euro themes - spain

Upload: guy-dviri

Post on 03-Apr-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    1/22

    ECONOMICS RESEARCH 4 May 20

    PLEASE SEE ANALYST CERTIFICATIONS AND IMPORTANT DISCLOSURES STARTING AFTER PAGE 19

    EURO THEMES

    Spain Dealing with sudden reversals

    Market anxiety about Spain has flared up again. It has been reawakened by avery large 2011 fiscal underperformance, a poorly managed upward revision to

    the 2012 deficit target, confirmation that Spain re-entered recession in the first

    quarter, and a perception that the ECBs recent injection of liquidity may be

    reaching the limit of its effectiveness.

    One additional factor has dented market confidence further: in the past sixmonths, Spains economic and financial challenges have been exacerbated by

    large capital outflows, which intensified in the early months of 2012. If this

    sudden reversal of international capital flows is not arrested, it could pose aserious threat to the countrys economic and financial stability.

    We have not changed our view, put forward in July 2010, that Spain remainssolvent with risks. Even under the worse-than-expected fiscal cost of

    recapitalising troubled banks, Spain appears fundamentally solvent. The fiscal

    adjustment required to stabilise public debt must bring the primary budget

    balance from a deficit of roughly 6% of GDP in 2011 to a surplus of 2% of GDP

    within the next five years. As long as the commitment to long-term fiscal

    adjustment remains in place, this requirement appears manageable. Managing

    the fiscal imbalances and the banking-sector fallout of the ongoing credit cycle

    alone does not, in our view, require external official support.

    However, what the Spanish authorities cannot manage on their own is sustained,large capital outflows of the sort that have recently been experienced. If foreign

    investors continue to reduce their exposure to Spain at an economically disruptive

    rate, the country will require external financial support to manage this adjustment.

    A sudden stop in capital flows has been offset by financing channeled throughBanco de Espaa

    -150

    -100

    -50

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    Jan-00 Jan-02 Jan-04 Jan-06 Jan-08 Jan-10 Jan-12

    Banco de Espana ex BdE

    Note: 12-month moving total, billion euros. Source: Haver Analytics, Barclays Research

    Update: This report replaces the previously published version to reflect updated Analyst

    Certification information. The content remains unchanged.

    Antonio Garcia Pascual

    +44 (0)20 3134 6225

    [email protected]

    Michael Gavin

    +1 212 412 5915

    [email protected]

    Piero Ghezzi

    +44 (0)20 3134 2190

    [email protected]

    Jonathan Glionna

    +44 (0)20 3555 1992

    [email protected]

    Miguel Angel Hernandez, CFA

    +44 (0)20 7773 7241

    [email protected]

    www.barcap.com

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1612628https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1612628
  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    2/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 2

    Spain Back in the line of fire

    After a two-month respite following the ECBs surprise 3y LTRO operations, Spain has

    returned as the focus of investors scepticism and anxiety. The change in sentiment was

    triggered by a combination of factors:

    the announcement of a large fiscal slippage in 2011 (2.5pp of GDP, which brought thefiscal deficit to 8.5% of GDP);

    the delay in the presentation of the 2012 fiscal budget (until end March 2012); a relaxation of the 2012 deficit target (from 4.4% to 5.3% of GDP, with an initial

    government proposal of 5.8% of GDP revised in a messy, public and somewhat

    acrimonious negotiation with other eurozone authorities);

    a rapid deterioration in economic activity which confirmed that the economy is movinginto a double-dip recession; and

    price action in government bond markets that was interpreted by some as evidence that thepalliative effects of the ECBs recent LTRO operations were beginning to reach their limit.

    Market sentiment aside, in the past six months or so, Spains economic and financial

    challenges appear to have been exacerbated by large capital outflows that had not previously

    been a problem. Spain is experiencing a sudden stop, familiar to analysts of emerging-market

    financial crises, in which international investors are seeking to reduce exposures that were

    created during the 2003-2008 credit boom, or expressing a negative view on Spain by shorting

    Spanish assets. Much of the foreign selling has been in the Spanish government bond market,

    where foreign ownership (excluding the ECB) had, by Q1 12, decreased to less than 25% of

    the outstanding central government securities, close to half what they owned in early 2010.

    In this context, investors are focusing on the still incomplete clean-up of the legacy real

    estate assets that remain on banks balance sheets. They are also worrying about additional

    bank losses that are likely to emerge as economic activity shrinks in the months ahead.

    Moreover, investors are wondering whether the government remains solvent, in light of last

    years fiscal underperformance, the potential costs of bank recapitalisation, and public

    political debate in Europe about the merits of fiscal austerity.

    Figure 1: Spanish government bond spreads back almost toNovember 2011 levels

    Figure 2: Spanish equities have fallen to 2009:Q1 levels

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    Dec-07 Dec-08 Dec-09 Dec-10 Dec-11

    10-year sovereign spread to Germany (bp)

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    Dec-07 Dec-08 Dec-09 Dec-10 Dec-11

    MSCI Spain MSCI Spain (financials)

    Source: Bloomberg Source: Bloomberg

    Spains economic and

    financial challenges appear to

    have been exacerbated by large

    capital outflows

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    3/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 3

    The fiscal swing required to stabilise public debt is roughly 8% of GDP over a five-year period,

    which would achieve a primary surplus of just over 2% of GDP by 2016. Our view is that this is

    manageable, and will likely be achieved. When we look at the evidence provided by European

    countries that underwent prolonged periods of fiscal consolidation in the past, the average

    fiscal adjustment for these countries has been of about 10% of GDP over a seven to eight-year

    period (for details, see Spain: solvent with risks, 8 July 2010). Moreover, Spain ran an average

    primary surplus of over 2% between 1998 and 2008. So the adjustment that Spain needs toachieve would appear to be within the realm of historical precedent, both in a cross-section

    and time-series sense. If a primary surplus of about 2.25% of GDP is achieved by the 2016

    time frame, we project a gradual decline in the public debt relative to GDP, even after including

    the fiscal costs of bank recapitalisation. In this important sense, the government is solvent. But

    is this enough to reverse the sudden stop and change investor sentiment?

    Does it add up? Public debt dynamics (yet) again

    The Spanish economic and financial crisis is not fiscal in origin, but rather stems from the

    unwinding of the more generalised financial and economic boom seen during the run-up to

    the 2008 international financial crash. But as the Spanish economy has traversed the

    downside of this economic and financial cycle, weaknesses in the underlying fiscalimbalances have been exposed, and potentially large fiscal risks have been created from

    domestic banks exposure to the ailing property and construction sector. A potential

    inability to manage the fiscal consequences of the broader economic and financial

    correction is a legitimate market concern, and market anxiety about a potential public credit

    event looms large as a potential amplifier (and international propagator) of the crisis. So,

    even though budgetary problems are more consequence than cause of the crisis in Spain,

    the question will the government be able to pay is a key consideration at this stage.

    The base case: Debt dynamics are precarious but manageable

    Figure 3 illustrates our core conclusion: the Spanish public debt dynamics add up, as long as

    the government makes (and society continues to support) a long-run fiscal effort. This is true

    in a base case that we consider plausible and conservative in some cases, and under importantrisk cases as well. Ultimately, we consider the task to be challenging, but manageable.

    Figure 3: Public debt dynamics add up under our base case, and under a banking-sectorstress test (Debt of the general public sector, % of GDP)

    30%

    40%

    50%60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    110%

    2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030

    Base case Higher cost bank recapitalization

    Source: Barclays Research

    The fiscal swing required to

    stabilise public debt is

    within the realm of historical

    precedent

    Market anxiety about a potential

    public credit event looms

    large as a potential amplifier

    of the crisis

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1612628https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1612628
  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    4/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 4

    This type of analysis is a pure exercise in arithmetic: its conclusions are only as good as the

    assumptions used. The assumptions of our base case (see also Figure 4) are as follows:

    A recession that reduces real GDP by 2.0% in 2012, with another 0.5% decline in2013. Recovery is forecast to take hold over the course of 2013, with growth turning

    positive in calendar 2014, and strengthening in 2015. In the long-run steady state

    (which, in these projections, means after 2015), we anticipate nominal GDP growth of3.75%, reflecting roughly 2% inflation and 1.75% real economic growth. We view this

    as a reasonable base case for the coming two years, and conservative over the long run

    in the sense that we assume no cyclical rebound from the ongoing recession, but rather

    a smooth convergence to the steady-state growth rate. On the other hand, we do not

    forecast a significant decline in inflation, which would complicate the debt dynamics (by

    increasing the real interest rate on the public debt).

