eu's internal energy market: tough decisions and a daunting

76
Discussion Paper Summer 2013 EU'S INTERNAL ENERGY MARKET: TOUGH DECISIONS AND A DAUNTING AGENDA

Upload: doanxuyen

Post on 08-Jan-2017

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

Discussion Paper

Summer 2013

EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt:toUgh DEciSionS anDa DaUnting agEnDa

Page 2: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

The authors in the Discussion Paper contribute in their personal

capacities, and their views do not necessarily reflect those of the

institutions they represent or of Friends of Europe and its board of

trustees.

Reproduction in whole or in part is permitted, providing that

full credit is given to Friends of Europe, and provided that any

such reproduction, whether in whole or in part, is not sold unless

incorporated in other works.

Friends of Europe is grateful for the financial support it received from

GDF Suez for the production of this discussion paper.

Publisher: Geert Cami

Project Director: Nathalie Furrer

Project manager: Julie Bolle

greening Europe Programme adviser: Mike Scott

Design & layout: Heini Järvinen

cover image: woodleywonderworks

Page 3: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

Table of contentsForeword 2

Introduction 4

Europe’s unresolved energy versus climate policydilemmaDavid Buchan, Senior Research Fellow at the Oxford Institute forEnergy Studies 7

The many steps EU governments must still take ifthe internal energy market is to workJerzy Buzek MEP 14

The ‘perfect storm’ threatening EU energyJean-François Cirelli, Vice Chairman and President of GDF Suez 21

The EU’s internal energy market must be completedwith a clear strategy targeting global competitivenessFernand Felzinger, President of the International Federation ofIndustrial Energy Consumers (IFIEC) Europe 26

The three ages of Europe’s single electricity marketJean-Michel Glachant, Director of the European UniversityInstitute’s Florence School of Regulation 33

Two solutions for Europe’s energy “trilemma”Mike Lawn and Jonas Rooze, both of Bloomberg NewEnergy Finance 39

A sustainable energy system needs efficient marketsAuke Lont, Chief Executive Officer of Statnett 45

Integrating energy and climate policy to drivelow-carbon growth in EuropeJohannes Meier and Arne Mogren, both of the EuropeanClimate Foundation 52

What EU governments must do to get the internalenergy market rightHans ten Berge, Secretary General of EURELECTRIC 59

“The stuff we have, a strong wind will blow it topieces”: Two decades behind schedule, we need tore-think the single energy marketJorge Vasconcelos, Founder of the Council of European Energy Regulators 65

Page 4: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

2 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

FOREWORDEurope needs a well-functioning internal energy market to address its energy and climate challenges. An open and well-connected market helps to keep energy prices in check despite the ongoing rise in commodity prices. It is also the best guarantee for securing energy supplies across the EU member states and ensures easy entry of renewable energy into the market. All this is crucial for creating growth and jobs in Europe and to mitigate climate change.

The leaders of EU governments are committed to making a fully functioning internal market a reality. The European Council in May underlined the importance of completing the market by the end of next year.

The EU has come a long way since the market liberalisation process started: Europe in 2013 is no longer a patchwork of different national energy systems, each with its own national company controlling the entire sector. Increasingly integrated markets through independently operated networks make it easier today for new players to enter the market and start competing with existing companies, both on the wholesale and the retail levels. Consumers profit from better prices, improved services and overall more choice. As the market matures, prices become fairer and more reliable and can serve as important investment signals.

We can also be optimistic about the additional beneficial effects of several recent pieces of legislation, such as the energy infrastructure package, the regulation on wholesale energy market integrity and transparency or the network code on fairer access to gas pipelines.

But completing the internal market is a complex task, and a lot still needs to be done. The first thing to do is to apply the rules that are already there and that the member states have committed to. This may sound easy, but a good many infringement cases are still being pursued against a large number of member states for non-transposition or non-compliance of the 2nd and 3rd internal energy market legislative packages.

Page 5: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

3EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

A second priority relates to the need for infrastructure investment. Infrastructure is the backbone of the whole energy system, and with energy islands still present in parts of Europe, and without sufficient cross-border interconnection capacity a truly European market simply won’t be possible. Giving investors the right signals is therefore a priority. Fortunately, transmission and distribution assets have characteristics that make them attractive to investors. Strict EU rules on unbundling are needed for the market to function, but they also limit investment possibilities. We have to be pragmatic and keep in mind the overall goal of the unbundling rules rather than applying a strict interpretation of legal texts to the letter. The Commission has therefore recently issued guidance on how to interpret the law without discouraging the most badly needed investments that are financial rather than strategic, whilst still ensuring the independent management of networks.

A final challenge is finding the right balance between consumers’ needs and our trust in what the liberalised markets can offer. All the member states need to ensure secure supply of energy at affordable prices for their citizens, and competitive prices for business. But public interventions – by setting regulated prices, say – are certainly not the best way to tackle these issues. They frustrate competition and ultimately they increase costs rather than keeping them down.

Europe today faces difficult economic challenges, but that is no excuse for abandoning our ambitious energy policy objectives. On the contrary, a well-functioning energy market is key to getting out along the road to economic recovery.

Philip loweDirector General for EnergyEuropean Commission

Page 6: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

4 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

INTRODUCTIONEurope’s attempts to create a single energy market now stretch back over more than 20 years; it’s been so long it’s an idea that’s in danger of answering a question no longer being asked.

The internal energy market (IEM) was born out of two aims, explains Jorge Vasconcelos, founder of the Council of European Energy Regulators; the first, to liberalise electricity and natural gas markets, so consumers benefit from more competitive prices and the second being the wider one of completing the single market as a whole with the goal of achieving an ever closer union.

The potential economic benefits are enormous. A fully integrated electricity market could save the EU up to €35bn a year by as soon as 2015, compared with 2012, says the European Commission.

But since the beginning of attempts to bring Europe’s energy markets together, the aims have evolved – not least that of including the decarbonising of the European economy – so that the three strands of European energy policy are now to improve competitiveness, security of supply and sustainability.

It’s possible today to see an energy market where all of these aspects have been enhanced – not in Europe but in the U.S., where shale gas has cut energy costs, energy imports and greenhouse gas emissions as utilities switch from coal to gas. European Commission President José Manuel Barroso pointed out not long ago that between 2005 and 2012 the price of gas for EU industrial companies jumped by 35%, while their U.S. counterparts are paying 66% less than in 2005. And electricity prices in Europe have risen by 38%, against a 4% drop in the U.S.

Jean-michel glachant of the Florence School of Regulation suggests that, however imperfect, we have the basics of an integrated energy market, a point that the European Climate Foundation’s Johannes meier and arne mogren reinforce.

Yet although energy prices in Europe continue to soar, efforts to integrate markets in the EU seem to have gone backwards, points out hans ten Berge, EURELECTRIC’s Secretary General.

Page 7: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

5EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

Jerzy Buzek, the former Polish prime minister who has also been president of the European Parliament, says that European countries’ energy markets are poorly interconnected, fragmented and highly concentrated, while the compatibility of national grids remains low. “The market is neither open nor competitive, and it strongly favours the energy industry, disadvantaging consumers”, he warns.

These problems are exacerbated by the biggest economic crisis in the EU’s history, the collapse of carbon prices in its Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS) and the increasingly national focus on energy policies of the member states.

The ETS has “more or less collapsed, with the traded price of carbon too low to change the behaviour of energy generators or consumers – because it has proved all too responsive to the market and to the recession-induced fall in energy demand,” says David Buchan of the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.

And while some of our contributors, such as Meier and Mogren, argue that “we need a robust carbon price in order to drive the long-term, low-carbon investments that will enable us to decouple growth from fossil fuel consumption and decarbonise the power sector”, Fernand Felzinger of the International Federation of Industrial Energy Consumers (IFIEC) Europe believes that “artificially increasing the CO2 price would reduce our chances of promoting a global decarbonising tool, would further sap the EU’s competitiveness and would send distorted signals to investors”.

Perhaps most worrying of all is what Jean-François cirelli, Vice-Chairman and President of GDF Suez, calls “the renationalisation of energy policies” which “poses a very real threat to energy investment in Europe”. This trend is reflected in part by the failure in many member states to implement market liberalisation measures and through the introduction of policies that take no account of the wider European market. “There’s an increasing tendency among member states to implement policies that are distinctly different to those of the rest of the EU, whether it is renewable energy support schemes, capacity remuneration mechanisms or energy taxes and regulations on end-user prices,” warns Cirelli.

Hans ten Berge agrees, pointing to the example of Germany, which has unilaterally embarked on its Energiewende policy, “while the UK has proposed an electricity market reform whose measures effectively disregard the implications for other markets”.

Page 8: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

6 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

This increased national focus at exactly the time when a pan-European approach is so important is complicating the task of integrating more renewable energy into the system. There is a growing acknowledgement that capacity remuneration mechanisms are essential if we are to have the back-up capacity to keep the lights on when the wind isn’t blowing or the sun shining.

mike lawn and Jonas rooze of Bloomberg New Energy Finance write that such measures need to be coordinated at a European level. “National capacity payments, while guaranteeing security of supply in each jurisdiction, discourage further interconnection and suggest that countries do not feel they can rely on their trading partners in the event of a shortfall in power supply.”

Part of the problem, they say, is that national subsidies for renewables, combined with the recession, have now so distorted the wholesale energy market that countries are worried about their ability to ensure future security of supply. The EU needs to push hard to develop cross-border trading of power from renewables to ensure that renewable capacity operates as efficiently as possible.

However, Felzinger argues that capacity payments should be “a last resort” and the focus should instead be on demand management.

For this to happen, Europe needs a much stronger transmission and distribution system – €600bn of the €1 trillion of investment needed between 2010 and 2020 must go to this sector, Commission President Barroso has emphasised.

Decarbonisation in the power sector will reduce flexible, fossil power generation, and replace it with intermittent power generation like wind power. To maintain security of supply, a much stronger European transmission grid will be needed, along with greater flexibility in generation, consumption and storage systems. Market prices will have to be an important driver for this change, explains Statnett’s auke lont.

This is true, but what an EU-wide IEM really needs are harmonised policies to create a level playing field for the free flow of electricity supplies across the EU. With the EU’s member states appearing to pull apart rather than closer together, the IEM could prove a source of much greater co-operation. Because it can provide jobs, reduce energy costs for everyone and make it easier to meet EU climate targets it’s a prize worth striving for. ●

Page 9: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

7EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

EUROPE’S UNRESOLVED ENERGY vErsus CLIMATE POLICY DILEMMA

The creation of a pan-European energy market is being undermined by member states’ reluctance to align their national renewable energy policies, or to rely on their neighbours for back-up capacity, writes David Buchan of the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies.

However great the disarray over Europe’s energy policy, there is still consensus on the goal of a pan-European energy market. The whole point of European Union membership is to provide greater scale for every sector of the economy, and energy is no exception.

In a single market of 28 countries, scale can promote wider competition and through competition convergence on the most efficient price level; scale provides security through diversity of energy sources, and scale can also provide a critical mass of low-carbon investment along with the political influence in the world to make a difference in international climate negotiations.

But there is no longer a consensus that this geographical unification of Europe’s national energy markets can be achieved through liberalisation – if Europe wants at the same time to achieve its climate goals of emission reduction and promotion of low carbon energy. This is because current climate policy is being carried out through increasing doses of random national intervention in the energy market, exactly what liberalisation was supposed to remove.

David BuchanSenior Research Fellow at the Oxford Institute for Energy Studies

Page 10: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

8 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

So what are the alternatives? Drop Europe’s climate goals, or coordinate at EU level the various national interventionist measures? For the moment, the European Commission is pursuing the second option. It is producing guidelines this summer that member states are being asked to follow in the design of their national subsidies for renewable energy and back-up capacity. These national renewable and capacity schemes – which are both key elements and consequences of climate policy – create a real risk of segmenting, or rather re-segmenting, the European energy market.

In 2009, the EU put together an energy and climate package of legislation that appeared to be coherent. A third package of internal energy market rules completed the legislative job of unbundling electricity and gas transmission companies from distorting supplier interests so that they could act as common carriers of energy for all. It strengthened the powers and independence (from interference by their governments) of national regulators, and put them under the pan-European umbrella of the Agency for Cooperation of Energy Regulators (ACER). It gave to this body, and to the upgraded European organisations of transmission system operators (TSOs), the task of developing blueprints for building future pan-European grids and of agreeing on market designs and network codes to integrate trading across borders.

On top of this foundation of traditional internal market liberalising and integration measures, a series of ambitious climate targets were overlaid. Some of these – such as mandatory national renewable targets – were clearly non-market in character. The Commission sought to prevent these targets from leading to a national carve-up of the energy market by proposing these targets could be met through a pan-European system of trading renewable power certificates. The European Council and Parliament rejected this in favour of maintaining national renewable subsidy schemes.

