap-and-trade is by no means clear, and it appears as though we are

now perceiving the very real limits on the ability of executive federalism and the

201 The bill passed by a margin of 219 to 212.

Page 264: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

252

separation of political power systems to implement cap-and-trade in North America.

Indeed, there is a great deal of political uncertainty at the national level with respect to a

federal or continental regime, and in fact, the debate has moved away from cap-and-trade

and is now more focused on regulation, on both sides of the 49th parallel. There is also

uncertainty at sub-federal levels, as evidenced recently by Arizona’s dropping out of the

WCI. Meanwhile, carbon taxes have re-emerged in policy debates elsewhere, and there is

no reason to question the ontological status of the tax policy instrument. For instance,

recent calls to consider a carbon tax have appeared in recent policy discussions in

Australia, where cap-and-trade was once thought to be the obvious policy choice

(Andrew et al. 2010).

Looking forward, it is highly unlikely that carbon taxes will ever be taken off the political

negotiation table. Cap-and-trade systems have proven to be politically complex and

difficult to design, requiring all manner of compromises to be made, and failure to reach

such accommodation might prove to be their political Achilles heel. In contrast, energy

taxes are infinitely simpler, requiring comparably less elaborate legislative design and

bureaucracy, and are inherently revenue raising, an important consideration in the current

fiscal context affecting many governments across the OECD. Moreover, governments are

very familiar with the tax instrument, and as this dissertation demonstrates, carbon taxes

have been in place in every country from the day fossil fuels were used. There is thus no

reason to believe that governments will stop taxing fossil fuels. The question thus

becomes how to reform rates of carbon energy taxation so that they are more compatible

with other economic, social and environmental objectives. As suggested by the findings

of this dissertation, the extent to which such reforms will take place will crucially depend

on the interaction between party preferences, electoral incentives, and the type of

electoral system used.

Page 265: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

253

Appendix 1: Variable definitions 1. FOSSIL FUEL INTERESTS coal_rgdp A measure of coal production (EIA) divided by real gross domestic product (Heston et al. 2009) to measure size of coal producers relative to size of economy. Units: toe/000 constant 2005 PPP$ in rgdp Note: real gross domestic product rgdp is rgdppc*population, with population data drawn from the WDI and rgdppc being real per-capita income in year 2005 measured at purchasing power parity, based on Penn World Tables version 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009). Source: Own calculations using data from EIA (2009) and Heston et al. (2009) net_coal_xp Is a measure of net coal trade balance (XP-IM) as a percentage of all coal consumed [Coal XP-IM in QBtu] / [Coal consumption in QBtu] Source: Own calculation using EIA energy data crude_rgdp A measure of crude oil production (IEA) divided by real gross domestic product (Heston et al. 2009) to measure size of oil producers relative to size of economy. Units: toe/000 constant 2005 PPP$ in rgdp Source: Own calculations using data from IEA (various volumes) and Heston et al. (2009). See note above.

net_crude_xp A measure of net crude oil exports (XP – IM) as a % total crude oil consumed [Crude oil XP-IM in ktoe] / [Crude oil Production + IM – XP in ktoe] *100 Source: own calculation using data from IEA World Energy Balances.

Page 266: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

2. TRADE EXPOSURE openk Is a measure of total trade as a percentage of GDP in constant $ Source: Penn World Tables 6.3Notes: See Heston et al. for original variable definition. Exports plus imports divided by RGDPL (real gdp per capita Laspayeres). This is the constant price equivalent of the OPENC variable and is the total trade as a GDP. 3. ELECTORAL SYSTEM pr Measures the primary electoral rule for assigning seats to the lower chamber. Is a modified version of the variablecountry’s score a “1” if the majority of seatsrepresentation and “0” if plurality. Source: adapted from Keefer (2007) dis_gall Gallagher’s (1991) proposed system, by which scholars refer to “the difference between parties’ shares of the votes and their shares of the seats” (Gallagher and Mitchell, 2005: 602). The measure, now commonly used in the literleast squares index and is calculated as follows:

dis_gall =

where vi is the share of votes for party i, number of parties. The measure can be conceptualizedsystems, a small change in the share of the votes can produce a relatively large change in the share of seats allocated to individual parties (hence, they are considered to lead to “disproportional” electoral results). In contrast, the seatproportional systems is relatively inelastic

total trade as a percentage of GDP in constant $

Tables 6.3 (Heston et al. 2009). Notes: See Heston et al. for original variable definition.

Exports plus imports divided by RGDPL (real gdp per capita Laspayeres). This is the constant price equivalent of the OPENC variable and is the total trade as a percentage of

Measures the primary electoral rule for assigning seats to the lower chamber.

a modified version of the variable housesys from the DPI, that is recoded scountry’s score a “1” if the majority of seats are allocated based on proportional representation and “0” if plurality.

eefer (2007)

measure of disproportionality produced by an electoral system, by which scholars refer to “the difference between parties’ shares of the votes and their shares of the seats” (Gallagher and Mitchell, 2005: 602).

now commonly used in the literature on electoral systems, is known as the least squares index and is calculated as follows:

is the share of votes for party i, si is the share of seats for party I and m is the

The measure can be conceptualized as the seats-vote elasticity. In more disproportional systems, a small change in the share of the votes can produce a relatively large change in the share of seats allocated to individual parties (hence, they are considered to lead to

lectoral results). In contrast, the seat-vote relationship in more proportional systems is relatively inelastic – a small change in the share of votes will

254

Exports plus imports divided by RGDPL (real gdp per capita Laspayeres). This is the percentage of

Measures the primary electoral rule for assigning seats to the lower chamber.

that is recoded so that are allocated based on proportional

measure of disproportionality produced by an electoral system, by which scholars refer to “the difference between parties’ shares of the votes

ature on electoral systems, is known as the

is the share of seats for party I and m is the

vote elasticity. In more disproportional systems, a small change in the share of the votes can produce a relatively large change in the share of seats allocated to individual parties (hence, they are considered to lead to

vote relationship in more a small change in the share of votes will

Page 267: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

255

produce a comparatively small change in the allocation of seats to parties (hence they are considered more “proportional”). Source: Armingeon et al. (2009) yr_dis_gall Is the 5 year moving average of dis_gall. The period 2002 to 2006 is only a 4 year average. For New Zealand the immediate average pre-reform is calculated from 1993 to 1995; then 1996 to 2000; and finally from 2001 to 2006. This is done to better capture the large difference in dis_gall between the two different electoral systems used. Source: Own calculations 4. PARTISANSHIP gov_left = cabinet composition: left wing parties in % total cabinet posts greenv = share of votes for all parties classified as green.202 = green1 + green2 + green3 greens = share of seats in the parliament for all parties classified as green. = sgreen1 + sgreen2 + sgreen3 green_party = dummy variable indicating presence (1) or absence (0) of green party in legislature (derived from greens). Source for above partisanship variables: Armingeon et al. 2009. See their appendix for categorization details. llc = percentage of cabinet portfolios in national government held by green/left libertarian (“new left”) parties (as defined by Kitschelt, 1994) and listed in Swank’s Appendix A1. llv = percentage of votes (lower chamber) for green/left-libertarian parties Note: these parties are mostly Greens. Source for left-libertarian variables: Swank (2007). 202 In some countries, there can be more than one party classified as “green.” Example: votes for the Green Party of Switzerland and the Green Alliance are added together for greenv.

Page 268: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

256

5. CONTROLS rgdp_pc = real gross domestic product per capita in constant (2005) USD Source: Penn World Tables v.6.3 (Heston et al., 2009) rgdp_pc_sq = square of rgdp_pc rural_pop = rural population (% of total population) Source: WDI pop_den = population density (people per square km) Source: WDI itax_rev = tax revenue from taxes on income, profit and capital gains as % total tax rev Source: OECD Revenue Statistics

itax_gdp = tax rev from taxes on income, profits and capital gains % gdp Source: see itax_rev Notes: category 1000, which includes taxes on individuals and corporations debt_gdp = total central government debt as % gdp Source: OECD Note: missing 1978-79 inf_cpi_all = general inflation rate – basket of all goods and services Source: OECD electy Election year; dummy variable coded 1 for years in which elections occurred, otherwise, 0. For US, both Congressional and Presidential election years are coded; for Fifth Republic in France, both Presidential and National Assembly elections are coded. For all other countries, national elections to the lower chamber of the national legislature are coded 1. Source: Swank (2009) and Armingeon et al. (2009)

Page 269: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

257

Correlation matrix: IVs in coal tax regressions | coal_tax openk net_co~p coal_p~d corpor~m left_cab pr dis_gall pr_leftc left_dis -------------+------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ coal_tax | 1.0000 openk | 0.1411 1.0000 net_coal_xp | -0.2578 -0.3666 1.0000 coal_prod | -0.2486 -0.3256 0.9177 1.0000 corporatism | 0.6610 0.5311 -0.4293 -0.3884 1.0000 left_cab | 0.6438 0.2519 -0.0073 -0.0077 0.5857 1.0000 pr | 0.3985 0.6075 -0.6211 -0.4910 0.7287 0.3490 1.0000 dis_gall | -0.3609 -0.4275 0.4584 0.3240 -0.6920 -0.1376 -0.8392 1.0000 pr_leftc | 0.7588 0.4975 -0.4830 -0.4128 0.8525 0.6328 0.8450 -0.7339 1.0000 left_dis | -0.1174 -0.2505 0.3824 0.2953 -0.3234 0.4174 -0.5158 0.7558 -0.3899 1.0000

Correlation matrix: IVs in heavy fuel oil tax regressions | hfo_tax openk net_cr~p crude_~d corpor~m left_cab pr dis_gall pr_leftc left_dis -------------+------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ hfo_tax | 1.0000 openk | 0.0610 1.0000 net_crude_xp | 0.0326 -0.1527 1.0000 crude_prod | 0.2865 0.0285 0.7363 1.0000 corporatism | 0.4117 0.5447 -0.0179 0.3000 1.0000 left_cab | 0.6218 0.0427 0.0002 0.1813 0.3279 1.0000 pr | 0.3482 0.5405 -0.4079 0.0086 0.5721 0.3507 1.0000 dis_gall | -0.2201 -0.4346 0.3573 0.0246 -0.6796 -0.0619 -0.7857 1.0000 pr_leftc | 0.6799 0.2707 -0.2209 0.1773 0.5311 0.7020 0.8036 -0.5885 1.0000 left_dis | 0.0334 -0.3313 0.1895 0.0484 -0.4155 0.5181 -0.3937 0.7388 -0.1380 1.0000