    Interest rates on newly issued public debt are assumed to be 6% in 2012 andthereafter. (The average interest rate on the public debt, currently at 4%, adjusts

    gradually, as the cost of newly issued debt is steadily rolled into the overall stock of

    debt.) We view this as a conservative assumption; 10y bonds are even now yielding less

    than 6%, and shorter-term debt issued by the government is substantially less

    expensive than this.1 Given the likelihood that risk-free interest rates are likely to

    (eventually) rise over time, the assumption of a constant Spanish interest rate implies a

    supposition that the Spanish bond spread will decline, which may seem optimistic. But

    the implied spread to German yields declines in five years to only 320bp (from roughly

    420bp today), which we consider very conservative, if anything resembling our baseline

    scenario materialises.2

    We project a gradual but firm and persistent adjustment of the non-interest budgetbalance from -6.1% of GDP in 2011 to -3.3% of GDP in 2012 , about -1.5% of GDP in

    2013, -0.15% in 2014, and a surplus of just over 1% of GDP in 2015. After 2015, we

    assume a non-interest budget surplus of 2.25% of GDP. Of the roughly 8 percentage

    point swing in the primary surplus that we envision, we believe that about 2.8% is

    already in place, with another 5.2% yet to be approved and implemented.

    We calculate that the fiscal cost from recapitalisation of the banking system will beslightly over 6 % of GDP (of which about 1.4% of GDP was paid in 2011 and is already

    included in the stock of debt). The remaining fiscal costs, about 4.7% of GDP, are likely

    to materialise in 2012-13. In an extreme but plausible stress scenario, we estimate that

    the recapitalisation cost for the sovereign would reach 11% of GDP. (See the appendix

    for a detailed explanation of these estimates.)

    We also account for two large items that will increase public debt in 2012. First andmost importantly, the government is planning to clear the excess accumulation of

    accounts payables with providers of goods and services to the different sub-central

    government administrations (regions and municipalities). These accounts, on which theadministration does not pay interest and which in normal times, have been at around

    3% to 3.5% of GDP, have increased since the crisis hit in 2008 to about 7% of GDP. The

    government is planning to clear c.EUR35bn (about 3.3% of GDP) in 2012. In turn, the

    1 The average maturity of the outstanding stock of public debt is about 6.6 years.2 The forward curve suggests that the 10y German interest rate will rise from 1.6% now to about 2.8% in five years. A 6%Spanish interest is thus consistent with a risk premium of about 320bp in five years time. In our baseline scenario, Spainspublic debt is projected to stabilise at a level comparable to that of France, with a more pronounced downward trend. Arisk premium comparable to Frances (now about 135bp) would therefore be plausible; 320bp strikes us as veryconservative.

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    5/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 5

    cash transfer to providers is likely to have a mitigating effect on the negative growth

    outlook. Second, there will be 0.9% of GDP increase in public debt in 2012 on account

    of Spains contribution to the loans to Greece, Ireland and Portugal, according to the

    Spanish contribution to the EFSF loans.

    Figure 4: Barclays base case assumptions for the debt sustainability analysis

    2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 Long run

    Real GDP growth 0.70% -2.00% -0.20% 1.00% 1.50% 1.75%

    Inflation 1.37% 1.20% 1.20% 1.75% 1.75% 2.00%

    Nominal GDP growth 2.09% -0.80% 1.00% 2.75% 3.25% 3.75%

    Average interest rate on new debt --- 6.00% 6.00% 6.00% 6.00% 6.00%

    Fiscal cost of bank recapitalization 1.40% 2.35% 2.32% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%

    Other extraordinary fiscal costs 0.00% 4.22% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00%

    Primary fiscal balance -6.10% -3.30% -1.60% -0.15% 1.10% 2.25%

    Note: The 2011 fiscal costs of bank recapitalisation, 1.4% of GDP, are the costs to the government thus far which arealready part of the stock of public debt. Source: Barclays Research.

    Under these assumptions, the Spanish public debt dynamics look precarious in the nearterm, but manageable over the longer term. The bad news is that the projected public debt

    continues to rise until 2015, when it reaches 91.5% of GDP. The very rapid rate of increase

    in the public debt is potentially unnerving, but our estimate of the peak level of

    indebtedness is marginally above the euro area average of 89%. (Of the c.23% of GDP rise

    in debt from the end-2011 level, about 4.7% is due to additional fiscal costs of recapitalising

    the banks, and will not therefore require market financing. The remaining c.18% would

    need to be financed by the market.) The good news is that a 2.25% of GDP primary surplus,

    well within the historical experience of many countries around the world, is sufficient to

    turn around the adverse debt dynamics, and secure a continued decline in the public debt

    burden, under our assumptions about long-run interest rates and growth. 3 Under the other

    assumptions of our base case, the public debt is projected to decline about 7.5 percentage

    points in the decade after the 2015 peak, which strikes us as a rate of improvement thatwould, if it materialised, justify substantially lower anxiety about the public credit than now

    exists, even though the level of debt would be higher.

    Our base case incorporates a fiscal cost of bank recapitalisation equal to about EUR65bn, or

    c.6% of GDP, of which roughly 1.4% of GDP was already recorded in 2011. However, there is

    substantial uncertainty around this estimate, and we have therefore stress-tested our

    projections for an additional EUR57bn (about 5.4% of GDP) in costs. As Figure 3 (above)

    illustrates, the debt dynamics remain manageable in this risk case. The public debt is projected

    to peak at 97.6% of GDP in 2015, compared with 91.5% in the base case, and it declines more

    slowly thereafter. But in this case too, the projected rate of decline is pronounced enough to

    alleviate anxieties about the sustainability of the Spanish public debt.

    Public debt dynamics are resilient to severe, but temporary adverse shocks

    The long-run resilience to higher costs of bank recapitalisation illustrates a more general

    point, which is that the Spanish debt dynamics are robust to a number of large, temporary

    shocks, as long as these do not upset the longer-term assumptions of the analysis. For

    example, in Figure 5 we illustrate the results under two severe, temporary shocks. The first

    3 Spains average primary balance 1998 -2008 was +2.1% of GDP. This includes the 2003-2008 credit boom, duringwhich it was arguably easier to maintain a healthy fiscal position. However, the primary budget surplus averaged2.15% during the pre-boom period 1998-2003, suggesting that a primary surplus of this magnitude should beattainable during more normal economic and financial conditions.

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    6/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 6

    scenario is a much deeper recession, in which growth is lower than the base case by 3% in

    2012 and 2% in 2013, with a cyclical rebound that is 3% higher in 2014 and 2% higher in

    2015.4 The debt peaks at a higher level, but after the cyclical event plays out, the evolution

    of the public debt remains stable.

    Figure 5: Debt dynamics are also manageable under severe, but temporary adverse

    shocks (Public debt, % of GDP)

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    110%

    2000 2003 2006 2009 2012 2015 2018 2021 2024 2027 2030

    Base case Deeper recession Slow fiscal adj

    Source: Barclays Research

    In the final risk case, we assess the impact of a substantially slower pace of fiscal

    adjustment, with primary fiscal balances of -4.5% in 2012 (vs -3.3% in the base case), -

    3.0% in 2013 (vs -1.6%), -1.5% in 2014 (vs -0.15%), and 0.0% in 2015 (vs 1.5%). Here, too,

    the debt rises to a higher level and declines more slowly than in the base case, but the

    dynamics are stable, which implies that the government is solvent in this risk case as well.

    It is important to acknowledge that this analysis is not a general equilibrium one, and does

    not incorporate all potential feedbacks. For example, a slower pace of fiscal adjustment mightlead to a temporarily stronger economy than in the base case, which could partially offset the

    adverse impact on the public debt dynamics. In a less benign example, an economic downturn

    of the magnitude that we used to illustrate the fiscal sensitivity to economic activity could

    trigger societal dynamics that upset political support for the gradual fiscal consolidation that is

    embedded in our projections. The risk cases are intended to provide us with some quantitative

    insight into the sensitivity of our base case to disappointing developments on a number of

    different levels. But they all embed the assumption that a long-run fiscal consolidation will

    continue to be supported by society, and for some risk cases this assumption may reasonably

    be questioned. We explore this issue in some more detail below; for now, we emphasise the

    point that, assuming the long-run scenario remains intact, and although public debt will rise

    sharply in the next couple of years, the Spanish debt dynamics look reasonably robust to

    temporary or cyclical developments, even ones that are large by comparison with what weconsider to be plausible downside risks.