The flagship climate instrument of the 2009 package, however, was the reformed Emissions Trading System (ETS). Although non-market in the sense of setting an arbitrary maximum cap on Europe’s carbon emissions, the ETS allows emitters to use the market mechanism of carbon allowance trading to comply with the cap. And back in 2009, the ETS instrument looked to be big enough and market-friendly enough to make EU climate policy appear compatible with a liberalised EU energy policy.

Page 11: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

9EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

But now the ETS has more or less collapsed, with the traded price of carbon too low to change the behaviour of energy generators or consumers because it has proved all too responsive to the market and to the recession-induced fall in energy demand. As the ETS has declined in importance, the non-market instruments of renewable targets and subsidies have grown in importance, and have created worries about insufficient conventional power back-up that EU policymakers simply hadn’t been able to foresee in 2009. And if EU climate policymakers are in a mess, many of those making EU energy policy are in revolt. Energy Commissioner Günther Oettinger now complains openly about the subordination of energy policy to climate policy, in particular about policies that have done little to reduce emissions and a lot to raise energy prices across Europe.

Bearing in mind the key link between fossil fuels and greenhouse gases – energy production accounts for around two-thirds of all greenhouse gases in terms of CO2

equivalence – how did we get to this situation of near-divorce in Europe between energy policy and climate policy?

One obvious reason is the recession. As well as effectively neutering the ETS as an instrument for encouraging new low carbon energy, it has also helped undermine the business case for investing in new relatively clean gas-powered electricity generation. Virtually no new gas plants are being planned, and some existing ones are being mothballed. The crisis in Europe’s financial sector has led to most banks and many insurers pulling out of project finance in energy and other infrastructure sectors to focus instead on re-building their capital ratios. This has created a bigger financing gap than could ever be plugged by the €5bn of EU budget money slated for energy infrastructure over the next seven years, and by the European Investment Bank’s plan to use a modest amount of public money for partnering private investors to try to revive project bonds.

“many of those making EU energy policy are in revolt. Energy commissioner günther oettinger now complains openly about the subordination of energy policy to climate policy, in particular about policies that have done little to reduce emissions and a lot to raise

energy prices across Europe.”

Page 12: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

10 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

The economic downturn has, above all, made Europe’s governments and public opinion neurotic about energy prices. These are being kept high by such outside factors as Russia’s linkage of its gas price in Europe to a still-buoyant global oil price, and by the upward push to liquefied natural gas prices of strong Asian demand, along with the renewable energy subsidy costs borne by Europe’s electricity consumers. The signs of this energy price neurosis are everywhere. From Bulgaria, where energy price protests recently overturned the government, to Spain which has retroactively (illegally, in terms of contract law) reduced subsidies on existing renewable projects. In the UK, the public, the media and the politicians are more focussed on the immediate issue of “price gouging” by energy companies than the country’s looming shortfall in electricity generation, while in Germany the powerful manufacturing sector is complaining, with some exaggeration, that energy costs risk causing de-industrialisation, not just in Germany but throughout Europe. For all these reasons, the focus of the European Council summit in May was on energy policy and prices, and on replicating the U.S. shale gas revolution to bring gas prices down. Europe’s energy price neurotics see shale gas as the EU’s get-out-of-jail card.

There is another reason why the ‘single marketeers’ who dominate EU energy policymaking fret at climate policy. This reason is the disruptive effect of national renewable energy programmes on EU policymakers’ attempts to integrate the market – both in terms of the geographical unification of national energy sectors and in terms of smoothly marrying conventional fossil fuels with renewables in the commercial marketplace. The EU is on track to meet its overall target of achieving an average of a 20% renewables share of total EU energy consumption by 2020. But while some member states will struggle to meet national targets that require a surge of new renewable energy deployment in the last few years running up to 2020, the biggest member state, Germany, is deploying renewable generation to a spectacular – and destabilising – extent.

“the building of more cross-border links, and negotiations on cross-border trading arrangements, are all in train, but are not moving as fast as the deployment of renewables or capacity scheme planning.”

Page 13: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

11EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

Germany has doubled its renewable generation capacity – wind, solar, biomass and small hydro – from less than 40 gigawatts (GW) in 2008 to more than 80 GW today. At maximum potential, this is almost enough to meet peak German energy demand of around 85GW. But most of this capacity (60 GW) is intermittent wind and solar energy. For much of the time, this meets only around a quarter of German demand, but occasionally it is enough to blow conventional generation – gas, coal and what remains of nuclear – right out of the marketplace and therefore out of the money.

There is therefore growing clamour by Germany’s providers of non-renewable power for some form of capacity subsidy as payment for keeping plants ready as standby generators. Some countries already have, or plan, capacity mechanisms, although not all have the same motive as Germany. The UK has a far smaller renewables sector than Germany, but plans to introduce a capacity market in 2014 because forced closure of dirty plant and years of dithering about new plant have left it with an impending shortage of overall capacity, not just back-up.

But all capacity schemes in Europe tend to prefer national generators over foreign ones, because most politicians would rather not rely on foreigners to keep their country’s lights on. This combination of national renewable and capacity schemes may deal the EU energy market a double blow – a blow to the energy sector’s geographical unity because the schemes are national, and a blow to the normal workings of a commercial marketplace because the schemes involve subsidies.

In this summer’s guidelines, the Commission is urging a Europeanisation, or at least a regionalisation, of national renewable and capacity schemes. This would involve neighbouring countries aligning the structure and level of their renewables subsidies to reduce distortion of trade and investment in renewables, and so allow neighbouring countries to participate in each other’s capacity schemes where there’s sufficient interconnection between them. That’s the rub; the

“rather than the artificial completion of Europe’s energy market, it is more important to aim for coherence of this market – in particular to reduce

the mismatch between fast-developing national renewable and capacity schemes and slower-moving infrastructure construction.”

Page 14: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

12 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

building of more cross-border links, and negotiations on cross-border trading arrangements, are all in train, but are not moving as fast as the deployment of renewables or capacity scheme planning.

The new EU infrastructure regulation, which streamlines national procedures for permitting priority trans-frontier energy links will speed transmission construction, especially of overhead electricity pylons that attract more public opposition than buried gas pipelines. But the difference will not be dramatic. TSO organisations in Europe are pumping out agreed network codes for electricity and gas as fast as they can, but they struggle to meet the arbitrary deadlines set by politicians. “We had been aiming to complete our work on network codes in 2015”, said a TSO executive. “But when the European Council in February 2011 suddenly set 2014 as the deadline for completion of the internal energy market, we found that in one day we had lost a year”.

Come next year, the European Council will find that it could no more command completion of the internal energy market by that date than the Anglo-Saxon King Canute could command the ocean tide to turn back. Yet next year will see substantial achievement, in particular the coupling of day-ahead trading for electricity in almost all the 28 national markets. The European Council will, though, find its 2011 edict of an end to the isolation of all EU energy markets by 2015 unfulfilled; the three Baltic states will still be linked to the Russian electricity and gas grid, partly because they cannot agree among themselves where and how to build both a regional nuclear reactor and a regional terminal to receive outside LNG supplies.

Rather than the artificial completion of Europe’s energy market, it is more important to aim for coherence of this market – in particular to reduce the mismatch between fast-developing national renewable and capacity schemes and slower-moving infrastructure construction. One way to do this would be for

“While some member states will struggle to meet national targets that require a surge of new renewable energy deployment in the last few years running up to 2020, the biggest member state, germany, is deploying renewable generation to a spectacular extent.”

Page 15: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

13EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

the European Commission to use its powers for policing state aids to say that it will approve national capacity schemes only if the member state in question devotes some money to improving interconnections with its neighbours. Increased interconnection would increase the member state’s ability to draw on its EU neighbours’ energy supply in case of emergency, and should also make it easier for countries to compensate for supply/demand imbalances caused by renewables. In doing this, the Commission would be taking a strong stand in the area of security of supply, which is one of great political sensitivity to national governments. Needless to say, the Commission now has to take a very strong stand if it is to regain control over the forces of disintegration that it failed to anticipate in 2009. ■

Source: European Commission

new realities in the global energy market

Page 16: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

14 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

THE MANY STEPS EU GOVERNMENTS MUST STILL TAKE IF THE INTERNAL ENERGY MARKET IS TO WORKA harmonised common energy market and coordinated investment in infrastructure are vital if Europe is to return to growth and remain competitive, writes former European Parliament President Jerzy Buzek. For now, he cautions, the market is still fragmented and opaque.

The prices of goods and services depend to a significant extent on the price of energy. Excessive energy prices influence the overall competitive potential of an economy, so 20 years after Bill Clinton's slogan "it’s the economy, stupid!" it is plain that the real depth of his catchphrase is that it acknowledges a prospering economy needs secure, stable and affordable energy. The U.S. seems to have learned this lesson particularly well. Thanks to falling energy prices, American industry is booming. The U.S. expects to achieve independence from oil and gas imports by 2035. By as soon as 2015, the U.S. will be producing more gas than Russia, and in 2017 it will be able to extract more energy resources than Saudi Arabia.

In striking contrast, energy prices in the EU are among the highest in all OECD countries and it is estimated that electricity costs in the European Union will by 2035 be 50% higher than in the U.S. and three times higher than in China. European industries pay four times more for gas than their American competitors. The EU’s dependency on energy imports of 50% at present is projected to grow by another 15 percentage points by 2030.

Jerzy Buzek mEPFormer President of the European Parliament (2009-2012) and a former Prime Minister of Poland (1997-2001)

Page 17: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

15EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

To be competitive, we should put all our efforts into reversing these trends. To facilitate this, we need a harmonised common energy market that is open and competitive, flexible, well-connected, well-regulated and transparent and predictable. The EU’s internal energy market (IEM) should be seen as the most important of all 12 of the fields in the Single Market Act II. It is after all, the single market which along with innovation based on research and new technologies, constitutes the most direct path towards a fully competitive Europe. And increasing economic competitiveness is needed more than ever to get the EU back on the path to the growth and to the creation of new jobs.

When I and Jacques Delors launched the European Energy Community (EEC) initiative in May 2010, our purpose was to motivate EU member states to think and act European on energy. The internal energy market is, with joint energy purchases and joint funding of low-emission technologies, one of the three pillars of the Community. Underlying the initiative was our belief that this sector should be integrated and harmonised just like the other sectors covered by the 1992 single market programme.

The EU’s member states have confirmed their commitment to a single energy market and at the European Council in February 2011 set a clear deadline for creating it by 2014. There’s been some progress but there remains more to be done than has so far been achieved.

Today's energy market in Europe is poorly interconnected. The compatibility of national grids remains low, and that creates challenges like energy islands and loop flows. The market is neither open nor competitive, and it strongly favours the energy industry, disadvantaging consumers. The market is also highly concentrated: single energy producers control over 50% of the markets in as many as 11 member states and in six countries single producers are near-monopolists, holding more than 80% of market share. This has a variety of implications for all stakeholders, it affects the quality of services and results in insufficient flexibility.

Energy prices are high, and in many cases on the increase, and this is a trend that’s likely to persist. Prices differ heavily across Europe, so in the wholesale trade gas in Tallinn can be 50% more expensive than in London, and electricity can be almost 70% more expensive in Rome than in Tallinn. What’s more in these

Page 18: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

16 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

fragmented markets, energy prices are too often rigidly regulated by member states. Before these energy markets can become fully competitive regulation needs to benefit consumers and prevent energy poverty. At present, though, it all too often imposes excessive limitations and doesn’t increase energy efficiency.

As well as being poorly interconnected and overpriced, the market isn’t transparent enough, so consumers have too little understanding of their options. They lack the tools to compare what is on offer from different suppliers, and they find it hard to tell whether switching between providers gives them access to cheaper and reliable energy supplies. In many member states switching simply isn’t possible, and in others although such possibilities exist it often fails to result in better prices or quality of service.

Our goal must be to create an energy market that will be rebalanced to benefit consumers, so they can better understand their rights and the market rules and are therefore able to make decisions based on clear information. In short, where both private and business consumers will be able to play the market game on equal terms with the energy sector.

Individual consumers would benefit from a truly integrated market via the lower prices resulting from increased competition. They would gain better control of their energy costs and that could generate consumer savings of as much as €13bn annually in the EU. The information available to consumers would be improved and its availability increased. An EU-wide system of protecting consumer rights could be put in place in which vulnerable consumers would be covered while the IEM also made dispute resolution easier. For the business sector, a single market in energy with half a billion consumers would mean new investment opportunities and a strong incentive to maintain business activity in the EU and thus create new jobs. Last but not least, it would offer opportunities for strengthening the economy with high-end technological innovation.

“Before these energy markets can become fully competitive regulation needs to benefit consumers and prevent energy poverty. at present, though, it all too often imposes excessive limitations and doesn’t increase energy efficiency.”

Page 19: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

17EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

Energy producers, for their part, stand to benefit from predictability, clear rules and as equal and fair access to the single market. In a fully competitive environment, they will be more strongly motivated to produce energy, and that in turn promises a reduced dependence on non-EU sources as well as a stronger negotiation position with external suppliers. All of that translates into greater energy security.