Correlation matrix: IVs in diesel and gasoline tax regressions | crude_~p net_oi~p openk pr yr_dis~l gov_left llc llv greenv greens green_~m electy log_rg~c rural_~p pop_den itax_gdp debt_gdp -------------+--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- crude_rgdp | 1.0000 net_oil_xp | 0.6856 1.0000 openk | 0.0393 -0.1047 1.0000 pr | 0.0456 -0.3336 0.4761 1.0000 yr_dis_gall | -0.0021 0.2516 -0.2775 -0.6624 1.0000 gov_left | 0.1008 0.0251 0.0640 0.1982 -0.0546 1.0000 llc | -0.0732 -0.1428 0.1965 0.0948 -0.0411 0.1956 1.0000 llv | 0.2040 0.0759 0.4516 0.3211 -0.2555 0.0442 0.2626 1.0000 greenv | -0.2236 -0.3669 0.5061 0.2332 -0.1483 0.0567 0.4162 0.5690 1.0000 greens | -0.2016 -0.3519 0.5142 0.3285 -0.3606 0.1274 0.4207 0.5261 0.8920 1.0000 green_dum | -0.2395 -0.4270 0.5094 0.3086 -0.2841 0.0990 0.2901 0.4634 0.8310 0.8428 1.0000 electy | -0.0292 -0.0018 -0.0728 -0.0531 -0.0222 -0.0611 -0.0431 -0.0235 -0.0048 -0.0060 -0.0222 1.0000 log_rgdppc | 0.3658 0.3592 0.2627 -0.2030 -0.0056 -0.0377 0.1184 0.2632 0.2725 0.2665 0.2642 -0.0223 1.0000 rural_pop | -0.0873 -0.3667 -0.2389 0.2029 -0.0910 -0.1778 -0.0291 -0.3397 -0.2437 -0.1819 -0.1119 -0.0009 -0.3934 1.0000 pop_den | -0.2627 -0.4166 0.2771 0.1557 -0.2152 -0.1138 0.0737 0.1165 0.2699 0.2988 0.2998 -0.0199 0.0416 -0.0203 1.0000 itax_gdp | 0.1637 0.4636 0.2227 -0.0062 -0.2116 0.0477 0.0284 0.4563 0.0123 0.0291 0.0058 -0.0150 0.2404 -0.5803 -0.1951 1.0000 debt_gdp | -0.2527 -0.3500 0.2934 0.1243 -0.0642 -0.0106 0.0518 -0.0067 0.0498 0.0669 0.0896 -0.0158 -0.2053 0.0820 0.3165 0.0171 1.0000

Page 270: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

258

Appendix 2: Operationalizing the dependent variable

The original data used to generate the dependent variables in this dissertation were

obtained from various volumes of the IEA’s quarterly publication, Energy Prices and

Taxes. A sample table from which the data are drawn appears below.

Table A.1: Tax rates on Unleaded Gasoline in Canada

Regular Unleaded (92 RON) Gasoline

(per litre) X-Tax Price Excise Tax GST Total Tax Total Price 2003 0.437 0.252 0.048 0.300 0.737 2004 0.508 0.254 0.053 0.307 0.815 2005 0.612 0.254 0.060 0.314 0.926 2006 0.661 0.260 0.064 0.324 0.985 Source: IEA (2008) Table A.2: Tax rates on Natural Gas in Switzerland

Natural Gas for Households (per 107 kilocalories GCV)

X-Tax Price Excise Tax GST Total Tax Total Price 2003 699.4 3.8 53.4 57.2 756.6 2004 704.2 3.8 53.8 57.6 761.8 2005 773.0 3.7 59.0 62.7 835.7 2006 887.1 4.3 67.7 72.0 959.1 Source: IEA 2008 These data are yearly averages based on statistics collected from national sources,

expressed in terms of national currency, in this case, Canadian dollars and Swiss Francs.

The fact that these data are expressed in units of national currency makes direct cross-

national comparison difficult. Moreover, the tax data are expressed in base units (e.g.

litres, tonnes, cubic metres), which are not directly comparable. For instance, in 2006, the

Canadian tax on gasoline ($0.324 Canadian dollars per litre) and the Swiss tax on natural

gas ($72 Swiss Francs per 107 kilocalorie) are not directly comparable, even though we

might want to compare them as taxes on carbon-based fuels.

Page 271: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

259

The type of data summarized in Tables A.1 and A.2 present different options for

transforming energy tax data into meaningful and comparable data. Each option carries

with it unique advantages and disadvantages. Ultimately, the goal is to estimate the

“implicit tax on carbon,” and this goal is the standard against which each option is

assessed.

Percentage of Revenue. Much of the tax policy literature operationalizes tax data in

terms of revenues. For instance, scholars concerned with explaining cross-national

differences in tax burdens (Steinmo and Tolbert, 1998), or in the “tax revenue structure”

(Kato, 2003), have operationlized taxation in terms of revenues derived from a particular

tax, expressed as a proportion of total tax revenue, or gross domestic product (GDP). In

the area of the environment, the OECD, Eurostat and IEA have established data

collection protocols for the collection of environmental tax data, providing a measure of

the magnitude of environmental taxes as a proportion of total tax revenues and GDP

(Eurostat, 2001; OECD 2010).203 Using this kind of data, scholars have described the

structure of environmental taxation, expressed as a percentage of GDP (Barde and

Braathen, 2007), and explained variation in environmental tax revenues expressed in

terms of both total tax revenue (Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003), and environmental tax

revenue per capita (Ward and Cao, 2010). Even the more descriptive work on carbon

taxes has also operationalized carbon tax policy using revenue data, giving some sense of

the relative magnitude of carbon taxes in the total tax system (Baranzini et al. 2000: 399

Table 2; Ekins and Barker, 2001: 341 Table 3.1).

To be sure, revenues derived from “environmentally-related” taxes can be interpreted as

indicators of the development of environmental protection over time and across countries

(Bruvoll, 2009: 3), the “environmental tax burden” (Ward and Cao, 2010), or for some,

even as an indicator of environmental concern (Ekins and Barker, 2001: 341). However,

tax revenues should not be taken as an indicator of the effectiveness of tax policy

(Barde and Braathen, 2007: 58). Moreover, as pointed out by Eismeier (1983) and others

203 This discussion sets aside Bruvoll’s (2009) concern that many of the taxes considered by the OECD, IEA and Eurostat to be “environmentally-related” are not environmental at all.

Page 272: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

260

(Stults and Winters, 2004), tax revenues are not a reliable indicator of tax policy, or for

our purposes, of the effect of policy on the relative price of fossil fuels. Revenues from

taxes on carbon-based fuels will be strongly associated (correlated) with levels of

consumption, or that which the tax may actually be intended to deter. This is problematic

because the carbon tax component of total tax revenues will rise and fall with levels of

consumption, irrespective of what happens to policy. As such, the revenue approach does

not really provide a reliable measure of tax policy affecting the relative price of fossil

fuels, or crucially for the present study, a measure of the implicit tax on carbon.

Second, such an approach faces problems of internal validity as well. To be sure,

measuring a carbon tax in terms of its contribution to total tax revenue might be a good

indicator of the magnitude of taxes on carbon, relative to taxes on other goods, for a

particular country in a given year. However, expressing carbon tax levels in terms of

their contribution to total tax revenues seems to be a better measure of the dependence of

a particular state’s public purse on taxing carbon, rather than an indicator of

environmental protection. Indeed, as much of the recent political economy research on

environmental taxation now suggests (Svendson et al. 2000; Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003),

including the present study, the purpose of environmental taxation, like all taxes, is

fundamentally to raise revenue.204

For these reasons, using tax revenues does not seem to be the best option for measuring

the effect of policy on the price of fossil fuels. If the purpose is to measure the implicit

carbon tax, it seems preferable to focus on actual tax rates.

Tax Rate in USD. One option is to convert tax data like that summarized in Tables A.1

and A.2, expressed in national currency per base unit, into the equivalent U.S. dollar

(USD) or Purchasing Power Parity (PPP). While the USD conversion essentially

converts price data into the equivalent USD using market exchange rates, PPPs convert

national currency into a common international currency, based on the relative

204 Svendsen et al. (2001: 497) take this argument further, suggesting that “many green taxes […] are merely fiscal taxes which have been labeled green taxes in order to legitimate them to the public.”

Page 273: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

261

“purchasing power” of different currencies vis a vis a common basket of goods. The

transformation from national currency to USD is relatively straightforward, involving a

simple calculation using exchange rate information from sources like the IMF, and more

easily accessible through OECD and World Bank databases. Similarly, data on PPPs are

readily available from the Penn World Tables (Heston et al., 2009).

In cross-national research, monetary data are commonly converted to a common

currency, like USD (Ciocirlan and Yandle, 2003) or PPP (Rogowski and Kayser, 2002)

in order to provide a common metric that facilitates international comparison. Due to

wide fluctuations in international currency markets and in highly variable factor prices,

however, international price comparisons in USD and PPPs should be undertaken with

caution. Variables converted to USD may be highly sensitive to fluctuations in exchange

rates, which are determined by market forces and monetary policy (IEA, 2008: 48).

Similar caution is warranted when using PPPs. While PPPs assume that prices for

internationally traded goods should be the same anywhere in the world once they are

expressed in a common currency (i.e. the Law of One Price), the reality is that not all

inputs going into the production of goods and services are traded internationally. As a

result, estimates of PPP may be sensitive to a host of domestic factors that vary from

country to country, producing an imperfect conversion ratio (Taylor and Taylor, 2004).

Notwithstanding these issues, USD and PPPs are the best “international” currencies

available for macro-comparative research. In the absence of an alternative, and consistent

with the comparative economics and political science literature, the present research uses

standardized data in USD and PPP. Moreover, as recommended by a recent OECD

(2010) study, using multiple base currencies can act as a check against bias created by

market exchange rates. Following this advice, I estimate separate regressions using

variables converted to both USD and PPPs as a check for robustness across models.205

205 In addition, exchange rate and PPP conversion ratios can be included in empirical models to control for any independent influence they might have.

Page 274: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Tax Component. In light of the potential

PPP, and alternative approach to standardizing IEA tax data is to take the proportion of

tax in the total price paid by consumers for a particular fuel. For instance, using the data

in Tables A.1 and A.2, it is po

for a particular fuel, using the following formula:

Tax Component =

Where: totaltax(t), is the total tax levied on a fuel at time t;

totalprice(t), is the total price of a fuel at tim

The above formula gives the percentage of

of a particular fossil fuel. Although the option of including or excluding VAT is

available (since the data as summarized in Tables A.1 and A.2 differentiate b

excise and VAT), I think it is

have the same effect on total price, and therefore, consumption.

The advantage of this measure is that it allows for cross

reliance on exchange rates, thus avoiding the potential sensitivity of the measure

fluctuations in international monetary

cost. Relative to energy prices,

time, and often remain constant

market fluctuations in energy prices, and inflation, will have an independent effect on the

“tax component” measure, irrespective of what happens to the tax ra

206 On the other hand, one might be solely interested in excise taxes, and it would therefore bedisaggregate as much as possible (Thanks to Steven Bernstein for raising this point). For instance, the reasons for governments levying VAT may bwant to analyze them seperately. Though this might be true, I would argue that if the purpose is to estimate and explain the implicit carbon price, VAT should be accounted for, since it too will affeccarbon. 207 For instance, if the formula above is applied to the data in the Table 4.1, it appears as though the tax component falls from 38% to 34% between the years 2004 and 2005. However, during this time, the

In light of the potential problems associated with data in USD and

PPP, and alternative approach to standardizing IEA tax data is to take the proportion of

tax in the total price paid by consumers for a particular fuel. For instance, using the data

in Tables A.1 and A.2, it is possible to calculate the tax component in the final price paid

for a particular fuel, using the following formula:

*100

is the total tax levied on a fuel at time t;

is the total price of a fuel at time t

The above formula gives the percentage of total tax (i.e. VAT + excise) in the

. Although the option of including or excluding VAT is

as summarized in Tables A.1 and A.2 differentiate b

excise and VAT), I think it is preferable to use total tax (including VAT), since VAT will

have the same effect on total price, and therefore, consumption.206

The advantage of this measure is that it allows for cross-national comparison without

thus avoiding the potential sensitivity of the measure

fluctuations in international monetary markets. This advantage, however, comes at a

cost. Relative to energy prices, tax rates on energy products change very slowly o

time, and often remain constant from one year to the next. In this context, such factors as

market fluctuations in energy prices, and inflation, will have an independent effect on the

“tax component” measure, irrespective of what happens to the tax rate or tax policy.