    There is less budgetary room for manoeuvre in the long run

    The same is not quite true for the assumptions about the long run. One way to see this is to

    note that in our base case, the public debt peaks at just over 90% of GDP. Given our

    assumption about the steady-state interest rate and rate of economic growth, to stabilise

    4 In this scenario, we adjust the primary budget surplus downward by 0.5% of GDP for every percentage point shortfall inGDP. This adjustment in the budget balance has more impact on the debt dynamics than the GDP shortfall itself.

    Assuming the long-run scenario

    remains intact, the Spanish debtdynamics look reasonably robust

    to temporary or cyclical

    developments

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    7/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 7

    the debt at this level would require a primary budget surplus of 2% of GDP. 5 Our

    assumption that the primary budget achieves 2.25% of GDP is therefore more than

    adequate to stabilise the debt ratio (as we see in the eventual downward drift in Figures 1

    and 3), but there is not a lot of room for policy slippage (no more than 25bp, to be precise,

    probably more precise than one should be in a long-run analysis of this sort). Nor is there

    much room for disappointment in the long-run rate of growth or interest rate, unless there

    is an offsetting fiscal effort.

    Now, there is a sense in which this hair-trigger property of the model exaggerates the actual

    risks surrounding the long run. If a society can generate 2.25% of GDP, 2.50% should not be

    ruled out. Moreover, a 6% interest rate (4% after adjustment for inflation and roughly 320bp

    higher than future German yields implied by forward curves) looks like a very conservative

    assumption about an economy where the public debt is on a gradual but pronounced

    downward trend. If other elements of the base case were unchanged but we assumed a risk

    premium similar to the 135bp that France is now paying, debt would decline very rapidly.

    There is room for good news, as well as bad, and we would not want to leave the impression

    that the long-run financial outlook is balanced on a mathematical razor blade.

    That said, the analysis does highlight an inescapable imperative to secure a long-term

    adjustment in the primary fiscal balance from last years 6.1% of GDP deficit to a surplus of

    something on the order of 2.25% of GDP, and to do it in a way that is sustainable for a long

    period of time. It also suggests that there is some theoretical room for delay relative to our

    base case, but the room is not unlimited.

    Is the fiscal consolidation feasible?

    How dismal is the fiscal arithmetic?

    Some investors believe, and elements of the commentariat have lately been arguing, that

    fiscal adjustment is all but impossible when an economy is as weak as Spains, even if the

    political commitment to adjust is in place. The idea is that fiscal adjustment weakens the

    economy (through familiar Keynesian channels), and the weakened economy underminesfiscal performance so dramatically that austerity is largely, if not totally, self-defeating.

    To investigate this idea further, let us denote by m the Keynesian multiplier. That is, a

    contractionary fiscal shock of one percent of GDP is assumed to reduce GDP by m

    percent. Let us denote by t the impact of a change in GDP on the budget balance; that is, if

    GDP declines by one percent while tax rates, unemployment compensation programs, and

    other elements of the budget structure are left unchanged, the budget deficit would worsen

    by t percent of GDP. With this notation, we can compute the magnitude of the fiscal

    measures required to reduce the budget deficit by one percent of GDP, which is:

    1/(1-m*t).

    Suppose you believe that Keynesian effects of fiscal policy are very powerful: for example, thatthe multiplier m is 1.5. (These are not our estimates, but arbitrary ones designed to illustrate

    the fiscal pessimists point of view.) In a highly-taxed society like much of Europe, the marginal

    impact of a change in national income on the budget is likely to be high; let us use 0.6 as a

    high, but not ludicrously high estimate of the sensitivity. Under these assumptions, to achieve

    1 percent of GDP improvement in the fiscal balance would require 10 percentage points of

    5 The debt-stabilizing primary budget balance is [d*(r-g)/(1+g)], where r is the nominal rate of interest, g is thenominal growth rate, and d is the ratio of debt to GDP.

    Some have argued that

    austerity is largely, if not totally,

    self-defeating

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    8/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 8

    fiscal adjustment! A full 90% of the fiscal effort would be undone by the adverse impact of the

    fiscal measures on the economy and, therefore, the budget.6

    Applied to the Spanish context, this nave calculation predicts that the 8 percent of GDP

    swing required in the Spanish budget balance would demand fiscal measures equivalent to

    80% of GDP! This is, of course, absurd, and results from inappropriately applying the model

    to policy changes that are so large that it cannot reasonably be used.

    While we do not agree with the fiscal pessimists that fiscal consolidation is next to

    impossible, we agree with the general principle that consolidation is likely to be costly in

    terms of economic activity in the short run, and that the economic repercussions aggravate

    the process of fiscal adjustment. This provides a clear justification for gradualism in the

    adjustment path; we doubt that any responsible person would advocate that the 8 percent

    of GDP fiscal adjustment that Spain faces should (or could) be undertaken in a single year.

    Moreover, the path of fiscal consolidation that we project for Spain, which we have argued

    is consistent with fiscal solvency over the medium term, is nonetheless less ambitious than

    the governments. This may be partly because our estimates of the fiscal spending

    multipliers and tax elasticity are higher than that the government is implicitly using. We

    also think it will become clear to the government and to the EC that such a front-loadedfiscal consolidation is unnecessary (and not feasible in our view). In particular, the

    government Stability and Growth Pact approved on 27 April proposes a reduction in the

    primary budget deficit of 3.9pp of GDP in 2012 and an additional 2.4pp of GDP next year, to

    bring the primary balance to 0.2% of GDP surplus in 2013. We are instead projecting a

    primary deficit of 1.6% of GDP in 2013. We emphasize that under our scenario the

    government remains solvent, with a trajectory for the public debt that is rather similar to the

    one envisioned in the UK governments fiscal consolidation. We advise investors to focus on

    the medium-term outlook, and to resist becoming overly fixated on deviations between the

    governments plan and outcomes over a few short years.

    For Spain, we think it is reasonable to assume that m is in the vicinity of 0.67 and t around

    0.5, which means that a 1% fiscal consolidation only produces an effective deficit reductionof 0.7%.8 Using the government target, to achieve 3.8pp of GDP consolidation in 2012 it

    should be on the back of fiscal measures worth about 5.4% of GDP. Our more conservative

    estimate of a likely 2.8pp of GDP consolidation in 2012 is based on adjustment measures

    worth about EUR41bn (about 3.8% of GDP).9

    6 If m*t is greater than one, the number 1/(1-m*t) could be negative. This describes a world in which a KeynesianLaffer curve exists, such that an increase in public spending would create such a powerful effect on demand andeconomic activity, that it would be (more than) self-financing. We dont share the view that we live in such a world,even during a period of weak demand and low economic activity.7 There is a body of opinion which holds that the fiscal multiplier in countries like Spain must be high, because thefiscal contraction cannot be offset with a decline in the interest rate (which is determined by the ECB, in Frankfurt). Wethink this is an inappropriate conclusion for Spain, where country risk has become an important determinant of assetprices and overall financial conditions. To the extent that a fiscal consolidation reduces the riskiness of Spanish assets,it can secure a strong improvement in financial conditions, offsetting the direct effects of the fiscal contraction on

    demand and economic activity. Some analysts think this can result (and in some historical examples, has resulted) inan expansionary fiscal consolidation. We would not, however, go so far in Spain under present conditions. Spainsstatus as a small, open economy also tends to generate a smaller multiplier than might be seen in a larger, moreclosed economy.8 At least in the short run. Most Keynesian models have the property that demand shocks from fiscal and monetarypolicy have only temporary effects on economic activity. In the long run (of some unspecified duration), throughvarious adjustments of wages and prices, economies heal and the policy multiplier becomes zero.9 In addition, the sizeable difference between the more aggressive government adjustment path an ours is mainlythreefold: first, the government is probably using multipliers (ie m and t) of smaller size than ours, we think becausethe government is considering that a large share of the expenditure cuts can be applied to activities (such as transfers)with low a low fiscal multiplier. Second, the government is including in the fiscal consolidation path, measures for 2013-15for which we do not have details yet; we are simply assuming a more conservative path than the governments. Third, weare also assuming slightly less fiscal adjustment in 2012 than the government, in particular we are excluding the EUR2.5bnexpected revenues from a tax amnesty, which may or may not yield such revenues.

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    9/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 9

    Is there political support for fiscal adjustment?

    Since Spain joined the EMU in 1999 and until 2004, under the conservative Partido Popular (PP),

    public expenditure (ex interest) remained constant as a share of GDP at 36%. Since 2004, when

    the Socialist government took office, public expenditure increased every year to peak at 44% of

    GDP in 2009. The trend reversed in May 2010 as the Socialist government stopped its counter-

    cyclical and expansionary fiscal policies and began implementing cuts to the public sector wage

    bill and pensions. Public expenditure dropped to 41% of GDP by end 2011.