The growth we are striving for needs to be sustainable and environmentally sensitive. By ensuring we have a more efficient means of producing, storing and distributing energy, a competitive European market will, along with investments in new technologies, make the sector more environmentally friendly. A well-designed open and coherent energy market should also speed the way to a low-emission economy.

In April of this year, I prepared a European Parliament report on the internal energy market. Entitled "Making the Internal Energy Market Work", it pointed to the actions that the EU’s institutions, member states and corporate sector must undertake urgently to facilitate the single energy market. The main areas in the report were:

� A comprehensive harmonisation of the regulatory framework is needed; the member states must fully transpose the Third Energy Package, yet it is most disturbing that not even the second package has been fully adopted by all EU countries. It will be impossible to build the third floor of a house when the second has not been finished, and to ensure the regulatory framework’s stability harmonised network codes and rules must first be introduced.

� Infrastructure investment must be better coordinated so as to ensure a fully EU-wide system of connectivity that is cost-effective. We are going to need €210bn just for the construction of new transmission networks for electricity and gas. This all includes €140bn for electricity infrastructure, intelligent networks, storage and high-voltage transmission networks; €70bn for reverse flow interconnectors, gas infrastructure: storage, gas pipelines and LNG terminals and €2.5bn for CO2 transporting infrastructure. The total investment needed amounts to around €1 trillion. It is worth stressing that the introduction of smart technologies must not be restricted to automatic meter-reading only but must be completed with dynamic, online grid management.

Page 20: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

18 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

It has to be acknowledged that certain aspects of infrastructure development may not be commercially viable but are needed to provide stable energy supply. Cross-border interconnectors are a key prerequisite for the internal energy market and are also an excellent example of the community-wide investment in energy infrastructure that could and should be funded with community resources. The cuts made to the Connecting Europe Facility during the negotiations of the 2014-2020 Multiannual Financial Framework seem very likely to constrain key investments of this sort. It is difficult to demand more Europe with less money.

To support future infrastructure investment, we ought to rethink our own protectionist measures. EU member states must refrain from regulating their own retail energy prices because all aspects of energy trading should be stable and predictable. The gradual phasing out of subsidies to renewables means that after 2020 they will be at a substantially lower level than today. But at the same time, carbon pricing will depend on the design of climate policy and its interconnection

World trends affect Europe

Source: European Commission

Page 21: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

19EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

with the Emissions Trading Scheme. Its stability requires that these should be free of disruptive interventions like the recently attempted backloading of emission allowances.

With the EU's economy stagnating, there is currently no demand for an increased supply of energy. That’s a normal market reaction and slow growth, no growth has made us more energy efficient. But in the scenario of returning to steady growth in a few years from now, demand for energy will again increase. Then, in line with basic market principles, those who have invested in new infrastructure and developed their production, storage and distribution capabilities, will have a clear advantage. The investment banking sector should play an important role here and help carry the risk of these future investments. That such investments will soon pay off is in little doubt – after any crisis, growing demand and rising prices mean the rates of return increase substantially.

Electricity prices: the U.S. is increasing its advantage largely thanks to shale gas

Source: European Commission

Page 22: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

20 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

Europe’s internal energy market is not an end-goal. It is a tool that will serve the long-term objectives of an efficient and reliable energy system and the cost-effective transition to a low-emission economy. It also has a chance to become our greatest asset in the global competitiveness race. We cannot ensure the prosperity of Europe’s citizens without affordable energy prices.

We know what must be done, and we also know there’s no time to lose. An integrated energy market will never become reality unless today’s spectrum of different national approaches to energy generation, storage and distribution, is replaced by an overall European approach. We need a genuine European Energy Community – a locomotive to move our energy project forward along the tracks to a shared destination. Winston Churchill once said that attitude is a small thing that makes a big difference. EU member states are on the horns of a dilemma – they have to decide whether to demonstrate close cooperation for the sake of their citizens, or to further delay taking these crucial steps and so endanger European competitiveness. Big difference or indifference – it is up to we Europeans to decide. ■

“Europe’s internal energy market is not an end-goal. it is a tool that will serve the long-term objectives of an efficient and reliable energy system and the cost-effective transition to a low-emission economy.”

Page 23: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

21EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

THE ‘PERFECT STORM’ THREATENING EU ENERGY

The European Commission’s market-fixated approach to EU energy policy has been overtaken by revolutionary changes. Jean-François Cirelli of the GDF Suez energy giant sets out a five-point plan for tackling Europe’s greatest competition challenge.

Few industrial sectors in Europe have been transformed as profoundly as energy. Four important developments have redefined the fundamentals of the sector: the shale gas revolution in the U.S., the fall-out from the Fukushima nuclear accident, Europe’s persistent economic crisis and the growing share of renewables in power generation.

Despite these radical changes, the decision-makers who define EU energy policy are still committed to the same market-based vision of the energy sector they’ve had for the past 20 years. But now, due in part to these transformations, the limitations of this approach are increasingly apparent. The co-existence of over-capacity in the power market with what appears to be a re-nationalisation of energy policies poses a very real threat to energy investment in Europe. It’s worth stressing that the problem is not market liberalisation as such, because we very much share the objectives and appreciate the importance of this approach. It’s the uneven implementation of these measures that is preventing the much-needed level playing field across member states. The benefits that we can expect from market liberalisation are so great that we Europeans have a duty to take action now. The current approach doesn’t have to be abandoned, but it must be reformed so that the confidence of operators can be re-established. That’s crucial if the EU’s internal energy market is to be a success.

Jean-François cirelliVice Chairman and President of GDF Suez

Page 24: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

22 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

The European Commission’s leitmotiv for the energy sector has for two decades been “the market”. This has created two flagships of energy policy – the internal energy market with its liberalisation packages, and the emissions trading system (ETS).

The centre-pieces of market liberalisation have been the first, second and third energy packages, adopted respectively in 1998, 2003 and 2009 with the aim of ensuring affordable, competitive, secure and sustainable energy supplies to private and industrial consumers. The Commission’s goal now is to finalise the internal energy market by 2014, notably, by enforcing the unbundling of networks away from the competitive parts of the electricity and gas business in Europe. The aim is for markets to be opened up. It has, naturally enough, been a challenging process for vertically integrated companies like GDF Suez, but we are now fully compliant and eager to participate fully and benefit from it.

The Commission’s complement to the energy packages has been enforcement of a carbon price in the form of the ETS market mechanism. This was supposed to create an incentive for the reduction of emissions in Europe, and to provide signals for low-carbon investments through establishing a price for carbon, making that the most attractive way to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.

Although we share the Commission’s goals, and believe in the potential of its policy instruments, it is with some regret that we would nevertheless underline the fact that neither the market liberalisations nor the ETS have yet borne fruit. The defining point about energy is that long-term investments are essential to its future. That requires long-term certainty and predictability, neither of which is provided by the Commission’s current market vision. The situation facing operators today has become critical, because overcapacity and the re-nationalisation of energy policies are combining to make the current market model unworkable.

Europe’s energy system now suffers from overcapacity in overall terms, although not at times of peak generation. This to some extent results from the economic downturn and a substantial drop in demand. It’s a significant challenge that has

“the decision-makers who define EU energy policy are still committed to the same market-based vision of the energy sector they’ve had for the past 20 years. But now, the limitations of this approach are increasingly apparent.”

Page 25: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

23EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

“although we share the commission’s goals, and believe in the potential of its policy instruments, it is with some regret that we would

nevertheless underline the fact that neither the market liberalisations nor the EtS have yet borne fruit.”

been aggravated by subsidised renewables coming onto the market in an un-coordinated manner that takes no account of their impact on the energy market or on the EU grid. There has also been a collapse in the carbon price, with the ETS no longer providing any incentive for investment in low-carbon technologies. Attempts to re-establish credibility for CO2 market quotas have failed, and that’s reflected in the extremely low price of emissions credits.

Operators of thermal power plants, and natural gas ones in particular are facing a short-term crisis that may yet have disastrous long-term consequences going well beyond the energy sector. These plants’ economic viability is being undermined by their growing role as back-up providers rather than base-load power sources. In practical terms, this means reduced hours of operation at the same time as higher operating and maintenance costs. Gas power stations are being pushed to the side by renewables and also by coal thanks to the extremely low ETS price of CO2. The upshot is that both existing and planned gas power stations are more and more uneconomical, and so are no longer viable investment options for utilities.

If this trend persists there will be closures, and no prospect of replacements being built. The EU would pay a high price for the absence of gas power plants, because coal, as the energy source that would largely replace gas, is not only far more polluting, but also far less flexible. Gas is therefore the most appropriate energy source in its own right, as well as the best back-up for often intermittent renewables. Europe’s increased energy needs once economic recovery takes root, as well as its commitment to reducing CO2 emissions, means that only gas, coupled with renewables, can ensure both needs are met.

In the meantime, the re-nationalisation of energy policies across the EU is running in stark contradiction to the aim of completing the single energy market. These liberalisations are not being implemented in several member states, despite the deadlines, and that’s creating serious uncertainties because national rules often vary significantly from country to country. We in the power generation business

Page 26: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

24 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

can only ask for full implementation of EU legislation so as to avoid a “multi-speed” Europe. These divergences need to be addressed urgently, which means that attacking market distortions should be among the Commission’s priorities.

The re-nationalisations in the energy sector go well beyond the liberalisation issue. There’s an increasing tendency among member states to implement policies that are distinctly different to those of the rest of the EU, whether they concern renewable energy support schemes, capacity remuneration mechanisms or energy taxes and regulations on end-user prices. The EU’s third energy package continues to allow for the regulation of end-user prices in several member states as an alternative letting the market determine prices. And the prices set by national authorities all too often fail to cover costs and the return on investments.

All this explains why EU-level action is so urgently needed. If 2014 is to be remembered for completion of the internal energy market rather than for the continued loss of confidence amongst operators, five key changes must be made.

First we need an improved framework for investment that offers long-term predictability and visibility. The rules of the game to which investors sign up, cannot be changed half-way through for political reasons. It is intolerable that retroactive decisions be put in place or existing regulations not be completely implemented. And when regulated, the price of energy for the end-user must be at a level that covers costs and fairly remunerates the capital invested.

Second, a coordinated European approach to capacity remuneration mechanisms (CRM) across Europe is essential if we are to have enough capacity to back-up renewables. A pan-European CRM would provide much-needed harmonisation of today’s patchwork of national CRMs, and would also speed up the integration of national energy markets. By providing appropriate remuneration for new and existing power generation, a well-designed European CRM would ensure security of electricity supplies without hindering the drive towards a single energy market.

Third, the coordination of renewable energy support schemes at the European level has become very necessary indeed. Excessively generous financial support schemes are at the root of policymakers’ concerns as well as those of the general public that could undermine the EU’s energy policy. And fourth, the ETS must be restructured to deliver a price signal that attracts low-carbon investments. A

Page 27: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

25EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

CO2 emissions reduction target for 2030, in line with the European Commission’s

objective of 80% decarbonisation by 2050, would be appropriate. This new target should be transposed to all sectors subject to the ETS as soon as is legally possible, and a contribution to this effort also needs to be made by those sectors not yet subject to the ETS. The ground for this medium-term measure could be prepared by a short-term reduction in the present allowances surplus, namely the set-aside of a minimum of 1 200Mt CO2.

Fifth and last, research and development on future technologies like energy storage, smart metres, smart grids, shale gas and new renewables need to be EU priorities. Increased funding for the new Horizon 2020 programme looks promising, even though the cuts of €10bn by the European Council in its agreement on the EU’s next Multiannual Financial Framework 2014-2020 are clearly regrettable.

The challenges facing Europe’s energy sector in general, and particularly gas, must not be under-estimated. Business-as-usual quite simply won’t be possible, so we need a revitalised EU approach that is balanced more in favour of investors by being based on long-term stability and visibility, a higher price for CO2 in the ETS, the implementation of CRMs and a more favourable energy market design. In short, we need a revamped EU energy policy that actually works. ■

Source: European Commission

completing the internal energy market

Page 28: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

26 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

THE EU’S INTERNAL ENERGY MARKET MUST BE COMPLETED WITH A CLEAR STRATEGY TARGETING GLOBAL COMPETITIVENESSCompanies in the EU face significantly higher energy prices than their competitors and the situation is getting worse, writes Fernand Felzinger, who argues that increasing the carbon price would be a disaster for Europe’s energy-intensive industries at a time when it needs to re-industrialise.

The EU’s energy policy is based on the three pillars of competitiveness, security of supply and sustainability. Of these, international competitiveness is obviously the one that has been left behind and needs urgently to be restored.

The European Commission’s “Industrial Policy Communication Update” of October last year warned that European industry is facing significantly higher energy prices than its global competitors, and that “the difference has increased drastically over the last decade”, for both gas and electricity. This, along with the overall deterioration of the EU economy, has put Europe’s energy-intensive industries in an extremely difficult situation. Since the beginning of the economic crisis in Europe, over 3m industrial jobs have been lost while, in competing areas like the U.S. with shale gas and China with coal, energy is clearly being used as a “production factor”.