On the other hand, one might be solely interested in excise taxes, and it would therefore begregate as much as possible (Thanks to Steven Bernstein for raising this point). For instance, the

VAT may be different than reasons for excise taxes, therefore one may Though this might be true, I would argue that if the purpose is to estimate

and explain the implicit carbon price, VAT should be accounted for, since it too will affect the price of

For instance, if the formula above is applied to the data in the Table 4.1, it appears as though the tax component falls from 38% to 34% between the years 2004 and 2005. However, during this time, the

262

problems associated with data in USD and

PPP, and alternative approach to standardizing IEA tax data is to take the proportion of

tax in the total price paid by consumers for a particular fuel. For instance, using the data

in the final price paid

the total price

. Although the option of including or excluding VAT is

as summarized in Tables A.1 and A.2 differentiate between

preferable to use total tax (including VAT), since VAT will

national comparison without

thus avoiding the potential sensitivity of the measure vis a vis

. This advantage, however, comes at a

tax rates on energy products change very slowly over

. In this context, such factors as

market fluctuations in energy prices, and inflation, will have an independent effect on the

te or tax policy.207 In

On the other hand, one might be solely interested in excise taxes, and it would therefore be better to gregate as much as possible (Thanks to Steven Bernstein for raising this point). For instance, the

, therefore one may Though this might be true, I would argue that if the purpose is to estimate

t the price of

For instance, if the formula above is applied to the data in the Table 4.1, it appears as though the tax component falls from 38% to 34% between the years 2004 and 2005. However, during this time, the

Page 275: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

263

fact, excise taxes and VAT have declined in real terms over time, since it is difficult for

governments to change tax rates on energy consumption each year to keep pace with

inflation. Using this measure might increase within panel variance in the estimate of the

size of energy taxes (relative to total price), when no changes to policy occur. On

balance, it would seem as though the noise created by using exchange rates and PPPs is

less severe than this possibility. Indeed, the “tax component” seems a better measure of

the potential erosion of real tax revenues (as opposed to the implicit carbon tax), since it

is not automatically adjusted for inflation/deflation.208 While an analysis of how closely

governments adjust energy tax rates for inflation is an interesting question, it is only

tangentially related to the present concern with taxing carbon. Future work may wish to

pursue this question.

Tax Policy Change (i.e. change in the nominal tax rate). To the extent that the present

analysis is interested in tax policy, and not the erosion of the tax rate, the focus can

legitimately be with the nominal tax rate, which is not adjusted for inflation. Here the

analysis is simplified in that policy changes are changes in the nominal rate, so the focus

of the study should be on years in which there is a change to the nominal rate. Using a

simple formula to calculate year to year percentage change, units of measurement are

washed out, eliminating the problem of cross-national comparison using national

currency data. However, the primary purpose of this study is to provide an estimate of

the implicit price on carbon, not changes in tax policy over time. The tax policy change

variable will be analyzed in future work, once broad trends in the data are identified, and

the original research questions of this dissertation are answered.

average excise tax remained unchanged at $0.254 Canadian dollars per litre. The reason for the fall in the tax component has to do with the fact that the tax rate did not keep up with inflation. 208 The question answered by the “tax component” measure is essentially the following: given changes in energy markets, is the tax becoming more/less important as a determinant of price? To be sure, this question has important implications for policy. For instance, the ratio between tax and price can generate opposing forces. If the price goes up, there is pressure for tax relief, but there is also an incentive for government to maintain the “real” tax rate. The potential erosion in “real” tax rates is a good reason why governments are ill-advised to set taxes at fixed rates, since adjusting tax rates might be politically difficult if visible to the tax payer. As a result, automatic adjustment mechanisms might be preferred, from a political standpoint. My thanks to Donald Dewees for raising this issue.

Page 276: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

264

Tax per tonne of CO2 (implicit carbon tax). A final option that is used in this dissertation

is to develop an estimate of the implicit carbon tax for each type of fuel. This approach

involves first standardizing tax rates in constant (2000) U.S. dollars (or PPPs), using

market exchange rates, then deflating by country-specific consumer prices. Next,

standardized tax rates (e.g. constant USD/base unit) are divided by corresponding

emission factors for each type of fuel, in order to transform the tax rate into from a tax

per unit to a tax per tonne of CO2.

To calculate the tax rate on a tonne of carbon dioxide, original tax rate (expressed in

terms of constant USD/unit of fuel) are divided by the corresponding emission factor for

that particular fuel. This gives the tax rate per unit of carbon. Depending on whether the

emission factor is given for Kg or metric tonne, an additional multiplication procedure is

required to ensure the tax rate is per tonne of CO2, as opposed to Kg.

For instance, to calculate the implicit carbon tax for motor fuels, tax rates (in USD) are

divided by the CO2 emissions from gasoline (2.32 Kg of CO2/litre) and diesel (2.66 Kg of

CO2/litre), which gives an estimate of the implicit carbon tax per kilogram of CO2.209

This figure is then multiplied by 1000, to express the tax in terms of per metric tonne of

CO2. The result is a standardized measure of the tax, in USD, per metric tonne of CO2

emitted into the atmosphere. Such a conversion allows for comparison across different

fuels with different carbon contents and different units of measurement (e.g. tones of coal

vs. litres of diesel fuel).

Example: If tax on a litre of gasoline is taxed at a rate of USD $0.28/litre (or the tax rate

in Canada in 2007), then the corresponding tax rate on a tonne of carbon dioxide is:

[0.28/2.32]*1000

= USD $120.69

209 These figures are generated from the EPA (2005: 1-2), which provide estimates of CO2 emissions from gasoline and diesel motor fuels using the method recommended by the IPCC. The original figures, expressed in gallons, are converted to litres by the following formula: 1 gallon = 3.8 metric litres.

Page 277: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

265

Thus, a tax of $0.28 USD per litre is equivalent to a carbon tax of $120.69 per tonne of

carbon dioxide. These transformed measures give a sense of the tax rate on a given fuel

(in this case, gasoline), in constant (2000) USD, per tonne of CO2 emitted, and are

directly comparable across countries, fuels and sectors.

Page 278: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

266

Appendix 3: Emission factors Emission Factor Units Coal210 2.77 tCO2/tonne Heavy fuel oil211 2.955 tCO2/kilolitre Light fuel oil 2.642 tCO2/kilolitre Diesel 0.00269 tCO2/litre Gasoline 0.00232 tCO2/litre Natural gas 2.34 tCO2/10

7kilocalories (GCV) Source: IPCC (1996) and IEA (2008a)

IPCC Emission Factors Emission Factor (tCO2) Unit Coal British Columbia 2.766 tonne Denmark 2.717 tonne Finland 2.364 tonne Netherlands 2.766 tonne Norway 2.605 tonne Sweden 2.490 tonne HFO 3.078 tonne HFO 2.955 kl LFO 2.642 kl Diesel 0.00269 l Gasoline 0.00232 l Natural gas 2.1 107 kcal Natural gas 0.001954 m3 Notes: calculated using default emission factors in revised 1996 IPCC Guidelines; adjusted for cross-national variation in chemical makeup and quality of fuels using country-specific calorific values from the IEA. EIA Emission Factors Emission Factor (tCO2) Unit Coal 2.471 tonne HFO 3.26 tonne HFO 3.126 kl LFO 2.69 kl Diesel 0.00269 l Gasoline 0.00235 l Natural gas 2.08 107 kcal Natural gas 0.001936 m3 Notes: using standard EIA emission factors assuming coal is bituminous (most commonly used type in OECD, exceptions are the predominant use of anthracite in the Netherlands and Norway, which means estimates of their tax rates are over-estimated to a small extent when these emission factors are used)

210 For coal, an emission factor for bituminous is used. Bituminous coal is the most commonly consumed type of coal in the OECD. 211 If converted to tCO2/tonne, the emission factor for HFO is 3.078. It is higher than the emission factor for coal due to the fact that HFO is a denser form of energy. Conversely, on an energy unit basis, which is the more common way to measure carbon content, coal is the dirtiest fuel, containing more carbon per TJ. On a per energy unit basis, coal is “dirtier” because more tonnes of coal must be burned in order to get the same amount of energy as from burning a tonne of HFO.

Page 279: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

267

Bibliography Ackerman, Frank and Lisa Heinzerling. 2004. Priceless: On knowing the price of everything and the value of nothing. New York: New Press. Adam, David. 2010. “Climategate scientists cleared of manipulating data on global warming” The Guardian. Thursday 8 July 2010. Adelle, Camilla, Marc Pallemaerts, and Joana Chiavari, 2009. “Climate Change and Energy Security in Europe: Policy Integration and its Limits.” Stockholm: Swedish Institute for European Policy Studies, Report No.4. Alcott, B. 2005. “Jevons’ Paradox,” Ecological Economics. 54: 9-21. Anderegg, William R. James W. Prall, Jacob Harold, and Stephen H. Schneider, 2010. “Expert credibility in climate change.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. June 21, 2010, doi:10.1073/pnas.1003187107. Andersen, Mikael Skou. 2003. “CO2 Taxation in the Nordic Countries: Results and Methodological Caveats” in Milne et al. eds. Critical Issues in Environmental Taxation: International and Comparative Perspectives Volume I. Richmond UK: Richmond Law and Tax Ltd., 163-174. Andersen, Mikael Skou and Paul Ekins eds. 2009. Carbon-Energy Taxation: Lessons From Europe. New York: Oxford University Press. Andrew, Jane, Mary A. Kaidonis and Brian Andrew. 2010. “Carbon tax: Challenging neoliberal solutions to climate change.” Critical Perspectives on Accounting. 21: 611-618. Anger, N. C. Böhringer and A. Lange. 2006. “Differentiation of Green Taxes: A Political-Economy Analysis for Germany” Centre for European Economic Research. Armingeon, Klaus, Marlène Gerber, Philipp Leimgruber and Michelle Beyeler. 2009. Comparative Political Data Set 1960-2007. Institute of Political Science, University of Berne. Babb, Sarah. 2001. Managing Mexico: Economists from Nationalism to Neoliberalism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Baltagi, Badi H. 1995. Econometric Analysis of Panel Data. New York: John Wiley and Sons.