    Against this background, the conservative PP won a land-slide victory and took office in

    December 2011, gaining a comfortable majority in parliament. PPs campaign was centred

    on fiscal consolidation, structural reforms and the clean-up of the banking sector. PPs clear

    victory was probably as much a result of support for the conservative-party policies (ie,

    fiscal consolidation and structural reforms) as a vote of disenchantment against the

    Socialist party, 23% unemployment, and the ongoing economic crisis. The latter seem to be

    a relevant factor in the outcome of the elections as evidenced in recent polls published by

    Spanish local media, which show a drop in PPs support following the labour market reform

    and the announcement of the 2012 fiscal budget.

    The PP has clearly signalled that it intends to take a more hawkish fiscal consolidationstrategy with a view to reverting public expenditure to about 35% of GDP by 2015, a level

    similar to 1999-2003. We think that the ability (or otherwise) of the conservative

    government to effectively control the expenditures of the regions will largely determine the

    success of the fiscal strategy, as the increase in regional expenditures have been the main

    factor driving the increase in public expenditure in recent years. Achieving a fiscal swing of

    approximately 8pp of GDP over a five-year period (our estimate) will require a less generous

    and more efficient welfare state, including sizeable cuts to social expenditures, health and

    education, which are responsibilities of the regions (health and education represent about

    80% of the total expenditure of the regions).

    It is not clear whether the political support for the new government will remain in place to

    carry out its fiscal consolidation plans, structural reforms and complete the clean-up of thebanking system. First, the Spanish society may not accept a less generous welfare state,

    especially in a context of rising unemployment. Second, the complex politics of fiscal

    devolution to the regions are likely to make a possible fiscal intervention of a large region

    not viable (more on this below). Third, politics have also played an important role in the

    clean-up process involving the savings bank sector. Savings banks had very close ties to the

    regions and as a result, some of the savings bank mergers were politically driven rather than

    based on pure economic and financial reasons. And political ties to the former savings

    banks remain and those may delay the clean-up process (although one can also argue that

    as problem banks are addressed and the boards are removed, those ties may eventually

    disappear).

    Can the central government effectively control the regions?

    The short answer is in theory, yes; in practice, it will not be a trivial task. The central

    government is backed by a brand new constitutional debt-break and a new organic law that

    sets expenditure-ceiling rules for all the sub-central government levels, and allows the

    central government, if needed, to potentially intervene a region and take away fiscal

    responsibilities. Also the new draft law of good governance proposes that any local

    authority that fails to comply with the fiscal consolidation targets (ie, that fails to comply

    with the new constitutional amendment or the new organic law above mentioned) can be

    dismissed and be banned from running for public office for a period of up to 10 years.

    It is not clear whether the

    political support for the newgovernment will remain in place

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    10/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 10

    In practice, however, these brand new mechanisms of fiscal control have not yet been put

    to the test. We think that politically it would be very costly for the central government to

    revert the process of fiscal devolution by taking responsibilities away from any region, even

    if temporarily.

    On the revenue side, the central government controls a large share of the regional taxes.

    Specifically, the central government controls the tax rates of the personal and corporateincome tax (PIT and CIT), as well as the VAT. The fiscal revenues from these taxes are

    shared between the central government and the regions (50% each). Hence, any decision

    by the central government to increase the PIT, CIT and VAT rates has a direct impact on the

    fiscal revenue of the regions. In the approved 2012 budget and in the new 2012-15 SGP, the

    government has approved (or proposed) changes to the corporate and personal income tax

    regime as well as an increase to indirect taxes, including a hike to the VAT rate in 2013 (the

    standard VAT rate is currently 18%, which is 3pp below the standard rate of Italy and 5pp

    below Ireland, Portugal and Greece).

    Bond buyers, banks, and the BOP Will Spain require help?

    For a country in Spains financial position, a policy framework that promises long-term

    sustainability is necessary, but may not be sufficient to avoid a crisis. The problem is familiar

    to those who have watched sovereign crises unfold in the past. There is at least a small risk

    that even a coherent program will unravel, because of unfavourable external conditions, a

    domestic political shock, or for some other reason. But in sovereign credit events, recovery

    rates are typically low, in substantial part because much of the debt owed by the sovereign is

    senior and not subject to restructuring, which means that credit risk is concentrated on those

    market participants who do not enjoy the senior status of the IMF, the ECB, or (in a different

    way) the domestic banking system. This means that even a relatively small probability of

    default can justify a high market risk premium, which can intensify doubts about the

    sustainability of the public debt, if the sovereign is (or, as in Spain, will soon enough be) highly

    indebted. But once market participants start to worry that debt service may ultimately be

    unsustainable, the small perceived probability of default is likely to be ratcheted higher, whichcan set in motion a downward spiral of confidence and debt prices that may result in full loss

    of access to debt markets, and that can be very difficult to break without some form of

    external assistance. (See Can Italy save itself?, 7 November 2011)

    In the final months of 2011, it seemed as though negative market dynamics like this

    threatened to envelop Italy, and with somewhat less intensity, Spain. In the end, the ECBs

    3y LTRO operations enabled Spanish and Italian banks to act as bond buyers of last resort

    for their respective sovereigns, allowing them both to finance their governments and

    providing an exit option for the international bondholders who have been reducing their

    exposure.10 It has not been lost on investors that the fate of the Spanish banking system has

    thereby become even more dependent upon the sovereign credit.

    Banks and bondholders

    It is not inevitable that foreign investors will continue to reduce their exposure to Spain at an

    economically disruptive rate. But it is a nontrivial risk. The question therefore arises whether,

    in the risk case of an extended international buyers strike, the Spanish banking system

    could continue to play the supportive role that it (along with the ECBs Securities Market

    Program) has played in the past few quarters. One aspect of this question is whether this

    10 Very importantly, the LTRO operations also reassured markets that banks would be able to fund themselves in theevent that rollover of amortizing bank debt was not complete. This may have been the most important element of theLTRO, but in this section we are focused on the public finances.

    There is at least a small risk that

    even a coherent program will

    unravel, because of unfavourable

    external conditions or a

    domestic political shock

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1763950https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1763950
  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    11/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 11

    would leave banks with an exposure to the sovereign that is unreasonable or

    unmanageable. This is not necessarily the most important consideration facing

    policymakers, but it is interesting and important to consider how the Spanish banking

    systems balance sheet could be altered in a risk case in which local banks are forced to

    compensate for an extended international buyers strike.

    In Figure 6, we illustrate the impact on the banking systems exposure to government in asevere, but not unthinkable, scenario, which incorporates the following elements:

    Domestic banks finance 80% of the general governments net issuance in 2012 and2013 (with other local institutions assumed to finance the remaining 20%).

    Domestic banks have already accommodated a massive reduction in foreign investorsexposure to the Spanish government, totalling an estimated EUR30bn in the four

    months of 2012 alone (an annualized rate of EUR 90 bn/year). Going forward, we

    assume in our stress test that banks absorb foreign selling amounting to EUR50bn per

    year. (For our purposes, it does not matter whether the foreign selling reflects failure to

    roll existing exposures or secondary-market selling.) To put this in perspective, we

    estimate that foreign (ex-ECB) ownership of central government debt securities had

    fallen to EUR141bn in March 2012 (see Spain: Banks still buying, foreigners still selling

    (but less), 30 April, 2012). Our projection implies another EUR83bn of cumulative selling

    by the end of 2013, reducing foreign exposure to a mere EUR56bn. This seems

    implausibly severe, but thats the point of a stress test.

    Finally, we estimate that the government will need to provide fiscal support to thebanking system in the amount of EUR50bn in the next two years. In the following

    calculations, we assume that this support takes the form of government bonds that are

    held by those banks that end up needing the fiscal support.

    Figure 6: Stress testing for an international bond buyers strike

    Dec-09 Dec-10 Dec-11 Feb-12 Dec-12 Dec-13

    Bank exposure to general government as % of:

    GDP 21% 22% 26% 30% 39% 49%

    Public debt 38% 37% 38% 43% 48% 55%

    Bank capital and reserves 79% 83% 76% 85% 105% 136%

    Bank assets 7% 7% 8% 9% 12% 16%

    Source: Haver Analytics, Barclays Research

    In this scenario, Spanish bank exposure to the general government would rise from roughly

    30% of GDP in February 2012 (the last month for which we have data) to 39% at the end of

    2012 and 49% at the end of 2013. By 2013, bank exposure would amount to 55% of the

    general governments debt.