When looking at the EU’s internal energy market, it’s impossible to ignore the interaction between climate and energy policies as both strongly impact the energy

Fernand FelzingerPresident of the International Federation of Industrial Energy Consumers (IFIEC) Europe

Page 29: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

27EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

market. The problem is that the assumptions on which these policies were based are no longer valid. This has important consequences when it comes to aligning both policies, and when debating the outlook for new targets.

The underlying assumptions of climate and energy policies need therefore to be revised as they are threatened by the drastic change in the fossil fuel price trend. In 2007 and 2008, the future seemed easy to predict: oil had peaked close to $150 a barrel and the only question seemed how long it would take to reach $200. On that basis, Europe’s climate and energy policies were coherent. By decarbonising its economy and developing renewable energy sources that over time would benefit from a declining cost curve, the EU would strengthen its long-term competitiveness, improve its security of supply and favour the emergence of “green industry” leaders. On top of that, the EU’s emissions trading system (ETS) would pave the way for an enlarged Kyoto protocol and a global market-based carbon price.

We now know that few things are as predicted only a few years ago:

� The shale gas and oil revolution in North America has led to a price decrease for both gas and power, with coal following suit.

� Conventional and unconventional gas reserves are more widespread than had been thought, and are now being re-evaluated at several hundred years of consumption.

� Gas prices around the world are not expected to increase except in areas where consumers get squeezed by a lack of gas-to-gas competition. The consequence is that it will take longer than had been anticipated to bring the total cost of recent renewable energy source (RES) technologies down to a globally competitive level. And the subsidies granted for 15-20 years will not be wiped off by rising market prices led by fossil fuels. They are a debt to be reimbursed over many years.

� The intermittent nature of wind and solar power generation means that ensuring power system stability requires significant investments in grid extensions and back-up capacities.

� The overly rapid scaling-up of immature technologies also adds significant costs to the system.

� As seen in last year’s Doha conference for climate change, the number of countries committed to reducing their greenhouse gas emissions in a binding manner has decreased, while coal-fired power plants are

Page 30: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

28 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

flourishing in China, where they provide energy-intensive industries with cheap power. By 2015, China will produce more than 50% of the world’s overall aluminium production, with its dedicated coal-based power consumption there greater than that of the whole Italian market.

Add to these elements the fact that Europe is grappling with its severe financial crisis and it becomes obvious that decarbonising the EU economy has to be driven in a cost-effective way.

What new objectives do we need for an efficient climate policy? The one thing that’s sure is that the EU will meet its 2020 reduction target of greenhouse gas emissions for the sectors covered by the ETS. A low CO2 price for its phase three confirms that a market-based system indeed delivers results at the lowest possible cost.

But does that change the global picture? Not on present trends as the EU will by 2030 represent only an estimated 6% of global emissions. The real challenge is therefore to arrive at a global agreement. The aim of a market-based system like the ETS was to develop an efficient global tool that’s other than just as tax; the temptation is often to use taxes for purposes they weren’t designed for.

As a tool the ETS is still useful, and linking it with Australia’s comparable system is an initiative which we at the International Federation of Industrial Energy Consumers (IFIEC) welcome. It is a first step towards globalising the scheme, and by comparing the two systems it offers an opportunity to correct the structural flaws of the EU system, namely, the ex-ante allocation of allowances which can incentivise carbon leakage. It is only once we have a global agreement and a global carbon price, that the goal of reducing greenhouse gas emissions will become a reality.

But we must avoid shooting ourselves in the foot. The paradox is that those who now advocate political intervention to artificially increase the carbon price, and thus electricity prices in Europe, also risk distorting a purely market-based signal for the sake of “giving the right price signal.”

But the right price signal for what? If it’s to make gas more attractive than coal for power generation, then we would need a carbon price that’s above 40€/t. And if the EU achieves that, what signal would it give to gas suppliers who refuse to offer competitive prices to Europe? Should we

Page 31: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

29EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

therefore ban the use of coal or lignite? That wouldn’t take into consideration the 2050 roadmap which showed that with carbon capture and storage (CCS) there will be room for all energy sources in the European mix. Keeping gas in the picture doesn’t require an artificially high carbon price as it will always be an important part of Europe’s energy mix, maybe not for baseload power generation but for heating at least. And transport might be another opportunity for the development of gas usage.

Or maybe the price signal should be to reduce the level of subsidies that span the difference between feed-in tariffs and market prices, and that are required by some RES investments? But this misses the point. In order to develop a sustainable Europe-based renewables industry, we need truly competitive technologies which, once mature enough, can be exported because they would be a valid alternative to carbon-based power. The real objective of RES development is not to impose a volume target in an abstract framework which might lead to unnecessary costs for the community, but to fix competitiveness targets which will bring us faster to grid parity. Although it may require a greater innovation and R&D effort, this is the sort of challenge which the EU is accustomed to.

Artificially increasing the CO2 price would reduce our chances of promoting a global decarbonising tool, would further sap the EU’s competitiveness and would send distorted signals to investors. What is instead needed for both social and environmental purposes is a re-industrialisation of Europe. As shown by a number of studies, the EU may be reducing its direct carbon emissions but is increasing its indirect carbon emissions by consuming goods manufactured in countries with a more carbon-based energy mix. The challenge is to fight more actively against this carbon leakage.

The most threatened industries are, of course, the energy intensive ones. This is why it is so important – for both jobs and the environment – to stimulate growth in energy-intensive industries confronted with international competition. After all, basic industries are key contributors to greening the economy. But to invest in

“artificially increasing the co2 price would reduce our chances of promoting a global decarbonising tool, would further sap the EU’s competitiveness and

would send distorted signals to investors.”

Page 32: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

30 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

Europe, industry needs access to globally competitive energy costs with long-term visibility and a stable regulatory environment.

Urgent structural measures are needed to safeguard the competitiveness of EU industry. These include reducing the gas price gap between Europe and the rest of the world because natural gas prices are at present three to four times higher than in North America, leading already to an alarming shift of investment from Europe to the U.S., creating a situation that is unsustainable. For gas intensive industries, the cost differences are tens of millions of euros a year, compared to competitors buying gas in the U.S.

The critical situation faced by gas intensive industries means we need a whole set of actions. Those that could yield short-term results include:

� The rapid implementation of the third energy package. Its 2014 target should on no account be postponed, and implementation should take place in all EU member states.

� There should be a decoupling of natural gas prices from oil prices, with gas prices defined by supply and demand, not by oil.

Further actions leading to mid- to long-term effects are:

� The promotion of investments in infrastructures like LNG terminals and pipelines which would enable further diversification of supply sources, and would increase competition.

� The encouragement of clean exploration and production of shale gas. Europe, according to the American Energy Information Agency, has almost as much technically recoverable shale gas as the United States. But exploration and development of shale gas are stuck at a very early stage because of political and regulatory uncertainties. Policymakers need to set an enabling framework that takes into account environmental concerns that can be minimised by using

“the rapid implementation of the EU’s internal energy market is not only necessary for internal competition but because it enables the overall costs of adapting the EU energy system to the new generation mix to be reduced.”

Page 33: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

31EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

technologies such as “green fracking”. The challenges of extracting shale gas in Europe are different to those in the U.S., but the EU nevertheless has the potential to form a medium-term “strategic bridge” towards long-term greener energy.

Another measure to safeguard the competitiveness of EU industry concerns electricity. For industrial consumers, electricity costs are twice as expensive in Europe as in North America and parts of Asia, and this situation will worsen with the cumulative cost impact of energy and climate policies.

The rapid implementation of the EU’s internal energy market (IEM) is not only necessary for internal competition but because it enables the overall costs of adapting the EU energy system to the new generation mix to be reduced. But by itself this cannot resolve the lack of competitiveness. In the context of rising costs, hardship regimes and exemptions from inappropriate cost allocations become an absolute necessity for those power-intensive industries in Europe that are most vulnerable to international competition. These measures must address the whole cost structure, from the power generated (easing restrictions on long-term contracts), to grid costs (the need for a cost-reflective approach taking into account baseload consumption profiles) and government’s contributions to multiple national support schemes.

The major question is whether these specific measures can provide enough visibility to spark investment? To be really efficient, a globally competitive market requires a globally competitive energy mix. The issue with scaling up immature RES technologies too quickly is that the total financial support keeps on increasing while burdening consumers with huge costs; in Germany alone these already stand at €20bn a year. The EU energy system now needs reforms that focus on the elimination of market distorting elements such as the over-subsidising of renewable energy and the lack of balancing responsibility for intermittent energy generation by solar and wind power.

“With European governments recognising industrial growth as the key to resolving the economic crisis as well as lowering global carbon emissions, adequate measures are needed to back the reindustrialisation of Europe.”

Page 34: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

32 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

Capacity mechanisms should be considered only as a last resort, and only after promoting cheaper demand-side solutions. Provided the conditions are designed adequately, energy-intensive industries can, on a voluntary basis, provide important and cost-efficient flexibility.

Energy and industrial policies must be linked. With European governments recognising industrial growth as the key to resolving the economic crisis as well as lowering global carbon emissions, adequate measures are needed to back the reindustrialisation of Europe. Energy is one of the main levers for this, and it’s essential that discussion of European priorities should focus on high energy prices. Completing the internal energy market is one of the elements, but it is not enough. Structural political initiatives that target global competitiveness are urgently needed. ■

Source: European Commission

Energy-intensive industries are most exposed

Page 35: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

33EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

THE THREE AGES OF EUROPE’S SINGLE ELECTRICITY MARKET

It is still far from perfect and has been painfully slow in taking shape, but an EU-wide power market has now emerged. Jean-Michel Glachant of the Florence School of Regulation nevertheless warns that renewable energy and a “smarter” grid remain challenges to its further development.

It took us a while to build an EU internal market for electricity. According to the Single European Act strategy of Commission President Jacques Delors, it should have been implemented back in 1992… but that turned out to be only the first stirrings of a 25-year process. There are many “good reasons” why Europe has been so slow, and they are set out in the first part of this paper, entitled “Not easy to do … 1990-2015”. But there’s no denying that today we are entering the last mile of this slow process, even if anti-market arrangements still prevail in many countries. The paper’s second part – “All done by 2015?” – asks whether this whole construction is robust enough, while the third part “Done forever? From 2015 to 2030” will suggest that the EU’s internal electricity market may yet be seriously challenged by two waves of disruptive innovations – renewables and the “smartening” of the energy system.

Not easy to do… 1990 – 2015Taking a quarter-century to build Europe’s internal market in electricity may seem an incredibly long journey as well as an example of the EU’s inability to accomplish serious industry reforms. But we should remember that no other “federal-style” government of a major country has achieved an internal market for electricity.

Jean-michel glachantDirector of the European University Institute’s Florence School of Regulation where he holds the Loyola de Palacio Chair

Page 36: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

34 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

The U.S., Canada, Brazil, Russia, India or China have none of them succeeded in opening up a continent-wide electricity market.

Let’s turn first to all the good reasons for the EU’s slowness. The project aimed to open up national monopolies’ territories to foreigners, and that of course was widely seen as a radical project that inevitably triggered opposition. The second reason was that there was no wave of technological innovation – unlike in the case of telecoms – to challenge the incumbent energy giants. Third, electricity is a difficult product to trade as it requires hundreds of technical, legal and economical rules and standards to be agreed before it becomes tradable. Electricity is, after all, no more than a coordinated flow of electrons jumping from one atom to the other inside the millions of metallic wires of a gigantic interconnected network. This very demanding market arrangement meant that electricity was for decades considered to be a typical “anti-market” product that was best suited to monopolies and even cartels.

In truth, it has been the communications revolution that has opened the way to new market arrangements in the electricity industry, and made them feasible. New communications technologies have given us the tools to register every move of electricity generators and consumers alike – and so permitting one generator and one consumer to trade bilaterally inside a market. The fourth reason is that the various national arrangements between industry players and public authorities cannot readily be merged into a common scheme of interoperable markets.

Several successive packages have been needed to get all EU countries to implement compatible market arrangements. Germany, for instance, did almost nothing to promote compatibility because it chose not to have any regulatory authority but only a cartel of industry representatives. A plague of national barriers fragmented the EU for decades, which is why we needed four packages – the Commission’s three energy ones plus the infrastructure

“Electricity is a difficult product to trade as it requires hundreds of technical, legal and economical rules and standards to be agreed before it becomes tradable. Electricity is, after all, no more than a coordinated flow of electrons jumping from one atom to the other inside the millions of metallic wires of a gigantic interconnected network.”

Page 37: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

35EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

package – to make it work at continental level. The rapid expansion of gas-fired power plants in the EU has nonetheless added a common industry factor between many countries and helped them to converge on compatible arrangements. Since the EU’s gas market reforms are far less advanced than those in electricity, we ended up with settling for a bit of help from the “gas dash” instead of a complete revolution. And by the end of this first period, the speed at which the industry consolidated into EU mega-giants was much faster than the speed at which national market arrangements converged towards a common EU market platform.