Page 280: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

268

Barde, J.P. and N.A. Braathen. 2007. “Green Tax Reforms in OECD countries: an overview” in P. Nemetz, ed. Sustainable Resource Management: Reality or Illusion? Edward Elgar, 42 – 87. Baranzini, A., J. Goldemberg and S. Speck. 2000. “A future for carbon taxes” Ecological Economics 32: 395-412. Barker, T. and P. Ekins. 2004. “The Costs of Kyoto for the US Economy” The Energy Journal 25 (3): 53-71. Barthold, T.A. 1994. “Issues in the Design of Environmental Excise Taxes,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (1): 133-151. Baumert, Kevin (1998) "Carbon Taxes Vs. Emissions Trading: What's the Difference, and Which is Better?" Global Policy Forum, http://www.globalpolicy.org/socecon/glotax/carbon/ct_et.htm. Baumgartner, F. and B. Leech. 1998. Basic Interests: The Importance of Groups in Politics and Political Science. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Bawn, Kathleen. 1993. “The logic of institutional preferences: German electoral law as a social choice outcome.” American Journal of Political Science. 37(4): 965-989. Becher, Michael. 2010. “Constraining Ministerial Power: the impact of veto players on labor market reforms in industrial democracies, 1973-2000.” Comparative Political Studies. 43(1): 33-60. Beck, Nathaniel (2001) “Time-Series-Cross-Section Data: What Have we Learned in the Past Few Years?” Annual Review of Political Science. 4: 271-293. Beck, Nathanial. 2006. “Time-Series-Cross-Section-Methods” Working Paper, June, 2006. Beck, N. and J.N. Katz. 2009. “Modeling Dynamics in Time-Series-Cross-Section Political Economy Data” Social Science Working Paper 1304, California Institute of Technology. Beck, N. and J.N. Katz. 1995. “What to do (and not to do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data” American Political Science Review 89(3): 634 – 647. Becker, Gary S. 1983. “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98 (3): 371-400. Becker, Gary S. 2009. “Do national security and environmental energy policies conflict?” Defining Ideas. Hoover Institution, Stanford. 2009 No.1. http://www.hoover.org/publications/defining-ideas/article/5440

Page 281: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

269

Beinecke, Frances. 2009. “Putting a Price on Carbon: An Emissions Cap or a Tax?” Environment 360: Opinion, Analysis, Reporting & Debate. Available at: http://e360.yale.edu/content/feature.msp?id=2148 Bento, Antonio M. and Mark Jacobsen. 2007. “Ricardian rents, environmental policy and the ‘double-dividend’ hypothesis.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 53: 17-31. Blais, André, Donald Blake and Stéphane Dion. 1993. “Do parties make a difference? Parties and the size of government in liberal democracies.” American Journal of Political Science. 37(1): 40-62. Blais, André, Donald Blake and Stéphane Dion. 1996. “Do parties make a difference? A reappraisal.” American Journal of Political Science. 40(2): 514-520. Blyth, Mark. 2002. Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Political Change in the Twentieth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bohi, D.R. and M.A. Toman. 1996. The Economics of Energy Security. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Boix, Carles. 1999. “Setting the Rules of the Game: The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies.” American Political Science Review. 93(3): 609-624. Bollen, Kenneth A. and Jennie E. Brand. 2008. “Fixed and random effects in panel data using structural equation models.” Population Working Paper. Botteon, M. and C. Carraro. 1993. “Is the European Carbon Tax Really Effective?” in C. Carraro and D. Siniscalco eds. The European Carbon Tax: An Economic Assessment, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers, 255-284. Bovenberg, A.L. 1999. “Green tax reforms and the double-dividend: An updated reader’s guide” International Tax and Public Finance. 6: 421-443. Bovenberg, A.L. and L. Goulder. 2002a. “Confronting Industry-Distributional Concerns in U.S. Climate-change Policy” paper presented at the Economie de l’environment et du développement durable conference organized by Iddri, 17 December, 2002. Bovenberg, A.L. and L. Goulder. 2002b. Environmental Taxation and Regulation” in Handbook of Public Economics, vol. 3, A. Auerbach and M. Feldstein, eds. North-Holland. Boyd, Roy, Kerry Krutilla, and W. Kip Viscusi. 1995. “Energy Taxation as a Policy Instrument to Reduce CO2 Emissions: A Net Benefit Analysis.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 29:1-24.

Page 282: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

270

Brännlund, Runar and Ing-Marie Gren eds. 1999. Green Taxes: Economic Theory and Empirical Evidence from Scandinavia, Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. British Columbia (2008) “Budget and Fiscal Plan 2008/09 – 2010/11” Bretschger, Lucas and Frank Hettich. 2002. “Globalisation, capital mobility and tax competition: theory and evidence for OECD countries.” European Journal of Political Economy. 18: 695-716. Brown, Lester. 2003. “Shifting Taxes,” in Plan B: Rescuing a Planet under Stress and a Civilization in Trouble. New York: W.W. Norton. Broz, Lawrence J. and Daniel Maliniak. 2009. “Malaportionment, Gasoline Taxes, and the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change” presented at the fourth annual meeting of the International Political Economy Society, Texas A&M University, November 13-14, 2009. Bruvoll, Annegrete. 2009. “On the measurement of environmental taxes.” Discussion Papers No. 599. Oslo: Statistics Norway. Bruvoll, A. and B.M. Larsen. 2004. “Greenhouse gas emissions in Norway: do carbon taxes work?” Energy Policy 32: 493-505. Buchanan, J.M. 2001. The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan: Externalities and Public Expenditure Theory, Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund. Buchanan, J.M. and G. Tullock. 1975. “Polluters’ Profits and Political Response: Direct Control versus Taxes,” American Economic Review, 65: 139-147. Cameron, David R. 1978. “The Expansion of the Public Economy: A Comparative Analysis.” The American Political Science Review. 72(4): 1243-1261. Campbell, C.J. 1997. The Coming Oil Crisis. Essex: Multi-Science Publishing Co. Cao, Xun and Aseem Prakash. 2010. “Trade Competition and Domestic Pollution: A Panel Study, 1980-2003.” International Organization. 64:481-503. Carraro, C. and D. Siniscalco eds. 1993. The European Carbon Tax: An Economic Assessment, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Carpenter, Chad. 2001. “Business, green groups and the media: the role of non-governmental organizations in the climate change debate.” International Affairs. 77: 313-328.

Page 283: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

271

Carter, Angela V. 2010. “Explaining Environmental Regulation in Petro-States: Petro-Politics in Alberta’s Tar Sands” paper presented at the Canadian Political Science Association’s 82nd Annual Conferece, 1-3 June, 2010, Montreal. Chandler, David. 2009. “Revised MIT climate model sounds alarm” Tech Talk. MIT. Chang, E.C. M.A. Kayser and R. Rogowski. 2008. “Electoral Systems and Real Prices: Panel Evidence for the OECD Countries, 1970-2000” British Journal of Political Science. 38: 739-751. Christiansen, Atle C. and Jørgen Wettestad. 2003. “The EU as a frontrunner on greenhouse gas emissions trading: how did it happen and will the EU succeed?” Climate Policy. 3: 3-18. Chubb, John E. 1983. Interest Groups and the Bureaucracy: The Politics of Energy. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. Ciocirlan, Cristina E. and Bruce Yandle. 2003. “The Political Economy of Green Taxation in OECD Countries.” European Journal of Law and Economics. 15:203-218. Clark, A. (2009) “Exxon Chief backs Carbon Tax,” The Guardian. 10/01/2009. Coase, R.H. (1960) “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics, 3:1-44. Collina, Tom Z. 2005. “Oil Dependence and U.S. Foreign Policy: Real Dangers, Realistic Solutions.” Testimony before the Committee on Foreign Relations, United States Senate. October 19, 2005. Congressional Budget Office. 2008. “Policy Options for Reducing CO2 Emissions” Congress of the United States. Cooke, Roger M. 1991. Experts in uncertainty: opinion and subjective probability in science. New York: Oxford University Press. Cooper, Richard. 1998. “Toward a Real Global Warming Treaty (The Case for a Carbon Tax)” Foreign Affairs, 77(2): 66-79. Corfee-Morlot, J and T. Jones. 1992. “Designing a Practical Tax System for Greenhouse Gas Emission Abatement: An Introduction” in Climate Change: Designing a Practical Tax System. Paris: OECD, 15 – 24. Cournede, B.S. and S. J. Gallon. 2003. “Input Versus Output Taxation of Electricity in France: How Choosing the Wrong Tax Instrument Can Lead to Environmental Damage” in Milne et al. eds. Critical Issues in Environmental Taxation: International and

Page 284: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

272

Comparative Perspectives Volume I. Richmond UK: Richmond Law and Tax Ltd., 211-226. Cox, Gary. 1997. Making Votes Count. Cambridge University Press. Creedy, J. and C. Sleeman. 2006. “Carbon taxation, prices and welfare in New Zealand” Ecological Economics, 57: 333-345. Crepaz, Markus M.L. 1998. “Inclusion versus Exclusion: Political Institutions and Welfare Expenditures.” Comparative Politics. 31:61-80. Cusack, Thomas R. 1999. “Partisan Politics and Fiscal Policy” Comparative Political Studies 32(4): 464-485.

Cusack, Thomas R., Torben Iversen and David Soskice. 2007. “Economic Interests and the Origins of Electoral Systems.” American Political Science Review. 101(3): 373-391. Dalton, Russel. 1994. The Green Rainbow: environmental groups in Western Europe. Yale University Press. Damania, R. 1999. “Political Competition, Rent Seeking and the Choice of Environmental Policy Instruments” Environmental and Resource Economics 13: 415-433. Darley, Julian. 2004. High Noon for Natural Gas: The Energy Crisis. White River VT: Chelsea Green. Deffeyes, Kenneth S. 2001. Hubbert’s Peak: The Impending World Oil Shortage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Demailly, Damien and Phillippe Quirion. 2005. “The Competitiveness Impact of CO2 Emissions Reduction in the Cement Sector.” Paris: OECD. Daugbjerg, Carsten. and A.B. Pedersen. 2004. “New Policy Ideas and Old Policy Networks: Implementing Green Taxation in Scaninavia” Journal of Public Policy. 24(2): 219-249. Daugbjerg, Carsten and Gert Tinggaard Svendsen. 2003. “Designing green taxes in a political context: from optimal to feasible environmental regulation.” Environmental Politics. 12(4): 76-95. De Mooij, R.A. 2000. Environmental Taxation and the Double Dividend. New York: Elsevier. Deutch, John and James R. Schlesinger. 2006. “National Security Consequences of U.S. Oil Dependency.” Council on Foreign Relations, Independent Task Force Report No. 58

Page 285: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

273

Dion, Stéphane. 2010. “North America’s Responsibility in the Fight against Climate Change” address by Stéphane Dion to the conference: Designing integration Regional Governance on climate change in North America. Waterloo, Ontario. September 24, 2010. Doern, B.G. ed. 2005 Canadian Energy Policy and the Struggle for Sustainable Development. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper Row. Downs, Erica S. 2006. “National Energy Security Depends on International Energy Security.” Brookings Institution. http://www.brookings.edu/opinions/2006/0317china_downs.aspx Drake, Frances. 2000. Global Warming: the Science of Climate Change, New York: Oxford University Press. Drukker, D.M. 2003. “Testing for serial correlation in linear panel-data models” The Stata Journal 3(2): 168-177. Duverger, Maurice. 1954. L’influence des Systèmes Electoraux sur la Vie Politieque. Paris: Armand Colin. Ekins, P. and S. Speck. 1999. “Competitiveness and Exemptions from Environmental taxes in Europe” Environmental and Resource Economics. 13: 369-396. Ekins, P. and T. Barker. 2001. “Carbon Taxes and Carbon Emissions Trading” Journal of Economic Surveys. 15(3): 325-375. Ellerman, A. Denny and Barbara K. Buchner. 2007. “The European Union Emissions Trading Scheme: Origins, Allocation, and Early Results,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy. 1:66-87. Enveldsen, M. 2005. The Theory of Environmental Agreements and Taxes: CO2 Policy Performance in Comparative Perspective. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2001. “The United States experience with economic incentives for protecting the environment.” National Center for Environmental Economics. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA). 2005. “Average carbon dioxide emissions resulting from gasoline and diesel fuel.” United States Environmental Protection Agency: Office of Transportation and Air Quality. EPA 420-F-05-001, February 2005.