    It would also amount to 136% of the banking systems capital and reserves (assuming that

    the systems capital remains close to the present level). This is dramatically higher than in

    the very recent past; in December 2011 this ratio was only 76%. But as Figure 7 illustrates,

    while it may not seem desirable, theres nothing historically unprecedented about this level

    of exposure. And, for what its worth, the equivalent ratio for US banks is roughly 124%, and

    in Germany it is 141%. It is certainly true that in this scenario the banks would be broken by

    a sovereign credit event. Thats also true in Spain today, and we suspect its true in the vast

    majority of the worlds economies.

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1816302https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1816302https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1816302https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1816302
  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    12/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 12

    In this scenario, it seems to us that the financial shoe doesnt pinch because it leads to an

    unreasonable or unmanageable exposure to the public sector; it pinches because the banks

    would almost certainly have difficulties financing the required increase in exposure. As Figure

    8 illustrates, bank exposure to the Spanish private sector has been declining since 2008, as

    households and firms unwind the preceding credit boom. This private deleveraging creates

    some room on bank balance sheets for additional bank financing of the government, but it has

    been proceeding at the rate of roughly EUR60bn during the past year, only about half the sizeof the fiscal support required of the banks in our (admittedly somewhat extreme) stress test.

    The problems would of course be compounded if banks have a hard time rolling over their

    outstanding liabilities in international capital markets, or faced large deposit outflows. In short,

    unless banks are provided with the liabilities that they need to increase their exposure to the

    government, private borrowers would be forced into an even more rapid (and economically

    destabilizing) deleveraging than they have been experiencing.

    Under alternative monetary arrangements, Spains central bank could act as lender of last

    resort for the banking system and provide the required financing itself. (It could even lend to

    the government more directly, unless constrained by law.) But that is ruled out under the

    existing framework, because the Spanish central bank cannot expand the supply of euros to

    finance either governments or banks. Moreover, even if Spain had its own currency, thecentral banks capacity to ease the financial stress would be limited by the fact that the run is

    external. The genius of the ECBs LTRO operations was that they provided not only liquidity for

    banks, but also the euros that Spain needed to plug a hole in the balance of payments.

    Bondholders and the balance of payments

    This brings us to Spains external finances which will, in our view, be the lynchpin of the

    financial crisis in the months (and, quite likely, years) to come. The 2003-2008 credit and

    investment boom was associated with a very large increase in the current account deficit,

    which peaked at well over 10% of GDP. As the boom has been unwound, the current

    account deficit has shrunk. (We expect it to shrink further, to about 0.9% of GDP in 2012,

    and to reach a small surplus in 2013.) But the deficit has not yet disappeared, and until it

    does it will require external finance.

    Figure 7: Spanish banks finance of government Back to thefuture?

    Figure 8: Spanish banks exposure to the nonfinancial privatesector has been falling since 2008 (EUR bn)

    0%

    50%

    100%

    150%

    200%

    250%

    300%

    1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

    Bank exposure to gen'l government (% of capita l and

    reserves)

    500

    750

    1,000

    1,250

    1,500

    1,750

    2,000

    2000 2003 2006 2009 2012

    Credit system exposure to private sector

    Source: Haver Analytics Source: Haver Analytics

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    13/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 13

    The problem today is not that the current account deficit is excessive. We view the current

    account adjustment to economically sustainable levels as essentially complete, with further

    reductions that we anticipate bringing it well within the sustainable range. The problem is

    that during the credit boom, Spain accumulated very large liabilities to external creditors of

    many kinds, and as the economic and financial situation has become more precarious,

    these creditors have been trying (with some considerable success recently) to exit the

    country. Figure 10 shows how dramatically external financial flows have collapsed in recentmonths, and how reliant the Spanish balance of payments has become upon financing

    channelled through Banco de Espaa. During the 12 months through February 2012, the

    country experienced EUR125bn of capital outflows (of which roughly EUR 77bn reflected

    foreign selling of central government debt securities). These outflows and the current

    account deficit were financed by inflows channelled through Banco de Espaa.

    If the potential problem were limited to foreign holdings of central government debt, which

    have fallen to only EUR141bn, as we noted above, we might feel some confidence that an

    end to the outflows is in sight. However, the countrys exposure is much larger than that.

    Spains loan, deposit, and portfolio investment liabilities (that is, liabilities that are

    reasonably easy to liquidate) to foreign creditors is an order of magnitude greater than this.

    Figure 9: The current account deficit has fallen, but stillrequires financing

    Figure 10: A sudden stop in capital flows has been offset byfinancing channeled through Banco de Espaa

    -140

    -120

    -100

    -80

    -60

    -40

    -20

    0

    20

    Jan-91 Jan-96 Jan-01 Jan-06 Jan-11

    Current account balance (bn euro)

    -150

    -100

    -50

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    Jan-00 Jan-02 Jan-04 Jan-06 Jan-08 Jan-10 Jan-12

    Banco de Espana ex BdE

    Note: 12-month moving total. Source: Haver Analytics Note: 12-month moving total, billion euros.Source: Haver Analytics, Barclays Research

    Figure 11: Spain has accumulated large liabilities to foreign investors

    Assets Liabilities Net

    International investment position 1,387.7 2,376.8 -989.1

    Direct investment 496.4 480.1 16.3

    Portfolio investment (ex-BdE) 257.5 873.6 -616.0

    Loans, deposits, and other assets 539.3 847.8 -308.4

    Banco de Espaa 94.5 175.4 -81.0

    Source: Haver Analytics

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    14/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 14

    Spain also has considerable foreign assets. But the net international investment position is

    still negative, in an amount equal to more than 90% of the Spanish GDP. And previous

    experience has highlighted the fact that foreign assets are very often not in the hands of the

    domestic borrower that needs to liquidate a foreign liability. When confidence is weak,

    gross liabilities become at least as important as the net position.

    There are no guarantees that the recent flight from Spanish assets will continue. There is in our

    view nothing intrinsically unsustainable about the external position Spain is not the only

    economy with large external liabilities, and the current account adjustment is well underway.

    Indeed, if we define external sustainability as maintaining a constant ratio of net external liabilities

    to GDP, Spain could afford to run a steady-state current account deficit in excess of 3% of GDP.

    The vulnerability arises from the large stock of liabilities, not an unsustainable rate of foreign

    borrowing. Keeping foreign creditors engaged on such a large scale requires confidence,

    and there is a risk that foreign investors confidence in Spain will not soon recover. If it does

    not, the flight from Spanish assets is potentially much larger than the rapidly dwindling

    foreign ownership of government debt.

    What next for Spain?

    Managing the fiscal imbalances and the banking-sector fallout of the ongoing credit cycle does

    not, in our view, require external official support. Neither the IMF, the EU, nor the ECB are likely to

    be able substantially to improve the governments strategy for fiscal consolidation, and they are

    certainly unable to improve the likelihood that political support for the adjustment will be

    sustained in the difficult years to come. Indeed, external conditionality can serve as a lightning

    rod for domestic opposition to painful adjustment measures. Recapitalising the banks may be

    expensive, but in our view the expense will turn out to be very modest by the standards of

    previous financial crises around the world, and in any event the required finance is domestic, not

    international, and it need not even be raised in markets. In our view, these problems are

    manageable by the Spanish authorities if political support for their strategy remains intact. And if

    it does not, it is unclear what external policy bodies can do to remedy the situation.

    What the Spanish authorities cannot manage on their own is sustained, large capitaloutflows of the sort that have recently been experienced in Spain. It is not impossible that

    these will subside. A convincing resolution of uncertainties surrounding the banking sector

    and strategy to secure fiscal sustainability should reduce underlying anxieties and reduce

    capital outflows. But if it does not, external financial support will be necessary to prevent a

    highly disruptive and disinflationary balance of payments crisis.

    In the event that capital outflows continue and external financial support is needed, there

    are two modalities that could, at least conceptually, address the external financing gap. The

    first is support that is channelled through the ECB, through some combination of a

    reactivated Securities Market Program (SMP), and something like the recent LTRO

    operations, which would channel international liquidity to Spain via the banks, who may use

    this to help fill the governments financing gap and cope with any funding gaps of their

    own, without creating an even more destabilizing credit crunch. If outflows are limited in

    size and duration, and the ECB retains political support to act as Spains international lender

    of last resort, this may be sufficient. And given the political and economic complications

    that may be involved in submitting Spain to a full-fledged IMF/EU/ECB program, it seems

    likely that this approach would be the policy response of first resort.