All done by 2015?If we ask ourselves whether the arrangements being implemented according to the third energy package and the infrastructure package add up to an “EU market”, the answer is yes. In the first place, we Europeans already have a set of national “day ahead” wholesale markets that are mostly connected by “implicit access” to physical interconnections: Any bid accepted in an exchange is simultaneously taken into account by the other exchanges and by the transmission network operators that manage the interconnections. Whenever there is significant congestion of the EU network the European market splits into smaller regional or national markets until the congestion is ended.

Second, we have more and more intraday and “real time” arrangements by which offers of capacity and energy services cross the borders of the electrical zones managed by the TSOs. Third, the network is itself becoming more and more “Europeanised”. New grid operation codes are being conceived at EU level, and a common planning of the EU grid is taking place under the “Ten Year Network Development Plan”. A set of “Projects of Common Interest” are also due to adapt our infrastructures better to the internal market’s needs.

Having said all this, it’s nevertheless true that anti-market arrangements still survive in many European countries. At the retail level, one can still see government price controls in France and many other countries. Sometimes these regulated retail prices are not even aligned on wholesale prices, and result in billions of euros in “tariff deficits”, as is notably the case in Spain. At the wholesale level, byzantine market arrangements can add up to a “re-regulated access regime”, not only in France and Spain but in the UK too in light of its planned new nuclear power stations. These national distortions have significant effects, but they cannot entirely

Page 38: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

36 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

block the internal market’s functioning. However imperfect the EU’s internal market may be, there can be no doubt that we are moving towards it.

Done for ever? From 2015 to 2030But it is far from guaranteed that this internal market for energy will work forever. The many national compromises that have been realigned and harmonised in successive EU compromises dealt with the past, and therefore were aimed at opening up an EU market as conceived in the 1990s. What we now face in the EU is the new energy policy designed in the Spring of 2007 at the European Council in Berlin – the 20-20-20 strategy to be in place by 2020. Add to that the wave of “smart” innovations and there’s a risk we’ll still end up with an internal market headache.

The reasons for saying so are, first, that renewables are being pushed in the electricity sector from outside the market. Both wind and photovoltaic energy (PV) run at the speed of their feed-in tariffs. With virtually no barriers to them from entering the electrical system, renewables enjoy considerable advantages: they are always guaranteed access to existing consumption, whereas thermal generation only has access to the remaining demand. In some EU countries, renewables also have the right to connect to the grid, and the grid owner has a duty to invest accordingly. Step by step, a significant proportion of Europe’s thermal power plants are selling less and less energy while providing more and more “flexible capacity” for the electrical system. Some countries like the UK and France are looking at bridging that power generation revenue gap by re-organising their national market’s capacity arrangements. Obviously enough, this might well break up the EU’s internal market as some thermal generators would still be paid only for the energy they can sell, while others would get both those energy revenues and also a national capacity payment.

Second, even if there were to be no capacity splitting of the market, the present wholesale market might well undergo profound changes under the pressure of the growing share occupied by renewables. When large amounts of energy generated by renewables enter the wholesale market, that greatly depresses the market price. The variable cash cost of generating electricity with renewables is low, and a competitive energy market will use the variable cost of marginal power generation to price the market as a whole. That price can then easily drop close to zero if the market is flooded by renewable energy. It can even fall below zero

Page 39: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

37EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

into negative prices: when the generators pay the buyers! Because thermal plants face difficulties when reducing their output – they have to contend with huge output start-up costs and other dynamics – they may prefer to pay for the right to keep their plants running. But in depressed conditions of this sort, how could the wholesale Day Ahead market that is the backbone of the EU internal market maintain its central position in the chain of electricity market arrangements that stretches from futures to real time?

Third, an important share of renewable energy isn’t fed in to the transmission grid but at distribution grid level. To get an idea of the importance of this, we should understand that historically the transmission system operators managed electrical flows in a way that more or less replicated the trades in the wholesale market. In the electrical system of the future, these flows will increasingly be operated on distribution grids. With the expansion of smart technologies, this challenge may perhaps be overcome. As we can already see that the distribution grids are going to be the core of the EU internal market, the question we should ask is how will they operate and how will they be regulated and monitored? The problem will be to avoid a situation in which several thousand distribution operators throughout Europe fragment the internal market by spontaneously diverging through myriad different policies. Another step that could push us into this fragmentation scenario is that the smartening of the electrical system will also push millions of consumption units through the smart metres and other devices. Many of these consumers will also be producers, thanks mainly to the PV panels that are famously turning them into “prosumers” – and they may therefore have an impact on both the offer and demand sides of these changing energy markets. Nobody yet knows how the corresponding new services, whether communication-related or energy-related, and new markets that are immediately responsive to demand will evolve – will each EU country be different, and each distribution operator?

Building Europe’s very large internal market for electricity has been a slow process of some 25 years, but it has been achieved, and only in the EU but nowhere else. We Europeans conceived our internal market arrangements “our way”, even

“as we can already see that the distribution grids are going to be the core of the EU internal market, the question we should ask is how will they operate

and how will they be regulated and monitored?”

Page 40: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

38 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

though many other ways were originally envisageable. Europe could for example, have opened up the wholesale market without opening the retail market. Or it could have made opening the wholesale market mandatory with a centralised exchange system operating a single price algorithm, just as England did for more than 10 years.

In the end, though, we Europeans did it in a way that works, contradicting the thousands who predicted failure, disruption and chaos.

I would conclude, though, by repeating that what we now call the EU internal market is just a compromise between all the other national-level compromises; it’s not a perfect mechanism capable of serving us all whatever the prevailing conditions. It may suffer greatly in the coming years from the effects of a massive increase in renewable energies or from a de-centralisation of the production – consumption loop. The future, now that the European Commission is trying to stimulate debate on the EU’s 2030 horizon, is far from clear. ■

Source: European Commission

Prices affect competitiveness

Page 41: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

39EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

TWO SOLUTIONS FOR EUROPE’S ENERGY “TRILEMMA”

National capacity payments are a slap in the face for energy market liberalisation, and will hinder further interconnections. Allowing suppliers from any member state access to capacity markets would help reduce market distortions, say Mike Lawn and Jonas Rooze.

The European Commission has long championed the shift of the EU’s energy market from one dominated by vertically integrated national monopolies to one where the market is separated into different competitive layers, making member state boundaries irrelevant. But national measures in support of renewable energy sources, along with the deep and prolonged recession, has so distorted the wholesale energy market that EU countries are increasingly worried about their own security of supply. This is leading to the creation of still more national policies that run counter to the dream of a Europe-wide free market in energy. The EU and its national governments both need to act to prevent fears over security of supply from leading to an expensive overbuilding of thermal power generating capacity.

mike lawnHead of Power and Gas Services at Bloomberg New Energy Finance

Jonas roozePolicy Analyst at Bloomberg New Energy Finance

Page 42: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

40 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

There has been much talk of an energy “trilemma” involving choices between trying to reduce carbon emissions at the same time as ensuring security of energy supply and keeping control of energy costs. But this trilemma looks more like a game of “whack-a-mole”, with the policy hammer coming down on one issue only to see unintended consequences pushing out of the ground elsewhere.

The policy drive to tackle decarbonisation – symbolically through EU-wide carbon pricing – has in reality had to contend with a patchwork of effective but highly market-distorting national subsidies for renewable energy. This has led to huge amounts of capital investment in the renewables sector, as shown in our clean energy investment figures below. For traditional generators, this means that thermal

“the policy drive to tackle decarbonisation – symbolically through EU-wide carbon pricing – has in reality had to contend with a patchwork of effective but highly market-distorting national subsidies for renewable energy.”

Figure 1: European new clean energy investment ($bn)

Source: Bloomberg New Energy Finance.Note: Total values include estimates for undisclosed deals and adjustment for re-invested equity but exclude corporate and government R&D.

Page 43: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

41EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

generation has been pushed up the supply curve, earning lower margins on fewer running hours. Although renewable power is delivered into the energy market at zero (and often negative) marginal cost, the consumer receives it at the cost of the subsidy – a price that is well above the prevailing power prices and that, through its impact on retail prices, causes a backlash against the whole support system.

The latest “mole” to emerge concerns the serious security-of-supply issues that thermal power closures and mothballing will raise within the next few years. These closures are in part driven by policy – notably the European Commission’s Large Combustion Plant (LCP) Directive reducing oil and coal capacity, and Germany’s energiewende, or energy transition policy for shutting down nuclear plants. Then there’s the marginal issue costs that is pushing the owners of gas-fired generators across Europe to mothball or even close loss-making units.

In the past, these closures would have marked the bottom of the cycle and resulted in increasing margins and running hours for the remaining plants, thus

Figure 2: Western European capacity payment schemes – state of play

Source: Bloomberg New Energy Finance, EurelectricNote: Countries displaying two colours are transitioning to or have proposed capacity markets. Germany is formalising its currently ad-hoc reserve scheme, while considering developing a full-blown capacity market.

Page 44: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

42 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

encouraging investment in new capacity and ensuring that power cuts remain low enough to keep consumers, and therefore politicians, comfortable. This time around, though, investors fear that the continued high generation of renewables will permanently distort market price signals, making thermal generation unprofitable in the foreseeable future, and leading to capacity shortfalls when low renewable generation coincides with high demand.

The tool being proposed for addressing these fears is capacity mechanisms. These allow generators to be paid for the reliability they provide to consumers, so in other words, generators would be paid extra just for being there. But this proposed fix could lead to the unwanted consequence of a risk that we would be paying for more capacity in Europe than is economically viable, leading to distortions in the single energy market and a further increase in consumer’s bills.

Rewarding reliable power plants in the face of the rising penetration of renewables is common to much of Europe, but these are solutions that are being proposed at national level. It’s a slap in the face for energy market liberalisation and the integration of the European power market. Any moves toward national capacity payments, may guarantee security of supply in each jurisdiction, but discourages further interconnection and suggests that countries don’t feel they can rely on their EU partners in the event of a fall in power supply: a very different approach from the one that has seen Europe integrate natural gas networks that depend heavily on one another for supply during cold periods. This proved highly effective during the winter of 2012/13 when the UK came close to running out of gas and was bailed out by supplies through its European connections.

Under the current proposals, each EU country will have to pay a high price for sufficient domestic capacity when low renewable energy generation coincides with high demand. And even though integrated transmission networks reduce the frequency of high demand/low renewable energy generation periods by allowing the cross-border transfer of renewable and thermal generation, the value of these interconnections will fall. The rush to national solutions for capacity, with little or no inclusion of international generators, will hinder future development of interconnection capacity.

Different mechanism designs and disparate capacity prices will lead to diverse energy prices, further distorting the Europe-wide energy market and leading to

Page 45: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

43EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

results that are diametrically opposed to the market opening that the third energy package promised.

The various national renewable energy support schemes that now exist across the EU have been a boon for the development of the renewables industry, allowing countries to experiment with the best scheme for their particular needs. Unfortunately they have also led to distortions in energy production across the region. A good example is the vast wind energy build-out in northern Germany which has caused severe problems for the transmission networks of neighbouring countries, sometimes delivering negative pricing. But it has also enabled southern Germany to benefit from cheap power that otherwise could not be delivered there due to transmission constraints.

Although technically the door has been left open for European countries to meet their binding renewables targets by trading generated energy, there has to date been no attempt to set up actual trading schemes despite emerging renewable surpluses in countries such as Spain, and emerging deficits in others like the Netherlands. Yet there are early signs of change, notably between the UK – where “Nimbies” don’t want to see any more wind farms in their backyards spoiling England’s green and pleasant land – and Ireland, which seems happy to take British cash for Irish windmills. This change gives hope to finding the first part of a two-part solution.

The EU should now push hard to develop cross-border trading of renewable power, with the condition that it must be physically deliverable and not just an on-paper transfer. This proviso would prevent the adverse effects of excessive renewables building leading to power generation that has nowhere to go – something that would inevitably follow if renewables trading were a purely paper exercise. Without the physical delivery constraint, the southern half of the continent would very likely be so flooded with solar photovoltaic power that its infrastructure and demand would both be unable to absorb, aggravating recurrent capacity issues in these countries.

“the various national renewable energy support schemes have been a boon for the development of the renewables industry, allowing countries to

experiment with the best scheme for their particular needs. Unfortunately they have also led to distortions in energy production across the region.”

Page 46: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

44 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

This brings us to the second part of the solution: capacity mechanisms as a response to the distorting impact of subsidies for renewables. Capacity payments could be made more efficient if the EU were to stand behind the demand for equal treatment of suppliers across the Union. Anyone who can deliver reliable capacity to a country must be allowed to participate in that country’s mechanism, no matter where the capacity is – again with the proviso that it is physically deliverable to that member state at times of need.

This would encourage national capacity mechanisms to become compatible with one another, allowing countries with excess capacity to make money supporting their neighbours, and minimising the new build needed to maintain reliable supplies. But, perhaps most important of all, it would provide clear market signals for the construction of interconnections that would allow mutual support in times of need and facilitate the transmission of low-carbon power.