Page 286: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

Esping-Anderson, G. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton University Press. European Commission (EC). 1991. “A Community Strategy to Limit to improve energy efficiency,” Communication from the Community to the Council. SEC (91) 1744 final, 14 October 1991. EC: Brussels. Falkner, Robert. 2009. Business Power and Conflict in International Environmental Politics. Palgrave Macmillan. Felder, Stefan and Reto Schleiniger. 2002. “Environmental tax reform: efficiency and political feasibility.” Ecological Economics. Fischer, C, C. Hanson and W. Pizer. 2008.Not necessarily either/or.” Resources for the Future Fisher, B.S. and M.D. Hinchy. 2004. “The Role of Energy Prices in Global Climate Change” in A.D. Owen and N. Hanley eds. York: Routledge, 193-213. Foucadre, Marion. 2006. “The Construction of a Global Profession: The Transnationalization of Economics” Fredriksson, Per G. and Daniel L. Millimet. 2004. “Electoral rules and environmental policy” Economic Letters, 84: 237 Fredriksson, Per G. and Daniel L. Millimet. 2007.Pollution Taxation.” Public Choice. Gallagher, Michael. 1991. “Proportionality, disproportionality and electoral systems” Electoral Studies. 10(1): 33-51. Gallagher, Michael and Paul Mitchell eds. 2005. Oxford University Press. Garrett, Geoffrey. 1998. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Press. Garrett, Geoffrey and Deborah Mitchell. 2001. “Globalization, government spending and taxation in the OECD.” European Journal of Political Research. Gayer, Ted and John K. Horowitz. 2005. “MarketRegulation.” Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics. Gelman, A. and J. Hill. 2007.Multilevel/Hierarchical Models.

The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton:

European Commission (EC). 1991. “A Community Strategy to Limit emissions and to improve energy efficiency,” Communication from the Community to the Council.

inal, 14 October 1991. EC: Brussels.

Business Power and Conflict in International Environmental Palgrave Macmillan.

Felder, Stefan and Reto Schleiniger. 2002. “Environmental tax reform: efficiency and Ecological Economics. 42: 107-116.

her, C, C. Hanson and W. Pizer. 2008. “Carbon taxes and cap-and-trade programs: Resources for the Future (working paper).

Fisher, B.S. and M.D. Hinchy. 2004. “The Role of Energy Prices in Global Climate Change” in A.D. Owen and N. Hanley eds. The Economics of Climate Change,

Foucadre, Marion. 2006. “The Construction of a Global Profession: The ransnationalization of Economics” American Journal of Sociology. 112(1):145

Fredriksson, Per G. and Daniel L. Millimet. 2004. “Electoral rules and environmental 84: 237-244.

Fredriksson, Per G. and Daniel L. Millimet. 2007. “Legislative Organization and Public Choice. 131:217-242.

Gallagher, Michael. 1991. “Proportionality, disproportionality and electoral systems” 51.

Gallagher, Michael and Paul Mitchell eds. 2005. The Politics of Electoral Systems.

Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge University

Garrett, Geoffrey and Deborah Mitchell. 2001. “Globalization, government spending and European Journal of Political Research. 39: 145-177.

Gayer, Ted and John K. Horowitz. 2005. “Market-based Approaches to Enviornmental Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics. 1(4):201-326.

Hill. 2007. Data Analysis Using Regression and Multilevel/Hierarchical Models. Cambridge University Press.

274

Princeton:

emissions and to improve energy efficiency,” Communication from the Community to the Council.

Business Power and Conflict in International Environmental

Felder, Stefan and Reto Schleiniger. 2002. “Environmental tax reform: efficiency and

trade programs:

Fisher, B.S. and M.D. Hinchy. 2004. “The Role of Energy Prices in Global Climate The Economics of Climate Change, New

112(1):145-194.

Fredriksson, Per G. and Daniel L. Millimet. 2004. “Electoral rules and environmental

“Legislative Organization and

Gallagher, Michael. 1991. “Proportionality, disproportionality and electoral systems”

itics of Electoral Systems.

Cambridge University

Garrett, Geoffrey and Deborah Mitchell. 2001. “Globalization, government spending and 177.

based Approaches to Enviornmental

Page 287: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

275

Genschel, Phillipp. 2002. “Globalization, Tax Competition, and the Welfare State.” Politics and Society. 30(2): 245-275. Gerlagh, R. and B. van der Zwaan. 2006. “Option and Instruments for a Deep Cut in CO2 Emissions: Carbon Dioxide Capture or Renwables, Taxes or Subsidies?” The Energy Journal, 27 (3): 25-48. Gerlagh, R. and W. Lise. 2005. “Carbon Taxes: A Drop in the Ocean, or a Drop that Erodes the Stone? The Effect of Carbon Taxes on Technological Change” Ecological Economics 54: 241-260. Goodstein, Eban. 1999. The Trade-Off Myth: Fact & fiction about jobs and the environment. Island Press. Goodstein, Eban, Kristen Sheeran, Peter Dorman, John Laitner, and Jonathan Isham. 2010. “Climate Policy and Jobs: An Update on What Economists Know” Economics for Equity and the Environment Network. June 2010. Gould, A.C. and P.J. Baker. 2002. “Democracy and Taxation” Annual Review of Political Science, 5 (87): 87-110. Goulder, Lawrence H. 1995. “Environmental Taxation and the Double Dividend: A Reader’s Guide.” International Tax and Public Finance, 2: 157-183. Goulder, Lawrence H. 1998. “Environmental Policy-Making in a Second-Best Setting” Journal of Applied Economics. 1(2): 279-328. Goulder, Lawrence H., Ian W.H. Parry, Roberton C. Williams III, and Dallas Burtraw. 1999. “The cost-effectiveness of alternative instruments for environmental protection in a second-best setting” Journal of Public Economics. 72: 329-360. Government Accountability Office (GAO). 2008. “Expert Opinion on the Economics of Policy Options to Address Climate Change.” United States Government Accountability Office. GAO-08-605. Grafton, R.Q., W.L. Adamowicz, D. Dupont, H. Nelson, S. Renzetti and R.J. Hill. 2004. The Economics of the Environment and Natural Resources. New York: Wiley. Green, Kenneth P, Steven F. Hayward and Kevin A. Hassett. 2007. “Climate Change: Caps vs. Taxes” Energy and Environment Outlook, no.2. American Enterprise Institute. Grossman, Gene M. and Alan B. Krueger. 1995. “Economic Growth and the Environment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 110(2): 353-377. Gupta, Sujata, Dennis A. Tirpak, et al. 2007. "Policies, Instruments and Co-operative Arrangements." In Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III

Page 288: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

276

to the Fourth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, edited by B. Metz, O.R. Davidson, P.R. Bosch, R. Dave and L.A. Meyer, 746-807: Cambridge University Press. [http://www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment report/ar4/wg3/ar4-wg3-chapter13.pdf] Hahn, Robert W. 1989. “Economic Prescriptions for Environmental Problems: How the Patient Followed the Doctor’s Orders” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 3(2): 95-114. Hahn, Robert W. 1990. “The Political Economy of Environmental Regulation: Towards a Unifying Framework,” Public Choice, 65: 21-47. Hahn, R.W. S.M. Olmstead and R.N. Stavins (2003) “Environmental Regulation in the 1990s: A Retrospective Analysis.” Harvard Environmental Law Review. 27: 377-415. Haigh, Nigel. 1996. “Climate change policies and politics in the European Community.” In Tim O’Riordan and Jill Jäger eds. Politics of Climate Change: a European Perspective. London: Routledge, 155-185. Hall, P.A. 1986. Governing the Economy. New York: Oxford University Press. Hall, P.A. 1997. “The Role of Interests, Institutions and Ideas in the Comparative Political Economy of the Industrialized Nations” in M.I. Lichbach and A.S. Zuckerman eds. Comparative Politics: Rationality, Culture and Structure. New York: Cambridge University Press: 174-2007. Hall, Peter. ed. 1989 The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism across Nations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Hall, P.A. and D. Soskice eds. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage, New York: Oxford University Press. Hall, P.A. and R.C.R. Taylor. 1996. “Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms” Political Studies. 44 (5): 936-957. Hall, P.A. and D.W. Gingerich. 2009. “Varieties of Capitalism and Institutional Complementarities in the Macroeconomy: An Empirical Analysis” British Journal of Political Science. 39: 449-482. Hamilton, Lawrence C. 2006. Statistics with Stata, Updated for Version 9. Toronto: Thomson Nelson. Hammar, Henrik, Åsa Löfgren, and Thomas Sterner. 2004. “Political Economy Obstacles to Fuel Taxation.” The Energy Journal 25 (3): 1-17. Hansen, James. 2008. “Climate threat to the Planet: Implications for Energy Policy” presented to the PACON Conference entitled, Energy and Climate Change: Innovative

Page 289: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

277

Approaches to Solving Today’s Problems, June 2008. (see also letter from Hansen to Obama). Hansen, James, Makiko Sato, Pushker Kharecha, David Beerling, Robert Berner, Valerie Masson-Delmotte, Mark Pagani, Maureen Raymo, Dana L. Royer and James C. Zachos. 2008. “Target Atmospheric CO2: Where should humanity aim?” Open Atmospheric Science Journal. 2:217-231. Hansen, James, Makiko Sato, Reto Ruedy, Ken Lo, David W. Lea, and Martin Medina-Elzade. 2006. “Gobal temperature change.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 103: 14288-14293. Hardin, Garrett. 1968. “The tragedy of the commons.” Science. 162: 1243-1248. Harrison, Kathryn. 2009. “A tale of two taxes: the fate of environmental tax reform in Canada and in the province of British Columbia” presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 2009, Toronto. Harrison, Kathryn. 2010. “The comparative politics of carbon taxation.” Annual Review of Law and Scoial Science. Forthcoming. Harrison, K. and L. Sundstrom. Eds. 2010. Global Commons, Domestic Decisions: the Comparative Politics of Climate Change. MIT. Hart, Austin. 2010. “Death of the Partisan? Globalization and Taxation in South America, 1990-2006” Comparative Political Studies. 43(3): 304-328. Hart, David M. 2004. “Business” is not an Interest Group: on the study of companies in American National Politics” Annual Review of Political Science. 7:47-69. Harvey, Danny L.D. 2010. Energy and the new Reality, Volume 1: Energy Efficiency and the Demand for Energy Services. London: Earthscan. Harvey, Danny L.D. 2000. Global Warming: the Hard Science. Harlow, Essex: Prentice Hall, 2000. Hassett, Kevin A. and Gilbert E. Metcalf. 2006. “What would a rational energy tax policy look like?” Tax Analysts Special Supplement on Energy. American Enterprise Institute: 89-92. Haugland, T., A. T. Lunde and K. Roland. 1992. “A Review and Comparison of CO2 Taxes in the Nordic Countries” in Climate Change: Designing a Practical Tax System. Paris: OECD, 25 – 54. Hays, J.C. 2003. “Globalization and Capital Taxation in Consensus and Majoritarian Democracies” World Politics. 56(1): 79-113.