    However, given the magnitude of the external liabilities that could potentially attempt to exit

    Spain, it is easily imaginable that the required financial support could outstrip the

    eurozones willingness to respond through the ECB. In this case, there would be little

    alternative to a full-fledged IMF/EU/ECB program.

    Spains vulnerability arises

    from its large stock of liabilities,

    not an unsustainable rate of

    foreign borrowing

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    15/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 15

    Appendix: Costs of the bank recapitalization

    Our updated expected loss analysis

    Consistent with our base case macroeconomic scenario, we estimate future expected losses

    for the Spanish banking system of EUR198bn (see Figure 14). We expect NPLs to peak at

    around 13% in H2 13 (excluding the effect of write-offs). While losses will increase across

    all portfolios, real estate losses will represent the lions share: by our estimates, economicactivity and housing prices will continue to weaken and this will imply that the NPL ratio for

    construction and developer loans will rise to 35%, from 20% currently. Average housing

    prices could drop by an additional 20-25% for a total peak-to-trough adjustment of 35-

    40%. Consequently, we estimate the average recovery rate in the construction and

    development portfolio to be just 35%, consistent with an average loss severity of 90% on

    land collateral and 55% on non-land.

    Mortgage NPLs will continue to increase, in our view. Unemployment is expected to

    continue rising through mid-2013, peaking at c.26%. We expect 12 month-euribor, the

    base rate for Spanish mortgages, to remain below 2.5% over the next 1.5 years, which will

    partly cushion the impact of the increase in unemployment. Considering these two factors,

    we see the residential mortgage NPL ratio rising to 5.0%, from 2.8% currently. We expect anaverage loss severity on residential mortgages of 20%, based on the following LTV analysis.

    Figure 12 shows the as reported current distribution of non-performing mortgages by LTV

    bucket, which we smooth for analytical purposes. Banks update mortgage LTVs based on

    indexed house prices, which we believe are not fully reflective of the true value of the

    collateral backing delinquent mortgage exposures. For this reason, we make an initial

    adjustment to reported LTVs equivalent to a 10% decline in house prices, which has already

    occurred but is not reflected in reported numbers. To the result, we apply a 25% fall in real

    estate prices, in line with our expectation. The result is an average expected loss on

    delinquent mortgages of 15%. Under this scenario, over half of all non-performing

    mortgages would be in negative equity (Figure 13). We finally add foreclosure costs of 5pp

    to arrive at our 20% expected loss assumption.

    Figure 12: Distribution of non-performing mortgages by LTV

    Figure 13: Portion of mortgage NPLs in negative equity after25% further decline in house prices, after adjustments

    0.000

    0.002

    0.004

    0.006

    0.008

    0.010

    0.012

    0.014

    0.016

    0.018

    0.020

    0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120% 1 40%

    Smoothed Actua l

    0.000

    0.002

    0.004

    0.006

    0.008

    0.010

    0.012

    0.014

    0.016

    0.018

    0.020

    0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% 120% 140%

    Source: Company data, Barclays Research Source: Company data, Barclays Research

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    16/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 16

    We have also estimated bank losses under an alternative stress scenario where we assume

    lower growth in 2012 (-4% real GDP) and 2013 (-2%) and housing prices falling by 35%

    from current levels. In this stress scenario total expected losses would amount to

    EUR266bn.

    Figure 14: Spanish banking system, estimated future expected losses

    Gross balances (EUR bn) Baseline Stress

    Retail mortgages 656 656

    Other retail loans 137 137

    Real Estate Corporate and Construction Loans 397 397

    Real estate assets (acquired) 95 95

    Non-Real Estate Loans 545 545

    Other Loans 45 45

    Total Exposure Relating to Lending Activities 1,880 1,880

    NPL ratio (% of exposures)

    Retail mortgages (2.8% currently) 5.0% 6.5%

    Other retail loans (6.9% currently) 14.0% 18.0%

    Real Estate Corporate and Construction (20.1% currently) 35.0% 40.0%

    Real estate assets (acquired) 100.0% 100.0%

    Non-Real Estate Corporate Loans (4.9% currently) 8.0% 10.0%

    Other Loans (2.7% currently) 5.5% 7.0%

    Loss Severity (% of delinquent balances)

    Retail mortgages 20% 30%

    Other retail loans 85% 100%

    Real Estate Corporate and Construction 65% 75%

    Real estate assets (acquired) 65% 75%

    Non-Real Estate Loans 50% 65%

    Other Loans 60% 80%

    Expected Loss (EUR bn)

    Retail mortgages 7 13

    Other retail loans 16 25

    Real Estate Corporate and Construction 90 119

    Real estate assets (acquired) 62 71

    Non-Real Estate Loans 22 35

    Other Loans 1 3

    Total Expected Loss on Lending Activities 198 266

    Expected Loss (as % of exposures)

    Retail mortgages 1% 2%

    Other retail loans 12% 18%

    Real Estate Corporate and Construction 23% 30%

    Real estate assets (acquired) 65% 75%

    Non-Real Estate Loans 4% 7%

    Other Loans 3% 6%

    Total Expected Loss on Lending Activities 11% 14%

    Buffers

    Stock of provisions 110 110

    Uncovered losses 88 156

    Source: Barclays Research

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    17/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 17

    Against the lifetime expected losses, 198bn in our base case, banks have already set aside

    110bn of provisions, leaving 88bn of uncovered sector losses at the end of 2011. These

    will not be entirely funded by the public sector, though. In addition to bank earnings,

    bondholder involvement can lessen the impact of bank recapitalisations on public finances,

    while other proposals such as the creation of bad banks, can have the potential to mitigate

    the need for public sector support.

    Potential for bondholder involvement

    In light of the potential capital shortfall faced by many banks, we expect the Spanish

    authorities and the banks themselves to continue looking for additional sources of capital.

    One key source is subordinated debt, which banks can buy back at a discount or swap into

    equity. Over recent months, Spanish listed banks have launched several capital

    management transactions, which have allowed them to improve their core capital levels by

    over 12bn in aggregate. Most of these transactions have taken the form of debt-for-equity

    exchanges. Transactions undertaken by non-listed institutions have come in the shape of

    discounted debt buybacks.

    Figure 15: Aggregate capital structure of Spanish banks

    12.2 9.5

    22.73.7

    4.0

    8.1

    10.8

    5.0

    15.9

    10.8

    7.1

    18.3

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    LT2 UT2 T1 Total

    Rest Bankia/BFA

    La Caixa/Caixabank BBVA/SANTAN

    Source: Bloomberg, company data, Barclays Research

    Banks will likely continue using liability management transactions to strengthen their capital

    bases. Although these transactions have been investor-friendly to date, such lenient

    treatment of bondholders may change if sovereign debt pressures persist. In fact, with the

    sector reform approved in February, the government already allowed banks to defer coupon

    payments on tier 1 securities to comply with the new provisioning requirements. Pressed for

    capital, banks could seek to further these measures by deferring hybrid coupons

    indefinitely, launching deeply discounted liability management transactions, or setting up

    bad banks, which allows them to allocate losses to specific sub-sets of liabilities (see

    European Banks: Completing the Spanish banking sector clean-up). As shown in Figure 15

    above, Spanish banks have an aggregate subordinated debt buffer of 65bn. Excluding

    BBVA, Santander and Caixabank, which we view as the most solvent institutions in the

    country, the buffer is 31bn, which we believe could provide an additional capital cushion of

    10bn going forward.

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1776684https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1776684
  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    18/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 18

    Sector-wide bad bank could increase transparency but not reduce fiscalcosts of banking

    In recent weeks, the Spanish government has been toying once again with the idea of

    creating a bad bank to hold the problem assets of the Spanish banking system. Figure 16

    below shows the bad bank structure alluded to in the press. Banks would transfer their

    problem assets to a newly created asset management company (AMC or bad bank). In

    return, the banks would receive equity stakes in these AMCs; this means that banks would

    continue to indirectly own the problem assets. However, problem assets would be

    deconsolidated from the banks balance sheets, as no single bank would own more than

    50% of the AMC.

    Figure 16: Bad bank structure as currently envisaged

    Bad bankequity

    Trouble assets

    Bank A

    Bank B

    Trouble assets

    Bad bankequity

    Bank C

    Troubleassets

    Bad bankequity

    BAD BANK

    Post-transfer losses Post-transfer losses

    Post-transferlosses

    Bad bankequity

    Trouble assets

    Bank A

    Bank B

    Trouble assets

    Bad bankequity

    Bank C

    Troubleassets

    Bad bankequity

    BAD BANK

    Post-transfer losses Post-transfer losses

    Post-transferlosses

    Source: Barclays Research

    A key element in this process would be asset valuation. The Spanish authorities could

    appoint an independent valuation agent, which would value the assets before the transfer. If

    the valuation haircut exceeds the provisions already set aside by the banks, a loss equal to

    the shortfall would be incurred, reducing the banks capital base. Some banks may need to

    be recapitalised as a result.11.In contrast, if the haircuts end up being too lenient, post-

    transfer losses would be born by the bad bank owners, which are the banks themselves.