Implementing the physical trading across borders of both renewable power and reliable capacity faces complicated, but not insurmountable, regulatory challenges. The European Network of Transmission System Operators for Electricity (ENTSO-E) and the Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators (ACER) could together be asked to take on the task of watching closely for any "gaming" that may emerge.

Without a strong and immediate stance on these issues by the EU and national governments, it’s likely that the concerns of national policymakers and regulators will quickly push Europe into a situation in which national schemes for renewable support and reliable capacity distort the European electricity market even more. This will lead to unnecessary costs to consumers, who will be forced to pay for renewable capacity that should be more cost-effectively managed elsewhere, and for thermal capacity that quite simply would not be needed if Europe’s energy market were more integrated. ■

“the EU should now push hard to develop cross-border trading of renewable power, with the condition that it must be physically deliverable and not just an on-paper transfer.”

Page 47: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

45EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

A SUSTAINABLE ENERGY SYSTEM NEEDS EFFICIENT MARKETS

Decarbonisation in the power sector will reduce flexible, fossil power generation, and replace it with intermittent power generation like wind power. To maintain security of supply, a much stronger European transmission grid will be needed, along with greater flexibility in generation, consumption and storage systems. Market prices will have to be an important driver for this change, explains Statnett’s Auke Lont.

The decarbonisation of Europe’s power generation by 2050, along with the reduction of emissions in the rest of the energy sector, is important, commendable but also challenging. Decarbonisation will demand very large investments in emission-free electricity generation and transmission, in energy efficiency and increasingly in energy storage. We need new and improved technology in most segments of the energy system as well as smart, consistent and predictable regulation to create the right framework for the EU’s internal energy market to operate efficiently.

Electricity market prices are essential to coordinating operational and investment decisions for generation, transmission and consumption right across Europe. For electricity, where generation and consumption have to be tightly in balance, the marginal cost of supply varies substantially over time and between different regions. This reflects differences in generation costs between technologies, start-up costs for power plants and variations in consumption. To minimise the total energy costs, power prices should reflect

auke lontChief Executive Officer of Statnett

Page 48: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

46 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

the marginal cost of supply as well as capacity constraints on generation and transmission.

When consumption is low and renewable power production is high we may increasingly see excesses of power so that marginal generation costs fall close to zero. At the other extreme, at times of high consumption and low renewables generation, the most expensive thermal power plants must be started up. And in the future we will need greater storage capabilities and increased consumer flexibility if we are to maintain security of supply in these situations.

The challenge of balancing supply and demand will increase as intermittent power generation grows and the share of fossil powered electricity generation decreases. There are broadly two challenges: the first is using the available power surplus efficiently when intermittent power generation is high and consumption is low. The second is maintaining security of supply when intermittent generation is low and demand is high. The most important of these challenges is to secure enough power supply when intermittent generation is low. The cost of forced rationing of power is huge in any modern society, and that cost will probably be even higher in the future as more economic activity and private consumption will rely on electricity.

Until 2030 or so, increases in gas-fired generation capacity may play an important role as a source of flexible power generation. But it is important to develop other solutions as well, in particular for the long-term.

The problems of power surpluses and then shortages can have very different consequences, although the same solutions can often be used to address both challenges.

A stronger European transmission grid is widely recognised as a core solution balancing supply and demand.

� A stronger grid contributes by averaging local variations in intermittent generation. At a given time, one European region may have little wind and another a lot. And while one region may be dominated by wind power, another region may be dominated by solar or hydro power.

Page 49: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

47EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

� A stronger grid also promotes a more efficient use of existing flexibility because available flexibility in one region can help in another. More interconnections, along with power prices that reflect the real value of flexibility, can also create opportunities and incentives to develop flexibilities in regions that have specific advantages such as pumped storage.

A stronger transmission system reduces the risk of shortages and eases excess generation problems by allowing exports to regions where prices are higher. Different types of energy storage can help tackle both the excess and the shortage challenges, because storage facilities can buy power to fill up their reservoirs when prices are low and then deliver to the market when prices are high. Price variations govern the short term operation of storage facilities and determine the profitability of new storage capacity.

Combined heat and power production (CHP) and the heating market offer an interesting opportunity for flexibility, notably in countries with a well-developed district heating system and in industries that consume large amounts of heat. By using the heat from power generation, CHP plants achieve high total energy efficiency, and coal in CHP will increasingly be replaced by gas and biomass to reduce CO2-emissions.

Producing electricity in CHP plants is often governed by demands for heat alone, which results in an inflexible supply of power. Yet CHP plants may become more flexible, and they may help solve both the excess and shortage problems. With storage of heat, more power may be generated in hours with high power prices, and the extra heat may be stored for later use. At times when power prices are low, power generation may be reduced or even stopped, and the demand for heat may be covered by stored heat. And by installing separate cooling systems, a CHP plant will be able to operate as a traditional thermal power plant, generating electricity whenever the power price is high enough.

“the cost of forced rationing of power is huge in any modern society, and that cost will probably be even higher in the years ahead as even more

economic activity and private consumption will rely on electricity.”

Page 50: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

48 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

The investment in separate cooling will only be profitable if power prices are very high in some periods.

When power prices are very low, a CHP plant can also stop generating power and heat from fuel, and instead produce heat from electricity. In district heating and in smaller heating systems without CHP, biomass or gas may be replaced by electricity from the grid when power prices are low. Heat storage would increase this flexibility. Heat pumps have low marginal cost when producing heat from electricity, and therefore can operate whenever there is a need for heat other than when power prices are very high. Then demand for heat may be covered by stored heat or by an alternative fuel like gas.

In some countries, like Germany, the heating sector is larger than the power sector, so the potential for flexibility in the power sector is considerable and is also in the nature of low-hanging fruit. But development of this flexibility also requires market prices that fully reflect power excesses and shortages. In the longer term, a stronger integration of electricity, gas and heating may be crucial to exploit the advantages of these energy carriers, in particular, their flexibility.

Having the flexibility to reduce demand when power prices are high contributes to the security of supply. Smart metering and smart control of consumption are essential to exploit this potential for flexibility, especially where small consumers are concerned. But smart metering is not enough. With just a few exceptions, reductions in power consumption involve significant costs in terms of lost production or lost consumer welfare. This means that very high prices at times of limited supply may be necessary to trigger investment in flexibility and its efficient use.

Along with a stronger and smarter grid, market prices will have an important role to play in balancing the electricity market. From a market perspective, prices should be allowed to skyrocket when there are shortages while also

“this means that very high prices at times of limited supply may be necessary to trigger investment in flexibility and its efficient use.”

Page 51: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

49EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

reflecting the full cost of CO2 emissions. But there are other important considerations that may lead the EU and governments to create regulations that reduce the strength of the price signals. In other words, subsidies for renewable energies may be justified by the need to speed-up technological developments or reduce the risk of carbon leakage. A similar justification can be advanced for energy efficiency targets. Subsidies for renewables and energy efficiency targets mean that a given emission target can be reached with a lower carbon price than through a climate policy based purely on carbon pricing. A side effect of this is that the power price, particularly in peak hours when less efficient fossil generation is needed, will not reflect the full cost of emissions.

Governments have questioned the ability of the current energy market to deliver the required security of supply in the future. Among the proposed solutions are capacity payments to promote investment and delay disinvestment. This concern for security of supply is understandable, and it is important to establish regulatory regimes that give investors the confidence to invest. But it is also important that regulations promote innovative, efficient and sustainable solutions and take advantage of all possible options regarding consumption, transmission, storage and generation. If they’re poorly designed, capacity payment systems can favour fossil generation and inefficient national solutions, and they may also lead to peak prices that are too low, because they do not reflect the real cost of capacity and the real cost of CO2 emissions. This may significantly reduce market-based incentives to develop capacity and flexibility.

Against this background, how can regulation aimed at 2030 and beyond exploit the EU internal market’s economic advantages while still allowing for the renewable support schemes and interventions needed for security of supply?

“it is also important that regulations promote innovative, efficient and sustainable solutions and take advantage of all possible options regarding consumption, transmission, storage and generation.”

Page 52: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

50 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

Guidelines for such a design should include the following:

� Market design, transmission investment incentives, support schemes for renewables and carbon pricing should be evaluated as a single package because the development of the energy system will be affected by regulation as a whole.

� A stronger and smarter European grid is essential because increased interconnection is key to more stable and efficient markets. Smart systems to exploit consumer flexibility must be established.

� With greater market integration, the economic advantages of harmonising national support schemes and other regulations increase.

� High and fairly predictable carbon prices are essential if Europe is to stay on track for the 2050 target. A high carbon cost creates a broad incentive to innovate and invest in energy efficiency, low carbon generation, and in flexibility too.

� To grow, renewable power needs to grow up. Subsidies should not replace market prices, but rather be in addition to them, thereby promoting renewable power generation where and when power prices are high. There should be no subsidy when power prices are negative and no priority for renewables in the grid because that is taken care of with support schemes and carbon pricing. Renewable energy should pay for its system costs like any other method of power generation. These changes in regulation promote efficient investments and operation.

� There may be a need to turn support schemes more in the direction of flexibility and maintaining security of supply rather than focusing on kWh. The current regulation only sees pumped storage as a use of energy, not as a tool to promote a sustainable energy system.

� If introduced, schemes of capacity payments must be carefully designed. Schemes should not be limited to conventional national power generation, but rather should promote technology-neutral and cost efficient, sustainable and innovative solutions for consumption, storage and generation. The procurement of capacity should not

Page 53: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

51EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

unjustifiably discriminate against suppliers from other countries, and where possible schemes should be harmonised.

� It may be very difficult to develop general support schemes that address the broad range of potential flexibility and capacity, particularly yet unknown solutions or contributions from small consumers or generators. Given this difficulty, regulations should make sure peak prices are high enough to encourage the necessary flexibility. ■

Source: European Commission

our energy mix will evolve

Page 54: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

52 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

INTEGRATING ENERGY AND CLIMATE POLICY TO DRIVE LOW-CARBON GROWTH IN EUROPEEurope’s efforts to control emissions are failing, yet the necessary technologies are already here – decarbonising the power system and then using it to run more of our economy is the key, say Johannes Meier and Arne Mogren.

It made grim headline news when newspapers reported this spring that the average CO2 reading in the atmosphere over a 24-hour period passed 400 parts per million at Mauna Loa in Hawaii, where observations have been recorded since 1958.

The best available evidence suggests that the amount of CO2 in the air hasn’t been so high for at least three million years. The reading from Mauna Loa is a sobering reminder that our efforts to bring human-produced emissions under control are failing so far. The period since the Industrial Revolution, the burning of fossil fuels has caused a 40% increase in atmospheric CO2.

Johannes meierChief Executive Officer of the European Climate Foundation

arne mogrenDirector of the European Climate Foundation's Power Programme and Member of the Energy Roadmap 2050 ad hoc Advisory Group

Page 55: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

53EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

Decarbonisation is among the greatest challenges of our time. What’s needed is clear: we must reduce emissions substantially. But the question remains: how are we going to do this before it’s too late? Specifically, how can we factor the decarbonisation goal into Europe’s ongoing efforts to create an effective internal energy market for gas and electricity? This article summarises current developments and lays out three “must-haves” for structuring the internal energy market in the run-up to 2030.

Europe has committed to bring greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions down by 80-95% by 2050, consistent with the internationally agreed target to limit global warming to below 2°C. A number of studies by the European Commission, EURELECTRIC, the European Climate Foundation and others point in the same direction: far-reaching decarbonisation in the run-up to 2050 is feasible building on known technologies. Higher shares of renewable energy, substantial energy efficiency improvements and better and smarter energy infrastructure are no-regrets options for transforming the European energy system. The role of gas with Carbon Capture and Storage (CCS) and nuclear power not only depends on acceptance by the general public but also on the extent to which these alternatives make economic sense.

Electrification and decarbonisation of the power system are at the very heart of a decarbonisation strategy for our economies. That implies a major build-out of renewables in most parts of Europe.

Decarbonisation will obviously not happen overnight. To drive the process, we need a step-wise approach, with clear targets and milestones. The EU already has a framework for steering energy and climate policies up to 2020, so the logical next step is to create a framework for 2030 that will give investors the confidence they need for funding over the long haul.

With or without decarbonisation, significant investments are needed to modernise Europe’s energy system, and these investments will have an impact on energy prices up to 2030. A decarbonised energy system doesn’t of itself lead to higher costs, but the cost mix will be different because capital expenditure will be up while operational expenditure will be down. Against this background, we face the big challenge of building confidence among investors that the decoupling of growth from traditional ways of using fossil fuels can and will happen. Well-functioning trade mechanisms, transparency and transaction efficiency are crucial to building investor confidence. In short, competitive markets must be at the core of the decarbonisation process.