Page 290: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

278

Heston, Alan, Robert Summers and Bettina Aten. 2009. Penn World Table Version 6.3, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania. Hoel, Michael. 1996. “Should a Carbon Tax be Differentiated Across Sectors?” Journal of Public Economics. 59: 17 – 32. Hoffmann, Matthew J. 2005. Ozone Depletion and Climate Change: Constructing a Global Response. Albany: SUNY Press. Hoffmann, Matthew J. 2009. “My Norm is Better than Your Norm: Norm Contestation in the Impasse in Climate Change Governance.” Draft paper. Hoggan, James and Richard Littlemore. 2009. Climate Cover-Up: The crusade to deny global warming. Vancouver: Greystone Books. Houghton, John Theodore. 2004. Global Warming: the Complete Briefing, Third Ed., New York: Cambridge University Press. Houle, David. 2009. “Alberta Climate Change Policy in the Canada-US Context,” paper presented at the Annual APSA meeting, Toronto Canada, 2009. Houle, David and Douglas Macdonald. 2009. “Understanding the selection of policy instruments in Canadian climate change policy” paper presented at the Annual 2009 CPSA meeting, Ottawa, Canada, 2009. Holladay, Scott J., Jonathan Horne and Jason A Schwartz. 2009. “Economists and Climate Change: Consensus and Open Questions.” Policy Brief No.5, Institute for Policy Integrity. November 2009. Holzinger, Katharina, C. Knill and T. Sommerer. 2008. “Environmental policy convergence: the impact of international harmonization, transnational communication and regulatory competition.” International Organization. 62: 553-587. Hoeller, P. and J. Coppel (1992) “Energy Taxation and Price Distortions in Fossil-Fuel Markets: Some Implications for Climate Change Policy,” chapter 12 in Climate Change: Designing a Practical Tax System, Paris: OECD, pp.185-211. Hovi, Jon and Bjart Holtsmark. 2006. “Cap-and-Trade or Carbon Taxes? The Feasibility of Enforcement and the Effects of non-Compliance,” International Environmental Agreements. 6: 137-155. Huber, Evelyne, Charles Ragin, John D. Stephens, David Brady, and Jason Beckfield, Comparative Welfare States Data Set, Northwestern University, University of North Carolina, Duke University and Indiana University, 2004.

Page 291: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

279

Huber, Peter J. and Elvezio Ronchetti. 2009. Robust Statistics. Second Ed. New Jeresey: John Wiley and Sons. Hugh, C. and I. Bailey eds. (2009) Turning Down the Heat: The Politics of Climate Policy in Affluent Democracies. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. Hughes, David J. 2006. “Peak Oil and the Future of Energy” presented at the City of North Vancouver Capilano College Global Stwardship Program, November 2006. Hyndman, R. (2009) “The Cost of Carbon: get used to uncertainty, and allow government, not traders, to set the price of carbon,” Alternatives. (35)1: 28-32. IEA. 2005. World Energy Outlook 2005: Middle East and North Africa Insights. Paris: OECD. IEA. 2007. Contribution of Renewables to Energy Security. Paris: OECD. IEA. 2007a. Energy Security and Climate Policy: Assessing Interactions. Paris: OECD. IEA. 2007b. World Energy Outlook 2007: Executive Summary. Paris: OECD. IEA. 2008a. Energy Prices and Taxes, Paris: OECD (various volumes). IEA. 2008b. CO2 Emissions from Fuel Combustion: 2008 Edition. Paris: OECD. IEA. 2009(a). Energy Prices and Taxes. Paris: OECD. IEA, 2009(b). World Energy Outlook 2009. Paris: OECD. IEA. 2010. “Energy Subsidies: Getting the Prices Right.” IEA Office of the Chief Economist. Monday 7 June 2010. IMF. 2008. “Paying for Climate Change” Finance and Development. 45(1). Inglehart, R., M. Basáñez, J. Díez-Medrano, L. Halman and R. Luijkx eds. 2004. Human Beliefs and Values: A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook based on the 1992-2002 Values Surveys. Mexico City: Siglo Veintinuno Editores. Inglis, B. and A.B. Laffer. 2008. “An Emissions Plan Conservatives Could Warm To” New York Times. http://www.nytimes.com/2008/12/28/opinion/28inglis.html IPCC. 2007a. “Chapter 13: Policies, Instruments and Co-operative Arrangements” in Climate Change 2007: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth Assessment Report on the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change.

Page 292: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

280

IPCC. 2007b. Climate Change 2007: The Physical Science Basis. Geneva: IPCC Secretariat. Iversen, Torben and John D. Stephens. 2008. “Partisan Politics, the Welfare State, and Three Worlds of Human Capital Formation.” Comparative Political Studies. 41(4/5): 600-637. Iversen, T. and D. Soskice. 2006. “Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute More than Others” American Political Science Review. 100(2): 165-181. Izzo, Phil. 2007. “Is it time for a new tax on energy? Economists say governments should foster alternatives – but not how Bush proposes” Wall Street Journal, 9 February 2007: A6. Jaccard, M. and C. Bataille. 2000. “Estimating Future Elasticities of Substitutes for the Rebound Debate,” Energy Policy. 28: 451-455. Jacoby, Henry D. and A. Denny Ellerman. 2004. “The safety valve and climate policy.” Energy Policy. 32: 481-491. Jaeger, Carlo C. and Julia Jaeger. 2010. “Three views of two degrees.” ECF Working Paper. Jaffe, A., S.R. Peterson, P.R. Portney and R.N. Stavins. 1995. “Environemtnal Regulation and the Competitiveness of US Manufcaturing: What does the evidence tell us?” Journal of Economic Literature, 33. Jaffe A. B. and R. N. Stavins. 1995. “Dynamic Incentives of Environmental Regulations: The Effects of Alternative Policy Instruments on Technology Diffusion” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29: S-43-S63. Jahn, D. 1998. “Environmental performance and policy regimes: explaining variations in 18 OECD-countries,” Policy Sciences. 31: 107-131. Jenkins, Holman W. Jr. 2007. “Decoding Climate Politics” Wall Street Journal, Business World. January 24, 2007; page A12. Jenkins, R., J. Barton, A. Bartzokas, J. Hesselberg and H.M. Knutsen. 2002. Environmental Regulation in the New Global Economy: The Impact on Industry and Competitiveness. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. Jo Martin, Cathie and Duane Swank. 2008. “The political origins of coordinated capitalism: business organizations, party systems, and state structure in the age of innocence” American Political Science Review. 102(2): 181-198.

Page 293: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

281

Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy, 1925-1975. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Johnson, C. 1999. “The Developmental State: Odyssey of a Concept” in M Woo-Cummings, ed. The Developmental State. Ithaca: Cornell University Press: 32-60. Johnson, P., S. McKay and S. Smith. 1990. “The Distributional Consequences of Environmental Taxes” The Institute for Fiscal Studies, London: Chameleon Press. Jowit, Juliette and Patrick Wintour. 2008. “Cost of tackling global climate change has doubled, warns Stern” The Guardian. 26 June 2008. Kanji, M. and N. Nevitte. 1997. “Environmental Support, Concern and Action: An Exploratory Crossnational Analysis” International Journal of Public Opinion Resarch. 9 (1): 66-76. Kasa, S. 2000. “Policy Networks as Barriers to Green Tax Reform: The Case of CO2 Taxes in Norway” Environmental Politics. 9(4): 104-122. Kato, Junko. 2003. Regressive Taxation and the Welfare State. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Katz, Ian. 2010. “The case for climate action must be remade from the ground upwards” The Guardian. Monday 8 February 2010. Katzenstein, P. J. ed. 1978. Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States, University of Wisconsin Press. Katzenstein, P. J. 1984. Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland and the Politics of Industry. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Katzenstein, P. J. 1985. Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Katzenstain, P.J. 2003. “Small States and Small States Revisited.” New Political Economy 8: 9-30. Keefer, Philip. 2007. “DPI2006: Database of Political Institutions: Changes and Variable Definitions,” Development Research Group, World Bank. Keohane, R.O. and J. Nye. 1977. Power and Interdependence. Boston: Little Brown. Killinger, Sebastian. 2000. International Environmental Externalities and the Double Dividend. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar.

Page 294: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

282

King, Gary, James Honaker, Anne Joseph and Kenneth Scheve. 2001. “Analyzing Incomplete Political Science Data: An Alternative Algorithm for Multiple Imputation.” American Political Science Reivew. 95(1): 49-69. Kirchgässner, Gebhard and Friedrich Schneider. 2003. “On the political economy of environmental policy.” Public Choice. 115:369-396. Kitschelt. Herbert P. 1988 [1994]. "The Rise of Left-libertarian Parties in Western Democracies: Explaining Innovation in Competitive Party Systems"." World Politics 40: 194-234. (Reprinted in: Ferdinand Müller-Rommel and Thomas Poguntke, eds., New Politics. Aldershot: Dartmouth Publishing Company, 1994) Klok, Jacob. 2002. “Negotiating EU CO2/energy taxation: Political economic driving forces and barriers” AKF Forlaget, February. Kristensen, Ida Pagter and Gregory Wawro. 2007. “On the Use of Fixed Effects Estimators for Time-Series Cross-Section Data,” Working Paper, July. Laakso, Markku, and Rein Taagepera. 1979. “The “effective” number of parties: A measure with application to West Europe.” Comparative Political Studies. 12: 3-27. Lachapelle, E. 2009. “What Price Carbon? Theory and Practice of Carbon Taxation in the OECD” paper prepared for the 81st Annual Conference of the Canadian Political Science Association, Carleton University, Ottawa, 27 – 29 May, 2009. Lane, Jan-Erik, David McKay and Kenneth Newton. 1997. Political Data Handbook OECD Countries. Oxford University Press. Lanoie, P., M. Patry and R. Lajeunesse. 2008. “Environmental Regulation and Productivity: New findings on the Porter Hypothesis,” Journal of Productivity Analysis. 30:121-128. Layzer, Judith A. 2007. “Deep Freeze: How Business Has Shaped the Global Warming Debate in Congress.” Pp. 93 – 126 in Michael E. Kraft and Sheldon Kamieniecki eds. Business and Environmental Policy: Corporate Interests in the American Political System. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. LeClair, M.S. 2006. “Achieving Gasoline Price Stability in the U.S.: A Modest Proposal” The Energy Journal, 27 (2): 41-54. Lenton, Timothy M., Hermann Held, Elmar Kriegler, Jim W. Hall, Wolfgang Lucht, Stefan Rahmstorf, and Hans Joachim Schellnhuber. 2009. “Tipping elements in the Earth’s climate system.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 105(6): 1786-1793.

Page 295: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

283

Levine, Michael E. and Jennifer L. Forrence. 1990. “Regulatory Capture, Public Interest, and the Public Agenda: Toward a Synthesis” Journal of Law Economics & Organization. 6: 167-198. Lewis-Beck, Michael. 1980. Applied Regression: An Introduction .Newbury: Sage. Lijphart, Arend. 1990. �The political consequences of electoral laws, 1945-85� American Political Science Review. 84(2): 481-496. Lijphart, A., M.M.L. Crepaz. 1991. �Corporatism and Consensus Democracy in Eighteen Countries: Conceptual and Empirical Linkages� British Journal of Political Science, 21 (2): 235-246. Liski, Matti and Olli Tahvonen. 2004. “Can carbon tax eat OPEC’s rents?” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 47: 1-12. Määttä, K. 2003. “Finnish Energy Taxation: How Well Has it Worked?” in Milne et al. eds. Critical Issues in Environmental Taxation: International and Comparative Perspectives Volume I. Richmond UK: Richmond Law and Tax Ltd.,175-188. Määttä, K. 1997. “Environmental Taxes – From an Economic Idea to a Legal Institution.” Kauppakaari Oy, Jyväskylä. Mæstad, O. 2003. “Environmental Policy in the Steel Industry: Using Economic Instruments” Paris: OECD. Macdonald, Douglas. 2007. Business and Environmental Politics in Canada. Broadview. Macdonald, Douglas, Jean Mercier, Jean Crête, Patrick Gonzales and Aurélie Le Gars. 2006. “Why do governments select voluntarism as an environmental policy instrument?” paper presented at the Annual CPSA, York University, Toronto Canada, 2009. MacKenzie, Donald. 2007. “The Political Economy of Carbon Trading” London Review of Books. 29(7): 29-31. Mankiw, Gregory N. 2006. “Raise the gas tax” Wall Street Journal. Ocotber 20, 2006. Mankiw, N.G. 2007. “One Answer to Global Warming: A New Tax,” The New York Times, 19/09/2007. Manne, A.S., and R.G. Richels. 1993. “The EC Proposal for combining carbon and energy taxes: the implications for future CO2 emissions.” Energy Policy 21(1): 5-12. Manow, Philip. 2009. “Electoral rules, class coalitions and welfare state regimes, or how to explain Esping-Andersen with Stein Rokkan” Socio-Economic Review. 7:101-121.