    Either way, the banks would continue to be liable for losses on problem assets. The Spanish

    authorities could also opt for the creation of a publicly owned bad bank, which would shield

    banks from losses materialising after the assets have been transferred however, losses

    would fall on the public accounts instead. In our view, in the absence of external investors,

    the creation of a sector-wide bad bank will not reduce the fiscal costs of banking sector

    recapitalisations. However, it can still improve investor confidence, if accompanied by a

    credible asset valuation process. This could pave the way for a return of private foreign

    capital into the country. However, the process may reinforce investor concerns if thevaluation process shows large provisioning shortfalls.

    11 A potentially positive element of a programme (EU/IMF) is that the supervisory authorities would very likely beforced (as part of the loan conditionality) to carry out an independent review of the loan portfolio as well as of thelegacy real estate assets to be transferred to the AMCs (possibly similar to Irelands PCAR exercise of March 2011). Inour view, that process is important to credibility and put a ceiling to the estimated losses from the problem real estateexposures

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    19/22

    Barclays | Euro Themes: Spain - Dealing with sudden reversals

    4 May 2012 19

    Bottom line: an additional 50bn of public sector support likely in 2012-13

    Starting from our 88bn of uncovered sector losses, we arrive at an additional cost of

    banking sector recapitalisations of 46bn in our base case, on top of the 16bn of capital

    already provided, taking the total costs of bank recapitalisations to 62bn (Figure 17). Pre-

    provision profits have remained resilient in recent quarters, supported by cheap LTRO

    funding and we estimate that the sector could generate 30-35bn of pre-provision profit a

    year. Of this, however, only a fraction can be offset against sector losses, because excess

    profits in stronger banks cannot be applied to cure losses in weaker institutions. As we

    showed in The new Spanish banking sector reform: Credit, macro, and equity implications,

    the 50bn of additional provisions implied by the governments February banking reform

    can only be reduced by 30bn after two years of earnings. In addition, subordinated

    bondholder involvement can also lower the need for public capital injections, by around

    10bn according to our estimates, while remaining assets within the Deposit Guarantee

    Fund could provide an additional 2.0bn cushion.

    Figure 17: Bad bank structure as currently envisaged (mn)

    Barclays estimate of uncovered lifetime losses 88,000

    loss absorption afforded by 2 years of pre-provision profits -30,000

    potential bondholder involvement -10,000

    assets within the FGD (after capital injection into CAM) -2,000

    Requirement for additional public sector support, not yet deployed 46,000

    Funded public capital injections provided to date 16,000

    Total cost of banking sector recapitalisations 62,000

    Source: Barclays Research

    The table below summarises the public support provided to the Spanish banking sector to

    date. Funded capital injections have totalled 16bn, of which 15.4bn have been provided

    by the FROB and 600mn by the FGD. In addition, the FGD has committed funds of 5.3bn

    to be injected into CAM prior to its acquisition by Sabadell, and it has provided assets

    protection schemes on almost 24bn, as part of the disposal process of nationalisedlenders. Pending sales of Banco de Valencia, CatalunyaCaixa and NovaCaixaGalicia, now

    controlled under FROB control, will likely add to this buffer of contingent liabilities in the

    coming months.

    Figure 18: Summary of public sector support provided to banks to date (mn)

    Pre-FROB intervention of CCM 596

    Initial cost of FROB 1.0 (ex. Banco Base) 9,674

    Total cost of FROB 2.0 (ex. CAM) 4,751

    Capital injection into Banco de Valencia 1,000

    Funded public capital injections provided to date 16,021Capital injections committed to date (not yet funded) 5,250

    Potential losses on asset protections schemes granted to date 23,907

    of which CCM 2,475

    of which CajaSur 392

    of which CAM 16,640

    of which Unnim 4,400

    Gross loss exposure of Spanish public sector, to date 45,178

    Source: Barclays Research

    https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1789789https://live.barcap.com/go/publications/content?contentPubID=FC1789789
  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    20/22

    Analyst Certification(s)We, Antonio Garcia Pascual, Michael Gavin, Piero Ghezzi and Jonathan Glionna, hereby certify (1) that the views expressed in this research report accuratelyreflect our personal views about any or all of the subject securities or issuers referred to in this research report and (2) no part of our compensation was, is orwill be directly or indirectly related to the specific recommendations or views expressed in this research report.

    Important DisclosuresBarclays Research is a part of the Corporate and Investment Banking division of Barclays Bank PLC and its affiliates (collectively and each individually,"Barclays"). For current important disclosures regarding companies that are the subject of this research report, please send a written request to: BarclaysResearch Compliance, 745 Seventh Avenue, 17th Floor, New York, NY 10019 or refer to http://publicresearch.barcap.com or call 212-526-1072.

    Barclays Capital Inc. and/or one of its affiliates does and seeks to do business with companies covered in its research reports. As a result, investors should beaware that Barclays may have a conflict of interest that could affect the objectivity of this report. Barclays Capital Inc. and/or one of its affiliates regularlytrades, generally deals as principal and generally provides liquidity (as market maker or otherwise) in the debt securities that are the subject of this researchreport (and related derivatives thereof). Barclays trading desks may have either a long and / or short position in such securities and / or derivativeinstruments, which may pose a conflict with the interests of investing customers. Where permitted and subject to appropriate information barrier restrictions,Barclays fixed income research analyst(s) regularly interact with its trading desk personnel to determine current prices of fixed income securities. Barclaysfixed income research analyst(s) receive compensation based on various factors including, but not limited to, the quality of their work, the overallperformance of the firm (including the profitability of the investment banking department), the profitability and revenues of the Fixed Income, Currencies &Commodities Division ("FICC") and the outstanding principal amount and trading value of, the profitability of, and the potential interest of the firms investingclients in research with respect to, the asset class covered by the analyst. To the extent that any historical pricing information was obtained from Barclaystrading desks, the firm makes no representation that it is accurate or complete. All levels, prices and spreads are historical and do not represent currentmarket levels, prices or spreads, some or all of which may have changed since the publication of this document. The Corporate and Investment Bankingdivision of Barclays produces a variety of research products including, but not limited to, fundamental analysis, equity-linked analysis, quantitative analysis,and trade ideas. Recommendations contained in one type of research product may differ from recommendations contained in other types of researchproducts, whether as a result of differing time horizons, methodologies, or otherwise. In order to access Barclays Statement regarding ResearchDissemination Policies and Procedures, please refer to https://live.barcap.com/publiccp/RSR/nyfipubs/disclaimer/disclaimer-research-dissemination.html.

    DisclaimerThis publication has been prepared by the Corporate and Investment Banking division of Barclays Bank PLC and/or one or more of its affiliates (collectivelyand each individually, "Barclays"). It has been issued by one or more Barclays legal entities within its Corporate and Investment Banking division as providedbelow. It is provided to our clients for information purposes only, and Barclays makes no express or implied warranties, and expressly disclaims all warrantiesof merchantability or fitness for a particular purpose or use with respect to any data included in this publication. Barclays will not treat unauthorized recipientsof this report as its clients. Prices shown are indicative and Barclays is not offering to buy or sell or soliciting offers to buy or sell any financial instrument.Without limiting any of the foregoing and to the extent permitted by law, in no event shall Barclays, nor any affiliate, nor any of their respective officers,directors, partners, or employees have any liability for (a) any special, punitive, indirect, or consequential damages; or (b) any lost profits, lost revenue, loss ofanticipated savings or loss of opportunity or other financial loss, even if notified of the possibility of such damages, arising from any use of this publication orits contents.Other than disclosures relating to Barclays, the information contained in this publication has been obtained from sources that Barclays Research believes tobe reliable, but Barclays does not represent or warrant that it is accurate or complete. Barclays is not responsible for, and makes no warranties whatsoever asto, the content of any third-party web site accessed via a hyperlink in this publication and such information is not incorporated by reference.The views in this publication are those of the author(s) and are subject to change, and Barclays has no obligation to update its opinions or the information inthis publication. The analyst recommendations in this publication reflect solely and exclusively those of the author(s), and such opinions were preparedindependently of any other interests, including those of Barclays and/or its affiliates. This publication does not constitute personal investment advice or tak einto account the individual financial circumstances or objectives of the clients who receive it. The securities discussed herein may not be suitable for allinvestors. Barclays recommends that investors independently evaluate each issuer, security or instrument discussed herein and consult any independentadvisors they believe necessary. The value of and income from any investment may fluctuate from day to day as a result of changes in relevant economicmarkets (including changes in market liquidity). The information herein is not intended to predict actual results, which may differ substantially from thosereflected. Past performance is not necessarily indicative of future results.This communication is being made available in the UK and Europe primarily to persons who are investment professionals as that term is defined in Article 19of the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (Financial Promotion Order) 2005. It is directed at, and therefore should only be relied upon by, persons whohave professional experience in matters relating to investments. The investments to which it relates are available only to such persons and will be entered intoonly with such persons. Barclays Bank PLC is authorised and regulated by the Financial Services Authority ("FSA") and a member of the London StockExchange.The Corporate and Investment Banking division of Barclays undertakes U.S. securities business in the name of its wholly owned subsidiary Barclays Capital