Page 56: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

54 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

But markets won’t achieve decarbonisation on their own. We need clarity on the overall architecture, aligning the energy and climate agendas. Power systems in Europe are already becoming more integrated thanks to a process that started a long time ago. Its main drivers are economies of scale because the sharing of resources and trading can lower the total system cost substantially.

Electricity is becoming integrated with gas and heat. In the long run, we will also see the electrification of transport. With decarbonisation as a major driver, electricity is a tool for efficiency gains, and higher volumes of variable power supply mean that different forms of demand response can add value. The ongoing internationalisation of

“With or without decarbonisation, significant investments are needed to modernise Europe’s energy system, and these investments will have an impact on energy prices up to 2030.”

large untapped potential for energy efficiency across the world

Source: European Commission

Page 57: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

55EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

the economy at large and its effect on users, especially energy-intensive companies, is also binding power markets closer together.

So market integration is already happening, but the effects are uneven and the EU’s capacity to handle the challenges of the decades ahead at European level is weak. The key will be setting a clear pathway for the no-regrets options while also leaving room for new technologies and market developments.

When the Single Market was established 20 years ago, electricity and gas were still viewed as national interests. All-inclusive monopolies and cartels dominated, while various forms of direct intervention – such as state ownership, subsidised capital and detailed price regulation – were governments’ main instruments for influencing these sectors, along with extensive cross-subsidies. The real market value of electricity was unknown – to the utilities, to the users and to the public. Outwardly, society appeared to have a firm grip on the utilities, but in reality the power sector to a large extent governed itself.

Significant investments will be required to renew or refurbish our energy system

Source: European Commission

Page 58: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

56 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

But, market innovation was on the way, beginning in the UK and in Norway. The approach taken to opening up the Nordic region was twofold – a shift from controlling details to using more general instruments such as taxes accompanied by the opening up of rigid market structures to competition and innovation. From the start, transparent market-based price creation was at the core of this shift. Unbundling, along with some additional measures, meant that control of physical flows in the system no longer led to dominance over economic transactions.

Without this opening up of the power sector, it is hard to imagine the progress so far on increasing renewables and reducing emissions would ever had taken place. There’s still a long way to go, but the basic principles are in place, and the decarbonisation agenda makes them more essential than ever. Without correct price signals, it is very hard for resources to be used efficiently.

We are still at only the initial stages of building more sustainable energy systems. There are critical challenges associated with large-scale deployment, such as fully integrating renewables into the EU’s electricity system in a way that deals with intermittency and improving co-operation among member states in meeting targets.

What’s needed, then, to make the EU’s internal energy market the centrepiece of a successful European decarbonisation drive? We should focus on three “must-haves”. First, European governments need to focus on integrating the internal energy market and other policy instruments into a powerful 2030 package. The complexity of the dependencies, inconsistencies and higher-order and side effects of the interventions and initiatives at different levels of governance is such that we see a lack of orientation and direction across actors. Support schemes like Feed-in Tariffs deliver, but they are costly and can have unforeseen consequences on market integration and on wholesale markets. The internal energy market and the deployment of renewables should be seen as correlated rather than in isolation. We need to move faster on integration to ensure that we have a European-wide market in place beyond 2020.

Second, we need a robust carbon price to drive the long-term, low-carbon investments that will enable us to decouple growth from fossil fuel consumption, and also to decarbonise the power sector. Emissions need to come with real costs.

Page 59: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

57EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

The internal energy market and the Emissions Trading System (ETS) are, in a way, two sides of the same coin. The current carbon price doesn’t provide the signals to investors needed to trigger massive low-carbon investments. A structural reform of the ETS so that investors can expect a robust and “de-politicised” carbon price would be a major step forward. Just using the carbon price as a backstop won’t drive change; the price needs to be sufficient, and complemented by policies targeting the parts of the abatement mix that the ETS doesn’t reach.

Third, we need a more forceful way of achieving physical integration of national markets. Plans and dialogues have been strengthened, but shared efforts to build infrastructure are still insufficient. We must view infrastructure as an enabler of decarbonisation and more efficient use of existing resources-generation as well as demand response. We also must do more to integrate our power, gas and heat systems. Grids and grid connections must be seen with a long-term perspective.

A powerful 2030 package combining market integration, a robust carbon price and strengthened infrastructure are prerequisites for European decarbonisation. All three ingredients are essential if we are to avoid the costs that will follow from a lost decade.

Once again, markets alone will not drive decarbonisation. We need to set targets – starting with decarbonisation – and transform those targets into market-relevant instruments. It’s worth repeating the insight from the Roadmap 2050 analyses that a 2030 GHG reduction target of less than 40% would over the longer term increase the costs of decarbonising the economy.

Complementary measures will be needed to scale up efficiency investments and to drive down costs for renewable technologies. One lesson learned from the 2020 package is the importance of avoiding a compromise motivated by political calculations. Complementary measures should be viewed systemically, not on a stand-alone basis, and there has to be a clear hierarchy and a comprehensive view of what should be achieved by when and how that can happen.

“We need a European “industrial policy” that tests new market solutions through step-by-step exposure to market risks. So far, this has happened

mainly at national level, but now the time has come to consider new solutions from a European perspective.”

Page 60: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

58 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

“Plans and dialogues have been strengthened, but shared efforts to build infrastructure are still insufficient. We must view infrastructure as an enabler

of decarbonisation and more efficient use of existing resources-generation as well as demand response.”

The internal energy market is a valuable resource for driving innovation and change in the EU, but we need to think much bigger than that, in terms of 2030. We believe that the internal energy market agenda should therefore be seen as an integrated element in the architecture of a new growth model for Europe, a growth model based on a low-carbon economy.

To help achieve this vision, we need a European “industrial policy” that tests new market solutions through step-by-step exposure to market risks. So far, this has happened mainly at national level, but now the time has come to consider new solutions from a European perspective. If those issues aren’t handled effectively, there’s a risk that the combination of integrated systems, open markets and national policies will trigger growing tensions and perhaps protectionist moves by some member states.

Without widespread support, and demand from member states for common solutions, it will be hard to pursue a low-carbon growth model. The economic crisis has fundamentally changed priorities for the time being. It may be tempting to use all resources to solve the immediate problems and provide local solutions, but is such a “balkanisation” of energy and climate issues really an attractive alternative for anyone? The fact is that European markets already depend on each other, and decarbonisation increases that dependency.

We need an ambitious idea for Europe, so a vision of low-carbon economic growth is exactly that. The internal energy market aligned with a robust carbon price and complementary measures to drive energy efficiency and renewable solutions, can and should play a crucial role in achieving the synergies needed for competitiveness, security of supply and sustainability. Hanging onto existing structures in business-as-usual scenarios isn’t a sufficient basis for a viable European future. A more positively forward-looking view of European energy is a growing imperative. ■

Page 61: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

59EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

WHAT EU GOVERNMENTS MUST DO TO GET THE INTERNAL ENERGY MARKET RIGHTUncoordinated national energy initiatives are harming the prospects for EU-level market integration. Europe’s politicians must pay more than lip service to a European energy market and take coordinated action, warns Hans ten Berge.

The EU’s leaders have already committed to transforming Europe into an energy-efficient, low carbon economy by 2050, they aim to have reduced Europe's greenhouse gas emissions by 80-95% compared to 1990 levels, and by as soon as 2020 they are targeted to have fallen by 20%.

An integrated EU-wide electricity market could lower the cost of decarbonisation because integrated, properly functioning markets and market-based instruments are more cost-efficient than any regulatory measures or political interventions. But the benefits of market integration go further than that: larger markets reduce prices by allowing more competition and greater economies of scale. They also offer more choice between different suppliers or contract types and are a better guarantee of security of supply. Rather than being seen as a secondary priority, market integration should be speeded up.

This doesn’t mean simply building more lines across national borders. Yes, an EU-wide electricity market requires a reinforced network – lines that can transport electricity from large offshore wind parks in the North Sea, for instance, to major consumption centres further south. But an EU-wide internal electricity market

hans ten BergeSecretary General of EURELECTRIC

Page 62: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

60 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

calls for more. It requires harmonised – or at least coordinated – EU-wide policies and policy instruments. Only they can create a level playing field for the free flow of electricity throughout the EU.

The list of potential coordination candidates is long: from support schemes for renewable energy and permit granting procedures for transmission lines to electricity trading rules and concerted efforts to reduce CO2 emissions. Unfortunately, national approaches still dominate in many of these areas. A truly common EU energy policy seems further away than even a few years ago, when the European Council of February 2011 agreed to complete the internal energy market by 2014.

Since then, member states seem to have taken two steps back for every single step forward. Germany has unilaterally started down its ‘Energiewende’ path, while the UK has proposed an electricity market reform whose measures effectively disregard the implications for other European markets. In short, national initiatives rather than European coordination seem to be the name of the game.

Instead of opening up borders to ensure security of supply, Europe’s governments are trying to achieve national energy self-sufficiency. Instead of letting market forces determine the correct price, governments are intervening in the market to set wholesale and/or retail prices. Instead of allowing the internal market to develop, governments are introducing discretionary – and sometimes retroactive – taxes with the stroke of a pen. The result is that the market is suffering and its role is diminishing. Market participants increasingly look to governments before they act, and their behaviour is increasingly driven by regulatory measures or interventions rather than market forces. This reluctance to move from uncoordinated national interventionist policies to market-based and common European ones persists in many areas. The expansion of renewables, for instance, is being driven by national subsidies rather than a single European

“an integrated EU-wide electricity market could lower the cost of decarbonisation because integrated, properly functioning markets and market-based instruments are more cost-efficient than any regulatory measures or political interventions.”

Page 63: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

61EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

scheme. This leads to a veritable war of subsidies between member states, which race to offer the most attractive schemes, regardless of location or actual technology needs. The results are often bizarre: Germany has more installed solar power than sunny Spain.

Grid expansion in Europe is similarly suboptimal: without an attempt to plan the grid from a European perspective, it seems likely that the strong national focus of regulators and transmission system operators will fail to address the essential infrastructure links needed at a regional or pan-European level. The result is uncoordinated and nationally focused grid expansions that prevent electricity from flowing where it is most needed. The missing interconnector between Spain and France is a case in point: though it’s vital to connect the Iberian peninsula with the rest of Europe, this project has been delayed for at least 20 years.

Market regulation is being driven by national decisions, with the effect of maintaining closed national markets and subverting plans for greater cross-border competition. The regulation of, say, renewables, capacity payments or price caps, is resolutely national. The same applies to actions for addressing security of supply. Rather than striving to speak with one voice, national solutions to generation adequacy concerns remain dominant, whether focused on capacity remuneration mechanisms, storage or other alternatives.

Looking beyond fairly narrow energy issues, even climate policy is coming under threat, despite being the only area in which there actually is an EU-wide market-based policy tool in the shape of the cap-and-trade EU Emissions Trading Scheme. Yet even this is being undermined by national decisions on carbon floors and carbon taxes, as well as by unclear interaction with targets on renewables and energy efficiency.

Why is all this so problematic and why should policymakers and citizens care? The answer is simple: because it is costly. Because purely national policy instruments are almost inevitably sub-optimal for Europe as a whole. European consumers are paying the price in higher electricity prices, and also through less choice or inferior quality of supply.

The EU’s internal energy market is now genuinely at a turning point. Either the EU changes course and pushes member states to align their national policies

Page 64: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

62 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

and targets with European ones or we will witness an erosion of the progress achieved so far, putting at serious risk the European Council’s 2014 target.

More than ever, a real push for market integration is now needed. The actions needed fall into four categories: market integration ‘proper’, along the lines of the EU’s Third Energy Package; renewables integration; generation adequacy; and grid investments.

First, and arguably most important of all, member states must correctly and rapidly implement existing EU energy market legislation. A step in this direction is for governments to remove such market distortions as regulated prices and price caps. More than half the member states still have regulated prices that completely obscure any price signal that the market could give, not least for investments.

The EU should also put pressure on member governments to move forward and implement the agreed ‘target models’ for day-ahead market coupling, intraday, balancing and forward markets. Key to this would be progress in north-west Europe, specifically in Denmark, Finland, Norway, Sweden, Britain, Belgium, France, Germany, Luxemburg and the Netherlands. Integration between these 10 countries is crucial to creating a full European energy market, and day-ahead and intraday market needs to be established among them by the end of 2013 if there’s to be any hope of an EU-wide market by 2014.

Second, the growing share of electricity from renewable sources needs to be integrated into the market. Renewable energy producers should meet the same requirements as other generators, notably on scheduling, nomination and balancing. This would not only help stabilise the electricity system but also would create a level playing field and a more cost-effective use of resources.

National support schemes for renewables should be aligned, putting an end to costly subsidy wars. As a first step, governments should start using the cross-border cooperation mechanisms foreseen in the EU’s 2009 Renewables Directive. The Commission should then steer the progressive convergence of national support schemes towards a single European model. And after 2020, support schemes for mature renewable technologies should be phased out. Instead,

Page 65: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

63EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

support should aim at promoting research, development and deployment of renewable technologies that are not yet market-ready.