Page 296: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

284

Marshall, A. 1890. [1961] Principles of Economics. Londong: Macmillan. Martin, Roger and Alison Kemper. 2010. “Carbon Pricing, Innovation, and Productivity: Implications for Canadian Policy Makers” Ottawa: Sustainable Prosperity. Mathiesen, L. and O. Mæstad. 2004. “Climate Policy and the Steel Industry: Achieving Emission Reductions by an Incomplete Climate Agreement” The Energy Journal, 25 (4): 91-114. Matthews, H. Damon, Nathan P. Gillett, Peter A. Stott and Kirsten Zickfield. 2009. “The proportionality of global warming to cumulative carbon emissions.” Nature. 459: 829-833. Mayhew, David R. 1974. The Electoral Connection. New Haven CT.: Yale University Press. McInnes, C. “With a political will, there’s a way” Vancouver Sun. October 30, 2009. http://www.vancouversun.com/business/With+political+will+there/2161382/story.html. Accessed on December 17, 2009. Meinshausen, Malte, Nicolai Meinshausen, William Hare, Sarah C. B. Raper, Katja Frieler, Reto Knutti, David J. Frame and Mules R. Allen. 2009. “Greenhouse gas emissions targets for limiting global warming to 2 oC.” Nature. 458:1158-1162. Michaels, David and Celeste Monforton. 2005. “Manufacturing Uncertainty: contested science and the protection of the public’s health and environment.” American Journal of Public Health. 95: 539-548. Mignone, B.K. 2007. “The National Security Dividend of Global Carbon Mitigation,” Energy Policy. 35(11): 5403-5410. Milne, J., K. Deketelaere, L. Kreiser and H. Ashiabor eds. (2003) Critical Issues in Environmental Taxation: International and Comparative Perspectives Volume I. Richmond UK: Richmond Law and Tax Ltd. Milner, H.V. 1997. Interests, Institutions and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, Roberto Perotti and Massimo Rostagno. 2002. “Electoral Systems and Public Spending.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117: 609-657. Mintz, Jack and Nancy Olewiler. 2008. “A Simple Approach for Bettering the Environment and the Economy: Restructuring the Federal Fuel Excise Tax” Ottawa: Sustainable Prosperity/University of Ottawa.

Page 297: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

285

Missfeldt, F. and J. Hauff. 2004. “The Role of Economic Instruments” in A.D. Owen and N. Hanley eds. The Economics of Climate Change, New York: Routledge, 115-146. Monroe, Burt L. 1994. “Disproportionality and Malaportionment: Measuring electoral inequity.” Electoral Studies. 13(2): 132-149. Morozova, Svetlana. V. 2005. Political Economy of Energy Taxation in the OECD, 1973-1995. Dissertation submitted to Claremont Graduate University. Molina, Mario, Durwood Zaelke, K. Madhava Sarma, Stephen O. Andersen, Veerabhardran Ramanathan, and Donald Kaniaru. 2009. “Reducing abrubt climate change risk using the Montreal Protocol and other regulatory actions to complement cuts in CO2 emissions” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. Early edition. Nai’ang, Wang, Zhao Qiang, Li Jijun, Hu Gang, Cheng Hongyi. 2003. “The sand wedges of the last ice age in the Hexi Corridor, China: paleoclimatic interpretation.” Geomorphology. 51: 313-320. National Research Council (NRC). 2010. Advancing the Science of Climate Change. Washington, D.C.: The National Academies Press. National Round Table on the Environment and Economy (NRTEE). 2007. “Getting to 2050: Canada’s Transition to a Low-emission Future” National Round Table on the Environment and Economy. National Round Table on the Environment and Economy (NRTEE). 2009. “Achieving 2050: A Carbon Pricing Policy for Canada” National Round Table on the Environment and Economy. Neumayer, Eric. 2003. “Are left-wing party strength and corporatism good for the environment? Evidence from panel analysis of air pollution in OECD countries” Ecological Economics. 45: 203-220. Newbery, David M. 2005. “Why Tax Energy? Towards a More Rational Policy” The Energy Journal. 26(3): 1-40. Nordhaus, William D. 2007. “To tax or not to tax: Alternative approaches to slowing global warming,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 1: 26-44. Nordic Council of Ministers (2002) The use of economic instruments in Nordic Environmental Policy 1999-2001. TemaNord 2002:581, Nordic Council of Ministers, Copenhagen. North, D. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Page 298: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

286

Norwegian Ministry of Finance. “The history of green taxes in Norway” http://www.regjeringen.no/en/dep/fin/tema/skatter_og_avgifter/The-history-of-green-taxes-in-Norway.html?id=418097 Oates, Wallace E. 1995. “Green Taxes: Can we protect the environment and improve the tax system at the same time?” Southern Economic Journal. 61(4):915-922. Oates, Wallace E. 1991 “Pollution Charges as a Source of Public Revenues, Washington, DC: Resources for the Future, Discussion Paper, pp.92-105. OECD (2009) Country Statistical Profiles. OECD.stat. OECD (2003) Environmental Policy in the steel industry: Using economic instruments. Paris: OECD. OECD (2001) Environmentally Related Taxes in OECD Countries: Issues and Strategies. Paris: OECD. OECD (2005) The Competitiveness impact of CO2 emissions reduction in the cement sector. Paris: OECD. OECD (2006) The Political Economy of Environmentally Related Taxes. Paris: OECD. OECD (2006a) Revenue Statistics. OECD (2007) Database on Instruments used for Environmental Policy and Natural Resource Management. http://www2.oecd.org/ecoinst/queries/index.htm. Last viewed on 15, May 2008. OECD. 1997. Environmental Taxes and Green Tax Reform. Paris: OECD. OECD. 2010. “Measuring Support to Energy – Version 1.0.” Background paper to the joint report by IEA, OPEC, OECD and World Bank on “Analysis of the Scope of Energy Subsidies and Suggestions for the G-20 Initiative.” OECD. 1999. “Economic Instruments for Pollution Control and Natural Resource Management in OECD Countries: A Survey.” Paris: OECD. Olewiler, Nancy. 1994. “The impact of environmental regulation on investment decisions” in Jamie Benedickson, G. Bruce Doern and Nancy Olewiler, Getting the Green Light: Environmental Regulation and Investment Decisions in Canada. C.D. Howe Institute. Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Harvard University Press.

Page 299: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

287

Olson, Mancur. 1971. “Increasing the incentives for international cooperation.” International Organization. 25: 866-874. Panova, V. V. 2006. “Explaining Compliance with International Energy Commitments: The G8 and the IEA,” paper presented at the 47th Annual Convention of the International Studies Association, San Diego, 22-25 March 2006. Papadakis, Elim. 1996. Environmental Politics and Institutional Change. Cambridge University Press. Papadakis, Elim. 1986. “The Green Alternative: interpretation of social protest and political action in West Germany.” Austrialian Journal of Politics and History. 32(3): 443-454. Pardy, Bruce. 2007. “Climate Change Charades: False environmental pretences of statist energy governance.” Delivered at the 14th Annual Queen’s Business Law Symposium, Energy and the Law. October 2007. Pardy, Bruce. 2008. “What’s wrong with this picture? A Skeptic’s Lament.” Presentation to the Carbon Pricing and Environmental Federalism Conference, Queen’s University. 17 – 18, 2008, Kingston, Ontario. Pal, L.A. and R. K. Weaver. 2003. The Government Taketh Away: The Politics of Pain in the United States and Canada. Georgetown UP. Parry, I.W.H. and W.A. Pizer. 2007. “Emissions Trading versus CO2 Taxes versus Standards” Issue Brief 5, Resources for the Future. Parry, Ian W.H. 1995. “Pollution Taxes and Revenue Recycling.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 29:S-64-S-77. Pearce, D. 1991. “The Role of Carbon Taxes in Adjusting to Global Warming” Economic Journal, 101(407): 938-948. Pearce, D. 2005. “The United Kingdom Climate Change Levy: A Study in Political Economy” Paris: OECD. Pearce, D. 2006. “The political economy of an energy tax: The United Kingdom’s Climate Change Levy” Ecological Economics. 28(2): 149-158. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. 1999. “The size and scope of government: Comparative politics with rational politicians.” European Economic Review. 43:699-735. Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. 2002. “Do constitutions cause large governments? Quasi-experimental evidence.” European Economic Review. 46: 908-918.

Page 300: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

288

Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. 2004. “Constitutional rules and fiscal policy outcomes.” The American Economic Review. 94: 25-45. Perrson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. 2008. “Electoral systems and economic policy” in Barry R. Weingast and Donald A. Wittman eds. Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford. Peters, B. Guy. 1980. “Determinants of Choice in Tax Policy” pp. 203-212 in Thomas R. Dye and Virginia Gray eds. The Determinants of Public Policy. Toronto: Lexington Books. Petit, J.R., J. Jouzel, D. Raynaud, N.I. Barkow, J.M. Barnola, I. Basile, M. Benders, J. Chappellaz, M. Davis, G. Delaygue, M. Delmotte, V.M. Kotlyakov, M. Legrand, V.Y. Lipenkov, C. Lorivs, L. Pépin, C. Ritz, E. Saltzman, and M. Stievenard. 1999. “Climate and atmospheric history of the past 420,000 years from the Vostok ice core, Antartica.” Nature. 399: 429-436. Pew Centre on Global Climate Change. 2010. “Targets and actions under the Copenhagen Accord.” http://www.pewclimate.org/copenhagen-accord Pezzey, J. 1992. “Analysis of unilateral CO2 control in the European Community and OECD. The Energy Journal. 13(3): 159-171. Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” American Political Science Review. 94(2): 251-267. Pierson, P. 1996. “The New Politics of the Welfare State,” World Politics 48 (2): 143-179. Pierson, P. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Pigou, A.C. 1920 [1960] The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan. Pizer, W.A. 1998. “Prices vs. Quantities Revisited: The Case of Climate Change,” Discussion Paper 98-02, Resources for the Future. Pizer, W.A. 1999. “Choosing Price or Quantity Controls for Greenhouse Gases” Climate Issues Brief No. 17, Resources for the Future. – tax will “produce expected net gains five times higher than even the most favourably designed quantity target” Plümper, Thomas and Vera E. Troeger. 2007. “Efficient estimation of time-invariant and rarely changing variables in finite sample panel analyses with unit-fixed effects.” Political Analysis. 18(4): 124-139. Porter, M.E. 1991. “America’s Green Strategy,” Scientific American. 264: 186.