    Inc., a FINRA and SIPC member. Barclays Capital Inc., a U.S. registered broker/dealer, is distributing this material in the United States and, in connectiontherewith accepts responsibility for its contents. Any U.S. person wishing to effect a transaction in any security discussed herein should do so only bycontacting a representative of Barclays Capital Inc. in the U.S. at 745 Seventh Avenue, New York, New York 10019.Non-U.S. persons should contact and execute transactions through a Barclays Bank PLC branch or affiliate in their home jurisdiction unless local regulationspermit otherwise.Barclays Bank PLC, Paris Branch (registered in France under Paris RCS number 381 066 281) is regulated by the Autorit des marchs financiers and theAutorit de contrle prudentiel. Registered office 34/36 Avenue de Friedland 75008 Paris.This material is distributed in Canada by Barclays Capital Canada Inc., a registered investment dealer and member of IIROC (www.iiroc.ca).Subject to the conditions of this publication as set out above, Absa Capital, the Investment Banking Division of Absa Bank Limited, an authorised financialservices provider (Registration No.: 1986/004794/06), is distributing this material in South Africa. Absa Bank Limited is regulated by the South AfricanReserve Bank. This publication is not, nor is it intended to be, advice as defined and/or contemplated in the (South African) Financial Advisory andIntermediary Services Act, 37 of 2002, or any other financial, investment, trading, tax, legal, accounting, retirement, actuarial or other professional advice o rservice whatsoever. Any South African person or entity wishing to effect a transaction in any security discussed herein should do so only by contacting a

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    21/22

    representative of Absa Capital in South Africa, 15 Alice Lane, Sandton, Johannesburg, Gauteng 2196. Absa Capital is an affiliate of Barclays.In Japan, foreign exchange research reports are prepared and distributed by Barclays Bank PLC Tokyo Branch. Other research reports are distributed toinstitutional investors in Japan by Barclays Capital Japan Limited. Barclays Capital Japan Limited is a joint-stock company incorporated in Japan with registeredoffice of 6-10-1 Roppongi, Minato-ku, Tokyo 106-6131, Japan. It is a subsidiary of Barclays Bank PLC and a registered financial instruments firm regulated bythe Financial Services Agency of Japan. Registered Number: Kanto Zaimukyokucho (kinsho) No. 143.Barclays Bank PLC, Hong Kong Branch is distributing this material in Hong Kong as an authorised institution regulated by the Hong Kong Monetary Authority.Registered Office: 41/F, Cheung Kong Center, 2 Queen's Road Central, Hong Kong.This material is issued in Taiwan by Barclays Capital Securities Taiwan Limited. This material on securities not traded in Taiwan is not to be construed as'recommendation' in Taiwan. Barclays Capital Securities Taiwan Limited does not accept orders from clients to trade in such securities. This material may not

    be distributed to the public media or used by the public media without prior written consent of Barclays.This material is distributed in South Korea by Barclays Capital Securities Limited, Seoul Branch.All equity research material is distributed in India by Barclays Securities (India) Private Limited (SEBI Registration No: INB/INF 231292732 (NSE), INB/INF011292738 (BSE), Registered Office: 208 | Ceejay House | Dr. Annie Besant Road | Shivsagar Estate | Worli | Mumbai - 400 018 | India, Phone: + 91 2267196363). Other research reports are distributed in India by Barclays Bank PLC, India Branch.Barclays Bank PLC Frankfurt Branch distributes this material in Germany under the supervision of Bundesanstalt fr Finanzdienstleistungsaufsicht (BaFin).This material is distributed in Malaysia by Barclays Capital Markets Malaysia Sdn Bhd.This material is distributed in Brazil by Banco Barclays S.A.This material is distributed in Mexico by Barclays Bank Mexico, S.A.Barclays Bank PLC in the Dubai International Financial Centre (Registered No. 0060) is regulated by the Dubai Financial Services Authority (DFSA). Principalplace of business in the Dubai International Financial Centre: The Gate Village, Building 4, Level 4, PO Box 506504, Dubai, United Arab Emirates. Barclays BankPLC-DIFC Branch, may only undertake the financial services activities that fall within the scope of its existing DFSA licence. Related financial products orservices are only available to Professional Clients, as defined by the Dubai Financial Services Authority.Barclays Bank PLC in the UAE is regulated by the Central Bank of the UAE and is licensed to conduct business activities as a branch of a commercial bankincorporated outside the UAE in Dubai (Licence No.: 13/1844/2008, Registered Office: Building No. 6, Burj Dubai Business Hub, Sheikh Zayed Road, DubaiCity) and Abu Dhabi (Licence No.: 13/952/2008, Registered Office: Al Jazira Towers, Hamdan Street, PO Box 2734, Abu Dhabi).

    Barclays Bank PLC in the Qatar Financial Centre (Registered No. 00018) is authorised by the Qatar Financial Centre Regulatory Authority (QFCRA). BarclaysBank PLC-QFC Branch may only undertake the regulated activities that fall within the scope of its existing QFCRA licence. Principal place of business in Qatar:Qatar Financial Centre, Office 1002, 10th Floor, QFC Tower, Diplomatic Area, West Bay, PO Box 15891, Doha, Qatar. Related financial products or services areonly available to Business Customers as defined by the Qatar Financial Centre Regulatory Authority.This material is distributed in the UAE (including the Dubai International Financial Centre) and Qatar by Barclays Bank PLC.This material is distributed in Saudi Arabia by Barclays Saudi Arabia ('BSA'). It is not the intention of the publication to be used or deemed asrecommendation, option or advice for any action (s) that may take place in future. Barclays Saudi Arabia is a Closed Joint Stock Company, (CMA License No.09141-37). Registered office Al Faisaliah Tower, Level 18, Riyadh 11311, Kingdom of Saudi Arabia. Authorised and regulated by the Capital Market Authority,Commercial Registration Number: 1010283024.This material is distributed in Russia by OOO Barclays Capital, affiliated company of Barclays Bank PLC, registered and regulated in Russia by the FSFM. Broke rLicense #177-11850-100000; Dealer License #177-11855-010000. Registered address in Russia: 125047 Moscow, 1st Tverskaya-Yamskaya str. 21.This material is distributed in Singapore by the Singapore branch of Barclays Bank PLC, a bank licensed in Singapore by the Monetary Authority of Singapore.For matters in connection with this report, recipients in Singapore may contact the Singapore branch of Barclays Bank PLC, whose registered address is OneRaffles Quay Level 28, South Tower, Singapore 048583.Barclays Bank PLC, Australia Branch (ARBN 062 449 585, AFSL 246617) is distributing this material in Australia. It is directed at 'wholesale clients' as defined

    by Australian Corporations Act 2001.IRS Circular 230 Prepared Materials Disclaimer: Barclays does not provide tax advice and nothing contained herein should be construed to be tax advice.Please be advised that any discussion of U.S. tax matters contained herein (including any attachments) (i) is not intended or written to be used, and cannotbe used, by you for the purpose of avoiding U.S. tax-related penalties; and (ii) was written to support the promotion or marketing of the transactions or othermatters addressed herein. Accordingly, you should seek advice based on your particular circumstances from an independent tax advisor. Copyright Barclays Bank PLC (2012). All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced in any manner without the prior written permissionof Barclays. Barclays Bank PLC is registered in England No. 1026167. Registered office 1 Churchill Place, London, E14 5HP. Additional information regardingthis publication will be furnished upon request.

  • 7/28/2019 Euro Themes - Spain

    22/22