Third, policymakers must address the investment gap that results from the fast-track implementation of renewables and increasing concerns about generation adequacy. In a growing number of European countries, the need for renewables has reduced the operating hours of conventional sources like coal and gas. This has made them increasingly unprofitable to run, calling into question future investment even though they are still crucial to the overall system. Conventional plants remain necessary to cope with the intermittency and unpredictability of renewables like wind and solar.

The result is that policymakers are struggling to find solutions that allow conventional plants to continue operating to safeguard electricity supplies. Unfortunately, member states rather than the EU have so far taken the lead in devising responses to this, most notably by setting up national capacity remuneration mechanisms, which are schemes that reward conventional generation for being available in times of need. The proliferation of these schemes across Europe without any coordination is worrying because if they are not market-based and technology-neutral they could distort and undermine the market. A regional approach is needed that would be compatible with the internal energy market. In the meantime, the European Commission is working to bring greater coherence to these on-going national initiatives, and EU governments would do well to support this regional aim.

Fourth and last, grid investments are inevitable if the internal electricity market is to function properly. Lengthy permit-granting procedures in most EU member states are among the major barriers to network development, including the interconnections that are key to a working internal energy market. The acceleration of interconnections should be a priority, and cutting red tape would also give an incentive for private investors to undertake infrastructure development not only

“implementing EU energy market legislation needs urgent action, as does the integration of renewables into the market along with a coordinated

approach to concerns over power generation adequacy.”

Page 66: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

64 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

in high-voltage, cross-border transmission grids but also in local, low-voltage distribution networks that are going to be increasingly important with the rise of renewables and the further development of demand response.

The EU must foster greater coherence between European and national energy policies, and promote the market’s central role in achieving EU energy policy objectives. Implementing EU energy market legislation needs urgent action, as does the integration of renewables into the market along with a coordinated approach to concerns over power generation adequacy. Grid investments that will help the internal energy market take off must be fostered too. Together all these actions are needed if Europe is to reap the benefits of a truly integrated electricity market.

The time for declarations is over; now it’s time to act. Governments must stop paying lip service in Brussels to the idea of integrated energy markets while rolling back any integration efforts at home. The current re-nationalisation of energy policies is costly, wasteful and inefficient – and ultimately it is the consumers who have to pick up the tab. In these times of tight public and private budgets, can elected politicians really afford to let consumers pay more than they must? ■

Source: European Commission

Boosting energy efficiency

Page 67: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

65EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

“THE STUFF WE HAVE, A STRONG WIND WILL BLOW IT TO PIECES”: TWO DECADES BEHIND SCHEDULE, WE NEED TO RE-THINK THE SINGLE ENERGY MARKETThe EU has made progress in integrating its markets, but there is still a long way to go, argues Jorge Vasconcelos. Europe needs a reinvented energy market and technological developments can help that to happen.

Shakespeare said it all in his little-known play “Pericles, Prince of Tyre”: “But shall I search the market?What else, man? The stuff we have a strong wind will blow it to pieces, they are so pitifully sodden.Thou sayest true; they’re too unwholesome, o’ conscience.”

All markets are social constructions of some sort, whether they are the slave markets of the past mentioned by Shakespeare or electricity markets of today. And like buildings, some markets are ancient, resilient, efficient and admired, while others are short-lived, fragile, defective and scorned. But unlike diamonds, markets are not forever: they exist to serve the social needs of their time.

Markets are an ingenious human achievement; they are neither a reproduction of natural processes nor the logical outcome of abstract reasoning. As Nobel laureate Ronald Coase pointed out, “the creation of new markets is frequently

Jorge VasconcelosFounder of the Council of European Energy Regulators and Member of the Energy Roadmap 2050 ad hoc Advisory Group

Page 68: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

66 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

complicated and sometimes even thwarted by ideological enmity, political resistance, fear of uncertainty, or mere ignorance.” His definition applies neatly to the EU’s internal energy market (IEM).

The IEM project set out to simultaneously meet two goals:

� To liberalise Europe’s electricity and natural gas markets, and so allow energy consumers to benefit from competitive prices through the play of market forces. It was an ambition being embraced by many governments around the world in the late 1980s and early 1990s.

� To contribute to the “ever closer union” proclaimed in the Treaty of Rome in 1957 and re-stated by the Single European Act of 1986 when December 31, 1992 was set as the deadline for the EU’s single market.

Twenty years later, the single European energy market is still not a reality. Political resistance, fears of uncertainty, ignorance and entrenched economic interests all bear a share of the responsibility. Yet even though it wouldn’t be accurate to describe the present situation as a single market, much has in fact been achieved over the past two decades, so it would be equally inaccurate to describe the result as an irremediable failure. From a legal standpoint, the EU has built the largest integrated electricity and natural gas markets in the world, serving the largest world economy, even if they are not yet fully integrated physically or in terms of price. EU member states’ national electricity and natural gas markets are fully liberalised, at both wholesale and retail level and some of these national markets have successfully built strong links with neighbouring markets, thus widening the choices available to consumers and enlarging suppliers’ customer basis.

But Europe now faces two simultaneous challenges. The first is to complete the IEM and achieve truly integrated European electricity and natural gas markets. This is both an economic necessity and a political imperative. The second is to reinvent the whole concept of the energy market to take account of recent and coming technological developments, together with the environmental goals set out by EU leaders in March 2007 (establishing an “integrated climate and energy policy”) and October 2009 (“to reduce emissions by 80-95% by 2050 compared to 1990 levels”).

Page 69: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

67EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

To complete the IEM, policymakers, industry and regulators need to deliver on a number of crucial actions. That means the strict and timely implementation of existing legislation, the abolition of all current market distortions and the prevention of new ones being introduced. Twenty years of legislation and extensive jurisprudence means it would be useful to bring all these elements into a coherent and simplified legal framework for energy. This task should not distract the European Commission from its essential role as watchdog and enforcer of EU law.

Appropriate regulation needs to be introduced at EU level. The Agency for the Cooperation of Energy Regulators (ACER) that was established in 2009 needs to be upgraded to make it a truly effective IEM regulatory agency, because having EU markets without EU regulators poses a major problem. If that isn’t done, market fragmentation will be a continuing threat and unilateral policies and regulatory decisions will jeopardise energy market efficiency and energy system reliability. This is an institutional change that will require strong political will and innovative legal solutions. Energy regulation at EU level is now as urgent as that of the EU’s financial markets.

Energy infrastructures must be expanded and upgraded, particularly where cross-border inter-connections are concerned, so as to enable the full integration of national markets. This is not so much a financial problem as a political, administrative and regulatory one.

Tight operational coordination at EU level needs to be introduced, with the clear assignment of responsibilities to the appropriate EU electricity and natural gas bodies and to the respective national system operators. Without proper operational coordination, existing and new transmission assets will remain under-utilised, with an increased risk of black-outs and gas supply disruptions.

Energy infrastructures must be modernised through the systematic introduction of modern information and communication technologies (ICT). This will improve the planning and operation of energy systems, whatever their configuration. It will also improve the functioning of Europe’s energy markets, both directly because more and more reliable information will be available to market agents, and indirectly through the more efficient use of physical infrastructure the better to enable energy trade. ICT also has a decisive effect on enabling demand

Page 70: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

68 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

participation in energy markets, the development of energy efficiency services and a large-scale deployment of electric vehicles. The “green economy” may well make a substantial contribution to growth and job creation in Europe.

Besides these points, there are a number of other features that represent a threat to electricity market efficiency and integration. Instead of becoming larger, more liquid and more robust, Europe’s electricity markets seem to be shrinking, losing liquidity and becoming more volatile and therefore fragile. By decreasing energy demand, the economic crisis is reducing market liquidity, and though it’s to be hoped this is temporary, there are other structural factors that can be expected to have a long-lasting impact on market liquidity.

The first of these is energy efficiency and conservation. Reducing energy demand by 20% as compared to the business-as-usual scenario is one of the EU’s 2020 energy and climate policy goals. Less demand means less market volume. A second factor is the increased amount of subsidised electricity, mainly from renewable energy sources and co-generation. Because it is directly subsidised, this does not compete with conventional generation in “conventional” markets. This type of “off-market”, “must-run” generation is expected to increase substantially up until 2020 and onwards.

Third, some large industrial consumers and electricity producers such as those based on nuclear power generation are promoting long-term contracts, and so further reducing conventional market liquidity. And fourth, increased protectionism may lead to a slow-down in the construction and use of cross-border interconnections.

With a 20-year missed deadline, “completing the IEM” can no longer have the same meaning as was initially foreseen. Energy markets were then expected to deliver competitive prices and provide customer choice. And the general belief

“Energy infrastructures must be modernised through the systematic introduction of modern information and communication technologies. this will improve the planning and operation of energy systems, whatever their configuration.”

Page 71: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

69EU's internal energy market: Tough decisions and a daunting agenda | 2013

was that efficient markets would also enhance security of supply and provide suitable environmental protection. But since then, public policies have changed and now energy markets are not only expected to deliver competitive prices but also make a decisive contribution to creating a low-carbon economy.

The impact of these policy changes is not to be ignored. In early 2011, the European Council stated that “reducing greenhouse gas emissions by 80-95% by 2050 compared to 1990 as agreed in October 2009 will require a revolution in energy systems, which must start now.”

Looking back at the difficulties encountered during the creation of electricity markets, and considering their current weaknesses and imperfections, some observers believe that Europe’s electricity markets will not be able to withstand the growing pressures of these changing public policy requirements. They warn that they will eventually collapse, leading to a “re-monopolisation” of the electricity industry. Others think that the present public policy goals are too ambitious and too expensive, and therefore cannot be achieved. They believe that policymakers will soon realise how such policies collide with hard market realities, and that governments and the EU will consequently have to recognise the need to soften these policies. It will be policies and not markets that will eventually collapse, according to those observers who stick to the “classical” energy market model.

So is a choice between market failure or policy failure the only one we are left with? Is there a way to escape this dilemma by reconciling efficient markets with ambitious policies?

In my view, both market sceptics and political cynics are wrong, because they underestimate the disruptive role of technology. It is very difficult – perhaps even impossible – to reconcile, at least in a cost-effective way, some policy goals with current electricity markets. But the introduction of new technologies will change the physical functioning of electricity systems, and as a result the functioning of electricity markets. The application of new technologies to energy systems, in particular ICT, will affect the way energy systems are planned and operated, and the way energy markets work. ICT has the potential to make energy and climate policies effective and electricity markets efficient. ICT may contribute simultaneously to improving market efficiency, facilitating the implementation of

Page 72: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

70 Friends of Europe | Greening Europe

public policies and adopting market-based mechanisms to implement renewable and energy efficiency policies.

Technology is not a magic solution to all market inefficiency problems or to policy implementation difficulties. What technology does allow for is the design and implementation of market-based mechanisms and incentives that enable a growing number of public policy goals to be met within the regulatory framework of liberalised electricity markets. Policy and regulatory innovation is needed to support technological innovation, thus keeping markets alive and functioning well, and to ensure that policies are implemented cost-effectively.

Identifying and optimising the benefits of ICT for energy systems and markets is the big challenge being faced by the energy industry and its regulators. Those who would deny the need for a revolution in energy systems sometimes pretend that ICT will have little or no impact upon energy markets, and so they advocate managing or regulating the energy industry on a basis of business-as-usual. They overlook, though, the dramatic impact of ICT upon our private lives, social relations and economic behaviour. These hopelessly antediluvian patriarchs seem to envisage the energy industry as a Noah’s Ark escaping the internet’s flooding. Others are so excited about ICT’s apparently infinite possibilities that they overlook the physical laws, economic restrictions and cultural inertia governing energy systems. They dream of the birth of a brave new “internet of energy” world.

What is urgently needed now is a realistic design for the transition process from today’s low-ICT, high-carbon energy systems to a high-ICT, low-carbon system of tomorrow.

“The stuff we have, a strong wind will blow it to pieces.” Strong wind and sunshine can literally blow conventional electricity markets to pieces if high penetration rates of wind and solar generation are attained without proper adaptation of “the stuff we have”. After 20 years, this “stuff” is pitifully sodden, too unwholesome and needs to be replaced anyhow. To find the appropriate replacement one will “search the market” for market-based solutions. But searching the market will nonetheless be interpreted as actively looking for “new stuff”, not as “old market soul-searching”. ■

Page 73: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting
Page 74: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting
Page 75: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

Friends of Europe – Les Amis de l’Europe

4, rue de la Science, B-1000 Brussels, Belgium

Bibliothèque Solvay, 137 rue Belliard, B-1040 Brussels, Belgium

tel.: +32 (0) 2 893 98 23 – Fax: +32 2 893 98 29

Email: [email protected]

Website: www.friendsofeurope.org

Page 76: EU'S intErnal EnErgy markEt: toUgh DEciSionS anD a DaUnting

With the support of the Europe for Citizens programme of the European Union

this project has been funded with the support of the European commission.the commission cannot be held responsible for any use which may be made of the information contained therein.