Page 301: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

289

Porter, M.E. and C. van der Linde. 1995. “Toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship.” Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9(4): 97-118. Poterba, J.M. 1991. “Tax Policy to Combat Global Warming: On Designing a Carbon Tax” in R. Dornbusch and J.M. Poterba eds., Global Warming: Economic Policy Responses. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. Poterba, J.M. 1993. “Global Warming Policy: A Public Finance Perspective.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(4): 47-63. Powell, Bingham G. 2000. Elections as Instruments of Democracy: Majoritarian and Proportional Visions. Yale University Press. Quinn, Dennis. 1997. “The Correlates of Change in International Financial Regulation.”American Political Science Review. 91: 531-551. Quinn, Dennis P. and Robert Y. Shapiro. 1991. “Business Political Power: The case of taxation.” American Political Science Review. 85(3): 851-874. Rabe, Barry. 2010. “The Aversion to Direct Cost-Imposition: Selecting Climate Policy Tools in the United States.” Governence. Forthcoming. Rabe, Barry. 2010. “The ‘Impossible Dream’ of Carbon Taxes: is the “Best Answer” a Political non-Starter?” Chapter 6 in Barry Rabe ed. Greenhouse Governance: Addressing Climate Change Policy in the United States. Brookings. Rabe, Barry, Erick Lachapelle and David Houle (forthcoming) “Climate Compared: Sub-federal Dominance on a Global Issue” forthcoming in Jenn Wallner, Martin Papillon, Luc Turgeon and Steve White eds. Canada Compared. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press. Rae, Douglas. 1971. The Political Consequences of Electoral Laws. Yale University Press. Raymond, Leigh. 2004. “Economic growth as environmental policy? Reconsidering the Environmental Kuznets Curve” Journal of Public Policy. 24: 327-348. Reinaud, Julia. 2008. “Issues Behind Competitiveness and Carbon Leakage: Focus on Heavy Industry.” Paris: International Energy Agency. Rodden, Jonathan. 2007. Political Geography and Electoral Rules: Why Single-Member Districts are Bad for the Left. Working Paper. Roediger-Schluga, T. 2002. “The Stringency of Environmental Regulation and the ‘Porter Hypothesis’” in L. Marsiliani, M. Rauscher and C. Withagen eds. Environmental Economics and the International Economy: 123-148.

Page 302: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

290

Rogowski, R. and M.A. Kayser. 2002. “Majoritarian Electoral Systems and Consumer Power: Price-level Evidence from the OECD Countries” American Journal of Political Science, 46 (3): 526-539. Rootes, Christopher ed. 2003. Environmental Protest in Western Europe. Oxford University Press. Rivers, Nic and Dave Sawyer. 2008. Pricing Carbon, Saving Green: A carbon price to lower emissions, taxes and barriers to green technology. David Suzuki Foundation. Sachs, Jeffrey D. (2009) “Putting a Price on Carbon: An Emissions Cap or a Tax?” Environment 360: Opinion, Analysis, Reporting & Debate. Available at: http://e360.yale.edu/content/feature.msp?id=2148 Salanié, B. (2003) The Economics of Taxation. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT. Sandmo, A. (2000) The Public Economics of the Environment. New York: Oxford University Press. Sandmo, A. (2005) “Environmental Taxation and Revenue for Development” in A. B. Atkinson ed. New Sources of Development Finance, New York: Oxford University Press, 33-57. Sandmo, Agnar. 1975. “Optimal Taxation in the Presence of Externalities.” Swedish Journal of Economics. 77:86-98. Sartori, Giovanni. 1970. “Concept misformation in comparative politics.” American Political Science Review. 64: 1033-1053. Schneider, Friedrich and Juergen Volkert. 1999. “No chance for incentive-oriented environmental policies in representative democracies? A Public Choice analysis.” Ecological Economics. 31: 123-138. Schroeder, L.D., D.L. Sjoquist, P.E. Stephan (1986) “Understanding Regression Analysis: An Introductory Guide” Newbury: Sage. Schumpeter, Joseph. 1950. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper Row. Shulz. 2007. “The merit of a carbon tax” http://www.aei.org/article/26624 Siaroff, A. 1999. “Corporatism in 24 industrial democracies: Meaning and measurement” European Journal of Political Research, 36: 175-205. Speck, S., J. McNicholas and M. Markovic. 2003. “National Experiences with Pollution Taxes: What have we Learned” in Milne et al. eds. Critical Issues in Environmental

Page 303: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

291

Taxation: International and Comparative Perspectives Volume I. Richmond UK: Richmond Law and Tax Ltd., 269-288. Stavins, R.N. 1998. “Market-based Environmental Policies” Discussion Paper 98-26, Resources for the Future. Stavins, R. and B. Whitehead. 1997. in M. Chertow and D. Esty eds. Thinking Ecologically: The Next Generation of Environmental Policy. Yale: Yale University Press, 105-115. Steinmo, S. 1993. Taxation and Democracy: Swedish, British and American Approaches to Financing the Modern State. New Haven: Yale University Press. Steinmo, S. and C.J. Tolbert. 1998. “Do Institutions Really Matter? Taxation in Industrialized Democracies” Comparative Political Studies, 31(2): 165-187. Steinmo, S., K. Thelen and F. Longstreth eds. 1992. Structuring Politics: Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. Stern, Sir N. 2006. Stern Review: Report on the Economics of Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Sterner, T. 2007. “Fuel taxes: An important instrument for climate policy” Energy Policy, 35: 3194-3202. Strom, K. 1990. Minority Government and Majority Rule. Cambridge University Press. Suzuki, David and Dennis DesRosiers. 2007. “It’s time to think the unthinkable: Put a tax on gas” The Globe and Mail. April 20. Svendsen, G.T., C. Daugbjerg, L. Hjøllund, A.B. Pedersen. 2001. “Consumers, industrialists and the political economy of green taxation: CO2 taxation in the OECD” Energy Policy 29: 489-497. Swank, Duane. 2002. Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States. New York: Cambridge University Press. Swank, Duane. 2006. “Tax Policy in an Era of Internationalization: Explaining the Spread of Neoliberalism.” International Organization. 60: 847-882. Swank, Duane. 2007. Electoral, Legislative, and Government Strength of Political Parties by Ideological Type, 1950-2006: A Data Base. http://www.marquette.edu/polisci/documents/part19502006code.pdf

Page 304: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

292

Swank, Duane and Sven Steinmo. 2002. “The New Political Economy of Taxation in Advanced Capitalist Democracies” American Journal of Political Science, 46 (3): 642-655. Taagepera, Rein and Bernard Grofman. 1985. “Rethinking Duverger’s Law: Predicting the Effective Number of Parties in Plurality and PR Systems – Parties Minus Issues Equals One” European Journal of Political Research. 13: 341-352. Taagepera, R. and M. Shugart. 1989. Seats and Votes: the effects and determinants of electoral systems. Yale University Press. Tans, P.P. 2007. “Global Net Emissions of will have to go to Zero” paper presented at the CHEMRAWN-XVII Greenhouse Gasses, Mitigation and Utilization Conference, Queen’s University 8-12 July 2007. Treiman, Donald J. 2009. Quantitative Data Analysis: Doing research to test ideas. Jossey-Bass. Truc, O. 2009. “The carbon tax has proven its effectiveness in Sweden” Le Monde. Thursday 2 July 2009. Available at: www.truthout.org/070309F?print Truman, D. 1951. The Governmental Process: Political Interests and Public Opinion. New York: Knopf. Uzawa, Hirofumi 2003. Economic Theory and Global Warming. New York: Cambridge University Press. Vehmas, J. 2005. “Energy-related taxation as an environmental policy tool—the Finnish experience 1990-2003” Energy Policy, 33: 2175-2182. Vehmas, J., J. Kaivo-oja, J. Luukkanen, and P. Malaska. 1999. “Environmental taxes on fuels and electricity – some experiences from the Nordic Countries” Energy Policy, 27: 343-355. Vermeend, W. and J. van der Vaart. 1998. Greening Taxes: The Dutch Model. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Vermeend, W. and J. van der Vaart. 1998. Greening Taxes: The Dutch Model. Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Victor, David. 2006. Toward Effective International Cooperation on Climate Change: Numbers, Interests, and Institutions. Global Environmental Politics 6 (3): 90-103. Vollebergh, H. 2007. “Impacts of Environmental Policy Instruments on Technology Change” OECD: Paris.

2CO

Page 305: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

293

Wade, R. 1990. Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization. Princeton New Jersey: Princeton University Press. Ward, Hugh and Xun Cao. 2010. “Domestic and International Influences on Green Taxation.” Presented at the International Studies Association Annual Convention, New Orleans, February 17-20, 2010. Weitzman, M.L. 1974. “Prices vs. Quantities” The Review of Economic Studies, 41(4): 477-491. Weyant, J.P. and J.N. Hill. 1999. “The Costs of the Kyoto Protocol: a Multi-Model Evaluation,” Special Issue of The Energy Journal, 20: 1-390. Whitford, Andrew B. and Karen Wong. 2009. “Political and Social Foundations for Environmental Sustainability.” Political Research Quarterly. 62:190-204. Wier, Mette, Katja Birr-Pedersen, Henrik Klige Jacobsen and Jacob Klok. 2005. “Are CO2 Taxes Regresive: Evidence from the Danish Experience.” Ecological Economics. 52(2): 239 – 251. Wilson, Sven and Daniel Butler. 2007. “A lot more to do: The sensitivity of Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis to simple alternative specifications,” Political Analysis, 15: 101-123. Winner, Hannes. 2005. “Has tax competition emerged in OECD countries? Evidence from Panel Data” International Tax and Public Finance. 12: 667-687. Wissema, W. and R. Dellink. 2007. “AGE Analysis of the Impact of Carbon Energy Tax on the Irish Economy” Ecological Economics 61: 671-683. Wooldridge, J. M. 2006. Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach. Mason: OH: Thomson. World Bank. 2010. “What is the role of carbon taxes in climate change mitigation?” Prem Notes: Special Series on the Economics of Climate Change. Number 2. World Bank. 2008. World Development Indicators. World Bank. 2007. World Development Indicators. World Values Survey. 2006. European and World Values Surveys Four-Wave Integrated Data File, 1981-2004, v.20060423. World Bank, OECD, IEA, OPEC. 2010. “Analysis of the Scope of Energy Subsidies and Suggestions for the G-20 Initiative.” IEA, OPEC, OECD, World Bank Joint Report. 16 June 2010.

Page 306: Energy Security and Climate Change Policy in the OECD: The … · 2013. 7. 1. · iii cross-national differences in these carbon-energy tax rates in order to identify the correlates

294

Yergin, Daniel. 2006. “Ensuring Energy Security.” Foreign Affairs. 85(2); 69-82. Yergin, D. 1989. The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money and Power. New York: Free Press. Yergin, D. 2006. “Ensuring Energy Security.” Foreign Affairs. April/May, 69-82. Yokoyama, A., K. Ueta and K. Fujikawa (2000) “Green Tax Reform: Converting implicit carbon taxes to a pure carbon tax” Environmental Economics and Policy Studies 3: 1-20. Zhang, ZX. and A. Baranzini. 2004. “What do we know about Carbon Taxes? An Inquiry into their Impacts on Competitiveness and Distribution of Income” Energy Policy. 32(4): 507 – 518. Zito, Anthony. 2002. “Integrating the environment into the European Union: the history of the controversial carbon tax.” Chapter 14 in Andrew Jordan, ed. Environmental Policy in the European Union. Actors, Institutions and Processes. London: Earthscan pp.241-255.